+ All Categories
Home > Documents > George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org

George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org

Date post: 09-Nov-2021
Category:
Upload: others
View: 3 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
13
Transcript
Page 1: George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org
Page 2: George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org

George G. Kaufman*

Housing has been one of the most volatileand, over the last ten years, most troubled ofindustries. The causes of housing's problemsare varied and complex, but one of them de­serves special mention-the imperfect function­ing of the mortgage market. Because most newresidential housing acquisition is financed bymortgage debt, conditions in the mortgage mar­ket are important to the housing industry. Thispaper examines one special aspect of the mort­gage market, the mortgage instrument. It con­siders, first, whether the characteristics of theconventional fixed interest rate mortgage(FRM) may have both limited and destabilizedthe supply of mortgage funds and, second,whether an alternative mortgage plan containinga variable rate may increase and smooth the

supply without reducing demand.'In this paper, we analyze the implications of

variable rate mortgages (VRMs) for bothlenders and borrowers. We pay particular em­phasis to the experiences resulting from the useof VRMs by six large savings and loan associa­tions and one large· bank in California whichhave been offering these mortgages since 1975.'The California experience is the most wide­spread use of VRMs in the country, and thusshould provide useful insights for other areas.Because many VRM characteristics are stipu­lated by law, we examine the implications ofthese constraints and recommend specificchanges in those features which appear to re­duce the efficiency of the instrument.

FRM and VRM: Theoretical Issues

Most mortgage funds are supplied by privatefinancial institutions. At year-end 1975, savingsand loan associations had extended 51 percentof all residential mortgages outstanding, com­mercial banks 17 percent, mutual savings banks10 percent, and life insurance companies 4 per­cent. Government supported agencies extended13 percent and other private lenders 5 percent.Although they are the largest lenders of mort­gage loans, thrift institutions (savings and loanassociations and mutual savings banks) andcommercial banks have complained of the rela­tive lack of profitability of mortgage lending,

"George G. Kaufman, Professor of Finance at the Uni­versity of Oregon, was Visiting Scholar at the FederalReserve Bank of San Francisco during Winter 1976. Hispaper is a shortened version of a study which is availablefrom the Bank's Research Department. Research assist­ance provided by Donna Luke.

5

and have at times appealed to the Federalgovernment for assistance. In response, the gov­ernment has introduced a host of mortgage sub­sidy programs and has limited the costs ofdepository mortgage-lending institutions by im­posing ceilings on the rates they may pay onsavings and time deposits. The latter restriction,popularly referred to as Regulation Q, not onlylimits cost increases for the bulk of the fundsavailable to depository institutions, but also pro­vides thrift institutions with a slight deposit rateedge over commercial banks as a means of en­couraging savings flows into the thrifts. Evi­dence suggests, however, that these restrictionshave not improved the operation of the mort­gage market. At times market rates of interesthave risen sharply above the Q ceilings, and

Page 3: George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org

funds have been redirected away from institu­tions not offering competitive rates. This hasexacerbated the volatility of mortgage flows.The growing evidence of the unsatisfactory per­formance of these government programs hasstimulated a search for other ways of assistingmortgage lending institutions which would havefewer side effects on the mortgage market.

Maturity and interest-rate intermediation

Because residential dwellings are both big­ticket items and long-lived assets, they arefinanced primarily by long-term mortgage loanscollateralized by the dwelling purchased. Manyof the institutions extending such loans raisetheir funds by selling securities in the form ofdeposits with considerably shorter maturities, sothat they engage in maturity intermediation. Inaddition, to the extent that the mortgages havea fixed rate of interest over their life, while rateson deposits may vary through time, the institu­tions also engage in interest-rate intermediation.Although these two activities in the past havebeen identical, they do not necessarily have tobe so. In fact, the VRM represents a device forseparating the two types of intermediation.

Economic theory tells us that the relationshipbetween a long-term rate and a short-term rateon securities which are similar in all respects butterm to maturity is determined largely by theexpected course of short-term rates during theremaining life of the longer-term security. Ifwe assume a world of perfect certainty in whichthe values of all future short-term interest ratesare known, the long-term rate is a geometricaverage of the current short-term rate and futureshort-term rates on out to the maturity of thelong-term security. This implies that, if a de­pository mortgage-lending institution is to breakeven, abstracting from costs of operations otherthan interest rates, the rate it charges on a fixedrate mortgage should be the geometric averageof the current deposit rate and the deposit ratesit expects to pay until the mortgage matures.

This relationship is illustrated in Figure 1.Time is measured on the horizontal axis andinterest rates on the vertical axis. 3 Consider aloan starting in period P and maturing in period

6

Figure 1

Log l1+ilA

P Z Q

Q. Assume that there is no prepayment provi~

sion, and that the current deposit rate at P is Aand that deposit rates are expected to risesteadily through the period C in Q. Again,abstracting from operating costs and a competi­tive return on capital, the appropriate fixed rateon the loan would be B. At the rate B, theexpected total return on the loan would equalthe expected total of deposits over the life ofthe loan, so that the institution would breakeven on its intermediation operations. The dol­lar gain in the triangle ABO would be exactlyequal to the loss in the triangle OCD.

Although the intermediary breaks even overthe life of the mortgage, in any arbitrary shorterperiod, e.g., one year, it may be incurring eithera profit or a loss. In our example, with depositrates expected to increase, the loan rate will beabove the initial deposit rate, so that the inter­mediary will be generating a profit. Throughtime, as deposit rates increase, the profit be­comes progressively smaller unti~ at Z the de­posit rate is equal to the loan rate. Thereafter,the deposit rate rises above the loan rate andthe institution experiences progressively largerlosses. Thus the appropriate accounting periodfor evaluating the performance of the inter­mediary is the life of the loan and not anyshorter period.

Under some circumstances the losses mayprecede the gains, with the loss and gain tri­angles reversed. In such a case, short-termloans from another financial institution or from

Page 4: George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org

a government agency may be needed to ease theinstitution's resulting liquidity problem. Itshould be noted, however, that the problem isone of liquidity and not of solvency.

Our analysis demonstrates that in a world ofcertainty the return on any successive combina­tion of shorter term investments summing to thematurity of the mortgage loan will be the sameas for the mortgage loan itself. This is true be­cause the long-term rate is an average of anycombination of composite shorter-term ratesand the latter, in turn, are averages of theircomposite shorter-term rates. Thus, the returnon a 1a-period loan is equal to that of two com­parable five-period loans-and the latter return,in turn, is equal to that of 1acomparable one­period loans. In a world of certainty, long-termmaturity and long-term interest-rate intermedia­tion are just as advantageous as similar shorter­term intermediation.

Figure 1 also shows that, if the loan ratechanges in synchronization with the deposit rate,the gain and loss periods are eliminated and the

institution breaks even at all times. In this in­stance, the institution engages only in maturityintermediation without interest-rate intermedia­tion.

Effect of uncertaintyWe can now remove the assumption of per­

fect certainty so that future rates are only ex­pected rates. If the intermediary's deposit rateexpectations are realized, the analysis is un­altered. The institution breaks even on its fixedrate mortgage lending but experiences sub­periods of gains and losses. If expectations arenot realized, then it no longer breaks even. Ifdeposit rates rise slower than anticipated, sayalong line AF in Figure 1, the gain triangle willbe enlarged and the loss triangle reduced. Theinstitution earns greater profits than expected.Conversely, if deposit rates rise faster than an­ticipated, say, along line AE, the loss trianglewill be greater than the gain triangle. The in­stitution will generate lasting losses and experi­ence a solvency problem. Because it is lasting,

7

Page 5: George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org

a solvency problem requires a different solutionthan a short-term liquidity problem.

When an intermediary extends a long-termloan at a fixed interest rate, it accepts the riskthat the underlying expected short-term interestrates may not be realized. Although this mayresult in gains or losses, many market partici­pants are risk averse and assign greater weightto an extra dollar loss than to an extra dollargain. A fixed rate mortgage contains two com­ponents for the borrower: (1) a long-term fi­nancing commitment and (2) insurance againstloss from higher than expected short-term inter­est rates. Like any insurance seller, the lenderwill charge a premium for the interest rate in­surance. The premium would be related to theexpected loss, or the probability of losses fromgreater than expected interest rate increasesmultiplied by the magnitude of the associatedloss. This premium is added to the long-termrate obtained by averaging the relevant expectedshort-term rates. If this is done and depositrates are realized, the gain triangle will exceedthe loss triangle. In Figure 2 the solid line ACis now the expected path of short-term rates,and the dotted lines above and below AC repre­sent the degree of uncertainty about that path.The rate BB I is purely expectational, based onexpected future short-term rates. This is thestandard explanation of the mortgage interestrate without risk. BD is the insurance premiumpayable by the borrower and is proportional tothe amount of risk. With the total market inter­est rate at PB I there is neither a profit to theintermediary nor a net loss to the fixed ratemortgage borrower, because the cost of provid­ing insurance for the former and the cost ofpurchasing insurance for the latter are thesame. If short rates turned out below expecta­tions, long rates would fall and the borrowerwould wish to refinance. With no prepaymentpenalty an underpriced premium would implythat realized losses exceeded expected losses,and the intermediary would incur net losses onits lending.

The analysis also indicates that the profit­ability of fixed rate mortgage lending is depen­dent only upon whether expected future interest

8

Figure 2

Log (1+j)

/

/ C

/~/ / / // I

6 '1 - - - - - :) - / "//- - l °1/ _/ .

rate changes are realized, and not on the shapeof the yield curve. Financial intermediariescan operate as profitably under descending orflat, as under "normal" ascending yield curves.Thrift institutions, in fact, expanded as rapidlyas commercial banks between 1905 and 1930,though the yield curve was downward slopingthroughout almost all of that period. Exceptwhere the yield curve is flat, realization of ex­pected interest rates shifts the yield curve, andconsequently, the level of profitability reflectsthe extent to which changes in the yield curveare greater or less than those consistent withthe realization of expected rates. Fixed ratemortgage lending can be profitable to inter­mediaries even if short-term rates rise morethan long-term rates, provided that the increasesdo not exceed expectations.

Implications of VRMVariable rate mortgages are long-term mort­

gage contracts in which the interest rate changesat prearranged periods, in sympathy withchanges in some designated market interest ratethat is referred to as the standard index.. 4 Unlikea series of consecutive short-term loans, a VRMavoids the transactions costs that accompany anew mortgage note. As Figure 1 indicates, aVRM would simplify the operations of the in­termediary by eliminating or greatly reducinginterest rate intermediation. Under the assump­tions that VRM interest rates 1) change con­currently with deposit rates and 2) are trans­lated into changes in the dollar amount (ratherthan in the number) of monthly payments, theinstitution's interest receipts and payments are

Page 6: George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org

perfectly synchronized and no interest rate riskarises.

What happens to the interest rate risk? Ifthere are no constraints on VRM interest ratechanges, all the risk is shifted to the borrower.The latter knows the amount of the first monthlypayment and the length of the mortgage, butnot the amount of the subsequent payments orof the total payments. In contrast, on a fixedrate mortgage he would know the amount of allpayments and the length of the payments. Ifinterest rates over the life of the mortgagechanged in line with market expectations, theborrower would pay the same average rate onthe VRM as on the FRM (less the FRM interestrate insurance premium), although the time pat­tern of the payments would be different. If

short-term interest rates increased more thanexpected, the VRM would be costlier to theborrower than the FRM, while if short-term in­terest rates increased less thiln expected, theVRM would be cheaper.

A compromise between an FRM and a fullVRM would involve a risk-sharing arrangementbetween the lender and borrower. 5 This couldbe accomplished by placing a symmetrical max­imum interest rate band on either side of therate on a new mortgage. Within the band, theborrower assumes the risk; outside the band, thelender assumes the risk. The wider the band, thegreater the risk assumed by the borrower. Thetwo polar cases are represented by an infinitelywide band, which is a pure VRM, and an infin­itesimally narrow band, which is a pure FRM.

The California ExperienceSix large state chartered savings and loan

associations in California began offering VRMsin early or mid-1975. Five of these associationsrank in the top ten in the country. (Their exam­ple was followed at year end by the Wells FargoNational Bank, the eleventh largest commercialbank in the nation.) These six savings and loanassociations together extended some $1.7 mil­lion of VRMs between April and December1975-about two-thirds of the total mortgagesthey made in this period. Although this experi­ence is too brief to develop meaningful conclu­sions, some tentative impressions can be ex­pressed. On the whole, the VRM is a muchmore complex instrument than either lenders orregulators generally realize. As a result, regula­tions and pricing practices could limit the valueof the instrument to both lenders and borrowers.In addition, difficulties could arise under sevendifferent headings, as described below.

Standard index

Regulations of the California Savings andLoan Commissioner tie the rate on VRMs to astandard index, defined as the last publishedweighted average cost of savings, borrowings,and Federal Home Loan Bank advances to Cali­fornia member associations of the FederalHome Loan Bank of San Francisco. Commer-

9

cial banks offering VRMs also use this S&L costof funds index. However, the index presentsthree problems, two economic and one political.

First, when individual lenders are forced touse an all-lender index, those institutions incapital-short areas may be discouraged frombidding more aggressively for deposits by offer­ing higher interest rates, knowing as they dothat the rates on their outstanding mortgageswill not be increased correspondingly. Becausea lender's decisions on the deposit rates it payswill not greatly affect the index value, someindividual institutions could bid less aggressivelyfor funds by offering lower rates and still benefitfrom higher mortgage rates. This reduces com­petition among individual lenders.

Secondly, the index is published semi-an­nually with a lag of two to eight months, andthus does not reflect current market rates. Ifmarket dates decline in any period, the drop willnot be reflected in the index until later. Yet tobe competitive with FRM lenders, VRM lendersmust lower their rates in the current period. Inthe absence of a decline in the standard index,they can remain competitive only by reducingthe differential between the market rate and thestandard index. This spread, which remainsconstant over the life of the mortgage, is de­signed to compensate the intermediary for the

Page 7: George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org

eosts and risks of operations, which remainunchanged. A lower spread than necessary tocover the costs would, of course, lead to un­profitable operations over the life of the mort­gage. It would appear at first that lower thanrequired spreads when the standard index lagsa decline in market rates would be offset byhigher than required spreads when the indexlags an increase in market rates. But because ofthe combined impact of prepayment provisionsand limits on maximum interest rate changes,borrowers are encouraged to switch from higherspread mortgages to lower spread mortgages,reducing the profitability of lending institutions.A more appropriate solution would be the useof an up-to-date index, such as a two-monthmoving average of the cost of funds for individ­ual institutions.

Lastly, a political problem arises because thecost of funds index is greatly affected by Regu­lation Q. Major increases have occurred in thecost of funds index in past periods when Regula­tion Q ceilings were increased. Because in­creases in Reg Q ceilings would lead to increasesin rates on all outstanding VRM mortgages, andnot only on new mortgages, it is reasonable topredict that all homeowners would exert sig­nificant political pressure to maintain-or evenreduce-Reg Q ceilings as market rates rose.If financial intermediaries could not offer com­petitive deposit rates, depositors would transfertheir funds away from these institutions intoprivate capital markets, depriving the mortgagemarket of funds.

Maximum interest rate limitA limit on the maximum VRM interest rate

change causes the risk of unexpected interestrate changes to be shared between lender andborrower. Two difficulties exist with the currentCalifornia regulations regarding this limit. First,they make possible asymmetrical rate changesfor the affected savings and loan associations.The rate cannot be increased more than 21/2percentage points above the initial rate, butthere is no limit on the amount it can decline asthe standard index falls below the initial rate.This regulation places a greater share of the

10

risk on the lender, increasing the rate that heis likely to charge on each new loan. Also, be­cause borrowers are allowed to prepay withoutpenalty within 90 days of any announced in­crease in loan rates, they have an incentive toshift into new VRMs during any later period ofdeclining market rates in order to take advan­tage of lower maximum VRM rates.

Secondly, the maximum limit is based uponthe initial VRM rate rather than upon the rateon a comparable FRM extended at the sametime. This feature benefits VRM borrowerswho obtain their mortgages when deposit orshort-term rates are high, because they can notonly ride the rates down, but can also convertto new VRMs with lower maximum interestrate limits. On the other hand, lenders are un­able to recoup these losses from those borrowerswho obtain their mortgages when rates are lowand assume only limited upside risk. As a re­sult, lenders must charge a higher interest ratein order to be compensated for the added risk.

Limits on the maximum interest rate change'also cause new VRMs to differ from comparableoutstanding VRMs, either in the loan rate or inthe maximum permissible loan rate. These dif­ferences, in tum, may encourage lenders andborrowers to shift from old to new mortgages,and thereby encourage the use of prepaymentand assumption restrictions to compensateeither party for potential losses from such trans­fers.

Prepayment feesPrepayment fees on mortgages have fre­

quently been a problem for lenders. If the pre­payment penalty fees are nonexistent or too low,in periods of low interest rates the lender willexperience losses from expected income and be­come reluctant to engage in additional lendingunder the same conditions. Casual inspectionsuggests that prepayment penalties generallyhave not been very severe on fixed rate mort­gages, so that borrowers have been able to re­finance into lower rate mortgages in periods ofdeclining rates. On the other hand, borrowerswere locked into lower rates during periods ofrising market rates. This situation has helped

Page 8: George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org

make FRMs unfavorable instruments for lend­ers.

If there were no limits on changes in VRMrates, old VRMs would yield the same rate asnew VRMs of the same credit quality-and thusthere would be no advantage to borrowers torefinance at lower rates, no loss to lenders, andno need for prepayment fees. However, ratesare generally not free to fluctuate without limit.If the maximum interest rate limits are eitherasymmetrical or centered around the initialVRM rate rather than the comparable FRMrate, it may be advantageous for the borrowerto refinance into a new VRM when interest ratesdecline sufficiently. This, of course, would bedisadvantageous to the lender, so that he wouldbe likely, if permitted by law, to impose prepay­ment penalties on VRMs when market rates fellbelow initial rates. At other times, there wouldbe no loss to the lender, so that he would belikely to permit prepayment without charge.

The California code permits prepayment ofVRMs without penalty anytime within 90 daysof an announced increase in loan rates. Thus,if rates had been falling for a period, borrowerswould be able to refinance into new, lower rateVRMs after the first announcement of an in­crease. This provision should be changed topermit prepayment without charge at any timethe loan rate is at or above the initial rate. Atother times, when the loan rate is below theinitial rate, prepayment penalties should bepermitted.

Loan assumptionsMost conventional FRMs have "due on sale"

clauses, which permit the lender to demand re­payment of the outstanding balance (plus pre­payment fees) at the time the mortgaged prop­erty is sold. This feature permits the lender toextend a new mortgage at a higher loan rate ifmarket rates have risen since the initial mort­gage contract. Restrictions on the assumptionof an existing mortgage by the property buyerare analogous to unrestricted prepayment, withtwo differences: the option to terminate the loanrests with the lender rather than the borrower,and the injured party is the borrower when in-

11

terest rates are above the initial rate (ratherthan the lender when interest rates are belowthe initial rate) .

Because of these general similarities, loanassumption provisions may be analyzed bestrelative to prepay1l1entprovisions. If there areno .prepayment penalties to compensate thelender when interest rates dedine, equity sug­gests that assumption should be restricted so asnot to compensate the borrower when interestrates increase. (Although the burden of higherrates falls. directly on the buyer, the new mort­gage rate affects the price at which property canbe sold and thus indirectly affects the seller.)On the other hand, if sufficient prepaymentpenalties are permitted to compensate the lenderfor any loss he may experience, restrictions onassumption would not appear to be warranted.

Unlike prepayment penalties, only part of th@assumption penalties-the part made up of thehigher rate on the new mortgage-accrues tothe lender. The remainder is absorbed in theprocess of obtaining a new promissory note,in the form of search loss, title insurance costs,recording costs, and legal costs. Thus, the effec­tive assumption costs to the borrower aregreater than the benefits to the lender.

As in the case of prepayment provisions, ifthere were no restrictions on VRM maximuminterest rate changes, there would be no needfor assumption restrictions. The rate on a newmortgage would be the same as on the oldmortgage. However, as already noted, restric­tions on interest rate changes may at times notmake the two mortgages equivalent, so thateither the borrower or the lender can find someadvantage at such times in choosing between anew and an old mortgage. As a result, someVRM lenders have imposed assumption restrict­tions similar to those on FRMs, even thoughunrestricted assumption has often been cited asan advantage of VRMs.

Because only part of the benefit from re­stricted assumption goes to the lender, it wouldhelp both sides if these restrictions were modi­fied. One alternative is to reset the maximuminterest rate band each time the property weresold. (This could be done without having to

Page 9: George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org

write a new promissory note.) The band on theexisting mortgage would then be equivalent tothat on a comparable new VRM. The necessarylegal changes could be achieved with only aminor change in the California code.

Implementation of rate changesChanges in loan rates may be implemented

either .• as changes in the dollar amount ofmonthly paYl1lents or as changes in the numberof unchanged monthly payments. Because de­posit rate changes are reflected only in changesin the amount of interest payments, discrepan­cies between the time of inflows and outflowsare reduced if loan rate changes are imple­mented in the same fashion, making interestreceipts match interest payments. However,VRM loan rates can increase sharply, increasingmonthly payments sharply, while most borrow­ers' incomes increase only slowly. As a result,borrowers may occasionally experience pay­ments difficulties.

To ease the burden of such rate changes,lenders frequently permit increases in loan ratesto be implemented, at the option of the bor­rower, as increases in the number of monthlypayments rather than in the dollar amount. Thiseliminates interest rate risk, but because cashinflows and outflows are not snychronized,liquidity problems may still arise. The lendermay need to meet deposit rate payments beforereceiving his loan rate payments. Thus, when­ever a lender increases the length of a mortgagein response to loan rate increases, he shouldreserve the right to shorten the length again tothe original maturity in the event rates decline.

California regulations permit VRM rate in­creases to be translated into increases in thenumber of monthly payments, provided that theremaining life of the mortgage does not exceed40 years. Although this is reasonable for amortgage with 20 or more years left to maturity,it appears to be an unnecessarily long extensionfor shorter mortgages. If rates increased overtime, some mortgages might never be completelyrepaid. A change in the regulations, permittingmortgage maturities to be lengthened by nomore than, say, 10 years in response to loan

12

rate. increases, could help lenders without creat­ing any undue problems for borrowers.

Complexity of mortgage contractBecause a VRM is a complex instrument, the

VRMcontract or promissory note is also com­plex--much more so than an FRM contract.Like theFRM note, the VRM note must specifythe initial •interest rate, the amount of themonthly payments, and the length of the mort­gage. But in addition, the VRM note must alsostipulate the conditions under which the interestrate can change, the methods by which an inter­est rate change may be implemented, the optionsavailable to either side for implementing ratechanges, the maximum and minimum limits oninterest rate changes, the frequency of possiblerate changes, and the maximum limits on thetotal interest rate change over the life of themortgage. VRM prepayment provisions arealso more complicated, since they can shift withthe relationship of the current market rate withthe initial rate. Lastly, the legal provisionsapplicable to VRMs are numerous, complex,and subject to frequent changes.

Asa result, it is easy for errors to appear inthe promissory note. An analysis of the notesused by the seven major users of VRMs in mid­January, 1976, revealed that many containederrors of nonconformity with the state laws andregulations then in effect. The largest numberof errors pertained to the alternative proceduresby which loan rate changes could be imple­mented. Such errors are not binding on theborrower, but they do reduce the amount ofinformation provided and thereby lower theborrower's ability to evaluate the contract.

In addition, almost all of the promissory notesomitted information that was materially relevantto the ability of the borrower to understand theprovisions and the value of the standard indexat the time the loan was originated. Because ofthe complexities of the instrument, lenders andborrowers alike should benefit from the devel­opment of a model VRM contract. This wouldbe of considerable use to lenders in preparingtheir own promissory notes and to borrowers inbecoming knowledgable about the informationthat is material to them.

Page 10: George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org

Consumer protectionThe intrinsic complexity of the VRM makes

it more important to protect borrowers againsterrors resulting from incorrect or omitted ma­terial information. One source of error uniqueto VRMs arises from the computation of thechange in monthly payments resulting fromchanging loan rates.

Interest rates on almost all new residentialmortgages of any type are denominated in mul­tiplesofO.25 percent, e.g. 91;4 percent. Borrow­erscan check the monthly payments. that areconsistent with this rate and the .loan maturityby using a standard mortgage payments table.(Computations of these amounts without theassistance of a calculator or computer is notrecommended.) However, as interest rateschange, the loan rate on outstanding VRMS canbe in multiples smaller than 0.25 percent. In­terest rate fractions in these smaller multiplesare not included in standard mortgage tables.Thus there is no easy way for a borrower tocheck the monthly payment stipulated by thelender and obtained through the use of a com­puter. To remove doubts about the accuracy ofsuch figures, all VRM lenders should makeavailable at their offices a monthly mortgagepayments table, perhaps in computer printoutform, for all interest 'rate fractions and maturi­ties in which their mortgages are outstanding.

California law requires lenders to provideborrowers with at least 30 days' written noticebefore the effective date of a change in VRMloan rates. When the economy is stable, withonly small changes in market interest rates, theremay be no changes in VRM loan rates for ex­tended periods of time. But some borrowersmay forget that these rates can actually change,and be both surprised and upset when an in­crease in monthly payments finally occurs.Lenders would be well advised to send borrow­ers a brief notice on every mortgage anniversary,possibly describing interest rate developmentsin the mortgage market since the last notice andreminding them that their loan rates couldchange if market rates change sufficiently. Atleast one smaller California savings and loanassociation, which has used VRMs for some

13

years, has found such a program successful indefusing borrower animosity to rate increases.

Evaluation of VRMThe mortgage industry has developed the

VR.Mas an alternative and/or supplement tothe FRM in order to reduce the financial pres­sures on mortgage-lending financial intennedi­aries, to increase the flow of funds through themortgage market, and to stimulate the purchaseof additional housing. Hence, the usefulness ofthe VRM as a mortgage instrument can beevaluated by examining its actual and potentialimpacts on the mortgage and housing markets.This, in turn, requires a determination of theadvantages and disadvantages of VRMs, rela­tive to FRMs, for mortgage borrowers and lend­ers. These advantages and disadvantages canbe set forth in tabular form, based in part ontheoretical considerations, and in part on ourobservation of California's limited experiencewith this instrument.

Mortgage BorrowersAdvantages

1. Possible gain from lower than currentlyexpected interest rates over the life of themortgage.

2. Possible gain from lower prepaymentfees. 6

3. Possible gain from more liberal assump­tion provisions. G

4. Greater availability in periods of great in­terest rate uncertainty.

Disadvantages1. Possible loss from higher than expected

short-term interest rates and need to pre­dict interest rates.

2. Possible risk of financial strain if mort­gage rate increases sharply but family in-­come remains unchanged.

3. Greater complexity of mortgage contract.4. Difficulty of ascertaining accuracy of

changes in monthly payments as a resultof changes in standard index.

Mortgage LendersAdvantages

1. Reduced solvency problem from risk of

Page 11: George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org

higher than expected cost of funds throughshifting of part or all of risk to borrower.

2. Reduced liquidity problem through in­creased synchronization of interest pay­ments and receipts, whenever changes inloan rates are translated into correspond­ing changes in dollar amount of monthlypayments.

Disadvantages

1. Difficulty in pricing of new VRMs andpotential inability to compete for newmortgages in periods of declining rates be­cause of standard index lagging behindmarket rate changes.

2. Reduction in potential gains from lowerthan expected cost of funds.

3. Elimination of potential profit from sale of"interest rate insurance."

4. Lack of synchronization of monthly pay­ments and receipts, and possible liquidityproblems, whenever changes in standardindex are translated into changes in num­ber of monthly payments.

5. Necessity of educating borrowers in com­plexities of mortgage contract, and possi­ble borrower animosity whenever ratesare raised on outstanding mortgages.

6. Difficulty in designing features of mort­gage contract and simple promissory note.

Mortgage Market

Advantages1. Possible increase in supply of funds from

lenders.2. Possible smoother supply of funds over

the cycle.3. Protection of solvency of thrift institu­

tions, provided that new contracts arepriced correctly.

Disadvantages

1. Possible decrease in demand for funds byborrowers because of greater risk.

2. Possible pressure on government frommortgagors to prevent increases in stand­ard index, particularly through use ofRegulation Q to hold down cost of fundsand thus level of index.

14

Housing Market

Advantages

Possiple greater demand for new and im­proved housing from greater availabilityof mortgage funds.

2. Possible smoother demand for new andimproved housing over cycle fromsmoother flow of mortgage funds.

3. Possiple greater demand for new and im­proved housing from increased ability ofll.Omeowners to sell, as a result of moreliberal prepayment and assumption pro­visions.

Disadvantages

1. Possible reduced housing demand fromreduced demand for mortgages.

2. Possible reduced housing demand from(a) increased disintermediation if freemovement of standard index is restricted;and (b) mispricing of mortgage if stand­ard index is not sufficiently current.

Conclusion

The VRM is a complex instrument, muchmore complex than first analysis would suggest,and there is good evidence that it is not yet fullyunderstood by any of the parties concerned­borrowers, lenders, or regulators. The potentialsuccess or harm of the VRM is heavily depen­dent upon the regulations and practices definingits .characteristics. The California experiencehighlights a number of requirements that mustbe met for the VRM to operate successfully:

1) the need to select an appropriate stand­ardindex;

2) the need for thrift institutions io under­stand fully the complexities of maturityand term structure intermediation;

3) the need to offset political pressures forgreater government interference with in­terest rates;

4) the need to determine loan rate changesin the light of the desired degree of risksharing and the implications for prepay­ment and assumption provisions;

5) the need to "educate" borrowers;

Page 12: George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org

6) the need to design the promissory note toprovide complete, accurate, and under­standable disclosure of all material infor­mation;

7) the need to provide proper protection toborrowers; and

8) the need for careful marketing of both the

initial contract and subsequent changes ininterest rates.

Inappropriate decisions in any of these areascould. greatly reduce the potential contributionof· VRMs. The California experience to datesuggests that it may not be easy to realize thefull potential of this mortgage instrument.

APPENDIXHow a VRM Works

The VRM is a long term mortgage contract inwhich the loan rate may change periodically, con­currently with changes in some predetermined mar­ket rate of interest, referred to as the standardindex. The provisions governing the relationshipbetween the loan rate and the standard index arestipulated in the promissory note and, in part, areestablished by state statute or regulation. Theseprovisions generally include the fixed differentialbetween the standard index and the loan rate, thefrequency at which the loan rate may be changed,the amount by which the loan rate may be changed(at any single time and over the life of the note),and the method by which changes in the loan rateare translated into changes in the monthly pay­ments (and at whose option). In California, manyof these provisions are stipulated either in the StateCivil Code or regulations of the Savings and LoanCommissioner.

The operation of a VRM may be illustrated witha hypothetical example developed in Table A-I.The standard index is the actual current value ofthe average cost of funds of insured savings andloan associations in the San Francisco FederalHome Loan Bank District. l The loan rate is as­sumed to be 11/2 percentage points (150 basispoints) above the standard index, to compensatethe lender for all costs of operation and providehim with a competitive return. Changes in the loanrate are subject to the following restrictions:

1. Limit per change:maximum = 25 basis pointsminimum = 10 basis poirits

2. Carryover: changes in the standard indexgreater than 25 basis points or less than 10basis points are carried over to the next and,if necessary, subsequent periods and added tothe change in the index at that- time.

1This rate is not published until some months after theclose of the respective semiannual period. Nevertheless,we assume here that it is available at the beginning of theperiod, in order to have a current index that permitslenders to price their new mortgages at the current mar­ket loan rate without changing the rate differential.

15

3. Number of changes: no more than one persix month period.

4. Overall limit: 250 basis points from the rateon a comparable fixed rate mortgage ex­tended on the same date.

The carryover (or cumulative) provision requiresthe computation of two numbers:

Total loan rate carryover (TC) = UC l + /':, SIUnused loan rate carryover (UC) = UC l +

/':, SI-P /':, =TC-P 6

where:SI = change in standard index

P 6 = permissible change in loan rateUC. l = unused carryover in previous period

A $20,000, 30-year VRM is assumed to be ex­tended on January 1, 1967, at 6.85 percent, basedon a standard index of 5.35 percent. (A compar­able FRM is assumed to cost 7 percent.) In thesecond semiannual period, the standard index de­clines by 32 basis points. As a result, the loan rateis reduced by the maximum 25 basis points to 6.60percent. The l'emaining 7 basis points are includedin the unused carryover and aI'e applied to thechange in the next period. By the end of the firsthalf of 1975, the standard index had climbed to6.41 percent, or 106 basis points over its initialvalue. The loan rate had increased by 105 basispoints to 7.90 percent. In the 16 semiannual peri­ods following the origination of the mortgage, thestandard index had declined five times and in­creased 11 times, while the loan rate had declinedtwice and increased seven times.

The montWy payments, as the table shows, are$131.06 in the first six months when the interestrate is at the initial 6.85 percent level. The pay­ments then decline to $127.77 in the next six monthperiod when the loan rate declines to 6.60 percent.(This assumes that all changes in the loan rate aretranslated into changes in the dollar amount ofmonthly payments.) In the first six months of1975, the last semiannual period shown, the month­ly mortgage payments have increased to $143.24.

Page 13: George G. Kaufman* - frbsf.org

The unpaid balance at the end of this period is$17,754.10.

In contrast, aFRM extended on January 1, 1967at a 7-percent fixed rate would call for constantmonthly payments of $133.20. At the end of theperiod, the unpaid balance would be $17,703.20,only $50 less than on the VRM. Of course, if in­terest rates had increased faster, the .differencewould have been greater, but the initial rate on theFRM may also have been higher.

FOOTNOTES1. For a discussion of alternative changes in mortgageplans, see D. Lessard and F. MOdigliani, New MortgageDesigns for Stable Housing in an Inflationary Environment(Boston: Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, 1975).2. Another large commercial bank began offering VRMsafter the conclusion of the study.

3. The interest rate on the vertical axis is scaled in termsof the logarithm of 1 plus the interest rate, to reflect re­investment of the interest on both the mortgage and thedeposit, as is required by the definition of compoundinterest.

4. The operation of a typical VRM is shown in Appendix(A).5. The risk could also be. shared or aSSUmed totally by theFederal government as a third party. For such suggestionssee . George •G.Kaufman, "The. Case for Mortgage RateInsurance," Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, No­vember 1975, and James L. Pierce, "A Program to ProtectMortgage Lenders Against Rate Increases," in FinancialInstitutions and the Nation's Economy (FINE), Committeeon Banking and Currency, U.S. House of Representatives,November 1975.6. Prepayment and assumption provisions depend on themagnitude of the maximum interest rate band and degreeof risk sharing. The larger the spread, the more liberal theprovisions are.

TABLE A"l

Monthly Payments and Unpaid BalanceVariable and Fixed Rate Mortgagest

1967-1975

133.20133.20133.20133.20133.20133.20133.20133.20133.20133.20133.20133.20133.20133.20133.20133.20133.20

Fixed Rate Mortgage:j:

Monthly UnpaidPayments Balance @

(dollars)

20,000.19,899.19,794.19,686.19,575.19,459.19,339.19,215.19,086.18,953.18,815.18,672.18,524.18,371.18,213.18,049.17,879.17,703.

131.06127.77127.77127.77127.77129.65132.78134.65134.65134.65133.45133.45133.45136.35139.23142.10143.24

6.856.606.606.606.606.757.007.157.157.157.057.057.057.307.557.807.90

Variable Rate Mortgage*

loan Monthly UnpaidRate Payments Balance @

(dollars)

20,000.19,897.19,785.19,670.19,551.19,428.19,304.19,181.19,057.18,928.18,795.18,655.18,510.18,359.18,209.18,059.17,908.17,754.

5.355.035.085.105.175.275.585.675.645.575.555.565.605.836.146.446.41

StandardIndex

1/1/671967.11967.21968.11968.21969.11969.21970.11970.21971.11971.21972.11972.21973.11973.21974.11974.21975.1

Period(Semi·Annuai)

t$20,OOO, 30-year mortgage extended January 1, 1967.*Initial loan rate 6.85 percent.tLoan rate = 7 percent.

@At end of semi-annual period.

16


Recommended