+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Healthy(Food(Accessibility(in((...

Healthy(Food(Accessibility(in((...

Date post: 28-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: hoangmien
View: 215 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
106
www.thefoodproject.org Healthy Food Accessibility in Underserved Boston Neighborhoods: The Affordability and Viability of Farmers’ Markets Narrative report PowerPoint presentation (“Getting to the Root of Popular Perceptions”) Robyn Lightner The Food Project / Amherst College The Food Project 10 Lewis Street, Lincoln, MA 01773 7812598621 (p) 7812599659 (f) [email protected] thefoodproject.org
Transcript

www.thefoodproject.org  

Healthy  Food  Accessibil ity   in    Underserved  Boston  Neighborhoods:    

The  Affordability  and  Viability    of  Farmers’  Markets  

   

• Narrative  report  • PowerPoint  presentation  (“Getting  to  the  Root  of  Popular  

Perceptions”)                      

Robyn  Lightner  The  Food  Project  /  Amherst  College  

         

The  Food  Project  10  Lewis  Street,  Lincoln,  MA  01773  781-­‐259-­‐8621  (p)    781-­‐259-­‐9659  (f)  

[email protected]    thefoodproject.org  

 

Healthy  Food  Accessibility  in  Underserved  Boston  

Neighborhoods:  

The  Affordability  and  Viability  of  Farmers’  Markets  

 

Robyn  Lightner  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Submitted  to  the  Department  of  Environmental  Studies  of  Amherst  College  in  partial  

fulfillment  of  the  requirements  for  the  degree  of  Bachelor  of  Arts  with  honors.  

 

Faculty  Advisors:  

Kate  Sims,  Assistant  Professor  of  Economics  

Jan  Dizard,  Professor  of  Sociology  

Amy  Wagaman,  Assistant  Professor  of  Mathematics  

 

April  8,  2011  

  2  

  3  

Table  of  Contents  

 

Acknowledgements  ………………………………………………………………………………….      5  

List  of  Abbreviations  ………………………………………………………………………………..      7  

Introduction    …………………………………………………………………………………………….    9  

Section  1  ..………………………………………………………………………………………………….  15  

Literature  Review:  Healthy  Food  Access  in  Underserved    

Neighborhoods  

Section  2  ………………………………………………………………………………………………….      33  

Observational  Study:  The  Affordability  of  Farmers’  Markets    

In  Underserved  Boston  Neighborhoods  

Section  3  .………………………………………………………………………………………………….    75  

Current  and  Future  Implications:  The  Viability  of  Farmers’    

Markets  in  Underserved  Boston  Neighborhoods  

Conclusion  ……………………………………………………………………………………………….      89  

Works  Cited  ……………………………………………………………………………………………..      93  

Appendices  ………………………………………………………………………………………………      97  

  4  

  5  

Acknowledgements  

This  whole  process  was  truly  a  collective  effort  involving  ideas,  support,  and  knowledge  from  a  whole  basket  full  of  people.    First  and  foremost,  I  cannot  begin  to  describe  what  wonderful  mentors  my  “Boston  advisors”  Cathy  Wirth  and  Cammy  Watts  have  been  throughout  the  entire  course  of  this  project.    You  both  not  only  hosted  me  as  an  unexpected  intern  last  summer,  but  taught  me  so  much  about  what  it  means  to  have  access  to  healthy  food  and  what  it  means  to  work  for  a  cause  that  you  are  absolutely  passionate  about.  This  report  would  not  have  been  completed  if  you  hadn’t  devoted  hours  to  collecting  data  in  Boston  and  sending  it  to  me  in  Amherst,  and  there’s  no  way  I  would  have  had  the  motivation  and  desire  to  take  on  the  continuation  of  this  study  had  I  not  felt  your  constant  encouragement  and  guidance  behind  me.         Many  others  deserve  great  appreciation  for  the  time  they  spent  collecting  data  for  me  over  the  summer  and  while  at  school:  Cara  Brumfield,  Farmer  Dave  Dracut,  Tim  Diehl,  Nebi  Stephens,  Cynthia  Loesch  and  the  B.O.L.D.  Teens  of  Codman  Square,  and  especially  Phuong  Luong,  who  could  not  have  been  more  flexible  and  willing  to  help.     Here  at  Amherst,  my  advisor  Kate  Sims  was  the  one  who  proposed  the  then-­‐crazy  idea  of  turning  my  summer  research  into  a  thesis  last  fall,  and  she  somehow  accepted  my  endless  questions  and  hesitations  with  remarkable  knowledge  and  reassurance.    Always  excited  to  help,  Professor  Sims  gave  me  the  confidence  to  write  and  calculate  like  I  never  have  before-­‐  she  pushed  me  to  reach  a  level  of  academic  potential  I  didn’t  know  I  had  and  am  so  grateful  to  have  uncovered.    Professor  Dizard,  you  have  always  managed  to  bring  me  back  to  reality  and  put  such  interesting  thoughts  into  my  already  food-­‐filled  head-­‐  perhaps  your  most  timely  piece  of  advice  being  “reading  kills  writing”.    Professor  Wagaman,  had  I  not  felt  so  confident  stepping  out  of  your  Statistics  class,  I  would  have  never  agreed  to  develop  this  study  for  The  Food  Project-­‐  your  ability  to  explain  new  concepts  to  a  humanities  person  has  been  invaluable  all  along.     To  my  roommates  and  teammates-­‐  thank  you  for  always  asking  questions  and  at  least  pretending  to  be  interested  in  what  I  was  always  doing  in  the  library  talking  about  farmers’  markets,  and  for  putting  up  with  all  of  my  weariness  and  stress,  you  guys  kept  me  somewhat  grounded!    And  finally,  to  Mom,  Dad,  Jeff,  and  Ry-­‐  you  have  put  up  with  so  much  but  continued  to  love  and  support  me.    I  promise  you  will  never  have  to  hear  the  word  “thesis”  as  an  excuse  from  me  ever,  ever,  again.    

  6  

  7  

List  of  Abbreviations    

 

 

BBB   Boston’s  Bounty  Bucks  

BCFF   Boston  Collaborative  for  Food  and  Fitness  

EBT   Electronic  Benefit  Transfer  

FMNP   Farmers’  Market  Nutrition  Program  

FRAC   Food  Research  and  Action  Center  

SFMNP   Senior  Farmers’  Market  Nutrition  Program  

SNAP   Supplemental  Nutrition  Assistance  Program  

WIC   Woman  Infants  and  Children  

  8  

  9  

Introduction  

For  many  Americans,  the  words  “clean  your  plate”  conjure  up  memories  of  

having  to  eat  those  last  few  spoonfuls  of  cauliflower  or  ask  for  extra  juice  just  to  

force  down  that  last  brussel  sprout.    No  matter  how  much  gravy  or,  in  my  case  

ketchup,  covered  those  daunting  final  bites,  day  after  day  they  always  had  in  

common  a  certain  despised  nine-­‐letter  word-­‐  vegetable.    Often  the  villain  in  cartoon  

shows,  vegetables  have  traditionally  become  targets  of  childhood  opposition,  

subjected  to  the  immature  infamy  associated  with  all  things  good  for  you.    But  no  

matter  how  much  picky  young  eaters  loathe  a  side  of  peas  and  carrots,  their  colorful  

presence  on  the  daily  table  represents  a  nutritional  privilege  not  easily  within  reach  

of  many  low-­‐income  urban  households.  

An  absence  of  fruits  and  vegetables  on  the  dinner  tables  of  the  poor  has  much  

more  to  do  with  a  lack  of  access  than  it  does  with  a  lack  of  affinity  for  produce.  The  

current  state  of  the  American  food  system  is  such  that  unhealthy  diets  are  more  

often  than  not  an  economically  and  practically  sensible  choice.    Attracted  by  the  

relative  price  and  convenience  of  processed  junk  foods,  it’s  no  coincidence  that  a  

national  health  crisis  has  erupted  over  a  rapid  increase  in  the  prevalence  of  diet-­‐

related  diseases  (Miller,  2010).    Thrust  into  the  public  conscience,  decisions  about  

what  Americans  should  and  should  not  be  consuming  have  become  a  huge  target  of  

aggressive  research,  debate,  and  reform.    Parallel  to  this  growing  discussion  on  all  

things  food  is  an  increasing  emphasis  on  utilizing  local  systems  of  production,  

  10  

particularly  with  regard  to  the  popularity  of  fresh,  local  agricultural  harvests.    

Several  nation-­‐wide  strategies  have  encouraged  the  integration  of  local  farm  

products  into  everyday  meals  as  a  method  of  supporting  community  economies  

while  increasing  intake  of  fresh  produce.    Such  programs  would  seemingly  have  

more  ground  to  cover  in  low-­‐income  city  neighborhoods  that  have  historically  

experienced  reduced  access  to  healthy  foods,  especially  fruits  and  vegetables,  and  

consequentially  suffered  from  increased  frequencies  of  diet-­‐related  health  

problems.      

  Yet  many  of  these  deprived  neighborhoods  are  taking  action  to  overcome  the  

obstacles  that  have  kept  fresh  produce  off  their  tables  by  confronting  a  series  

accessibility  issues  and  embracing  what  their  local  agriculture  has  to  offer.    Section  

One  of  this  report  explores  the  national  context  of  healthy  food  access  in  low-­‐income  

areas  before  focusing  on  specific  characteristics  of  the  Boston  food  access  

environment.    Contained  in  the  concept  of  access  are  the  separate  but  related  

matters  of  physical  availability,  affordability,  and  practical  awareness,  all  of  which  

are  crucial  to  understanding  the  challenges  facing  the  introduction  of  fresh  fruits  

and  vegetables  into  healthy  food  deficient  communities.    Products  of  the  heightened  

energy  behind  local  agriculture,  farmers’  markets  are  highlighted  as  a  growing  

source  of  fresh  produce  across  the  United  States.  For  low-­‐income  shoppers,  federal  

nutrition  assistance  programs  currently  include  vouchers  and  coupons  specifically  

for  use  at  farmers’  markets,  and  programs  at  the  state  level  are  rapidly  expanding  to  

further  incentivize  the  purchase  and  consumption  of  fresh,  local  produce.    An  

impetus  for  healthy  food  access  in  the  Northeast,  Boston  Bounty  Bucks  is  one  such  

  11  

program  that  offers  SNAP  (food  stamps)  users  50%  off  their  purchase  of  up  to  

$20.00  at  farmers’  markets  and  equips  vendors  with  appropriate  EBT  terminals  that  

make  purchasing  with  SNAP/EBT  possible.  

  Though  a  great  way  to  merge  support  for  local  environments  and  economies  

with  improvements  in  healthful  dietary  options,  farmers’  markets  are  afflicted  by  a  

widespread  perception  that  their  produce  is  much  more  expensive  than  

conventional  grocery  produce.    As  a  result,  it  seems  many  price-­‐sensitive  shoppers  

categorically  reject  shopping  at  farmers’  markets,  in  turn  missing  out  on  an  

opportunity  to  purchase  many  of  the  nutritious  foods  their  bodies  need  more  of.    

But  is  this  commonly  discussed  perception  true  in  Boston?    With  support  from  The  

Food  Project  and  the  helpful  curiosity  of  the  communities  involved,  I  developed  an  

observational  study  to  examine  this  issue  by  comparing  produce  prices  at  farmers’  

markets  and  supermarkets  in  two  underserved  Boston  neighborhoods  throughout  

the  2010  summer  season.  Finding  the  few  previous  attempts  at  investigating  

variation  in  price  to  prove  inadequate-­‐  especially  for  application  in  poor  urban  

areas,  I  confronted  the  need  for  an  assessment  of  fruit  and  vegetable  prices  that  

considers  the  unique  context  of  farmers’  markets  in  areas  that  demand  affordability.  

  Section  Two  begins  with  a  careful  explanation  of  the  design  process  and  

methodology  of  this  study,  covering  the  details  of  variable  selection  and  data  

collection  procedures.    The  analysis  component  outlines  a  series  of  multivariate  

regression  tests  to  estimate  the  difference  in  price  between  farmers’  markets  and  

supermarkets  in  the  defined  neighborhoods  of  Dorchester  and  Roxbury,  and  

successively  controls  for  the  fixed  effects  of  produce  type,  time,  and  quality  rating.    

  12  

The  two  principle  findings  resulting  from  this  analysis  were  that  1)  on  average,  the  

mean  price  per  pound  of  produce  at  farmers’  markets  was  2.9%  greater  than  at  

supermarkets,  after  controlling  for  produce  type,  time,  and  quality,  and  2)  the  

quality  of  produce  at  farmers’  markets  scored  significantly  better  than  quality  at  

supermarkets.    Subsequent  analyses  of  seasonality  by  location  and  each  produce  

type  separately  help  show  patterns  of  fluctuation  in  price  over  the  course  of  the  16-­‐

week  season  and  thus  the  importance  of  taking  timing  into  account  in  similar  future  

studies.    In  discussing  the  results,  I  draw  upon  first-­‐hand  experience  and  

communication  to  make  several  inferences  about  factors  that  may  have  influenced  

or  caused  our  findings.    With  the  intent  of  establishing  a  replicable  method  for  

future  studies  of  this  kind,  I  also  comment  on  strengths  and  weaknesses  of  this  

research  design  throughout  the  discussion.      

  In  Section  Three,  I  reflect  on  the  benefits  of  implementing  farmers’  markets  

in  low-­‐income  areas,  focusing  on  the  opportunities  for  cost-­‐savings,  higher  quality,  

and  community  development,  among  others.    I  then  go  over  several  barriers  that  I  

feel  are  most  pertinent  and  crucial  to  the  future  viability  of  Boston  farmers’  markets.    

In  addition  to  misperceptions  about  price,  operational  and  administrative  duties  

impose  a  major  burden  on  successful  market  functioning,  just  as  low  farmer  

retention  rates  threaten  the  long-­‐term  growth  of  farmer-­‐to-­‐household  relationships.    

A  brief  list  of  recommendations  for  action  complete  my  evaluation  of  healthy  food  

access  in  Boston  and  ideally  stimulate  further  discussion  about  how  the  City  can  

perpetuate  recent  progress  and  remain  an  exemplary  model  of  using  local  

producers  to  increase  healthy  food  access  for  those  who  need  it  most.  

  13  

Ultimately,  the  purpose  of  my  first-­‐hand  observational  research  is  to  

accurately  educate  Boston  communities  about  the  affordability  and  accessibility  of  

healthy  food  in  their  neighborhoods  and  to  inform  the  efforts  of  community  groups,  

policy  advocates,  and  farmers  so  collective  energies  and  funds  are  more  efficiently  

directed.  

 

  14  

  15  

Section  1  

Literature  Review:  Healthy  Food  Access  in  Underserved  

Neighborhoods  

 

A  first  step  in  this  investigation  is  to  review  existing  literature  regarding  food  

accessibility  to  gain  a  better  understanding  of  the  national  context  in  which  this  

debate  falls.    The  contention  that  residents  in  low-­‐income,  urban  neighborhoods  are  

disadvantaged  by  the  limited  accessibility  of  nutritious  foods  is  based  on  the  

separate,  yet  related,  categories  of  healthy  food  availability  and  affordability.    The  

local  effects  of  these  issues  are  subsequently  examined  in  the  context  of  the  

immediate  Boston  neighborhoods  at  the  center  of  this  report.    As  the  focus  of  my  

own  research  is  to  investigate  differences  in  the  cost  of  healthy  food  for  a  specific  

area,  I  will  introduce  popular  literature  on  availability  and  variety  of  healthy  food  

options  before  concentrating  on  material  that  more  closely  relates  to  the  role  of  

affordability  within  healthy  food  accessibility.    The  second  half  of  my  review  

narrows  in  on  farmers’  markets,  paying  particular  attention  to  three  very  different  

studies  that  have  attempted  to  compare  costs  between  farmers’  markets  and  

conventional  grocery  outlets.    Finally,  I  will  summarize  existing  gaps  in  the  

literature  surrounding  accessibility  of  healthy  food  and  suggest  areas  for  further  

investigation.  

     

 

  16  

1.1.  Low-­income  neighborhoods  have  a  higher  rate  of  health  problems  

Nearly  every  piece  of  literature  included  in  this  review  highlighted  the  well-­‐

researched  fact  that  low-­‐income  neighborhoods  have  higher  rates  of  health  

problems  than  more  affluent  neighborhoods  (Larson  et  al.,  2009;  Neault  et  al.,  2005;  

Winne,  2008).    The  most  frequently  mentioned  of  these  health  risks  are  obesity,  

childhood  obesity,  heart  disease,  malnutrition,  hypertension,  and  type-­‐2  diabetes.    

Hendrickson  et  al.  (2006)  emphasizes  the  correlation  between  these  health  risks  

and  increased  rates  of  mortality,  successfully  conveying  the  problem’s  severity  and  

urgency.      In  “The  Real  Cost  of  a  Healthy  Diet”,  Neault  et  al.  (2008)  effectively  

juxtaposes  rates  of  under-­‐nutrition  (consuming  too  few  of  some  essential  nutrients)  

and  over-­‐nourishment  (consuming  an  excess  of  calories)  to  highlight  the  troubling  

paradox  relating  food  insecurity  and  serious  heath  problems.  Regardless  of  

presentation,  the  many  studies  featured  in  this  literature  review  all  underline  the  

disturbingly  high  incidences  of  diet-­‐related  disease  in  low-­‐income  areas  that  have  

prompted  such  aggressive  analysis  of  food  accessibility.    

From  the  Boston  Public  Health  Commission’s  annual  “Health  of  Boston”  report,  it  

is  obvious  that  the  national  trend  of  increased  health  problems  in  low-­‐income  

neighborhoods  is  of  major  concern  in  Boston  communities  as  well.    In  2008,  lower  

income  Boston  residents  (having  household  incomes  of  $25,000  or  less)  reported  

higher  rates  of  asthma,  diabetes,  heart  disease,  high  blood  pressure,  and  obesity  

compared  to  higher  income  residents.  Roxbury,  North  Dorchester,  and  South  

Dorchester  were  three  of  the  five  neighborhoods  with  the  highest  annual  heart  

disease  hospitalization  rate;  in  particular,  Roxbury’s  rate  was  more  than  50%  higher  

  17  

than  the  city’s  rate  overall1  (Health  of  Boston,  2010).  Roxbury  and  North  Dorchester  

also  reported  two  of  the  top  three  neighborhood  rates  for  asthma  hospitalization.  

 1.2.  Low-­income  neighborhoods  have  reduced  access  to  healthy  food  

Along  with  factors  such  as  exercise  level  and  time  spent  outdoors,  the  single  

most  important  and  studied  factor  related  to  the  disparity  of  health  concerns  in  low-­‐

income  urban  neighborhoods  is  the  accessibility  of  healthy  food.  Use  of  the  term  

access  or  accessibility  can  be  interpreted  as  the  physical  distance  from  home  to  retail  

outlets,  the  types  and  distribution  of  food  retail  located  in  the  region,  availability  of  

transportation  to  retail  outlets,  and/or  affordability  of  healthy  food.  Other  relevant  

factors  such  as  public  food  assistance,  consumer  behavior,  community  support,  and  

nutrition  education  are  also  explored  to  some  extent.    To  identify  a  type  of  

neighborhood  characterized  by  limited  food  access,  researchers  use  the  term  “food  

desert”,  defined  by  the  USDA  as  a  neighborhood  where  residents  do  not  have  access  

to  affordable  and  nutritious  food  (Whitacre  et  al.,  2009).  Beyond  this  description,  

both  Walker  et  al.  (2010)  and  Hendrickson  et  al.  (2006)  recognize  persistent  

inconsistency  in  the  utilization  of  the  term  “food  desert”  and  warn  that  such  

significant  lack  of  consensus  about  which  measures  are  required  for  identifying  food  

deserts  can  only  perpetuate  the  debate  about  the  extent  of  their  existence.    Though  a  

densely  populated,  low-­‐income  urban  environment  is  more  commonly  implied,  

Winne’s  extensive  historical  account  Closing  the  Food  Gap  (2008)  demonstrates,  

                                                                                                               1  Annual  heart  disease  hospitalization  rate  for  Boston  was  19.8  per  1,000  population  (Health  of  Boston,  2010)  

  18  

given  the  multiple  factors  contributing  to  the  meaning  of  “access”,  a  “food  desert”  

can  also  describe  a  rural  area  having  a  very  small,  widespread  population.  

Despite  the  confusion  in  nomenclature,  connections  between  all  of  the  factors  

mentioned  are  important  to  understanding  the  accessibility  of  healthy  food  within  a  

certain  neighborhood.      

       1.3.  A  Closer  Look  at  Accessibility  

Availability  and  variety  

Food  accessibility  for  inner-­‐city  residents  is  interpreted  in  this  section  as  the  

physical  accessibility  of  food  outlets  based  on  geographical  factors  (i.e.  where  food  

stores  are  located)  and  variety/  distribution  of  retail  outlet  types.    It  is  widely  noted  

that  in  low-­‐income  urban  neighborhoods  fast-­‐food  restaurants  and  small  

convenience  stores  have  always  been  more  prevalent  than  supermarkets  or  produce  

stands  (Winne,  2008).    According  to  Hendrickson  et  al.  (2006),  the  lack  of  

competition  among  the  few  grocery  stores  located  in  inner  cities  leads  to  fewer  

varieties  of  healthy  or  fresh  food  for  consumers,  and  the  availability  and  variety  of  

certain  food  products,  particularly  fresh  fruits  and  vegetables,  varies  greatly  among  

stores  located  in  different  neighborhoods.    Additionally,  the  issue  of  lack  of  

transportation  is  echoed  throughout  the  literature  citing  that  many  low-­‐income  

households  do  not  have  access  to  a  car  and  cannot  afford  the  costs  associated  with  

getting  to  a  supermarket  outside  of  their  immediate  neighborhood  (Walker  et  al.  

2010).  As  a  result  of  this  lack  of  transportation,  low-­‐income  households  are  less  

likely  to  travel  the  distance  to  a  supermarket  outside  of  their  neighborhood  and  will  

purchase  food  items  from  the  stores  that  are  nearby,  often  possibly  sacrificing  cost  

  19  

and  quality  for  convenience  (Hendrickson  et  al.,  2006).    Further,  among  households  

with  limited  transportation,  one  survey  uncovered  a  trend  where  families  made  one  

or  two  trips  per  month  outside  their  neighborhood  to  the  supermarket  to  purchase  

non-­‐perishables,  and  relied  on  local  suppliers  (and  their  limited  selection)  for  day-­‐

to-­‐day  perishables  (Whitacre  et  al.,  2009).    Though  the  limitations  of  smaller  

convenience  stores  are  well  cited,  at  the  more  human  level  there  also  exists  a  

common  inclination  among  residents  to  frequent  their  local  store  to  maintain  

loyalty  and  a  relationship  with  the  owner  (Whitacre  et  al.,  2009).    

Such  a  pattern  of  reduced  availability  has  been  examined  in  the  Boston  area  

and  shown  to  exist  in  several  dimensions.    The  “Real  Cost  of  a  Healthy  Diet”,  a  report  

published  by  the  Boston  Medical  Center,  investigated  the  availability  and  cost  of  the  

USDA’s  “Thrifty  Food  Plan”*  in  Boston  food  outlets  and  found  that,  on  average,  16%  

of  the  plan’s  items  were  not  available  in  surveyed  stores.  Similarly,  a  survey  

conducted  by  the  “Boston  Collaborative  for  Food  and  Fitness”  in  six  low-­‐income  

neighborhoods,  including  the  three  featured  in  our  study,  showed  that  an  average  of  

33%  of  food  retail  locations  did  not  carry  any  produce.    Note:  all  types  and  sizes  of  

retail  stores  were  included  (bodegas,  mega-­‐markets,  restaurants,  fast  food,  etc.)  

with  the  exception  of  direct  retail  farmers’  markets.  

   Affordability  

The  literature  indicates  a  general  consensus  that  low-­‐income  households  pay  

more  for  their  food,  largely  due  to  the  prevalence  of  higher  priced  small-­‐sized  

                                                                                                               *  The TFP consists of food lists and menu plans that serve as the national standard for a nutritious diet at the lowest possible cost. This cost-specific food plan guides national nutrition policy in the U.S. (such as determining maximum food stamp allotments) (Neault et al., 2008).

  20  

convenience  stores  in  surrounding  neighborhoods  (Larson  et  al.,  2009;  Neault  et  al.,  

2005;  Whitacre  et  al.,  2009).  Likely  reasons  for  higher  prices  in  low-­‐income,  inner  

city  areas  were  suggested  at  “The  Public  Health  Effects  of  Food  Deserts”  workshop  

hosted  by  the  Institute  of  Medicine  and  National  Research  Council  in  2009  

(Whitacre  et  al.).    In  these  neighborhoods  high  crime  and  theft  rates  induce  extra  

security  costs  for  businesses,  while  low  employee-­‐labor  skills,  lower  sales  volume,  

and  high  turnover  rates  lead  to  higher  operating  costs.  Additionally,  inner  cities  

have  less  available  land  and  more  zoning  restrictions  so  large  chain  stores  prefer  to  

locate  in  the  suburbs.  Finally,  low  competition  among  the  few  grocery  stores  located  

in  urban  areas  may  lead  to  higher  prices  for  local  residents  (Walker  et  al.,  2010).    

USDA  studies  are  widely  used  to  validate  this  theory,  finding  that  the  prices  in  

smaller,  independent  markets  are  at  least  10%  higher  than  prices  in  larger  

supermarkets  (Whitacre  et  al.,  2009;  Walker  et  al.,  2010).  However,  while  these  

USDA  studies  include  all  types  of  small  (and  large)  food  retail  outlets  in  both  high  

and  low-­‐income  urban  neighborhoods,  they  fail  to  differentiate  between  

neighborhood  income  types.    Because  of  such  indiscriminate  collection  of  price  data,  

this  aspect  of  USDA  research  does  not  necessarily  illustrate  a  relationship  between  

small  retail  stores  in  low-­‐income  neighborhoods  and  higher  prices.  Another  USDA  

report  found  that  urban  supermarket  prices  are  higher  than  suburban  prices,  but  

again  did  not  break  down  the  analysis  to  examine  differences  in  socioeconomic  

makeup  of  the  urban  (and  suburban)  areas.    Most  effectively,  Hendrickson  et  al.  

(2006)  used  an  appropriately  comprehensive  approach  of  consumer  surveys  

combined  with  statistical  analysis  and  found  that  food  prices  are  higher  and  food  

  21  

quality  is  poorer,  often  inedible,  in  areas  where  poverty  is  the  highest,  compared  to  

more  affluent  areas,  concluding  that  residents  living  in  areas  without  a  supermarket  

do  in  fact  pay  more  for  their  food.  Thus,  healthy  foods  are  less  accessible  to  inner  

city  residents  in  terms  of  affordability  in  addition  to  geographical  location  and  

variety  of  retail  outlets.      

The  affordability  of  healthy  food  is  a  problem  in  Boston.    The  average  

monthly  cost  of  the  Thrifty  Food  Plan  in  Boston  was  39%  higher  than  the  USDA’s  

reported  cost.  Several  studies  also  demonstrate  the  fact  that  residents  in  poorer  

Boston  neighborhoods  cannot  afford  their  food.  For  example,  of  574  people  

interviewed  by  BCFF  in  low-­‐income  neighborhoods  including  Dorchester  and  

Roxbury,  59%  said  their  household  grocery  purchases  were  affected  by  rising  food  

prices,  17%  reported  skipping  meals,  and  13%  said  they  served  fewer  vegetables  

(BCFF,  2010).    When  asked  about  the  prevalence  of  fruits  and  vegetables  in  their  

diets,  60%  of  respondents  in  these  neighborhoods  did  not  eat  vegetables  on  a  daily  

basis  and  14%  reported  no  consumption  at  all  (the  numbers  for  fruit  consumption  

were  equally  dismal,  at  65%  and  16%,  respectively)  (Kim,  2010).  

 1.4.  Impact  of  Rising  Food  Prices  on  Low-­Income  Households  

With  2011  came  a  wave  of  increased  commodity  costs  that  struck  Americans’  

shopping  carts  hard,  but  rising  prices  were  no  newcomers  to  the  produce  section.    

Over  the  last  four  years,  one  study  in  Seattle  found  that  food  prices  rose  significantly  

and  disproportionately-­‐  25%  for  the  most  nutritious  foods  (including  produce)  and  

16%  for  the  least  nutritious  and  junk  foods  (Miller,  2010).    According  to  the  

Nationally-­‐released  Consumer  Price  Index-­‐  which  measures  changes  in  costs  for  

  22  

dozens  of  living  expenses,  in  December  2010  the  overall  food  price  index  rose  by  0.1  

%  while  the  fruit  and  vegetable  price  index  rose  1.8  %  (BLS,  2010).    The  number  of  

Americans  receiving  SNAP  benefits  has  surged  by  58.5%  over  the  last  three  years  

(Miller,  2010),  and  a  report  released  by  the  Food  Research  and  Action  Center  

(FRAC)  earlier  this  month  said  almost  1  in  5  Americans  struggled  to  afford  food  for  

their  families  in  2010,  with  some  of  the  highest  rates  of  food  hardship  occurring  just  

last  fall.    Yet  no  relief  is  in  sight  for  these  households  as  an  ominous  release  by  the  

Department  of  Agriculture  expects  overall  food  prices  to  rise  3  to  4%  this  year  alone  

(USDA,  2010).    M.  Fisher  (2009)  explains  that  rising  food  prices  have  the  tendency  

to  affect  lower  income  more  than  higher  income  consumers  because  they  spend  a  

larger  amount  of  their  income  on  food.    Limited  budget  households  also  react  by  

devoting  a  larger  share  of  their  food  expenditures  to  non-­‐perishable  staple  foods  

like  corn,  wheat,  and  rice,  leaving  only  a  paltry  share  for  nutritious  fresh  fruits  and  

vegetables  (Fisher,  M.,  2009).    And  more  substantially  than  for  other  types  of  food,  

an  increase  in  price  of  fresh  produce  correlates  directly  with  a  decline  in  

consumption,  implying  that  when  food  prices  rise,  price-­‐sensitive  households  may  

further  cut  down  on  their  already  low  intake  of  fruits  and  vegetables  (Coleman  et  al.,  

1968).  

  In  addition  to  the  recent  rise  in  food  prices,  Boston  has  historically  reported  

more  expensive  food  costs  than  most  American  cities,  intensifying  the  burden  for  

consumers  on  limited  incomes.    In  1966,  Boston  had  the  3rd  highest  retail  food  price  

index  across  20  major  cities  (Coleman,  1968)  and  the  pattern  continued  as  of  

December  2010,  when  Boston  reported  the  2nd  highest  food  price  index  (after  New  

  23  

York)  and  spent  about  28%  more  than  the  national  average  on  fruits  and  vegetables  

(BLS,  2010).    The  city’s  astounding  91.9%  growth  in  SNAP  participation  between  

May  2005  and  May  2010  (enrollment  of  57,052  and  109,049  person,  respectively)  

shows  that  Boston  households  are  desperately  trying  to  cope  with  the  reality  that  

they  can  no  longer  afford  to  feed  their  families  (Vollinger,  et  al.,  2010).    Particularly,  

a  substantial  17,000  (roughly  one  third  of)  Dorchester  residents  are  currently  

dependent  on  federal  assistance  for  food,  with  $34  and  $7  million  in  SNAP  

redemptions  at  the  neighborhood’s  supermarkets  and  convenience  stores,  

respectively  (Zarrell,  2011).    A  recent  BCFF  survey  found  that  51%  and  63%  of  

surveyed  residents  in  Dorchester  and  Roxbury  claimed  their  grocery  purchase  were  

affected  by  higher  food  prices;  specifically,  12%  and  8%  of  families  in  these  

neighborhoods  said  they  were  serving  fewer  vegetables-­‐  numbers  that  are  even  

more  disturbing  considering  only  50%  and  25%  of  residents  reported  eating  

vegetables  every  day  (BCFF,  2010).    At  a  time  when  conventional  food  outlets  are  

forced  to  assume  greater  commodity  costs  that  must  be  transferred  to  the  customer  

and  eventually  paid  back  into  the  massive  food  production  industry,  farmers’  

markets  take  on  the  increasingly  important  role  of  local  producers  and  suppliers,  

helping  to  strengthen  the  economy  of  local  communities  by  keeping  money  

circulating  nearby.  

   1.5.  Expansion  of  Direct  Retail  Outlets-­  “Farmers’  Markets”  

With  increasing  attention  around  issues  of  healthy  food  accessibility,  

communities  around  the  United  States  are  mobilizing  to  make  fresh  produce  

available  and  affordable  to  low-­‐income  communities.  One  of  the  most  effective  ways  

  24  

has  been  through  the  creation  of  farmers’  markets  in  low-­‐income  areas.  When  

paired  with  federal  nutrition  assistance  program  benefits,  farmers’  markets  are  

becoming  an  increasingly  important  source  of  fresh,  local  produce  for  urban  

residents  (Winne,  2009).    The  most  recent  literature  almost  always  mentions  the  

rapid  growth  of  farmers  markets  over  the  last  decade,  as  highlighted  by  the  USDA  

data  indicating  a  300%  increase  in  the  number  of  farmers  markets  between  1994  

and  2009  (Pirog  and  McCann).  Most  recently,  the  2010  National  Farmers  Market  

Directory  lists  6,132  operational  markets,  showing  a  16%  increase  from  2009.    

Research  using  consumer  surveys  has  also  verified  a  number  of  reasons  why  

individuals  patronize  farmers  markets,  such  as  perceived  freshness  and  taste,  

supporting  local  business  and  community  building  (Pirog  and  McCann,  2009),  

enjoyment  of  relationships  with  producers,  an  opportunity  to  assist  the  small  

producer  (Sommer  et  al.  1980),  perceived  higher  vitamin  index,  freshness,  and  

many  others.    The  development  and  promotion  of  farmers’  markets  is  most  

popularly  emphasized  as  a  strategy  to  increase  neighborhood  fruit  and  vegetable  

consumption  as  part  of  a  healthier  lifestyle;  more  so,  establishment  of  a  farmers’  

market  is  a  way  to  foster  community  partnerships,  support  local  agriculture,  

develop  leadership  in  youth,  and  reconnect  urban  areas  with  the  natural  food  

system  (Winne  2008).    

While  its  healthy  food  access  gap  runs  parallel  to  the  problematic  national  

trend,  Boston  has  become  an  outstanding  leader  at  the  front  of  a  more  promising  

national  movement-­‐  the  expansion  of  universal  access  to  farmers’  markets.    

According  to  Jeff  Cole,  executive  director  of  the  nonprofit  Mass  Farmers  Markets,  

  25  

Boston  has  “more  farmers  markets  per  capita  than  any  other  city  in  the  United  

States”,  a  claim  backed  by  the  city’s  2010  count  of  27  markets,  representing  more  

than  a  30%  increase  since  2008  (Denison,  2010).    

 1.6.  Expansion  of  Federal  Assistance  and  Incentives  to  Farmers’  Markets  

Though  the  significant  increase  in  the  prevalence  of  farmers’  markets  is  a  

more  recent  trend,  the  government  acknowledged  affordability  as  a  barrier  to  their  

success  with  low-­‐income  populations  nearly  two  decades  ago  (Schumacher  et  al.,  

2009).    To  promote  the  consumption  of  fresh  produce  among  low-­‐income  

Americans,  the  USDA  created  programs  to  supplement  existing  federal  food  

assistance  dollars  and  encourage  consumers  to  shop  at  farmers’  markets.      The  

Farmers  Market  Nutrition  Program  (FMNP)  began  providing  additional  subsidies  

toward  purchases  at  farmers’  markets  for  WIC  participants  (low-­‐income  Women  

Infants  and  Children)  in  1992  and  later  expanded  those  benefits  to  low-­‐income  

seniors  in  2000  with  the  Senior  Farmers  Market  Nutrition  Program  (SFMNP)  

(Schumacher  et  al.,  2009).    To  help  make  produce  at  farmers’  markets  even  more  

affordable  to  low  income  populations,  several  states  have  recently  implemented  

pilot  incentive  programs  that  provide  matching  or  bonus  funds  for  SNAP,  FMNP,  and  

SFMNP  dollars  used  at  farmers’  markets.  Though  most  of  these  programs  are  still  in  

their  infancy,  Schumacher  et  al.  report  “early  qualitative  evidence  shows  these  

programs  to  be  successful  at  attracting  low  income  customers  to  farmers’  markets,  

getting  low  income  customers  into  the  routine  of  shopping  at  farmers  markets,  and  

increasing  sales  for  farmers’  market  vendors”  (Schumacher  et  al.,  2009).  

  26  

Confronting  the  affordability  hurdle,  Boston,  with  the  support  of  Wholesome  

Wave,  Farm  Aid,  Mayor  Menino,  and  The  Food  Project,  introduced  the  “Boston  

Bounty  Bucks”  farmers’  market  subsidy  program  in  2008.    To  allow  customers  the  

option  of  purchasing  produce  with  their  SNAP/EBT  cards,  this  program  first  equips  

vendors  with  wireless  EBT  terminals,  along  with  proper  training,  funding  for  

terminal  usage  fees,  and  technical  support.  For  the  hundreds  of  Boston  residents  

that  depend  on  federal  nutrition  assistance  and  have  been  previously  limited  to  

conventional  grocery  and  convenience  stores,  the  ability  to  buy  fresh,  local  fruits  

and  vegetables  from  a  farm  stand  offers  a  different  environment  that  makes  buying  

and  consuming  produce  more  appealing.    The  program’s  main  incentive  is  to  

provide  matching  funds  for  customers  that  use  SNAP/EBT  dollars  at  participating  

farmers’  markets  (up  to  $20).  In  addition  to  increasing  the  purchasing  power  of  

people  with  low  incomes  and  broadening  the  customer  base  at  farmers  markets,  this  

double  voucher  program  supports  local  farmers  and  producers  willing  to  sell  in  low-­‐

income  neighborhoods  (Schumacher  et  al.,  2009).    A  2009  survey  on  the  progress  of  

the  Boston  Bounty  Bucks  program  reported  $20,  093.77  in  SNAP  and  matching  BBB  

purchases  at  thirteen  participating  farmers’  markets,  and  found  that  customers  

credited  the  subsidy  program  as  an  important  factor  in  their  increased  consumption  

of  fruits  and  vegetables  (Kim,  2010).    By  2010,  twenty-­‐one  farmers’  markets  

throughout  the  Boston  metropolitan  area  participated  in  the  BBB  program  and  the  

usage  of  SNAP  ($41,402.28)  along  with  BBB  matches  ($36,409.46)  combined  for  a  

total  of  $77,811.74  in  sales-­‐  a  387%  increase  over  the  previous  summer.    

Representing  28.5%  of  total  Boston  sales,  the  ten  markets  located  in  Dorchester  and  

  27  

Roxbury  reported  a  total  of  $21,699.58  in  combined  SNAP/BBB  sales  (The  Food  

Project,  preliminary  report,  2011).  

   1.7.  Relative  Cost  of  Direct  Retail:  Consumer  Perceptions  

There  exists  a  widespread  popular  perception  that  farmers’  market  produce  

is  more  expensive  than  produce  in  conventional  supermarkets  (Jones,  2009).      

Evidence  comes  from  Grace  et  al.’s  (2005)  survey  of  shoppers  at  a  farmers’  market  

in  Portland,  Oregon.  The  study  found  that  22%  of  participants  mentioned  price  

when  asked  what  would  influence  them  to  use  farmers’  markets  regularly,  claiming  

that  farmers’  markets  were  too  costly  for  their  budgets  and  decidedly  more  

expensive  than  conventional  grocery  options  with  statements  like  “markets  offer  

higher  quality  produce  than  grocery  stores,  but  prices  are  unreasonable”,  and  

“farmers’  markets  are  for  rich  people”.    Not  surprisingly,  nearly  42%  of  those  who  

discussed  price  as  a  major  factor  had  never  been  to  a  farmers’  market  before,  

inferring  that  outside  information-­‐not  personal  experience-­‐  caused  them  to  form  the  

perception  that  farmers’  markets  are  expensive.  The  survey  also  impressively  

identified  that  many  shoppers  believed  farmers’  markets  sold  mostly  organic  

produce,  which  they  identified  was  categorically  beyond  their  price  range  and  thus  

not  worth  the  trip.  

These  perceptions  may  be  fed  by  the  cultural  popularity  of  buying  local  in  

affluent  communities,  the  placement  of  a  higher  premium  on  local  produce  with  the  

expectation  that  it  has  fewer  chemical  preservatives,  the  presence  of  expensive  

artisanal  and  specialty  goods  at  farmers’  markets,  or  possibly  a  reality  of  higher  

prices.  However,  many  proponents  of  direct-­‐retail  insist  that  lower  prices  are  more  

  28  

likely  because  farmers’  markets  allow  farmers  to  sell  their  produce  directly  to  the  

consumer,  avoiding  the  expense  of  a  middleman  and  rising  fuel  costs  (Larsen  et  al.,  

2009).    Another  common  discussion  emphasizes  the  impact  of  produce  seasonality  

on  prices,  as  direct-­‐retail  outlets  may  be  able  to  provide  lower  prices  on  in-­‐season  

produce  than  supermarkets  (Sommer  et  al.).  

   1.8.  Relative  Cost  of  Direct  Retail:  Previous  Research  

The  confusion  over  whether  farmers’  market  produce  is  indeed  more  or  less  

expensive  that  supermarket  produce  is  perhaps  most  perpetuated  by  the  

outstanding  lack  of  relevant  price  comparison  studies  available.    I  shared  this  

frustration  in  my  attempts  at  recovering  appropriate  literature  and  learned  that  

other  researchers  were  equally  disappointed  at  the  underdevelopment  of  this  

investigative  cause  (Larsen  et  al.  2009,  Jones  2009,  Pirog  and  McCann,  2009).  

Undoubtedly  the  first  study  to  compare  the  prices  of  produce  at  farmers’  

markets  with  those  at  conventional  supermarkets,  Sommer  et  al.’s  1980  “Price  

Savings  to  Consumers  at  Farmers  Markets”  is  worth  great  attention.    As  the  study  

celebrates  its  30-­‐year  anniversary,  many  statements  seem  ancient  compared  to  the  

sweeping  farmers’  market  trends  of  today  and  thus  are  difficult  to  relate  to  current  

accessibility  issues.    Nonetheless,  Sommer  et  al.  (1980)  showed  similar  enthusiasm  

for  the  establishment  of  24  Markets  in  California  due  to  a  renewed  interest  in  

farmers’  markets  for  their  direct  marketing,  “exciting  shopping  experience”,  and  an  

“opportunity  for  city  and  country  people  to  come  together”.  The  results  of  the  study  

showed  a  statistically  significant  difference  where  overall  unit  costs  at  the  farmers’  

markets  were  34%  lower  than  overall  unit  costs  at  nearby  supermarkets.  

  29  

Sommer  et  al.’s  methodology  was  carefully  planned  and  succeeded  in  several  

areas.  The  study  was  conducted  at  15  out  of  18  then  current  California  Farmers’  

markets  and  2-­‐3  nearby  supermarkets  over  the  summer  and  fall  seasons  which  

allowed  for  the  collection  of  many  data  points  and  adequately  accounted  for  

seasonal  variability.    One  drawback  is  that  when  different  pricing  systems  were  

used  in  corresponding  retail  outlets  (ex.  apples  sold  by  the  basket  and  apples  by  the  

pound),  these  products  were  simply  omitted  from  the  study  rather  than  using  a  

simple  standardization  calculation  to  avoid  the  loss  of  data.  The  study  also  cross-­‐

compared  city  size  with  price;  and  though  no  significant  findings  resulted,  it  

indicates  a  realization  that  not  all  farmers’  market  environments  are  comparable.    

Although  Sommer  et  al.’s  study  is  dated,  as  one  of  the  first  contemporary  studies  of  

its  kind,  it  is  crucial  to  analyze  the  design  of  these  studies  in  order  to  develop  a  

better  standard  for  this  area  of  research.  

A  2009  study  conducted  by  Pirog  and  McCann  employed  the  use  of  a  “market  

basket”  sample  of  foods  across  farmers’  markets,  supermarkets,  natural  foods  

markets,  and  butcher  shops  in  Iowa  to  compare  the  prices  of  locally  grown  foods  

and  foods  procured  from  a  national  distributor.    They  found  that  the  mean  price  per  

pound  of  vegetables  sold  at  farmers  markets  ($1.25)  was  10%  lower  than  at  

supermarkets  ($1.39),  but  the  difference  between  these  values  proved  statistically  

insignificant.      

  Pirog  and  McCann  credit  competitive  pricing  of  summer  squash  at  farmers’  

market  (due  to  seasonality,  supply,  or  weather)  with  skewing  the  advantage  toward  

locally  grown  foods.    Regarding  data  collection  methods,  the  developers  enforced  

  30  

very  strict  procedures  in  order  to  maintain  consistency;  however,  I  believe  the  

choice  of  collection  period  overshadows  these  efforts  and  is  the  prime  reason  

behind  this  study’s  lack  of  significant  data.    By  using  only  5  data  points  between  July  

and  August,  which  the  authors  admit  represents  the  “height  of  local  fresh  fruit  an  

vegetable  availability  in  Iowa”,  along  with  a  selection  of  crops  that  are  particularly  

abundant  during  that  time,  the  locally-­‐grown  results  were  predisposed  to  reflect  the  

extreme  variation  in  price  related  to  crop  production  (non-­‐local  summer  squash  

was  nearly  twice  the  price  of  local  varieties).    Such  results  were  likely  expected  and  

may  have  been  desired  by  the  researchers  in  order  to  support  their  organization’s  

local  and  sustainable  agriculture  initiatives.  

A  Seattle  University  Business  class  in  partnership  with  the  city’s  

Neighborhood  Farmers’  Market  Alliance  conducted  another  study  with  potentially  

similar  motivation.    The  May  2010  study,  led  by  Professor  Stacey  Jones,  concluded  

that  prices  at  the  main  Seattle  farmers’  market  were  nearly  30  percent  lower,  on  

average,  than  those  at  one  supermarket,  but  did  not  differ  significantly  from  prices  

at  the  two  other  surveyed  supermarkets.    Having  collected  data  only  over  the  course  

of  five  consecutive  days  in  May  and  using  very  different  types  of  supermarkets,  

among  other  drawbacks,  the  students’  admission  that  their  study  is  far  from  

comprehensive  seems  correct.  Again,  the  condensed  sampling  period  does  not  

provide  for  an  analysis  of  a  trend,  but  rather  of  a  specific  event.    

These  observational  studies  vary  in  process,  purpose,  and  accuracy,  

reinforcing  a  need  for  the  development  of  better,  more  uniform  methodology  

  31  

comparing  produce  prices  at  supermarkets  to  prices  at  direct  retail  outlets,  and  

specifically  at  farmers  markets.    

 1.9.  Conclusion    

This  review  demonstrates  the  breadth,  complexity,  and  interconnectedness  

of  national  food  access  issues  that  contribute  to  the  confusion  of  public,  and  even  

academic,  perceptions  about  the  ability  of  underserved  neighborhoods  to  access  

healthy  foods.    Still,  noticeable  gaps  in  the  literature  exist.  While  several  studies  

have  examined  supermarket  access  for  low-­‐income  households,  very  few  have  

explored  the  impact  on  food  prices  or  nutritional  benefits  or  alternative  food  

purchasing  options  like  farmers’  markets.    Further  research  should  be  directed  at  

measuring  the  immediate  impact  of  funding  allocated  to  farmers’  markets  in  low-­‐

income  urban  environments  in  order  to  demonstrate  tremendous  improvements  in  

food  access  and  strengthen  proposals  for  necessary  future  funding.  

  Finally,  the  need  for  a  replicable  methodology  for  comparing  produce  prices  

at  conventional  grocery  outlets  with  those  at  direct  retail  outlets  is  very  clear.    This  

methodology  should  ideally  include  strategies  that  account  for  the  hard  to  measure  

effects  of  seasonality  and  quality,  and  also  consider  the  impact  of  public  food  

assistance.    Most  importantly,  it  is  clear  there  is  a  need  for  neighborhood-­‐specific  

price  comparison  studies  to  address  the  concerns  of  local  consumers.    Through  the  

creation  of  an  agreed-­‐upon,  replicable  method  of  price  analysis,  efforts  to  improve  

food  access  in  underserved  neighborhoods  across  the  nation  will  be  made  more  

visible.      By  developing  and  conducting  a  pilot  study  in  two  Boston  neighborhoods  

  32  

that  have  become  leaders  in  the  community-­‐guided  healthy  food  access  movement,  

the  observational  phase  of  this  report  aims  to  contribute  to  this  process.  

  33  

Section  2  

Observational  Study:  The  Affordability  of  Farmers’  Markets  in  

Underserved  Boston  Communities  

 

1.  Overview  

This  study  uses  comparative  price  analysis  of  produce  items  to  assess  the  

relative  costs  of  produce  at  local  farmers’  markets  and  supermarkets  in  the  Boston  

neighborhoods  of  North  Dorchester,  South  Dorchester,  and  Roxbury.    In  this  section,  

I  begin  with  the  methodology  of  this  study:  the  identification  of  direct-­‐retail  

(farmers’  markets)  and  conventional  grocery  outlets  within  the  defined  

neighborhoods,  an  explanation  of  how  a  variety  of  produce  types  were  deemed  most  

appropriate  for  the  time  and  demographic  focus  at  hand,  and  a  detailed  description  

of  how  price  and  quality  data  were  collected.    Next,  I  outline  a  series  of  regression  

tests  used  in  the  statistical  analysis  of  data,  and  present  results  on  variation  in  

availability,  quality,  and  price  per  pound.    The  final  section  is  a  comprehensive  

discussion  of  statistical  and  observational  results,  along  with  conclusions  and  

inferences  derived  from  relevant  information  about  the  circumstances  surrounding  

produce  production  and  distribution  at  these  retail  environments.    Cammy  Watts  

and  Cathy  Wirth,  on  behalf  of  The  Food  Project  (Boston,  MA),  supervised  the  

development  and  completion  of  this  study  over  the  course  of  the  summer  of  2010;  

hence,  the  plural  “we”  is  used  when  referring  directly  to  the  study’s  design  and  

fulfillment.  

  34  

2.  Objectives  

The  main  goal  of  the  study  was  to  learn  how  the  price  of  produce  differs  

between  farmers’  markets  and  supermarkets  in  these  neighborhoods,  if  at  all.    Since  

farmer’s  markets  in  low-­‐income  areas  are  unique  and  often  feature  different  price  

points  than  markets  in  more  affluent  areas,  our  efforts  were  focused  entirely  on  the  

retail  options  specific  to  a  defined  geographic  area.    While  this  limits  generalization  

of  the  results  to  a  broader,  more  economically  diverse  area,  it  emphasizes  the  need  

for  food  access  research  that  is  more  concentrated  on  specific  urban  demographics  

and  communities.    As  low-­‐income  communities  suffer  disproportionately  from  diet  

related  disease,  it  makes  sense  to  focus  research  on  food  access  in  these  areas.    A  

second  major  goal  of  this  study  is  to  pilot  a  methodology  for  comparing  produce  

prices  and  other  observational  data  for  other  researchers.    Without  a  replicable  

model,  the  compilation  of  a  larger,  more  useful  set  of  local  and  national  price  data  

will  not  be  possible.      Additionally,  I  will  include  our  secondary  efforts  to  assess  

produce  quality  at  all  locations,  recognizing  that  the  subjective  nature  of  this  

analysis  makes  it  a  more  complex  challenge.  

   3.  Methodology  

3.1.  Variable  Selection  

The  study  identified  the  geographic  area  of  interest  as  the  neighborhoods  of  

North  Dorchester,  South  Dorchester,  and  Roxbury.    These  neighborhoods  were  

chosen  based  on  similar  socio-­‐economic  statistics,  proximity  to  one  another,  high  

density  of  farmers’  markets,  diversity  of  cultural  backgrounds,  and  the  nature  of  The  

  35  

Food  Project’s  relationship  with  and  past  research  into  these  communities.  These  

neighborhoods  consist  predominantly  of  people/  families  on  limited  incomes  

(Health  of  Boston,  2010).  Recognizing  the  high  rate  of  chronic  disease  related  to  

poor  eating  habits  in  this  area,  we  also  feel  that  this  population  could  greatly  benefit  

from  more  information  about  the  availability  of  fresh,  healthy  food  within  this  

specific  area  (Health  of  Boston,  2010).      

 

3.2.  Retail  Outlets  

We  identified  all  ten  farmers’  markets  

located  within  these  three  neighborhoods  that  

were  initially  scheduled  to  run  throughout  the  

summer  of  2010.    All  of  these  markets  are  

similarly  small  in  size,  having  three  or  fewer  

vendors;  but  have  been  operating  for  very  

different  amounts  of  time,  ranging  from  two  to  

thirty  years.  The  markets  in  this  sample  have  

been  implemented  for  a  variety  of  reasons:  

“main  street”  organizations  hope  to  foster  

economic  development,  health  centers  aim  to  

promote  healthy  eating,  youth  programs  look  to  encourage  leadership,  and  other  

non-­‐profits  work  to  nurture  community  building  (see  Appendix  A).    We  then  

identified  all  seven  large  to  mid-­‐size  conventional  grocery  stores  within  the  

Figure  4.1.  

  36  

geographic  area  based  on  conversations  with  residents  regarding  the  most  

frequented  stores.    All  of  the  retail  outlets  accept  EBT/  SNAP  and  WIC  coupons;  all  of  

the  farmers’  markets  also  accept  FMNP  coupons,  senior  coupons  (SFMNP),  and  

participate  in  the  Boston’s  Bounty  Bucks  double  voucher  program  (which  provides  a  

50%  discount  for  EBT  card  users  up  to  $20).    

 3.3.  Time  Periods  

Using  the  anticipated  starting  and  ending  dates  for  the  

markets,  we  identified  a  sixteen-­‐week  period  from  July  5  to  October  

24  during  which  all  of  the  farmers’  markets  would  be  open  for  the  

2010  season.    To  account  for  predicted  fluctuation  in  produce  price  

and  availability  throughout  the  market  season,  this  period  was  

divided  into  eight  separate  14-­‐day  periods.    Data  for  each  location  

was  collected  exactly  one  time  within  the  same  time  period,  and  is  

assumed  to  be  representative  of  average  values  during  those  14  

days.  

3.4.  Produce  Types  

  The  study  identified  ten  types  of  produce  that  represented  common  “staple”  

food  items  for  the  local  population.    This  list  also  reflects  a  selection  of  items  that  we  

found,  through  research  and  inquiry  with  vendors  in  the  study,  would  be  most  

readily  available  at  markets  throughout  the  course  of  the  season.      Further,  we  chose  

items  for  which  specific  type/  growing  conditions  are  not  as  important  (compared  

to  the  price  differences  among  varieties  of  apples,  for  instance).  This  list  is  very  

Figure  4.2.  

  37  

specific  in  its  description  of  each  item  in  order  to  ensure  that  the  most  consistent  

samples  of  produce  are  being  compared  across  all  of  our  collection  locations.  

• Carrots:  unpeeled,  w/  green  tops  and  w/o  green  tops  

• Cucumbers:  unwrapped,  not  English  

• Onions  (yellow):  large,  loose  (not  bagged)  

• Tomatoes  (field):  about  fist  size,  not  hot  house/  greenhouse,  not  heirloom,  no  

vine  

• Zucchini:  green  summer  squash  

• White  Potatoes:  loose  

• Scallions:  green  onions  (not  red  bulb)  

• Lettuce:  green  leaf,  romaine/  Bibb  variety,  not  bagged/washed/trimmed  

• Bell  Peppers  (green):    loose  

• Green  Beans:  loose  

 

3.5.  Vendor  Research  

Realizing  that  some  Farmers’  Markets  feature  more  than  one  vendor,  we  

looked  into  a  sample  of  vendors  selling  goods  across  all  of  the  markets.    For  each  

vendor,  we  researched  and  recorded  information  that  would  be  relevant  to  the  

quality  of  the  items  being  sold  at  the  markets;  such  as,  organic  certification  (if  any),  

growing  methods/  pesticide  usage,  amount  of  time  elapsed  between  point  of  

harvest  and  point  of  sale,  distance  from  point  of  harvest,  non-­‐profit  status,  

strategies/  methods  of  price  variation  at  different  places  of  vending,  etc.  (see  

Appendix  D).    For  each  supermarket,  we  investigated  similar  factors  related  to  the  

quality  and  background  of  the  items  being  sold.  

3.6.  Data  Collection  

  38  

The  study  consists  of  first  person  observations  and  data  collection  (see  

Appendix  B)  at  all  farmers’  markets  and  supermarkets  throughout  the  course  of  the  

2010  summer  market  season,  defined  as  July  5  to  October  24.    All  observations  per  

time  period  were  taken  within  the  same  14-­‐day  span,  each  period  beginning  on  a  

Tuesday  and  ending  on  a  Monday.      Based  on  farmer  and  vendor  interviews,  we  

assumed  that  farmers’  market  prices  were  consistent  throughout  each  respective  

day  the  market  was  operating  and  did  not  fluctuate  from  market  opening  to  closing  

on  the  date  observations  were  made2.      All  individuals  who  collected  data  at  any  

point  throughout  the  survey  went  through  a  training  workshop  prior  to  collection  in  

order  to  ensure  consistency  of  data  collection  at  all  times  and  locations  (see  

Appendix  C).  All  vendors  were  notified  of  our  study  prior  to  collection  in  order  to  

enable  cooperation  and  support.    

For  each  item  at  a  location,  the  price  per  pound  was  recorded  as  labeled;  

however,  many  items  were  sold  in  a  unit  other  than  pounds  (per  head,  per  bunch,  

per  bag,  per  each).    In  this  instance,  a  random  sample  of  three  units  was  weighed  on  

a  scale  to  obtain  an  average  weight  for  that  item  at  that  location.  The  price  per  unit  

was  then  converted  to  a  price  per  pound  based  on  the  average  weight  of  the  item  in  

each  random  sample.  An  average  price  per  pound  was  collected  for  each  vendor  

independently  and  later  combined  into  an  overall  mean  price  per  pound  for  each  

market.    At  each  farmers’  market,  prices  from  all  vendors  were  observed  to  the  best  

of  our  ability  but  may  have  varied  according  to  availability  of  item,  cooperation  of  

                                                                                                               2  Several  vendors  frequently  dropped  prices  at  the  end  of  the  market  to  move  produce,  but  we  did  not  have  the  capacity  to  capture  time  discrepancies  in  price  for  each  market  and  hope  staggered  collection  times  account  for  some  of  this  potential  discount  opportunity.  

  39  

vendor,  and  precision/accuracy  of  scale(s)  used.    If  an  item  was  not  available  for  any  

reason,  its  price  was  not  recorded,  even  if  it  had  been  available  earlier  in  the  market.      

At  each  conventional  market,  the  same  process  was  implemented  with  

regard  to  non-­‐pound  units.    In  the  case  that  more  than  one  option  of  a  produce  type  

is  on  display,  we  recorded  data  for  the  smallest,  most  conventional  (i.e.  non-­‐organic)  

unit  sold.    This  means  that  if  loose  field  tomatoes  were  available  in  both  organic  and  

non-­‐organic  varieties,  we  would  record  data  for  the  non-­‐organic  variety;  or,  if  

carrots  without  greens  were  available  only  in  2  lb.,  5  lb.,  or  10  lb.  bags,  we  recorded  

data  for  the  2  lb.  bag.    While  aware  that  several  conventional  supermarkets  have  

volume  or  “loyalty  card”  discounts  available,  we  did  not  take  these  into  account  

because  such  discounts  were  not  consistent  with  farmers  markets’  pricing  schemes  

and  because  low-­‐income  households  are  often  cash-­‐constrained  and  not  able  to  take  

advantage  of  such  bulk  purchasing.    

Data  collection  also  included  recording  an  indicator  of  visual  quality.    

Collectors  commented  on  and  ranked  the  overall  visual  quality  of  the  produce  type  

on  display  using  a  scale  of  1  to  3  where  1=  “wouldn’t  buy  the  item”,  2=  buy  “item  

only  if  necessary”,  and  3=  “excited  to  buy  and  use  item”  (see  Appendix  E  for  

examples).      In  some  cases,  collectors  couldn’t  decide  between  whole  numbers  and  

resorted  to  using  1.5  or  2.5.    In  order  to  treat  quality  consistently,  all  half-­‐number  

values  (50  total)  were  rounded  toward  the  mode  rating  for  the  same  produce  item  

at  the  same  vendor  or  supermarket  across  all  time  periods.  

There  were  a  few  occasions  when  it  was  found  at  the  last  minute  that  none  of  

the  collection  proxies  were  able  to  collect  the  data  for  a  certain  location  for  a  time  

  40  

period  or  there  was  a  miscommunication  where  a  market  was  missed  entirely.  In  

these  cases  we  conducted  phone  interviews  with  each  vendor  immediately  upon  

realizing  the  mistake  in  order  to  collect  their  availability  and  prices  from  the  most  

recent  missed  market.    For  example,  the  Ashmont  farmers’  market  was  rained  out  

on  the  second  Friday  of  collection  period  3  and  the  data  had  not  been  collected  on  

the  first  Friday,  so  we  acquired  information  about  what  was  available  at  the  first  

Friday’s  markets  and  what  the  prices  were.    Since  we  could  not  be  present  to  weigh  

items  sold  in  units  other  than  pounds,  we  interpolated  unit  weight  by  averaging  

average  unit  weights  for  one  unit  of  that  item  across  all  time  periods  and  used  the  

period  of  interest’s  unit  price  to  calculate  a  standardized  price  per  pound  value.    So  

to  approximate  the  price  per  pound  of  carrots  sold  for  $2.50  per  bunch  by  Spring  

Brook  Farm  (Vendor)  at  the  Ashmont  Farmers’  Market  during  time  period  3,  we  

calculated  the  average  unit  weight  of  a  bunch  across  all  time  periods  that  it  was  

available  [(.75+1.33+.  93)/3=  1.00  lb.],  then  followed  the  standardizing  calculation  

used  for  all  data  [$2.50/1.00  lb.  =  $2.50/lb.].    While  we  initially  withheld  data  for  

non  pound  units  when  corresponding  unit  weight  was  not  provided,  because  of  the  

number  of  missing  data  points  overall  due  to  highly  varying  produce  availability  

from  week  to  week,  we  felt  it  was  reasonable  to  estimate  these  data  points  because  

we  were  certain  the  item  was  available  at  the  time  but  it  was  logistically  impossible  

to  obtain  a  unit  weight.    The  same  averaging  process  was  also  done  to  obtain  each  

items  estimated  visual  rating.  Data  for  a  certain  price  in  a  certain  time  period  was  

never  interpolated  for  a  produce  item  that  was  not  available  during  that  period,  as  

  41  

we  recognize  availability  is  an  important  factor  in  reviewing  produce  at  both  

farmers  markets  and  supermarkets.  

 4.  Statistical  Analysis    

4.1.  Statistical  Method  

The  primary  goal  of  this  analysis  was  to  determine  the  difference,  if  any,  

between  price  per  pound  of  produce  items  at  farmers’  markets  and  price  per  pound  

of  produce  items  at  supermarkets.  We  also  wanted  to  determine  whether  the  

difference  between  price  and  retail  location  type  could  be  explained  by  other  

variables,  namely  produce  type,  time  period,  and  quality  rating.  Multiple  regression  

was  used  to  control  for  these  other  variables.    

Regression  analysis  uses  one  response/dependent  variable  and  one  or  more  

predictor/independent  variables  to  estimate  a  mathematical  model  that  describes  

the  direction  and  strength  of  the  relationship  between  these  variables  of  interest  

(Kleinbaum  et  al.,  1998).  Forming  a  model  with  various  parameters  based  on  a  

research  question  allows  for  the  construction  of  hypotheses  that  can  be  tested  to  

provide  information  about  a  certain  parameter’s  slope  estimate  and  its  significance.  

After  reviewing  all  of  the  collected  data,  I  specified  a  series  of  models  and  

hypotheses  for  the  effects  of  single  and  combined  variables  based  around  mean  

price  per  pound  as  the  important  outcome  variable  of  interest.  Statistical  analyses  

were  performed  using  STATA,  version  9.0  (StataCorp,  College  Station,  TX,  2008).  

 

 

4.2.  Defining  the  Regression  Model  

  42  

In  defining  the  regression  model,  I  concentrated  on  constructing  a  model  

most  relevant  to  the  research  question  of  “How  does  the  mean  price  per  pound  

(PRICE)  change  with  variation  in  location  type  (LOCATION),  while  produce  type  

(PRODUCE),  time  period  (TIME),  and  quality  rating  (QUALITY)  are  held  constant?”  

For  this  model,  the  dependent  variable  throughout  the  succeeding  regression  tests  

is  the  standardized  mean  price  per  pound  [PRICE  (Y)]  of  a  fixed  amount  of  a  

produce  item.  All  four  independent  variables  of  interest  are  categorical  and  are  

added  in  succession  to  assess  relative  importance  and  individual  trends.    To  

distinguish  between  the  two  options  for  the  non-­‐fixed  independent  variable  

LOCATION,  the  codes  1=Farmers’  Market  or  “FM”  and  0=  Supermarket  or  “SM”  were  

used.  The  numbers  0-­‐7  correspond  to  the  eight  periods  of  TIME,  the  numbers  0-­‐9  

identify  the  ten  unique  types  of  PRODUCE,  and  the  numbers  0-­‐2  are  used  

categorically  to  denote  QUALITY  rating  along  the  previously  described  1-­‐3  scale  of  

assessment.    These  variables  were  then  converted  into  sets  of  dummy  or  indicator  

variables  for  each  time  period,  produce,  and  quality  category.    

Note  that  if  a  nominal  variable  has  k  categories,  then  k-­‐1  indicator  variables  

are  assigned  to  index  these  categories  because  the  first  level  of  each  nominal  

variable  is  indicated  by  the  presence  of  zeros  in  all  of  the  hypothetical  reference  

cells  (i.e.  there  are  a  total  of  8  time  periods,  but  only  seven  indicator  variables  are  

used  because  “time1”  is  actually  the  indicator  variable  of  time  period  2,  “time2”  is  

the  indicator  variable  for  time  period  3,  and  so  on).    The  complete  population  

regression  model  below  represents  the  full  model  of  price  variation  between  

locations  while  controlling  for  fixed  effects  with  each  set  of  indicator  variables.  As  

  43  

was  mentioned  earlier,  fixed  effects  are  added  in  succession  to  provide  alternative  

angles  of  analysis.    The  command  “robust”  is  added  to  account  for  the  fact  that  there  

may  be  heteroskedasticity  in  the  error  terms.3    

The  value  of  β0  represents  the  intercept  and  varies  according  to  the  equation,  

and  the  reported  value  of  β1  represents  the  estimated  coefficient  of  variation  for  the  

variable  of  primary  interest,  which  is  the  location  of  the  sale.  

4.3. Description of Sample

Preliminary  descriptive  statistics  (Table  4.1)  relate  a  helpful  outline  of  the  

data  before  introducing  and  controlling  for  other  variables.    Out  of  1760  possible  

observations  of  price  (and  quality)  at  both  farmers  markets  and  supermarkets  at  the  

outset  of  this  study,  a  total  of  1032  data  points  were  actually  recorded.    Despite  the  

initial  over-­‐representation  of  possible  observations  at  farmers’  markets  due  to  a  

higher  number  of  vendors  and  collection  sites,  both  location  types  have  fairly  equal  

representation  in  the  final  data  set,  with  52%  from  farmers  markets  and  48%  from  

                                                                                                               3  This  will  tend  to  give  more  conservative  estimates  of  the  standard  errors  (and  p-­‐values).  

#

Possible Data Pts

# Recorded Data Pts.

% of Possible Data

Recorded

% of Overall

Data

Mean Price/lb

($)

SD Price/lb

($)

Mean Quality

SD Quality

FM 1200 537 45% 52% 1.76 .904 2.74 .47

SM 560 495 88% 48% 1.72 .985 2.46 .62

Total 1760 1032

Y = PRICE = β 0 + β 1 LOC + β 2 TIME1 + … + β 8 TIME7 + β 9 PROD1 + … + β 17 PROD9 + β 18QUAL1 + β 19QUAL2 + E

Table  4.1  

  44  

supermarkets.    This  equality  was  not  intended,  as  the  goal  of  the  study  was  to  collect  

a  majority  of  possible  observations  regardless  of  relative  representation  (analysis  

would  weigh  each  location  appropriately);  yet,  it  hints  at  the  significant  impact  of  

produce  availability  by  location  type  throughout  the  study.  Notably,  the  difference  in  

the  proportion  of  realized  data  points  for  each  location  type  is  very  large;  only  45%  

of  possible  observations  at  farmers  markets  were  actually  realized  and  included  in  

the  final  data  set,  compared  with  88%  of  possible  observations  at  supermarkets.    An  

unrealized  data  point  most  commonly  resulted  from  the  case  that  a  certain  produce  

item  was  not  available  at  the  time  or  day  of  data  collection,  but  may  have  also  been  

the  consequence  of  misreported  data,  a  sold  out  item,  or  market  cancellation  due  to  

weather,  among  others.    This  discrepancy  will  receive  more  detailed  attention  in  the  

later  section  on  availability.      

 4.4.  Overall  Differences  in  Means  

  This  data  also  shows  that  the  overall  mean  price  per  pound  was  four  cents  

greater  at  farmers’  markets  ($1.76)  than  at  supermarkets  ($1.72).  The  variance  of  

mean  price  per  pound  at  farmers  markets  (0.904)  was  significantly  lower  (p  =  .026)  

than  the  variance  for  the  same  value  at  supermarkets  (0.985),  meaning  that  overall  

variation  in  mean  price  per  pound  was  greater  at  supermarkets.    As  for  the  

measurement  of  quality  on  a  scale  of  1  to  3,  preliminary  analysis  indicated  that  

mean  quality  at  farmers’  markets  (2.74)  was  significantly  higher  (p  <  0.00)  than  at  

supermarkets  (2.46).    Validating  this  result,  a  two-­‐  sample  z-­‐test  showed  that  the  

proportion  of  “3’s”  (highest  quality)  ratings  received  by  farmers’  markets  (.759)  was  

  45  

significantly  higher  than  the  proportion  of  “3’s”  received  by  supermarkets  (.533),  

yielding  a  test  statistic  of  7.56  and  a  p-­‐value  of  0.00.    

   Regression  of  price  on  location:  

Equation   Fixed  Effects   β1   P-­value  

PRICE  =  β0  +  β1  LOC  +  E   NONE   .042   .480  

 

First,  a  simple  regression  of  the  dependent  variable  PRICE  on  LOCATION  

alone  describes  the  variation  in  price  between  farmers’  markets  and  supermarkets  

without  controlling  for  any  other  factors.    This  test  gives  the  same  result  (about  

four-­‐cents)  as  the  simple  difference  in  means,  indicating  that  mean  price  per  pound  

was  higher  at  farmers’  markets  than  at  supermarkets,  though  not  significantly  so.    

Here,  the  estimated  coefficient  of  variation  value  for  β1    =  0.042  signifies  that  on  

average,  farmers’  market  prices  are  $0.042  (roughly  2.5%)  higher  than  supermarket  

prices  based  on  the  mean  supermarket  price  of  $1.72.    

Regression  of  price  on  location  controlling  only  for  produce  type:  

Equation Fixed Effects β1 P-value

PRICE = β0 + β1 LOC + β2 PROD1 + … + β810PROD9 + E PRODUCE .098 .019

Next,  a  regression  of  the  dependent  variable  PRICE  on  LOCATION  while  

controlling  for  PRODUCE  describes  how  price  varies  by  location  type  while  

controlling  for  the  most  inherent  categorical  difference  in  this  data-­‐produce.    The  

value  for  β1  =  .098  suggests  that  mean  price  per  pound  was  higher  at  farmers’  

Table  4.2  

Table  4.3.  

  46  

markets  than  at  supermarkets,  after  controlling  for  produce  type,  by  $0.098  or  

roughly  6.2%,  on  average,  while  the  very  low  p-­‐value  of  0.019  indicates  that  this  

variation  is  indeed  statistically  significant.    Since  controlling  for  produce  type  did  

lead  to  a  significant  10-­‐cent  average  increase  in  price  at  farmers’  markets,  this  

model  suggests  that  the  influence  of  location  type  on  price  was  subject  to  greater  

variation  within  each  unique  produce  category.  

 

Regression  of  price  on  location  controlling  only  for  time:  

Equation Fixed Effects β1 P-value

PRICE = β0 + β1 LOC + β2 TIME1 + … + β8 TIME7 + E TIME .038 .516

A  regression  of  the  PRICE  on  LOCATION  while  controlling  only  for  TIME  

describes  how  price  varies  by  location  type  while  controlling  for  the  potentially  

confounding  effect  of  seasonality  as  measured  by  time  period.    The  estimated  

coefficient  of  .038  again  suggests  that  mean  price  per  pound  was  higher  at  farmers’  

markets  than  at  supermarkets  by  $0.038  or  roughly  2%,  on  average,  while  the  very  

high  p-­‐value  of  0.516  asserts  that  this  variation  is  not  statistically  significant.    Since  

controlling  for  time  had  little  impact  on  the  extent  or  strength  of  the  results,  this  

model  also  suggests  that  time  period  alone  did  not  have  much  of  an  effect  on  

variation  in  price  between  location  types.    This  may  be  due  to  the  fact  that  both  FM  

and  SM  were  sampled  in  each  time  period,  so  the  data  is  well  balanced  across  time  

for  each  location  type.  

 

Table  4.4.  

  47  

Regression  of  price  on  location  controlling  only  for  quality:  

Equation Fixed Effects β1 P-value

PRICE = β0 + β1 LOC + β2 QUAL1 + β3

QUAL2 + E QUALITY .007 .923

A  regression  of  PRICE  on  LOCATION  while  controlling  only  for  QUALITY  

describes  how  price  varies  by  location  type  while  controlling  for  the  effect  of  quality  

rating.    The  estimated  coefficient  of  .007  implies  that  mean  price  per  pound  was  

higher  at  farmers’  markets  than  at  supermarkets  by  $0.007,  or  less  than  1%,  on  

average,  while  the  high  p-­‐value  of  0.923  indicates  that  this  variation  is  not  

statistically  significant.    As  holding  only  quality  fixed  did  not  result  in  a  significant  

estimated  coefficient  of  variation,  this  model  would  propose  that  differences  in  

quality  between  location  types  did  not  have  a  impact  on  overall  price  per  pound  

variation  across  all  produce  types  and  time  periods.  

 Regression  of  price  on  location  controlling  for  time  and  produce  type:  

Equation Fixed Effects β1 P-value

PRICE = β0 + β1 LOC + β2 TIME1 + … + β8

TIME7 + β9 PROD1 + … + β17 PROD9 + E PRODUCE &

TIME .095 .023

A  regression  of  PRICE  on  LOCATION  while  controlling  for  both  TIME  and  

PRODUCE  shows  how  price  varies  by  location  type  while  controlling  for  the  effects  

of  time  period  and  produce  type.    This  test’s  estimated  coefficient  of  0.095  again  

suggests  that  mean  price  per  pound  was  higher  at  farmers’  markets  than  at  

supermarkets,  but  now  by  the  larger  amount  of  $0.095  or  about  5.8%,  on  average.    

Table  4.5.  

Table  4.6.  

  48  

The  p-­‐value  of  0.023  is  also  notably  lower,  indicating  that  the  increase  in  price  per  

pound  at  farmers’  markets  when  holding  time  and  produce  type  constant  is  

statistically  significant  at  a  5%  level.      

 

Regression  of  price  on  location  controlling  for  time,  produce  type,  and  quality:  

Equation Fixed Effects β1 P-value

PRICE=β0+β1LOC+β2TIME1+…+β8 TIME7+β9 PROD1+…+β17

PROD9+β18QUAL1+β19QUAL2+E

PRODUCE, TIME, & QUALITY .086 .088

A  regression  of  the  dependent  variable  PRICE  on  the  independent  variables  

LOCATION,  TIME,  PRODUCE,  and  QUALITY  describes  how  price  varies  by  location  

type  while  controlling  for  the  potentially  confounding  effects  of  time  period,  

produce  type,  and  quality  rating.    This  is  our  preferred  model  because  it  controls  for  

as  many  other  factors  as  possible  that  could  be  confounding  the  results.    This  test  

again  suggests  that  mean  price  per  pound  was  higher  at  farmers’  markets  than  at  

supermarkets,  by  a  $0.086  or  nearly  6%,  on  average.    While  the  p-­‐value  of  0.088  is  

higher  than  the  previous  test,  it  still  shows  that  the  increase  in  price  per  pound  

recorded  at  farmers’  markets  is  marginally  significant  (p  <  0.10).  Controlling  for  

time,  produce,  and  quality  confirms  that  the  higher  prices  observed  at  farmers’  

markets  are  not  driven  by  these  potentially  confounding  factors.    

A  side-­‐by-­‐side  comparison  of  these  successive  fixed  effects  in  Table  4.8  

illustrates  how  the  estimated  coefficient  of  variation  changes  as  subsequent  factors  

are  controlled  for.    Further,  by  comparing  the  estimated  coefficient  in  the  first  

Table  4.7.  

  49  

column  to  the  same  value  in  the  final  column,  the  potential  for  very  different  

outcomes  from  the  exact  same  data  set  is  clear  and  the  importance  of  controlling  for  

the  three  fixed  effects  of  produce  type,  time,  and  quality  is  reinforced.  

 

Regression Summary of PRICE on Successive Fixed Effects

 

 Log  Transformation  

Because  the  normality  assumption  for  (x,  y)  was  not  strongly  confirmed  at  

the  beginning  of  the  analysis,  the  next  step  examines  the  robustness  of  the  results  

using  an  alternate  dependent  variable.    To  do  this  transformation,  the  dependent  

variables  (y-­‐values  of  PRICE),  were  converted  using  the  natural  log  function  to  

generate  a  new  list  of  dependent  variables  called  “lnPRICE”.      A  histogram  plot  of  the  

new  (x,  lny)  distribution  confirms  that  this  log  transformation  successfully  created  a  

more  normal  distribution  (see  appendix  G).  In  order  to  capture  any  difference  in  

(1) (2) (3) (4)

LOCATION β1

(p-value)

.042 (.480)

.098 (.019)

.095 (.023)

.086 (.088)

R2 .001 .498 .499 .505 Fixed Effects

PRODUCE No Yes Yes Yes

TIME No No Yes Yes

QUALITY No No No Yes

Table  4.8.  

  50  

outcome  resulting  from  a  more  normally  distributed  data  set  and  truer  fitting  

regression  model,  the  same  preceding  series  of  tests  was  conducted  using  this  new  

set  of  natural  logs  lnPRICE  as  the  dependent  variable  while  keeping  all  independent  

and  indicator  variables  unchanged.    For  this  series  of  tests,  the  estimated  coefficient  

β1  can  be  interpreted  as  a  percentage  change  in  prices  attributed  to  shopping  at  a  

farmer’s  market  compared  to  a  supermarket.    The  results  of  successive  regressions  

are  summarized  in  Table  4.9  below.  

Regression Summary of lnPRICE on Successive Fixed Effects

 

  A  regression  of  the  dependent  variable  lnPRICE  on  LOCATION  alone  yields  an  

estimated  coefficient  of  .024  and  a  p-­‐value  of  .189.    This  result  suggests  that  when  

no  other  variables  are  controlled  for,  the  price  per  pound  is  2.4%  greater  at  farmers’  

markets,  however,  this  variation  is  not  statistically  significant.  

A  regression  of  the  dependent  variable  lnPRICE  on  LOCATION  controlling  for  

PRODUCE  alone  yields  an  estimated  coefficient  of  .035  and  a  p-­‐value  of  0.007.    These  

(1) (2) (3) (4)

LOCATION β1

(p-value)

.024 (.189)

.035 (.007)

.034 (.008)

.029 (.043)

R2 .005 .508 .509 .517 Fixed Effects

PRODUCE No Yes Yes Yes

TIME No No Yes Yes

QUALITY No No No Yes

Table  4.9.  

  51  

results  suggest  that  when  produce  type  is  held  constant,  the  price  per  pound  is  3.5%  

greater  at  farmers’  markets.    The  extremely  low  p-­‐value  of  .007  asserts  the  

statistical  significance  of  this  result  and  implies  that  a  price  variation  did  exist  

between  location  types.  

A  regression  of  the  dependent  variable  lnPRICE  on  LOCATION  controlling  for  

PRODUCE  and  TIME  yields  an  estimated  coefficient  of  .034  and  a  p-­‐value  of  0.008.    

These  results  suggest  that  when  produce  type  and  time  period  are  held  constant,  the  

price  per  pound  is  3.4%  greater  at  farmers’  markets.    The  extremely  low  p-­‐value  of  

.008  asserts  the  statistical  significance  of  this  result.  

Finally,  a  regression  of  the  dependent  variable  lnPRICE  on  LOCATION  

controlling  for  PRODUCE,  TIME,  and  QUALITY  yields  an  estimated  coefficient  of  .029  

and  a  p-­‐value  of  0.043.    These  results  suggest  that  when  produce  type,  time  period,  

and  quality  are  held  constant,  the  price  per  pound  is  2.9%  greater  at  farmers’  

markets.    The  very  low  p-­‐value  of  .043  asserts  the  statistical  significance  of  this  

result.  Most  importantly,  this  test  confirms  the  initial  test  results  using  PRICE  as  the  

dependent  variable,  meaning  that  the  overall  results  indicating  a  price  increase  at  

farmers’  markets  are  robust  to  alternate  specifications.    Importantly,  because  this  

test  results  gives  percentage  increase  expected  in  produce  price  at  farmers  markets,  

it  can  be  easily  applied  to  future  real-­‐world  examples  and  will  therefore  serve  as  the  

final  model  moving  forward.  

           

  52  

Variation  in  Price  by  Location  and  Produce  Item  

Supermarkets Farmers’ Markets

Next,  by  using  a  series  of  regression  tests  to  examine  how  price  varies  with  

location  type  for  each  produce  type  independently,  we  can  investigate  the  claim  that  

location  type  affects  the  price  per  pound  of  all  produce  types  differently  and  also  see  

if  certain  items  are  driving  the  results.    Two  types  of  tests  were  conducted  using  the  

hypothesis  and  variables  from  the  previous  section;  the  first  regression  does  not  

include  any  fixed  effects,  and  the  second  controls  for  the  fixed  effects  TIME  and  

QUALITY.    Because  the  data  was  divided  among  10  items  and  tests  were  conducted  

independently  for  each  item,  a  significance  level  of  α  =  0.01  is  used  to  determine  

No Fixed Effects

Time, Quality Fixed

# Observation

s

Mean Price/lb ($)

Standard Deviation

β1 P-value β1 P-

value Bell

Peppers 56 62 1.52 1.72 .284 .399 .194 .003 .172 .010

Carrots 24 59 2.02 1.73 .661 .999 -.285 .131 -.347 .052

Cucumbers 56 49 .989 1.24 .311 .419 .247 .001 .219 .001

Green Beans 48 56 1.74 2.09 .507 .661 .355 .003 .227 .062

Lettuce 42 45 2.04 1.94 .594 1.05 -.099 .588 -.028 .902

Onions 56 49 1.28 1.28 .332 .836 0 .918 .005 .971

Potatoes 56 45 .919 1.29 .156 .516 .381 .000 .401 .000

Scallions 55 32 3.79 3.35 1.17 1.46 -.446 .142 -.417 .188

Tomatoes 55 74 1.84 2.06 .534 .528 .215 .025 .137 .220

Zucchini 47 66 1.28 1.39 .269 .544 .098 .209 .169 .054

Table    4.10.  

  53  

statistical  significance.  For  each  of  ten  produce  types,  the  median  number  of  total  

observations  across  both  location  types  was  103,  varying  from  as  many  as  129  for  

tomatoes  to  only  49  for  onions.  

For  the  first  set  of  calculations,  PRICE=  β0  +  β1  LOC  +  E  (by  PRODUCE),  the  

dependent  variable  is  PRICE  and  the  lone  independent  variable  is  LOCATION.  Out  of  

10  produce  items,  only  3  reported  negative  estimated  coefficients  of  variation  

[carrots  (-­‐$0.285),  lettuce  (-­‐$0.099),  and  scallions  (-­‐$0.446)]  suggesting  higher  

prices  at  supermarkets  than  farmers’  markets,  on  average,  but  due  to  higher  p-­‐

values  none  of  these  results  were  statistically  significant.  Of  the  7  items  with  

positive  estimated  coefficients  suggesting  a  higher  price  per  pound  at  farmers’  

markets  on  average,  5  indicated  a  statistically  or  marginally  significant  increase  in  

price  based  on  very  low  p-­‐values:  (+$0.194;  P  =  .003),  cucumbers  (+$0.247;  P  =  

.001),  green  beans  (+$0.355;  P  =  .003),  potatoes  (+$0.381;  P  =  .000),  and  tomatoes  

(+$0.215;  P  =  .025).  

In  the  second  series  of  tests,  PRICE  =  β0  +  β1  LOC  +  β2  TIME1  +  …  +  β8  

TIME7  +  β9  QUAL1  +  β10  QUAL2  +  E    (by  PRODUCE),  the  fixed  effects  TIME  and  

QUALITY  are  introduced  to  control  for  potentially  confounding  effects.  The  same  3  

items  [carrots  (-­‐$0.347),  lettuce  (-­‐$0.028),  and  scallions  (-­‐$0.417)]  reported  

negative  estimated  coefficients  of  variation  suggesting  higher  prices  at  

supermarkets  on  average,  but  again  had  high  p-­‐values  making  this  variation  not  

statistically  significant.  Notably,  while  the  same  7  items  again  reported  positive  

estimated  coefficients  suggesting  a  higher  price  at  farmers’  markets  on  average,  this  

time  only  3  indicated  a  statistically  significant  increase  in  price  based  on  very  low  p-­‐

  54  

values:  bell  peppers  (+$0.172;  P  =  .010),  cucumbers  (+$0.219;  P  =  .001),  and  

potatoes  (+$0.401;  P  =  .000).  Such  a  difference  in  significant  results  from  the  first  

model  to  the  second  reinforces  the  importance  of  controlling  for  the  fixed  effects  of  

time  period  and  quality  in  order  to  isolate  the  relationship  between  price  per  pound  

and  location  type.  

 Variation  in  Price  by  Time  Period  

A chart of TIME vs. PRICE alone without accounting for location type, produce

type, or quality rating illustrates how overall mean price across both location types varies

throughout the 8 time periods. An overall decreasing trend in mean price per pound is

Time Period

1 (7/5 -7/18)

2 (7/19-8/1)

3 (8/2-8/15)

4 (8/16-8/29)

5 (8/30-9/12)

6 (9/13-9/26)

7 (9/27-10/10)

8 (10/11-10/24)

Mean Price/lb

($) 1.865 1.749 1.713 1.738 1.742 1.666 1.666 1.759

Figure  4.3.

Table  4.11.  

  55  

seen between time periods 1 and 7, where the average change in price from one period to

the next was about -2 %, and the overall mean price had decreased by 10% at the end of

week 7. Between the final time periods 7 and 8, overall mean price increased by nearly

6%.

Introduce Location Effect

Time Period 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

2.01 1.78 1.73 1.78 1.82 1.61 1.61 1.48 Mean Price/lb ($) 1.70 1.69 1.69 1.68 1.66 1.69 1.72 1.89

Supermarkets Farmers’ Markets

Figure  4.4.  

Table  4.12.  

  56  

A  chart  of  TIME  vs.  PRICE  for  each  location  type  without  accounting  for  

produce  type  or  quality  rating  (Figure  4.4)  illustrates  how  overall  mean  price  at  

each  location  type  varies  throughout  the  8  time  periods.    An  overall  decreasing  

trend  in  mean  price  per  pound  at  farmers’  markets  is  contrasted  with  a  relatively  

constant  and  ultimately  increasing  trend  at  supermarkets.    At  farmers  markets,  

there  was  a  14%  initial  drop  in  mean  price  across  time  periods  1  and  2,  followed  by  

a  slight  increase  from  period  3  to  4,  and  ending  with  another  large  decrease  of  19%  

over  the  final  four  time  periods.    Supermarkets  reported  a  very  constant  mean  price  

from  time  periods  1  through  7,  never  deviating  more  than  0.03  from  the  mode  1.69,  

but  saw  about  a  10%  increase  during  time  period  8.    Interestingly,  the  largest  

differences  in  mean  price  per  pound  occurred  during  the  very  first  and  last  time  

periods.    In  time  period  one,  mean  price  at  farmers’  markets  ($2.01)  was  about  18%  

higher  than  at  supermarkets  ($1.70);  while  in  time  period  8,  mean  price  at  

supermarkets  ($1.89)  was  a  striking  28%  higher  than  at  farmers’  markets  ($1.48).  

 Introduce  Produce  Type  

Graphs  of  TIME  vs.  PRICE  at  each  location  type  for  each  produce  item  

separately  demonstrates  how  overall  mean  price  for  each  type  of  produce  varies  by  

location  over  the  course  of  the  summer  season  (see  Appendix  I).      First,  cucumbers  

at  farmers’  markets  exhibited  a  slightly  decreased  price  trend  overall  (though  still  

significantly  more  expensive  than  at  supermarkets),  marked  by  a  notable  sudden  

decrease  in  mean  price/lb.  by  about  $0.40  during  time  period  6  (9/13-­‐9/26).    A  very  

similar  pattern  was  followed  by  farmers’  market  bell  peppers,  which  exhibited  a  

momentary  $0.60  decrease  in  mean  price/lb.  during  the  same  time  period  6  (see  

  57  

figure  4.5).    Interestingly,  zucchini  showed  an  opposite  pattern,  with  an  overall  

increasing  trend  punctuated  by  a  momentary  $0.50  increase  in  mean  price/lb.  

during  week  6.    The  mean  price/lb.  of  carrots  dropped  rapidly  by  $0.50  during  time  

period  4  (8/16  -­‐8/29),  recovered,  then  dropped  rapidly  again  by  nearly  $1.00  

between  periods  6  and  8  (9/13-­‐  10/24).    The  price/lb.  of  scallions  spiked  by  $1.50  

during  time  period  4  (8/16-­‐8-­‐29),  and  the  price/lb.  of  lettuce  spiked  by  about  $1.25  

during  time  period  5  (8/30-­‐9/12)  (see  figure  4.6).      Onions  demonstrated  a  rapid  

decline  of  about  $1.40  from  the  start  of  the  study  until  time  period  3  (7/5-­‐8/15),  

and  then  remained  relatively  stable  at  the  decreased  price/lb  (around  $1.00).    

Potatoes  acted  similarly,  showing  a  decrease  of  nearly  $1.00    (from  $2.00)  between  

time  periods  1  and  3  (7/5-­‐8/15),  and  then  staying  between  $1.00  and  $1.50  for  the  

remainder  of  the  market  season.    Interestingly,  the  mean  price/lb.  of  green  beans  

increased  at  farmers’  markets  and  decreased  at  supermarkets  during  the  same  time  

periods  (4-­‐7)  by  about  the  same  margin.  

5.  Discussion  of  Results    5.1.  Summary  

These  results  offer  some  support  to  the  widespread  consumer  perception  that  

produce  costs  more  at  farmers’  markets  than  at  supermarkets  in  the  underserved  

Boston  neighborhoods  of  Roxbury  and  Dorchester,  but  the  difference  is  not  very  

large.    I  found  that  when  time  period,  quality  rating,  and  produce  type  were  held  

constant,  the  mean  price  per  pound  of  produce  at  area  farmers’  markets  was  a  

marginally  significant  8.6  cents  greater  than  at  supermarkets,  on  average.    With  the  

dependent  variable  lnPRICE,  the  log  of  price,  the  results  suggest  a  significant  2.9%  

  58  

increase  in  price  per  pound  on  produce  at  farmers’  markets  compared  to  

supermarkets.    In  addition,  I  found  that  bell  peppers,  cucumbers,  and  potatoes  cost  

significantly  more  per  pound  at  farmers’  markets  when  the  effects  of  time  and  

quality  were  controlled  for.    A  plot  of  time  period  vs.  mean  price  per  pound  by  

location  showed  that  prices  at  farmers  markets  decreased  markedly  throughout  the  

sixteen-­‐week  season,  while  supermarket  prices  remained  nearly  constant  before  a  

noticeable  increase  during  the  final  time  period.    As  anticipated,  overall  quality  

rating  was  significantly  greater  at  farmers’  markets  than  at  supermarkets.    The  

robustness  of  the  statistical  results  on  overall  price  differences  was  also  confirmed  

using  a  natural  log  transformation  of  price.  

 5.2.  Magnitude  of  Price  Differences  

The  statistically  significant  2.9%  increase  in  mean  price  per  pound  of  

vegetables  at  farmers’  markets  (from  the  log  of  price  model)  indicates  that  farmers’  

market  produce  is  more  expensive,  on  average,  than  produce  purchased  from  

traditional  grocery  outlets.    But  what  is  the  practical  significance  of  this  variation  to  

the  consumer?    Several  researchers  have  found  that  fruit  and  vegetable  

consumption  is  lower  when  fruit  and  vegetable  prices  are  higher  (Powell  and  Bao,  

2009),  yet  do  these  results  imply  a  noteworthy  obstacle  to  produce  consumption  via  

a  farmers  market  in  certain  Boston  neighborhoods?  It  may  be  difficult  to  have  a  

concrete  sense  for  how  much  “value”  or  weight  about  3%  carries,  so  I  will  translate  

this  amount  into  an  estimated  total  cost  increase  if  a  consumer  purchased  produce  

only  at  a  farmers’  market  throughout  the  summer  season.    The  Economic  Research  

Service  of  the  USDA  recently  published  a  report  of  fruit  and  vegetable  prices  

  59  

declaring  that  an  adult  on  a  2,000-­‐calorie  diet  could  satisfy  recommendations  for  

fruit  and  vegetable  consumption  (amounts  and  variety)  in  the  2010  Dietary  

Guidelines  for  Americans  at  an  average  of  $2  to  $2.50  per  day  (Stewart  et  al.,  2008).    

By  using  the  mean  of  this  range,  $2.25,  an  increase  by  3%  would  increase  daily  cost  

of  consuming  the  recommended  fruit  and  vegetable  amount  by  about  7-­‐cents  to  

$2.32.    Over  the  course  of  the  16-­‐week/112  day  summer  market  season  used  in  this  

study,  purchasing  the  recommended  daily  amount  of  produce  would  increase  from  

$252.00  to  $259.84-­‐  nearly  $8.00.    Though  more  weighty  for  a  price-­‐sensitive  

shopper,  I  consider  an  additional  $8  over  the  course  of  nearly  four  months  to  be  a  

relatively  minimal  cost  to  the  average  shopper’s  wallet.    Of  course,  the  ERS  

estimation  does  not  provide  an  entirely  precise  basis  for  analysis  given  that  it  was  

derived  from  national  data  (Boston  has  a  history  of  food  prices  higher  than  the  

national  average),  that  most  Americans  do  not  consume  recommended  amounts,  

and  that  it  also  includes  fruits,  which  were  not  considered  in  this  study.    Even  so,  

this  sort  of  extrapolation  provides  an  approximate  number  that  may  be  helpful  in  

conveying  a  more  realistic  message  of  actual  cost  differences  to  residents  of  

Dorchester  and  Roxbury  and  to  policymakers  responsible  for  incentivizing  the  

purchasing/consumption  of  fresh  produce.  

 In  its  measurement  of  price  per  pound  of  produce,  a  few  notable  limitations  

are  encountered  by  this  study’s  methodology.    First,  data  was  recorded  based  on  

standardized  price  per  pound  of  produce  as  it  would  be  presented  to  a  customer  at  a  

retail  outlet  and  was  not  adjusted  to  represent  an  edible  equivalent  (stems,  skins,  

greens,  and  other  non-­‐edible  parts  removed).    The  USDA’s  ERS  examined  the  

  60  

importance  of  such  an  adjustment  and  found  that  retail  prices  appeared  to  be  a  poor  

indicator  of  prices  per  edible  cup  equivalent,  though  great  variation  based  on  

produce  type  existed.    Next,  this  study  did  not  differentiate  between  produce  sold  on  

a  random  weight  basis  ($1.29  per  pound  for  loose  tomatoes)  and  produce  sold  in  

prepackaged  containers  bearing  retailer’/manufacturer’s  name  or  produce  sold  on  a  

“count  basis”  ($2.00  per  2  lb.  bag  of  carrots  or  $1.50  per  head  of  lettuce).    Overall,  

the  USDA’s  ERS  suggested  that  a  distinction  in  produce  marketing  form  was  not  an  

important  factor  in  price,  but  often  prepackaged  containers  or  bags  offered  bulk  

discounts  that  are  important  to  mention.    When  collecting  data,  this  study  recorded  

prices  for  the  smallest  amount  of  the  conventional  type  of  produce  and  did  not  

include  prices  for  bulk  packages  (5  lb.  bag  of  potatoes)  because  it  was  assumed  that  

customers  on  a  limited  budget  may  not  be  able  to  take  advantage  of  volume  

discounts,  and  also  because  farmers’  markets  rarely  offer  such  discounts.    This  

decision  is  backed  by  Kunreuther  et  al.  (1973),  who  argued  that  the  poor  are  

disadvantaged  because  they  are  unable  to  participate  in  the  purchase  of  economy-­‐

sized  packaged  goods  due  to  the  limits  of  available  grocery  money  and  storage  

space.    While  this  is  a  legitimate  assumption,  many  shoppers  are  able  to  take  

advantage  of  significant  bulk  discounts  at  supermarkets  that  are  not  as  readily  

available  at  farmers’  markets;  for  example,  Shaw’s  loose  onions  were  sold  for  

$1.79/lb.  compared  with  a  2  lb.  package  of  onions  for  $0.92/lb  (about  a  50%  

discount),  and  Tropical  Foods  sold  loose  potatoes  for  $0.79/lb.  compared  with  a  5  

lb.  bag  for  $0.34/lb  (nearly  a  60%  discount).      

  61  

Lastly,  special  discount  offers  were  available  at  both  location  types  but  were  

not  factored  into  price  analysis.    Supermarkets  offered  some  sort  of  “frequent  

shopper”  discount  almost  weekly  where  shoppers  with  say,  a  “Stop  and  Shop  Card”  

could  benefit  from  special  price  cuts  like  zucchini  for  $0.50/lb.  (regular  price  =  

$1.49)  or  green  beans  for  $0.20/lb.  (regular  price  =  $1.69).    Farmers’  market  

shoppers  receiving  SNAP  assistance  frequently  benefited  from  utilizing  the  city-­‐

wide  incentive  program  “Boston’s  Bounty  Bucks”  to  save  50%  on  purchases  up  to  

$20.00.    Interestingly,  when  shoppers  took  full  advantage  of  the  Bounty  Bucks  

program  and  selected  $20.00  worth  of  produce,  they  were  able  to  save  $10.00  at  a  

farmers’  market  in  just  one  trip-­‐  the  same  amount  that  my  earlier  extrapolation  

suggested  as  the  total  additional  cost  at  farmers’  markets  over  the  course  of  the  

summer.    This  comparison  quite  clearly  implies  that,  for  low-­‐income  residents  of  

Boston  who  receive  federal  SNAP  assistance,  shopping  at  a  farmers’  market  may  in  

fact  be  an  extremely  economical  way  to  maximize  monthly  benefits  while  reaping  

the  greater  nutritional  advantages  of  fresh  produce.  

 5.3.  Availability  

One  major  drawback  of  farmers’  markets  highlighted  by  the  data  was  the  

relative  frequency  of  unavailable  items.    Only  45%  of  the  initially  assigned  data  

points  were  available  at  farmers  markets,  compared  with  88%  at  supermarkets.    

This  result  is  most  likely  influenced  by  heightened  time  and  climate  sensitivity  at  

farmers’  markets.    Vendors  are  limited  by  what  they  can  transport  to  the  market  

from  the  farm,  usually  only  assign  one  vendor/vehicle  for  small  markets  in  these  

neighborhoods,  and  in  many  cases  supply  quantities  reflective  of  low  demand.    

  62  

Consequently  for  collectors,  the  later  data  collection  took  place,  the  more  likely  it  

was  that  an  item  was  sold  out  and  therefore  excluded  from  the  final  data  set.      

Enhancing  this  obstacle  is  the  fact  that  the  markets  included  in  this  study  were  

usually  scheduled  to  open  only  one  day  a  week  (two  markets  opened  two  times  a  

week)  for  a  few  hours,  further  limiting  collectors  as  to  when  data  could  be  recorded.  

Also,  it  must  be  noted  that  data  only  reflects  the  availability  of  the  ten  chosen  

produce  items  rather  than  overall  produce  stock,  thus  in  most  cases  it  does  not  

adequately  express  the  wide  variety  and  plentiful  supply  of  other  produce  items  at  

farmers’  markets.    For  example,  most  vendors  had  some  sort  of  green  leafy  produce  

available  (spinach,  calaloo,  arugula),  but  since  these  items  are  subject  to  vast  price  

variation  at  supermarkets  and  less  certain  availability  at  farmers’  markets,  they  

were  not  included  and  their  availability  not  reflected.    On  many  occasions  when  a  

certain  item  was  not  recorded  and  thus  deemed  unavailable,  closely  similar  items  

were  in  fact  available  at  farmers’  markets  (plum  or  cherry  tomatoes,  red  potatoes,  

“salad  mix”),  but  were  not  included  because  they  did  not  fit  the  specific  criteria  for  

comparison.        Still,  the  limited  supply  and  unpredictable  availability  of  farmers’  

markets  are  not  only  obstacles  to  data  collection  and  analysis,  but  also  more  

significantly  are  a  major  hindrance  to  their  utilization  and  popularity  among  

residents  and  shoppers.  

While  this  expected  pattern  of  decreasing  availability  due  to  limited  supply  at  

farmers’  markets  is  clearly  a  disadvantage,  it  is  further  and  perhaps  unfairly  

exaggerated  by  comparing  it  to  the  endless  supply  of  produce  available  to  larger  

distributors  and  supermarkets.      Unlike  supermarkets  that  rely  on  a  continental  

  63  

network  of  greenhouses,  massive  farm  operations,  and  refrigerated  storehouses,  

farmers’  markets  are  directly  sensitive  to  the  day-­‐to-­‐day  growing  conditions  of  

specific  items  and  can  only  sell  what  is  locally  available  for  harvest.    For  a  growing  

number  of  Americans,  this  closeness  with  the  farm  and  acceptance  of  nature’s  

unpredictability  is  appreciated  and  even  favored  over  the  dependable  stock  of  

supermarkets  (Whitacre,  2009),  but  I  speculate  that  such  an  attitude  is  not  a  reality  

for  residents  in  low-­‐income  neighborhoods.  Though  contemporary  popular  and  

academic  culture  may  suggest  that  the  enormous  network  of  processed  agricultural  

commodity  crops  is  negatively  affecting  our  health  and  environment,  its  ability  to  

create  a  consistent,  reliable  supply  of  fresh  produce  is  highly  valuable  to  the  lower-­‐

income  consumer.    The  truth  is  that  low-­‐income  shoppers  in  particular  tend  to  make  

fewer  monthly  trips  to  buy  groceries  due  to  transportation,  federal  support,  and  

proximity  constraints  (Whitacre,  2009);  therefore,  a  larger  distributor  maximizes  

options  for  those  not  likely  or  capable  of  making  multiple  trips  to  buy  food.  

On  the  other  hand,  however,  the  existence  of  these  ten  farmers’  markets  in  the  

middle  of  dense  neighborhoods  puts  fresh  produce  closer  within  the  reach  of  

households  that  need  it  most.    Larsen  and  Gilliland  (2008)  showed  that  for  residents  

of  low-­‐income  urban  communities  that  purchase  food  based  on  proximity  due  to  

transportation  constraints,  the  increased  access  to  healthy  foods  provided  by  a  

farmers’  market  would  likely  improve  some  household  diets.  Regardless  of  how  

small  any  market’s  selection  is,  the  quality,  freshness,  and  nutrition  of  the  produce  

far  surpasses  that  of  the  produce  and  food  options  at  other  neighborhood  bodegas  

and  corner  stores  that  supplement  trips  to  larger,  more  distant  supermarkets.  

  64  

 5.4.  Quality  

The  incorporation  of  a  quality  rating  into  this  study  was  meant  to  assess  the  

common  hypothesis  that  farmers’  market  produce,  while  more  expensive,  is  

undoubtedly  of  better  quality.    Results  support  this  hypothesis,  showing  that  

farmers’  markets  received  a  significantly  greater  proportion  of  highest  quality  

ratings  than  did  supermarkets.    While  this  difference  in  quality  is  certainly  justified  

by  data  and  first-­‐hand  accounts,  it  is  necessary  to  note  the  limitations  inherent  in  

measuring  produce  quality.    As  quality  is  a  subjective  assessment  prone  to  all  sorts  

of  individual  preferences,  studies  involving  produce/foodstuffs  often  choose  to  

disregard  it  altogether  for  fear  of  jeopardizing  the  objective  validity  of  their  

research.    I  feel  that  quality  is  an  extremely  important  aspect  of  a  consumer’s  

decision-­‐making  process  and  it  must  not  be  dismissed  or  ignored  but  rather  handled  

with  caution.  In  designing  a  system  for  measuring  quality,  this  study  aimed  to  

minimize  subjective  influences  by  using  a  limited  range  of  values  (1-­‐3)  and  training  

all  collectors  using  reference  examples  for  each  rating.  Since  most  people  rely  on  it  

when  selecting  items  to  purchase,  visual  rating  is  a  realistic  and  useful  form  of  

quality  assessment  that  plays  a  particularly  strong  role  in  the  discussion  on  food  

access.  It  is  worthwhile  to  acknowledge  that  the  measure  of  visual  quality  rating  

used  in  this  study  is  not  necessarily  a  parallel  indicator  of  taste,  which  has  been  

shown  repeatedly  to  play  the  most  influential  role  in  fruit  and  vegetable  

consumption  decisions  (Glanz  and  Goldberg,  1998;  Reicks  et  al.,  1994;  Treiman  et  

al.,  1996).    However,  in  her  discussion  on  food-­‐purchasing  decisions,  Cummins  

(2010)  remarked  that  perceived  quality  of  produce,  (i.e.  what  a  shopper  infers  about  

  65  

taste,  freshness,  and  nutrition  based  on  visual  presentation)  is  a  very  important  

factor,  and  likely  acts  as  a  mediating  variable  in  the  decision  to  buy  fresh  produce.    

Additionally,  a  similar  survey  by  French  (2002)  concluded  that  individuals  of  lower  

socioeconomic  status  -­‐like  those  central  to  this  study-­‐  might  place  greater  

importance  on  this  perceived  quality  than  on  actual  taste,  freshness,  or  nutrition.    

These  references  assert  the  importance  of  first  impressions  of  produce  quality  in  the  

overall  perception  of  value  and  verify  the  decision  to  incorporate  perceived  quality  

rating  in  this  study.  

Knowing  that  1)  lower-­‐income  families  purchase/consume  less  fresh  produce  

than  higher-­‐income  families  and  2)  lower-­‐income  families  have  reduced  

accessibility  to  good  quality  fresh  fruits  and  vegetables,  these  results  indicate  that  

farmers’  markets  are  introducing  produce  items  of  higher  perceived  visual  quality  

into  surrounding  communities.    Traditionally,  local  corner  stores  in  Dorchester  and  

Roxbury  tend  to  stock  produce  from  Chelsea  Produce  Terminal,  often  just  to  fulfill  

new  WIC  requirements  on  minimum  produce  offerings;  thus,  whatever  produce  

they  sell  is  likely  of  low  quality  in  an  effort  to  keep  prices  as  low  as  possible  

(Whitacre,  2009).    The  likely  effect  of  this  pattern  is  recounted  by  Hendrickson  et  al.  

(2006)  found  that  residents  in  underserved  Minneapolis  communities  felt  that,  even  

if  they  had  the  money  to  spend  on  fresh  produce,  the  quality  of  produce  in  their  area  

was  so  poor  it  would  not  be  worth  it.    By  making  higher  quality  produce  more  

available,  lower-­‐income  consumers  are  more  likely  to  purchase  fruits  and  

vegetables  previously  deemed  undesirable,  enjoy  eating  them,  and  continue  to  

include  produce  in  their  diet.      

  66  

Though  important  inferences  can  be  drawn  from  this  study’s  results,  there  are  

countless  ways  in  which  the  assessment  of  quality  can  be  enhanced  in  future  

research.    Ideally,  more  intensive  training  would  be  required  to  provide  all  

collectors  with  uniform  examples  of  each  produce  item  at  each  rating  level.    

Collectors  would  also  benefit  from  the  use  of  a  visual/pictorial  reference  guide  when  

making  assessments  in  the  field.    Finally,  a  systematic  series  of  blind  taste  tests  and  

shelf-­‐life  assessments  would  account  for  the  fact  that  taste  and  perishibility  are  two  

other  very  important  qualitative  factors  in  deciding  overall  value  and  whether  or  

not  to  purchase  an  item  again.  

 Growing  and  Harvesting  Methods  

  When  discussing  quality,  it  is  also  important  to  mention  the  variations  in  

growing  methods  used  by  supermarket  producers  and  local  farmers’  market  

vendors.    First,  almost  all  supermarket  produce  included  in  this  study  was  not  

specified  as  “organic”  or  “organically  grown”,  and  based  on  information  provided  by  

produce  managers  at  all  supermarkets,  is  assumed  to  be  grown  according  to  

conventional  large-­‐scale  agricultural  methods  including  the  active  use  of  pesticides.    

The  one  major  exception  to  this  assumption  is  the  case  of  Stop  and  Shop’s  scallions,  

which  were  heavily  marketed  as  “organic”  at  all  stores  via  the  name  “Nature’s  

Promise”.    Research  uncovered  that  Stop  and  Shop  is  able  to  mass-­‐produce  organic  

scallions  in  Mexico  for  an  inexpensive  cost  and  may  use  them  as  a  “loss  leader”  by  

presenting  an  organic  product  at  an  unusually  low  price  (Danielle  Andrews,  

personal  communication,  summer  2010).  

  67  

  As  for  the  fourteen  vendors  at  the  ten  farmers’  markets  in  Dorchester  and  

Roxbury,  two  vendors  (Serving  Ourselves  and  Langwater  Farms)  were  certified  

organic  and  the  thirteen  others  all  reported  using  organic,  sustainable  farming  

practices  but  were  not  officially  certified.    In  many  cases  these  farms  were  practicing  

“Integrated  Pest  Management”  (IPM),  which  involves  very  minimal  pesticide  usage  

and  is  required  for  at  least  a  year  prior  to  becoming  certified  organic.    Urban  farms  

like  The  Food  Project,  Revision  House,  and  Village  at  Work  used  almost  entirely  

organic  methods,  but  could  never  become  certified  organic  because  they  lie  within  

50  feet  of  the  road  and  are  too  close  to  neighbors  who  may  be  using  pesticides  

(Cammy  Watts,  personal  communication,  summer  2010).  The  major  barrier  to  

organic  certification,  however,  is  the  enormous  expense  to  the  farmer.    Following  

the  initial  costs  of  transforming  the  agricultural  structure  of  a  farm  and  becoming  

certified,  additional  costs  are  constantly  required  to  renew  the  certification,  

maintain  high  standards  of  organic  practices,  and  change  marketing  strategies  

accordingly.    These  expenses  are  the  reason  that  certified  organic  produce  almost  

always  costs  more  at  any  retail  outlet  and  also  create  a  financial  barrier  to  the  

consumption  of  organic  produce  by  low-­‐income  shoppers.    While  the  nutritional  

benefits  of  organic  produce  are  still  being  debated,  there  is  some  evidence  to  

suggest  that  organic  produce  contains  higher  levels  of  nutrients  and  tastes  better  

than  produce  grown  using  pesticides;  plus,  buying  organic  undoubtedly  supports  

the  efforts  of  farmers  who  are  aiming  to  improve  the  ecological  health  of  the  land  

that  they  farm  on  (Reganold,  2001).    Therefore,  the  fact  that  customers  are  able  to  

buy  organically  grown  produce  at  farmers’  markets  in  Dorchester  and  Roxbury  

  68  

without  incurring  the  transfer  of  additional  costs  due  to  organic  certification  means  

that  shoppers  are  likely  getting  a  higher  quality  item  for  a  lower  price  than  would  be  

marketed  at  a  supermarket.      While  most  low-­‐income  consumers  would  not  usually  

pay  more  for  an  organic  item,  there  is  potential  for  them  to  appreciate  the  idea  of  

being  able  to  purchase  organically  grown  fruits  and  vegetables  to  feed  their  

households,  leading  to  an  overall  increased  motivation  to  shop  at  and  consume  

produce  from  farmers’  markets4.  

 5.5.  Seasonality  

When  proposing  her  dissertation  research  project  on  farmers’  market  produce  

in  North  Carolina,  Natalie  Valpiani,  a  Masters  candidate  at  the  Tufts  Friedman  

School  of  Nutrition  Science  and  Policy  noted  that  the  widely  held  idea  that  produce  

prices  change  according  to  season  is  a  concept  that  many  intuitively  take  for  

granted,  yet  there  is  little  data  supporting  such  conclusions  (personal  

communication,  July  2010).    In  particular,  seasonal  changes  in  price  would  likely  be  

attributed  to  certain  produce  types  in  certain  regions  and  climates.    The  inclusion  

and  controlling  of  time  effect  in  this  study  was  meant  to  better  gauge  what  impact,  if  

any,  seasonality  had  on  the  prices  of  ten  produce  items  over  the  course  of  a  New  

England  summer.  

                                                                                                               4  Note:    although  this  secondary  qualitative  factor  was  not  anticipated  to  be  a  selling  point  to  

the  price-­sensitive  shopper  featured  in  this  study,  the  behavior  during  the  summer  of  2010  suggested  otherwise:    a  report  on  the  use  of  Boston  Bounty  Bucks  found  that,  at  Copley  Square-­one  of  Boston’s  most  popular  and  expensive  markets,  SNAP  redemption  amounts  were  second  highest  at  a  certified  organic  vendor,  Atlas  Farms  (Cammy  Watts,  personal  communication,  March  29,  2011).      This  surprising  statistic  might  indicate  that  when  using  “free  money”  from  the  Bounty  Bucks  program,  even  lower-­income  shoppers  prefer  purchasing  organically  grown  produce.    

  69  

Due  to  the  temperate  climate  of  the  Northeast,  most  agricultural  crops  can  

only  be  produced  outside  greenhouses  during  the  months  between  late  spring  and  

early  fall.    As  a  result,  locally  grown  produce  is  subject  to  strong  seasonal  price  

fluctuation  during  these  months  based  on  the  highs  and  lows  of  each  produce  type’s  

unique  growing  pattern.    Generally,  such  seasonal  price  changes  at  the  farm  level  

have  diminished  impact  on  retail  prices  at  larger  distributors  like  supermarkets  due  

to  many  more  overhead  costs  such  as  advertising,  packaging,  and  transportation  

(Fisher,  M.,  2009).    In  contrast,  selling  directly  to  the  consumer  enables  farmers  to  

avoid  these  overhead  costs,  allowing  them  more  flexibility  to  adjust  prices  based  on  

surplus  or  scarcity  in  the  supply  of  any  individual  crop.    This  means  that  the  

consumer  has  the  ability  to  take  advantage  of  periodic,  often  significant  price  

reductions  at  farmers’  markets  resulting  from  an  overabundance  of  a  particular  

crop  at  the  height  of  its  growing  season.    By  recognizing  and  accounting  for  such  

potentially  significant  price  fluctuation  over  the  course  of  the  market  season,  this  

study  makes  improvements  over  previous  research  that  ignored  the  effects  of  time  

entirely  and  therefore  may  have  produced  misleading,  skewed  results  (Pirog  &  

McCann,  2009).  

The  overall  results  of  this  study  show  greater  fluctuation  and  a  general  

decreasing  price  pattern  at  farmers’  markets,  while  supermarket  prices  kept  

extremely  stable  until  a  marked  increase  during  time  period  8  (see  figure  4.4).    This  

likely  suggests  that  supermarkets  changed  their  producers  from  outdoor  growers  

during  the  summer  months  to  pricier  greenhouse  growers  once  the  weather  began  

to  turn  cold.  One  pattern  that  shows  quite  apparently  on  these  individual  time  plots  

  70  

is  that  of  the  consistency  of  price/lb.  at  supermarkets  versus  greater  volatility  in  

price  at  farmers’  markets.      

Plotting  time  period  against  mean  price/lb  by  location  type  for  each  produce  

item  separately  reveals  more  information  as  to  how  changes  in  specific  crop  

availability  may  have  influenced  overall  price  trends  (see  appendix  I).    For  example,  

cucumbers  and  bell  peppers  were  consistently  more  expensive  at  farmers’  markets,  

but  both  showed  a  notable  drop  in  price  below  that  of  supermarkets  during  time  

period  6,  possibly  indicating  a  surplus  harvest.    Likewise,  the  mean  price  per  pound  

values  of  scallions  and  lettuce  were  somewhat  even  at  both  locations  up  until  

periods  5  and  6,  respectively,  when  farmers’  markets  became  much  less  expensive  

through  the  end  of  the  season.    Importantly,  prices  for  all  produce  items  except  

scallions  were  higher  at  farmers’  markets  during  time  period  1,  and  many  continued  

Time  Period  

Time  Period   Time  Period  

Time  Period  

Figure  4.5.   Figure  4.6.  

  71  

to  be  noticeably  higher  until  period  2.    This  may  be  due  to  vendors’  starting  prices  

high  and  then  adjusting  to  consumer  response  or  because  it  was  still  early  in  the  

season  and  farmers  had  smaller  harvest.    Regardless,  initial  impressions  of  a  

farmers’  market  as  having  higher  prices  early  in  the  season  have  the  potential  to  

deter  shoppers  from  returning  in  the  future  when  prices  are  lower.  

 5.6.  Produce  Type      

With  numerous  types  of  produce  available  for  purchase  at  most  conventional  

grocery  outlets,  the  ten  specific  types  chosen  for  this  study  reflect  deliberate  

planning.  One  thing  that  a  majority  of  studies  on  fruit  and  vegetable  consumption  

consider  when  selecting  which  types  to  investigate  is  the  National  Health  and  

Nutrition  Examination  Survey  (NHANES)  data  ranking  consumption  rates  of  the  

most  popular  produce  items.    This  national  reference  was  not  considered  when  

selecting  produce  types  for  this  study,  meaning  that  our  results  do  not  necessarily  

convey  information  about  the  most  popular  vegetables  and  may  therefore  lack  

relevance  to  consumer  preferences.    This  should  not  be  considered  a  serious  

limitation  for  several  reasons.  First,  national  averages  do  not  necessarily  reflect  the  

preferences  of  ethnic  minorities  and/or  low-­‐income  consumers  such  as  those  living  

in  Dorchester  and  Roxbury.    Aware  of  farmers’  markets’  less  predictable  stock  of  

produce,  the  selection  process  did  not  intentionally  overlook  this  nationally  

referenced  data  but  instead  decided  to  choose  based  on  farmer  and  farmers’  market  

manager  interviews  regarding  which  produce  types  would  be  most  frequently  

available  in  order  to  maximize  realized  data  collection.      

  72  

One  trend  noted  throughout  the  season  at  farmers’  markets  was  the  presence  

of  vegetables  that  looked  different  or  were  of  a  slightly  differently  variation  than  the  

conventional  type  of  produce  consumers  have  come  to  expect  in  supermarkets.  

Some  items  may  look  slightly  different  or  vary  more  in  size/shape/appearance  than  

what  you  would  expect  to  find  at  a  supermarket  because  the  produce  at  farmers’  

market  is  not  grown  according  to  mass-­‐agricultural  specifications  for  conformity.    

Similarly,  produce  at  a  farmers’  market  often  comes  with  a  bit  more  dirt  residue  

than  you’d  expect  to  find  at  a  supermarket  because  massive  cleaning  machines  

aren’t  feasible  for  farmers  and  vendors  place  lesser  emphasis  on  the  presentation  of  

a  clean,  glistening  product  than  do  supermarkets.    These  less-­‐perfect  characteristics  

may  be  appreciated  as  reminders  or  evidence  of  the  straight-­‐from-­‐the-­‐ground  

freshness  and  local  origin  of  farmers’  market  produce,  but  they  could  also  deter  

consumers  who  aren’t  used  to  such  variation  in  appearance  and  are  hesitant  to  try  

something  new,  or  who  interpret  more  dirt  as  more  time  and  effort  needed  to  clean  

and  prepare  produce.      

Although  relatively  limited  compared  to  the  selection  of  more  traditional  

fruits  and  vegetables  at  a  supermarket,  farmers’  markets  frequently  seemed  to  serve  

an  important  function  in  enabling  ethnic  and  cultural  cooking  traditions  that  play  an  

important  role  in  food  choice  and  meal  preparation  (Fisher,  A.,  1999).    It  was  

apparent  that  shoppers  of  different  ethnic  backgrounds  appreciated  and  purchased  

certain  non-­‐mainstream  produce  types  with  excitement  while  expressing  their  

frustration  over  the  absences  of  these  culturally  important  items  in  conventional  

markets  or  corner  stores  (calaloo,  green  tomatoes,  collards).      The  ability  for  

  73  

farmers’  market  vendors  to  tap  into  ethnic  appetites  not  satisfied  by  supermarkets  

is  an  important  aspect  of  their  ability  to  encourage  produce  consumption.  

Overall,  it  is  likely  that  farmer’s  markets  tend  to  offer  a  significantly  better  variety  

and  quality  of  produce  items  than  what  is  currently  available  at  nearby  corner  

stores  in  Dorchester  and  Roxbury.    Improved  selection  could  enhance  the  

purchasing  experience  and  therefore  increase  the  likelihood  of  produce  

consumption.  

 5.7.  Contributions  of  Methodology    

This  study  has  proved  successful  in  accomplishing  one  of  its  major  

objectives-­‐  to  pilot  a  methodology  that  could  be  used  by  other  organizations  and  

policy  surveyors  to  assess  the  affordability  of  farmers’  markets  within  specific  

neighborhoods  rather  than  larger,  diverse  metropolitan  areas.    Since  it  is  yet  to  be  

determined  if  national  findings  on  socioeconomic  and  geographic  factors  relating  to  

food  access  can  be  broadly  applied  to  smaller  areas  with  similar  demographics  

(Whitacre,  2009),  applying  this  methodology  to  a  geographically,  demographically,  

and  socioeconomically  well-­‐defined  area  will  also  add  to  the  proposed  “Healthy  

Incentives  Program”  (HIP,  Farm  Bill  2008)  research  into  national  farmers’  market  

programs  by  bringing  attention  to  the  importance  of  investigating  food  access  issues  

at  a  more  specific  community-­‐level.      Both  farmers’  markets  and  supermarkets  are  

influenced  by  the  respective  needs  of  their  surrounding  populations.    While  

supermarkets  have  been  found  to  be  more  expensive  in  the  inner  city  than  in  

suburban  areas  (Ashman,  1999),  farmers’  markets  are  particularly  sensitive  to  the  

environment  in  which  they  are  located  and  exhibit  tremendous  diversity  in  

  74  

structure,  size,  composition,  product,  popularity,  and  purpose  (Fisher,  A.,  1999).    By  

emphasizing  unique  characteristics  of  the  health  and  diet-­‐related  environment  in  

the  most  local  context,  this  study  is  able  to  examine  distinct  influences  on  

purchasing  and  consumption  patterns  that  pertain  directly  to  certain  

neighborhoods.  

Another  significant  contribution  made  by  this  study  is  its  avoidance  of  

defining  a  healthy  food-­‐deficient  area  based  on  the  uncertain  definition  of  a  “food  

desert”  or  by  distance  to  a  supermarket.  Nearly  all  of  the  literature  on  racial,  

socioeconomic  and  geographic  disparities  in  food  access  or  food  consumption  

trends  mentions  access  to  supermarkets  as  an  important  factor  when  diagnosing  

obstacles  to  healthy  food  access  (Walker,  2010),  yet  Dorchester  and  Roxbury,  like  

many  other  urban  areas,  are  not  “food  deserts”  and  most  neighborhoods  fall  within  

reasonable  distance  of  at  least  one  of  the  seven  supermarkets  in  this  study.    These  

types  of  neighborhoods  still  have  needs  in  terms  of  access  to  and  education  about  

healthy  food  and  have  complex  socioeconomic  and  perceptual  issues  related  to  food  

consumption  that  go  beyond  the  proximity  of  supermarkets.    Realizing  that  a  

household’s  proximity  to  a  supermarket  is  not  something  that  can  easily  be  changed,  

especially  in  dense  inner  city  areas,  this  study  explores  the  current  status  of  

farmers’  markets  as  alternatives  to  supermarkets  in  economically  disadvantaged  

neighborhoods.  

  75  

Section  3  

Current  and  Future  Implications:  The  Viability  of  Farmers’  Markets  

in  Underserved  Boston  Communities  

 

  While  clarification  of  relative  produce  price  and  quality  at  farmers’  markets  

and  supermarkets  provides  an  opportunity  to  encourage  the  purchase  of  local  fruits  

and  vegetables  in  low-­‐income  neighborhoods,  there  are  many  other  opportunities  to  

consider  when  thinking  about  the  long-­‐term  potential  for  farmers’  markets  to  

positively  affect  diet-­‐related  health  in  underserved  communities.    Crucial  to  

understanding  the  overall  value  of  farmers’  markets  is  a  review  of  the  individual  and  

community  gains  they  make  available.    Equally  important  is  a  detailed  account  of  the  

unique  challenges  confronted  by  small  farmers’  markets  in  low-­‐income  areas.    

Drawing  from  first-­‐hand  experience  and  several  months  of  involvement,  I  comment  

on  the  benefits  and  barriers  facing  small  farmers’  markets  in  communities  like  

Dorchester  and  Roxbury  before  proposing  a  few  goals  aimed  at  enhancing  their  

viability  into  the  future.  

 

1.  Benefits  of  Farmers’  Markets  

The  potential  benefits  to  be  had  from  the  presence  of  farmers’  markets  in  

underserved,  low-­‐income  neighborhoods  of  Boston  are  numerous.    First,  farmers’  

markets  make  healthy,  fresh  food  more  available  to  communities  in  terms  of  

proximity  and  convenience.  Due  to  limited  transportation  and  free  time  due  to  busy  

work  schedules,  low-­‐income  households  are  less  likely  to  travel  the  distance  to  a  

  76  

supermarket  outside  of  their  neighborhood’s  small  corner  stores,  therefore  

sacrificing  cost  and  quality  for  convenience  (Walker,  2010).  But  because  the  

farmers’  markets  in  this  study  are  so  small  and  feature  only  1-­‐3  vendors,  they  can  be  

located  at  closer  intervals  than  larger  scale  markets  and  are  very  flexible  with  

regard  to  finding  a  host  location.    This  means  that,  for  the  transportation  

constrained  low-­‐income  consumer  who  values  proximity,  outlets  selling  fresh,  

higher  quality  fruits  and  vegetables  are  more  conveniently  available  and  more  likely  

to  be  considered  an  option  when  deciding  where  to  purchase  food.  

    Next,  because  credits  can  only  be  redeemed  at  participating  farmers’  markets  

(though  most  Boston  markets  now  participate),  the  introduction  of  FMNP/SFMNP  

and  Boston  Bounty  Bucks  make  new  money  saving  opportunities  available  to  SNAP  

users  while  enticing  them  to  buy  more  fruits  and  vegetables.    Since  recipients  of  

FMNP/SFMNP  must  use  their  “free  money”  at  farmers’  markets,  the  programs  

essentially  force  them  to  enter  a  produce-­‐purchasing  environment  that  many  would  

not  have  chosen  otherwise.    Through  this  incentive  program  users  are  exposed  to  

different  stimuli  and  expectations  that  could  potentially  change  their  previous  

associations  to  buying  produce  for  the  better.    This  potential  to  attract  new  

consumers  is  demonstrated  by  McCormack  et  al.  (2010),  whose  survey  of  SFMNP  

recipients  at  farmers’  markets  found  that  68%  of  respondents  had  never  shopped  at  

a  farmers’  market  before.    More  importantly,  a  majority  of  shoppers  in  the  survey  

found  the  produce  quality  to  be  much  better  or  better  than  at  supermarkets,  and  

38%  of  those  who  used  SFMNP  coupons  continued  to  shop  at  a  farmers’  market  in  

  77  

the  future,  indicating  that  many  new  shoppers  were  impressed  and  compelled  to  

return  to  this  new  environment.    

Not  only  do  farmers’  markets  offer  a  convenient  way  to  obtain  healthy  food  

and  an  outlet  for  the  redemption  of  subsidy  and  coupon  credits,  but  they  also  do  

these  things  in  a  unique  environment  that  could  change  the  experience  of  buying  

produce  for  people  in  these  communities.    This  study  supports  several  others  that  

found  that  farmers’  markets  offer  produce  of  a  higher  quality  than  what  is  

conventionally  available  in  area  supermarkets  and  corner  stores,  and  access  to  

improved  quality  suggests  increased  rates  of  consumption  because  overall  value  in  

terms  of  cost  and  benefit  to  the  consumer  is  greater  (Cox  et  al.,  1997).    

Improvements  in  quality  can  be  attributed  to  factors  such  as  freshness,  organic  

growing  methods,  and  nutritional  value.    Freshness:  at  the  time  of  purchase,  it  has  

usually  only  been  24-­‐48  hours  since  the  locally  grown  produce  has  been  harvested  

from  the  earth,  making  it  much  fresher  than  what  is  sold  at  most  conventional  

markets  (Farmer  Dave  Dumaresq  of  Brox  Farm,  personal  communication,  June  

2010).    Grown  using  organic  practices:  all  of  the  produce  sold  at  these  farmers’  

markets  was  grown  using  organic  methods  or  IPM  (Integrated  Pest  Management),  

meaning  it  has  been  exposed  to  no  or  minimal  pesticides.    Nutritional  value:    all  

produce  was  harvested  on  farms  located  within  two  hours  driving  time  of  Boston,  

which  means  it  was  not  subjected  long  distance  travel  that  has  been  shown  by  some  

research  to  substantially  deplete  nutrients  (Schoonover,  2007).      

Outside  of  produce  quality,  farmers’  markets  also  offer  positive  experiential  

qualities  like  social  atmosphere,  buying  directly  from  a  farmer,  and  supporting  local  

  78  

produce.    As  a  public  and  social  space,  farmers’  markets  facilitate  mingling  and  

sharing  of  produce  preparation  tips  by  diverse  community  dwellers  of  all  ages  and  

serve  as  a  vehicle  for  community  discussion  and  development;  one  sociologist  even  

calculated  that  people  have  ten  times  as  many  conversations  at  a  farmers’  market  

than  at  a  supermarket  (Halweil,  2002)!  Through  the  direct  sale  of  produce  from  the  

farmer  to  the  shopper,  farmers’  markets  also  seek  to  connect  local  producers  with  

local  consumers  in  a  mutually  beneficial  educational  linkage  that  encourages  

continued  patronage  (Pollan,  2010).    Finally,  shoppers  who  patronize  farmers’  

markets  not  only  ensure  themselves  of  a  more  healthy  food  supply  for  their  families,  

but  also  go  a  long  way  toward  supporting  the  survival  of  small  scale  sustainable  

agriculture  and  the  economy  of  local  farmers  and  producers.  

 2.  Barriers  to  Farmers  Markets  

Though  the  potential  for  benefits  is  large,  including  providing  healthy  food  

access  in  these  underserved  communities,  farmers’  markets  in  low-­‐income  urban  

neighborhoods  are  experiencing  substantial  economic,  administrative,  and  social  

barriers  to  their  success  (Briggs  et  al.,  2010).    While  aggressive  efforts  to  open  

farmers’  markets  in  underserved  urban  communities  have  been  applauded  and  

replicated  throughout  the  country,  many  of  these  programs  are  nearing  collapse  due  

to  exhausted  funds  and  low  rates  of  farmer  retention.    Initially  opened  as  pilot  

programs,  these  small  markets  are  more  often  than  not  run  by  non-­‐profit  

organizations  and  community  health  centers  that  rely  entirely  on  government  

funding  to  absorb  operating  costs,  in  turn  making  them  extremely  vulnerable  to  any  

change  in  funds  or  donations.  On  top  of  the  many  daily  and  weekly  administrative  

  79  

duties  of  publicity,  legal  paperwork,  and  logistical  coordination,  most  farmers’  

market  managers  are  strained  by  the  process  of  having  to  ceaselessly  and  single-­‐

handedly  apply  for  grants  from  federal/state  programs,  private  donors,  public  

foundations,  etc.  in  order  to  keep  the  market  afloat.      And  though  positive  and  

important  steps  forward,  the  addition  of  incentive  programs  like  SFMNP  and  Boston  

Bounty  Bucks  requires  additional  administrative  work  such  as  applications,  

training,  troubleshooting,  and  assistance  that  further  burdens  the  farmers’  market  

manager  who  already  faces  exceptional  challenges.      

   2.1.  Disproportional  Operational  Fees  

The  process  and  costs  of  registration,  renewal,  and  retail  permits  present  a  

major  barrier  to  small  markets  in  low-­‐income  areas.    There  are  certain  fees  

demanded  of  every  market,  regardless  of  size,  to  be  paid  to  the  City  of  Boston  

and/or  the  Inspectional  Services  Department  (ISD),  and  for  non-­‐profit  markets  that  

pay  to  operate  without  earning  profit,  even  minimal  fees  are  a  financial  stressor.    

For  example,  in  Boston,  there  is  a  fee  of  $50  for  the  “Use  of  Premises”  permit  to  

operate  a  farmers’  market  even  on  private  property.    The  process  of  obtaining  this  

permit  involves  compiling  paperwork  locating  a  certified  plot  plan  for  the  property  

(no  easy  task  in  some  cases),  and  making  several  visits  to  the  ISD  office,  which  

multiple  farmers’  market  managers  have  found  daunting  (Cathy  Wirth,  personal  

communication,  summer  2010).    Next,  farmer’s  market  managers  usually  charge  a  

“market  fee”  to  each  farmer  who  wants  to  sell  at  their  market  in  order  to  raise  funds  

for  basic  operating  costs.    For  the  markets  in  Dorchester  and  Roxbury,  charging  

farmers  to  come  to  a  market  is  not  realistic  when  farmers  are  already  dropping  

  80  

prices  and  dealing  with  low  sales  volume.    Also,  ISD  requires  that  vendors  selling  

bread,  granolas,  or  foods  other  than  fruits  and  vegetables  pay  a  $100  fee  for  each  

market  they  sell  at.    Some  market  managers  see  breads  and  non-­‐produce  items  as  

ways  to  draw  people  to  farmers’  markets,  but  this  cost  is  prohibitive  for  vendors  

coming  to  markets  in  low-­‐income  areas  and  discourages  farmers  from  selling  

popular  non-­‐produce  items  that  could  really  boost  attendance  (Cammy  Watts,  

personally  communication,  summer  2010).    

 2.2.  Restrictions  on  Educational  Activities  

A  farmers’  market  serves  as  an  ideal  vehicle  for  education  about  the  health  

effects  of  produce  and  can  provide  resources  to  help  shoppers  use  produce  in  new,  

simple  ways.        Demonstrations  and  free  samples  are  some  of  the  most  popular  

educational  activities  at  farmers’  markets  and  both  add  to  the  atmosphere  of  the  

market  and  attract  shoppers.    Unfortunately,  Boston  has  some  of  the  most  

restrictive  regulations  around  sampling  at  farmers’  markets  of  any  city  in  the  state.    

Market  managers  and  farmers’  market  advocacy  groups  have  been  struggling  with  

these  restrictions  for  years,  and  have  brought  their  concerns  to  organizations  

including  the  Mayor’s  Food  Council  and  the  MA  Department  of  Agriculture.  (Cathy  

Wirth,  March  28,  2011).    Efforts  to  work  within  the  limits  of  the  existing  regulations  

have  been  challenging.  Last  summer  a  group  of  nutritionists  at  UMASS  Extension  

wanted  to  conduct  small  food  preparation  demonstrations  with  samples  at  each  

market  to  show  shoppers  simple  methods  for  using  available  produce.    Tremendous  

effort  and  compromise  was  required  to  come  to  an  agreement  with  ISD  regarding  

the  health  precautions  that  would  be  required,  and  it  was  decided  that  the  group  

  81  

must  prepare  the  samples  in  a  certified  off-­‐site  kitchen  and  then  offer  them  in  

sealed,  refrigerated  containers  (UMASS  representative,  personal  communication,  

July  2010).    During  the  first  few  weeks  of  the  market  season  the  samples,  along  with  

piles  of  colorful  recipe  pamphlets,  were  well  received  by  shoppers  as  an  added  

bonus  of  the  farmers’  market  experience;  but  then,  an  issue  with  proper  

refrigeration  caused  ISD  to  prohibit  the  distribution  of  samples  for  the  remainder  of  

the  season.  Even  UMASS,  with  its  team  of  nutritionists  and  certified  food  

preparation  spaces,  could  not  do  sampling  at  markets  under  current  regulations  in  

Boston.    These  regulations  need  to  be  modified  to  better  match  the  resources  

available  to  small  markets,  while  still  maintaining  important  food  safety  standards  

for  the  public.    Safe  sampling  at  markets  of  various  sizes  has  been  possible  in  other  

parts  of  the  state,  and  should  be  possible  in  Boston  as  well.  

 2.3.  Low  Farmer  Retention  

One  of  the  most  pressing  dilemmas  for  these  farmers’  markets  and  for  the  

city  is  how  to  continue  to  promote  them  as  affordable  for  the  low-­‐income  shopper  

while  also  supporting  the  farmers  that  serve  low-­‐income  neighborhoods  by  

lowering  prices  and  sales  volumes  (relative  to  markets  in  more  affluent  areas).    

While  many  of  the  vendors  included  in  this  study  were  local  non-­‐profit  

organizations,  the  for-­‐profit  farmers  that  sell  in  Dorchester  and  Roxbury  are  mainly  

coming  to  these  neighborhoods  because  they  have  a  personal  commitment  to  

getting  fresh  food  to  underserved  communities  and  they  see  the  potential  for  

attracting  a  new  customer  base.    But  often  the  financial  burden  of  dropping  prices  

and  unpredictable  sales  volume  is  too  much  and  farmers  have  to  cancel-­‐  as  was  the  

  82  

case  when  both  vendors  at  the  Grove  Hall  market  dropped  out  causing  the  market  to  

be  terminated.    This  tendency  is  understandable  given  the  nature  of  the  family  farm  

business.    According  to  the  National  Farmers’  Market  Survey,  small  farms  rely  on  

off-­‐farm  sources  of  income  like  farmers’  markets  for  85-­‐95%  of  what  they  bring  in,  

and  more  than  25%  of  vendors  derive  their  sole  source  of  income  from  farmers’  

markets  (Rogers,  2010).    Plus,  New  England  farmers’  rely  on  the  compact  summer  

months  for  the  majority  of  their  profit,  making  every  hour  of  sales  count.    

Furthermore,  knowing  that  all  of  the  farmers  use  organic  growing  methods,  they  

must  endure  the  pressure  of  higher  production  costs  on  top  of  the  standard  

instabilities  of  bad  weather,  pests,  and  diseases.    Low  farmer  retention  not  only  puts  

stress  on  the  market  manager  to  find  replacements,  but  more  seriously  impedes  the  

powerful  ability  of  a  farmers’  market  to  enable  a  lasting  connection  between  the  

farmer  and  residents  and  create  mutual  sense  of  loyalty  with  the  neighborhood.    A  

point  worth  noting,  perhaps  the  most  highly  attended  farmers’  market  in  this  study  

was  Field’s  Corner,  where  farmers  and  vendor  Kotchi  Berberian  has  been  selling  

produce  to  the  same  community  for  some  35  years!  

 2.4.  Low  Produce  Consumption  

Historically,  income  level  has  been  shown  to  impact  fruit  and  vegetable  

consumption,  implying  that  for  many  people,  food  choices  are  more  an  issue  of  

economics  than  of  nutrition.    That  lower-­‐income  families  rely  on  an  intake  of  junk  

and  fast  food  and  disregard  produce,  according  to  nutrition  access  warrior  Adam  

Drewnowksi  and  many  others,  is  a  product  of  the  fact  that  sugary,  fat,  processed  

foods  are  cheaper,  more  easily  prepared,  and  taste  good  (Miller,  2010).  Further,  

  83  

households  who  rely  on  federal  nutrition  assistance  programs  may  purchase  less  

produce  at  the  end  of  the  month  due  to  cash  flow  limitations  when  their  money  runs  

out,  and  households  that  make  fewer  monthly  shopping  trips  have  lower  and  less  

consistent  consumption  rates  for  fruits  and  vegetables  (Fisher,  A.,  1999).  Specifically  

in  Massachusetts,  only  28.7%  of  adults  eat  the  recommended  daily  amount  of  

vegetables  (CDC,  2009)-­‐  a  number  that  is  likely  lower  in  Dorchester  and  Roxbury  

because,  in  addition  to  the  factors  above,  lower-­‐income  adults  have  also  been  found  

to  eat  less  than  the  average  consumption  rate  of  vegetables  (Dong  and  Lin,  2009).    

The  literature  suggests  that  in  addition  to  cost  and  transportation,  other  external  

barriers  to  produce  consumption  in  low-­‐income  populations  include  perishability,  

seasonality,  time,  knowledge  of  health  benefits,  and  preparation  skills.    Though  this  

study  has  shown  that  farmers’  markets  in  Dorchester  in  Roxbury  can  erode  many  of  

these  barriers,  increasing  availability  and  quality  of  produce  does  necessarily  

guarantee  increased  consumption,  especially  when  challenged  by  internal  

perceptions  of  prices  at  farmers’  markets.    Farmer’s  markets  depend  solely  on  the  

patronage  of  consumers  for  their  success,  so  the  widely-­‐held  belief  that  farmers’  

markets  are  more  expensive  than  conventional  retail  outlets  presents  a  major  

obstacle  not  only  to  the  host  organizations  and  markets,  but  also  to  low-­‐income  

consumers  who  ignore  these  new  opportunities  to  purchase  produce  because  of  

their  misinformed  perceptions.  

 3.  Policy  Implications  

The  main  objective  of  this  study  is  to  clarify  popular  misperceptions  of  

farmers’  market  prices  in  order  to  better  educate  communities  about  the  availability  

  84  

of  healthy  food  in  their  neighborhoods.    Finding  that  healthy  produce  costs  only  a  

minimal  3%  more  at  farmers’  markets  than  at  supermarkets,  efforts  must  be  

directed  at  making  this  information  available  to  the  consumer  so  that  farmers’  

markets  are  perceived  to  be  an  affordable  option  for  low-­‐income  consumers.  Price  

reductions  have  proven  to  be  an  effective  strategy  to  increase  the  purchase  of  more  

healthful  foods  (French,  S.,  2002;  Dong  and  Lin,  2009),  and  even  by  Powell  and  Bao  

(2009)  to  predict  a  reduction  in  the  prevalence  of  childhood  obesity.  Though  this  

report  does  not  necessarily  recommend  a  lowering  of  actual  prices,  it  anticipates  

that  lowering  perceived  price  would  have  a  similar  effect  on  purchasing  behavior.    

Beyond  correcting  peoples’  perceptions  of  prices  at  farmers’  markets,  the  focus  

should  become  the  overall  value  of  farmers’  market  produce  and  the  farmers’  

market  in  general  as  a  community-­‐serving  method  of  increasing  access  to  fresh  

fruits  and  vegetables.      

 3.1.  A  More  Practical  Alternative  to  Supermarkets  

Though  a  great  number  of  studies  focused  on  policy  have  aimed  to  emphasize  

the  importance  of  introducing  more  supermarkets  with  fresh  produce  into  low-­‐

income  areas  deficient  in  healthy  food  access,  this  study  supports  the  claim  that  

farmers’  markets  are  a  practical  and  viable  alternative  to  the  opening  of  

supermarkets  in  underserved  Boston  communities.    The  costs  and  challenges  of  

introducing  a  supermarket  into  a  dense  city  neighborhood  are  few  but  immense:  

security  costs  are  much  increased,  traffic  issues  must  be  addressed,  and  above  all  it  

is  extremely  difficult  to  acquire  a  big  enough  piece  of  land  to  accommodate  such  a  

large  building  because  urban  property  is  fragmented  into  many  small,  more  sellable  

  85  

pieces  of  land  (Walker,  2010).  Because  Boston  has  successfully  worked  to  address  

an  earlier  lack  of  supermarkets  and  overcome  these  obstacles  through  partnerships  

with  retailers  and  substantial  financial  incentives,  even  the  most  underserved  

neighborhoods  in  Boston  are  still  within  a  mile  of  a  supermarket;  therefore,  the  lack  

of  produce  in  low-­‐income  households  must  be  addressed  through  alternative  

means.    The  main  point  here  is  that  people  tend  to  make  food  choices  based  on  food  

outlets  available  in  their  immediate  neighborhoods  (Furey  et  al.,  2001).      Knowing  

that  this  tendency  becomes  more  problematic  in  poor  urban  neighborhoods  like  

Dorchester  and  Roxbury  where  there  is  often  higher  density  of  fast  food  restaurants  

and  corner  stores  filled  with  cheap,  prepared,  unhealthy  meal  options  (Walker,  

2010),  it  is  easy  to  see  how  many  small  farmers’  markets  in  each  neighborhood  

corner  or  community  have  the  potential  to  become  similarly  convenient,  yet  healthy  

options.    These  small  farmers’  markets  are  mobile,  so  they  can  relocate  to  reach  

more  residents  if  a  particular  corner  or  lot  doesn’t  work  out,  and  they  do  not  impose  

any  nuisance  (such  as  construction  or  car  traffic)  to  surrounding  residents.    In  terms  

of  costs  to  the  City,  rather  than  millions  of  dollars  in  tax  incentives,  what  these  

farmers’  markets  need  is  the  continued  support  of  the  City  through  the  proper  

allocation  of  several  smaller  grants  to  address  infrastructural  and  public  awareness  

issues  that  increase  their  viability  into  the  future.    Because  they  are  relatively  

inexpensive  to  sustain  and  can  result  in  better  long  term  health  for  Boston  

communities,  my  research  proposes  that  farmers’  markets  are  a  very  high-­‐return  

investment  that  must  continue  to  receive  support  to  maintain  their  momentum  and  

maximize  this  return.  

  86  

3.2.    Recommendations  for  Action  

Recognizing  that  financial  constraints  are  a  legitimate  concern  when  

recommending  a  plan  of  action,  I  believe  there  are  four  practical  ways  Boston  can  

tackle  the  barriers  facing  farmers’  markets  and  create  a  more  sustainable  system  for  

their  continued  success  into  the  future.  

 1) Lower  registration  and  permit  costs  for  markets  in  certain  neighborhoods:5  

• Reduce  or  eliminate  cost  of  “Permission  to  Use  Premises”  permit  for  

markets  with  four  or  fewer  vendors,  possibly  restrict  to  markets  

located  in  low-­‐income  neighborhoods.  

• Reduce  or  eliminate  cost  of  “Market  Retail  Permit”  for  vendors  selling  

locally  produced  farm  products  and  value-­‐added  products  other  than  

vegetables  at  markets  with  four  or  fewer  vendors,  possibly  restrict  to  

markets  located  in  low-­‐income  neighborhoods.  

 

2) Offer  greater  support  for  farmers  selling  in  low-­‐income  neighborhoods:  

• Reinforce  connections  between  farmers  and  consumers  through  

school  or  community  group  field  trips  to  the  farm  in  order  to  generate  

a  first-­‐hand  connection  between  the  farm  environment  and  produce  

they  can  purchase.  This  would  increase  the  likelihood  of  community  

members  to  return  to  the  market  having  met  the  grower  of  their  food  

and  visited  the  land  on  which  it  was  grown.  

                                                                                                               5  See  Baran  (2010)  for  example  of  how  this  was  done  at  “Mini-­‐Markets”  in  Minneapolis  

  87  

• Provide  farmers  with  financial  or  publicity  incentives  to  selling  in  low-­‐

income  neighborhoods.  

• Pilot  programs  with  farmers  to  grow  high-­‐demand  ethnic  crops  to  

attract  customers  to  the  markets.  

• Encourage  market  managers  to  hire  an  interpreter  from  the  

community  to  work  at  the  market  each  week  to  break  down  language  

barriers  and  encourage  questions.  

 

3) Increase  flexibility  of  health  regulations  restricting  food  demos  at  farmers’  

markets  

• Consider  a  mobile  “food  demo”  truck  outfitted  with  all  of  the  properly  

regulated  kitchen  equipment  necessary  to  give  basic  lessons  and  

samples.  

• Consider  demos  that  don’t  feature  edible  samples,  such  as  washing,  

peeling,  slicing,  and  storing  lessons  or  examples.  

• Follow  example  of  many  other  communities  that  permit  tastings  and  

cooking  demos  at  farmers’  markets  that  do.  

 

4) Educate  consumers  about  the  affordability  of  neighborhood  farmers’  markets  

• Focus  on  the  seasonal  height  of  specific  produce  types  and  use  time-­‐

sensitive  publicity  to  encourage  purchasing  when  price  is  lowest.    For  

example,  highlight  bell  peppers  and  cucumbers  as  “Top  Pickings”  or  

“Highest  Seeds”  during  the  last  two  weeks  of  September  (time  period  

  88  

6),  and  do  the  same  for  scallions  and  lettuce  during  the  first  two  

weeks  in  October  (time  period  7).    By  emphasizing  the  great  value  of  

just  one  item  to  get  people  there,  markets  can  lead  shoppers  to  

purchase  other  items  and  absorb  a  new  environment  as  well.  

• Create  a  citywide  graphic  that  shows  a  visual  of  how  much  produce  

$20  could  get  a  SNAP  user  at  farmers’  markets  and  how  that  produce  

translates  into  a  few  days  worth  of  vegetable  servings.  

• Create  a  side-­‐by-­‐side  visual  comparison  of  the  amount  of  produce  a  

shopper  could  buy  using  $10  worth  of  SNAP  at  a  supermarket,  then  

show  that  same  amount  doubled  for  farmers’  markets  to  demonstrate  

the  double  voucher  benefits  available  through  Boston  Bounty  Bucks.  

 

  89  

Conclusion

 

Over  the  last  five  years  there  has  been  a  significant  movement  to  increase  

accessibility  of  healthy  foods  in  the  predominantly  low-­‐income,  urban  Boston  

neighborhoods  of  Dorchester  and  Roxbury.  Resulting  from  the  combined  efforts  of  

policy  reform,  community  leadership,  and  non-­‐profit  organizations,  one  of  the  

movement’s  most  visible  indicators  of  progress  is  the  emergence  of  ten  farmers’  

markets  within  this  eight  square  mile  area  (Massfarmersmarkets.org).    While  a  

major  a  step  in  the  right  direction,  these  efforts  have  been  challenged  by  a  number  

of  operational  factors  in  addition  to  a  widespread  local  perception  that  farmers’  

market  produce  is  much  more  expensive  than  produce  sold  at  conventional  

supermarkets.  This  report  aimed  to  clarify  such  perceptions,  uncover  persistent  

barriers  facing  farmers’  markets  in  underserved  Boston  neighborhoods,  and  suggest  

action-­‐oriented  goals  to  keep  the  City’s  efforts  viable  in  the  future.      

In  the  end,  this  study  provides  much-­‐needed  evidence  for  a  campaign  to  

educate  consumers  about  the  economic  value  of  farmers’  markets.    Finding  that  

farmers’  market  produce  costs  only  a  marginal  3%  more  and  is  of  significantly  

higher  quality  than  supermarket  produce,  it  offers  support  for  the  previously  

dismissed  message  that  farmers’  markets  offer  tremendous  value  to  the  low-­‐income  

Boston  shopper.    This  cost-­‐savings  value  of  this  opportunity  is  further  increased  for  

SNAP  recipients,  who  can  get  nearly  double  the  fruits  and  vegetables  they  would  get  

at  a  supermarket  for  half  the  price  at  a  farmers’  market  through  Boston  Bounty  

Bucks.    In  addition  to  launching  a  campaign  featuring  the  message  of  affordability  at  

  90  

farmers’  markets,  the  City’s  underserved  neighborhoods  could  benefit  from  a  more  

consistent  operational  model  for  smaller  farmers’  markets.    Relaxing  or  negotiating  

the  health  regulations  imposed  on  fruit  and  vegetable  demonstration  programs  

would  maximize  the  educational  potential  of  a  farmers’  market,  while  lessening  the  

burden  of  basic  registration  fees  and  permits  would  allow  market  managers  and  

funds  to  be  focused  on  more  pressing  administrative  duties.  By  strengthening  the  

support  and  feedback  systems  between  vendors  and  the  immediate  neighborhoods  

in  which  they  sell,  Boston’s  underserved  communities  will  begin  to  build  lasting,  

sustainable  connections  that  keep  loyal  residents  and  farmers  returning  to  the  

markets.  

Farmers’  markets,  while  simple  in  concept,  have  much  more  to  offer  than  the  

exchange  of  fruits  and  vegetables  for  money.    They  offer  a  living,  breathing  social  

space  that  encourages  community  building  around  a  healthy  lifestyle  choice.    Boston  

has  done  an  outstanding  job  in  its  efforts  to  stay  at  the  forefront  of  the  healthy  food  

access  wave  through  incentives  like  Boston’s  Bounty  Bucks  and  the  Boston  

Collaborative  for  Food  and  Fitness,  but  it’s  time  to  fill  out  the  foundation  and  make  

farmers’  markets  really  do  something  for  these  neighborhoods.  The  good  thing  

about  farmers’  markets  is  that  they’re  small,  mobile,  and  at  most  require  a  “little  

dig”  into  the  city’s  pockets  for  some  basic  streamlining  and  infrastructural  support.      

The  City  and  the  Nation  have  applauded  The  Boston  Food  Council’s  efforts  to  put  

fresh,  nutritious  food  on  every  household  table  and  the  next  few  years  are  crucial  to  

the  lasting  success  of  their  work.    The  praiseworthy  accomplishment  of  getting  local  

farmers  with  fresh  produce  into  underserved  neighborhoods  is  one  thing,  but  

  91  

making  sure  their  carrots  and  green  beans  make  it  onto  dinner  tables-­‐  and  stay  

there-­‐  is  where  Boston  is  next  poised  to  take  charge.  

   

  92  

  93  

Works  Cited    

   Ashman,  Linda,  et  al.  (1993)  Seeds  of  Change:  Strategies  for  Food  Security  for  the  

Inner  City.    UCLA.    Baran,  Madeleine.  (Jul  20,  2010)  Mini  Farmers’  Markets  Thrive  in  Minneapolis.  

Minnesota  Public  Radio.  <http://minnesota.publicradio.org/display/web/  2010/  07/20/mini-­‐farmers-­‐markets-­‐thrive-­‐in-­‐minneapolis/>.  

 Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.  March  2011.  

<http://www.bls.gov/news.release/cpi.nr0.htm>.    Bureau  of  Labor  Statistics.  March  2011.<  

http://www.bls.gov/news.release/cpi.t03.htm>.    Briggs,  S.,  Fisher,  A.,  Lott,  M.,  Miller,  S.,  and  Tessman,  N.  (2010)  Real  Food:  Real  

Choices:  Connecting  SNAP  Recipients  with  Farmers  Markets.    Community  Food  Security  Coalition  and  Farmers  Market  Coalition.      

 Centers  for  Disease  Control  and  Prevention.    (2009)  State  Indicator  Report  on  Fruits  

and  Vegetables.  <http://www.fruitsandveggiesmatter.gov/health_  professionals  /data_behavioral.html>.  

 Coleman  et  al.  (1968)  Food:  Consumption,  Prices,  Expenditures.  Agricultural  

Economic  Report  No.138.  USDA/ERS.  Washington,  D.C.    Cox,  David  N.,  Anderson,  Annie  S.,  Lean,  Michael  E.J.,  and  Mela,  David.  (1997)  UK  

consumer  attitudes,  beliefs  and  barriers  to  increasing  fruit  and  vegetable  consumption.  Public  Health  Nutrition  1  (1),  61-­‐68.  

 Cummins,  S.,  Smith,  D.M.,  Aitken,  Z.,  Dawson,  J.,  Marshall,  D.,  Sparks,  L.,  Anderson,  

A.S.  (2010)  Neighborhood  deprivation  &  the  price  and  availability  of  fruit  &  vegetables  in  Scotland.    Journal  of  Human  Nutrition  &  Dietetics  23,  494-­‐501.  

 Denison,  D.C.  “Rich  Produce  at  City’s  Farmers’  Markets”.  The  Boston  Globe.    19  

October  2010.    <http://www.boston.com/business/articles/2010/10/19  /rich_produce_at_citys_  farmers_markets/?p1=Upbox_links>.  

 Dong,  D.,  and  Lin,  B.H.  (2009)  Fruit  and  Vegetable  Consumption  by  Low-­‐Income  

Americans:  Would  Price  Reduction  Make  a  Difference?    Economic  Research  Report  Number  70.  ERS/USDA.    

 

  94  

Fisher,  Andy.  (1999)  Hot  Peppers  and  Parking  Lot  Peaches:  Evaluating  Farmers’  Markets  in  Low  Income  Communities.    Community  Food  Security  Coalition.  Venice,  CA.    

 Fisher,  Meredith.  (2009)  The  Price  of  Food.  Nova  Science  Publishers,  Inc.:  New  York,  

2009.    French,  Simone  A.  (2003)  Pricing  Effects  on  Food  Choices.    Symposium:  Sugar  and  

Fat-­‐  From  Genes  to  Culture.    American  Academy  for  Nutritional  Sciences.      Furey  et  al.,  2001  S.  Furey,  C.  Strugnell  and  H.  McIlveen,  (2001)  An  investigation  of  

the  potential  existence  of  “Food  Deserts”  in  rural  and  urban  areas  of  Northern  Ireland,  Agriculture  and  Human  Values  18,  447–457.  

 Glanz,  K.,  Basil,  M.,  Maibach,  E.,  Godlberg,  J.,  Snyder,  D.  (1998)  Why  Americans  eat  

what  they  do:  Taste,  nutrition,  cost,  convenience,  and  weight  control  concerns  as  influences  on  food  consumption.    Journal  of  the  American  Dietetic  Association  98  (10),  1118-­‐1126.  

 Government  Accountability  Office.  Food  Stamp  Program:  Options  for  Delivering  

Financial  Incentives  to  Participants  for  Purchasing  Targeted  Foods  (GAO-­‐08-­‐415).  July  2008.  

 Grace,  C.,  Grace,  T.,  Becker,  N.,  &  Lyden,  J.  (2005).  Barriers  to  using  urban  farmers’  

market:  An  investigation  of  food  stamp  clients’  perception.  <http://www.oregonfarmersmarkets.org/EBT/docs/BarrierstoUsingFarmersMarkets102206.pdf.>.  

 Halweil,  Brian.  (2002)  Homegrown:  The  Case  for  Local  Food  in  a  Global  Market.    

Worldwatch  Institute  Paper  163.    “Health  of  Boston  2010”.  Boston  Public  Health  Commission  Research  Office.  2010.      Hendrickson,  D.,  Smith,  C.,  Eikenbery,  N.  (2006).    Fruit  and  vegetable  access  in  four  

low-­‐income  food  deserts  communities  in  Minnesota.    Agriculture  and  Human  Values  23:371-­‐383.  

 Kaemingk,  Michael.    “Farmers  Market  Price  Comparison  Study”.  Seattle  University  

Albers  School  of  business  and  Economics.    Spring  2010.  September  2010.  <http://www.capitolhillseattle.com/media/fooddrink/2010/6/16/2010_Price_Study_Kaemingk.pdf>  

 Kim,  Gina.    “Boston  Bounty  Bucks:  Increasing  Access  to  and  Affordability  of  Fresh  

Fruits  and  Vegetables  for  SNAP  Participants”.    The  Food  Project.  Boston,  MA.  February  2010.  

 

  95  

Kleinbaum,  D.,  Kupper,  L.,  Muller,  K.,  Nizam,  A.  Applied  Regression  Analysis  and  Other  Multivariable  Methods.  Duxbury  Press:  Pacific  Grove,  CA,  1998.  

 Larsen,  K.,  and  Gilliland,  J.  (2008).  Mapping  the  evolution  of  'food  deserts'  in  a  

Canadian  city:  Supermarket  accessibility  in  London,  Ontario,  1961-­‐2005.  International  Journal  of  Health  and  Place  15,  1158-­‐1162.  

 Larson,  NI;  Story,  MT;  Nelson,  MC.  (2009).  Neighborhood  Environments:  Disparities  

in  access  to  healthy  foods  in  the  US.  American  Journal  of  Preventative  Medicine.  36:  74-­‐81.  

 McCormack,  L.A.,  Laska,  M.N.,  Larson,  N.I.,  Story,  M.  (2010)  Review  of  the  nutritional  

implication  of  farmers’  markets  and  community  gardens:  a  call  for  evaluation  and  research  efforts.    Journal  of  the  American  Dietetic  Association  110,  399-­‐408.  

 Miller,  Lisa.  (November  29,  2010)  Divided  We  Eat.  Newsweek,  42-­‐48.    McCann,  N.  and  Pirog,  R.  (2009).  Is  Local  Food  More  Expensive?  A  Consumer  Price  

Perspective  on  Local  and  Non-­‐Local  Foods  Purchased  in  Iowa.    Leopold  Center  for  Sustainable  Agriculture.  September  2010.  <  http://www.leopold.iastate.edu/pubs  /staff/prices.html>  

 Neault,  N.,  J.T.  Cook,  V.  Morris,  D.A.  Frank  (2005)  The  Real  Cost  of  a  Healthy  Diet:  

Healthful  Foods  Are  Out  of  Reach  for  Low-­‐  Income  Families  in  Boston,  Massachusetts.  Boston  Medical  Center  Department  of  Pediatrics.  

 Newby,  P.K.  “Compiled  Community  Assessment  Reports”.  Boston  Collaborative  for  

Food  and  Fitness.  2010.  <  http://www.bcffonline.org/Learn/Pages/  default.aspx>.  

 Pollan,  Michael.    (June  10,  2010)  The  Food  Movement,  Rising.  The  New  York  Review  

of  Books.  <  http://www.nybooks.com/articles/archives/2010/jun/10/food-­‐movement-­‐rising/>.  

 Powell,  Lisa  M.,  and  Bao,  Yanjun.  (2009)  Food  prices,  access  to  food  outlets  and  child  

weight.  Economics  and  Human  Biology  7,  64-­‐72.    Reicks  M,  Randall  JL,  Haynes  BJ.  (1994)  Factors  affecting  consumption  of  fruits  and  

vegetables  by  low-­‐income  families.  Journal  of  the  American  Dietetic  Association  94,  1309–1311.  

 Rogers,  Heather.  (July/August  2010)  Slowed  Food  Revolution.    The  American  

Prospect  21  (6),  12-­‐16.    

  96  

Schoonover,  Heather.    (2007)  A  Fair  Farm  Bill  for  Public  Health.  Institute  for  Agriculture  &  Trade  Policy.  <http://www.iatp.org/iatp/publications.cfm  ?accountID  =258&refID  =98598>.  

 Schumacher,  A.,  Winch,  R.,  and  Park,  A.  “Fresh,  Local,  Affordable:  Nutrition  

Incentives  at  Farmers’  Markets  2009  Update”.  Wholesome  Wave.  November  2009.  October  2010.  

 Sommer,  R.,  Wing,  M.,  Aitkens,  S.  (1980)  Price  savings  to  consumers  at  farmers’  

markets.  Journal  of  Consumer  Affairs,  14,  452–462.    Stewart,  Hayden,  Jeffrey  Hyman,  Jean  C.  Buzby,  Elizabeth  Frazão,  and  Andrea  

Carlson.  (February  2011)  How  Much  Do  Fruits  and  Vegetables  Cost?  EIB-­‐71,  U.S.  Department  of  Agriculture,  Economic  Research  Service.    

 Thayer,  J.,  Murphy,  C.,  Cook,  J.,  Ettinger  de  Cuba,  S.,  DaCosta,  R.,  Chilton,  M.  “Coming  

Up  Short:  High  Food  Costs  Outstrip  Food  Stamp  Benefits”.    Boston  Medical  Center  &  The  Philadelphia  GROW  Project  at  Drexel  University.  September  2008.    

 Theuer,  Richard  C.  (September  2006)  Do  Organic  Fruits  and  Vegetables  Taste  Better  

Than  Conventional  Fruits  and  Vegetables?  The  Organic  Center.    Treiman,  Katherine,  et  al.  (1996)  “Attitudes  and  Behaviors  related  to  Fruits  and  

Vegetables  Among  Low-­‐Income  Women  in  the  WIC  Program.”  Journal  of  Nutrition  Education  28  (3).  

 “USDA  National  Farmers  Market  Directory”.  Agricultural  Marketing  Service.  Aug.  

2010.      Vollinger,  et  al.  (January  2011)  SNAP  Access  in  Urban  America:  A  City-­‐by-­‐City  

Snapshot.  Food  and  Research  Action  Center  (FRAC).    Walker,  R.,  Keane,  C.,  and  Burke,  J.  (2010).  Disparities  and  access  to  healthy  food  in  

the  United  States.  Health  and  Place  16:  876-­‐884.    Whitacre,  P.,  P.  Tsai,  and  Mulligan  J,  comps.  The  Public  Effects  of  Food  Deserts  

(Workshop  Summary),  Washington,  D.C.  National  Academies,  2009.    Winne,  Mark  (2008).  Closing  the  Food  Gap.  Beacon  Press,  Boston.    

Zarrell,  Rebecca.  (February  10,  2011)  One  Third  of  Dorchester  Households  Now  Use  Food  Stamps.  The  Dorchester  Reporter.  

<http://www.dotnews.com/2011/dot-­‐seeing-­‐sharp-­‐hike-­‐use-­‐food-­‐stamps  >.

  97  

Appendices  

A: Spreadsheet of all Farmers’ Markets

B: Data Collection Form

C: Data Collection Instructions

D: Vendor Research Questions

E: Table of Quality Comments

F: Summary Tables of Mean Price

G:  Histograms  Showing  PRICE  and  lnPRICE  distributions  

H:  STATA  Output

I: Time  v.  Price  per  Pound  Graphs,  by  Produce  Type  and  Location

  98  

Appendix A: Farmers Market Information

  99  

Appendix B: Data Collection Form

  100  

Appendix C: Data Collection Instructions TFP Price Comparison Study- Data Collection Instructions Produce:

• Carrots: unpeeled, w/ green tops and w/o green tops • Cucumbers: unwrapped, not English • Onions (yellow): large, loose (not bagged) • Tomatoes (field): about fist size, not hot house/ greenhouse, not heirloom, no

vine/cherry/plum • Zucchini: dark green summer squash • White Potatoes: loose • Scallions: green onions (not red bulb) • Lettuce: green leaf, romaine/ Bibb variety, not bagged/washed/trimmed • Bell Peppers (green): loose • Green Beans: loose

Visual (1-3): Rate the produce on a scale of 1 to 3 and record any observations regarding appearance based on color, size, blemishes, consistency, etc. 1= wouldn’t buy item; 2= buy item only if necessary; 3= excited to buy and use item Ex. 2-Wilted lettuce or 1-bruised, wrinkled tomatoes Place of Harvest: (Leave blank at Farmers’ Market) Record country/state of origin; if not stated, record brand name. Cost per unit: Record price indicated on sign along with type of unit (pound, bunch, bag, head, etc.) Ex. Scallions, $1.25/ bunch or Potatoes, $1.00/ lb. Total Weight: Collect 3-5 units randomly and weigh together using clean, dry scale. Record total weight (lbs.) Ex. 1.28 lbs. # of Units: Record # of units weighed (should be 3 in most cases) Avg. Unit Weight and Avg. Cost per Pound: Leave Blank Notes: • Record if produce has dirt, roots, leaves, stems, etc. still intact (initial criteria met). • If more than 1 item fits criteria, record data for cheapest/most conventional • If certain item wasn’t available, see if you can find out why by asking the vendor. • Was there an unusual amount of variation among a single produce type? Please record ALL data CLEARLY & label any data collected elsewhere

  101  

Appendix D: Vendor Research Questions Considered:

• Any organic certification? • Distance from point of harvest • Time elapsed since harvest; weekly schedule for harvest? • What markets are you selling at? • Do you vary price according to the market? Why? How so? • Does price vary within a 14-day period? How? Over the summer? • Does size vary within 14-day period? How? Over the summer? • What do you sell by the unit? Why? What do you sell by the pound? Why? • Are units standardized in any way?

Appendix E: Table of Quality Comments by Quality Rating and Location

  1   2   3  

Farmers’  Markets  

“Spongy,  soft”  (cucumbers)  

“Carrots  looked  fresh  but  weirdly  shaped”;  “oddly-­‐shaped”;  

“huge”  

“Fresh  looking,  bright  green,  not  wilted  at  all  (lettuce)”;  “great,  full,  fresh”;  “very  colorful,  heirloom”;  “huge”  

Supermarkets  

“Wrinkled,  brown  spots  (green  beans)”;  

“very  green  (potatoes)”;  “many  spots”;  “oily,  covered  in  grease-­‐so  gross!  (Cucumbers)”  

“Clearly  have  been  refrigerated  

(tomatoes)”;  “many  are  very  green  (potatoes)”  

“(2.5)  Best  looking  tomatoes  I’ve  seen  in  store  all  summer”  

  102  

Appendix F: Summary Tables of Mean Price

  103  

Appendix  G:  Histograms  Showing  PRICE  and  lnPRICE  distributions  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Appendix  H:  STATA  Output  

Figure  G.1.   Figure  G.2.  

Table  H.1.   Table  H.2.  

  104  

Appendix  I:  Time  v.  Price  per  Pound  Graphs,  by  Produce  Type  and  Location

Note:  Time  period    indicated  on  x-­axis,  mean  price  per  pound  ($)    indicated  on  y-­axis                

Time  Period  Time  Period  

Time  Period  

Time  Period   Time  Period  

Time  Period  


Recommended