+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Industrialisation and the Environmental Quality under ...archive.ias.unu.edu/resource_centre/UNU-IAS...

Industrialisation and the Environmental Quality under ...archive.ias.unu.edu/resource_centre/UNU-IAS...

Date post: 05-Jun-2018
Category:
Upload: duongminh
View: 224 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
54
UNU/IAS Working Paper No. 106 Industrialisation and the Environmental Quality under Economic Reforms: An Indian Case Study K. Narayanan and T. Palanivel October 2003
Transcript

UNU/IAS Working Paper No. 106

Industrialisation and the Environmental

Quality under Economic Reforms:

An Indian Case Study

K. Narayanan and T. Palanivel

October 2003

Industrialisation and the Environmental Quality under Economic Reforms:

An Indian Case Study

K. Narayanan and T. Palanivel

UNU/IAS

Abstract

The purpose of this study is to analyse the linkages between industrialisation and the

environmental quality in the context of on-going economic reforms in India. The study

also explores the possibility of accelerating and sustaining a higher industrial growth for

India. In dealing with the industry-environment linkages, the study follows the

analytical framework provided by the Environmental Kuznets Curve. It finds evidence

to support an inverted U shaped relationship between industrial value added per capita

and carbon emissions. However, the relationship turned out to be U shaped in the case

of water pollution. Multiple regression analysis indicates that, apart from industrial

value added, trade, technology and economic reforms also emerge significant in

determining environmental quality. Overall, the analysis points out a vital role for FDI

in accelerating and sustaining India’s industrial growth.

--------------------------------------

This is a part of the larger work that we are carrying out in the project on Sustainable Development Framework for India. We

benefited from the discussions that we have had with Professors Kirit Parikh, K. L. Krishna, N.S. Siddharthan and Yukihiko

Kiyokawa. The usual disclaimers apply.

1

1. Introduction

In the 1990s there have been many attempts to evaluate the impact of economic growth

on environment quality. There was little agreement as to whether economic growth led

to environmental degradation or to increasing environmental quality. At the one

extreme there are some who argue that economic growth results in ever increasing use

of energy and materials and hence more environmental degradation. At the other

extreme are some others who claim that the faster road to environment improvement is

more economic growth. In the early 1990s, a number of empirical studies [Grossman

& Krueger 1991, 1994, Shafik and Bandopadhyaya 1992, Panayotou 1995] found an

inverted U-shaped relationship between income and some local environment pollutants

such as particulate and sulfur dioxide. This implies a changing relationship between

environment quality and economic growth: environmental degradation gets worse in

the early stages of development, but eventually reaches a peak and starts improving as

income exceeds a certain level. This relationship has been defined as the

Environmental Kuznets’ Curve [EKC] after Simon Kuznets who first observed a

similar changing relationship between income and inequality.

Most of the empirical studies on EKC are based on either a cross-country data at a

given time point or panel data for samples of developed and/or developing countries.

However, an EKC obtained from cross-country regressions1 “may simply reflect the

juxtaposition of a positive relationship between pollution and income in developing

countries with a fundamentally different negative one in developed countries, not a

1 Levine and Zervos (1993) have identified the conceptual and statistical problems associated with cross-

country regressions on empirical linkages between economic growth and indicators of national policies.

2

single relationship that applies to both categories of countries” [Vincent 1997 pp. 417].

The same problem might hold true for results obtained from panel data because of the

differences that exist between these two data sets. Moreover, as Unruh and Moomaw

(1998) pointed out “it does not seem appropriate to infer a GDP-dependent dynamic

equation of motion for a national pollution trajectory from a static analysis” [p.228].

Further, these studies ignored the role of economic reforms and the resultant structural

change in the economy, as well as technology transfer for pollution abatement and

energy efficiency, in the EKC analysis.

Departing from the conventional approach of linking environment quality with overall

economic growth, this paper examines the operation of EKC from a developing country

[viz., Indian] perspective and analyses the inter-relationship between environmental

quality and industrial growth. Moreover, unlike many earlier studies, this paper uses

time series data. Industrial growth [defined as value added per capita] rather than

income per capita is chosen because industry is viewed as a more polluting sector

compared to agriculture or service sector. Theoretical analysis of EKC clearly states

structural change in the economy as an important reason for inverted U-shape

[Panayotou 1993].2 That is economic growth bring about structural change that shifts

the center of gravity of the economy from low-polluting agriculture to high polluting

industry and eventually back to low polluting services. Moreover, after pursuing an

inward-looking development strategy for more than four decades, India decided to take

a historic step of shifting its’ policy paradigm in 1991. The seeds of economic

2 In the literature, there are many other reasons given for an inverted U-shaped relationship the details of

which are discussed in Section 4.

3

liberalisation were visible during the 1980s itself. Much of this policy focussed on

reforms with respect to industry and trade. As a result of this shift in the policy the

Indian industrial sector grew at a higher rate than that of the previous decades and

emerged as an engine of growth of the economy. Therefore, any meaningful link

between economic growth and environment should take into account the role of

industrial sector in the analysis.

Further, since liberalisation in economic policies also enabled large inflow of foreign

capital, technology and trade, attempt would also be made to examine the impact of

economic reforms in general and these variables in particular in determining the level

of air and water pollution. Specifically, in this study, factors such as economic reforms,

trade and technology are also brought into industry environment linkages.

The study is divided into five broad sections. Section 2 deals with an overview of the

industrialisation experience in India during last 50 years. Section 3 presents a discussion

on the link between industrialisation and environment quality in India. While section 4

discusses the framework of analysis, data and methodology used in the analysis of

industry-environment linkages, section 5 presents the results of econometric analysis.

Section 6 discusses some of the implications of the results of the analysis for sustainable

industrialisation. In Section 7, a brief summary and major conclusions of the study are

presented.

4

2. An Overview of the Industrialisation Experience

2.1 Policy Framework

The basic element of early industrialisation strategy was import substitution. Export

pessimism was the underlying assumption. Consequently, since 1956, India placed high

emphasis on the capital goods sector or the heavy industry. The choice of capital or

investment goods sector over consumer goods’ sector was made on the assumption that

the economy suffered from serious “capital constraint’. Capital constraint was said to be

operating in terms of both financial capital [due to low propensity to save] and availability

of physical capital goods. Allocating a larger share of the nation’s limited investable

resources to create the capacity to produce capital goods whose output will also be used to

produce capital goods was expected to remove this capital constraint.

The policy imperatives to implement this strategy includes industrial licensing, control on

capacity, import and export controls, control of capital issues, control of foreign exchange,

allocation of raw materials, price controls and allocations of credit. These measures

suggest that the planners and policy makers understood the need for using a wide variety

of instruments and controls to steer the industrial development in a desired direction.

During the late 1960s and early 1970s, government introduced further regulations to

restrict the growth of monopoly in Indian industries and monitor the foreign exchange

flows into the economy.

The heavy industry biased industrialisation strategy stressed heavily on a “closed

economy” approach. Very limited role was assigned to international trade. Achievement

5

of national self –sufficiency was given top priority in the policy formulation. It was

widely believed that controls and regulations of exports and imports, and state trading in

select commodities, are necessary not only from the point of view of utilising limited

foreign exchange resources available but also for securing an allocation of the productive

resources of the country in line with the targets defined in the Plan [Planning Commission

1950]. The implementation of import substitution was ought to be achieved through the

insistence on indeginisation requirements of the industrial output in most industries.

These elaborate system of government control over production, investment, technology,

locational choice, prices and foreign trade instituted in the mid 1950s led to lackluster

growth, an internationally uncompetitive industrial structure, a perpetually precarious

balance of payments, and above all, rampant rent seeking and the corruption of social,

economic, and political systems.3 Consequently, India neither achieved self-reliance in

industrial growth nor eradicated poverty. Moreover, during the late 1960s and 1970s,

Indian industry experienced a deceleration due to low productivity, high costs, low quality

of production and obsolete technology [Ahluwalia, 1985]. Recognition of these

bottlenecks lead to some fresh thinking among Indian planners on the need to promote

technological modernisation and competitiveness, apart from efforts to remove these

supply-side hurdles.

In the early 1980s, three important committees namely, the Abid Hussain Committee, the

Narasimhan Committee and the Sengupta Committee were set up to review industrial and

3 See for example, Srinivasan (1994) and Ahluwalia (1991).

6

trade policies. These committees recommended easing up of trade policy, the substitution

of physical and quantitative controls by fiscal and other means of macroeconomic

management, the promotion of greater public sector autonomy in business and operating

decisions and the need for measures for enhancing productive efficiency and technological

modernisation.

These recommendations resulted in the process of de-regulation during the 1980s, but

gathered more momentum in the early 1990s. The measures introduced in the 1980s

include (i) de-licensing without any investment limit of thirty-two groups of industries, (ii)

broad-based classification of commodities for issue of licenses, (iii) automatic permission

for expansion of capacities, (iv) permission to MRTP and FERA companies also to avail

(ii) and (iii), if they are located in an industrially backward region, (v) increase in the paid

up capital limit of the firms to be covered under the MRTP Act from Rs.20 crores to

Rs.100 crores and key changes in trade policy including increasing access of exporters to

inputs at international prices and classification of several important inputs, parts and

components under OGL. Further, selective permission for foreign direct investments was

also granted in cases where the FDI involve transfer of technology.

As a result, during the 1980s industrial output and productivity performance improved

significantly [Kelkar and Kumar 1990, Nagaraj 1991 and Ahluwalia 1991]. However,

inspite of showing an up-beat performance during the early years of moderate reforms, the

industrial sector exhibited severe structural rigidities by the end of this decade. The

industrial growth rate, for the first time, turned out negative in 1990-91. The economy also

experienced a severe balance of payments problem in 1991. The economy in early 1990s

7

was seen as having a variety of problems including an inefficient, high cost and non-

competitive industrial structure, serious infrastructure related bottlenecks and

significant constraints on the availability of financial capital. It was argued that policy

induced rigidities had constrained the choices of industries, apart from protecting them

from internal and external competition. Efforts were directed to identify these rigidities

and it was widely recognised that bureaucratic determination of plant capacity, product

mix and location resulted in ignoring the market processes. Trade in scarce materials

became more lucrative than efficient manufacturing. Further, the trade policy also had

an anti-export bias, which blunted export orientation. This bias was reinforced by

curbing of imports via tariffs and quantitative restrictions as a part of the import

substitution strategy. All these necessitated major reforms not only in the industrial

sector, but also in the trade, exchange rate, financial and fiscal sectors.

The reform measures, introduced since July 1991, are designed to remove these policy-

induced distortions and foster efficiency to face global competitiveness. Liberalilsation

measures include, widespread industrial de-licensing, dilution of MRTP Act, trade

reforms including lowering of tariffs and removal of physical barriers on imports,

opening up of many sectors for FDI and higher equity participation, changes in FERA,

liberalisation of policies related to foreign technology purchase and licensing, capital

market reforms, liberal permission for inward flow of foreign portfolio investments

from foreign institutions and allowing the exchange rate to be determined by the market

forces. In the following section, the impact of these policies on the industrial

performance is examined.

8

2.2 Performance

This section deals with an analysis of the changing share of the industrial sector in general

and the manufacturing sub-sector in particular in gross domestic output of the economy.

There has been a significant shift in the sectoral share of GDP over the last 50 years.

Tough the share of agricultural sector has been declining (from 55 to 25 per cent) over the

years; it is still account more than one fourths of the GDP and has had a significant impact

on industrialisation, employment and incomes. The share of industrial sector and service

sector in GDP has been increasing steadily from 16 and 28 per cent in 1951 to 32 and 43

per cent respectively in 1999 (see Chart 1).

Chart 1: Sectoral Shares of GDP

Table 1 provides the trends in the rate of capital formation at broad sectoral levels. It is

evident that during the last three decades, the share of industry in total capital formation

[or investment] has increased from 50 per cent to 60 per cent. The share of investment

Sectoral Share of GDP

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

80

90

100

1951 1955 1959 1963 1967 1971 1975 1979 1983 1987 1991 1995 1999

Per

cen

t

Agriculture Industry Services

9

in agriculture has actually declined from 3.35 to 2.90, while that of services has

increased slowly from 6.03 to 8.31. This highly increasing share of industry in the total

investments made in the economy is evidence of a dominant role played by the

industrial sector in the overall economy.

The reforms of 1991 are expected to correct the distortions made by the earlier

industrialisation strategy and more specifically to tackle the problems of a high cost and

globally uncompetitive industrial sector which is out of tune with India’s capital scarcity

and labour abundance.

Table 1: Average Rates of Capital Formation: Destinations (Per Cent of GDPMP)

Period Agriculture Industry Services

1971-75 3.35 9.75 6.03

1976-80 4.19 11.26 6.80

1981-85 3.76 13.32 7.53

1986-90 3.04 15.15 7.31

1991-95 2.84 15.06 7.55

1996-98 2.90 15.67 8.31

Source: Pandit and Mohanty, 2001.

A growing body of literature has examined the impact of liberalisation in industrial and

trade policies on manufacturing sector performance in different countries.4 While most of

the studies focused on making inter-country comparisons, a few studies analyse the impact

4 Refer USITC (1997) for a detailed review.

10

of trade liberalisation on manufacturing productivity.5 Studies examining the impact of

de-regulations policy point out that productivity trends in the organized manufacturing

sector in India show a clear turn for the better in the 1980s [Ahluwalia, 1991]. Similar

evidence for the post 1991 period is yet to be well documented.6 Kumar (2000) examines

the macro implications of economic reforms, in particular highlighting growth and

sustainability, fiscal adjustment and stability and external sector. He documents changes

in sectoral performance, industrial restructuring, foreign direct investment flow, enterprise

level R & D during the post reform period. Basant (2000) observes that liberalisation has

promoted a trend of corporate restructuring and consolidation through mergers and

acquisitions. There are also evidences of differences in the mode of technology transfer

[Siddharthan, 1999] during the post reform period. However, the processes by which

increased dynamic efficiency is achieved in response to industrial and trade liberalisation

are not spelled out explicitly in the literature available so far. Moreover, although there is

a broad consensus on the need for economic reforms in India; especially because of its’

ability to improve competitiveness and the resultant impact on improving efficiency in

resource use; there has hardly been any attempt in the literature so far on the possible

outcome of such an improved efficiency on sustainability of the very foundations of recent

industrial growth. This study, while examining the nature and pattern of industrialisation

in the post-reform period, largely focuses on this missing aspect of recent industrialisation

in India. Specifically, an attempt has been made to bring out the inter-relationship

between industrialisation and environmental quality, and examine the role of economic

5 Roberts and Tybout (1996) present research studies based on data on panels of producers surveyed in

five newly industrializing countries: Chile, Columbia, Mexico, Morocco and Turkey. 6 Das (1999) finds that productivity performance of Indian industries worsened in the 1990s [1990-91 to

1994-95] as against the 1980s. However, most industries witnessed entry of global players during the

post 1995-96 period and therefore the trend could well be different if one considers these later years also.

11

reforms, trade and technology in determining environmental quality in a developing

economy like India.

In evaluating the industrialisation experience during the last 50 years, it is important to

take into account the overall policy framework and performance of the economy. Also,

while assessing the possibilities of sustaining and accelerating industrial growth, the

possible performance of the economy as well as India’s obligations under the WTO

regime have to be examined.

Table 2 presents the growth rates of industrial production. It can be observed that the

trend growth rate has been increasing from about 5 per cent during the 1970s to 7 per

cent during the second half of 1980s and 1990s.

Table 3 presents the trend rates of growth of the industrial sector during two time

periods, 1970 to 1985 and 1986 to 2000. These two periods represent a regulated and

liberal policy regime. The trend clearly points out an increase in the growth from the

first to the second period.

12

Table 2: Growth Rates of Industrial Production (Per Cent)

1976-80 1981-85 1986-90 1991-95 1996-00

Based on 5 year moving average

Based on observed data

5.28

1.34

5.66

6.21

7.11

7.59

6.25

5.47

7.10

7.05

Source: Pandit and Mahanty, 2001.

Table 3: Trend Rates of Growth (Per Cent)

Period Industry

1970 – 85 4.76

1986 – 00 6.52

1970 – 00 5.81

Table 4: Growth in Value-added of Select Industries

Industries 1980s 1990s

Textiles 5.3 [32.76] 8.0[26.15]

Leather Products 5.6[1.4] 8.3[1.13]

Rubber, Plastics etc 15.2[3.22] 5.5[6.22]

Chemical Products 10.6[9.18] 9.0[11.84]

Basic Metals 6.0[7.62] 5.8[6.43]

Metal Products 5.9[5.15] 5.6[4.31]

Machinery& Equipment 6.9[5.04] 9.4[7.78]

Transport Equipment 7.1[6.92] 9.1[6.45]

All Manufacturing 7.8 7.1

Note: Figures within parentheses are industry share in value-added in 1980-81 and 1990-91

Source: Srivastava [2000]

Changing pattern of growth of different sub-sectors within the broad manufacturing

sector is presented in Table 4. It can be observed from the table that while traditional

13

industries like textiles, leather products and transport equipment shows an increasing

trend in the 1990s when compared to the 1980s, chemical products, rubber and plastics

and metals show a decline in the 1990s when compared to the 1980s. This gradual shift

in the focus of industrial growth may have some serious implications for environment

quality.

As the experience of developed economy show, productivity growth is a key feature of

economic development. For an analysis of productivity growth, we need to know not

only the trends but also whether the observed growth is the result of an increase in

resource base size or improvement in resource use efficiency. Since Indian economy is

known for its resource limitations, productivity growth from resource use efficiency is

crucial for sustainable economic growth. It is in this context, productivity growth

(productivity is a relatively simple concept: it is the relationship between output and

inputs. It can be considered in terms of either partial factor productivity or total factor

productivity) assumes policy significance.

14

Chart 2: Sectoral TFPG Estimates for Indian Economy

Source: Mukherjee, R., M. Chattopadhyay, and C. Neogi, 2000.

As one might expect, there were large variations among sectors in the rate of growth in

TFP. The manufacturing sector witnessed a faster growth in productivity compared to

other sectors. Agriculture sector also shows a significant increase in productivity. Other

activities including services and public administration showed a relatively slow growth in

productivity (see Chart 2).

Few attempts have been made to examine the impact of economic reforms on total

factor productivity in Indian industries.7 The results of these estimates are inconclusive.

At best it may be pointed out that there could be large variation in productivity

performance in the Industrial sub-sectors between the pre and post-reform period.

7 Refer Das (2000) for a review of all these studies.

Trends in Productivity in Selected Sectors

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

1950 –51 1954 – 55 1958 – 59 1962 – 63 1966 – 67 1970 – 71 1974 – 75 1978 – 79 1982 – 83 1986 – 87 1990 – 91 1994 – 95

1950

-51=

100

Agr. Manuf. + mining Others

15

Krishna and Mitra [1998] have also observed statistically significant increase in

productivity growth in four industry groups chosen by them. Das (2000) also reports

mixed trend for productivity performance in Indian manufacturing. For the

manufacturing sector in total, the total factor productivity [TFPG] is around 1.81 per

cent per annum for the period 1980-95. Comparison of different industries have shown

that TFP growth rates are either negative or in the range of 0 to 2 per cent range. His

results indicate that trade liberalisation, particularly the reduction of the non-tariff

barriers, leads to improvements in productivity growth through increasing exposure to

competition, especially in the intermediate goods industries.

2.3 Building Technological Capabilities

Technological capabilities comprise a broad range of effort that every enterprise must

itself undertake in order to access, implement, absorb and build upon the knowledge

required in production. Since technology cannot simply be transferred like a physical

product, nor can purchases of blueprints or patents give ready made technological

upgradation, firms in a developing country like India need to develop capabilities to

acquire and absorb these new technologies from abroad [Kumar and Siddharthan, 1997].

However, firms operating in a “protected” market may not have had incentives to acquire

these capabilities. Therefore, there would be large-scale variation between firms within an

industry as well as across industries in efforts to build technological capabilities. Simple

comparisons of R & D intensities reveal large variation across industries, although the

intensity itself is very low for most industries. Evidence of promoting local technological

efforts to build a National System of Innovation is hard to find in India. Most studies have

shown that indeginisation requirements, which the Government policy has been insisting

16

upon, although has facilitated technological learning, dampened the international

competitive capabilities by limiting the direction of exports to those countries that have

similar market and resource conditions. This, in turn, could also result in low and

differential competitive capabilities. With liberalisation and the resultant increased FDI

inflow, there is a continual flow of technology. One could witness productivity

improvements through spillover of foreign direct investment. However, spillover varies

between industries and indicates the possibility to increase with the level of local

capability and competition. Therefore, any amount of policy effort to promote technology

transfer may not always produce the intended results. At best, requirements may secure

diffusion of a large share of a smaller technology stock. Alternative policies, such as

support to education and competition in the domestic markets may, on the other hand,

increase both the inflow of technology and the absorptive capacity of domestic firms.

Therefore, host country governments have limited possibilities to influence the

multinationals in their choice of production location, choice of techniques, etc. However,

much of it depends on the performance of host country industries. Moreover, MNCs can

also be lured to undertake R & D efforts in host countries with the advantage of cheap

scientifically and technically qualified manpower.

Trends in R & D intensities [R & D expenditure as a ratio of Sales Ratio] for select

industry groups are given in the following table. It appears that although the R & D

intensity of industrial sector in total shows only a marginal decline during the last 16 years,

there are large differences between different industrial sub-sectors. Transportation and

Telecommunication were the only sectors where R & D intensity seems to have increased

marginally. In all other cases, it has actually declined in the post liberalisation period.

17

This could be because during the years immediately after economic reforms, most

industries experienced large inflow of FDI and transfer of technology from the parent to

the affiliates. The industrial sector experienced technological paradigm shift and as a

result, dependency on imports of technology was more than in-house technological efforts.

Table 5: Ratio of R & D to Sales in Select Industries

Industry 1980-83 1988-91 1994-95

Chemicals 0.95 0.69 0.65

Textiles 0.45 0.25 0.26

Paper & Pulp 0.49 0.23 0.12

Sugar 0.44 0.77 0.47

Food processing 0.29 4.25 1.2

Glass 1.11 0.51 0.5

Transportation 1.07 0.65 1.09

Telecommunications 1.86 1.23 1.96

Machine Tools 3.92 1.37 1.67

Electrical &

Electronics

0.80 0.94 0.78

All Industries 0.74 0.73 0.70

Source: Basant, 2000.

2.4 FDI and Shifts in Technological Paradigm

Liberalisation of economic policies and the outward orientation introduced since 1991 has

brought about a dramatic change in Indian industries. These policy measures considerably

transformed the environment in which the industrial firms had been operating. As a

consequence, most industries witnessed the entry of new firms involving foreign equity

and adoption of strategies by the already existing firms to introduce technological change

and improve their performance. The new players brought in modern engineering, efficient

processes and effective shop-floor layouts. The new manufacturing strategies include

breaking up of the plant into modules and cells, reduce the complexity of purchasing

18

logistics, reduction of inventories and product complexity, and creation of simpler

processes by encouraging flexibility and teamwork. Manufacturing activity in many

industries also makes extensive use of CAD/CAM [computer-aided designs and

computer-aided management] in their plants. Moreover, the materials used in most

industries have also undergone a change from traditional steel and cast iron to aluminum

and thermoplastics. Some of the existing industries have oriented their systems by

replacing the batch system by work flow, organising the production in product modules

and by keeping the product-mix flexible in order to save time, reduce cost and increase

quality. The new joint ventures, it appears, are becoming catalysts to activate the

capabilities of the existing plants in areas of cost control and product development. As a

result, the policy changes to introduce market-induced efficiency have had far reaching

implications for the nature and pattern of industrialisation.

Table 6: Sectoral Distribution of Stock of FDI in India

Industry Group FDI Stock as in

March 1980

FDI Stock as in

March 1990

Approvals

1991-97

I. Plantation and Horticulture 4.1 9.5 0.33

II. Mining 0.8 0.3 1.06

III. Petroleum and Power 3.9 0.1 28.91

IV. Manufacturing 86.9 84.9 37.18

Of which

Food and Beverages 4.2 6.0 5.17

Textiles 3.4 3.4 1.62

Machinery and Machine Tools 7.6 13.1 2.24

Transport Equipment 5.5 10.4 4.84

Metal and Metal Products 12.7 5.2 6.0

Electrical and Electronics 10.4 10.9 5.44

Chemical and Allied Products 32.3 28.4 6.88

Miscellaneous Manufacturing 10.7 7.5 6.01

V. Services [Mostly Infrastructure] 4.1 5.2 31.31

Source: Kumar, 1998.

19

From the above given table, it is evident that FDI flow into the Indian economy has

undergone substantial change during the last two decades. Bulk of the flow is going to

the industrial sector [broadly defined to take into account the infrastructure industries

also]. There appear to be a dramatic change in the share of many industrial sub-sectors:

namely, chemical and allied products, metal and metal products and textiles showing a

declining trend and petroleum and power and infrastructure industries [mostly

telecommunications] showing an increasing trend.

3. Industrialisation and Environmental Quality

3.1 Policy Towards Environmental Protection

It is widely believed that environmental protection is presenting a fundamental challenge

in the face of the nation’s desire to industrialize faster. Although India’s response to

environmental problems dates back to 1972 when the government established a National

Committee on Environmental Planning and Coordination [NCEPC], it hardly had any

meaningful impact on the polluters. NCEPC was replaced by a National Committee on

Environmental Planning [NCEP] in 1981 and it was authorised to prepare an annual ‘state

of the environment’ report. Therefore, governmental efforts for air and water pollution

management could be traced only to the list of policies during the last two decades:

National Water Policy 1987; National Conservation Strategy and Policy Statement on

Environment and Development, 1992; and Policy Statement for Abatement of Pollution,

1992. The strategy and policy statements prescribe command and control, technological

measures, zoning, fiscal incentives, and use of economic instruments as mechanisms for

air and water pollution control. That is the approach to control pollution in India is to use

regulatory instruments along with systems for monitoring the prescribed standards to

20

achieve the government’s policy goals. Standards for ambient and point source

emissions/discharges are set by various acts of the government and compliance is

mandatory. There are provisions for penalties as given in these acts. The Central and

State Pollution Control Boards monitor all these.8

Despite the aforementioned legislation and policy measures adopted by the government,

air and water pollution remains a major concern in India. The very poor quality of air and

water in many parts of the country suggest that these policies have not worked too well. A

great deal of effort is needed to improve the enforcement mechanism to ensure that the

policies drawn up for the control of air and water pollution are implemented both in letter

and spirit. Also, as experience in developed countries has shown, firms react to popular

pressure. In order to generate such pressure, citizens should be given the right to

information and effluent quality measurements of all firms should be publicly available.

3.2 Industry Environment Linkages

In this section, we analyse the impact of industrialisation on environmental quality in

terms of India’s past as well as that of neighboring countries. Industrialisation is likely

to affect environment in many ways. Polluting the atmosphere, especially in terms of

air and water quality has been one of the most important negative externality of

industrial development. This paper analyses the impact of recent industrial

development on air and water pollution.

8 Detailed outline of the policies could be found in Parikh et al (2000) and Palanivel (2001).

21

“Air pollution could be defined as the presence in the atmosphere of one or more

contaminants in such quantities and for such duration as is injurious, or tends to be

injurious, to human health or welfare, animal or plant life, or property or would

unreasonably interfere with the enjoyment of life or property” [TERI, 1998]. Air

pollution has been aggravated by, among others, industrialisation, increasing traffic,

and higher levels of energy consumption. The major pollutants are particulate matters,

sulphur dioxide (SO2), nitrogen oxides (NO2), Carbon monoxide (CO2), and

hydrocarbons (HC). Of all these air pollution indicators, the present study would

examine changes with respect to Carbon monoxide (CO2) for which a time series data

has been made available by WDR 1999. This is not to argue that other forms of

pollution are unimportant. They are indeed, equally, if not more important than CO2.9

Currently, annual ambient air quality data are available for only three pollutants,

namely SPM, SO2, and NO2 and that also for only two years, 1993 and 1994. An

analysis carried out by TERI (1998) indicates that at majority of the locations in

residential and industrial areas, the air quality standards are violated with respect to

SPM. However, in general, SO2 and NO2 levels in India are within the prescribed

limits. The present study would, therefore, focus largely on Carbon monoxide

emissions.

CO2 is one of the most widely distributed of all air pollutants-global emissions

probably exceed the combined emissions of all other major air pollutants. The most

important effect of carbon monoxide emission is that it deprives tissues of oxygen and

9 Efforts are being made to collect time series data on SPM, SO, NO, and HC in order to test EKC with

respect to these indicators as well.

22

people with cardio-respiratory diseases turn out very sensitive to these changes.

Although air pollution is considered to be more of a localized problem, the analysis of

causal factors responsible for air pollution at the national level does yield some insights.

Table 7: Annual Average Rate of Change in Carbon Monoxide [CO2] (in Per Cent

Terms)

Environment

Indicator

Country 1981-90 1991-96 1981-96

CO2 kg per $ of

GDP

India 0.98 1.07 1.02

China -3.85 -5.23 -4.37

Indonesia -0.31 -0.72 -0.46

CO2 kgppp

India -3.04 -1.35 -2.40

China -7.75 -7.50 -7.65

Indonesia -4.25 -3.07 -3.81

CO2

India 6.89 6.73 6.83

China 5.03 5.79 5.31

Indonesia 6.08 7.03 6.44

CO2 per capita

India 4.65 4.84 4.72

China 3.51 4.59 3.92

Indonesia 4.15 5.25 4.56

Source: Authors calculation on the basis of data provided by WDR 1999.

Table 8 provides a comparative picture of India in terms of energy efficiency. It can be

noticed that although India’s energy performance is increasing at the rate of about 1.74-

per cent per annum, it is far from being satisfactory when compared to what China has

achieved. The rate of growth in energy efficiency has actually declined marginally

during the post when compared to the pre reform period. Although there are large-

scale variations in energy consumption between different industrial sector [Chakraborty

23

and Mukhopadhyaya, 2000], this study has pointed out that some of the industries have

become very efficient with respect to energy utilisation during the post reform period.

When one compares the rate of change in commercial energy consumption, India seems

to be comparable to that of both China as well as Indonesia. It is heartening to note that

the rate of growth in commercial energy consumption has actually declined more for

India when compared to China and Indonesia [for whom it has actually increased].

This decline in the commercial energy consumption would have serious positive impact

on environmental quality, especially the carbon emissions.

Table 8: Annual Average Rate of Change in Energy Consumption

Environment

Indicators

Country 1981-1990 1991-1996 1981-1996

Commercial Energy

Consumption

India 4.17 2.75 3.64

China 3.94 3.56 3.80

Indonesia 2.87 4.64 3.53

GDP Per Unit of

Energy

Consumption

India 1.75 1.72 1.74

China 5.25 7.15 5.96

Indonesia 1.18 2.65 1.73

Source: Authors calculation on the basis of data provided by WDR 1999.

Sustainable water use has quantitative and qualitative dimensions. While the first may

imply a cutback on magnitude of water use resulting in reduced production in the

absence of improved technology of water use, the second implies that the nature of

water as a flow and of water bodies as stores of water be maintained intact. India’s

water resources contain 113 river basins, of which 14 are major, 44 are medium and the

24

remaining 55 are minor. The fourteen major river basins account for 83 per cent of the

total area of the basins, contribute 85 per cent of the total surface flow, and house 80

per cent of the population served by the basins. The major river basins are those of

Brahmaputra, Ganga, Indus, Godavari, Krishna, Mahanadi, Narmada, Cauvery,

Brahmani, Tapti, Mahi, Subarnarekha, Pennar, and Sabarmati. The quality of river

water is monitored at 480 stations under different programmes such as MINARS

[monitoring of Indian national aquatic resources], GEMS [global environmental

monitoring systems], and GAP [ganga action plan]. A number of physical, chemical,

biological and bacteriological parameters are being measured under the programme, but

the important ones are BOD [biochemical oxygen demand], DO [dissolved oxygen],

and TC [total coliform count]. The sources of pollution are many and varied. This

study examines the role of industry in water pollution.

Data on pollution load in terms of BOD at all India reveal that as in 1995-96, the share

of industry BOD in total BOD is about 17.5 per cent as against the urban BOD which

constitutes about 82.5 per cent. In absolute terms, industry BOD is 751.4 thousand tons

when compared to 3538.79 thousand tons of urban in a total of 4290.17 thousand tons.

Chopra and Goldar (2000) have calculated the pollution load ratio R [where R =

BOD/Surface water available for non-agricultural sectors] to be 9.53 as in 1995-96.

There is large-scale variation between different States in India with respect to BOD.

Among different industrial sectors, water pollution is concentrated within a few

industrial sub-sectors mainly in the form of toxic wastes and organic pollutants. Out of

the total pollution contributed by industrial sub-sector, 40-45 per cent of the total

25

pollutants can be traced to the processing of industrial chemicals and nearly 40 per cent

of the total organic pollution to the food products industry alone. Food products and

agro-based industries together contribute 65-70 per cent of the total industrial

wastewater in terms of organic load. According to CPCB (1994) most of the defaulting

industries to operate without adequate pollution control facilities are mainly sugar mills,

distilleries, leather processing units, and thermal power stations. Among these it is the

small-scale sector, which lack the treatment facilities the most. The annual average rate

of change in water pollution as well as the share of different industries in Water

pollution is given in the following tables.

Table 9: Annual Average Rate of Change Per Cent in Water Pollution

[All India in Terms of BOD]

Indicator 1980 to 1990 1991-1996 1980-1996

BOD per day

India 0.0019 2.58 0.97

China 8.07 0.87 5.37

Indonesia 9.43 6.73 8.42

BOD per day per

worker

India -0.45 -0.83 -0.59

China 0.05 0.00 0.03

Indonesia -1.41 -1.75 -1.54

Source: Authors calculation on the basis of WDR 1999.

Table 10: Industrial Distribution of Water Pollution [BOD] (Per Cent Share)

Industry/Time 1980 1985 1990 1996

Chemical 5.98 7.48 7.29 8.23

Clay & Glass 0.18 0.25 0.22 0.21

Food 53.85 47.52 50.92 51.14

Metal 14.10 16.58 15.32 14.47

Paper & Pulp 7.57 8.76 7.96 7.92

Textiles 14.08 14.44 13.18 12.54

Wood 0.38 0.40 0.32 0.29

Others 3.85 4.57 4.79 5.20

Source: WDR, 1999.

26

From Table 10, it can be observed that the share of industries in water pollution is

changing over the period 1980 to 1996. Chemical industries appear to be an important

candidate for water pollution monitoring. Although the share of Food is the maximum,

there are signs of decline in this sector. Another important pollutant, Textiles is also

showing a declining trend. Increase in the share of Chemicals could also be because

the composition of industrial output has changed from metal and metal based to

chemical and chemical based and also to micro electronic based. Such a trend was

reported even during the 1980s [Kelkar and Kumar (1990)].

The Central Pollution Control Board [CPCB] identified a total of 1551 medium and

large industrial units in the country under the seventeen highly polluting industrial

sectors. Of these about 77 per cent are predominantly water polluting and 15 per cent

are predominantly air polluting, and the remaining 8 per cent are both air and water

polluting industries. Annual progress in the implementation of pollution control

measures in the 17 categories of highly polluting industries is presented in the

Economic Survey of the India [2000-01]. According to the CPCB, as on 30th

September 2000 out of a total of 1,551 large and medium industries identified in 1992

in the 17 categories of highly polluting industries, 1,326 industries have installed the

requisite pollution control facilities to comply with the prescribed environmental

standards. 168 industries have closed down and only 57 industries are yet to install the

necessary pollution control facilities.

With respect to water pollution, the Ministry of Environment and Forests in

coordination with the CPCB identified 851 industries along the major rivers and lakes

27

in the country which were found discharging their untreated or partially treated

effluents in the fresh water bodies. As on 30 September 2000 596 units were found to

comply with prescribed standards and another 232 units have been closed. Only 23

units have not installed the requisite pollution control facilities.

In sum, it could be stated that economic reforms carried out since 1991 has resulted in

large inflow of foreign capital and shifts in technological paradigms. Shifts in

technological paradigm in most industries also represent changing input requirements. As

a result any attempt to discuss the sustainability of industrial growth should focus on the

implications of the use of these resources by the industrial sector in terms of domestic

production capabilities. Evidence in India suggests that not only the material used in

industrial production has undergone drastic change during the recent period, but also the

industrial output has become more import intensive. The industrial sector appears to have

started using energy saving technologies. These factors to-gether point to certain issues of

sustainability. While the former would mean some implications for balance of payments,

the latter poses serious questions about channeling investment to power generation and the

resultant pollution aspects.

Secondly, increased competition and FDI inflow in a more liberal regime has also

contributed to improving productive efficiency of most industrial sectors. Increased

industrial output could be sustained either by maintaining the increased rate of investment

or by improving the efficiency of existing capital and labour. Developing countries,

during their initial phase of liberalisation, are more likely to depend on the former for

sustaining the industrial growth. What are the possibilities for maintaining domestic and

28

foreign investments in Indian industries, therefore, assumes considerable importance in

the sustainability analysis.

Thirdly, there appear to be serious environmental consequences of the new industrial

output and a careful examination of the effectiveness of new technology and policy

measures in facilitating green industrial output is the need of the hour.

4. Analytical Framework, Data and Methodology

The analytical framework used in examining the link between industrialisation and

environmental quality is basically drawn from the literature on Environmental Kuznets

Curve [EKC]. The framework is based on the assumption that at the beginning of a

growth path in a country increase in GDP corresponds with high environmental

degradation. Environmentally friendly technologies are not yet accessible and the

awareness of environmental problem is low. Environmental degradation increases with

income up to a certain point beyond which environmental quality is enhanced by higher

GDP per capita, implying an inverted U-shaped relationship between these two

variables. The literature identifies many reasons for an inverted U-shaped relationship

including (I) structural change, (ii) technology, (iii) trade, (iv) migration, etc.10

In the context of industrialisation, following Lopez (1994) it could be argued that when

producers’ free ride on the environment or pay fixed pollution prices, growth results

inescapably in higher pollution levels. When producers pay the full marginal social

10

Refer Panayotou (2000) for a detailed review.

29

cost of pollution they generate, the pollution-income relationship depends on the

properties of technology and of preferences. With homothetic preferences pollution

levels still increase monotonically with income but with non-homothetic preferences,

the faster the marginal utility declines with consumption levels and the higher the

elasticity of substitution between pollution and other inputs, the less pollution will

increase with output growth. Empirically plausible values for these two parameters

result in an inverted U-shaped relationship between pollution and income.

Although most of the empirical testing of ‘inverted U’ movement of pollution with the

growth of per capita income for a large number of countries was carried out during the

mid 1990s, some of the earlier studies also raised the theoretical possibility of an

‘inverted U’ shaped EKC [Beckerman 1972, Simon 1977, 1981]. Lack of reliable data

on pollution prevented any further work in this area but with the advent of Global

Environmental Monitoring System (GEMS) on air and water, the Toxic Release

Inventory (TRI) etc., empirical investigation on EKC started in 1990s at a larger scale

[Grossman and Krueger, 1995, Shafik and Bandyopadhyay, 1992, Selden and Song,

1994, Torras and Boyce 1998, Kaufmann, et.al 1998, Carson et. al 1997, Ravallion,

Heil and Jalan 2000]. Almost every study has tried to analyse the relationship of a

select pollutant e.g. CO2, SPM, NOx, Sox, BOD, etc and the growth of per capita

income for various developed and/or a cross section of developed and developing

countries. As mentioned in Section 1, most of the studies following EKC have tested

and reported many plausible relationship between economic growth and the

environment, including the possibility of no relationship also, in examining this inter-

relationship.

30

EKC is based on the argument that continuous economic growth induces environmental

improvement through structural and technological change (Grossman 1993, Seldon and

Song, 1994). EKC runs across on the argument that negative environmental impact of

the greater output will be outweighed by the technological (read environmental

friendly) advancement in production mechanism. The implication of this theory for

industrialisation is through the following ways:

i) Growth in output will favour the shift from pollution intensive to non-pollution

intensive industries

ii) Energy consumption per unit of output will decline and hence less pollution.

It is now well established that, in a developing country like India, share of FDI in total

industrial output increases with the industrial growth. Technological improvement in

industries through FDI and removal of institutional barriers and increased

competitiveness accelerate productivity which imply lesser use of capital and energy

for the same output level or greater output from the same level of capital investment

and energy consumption.

Moreover, as the analysis presented in the previous section has revealed, there has been

a change in the industrial composition of FDI, especially in the post reform period and

large inflow of FDI and the resultant impact on competitiveness has encouraged

technological paradigm shifts in most manufacturing industries. Technological

paradigm shifts assume considerable importance because, during the pre-reform period,

industrial establishments were only allowed to traverse on a given technology and any

31

shift in the paradigm required prior approval of the government [and fresh license].11

As a result, any attempt to capture the industrialisation-environment linkage need to

take into account the role of trade, FDI and technology. Moreover, a large body of

empirical analysis dealing with air quality has also tested “race to the bottom”

hypotheses.12

In the race to the bottom world, decent environment standards impose

high costs on polluters in high-income countries. To remain competitive, these firms

relocate to low-income countries whose government and people are desperate for

investment.

Statistical data for the analysis presented in this section is largely drawn from the

World Development Report 1999. Definition of the variables used in the analysis is

given in the appendix. The empirical exercise is carried out in two stages: firstly an

attempt has been made to test for possible relationship between air and water pollutant

with industrial value added per capita and secondly, the study examines the role of

economic reforms, trade and technology in determining environmental quality

[represented by CO2 and BOD].

The reduced form equation that most studies testing EKC have used takes the form:

The simplest model specification [Shafik and Bandyopadhyay 1992, Hettige, Lucas and

Wheeler 1992, Shafik 1994 and Rothman 1998] shows a relationship between an

environmental indicator (E) and the income per capita (Y):

11

For a discussion on the impact of liberalisation on shifts in technological paradigm refer Narayanan

(1998). 12

See Wheeler (2000) for a review of these studies and recent empirical testing of the “race to the

bottom” model.

32

E it = o + 1 Y it + 2 Y2it + it

Where E = environment indicator, Y = income per capita, is the error term and ’s are

the parameters to be estimated.

To this basic model, Panayotou (1997) has included Population (P), Growth (g), and

Policy (p). Cropper and Griffiths (1994), Cole, Rayner, and Bates (1997), Suri and

Chapman (1998), Kaufmann, Davidsdottir, Garnham, and Pauly (1998) have

introduced variables related to trade in the basic environment-income functional form.

Ratnayake and Kim (1999) attempted to explain air and water pollution in terms of

lagged average of incomes, strictness of authority, registered vehicles per capita, apart

from Gross regional domestic product per capita. Regional, rather than total GDP was

considered because they estimated the regression for a pooled data for different cities in

South Korea.

The present study also begins with the functional form widely used in the literature.

However, since the focus is to explain the link between industrialisation and

environmental quality, the study uses industrial value added per capita, rather than GDP

per capita. Moreover, the study also analyses the role of economic reforms, technology

and trade in explaining air and water pollution at the all India level. Further, since

liberalisation in India witnessed large inflow of foreign capital, an attempt would also

be made to examine the role played by foreign investment in determining air and water

quality. The regression equation estimated, therefore, takes the form:

E t = o + 1 I t + 2 I2t + 3 Tr + 4 Th + 5 FDI + 6 DR + it

Where E = environment quality [represented by CO2 and BOD]

33

Tr = Trade in goods as a share of goods GDP

Th = Technological efforts [represented by GDP per unit of energy consumed in the

case of CO2 equation and R & D intensity in the case of BOD]

FDI = foreign direct investment and

DR = dummy variable having 0 and 1 observations for the period before 1991 and after

1991 respectively.

The results of the model estimation are discussed in the next section.

5. Empirical Results

This section begins with an examination of the relationship between air quality and

industrialisation [Figures are presented in the appendix]. An inverted U-shaped

relationship between industrial value added per capita and the indicator of air quality is

displayed by carbon monoxide. It shows that at lower levels of industrial value added

per capita, air pollution rises and then after reaching a peak, gradually declines when

the value added increases. This relationship between CO2 and industrial value added

per capita is statistically significant at 1- per cent level in a two-tailed test. The

estimated turning point for the inverted U shaped curve appear to be around industrial

value added per capita US $ 85 [at constant1995 prices], which India achieved in the

year 1995.

However, in the case of water pollution, the reverse seems to be taking place. The

curve takes a U shaped relationship showing that at both very low as well as very high

levels of industrial value added per capita, BOD tends to be high. That is, as the

34

industrial value added increases, the water pollution level goes down and after a certain

point the additional industrial output is leading to increased water pollution. This curve

estimation is also significant at 1- per cent level in a two-tailed test. Generally the

turning points for water quality indicators occur at relatively lower levels of income

than those for air pollution. The turning point for upward sloping appears to be at

industrial value added per capita US $ 65 [at constant 1995 prices].

Earlier studies dealing with a particular country case [Ratnayake and Kim 1999 (for

South Korea) and Vincent 1997 (for Malaysia)] also tested EKC and report mixed

results, but regressed different pollution indicators on income per capita. In the context

of a developing country like India, it is very important to note that the relationships

between pollution emission and industrial value added should only be taken as

indicatory. It is possible to attribute the inverted U-shaped relationship between carbon

emissions and industrial value added to the observed increase in energy efficiency.

Further, from the observed industrial distribution of FDI one could support the

contention that the new industrial output is much less pollution intensive than the older

ones. However, it is not possible to feel complacent, especially because, as has been

observed in section 3, pollution emissions in absolute terms appear to have increased in

India during the post reform period when compared to the 1980s. Much of this increase

in pollution [CO2] could be attributed to the growth of transport sector.

With respect to water pollution, it must be observed that chemical industry, which has

grown at a high rate during the last two decades, could be the major factor. It could be

argued that most industrial establishments do not fulfill the effluent treatment

35

considerations. It is quite likely that these industries are actually not in a position to

invest the amount of money required for water pollution abatement. Murti (1997)

estimated the capital stock required for water pollution abatement in Indian industry in

a hypothetical situation where all polluting industries would comply with standards.

The total capital stock is estimated at Rs.59,179 million. Assuming a discount rate of

15 per cent and lifetime of fifteen years gives a capital recovery of factor of 0.171.

Using this, the total annualized capital cost required for water pollution abatement in

major water polluting industries is Rs.10,120 million. Total annual investment needed

for water pollution abatement across industries [inclusive of wage bill, material cost,

and power cost] is estimated at Rs.14,089 million which is about 1.17 per cent of the

annual turnover of all water polluting industries. Can the policy measures adopted

direct the industries to carry out this is a big question that needs to be answered.

Further, it may be pointed out that industrial output may not be the only factor

explaining CO2 and BOD, and therefore, it is important to examine the role of industrial

value added in the presence of other explanatory variables, especially factors capturing

technological efforts, foreign direct investment and trade orientation. The results of

least squares estimation are presented in the following two tables.

In both tables, three columns present the estimated equations. The difference between

the equations is that the basic model takes into account the role of industrial value

added along with a dummy variable to capture the effect of economic reforms. In the

subsequent equations, economic reform is captured by two specific factors: trade and

FDI. This is because, most significant changes in India, especially after the

36

implementation of economic reforms, have been with respect to trade and foreign

capital inflow. The third equation was estimated to check for the possible adverse

effect of multicollinearity. Variable capturing technological capability was dropped at

this stage because it had a very highly significant correlation with the trade variable.

Table 11: Determinants of Carbon Emissions

Dependent Variable LCO2

Variables Equation 1 Equation 2 Equation 3

Constant -4.037

(-4.949) -4.800

(-3.743) -5.319

(-4.269)

LIVAPC 4.142

(4.522) 5.020

(3.319) 5.962

(4.414)

LIVAPC2 -0.983

(-3.720) -1.262

(-2.766) -1.600

(-4.218)

Policy 0.0015

(2.224)

LTECH -1.001

(-2.254)

-0.732

(-1.269)

LFDI 0.00267

(0.406)

0.00629

(1.032)

LTRADE 0.106

(1.644)

0.135

(2.187)

R Sqr 0.931 0.922 0.911

R bar Sqr 0.908 0.887 0.881

D.W. 2.643 2.197 1.985

F 40.492 26.005 30.548

NOBS 17 17 17

Source: Authors’ calculation.

Note: Figures in parenthesis are t-values. Co-efficients in bold are significant at 1 per

cent level and those underlined are significant at 5 or 10 per cent level in two tailed test.

From the results presented in these two tables, it is evident that EKC holds true even in

the presence of other variables only in the case of carbon emissions. With respect to

BOD, the moment one introduces other explanatory variables, industrial value added

turns out insignificant. This could be because industrial waste, which is one of the

37

important factors contributing to water pollution, may be a more dominating factor

rather than industrial output by itself. This could also be due to the fact that BOD is

defined in terms of the amount of oxygen that bacteria in water will consume in

breading down waste.

Technological efforts appear to be an important factor in explaining pollution emissions.

In both CO2 as well as BOD, the variables used to capture technological efforts

emerged significant with a negative sign, indicating that greater the efforts are lesser

the pollution would be. Improvements in technological efforts, especially energy

saving and environmentally benign could also be attributed to the government policy on

pollution abatement introduced since 1993 and increasing presence of FDI with the

latest technological configuration.

38

Table 12: Determinants of Water Pollution

Dependent Variable: BOD

Variables Equation 1 Equation 2 Equation 3

Constant 12.037

(6.393) 6.183

(3.196) 8.335

(4.779)

LIVAPC -6.530

(-3.150)

-0.435

(-0.207)

-2.189

(1.511)

LIVAPC2 1.803

(3.161)

0.134

(0.234)

0.726

(1.387)

Policy 0.0337

(2.130)

LTECH -0.273

(-2.044)

LFDI 0.00895

(1.032)

LTRADE 0.228

(1.884)

0.407

(4.446)

R Sqr 0.811 0.928 0.899

R bar Sqr 0.767 0.895 0.875

D.W. 0.828 1.650 1.511

F 18.583 28.220 38.475

NOBS 17 17 17

Source: Authors’ calculation.

Note: Figures in parenthesis are t-values. Co-efficients in bold are significant at 1 per

cent level and those underlined are significant at 5 or 10 per cent level in two tailed test.

The policy dummy variable to capture the impact of economic reforms turned out

significant with a positive sign, indicating the possibility of an increasing trend in

pollution emission during the post reform period. Decomposing the policy effect into

trade and FDI, we find that the trade variable emerge significant with a positive sign.

This would imply that during the years immediately after reforms, trade is likely to

dominate, and in the process may also cause certain environmental damage. However,

over a period of time, especially after the countries start imposing legislation to regulate

unwarranted trade, the relationship might change. In the case of FDI the results do not

indicate “race to the bottom” world experience for India. FDI, although had a positive

39

sign in determining both CO2 as well as BOD, turned out insignificant. A more careful

analysis on the actual technology used by the FDIs in their Indian plants would provide

better insights.

6. Implications for Sustainable Industrialisation

The economic reforms since mid 1985 have helped Industry to accelerate its growth.

Industry grew at an annual average rate of about 4.76 per cent during 1970-71 to 1984-

85. In the late 1980s, its growth rate improved significantly, to reach an average of

over 7 per cent. This was the period when the first steps towards industrial and trade

reforms were introduced, and they clearly had favourable effects on industrial growth.

The growth rate declined to about 5-6 per cent in the early 1990s due to contractionary

fiscal and monetary policies adopted to address the BOP crisis in 1990-91. However,

the fresh reforms in the early 1990s helped growth to accelerate again little over to 7

per cent per year during the second half of 1990s. In fact, for three consecutive years,

1994-97, industry grew about 10 per cent per annum. This not only shows that Indian

industry has capacity to grow at about 10 per cent per year, but also reflects that

accelerating growth to 12 per cent is not impossible. We believe that the Industrial

sector is likely to grow at about 8 per cent per annum during the next 4 or 5 years even

at the current level of investment and resource efficiency. Certainly the rate could be

raised if India were able to raise its investment as well as efficiency levels. Pandit and

Mohanty (2001) have projected slightly more than 8 per cent growth rate for the

industrial sector during the next twenty years, taking into account the possibility of FDI

inflow in industry and infrastructure sectors. One clear point that emerges from their

study is that to achieve higher rates of industrial growth, we need to step up FDI inflow.

40

The real issue is whether Indian industry can sustain this higher growth over the long

run, as well as whether Industry could further accelerate growth to reach a double-digit

level, at least for some years when infrastructure bottlenecks have been substantially

reduced. In other words, we ask whether Indian industry has the necessary resources to

support this high growth target. Sustainability of growth hinges, among other things, on

robust saving and investment processes. It is well known that while the bulk of

domestic savings come from the household sector, the bulk of domestic investment is

undertaken by the private corporate and the public sectors [Table 11]. One feature of

the behaviour of the rate of saving is the steady decline of the saving rate in the public

sector since the mid 1970s. A slight reversal of this downward trend in the last few

years does not as yet appear to be permanent. On the other hand, the saving rates of the

private corporate sector as well as the household sector have both steadily increased the

former more vigorously.

41

Table 13: Average Rates of Savings and Investment (Per Cent of GDPMP)

Period Gross Domestic Saving Domestic Gross

Capital Formation

Households Corporate Public Total

1971 – 75 13.08 1.83 3.24 18.15 19.04

1976 – 80 16.81 1.71 4.97 23.50 22.93

1981 – 85 15.69 1.80 4.11 21.61 23.48

1986 – 90 18.25 2.29 2.65 23.19 25.91

1991 – 95 21.09 3.56 1.53 26.18 27.91

1996 – 99 21.75 4.51 2.33 28.59 30.26

Source: Pandit and Mohanty, 2001.

Further, while India has recognized the role of foreign direct investment (FDI), its

performance in attracting substantial capital inflows through this route still remains a

pipe dream. In the current global environment, China appears to be the only country

that will be able to sustain its record of mopping up huge FDI. Following China, this is

the most opportune time for India to gear its institutional and infrastructure systems to

realize at least $5 billion to $6 billion of FDI in the next few years in new projects, be it

in manufacturing or infrastructure areas. Further, India must create an atmosphere to

attract efficiency-seeking investments and increase the value added content of its

exports [Kumar and Siddharthan 1997]. It would be possible for India to do so by

increasing its resource advantage and undertaking administrative reforms that facilitate

a smooth flow of business and knowledge sharing.

There is large potential for improving the productivity of the industrial sector in general

and energy efficiency in particular. The recent experience has shown that technology

transfer through FDI has led to scope for improving productivity and energy efficiency.

42

Mukherjee et al (2001) point out that TFP of the industrial sector has increased from

0.75 per cent during the 1970s to 2.98 in the 1980s and to 3.07 in the 1990s. There is

large scope for improvement in the TFP levels. Similarly, with regard to the energy

there exists large potential to improve. As has been pointed out earlier, India is lagging

behind China in energy efficiency. If India is able to increase the output per unit of

energy consumption at the present Chinese level, there would be large saving potential

of crucial energy output and therefore it can be very useful in promoting sustained

industrial growth. Batra (2001) has pointed out that the oil intensity in the industrial

sector in India would decline from 0.023 [kg per 1000 rupees or 20 US $] in 1980 to

0.007 by 2045. Between 1980 and 2000, the oil intensity has declined from 0.023 to

0.013. Savings in energy consumption may put much less pressure on the energy

supply position. Moreover, if India implements strict environmental regulations, SPM

emissions and BOD loads will also be within the controlled emission norms for all

industrial units. Batra (2001) has pointed out that it will be possible for India to reduce

the current controlled emissions by at least 10 per cent, and by 2019 it is envisaged that

at least 20 per cent of the output will comply with these new norms. By 2047 the entire

production from all units will do so. It may, therefore, be argued that environment may

not pose serious problem in sustaining industrial growth. Adoption of energy efficient

technology in most industries may also lead to better environment.

Most recent estimates have shown that R & D expenditure in India has reached a level

of one per cent of the GDP. It is heartening to know that India has touched the one per

cent benchmark level after so many years of efforts. However, if it strives to make it to

at least 3 to 4 per cent of the GDP, and directing its’ R & D activities to complement

43

technology transfers, especially in the field of environmentally benign and energy

saving technology, it would go a long way to solve adverse effects on environment as

well as provide scope for greater international competitiveness. The state can also

encourage the establishment of joint R & D units by several enterprises in a given

industry to take advantage of economies of size in research [Siddharthan, 2001].

Last, but not the least, attention must also be focussed on using the openness to explore

foreign markets in order to sustain industrial growth. East Asian and the recent Chinese

experience have shown that there is great potential for the present day developing

countries to use trade to boost its industrialisation. Indeed, it needs to be pointed out

that much of the problems that the exporters in India face relate to delays in shipments

and corrupt bureaucracy. Infrastructure investments, especially to improve port

facilities would go a long way to boost Indian exports.

Summing up, these are trying times and to rise to the occasion, what we require is a

cohesive politico-techno- economic leadership response.

6. Summary and Conclusions

In examining the inter-relationship between industrialisation and environmental quality

and to provide a scenario for accelerating and sustaining higher growth rate for the

industrial sector in India, the study largely followed the analytical framework provided

by the Environmental Kuznets Curve [EKC]. However, since India moved from an

inward looking policy to a more open-economy approach since 1991, attempts were

also be made to examine the impact of economic reforms on this inter-relationship.

44

Further, the analysis presented in section 2 reveals that the acceleration in industrial

growth that India experienced during the last two decades has been largely contributed,

among others, by the nature and quantum of foreign direct investments [FDI] and the

resultant shifts in technological paradigm in which the industrial sector was operating

for a long time. The present study, therefore, has also taken into account the role of

technological factors in explaining the determinants of environmental quality.

This paper finds evidence to support an inverted U shaped relationship between

industrial value added per capita and carbon emissions. However, the relationship

turned out to be U shaped in the case of water pollution. Multiple regression analysis

indicates that, apart from industrial value added, trade, technology and economic

reforms also emerge significant in determining environmental quality.

Overall, the analysis points out a vital role for FDI in accelerating and sustaining

India’s industrial growth. Policy initiatives to attract efficiency seeking FDI, especially

in the manufacturing and the infrastructure sector would go a long way to place the

industrial sector on sustained growth path. Further, care also needs to be taken to

regulate the pattern of industrialisation, especially in terms of adapting energy saving

and environmentally benign technologies. Transparency in environmental management

system and capacity building in pollution control boards would also ensure that

environmental laws are effectively enforced. The sooner the State directs its’ policy

toward these pressing issues, the better would be the scenario for sustained industrial

growth.

45

References

Ahluwalia, Isher J. (1991): Productivity and Growth in Indian Manufacturing, Oxford

University Press, Delhi.

----------- (1985): Industrial Growth in India: Stagnation since the Mid-Sixties, Oxford

University Press, Delhi.

Basant, Rakesh (2000): “Corporate Response to Economic Reforms” in Nagesh Kumar

(ed.) Indian Economy under Reforms: An Assessment of Economic and Social

Impact, Bookwell, New Delhi, pp.45-92.

Batra, R. K. (2001) (ed.): Green India 2047: Directions, Innovations and Strategies for

Harnessing Action, Tata Energy Research Insitute, New Delhi.

Beckerman, W.B. (1972) Economic Development and the Environment : A False

Dilemma reprinted in Beckerman W.B. (1995) Growth, the Environment and the

Distribution of Incomes: Essays by a sceptical Optimist, Edward Elgar

Carson, R.T, Y.Jeon and D.R. Mccubbin (1997) ‘The relationship between air pollution

emissions and income : US data Environment and Development Economics 2

Chakraborty, D. and K. Mukhopadhyay (2000): “Economic Reforms and Energy

Consumption Changes in India – A Quantitative Analysis”, paper presented in a

Conference on Industrialization in a Reforming Economy: A Quantitative Assessment,

Delhi School of Economics, Delhi, December 20-22.

Chopra, Kanchan and Biswanath Goldar (2001): “Sustainable Development Framework

for India: The Case of Water Resources”, UNU/IAS, Project Report.

Cole, M.A., A.J. Rayner, and J.M. Bates (1997): The Environmental Kuznets Curve:

an Empirical Analysis.

Cropper, M. and C. Griffiiths (1994): “The Interaction of Population Growth and

Environmental Quality, Population Economics, no.84.

Das, Deb Kusum (2000): “Productivity Growth in Indian Manufacturing: Does Trade

Liberalization Matter?”, paper presented in Conference on “Industrialization in a

Reforming Economy-A Quantitative Assessment” at the Delhi School of Economics,

December 20-22.

Grossman, G. (1993): “Pollution and growth: what do we know?” in Goldin, I. and

Winters, L. (eds.) The Economics of Sustainable Development, Cambridge

University Press, Cambridge.

Grossman, G. and A. Krueger (1995): “Economic Growth and the Environment”,

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110 (2), pp.353-77.

46

-------------- (1996): “The Inverted-U: what does it mean?” Environment and

Development Economics, 1, pp.119-22.

Kaufman, R.K., B. Davidsdottir, S. Garnham and P. Pauly (1998): “The determinants of

atmospheric SO2 concentrations: reconsidering the environmental Kuznets curve”,

Ecological Economics, 25, pp.209-20.

Kelkar, Vijay and Rajeev Kumar (1990): “Industrial Growth in the Eighties: Emerging

Policy Issues”, Economic and Political Weekly, January 27.

Krishna, K. L. (1999): “Industrial Growth and Diversification” in Uma Kapila (ed.)

Indian Economy Since Independence, Academic Foundation, New Delhi.

Krishna and Mitra (1998): “Trade Liberalisation, Market Discipline and Productivity

Growth: New Evidence from India”, Journal of Development Economics, 56, pp.447-62.

Kumar Nagesh (2000): “Economic Reforms and Their Macro-Economic Impact”,

Economic and Political Weekly, March 4, pp.803-12.

---------- (1998): “Liberalisation and Changing Patterns of Foreign Direct Investments:

Has India’s Relative Attractiveness as a Host of FDI Improved?”, Economic and Political

Weekly, vol. 33, No.22, May 30.

------- and N. S. Siddharthan (1997): Technology, Market Structure and

Internationalization, Routledge, New York and London.

Levine, R. and S.J. Zervos (1993): “What have we learned about policy and growth from

cross-country regressions”, American Economic Review, 83, no.2, pp.426-30.

Lopez, R. (1994): “The Environment as a Factor of Production: The Effects of Economic

Growth and Trade Liberalisation”, Journal of Environmental Economics and

Management, 27, pp.163-84.

Mukherjee, Robin, Manabendu Chattopadhyay and Chiranjib Neogi (2001): Sustainable

Development Framework for India: Productivity, Human Development and Basic Needs

in India, UNU/IAS Project Report.

Murty, M.N. (1997): Natural Resources Accounting: Measuring Environmentally

Adjusted Value Added with Illustrations from Indian Industry, Reported submitted to

IDRC, Canada.

Nagaraj, R. (1991): “Industrial Growth: Further Evidence and Towards an Explanation

and Issues”, Economic and Political Weekly, October 13.

Narayanan, K. (1998): “Technology Acquisition, De-regulation and Competitiveness: A

Study of the Indian Automobile Sector”, Research Policy, vol.27, no.2, pp.215-28.

47

Palanivel, T. (2001): “Sustainable Development Framework for India”, paper presented in

the 3rd

IRSA International Conference, Jakarta, Indonesia, March 20-21.

Panayotou, Theodore (2000): “Economic Growth and the Environment”, Center for

International Development at Harvard University Working Paper No.56, , Environment

and Development Paper No.4, July.

------------- (1997): “Demystifying the Environmental Kuznets Curve: Turning a Black

Box into a Policy Tool”, Environment and Development Economics.

------------(1995): “Environmental Degradation at Different Stages of Economic

Developoment”, Beyond Rio (The Environmental Crisis and Sustainable Livelihood in the

Third World).

------------ (1993): “Empirical Tests and Policy Analysis of Environmental Degradation at

Different Stages of Economic Development”, Working Paper WP238 Technology and

Employment Programme, Geneva: International Labor Office.

Pandit, V. and Mohanty (2001): “Sustainable Development Framework for India: Macro

Economic Forecasting”, UNU/IAS Project.

Parikh, Kirit, Jyoti Parikh and Tata L. Raghu Ram (1999): “Air and Water Quality

Management: New Initiatives Needed”, in Kirit S. Parikh (ed.) India Development

Report 1999-2000, Oxford University Press, New Delhi., pp.85-96.

Planning Commission (1950): “First Five Year Plan”, Planning Commission, Government

of India, New Delhi.

Ratyanake, Ravi and Woo-Young Kim (1999): “Economic Growth and The Environment

in High-Performing East Asian Countries: Lessons from South Korea”, Department of

Economics, University of Auckland.

Ravallion, M, Mark Heil and Jyotsana Jalan (2000) ‘Carbon emission and income

inequality’, Oxford Economic Papers, 52.

Roberts, Mark J. and James R. Tybout (1996): Industrial Evolution in Developing

Countries, Oxford University Press, New York.

Seldon, T. and Song, D. (1994) ‘Environmental quality and development: is there a

Kuznets Curve for air pollution emissions?’ Journal of Environmental Economics and

Management, 27.

Shafik, N. and S. Bandyopadhyay (1992): Economic Growth and Environmental

Quality: Time Series and Cross-Country Evidence, World bank, Washington D.C.

Siddharthan, N.S. (2001) “Globalisation and the Budget: Urgent need for Institutional

Reforms”, Economic and Political Weekly, March 17, pp.889-92.

48

------------ (1999): ” WTO and the Globalisation of Enterprises”, Economic and Political

Weekly, vol. 34, no.21, pp.1287-91.

Simon J.J. (1981) The Ultimate Resource, Princeton University Press

---------- (1977) The Economics of Population Growth, Princeton University Press

Srivastava, Vivek (2000): “Impact of India’s Economic Reforms on Industrial

Productivity, Efficiency and Competitiveness” Part I, National Council of Applied

Economic Research, New Delhi.

Srinivasan, T. N. (1994): “Foreign Trade Policies and India’s Development”, in T.N.

Srinivasan (ed.) Agriculture and Trade in India and China, ICEG, San Fransisco.

Suri, V. and D. Chapman (1998): “Economic Growth, trade and energy: Implications for

the Environmental Kuznets Curve”, Ecological Economics, 25, pp.195-208.

TERI (1998): Looking Back to Think Ahead: Green India 2047, Teri, New Delhi.

Torras, M and Boyce, J.K (1998) ‘ Income, Inequality and Pollution: A Reassessment

of the Environmental Kuznets Curve’, Ecological Economics, 25

Unruh, G.C. and W.R. Moomaw (1998): “An Alternative Analysis of Apparent EKC-

type Transitions”, Ecological Economics, 25, pp.221-29.

USITC (1997): The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalisation: An Empirical Analysis,

USITC Publication 3069, USITC, Washington.

Vincent (1997): “Testing for Environmental Kuznets Curves within a developing country”,

Environment and Developmental Economics, Vol.2, part 4, pp.417-33.

Wheeler, David (2000): “Racing to the Bottom? Foreign Investment and Air Quality in

Developing Countries”, Development Research Group, World Bank, November.

49

APPENDIX 1

Definitions

Industry shares of emissions of organic water pollutants refer to emissions from

manufacturing activities as defined by two-digit divisions of the International Standard

Industrial Classification (ISIC), revision 2: stone, ceramics, and glass (36). Emissions of

organic water pollutants are measured by biochemical oxygen demand, which refers to

the amount of oxygen that bacteria in water will consume in breaking down waste. This

is a standard water-treatment test for the presence of organic pollutants.

Emissions of organic water pollutants are measured by biochemical oxygen demand

[BOD], which refers to the amount of oxygen that bacteria in water will consume in

breaking down waste. This is a standard water-treatment test for the presence of organic

pollutants.

Emissions per worker are total emissions of organic water pollutants divided by the

number of industrial workers. Organic water pollutants are measured by biochemical

oxygen demand, which refers to the amount of oxygen that bacteria in water will

consume in breaking down waste. This is a standard water-treatment test for the

presence of organic pollutants.

50

GDP per unit of energy use is the U.S. dollar estimate of real GDP (at 1995 prices) per

kilogram of oil equivalent of commercial energy use. Commercial energy use refers to

apparent consumption, which is equal to indigenous production plus imports and stock

changes, minus exports and fuels supplied to ships and aircraft engaged in international

transportation. For more information, see WDI table 3.8.

Commercial energy use refers to apparent consumption, which is equal to indigenous

production plus imports and stock changes, minus exports and fuels supplied to ships

and aircraft engaged in international transportation.

Carbon dioxide emissions from industrial processes are those stemming from the

burning of fossil fuels and the manufacture of cement. They include contributions to the

carbon dioxide produced during consumption of solid, liquid, and gas fuels and gas

flaring.

Value added in manufacturing is the sum of gross output less the value of intermediate

inputs used in production for industries classified in ISIC major division 3. Chemicals

comprise ISIC groups 351 and 352.

Trade in goods as a share of goods GDP is the sum of merchandise exports and imports

divided by the current value of GDP in U.S. dollars after subtracting value added in

services.

51

APPENDIX 2

EKC BETWEEN CARBON EMISSIONS AND INDUSTRIAL

VALUE ADDED PER CAPITA

APPENDIX 2 EKC BETWEEN CARBON EMISSIONS AND INDUSTRIAL VALUE

ADDED PER CAPITA

CO222KG$N

IVAPCN

110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40

2.7

2.6

2.5

2.4

2.3

2.2

2.1

Observed

Linear

Quadratic

52

APPENDIX 3

EKC BETWEEN BOD AND INDUSTRIAL VALUE ADDED PER

CAPITA

OWPPDN

IVAPCN

110 100 90 80 70 60 50 40

1700000

1600000

1500000

1400000

1300000

1200000

Observed

Linear

Quadratic


Recommended