+ All Categories
Home > Documents > INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN...

INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN...

Date post: 27-Jun-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 2 times
Download: 1 times
Share this document with a friend
34
1 INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski* ABSTRACT This research proposes and examines new measures for assessing the state of housing affordability inequality. We employ a large micro-level dataset by which we estimate and evaluate the time-varying housing affordability inequality in Israel over the period 1992-2011. Results show that our developed housing affordability inequality Gini coefficient has considerably increased in the past decade. Moreover, controlling for changes in net income inequality and macroeconomic conditions, housing affordability inequality is found to positively correlate with average housing prices (computed in net-income terms). Furthermore, our method allows for an examination of segmentation in housing affordability. We find that segmentation particularly prevails across the household head’s gender, family status, working status, and the number of income providers in the household. Research outcomes may direct decision-makers in designing policies aiming to reduce inequality and segmentation in housing affordability. Current Version: September 18, 2014 Key Words: Housing affordability; Inequality; Gini; Atkinson; Decomposition; Segmentation. JEL Codes: I32, R31, Z13 * Danny Ben-Shahar, Alrov Institute for Real Estate Research, Faculty of Management, Tel Aviv University, Tel Aviv, 6139001, Israel, email: [email protected]; and Jacob Warszawski, Faculty of Architecture and Town Planning, Technion – Israel Institute of Technology, Technion City, Haifa 32000, Israel; email: [email protected]. The authors thank Roni Golan, Ofer Huberman, and Doron Sayag for their invaluable assistance in generating the dataset and Shlomo Yitzhaki and seminar participants at the Technion and the 2014 International AREUEA meetings and the 2014 Israel Regional Science meetings for helpful comments.
Transcript
Page 1: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

1  

INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION

Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

ABSTRACT

This research proposes and examines new measures for assessing the state of housing affordability inequality. We employ a large micro-level dataset by which we estimate and evaluate the time-varying housing affordability inequality in Israel over the period 1992-2011. Results show that our developed housing affordability inequality Gini coefficient has considerably increased in the past decade. Moreover, controlling for changes in net income inequality and macroeconomic conditions, housing affordability inequality is found to positively correlate with average housing prices (computed in net-income terms). Furthermore, our method allows for an examination of segmentation in housing affordability. We find that segmentation particularly prevails across the household head’s gender, family status, working status, and the number of income providers in the household. Research outcomes may direct decision-makers in designing policies aiming to reduce inequality and segmentation in housing affordability.

Current Version: September 18, 2014

Key Words: Housing affordability; Inequality; Gini; Atkinson; Decomposition;

Segmentation.

JEL Codes: I32, R31, Z13

* Danny Ben-Shahar, Alrov Institute for Real Estate Research, Faculty of Management, Tel Aviv University, Tel Aviv, 6139001, Israel, email: [email protected]; and Jacob Warszawski, Faculty of Architecture and Town Planning, Technion – Israel Institute of Technology, Technion City, Haifa 32000, Israel; email: [email protected]. The authors thank Roni Golan, Ofer Huberman, and Doron Sayag for their invaluable assistance in generating the dataset and Shlomo Yitzhaki and seminar participants at the Technion and the 2014 International AREUEA meetings and the 2014 Israel Regional Science meetings for helpful comments.

Page 2: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

2  

1 INTRODUCTION

Housing is commonly the single largest expenditure item for most households, while

poor and near-poor families often devote half their income to housing (Quigley and

Raphael, 2004). It is not surprising, then, that the recent social protests occurring in

many Western cities around the world were largely incited by requests for a supply of

housing at affordable prices. This further explains the major interest that the general

public, policymakers, and regulators have in the discussion of housing affordability.

Various ratios are found in the literature for measuring housing affordability.

Among these are housing-loan-repayment-to-income, ongoing-housing-cost-to-

income, debt-to-housing-price, and housing-price-to-income (see, for example, Myer

and Engelhardt (1996), Thalmann (1999), Quigley and Raphael (2004), Brounen et al.

(2006), Stone (2006), Norris and Shiels (2007), Kim and Cho (2010), and Haffner and

Heylen (2011).1 Also, while the state of housing affordability is commonly explored

by focusing on an average and/or median figure, some studies further explore

affordability among populations stratified by socio-economic and demographic

characteristics such as income, poverty status, race, and ethnicity (see, for example,

Quigley and Raphael, 2004; Meen, 2011).

Surprisingly, however, to the best of our knowledge previous research has

never attempted to develop a measure that summarizes and examines the state of

housing affordability inequality.2 In this study, we assume this task by adapting a

widely accepted measure for estimating income equality to the context of housing

affordability—thereby developing a novel approach for assessing the state of housing

affordability inequality. Further, we empirically examine the factors that associate

                                                                                                                         1 Studies of housing affordability alternatively adopt the residual income approach, by which they examine how costs of basic goods net of housing costs associate with income (e.g., Whitehead, 1991; Stone, 2006; Kutty, 2005; & Chen et al., 2010). One of the controversies surrounding both the ratio and the residual income approaches concerns the threshold above which affordability may become increasingly subjective, as well as the definition and measurement of affordability below that threshold (Stone, 2006). 2 Matlack and Vigdor (2008) associate the rise in household income inequality with the deterioration of housing affordability for poor households by focusing on residual income and the rent-per-income ratio. Our study thus differs from that of Matlack and Vigdor (2008) on three central issues. First, we do not include subjective estimates of household basic needs for goods. Moreover, we consider the entire distribution of household housing affordability as opposed to focusing on the lower tail of the affordability distribution (the latter also associates with Whitehead, 1991; Stone, 2006; & Kutty, 2005). Finally, we develop a Gini measure that summarizes the level of housing affordability inequality.

Page 3: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

3  

with the time-varying dynamics of the derived housing affordability inequality

measure.

The Gini coefficient is commonly used in socio-economic literature to

estimate the state of income inequality (see, for example, Alderson and Nielsen, 2002;

Jäntti and Jenkins, 2010; Leigh, 2007; Frank, 2009).3 The methodology for estimating

the income Gini coefficient has been extended and implemented, however, to measure

the state of inequality in other areas such as education and human capital (Földvári

and Leeuwen, 2011), fossil resource consumption (Papathanasopoulou and Jackson,

2009), ecological entitlements (Ruitebeek, 1996), innovative activity states and R&D

spillovers (Audretsch and Feldman, 1996), firm size across industries and locations

(Jovanovic, 1982), and child achievements (Sastry and Pebley, 2010).

In the housing literature, the Gini coefficient approach has been applied by

Buckley and Gurenko (1997) to measure the effect of housing subsidies on living

space inequality; by Landis et al. (2002) to measure inequality in housing values,

housing costs, and monthly rent; and by Henley (2003) to study changes in the

distribution of housing wealth. Robinson et al. (1985) applied the Gini coefficient to

measure inequality in housing consumption. Also, studies by Tilly (2006) and

Matlack and Vigdor (2008) discuss the association between income inequality and

housing affordability challenges at the bottom of the income distribution. More

recently, Dewilde (2011), Dewilde and Lancee (2012), and Norris and Winston

(2012a,b) relate income inequality to homeownership and homeownership inequality.

In this study, we propose and compute a Gini coefficient of housing

affordability inequality based on the net income-to-housing price ratio. Intuitively, a

household net income-to-housing price ratio measures the share (portion) of the

housing unit that a household’s periodic net income could purchase, had it designated

its entire net income to the purchase of a housing unit identical to the one in which it

resides.4 Similar to the income Gini coefficient, our derived housing affordability

                                                                                                                         3 Recall that the Gini coefficient measures the area between the Lorenz curve and a hypothetical line of absolute equality, and is expressed as a percentage of the total area under this line. The Gini coefficient thus commonly ranges from zero (perfect equality) to one (complete inequality). For alternative measures of inequality as well as criticism and limitations of the Gini measure, see, for example, Cowell (2000). 4 Intuitively, a household housing price-to-net income ratio can be interpreted as the number of time periods it would take one to complete the purchase of a dwelling unit, had the household earmarked its entire net income to purchase a unit identical to the one in which it resides. Formulation of the Gini

 

Page 4: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

4  

inequality measure thus indicates on the micro-level degree of inequality in household

ability to purchase a housing unit—measured by the portion of the housing unit that a

household’s periodic net income could purchase.5 We further estimate the factors that

associate with our proposed housing affordability inequality measure and, following

Yitzhaki and Lerman (1991), Lambert and Aronson (1993), and Cowell (2000), we

examine segmentation in housing affordability by stratifying the household sample

according to various socio-demographic and locational characteristics.

The analysis is based on a large micro-level sample representative of all

households in Israel over the period 1992–2011. The data include 156,583

observations of household socio-economic, demographic, locational, and dwelling

unit characteristics (see further details in the Data section below).6 Results show that

housing affordability inequality, as assessed by our proposed housing affordability

Gini coefficient, exhibits a substantial increase over the past decade. This increase is

accompanied by a more moderate increase in equivalent net income Gini coefficient.

Empirical examination of the time-varying housing affordability inequality measure

reveals a highly significant positive correlation with average housing prices (in net

income terms), controlling for changes in net income inequality and macroeconomic

conditions. In addition, we find that while housing affordability has considerably

dropped for all socio-demographic segments over the 1992–2011 period, meaningful

segmentation in housing affordability particularly prevails across household head

gender, household family status, household head working status, household number of

income providers, and household geographical location. Finally, we show that our

                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                                           coefficient method prevents us, however, from applying it directly to the housing price-to-net income ratio. Instead, the net income-to-housing price ratio may both conform to the Gini methodology and be consistent with the literature that measures housing affordability. 5 Ultimately, in computing the housing affordability inequality, one might wish to focus on household “required” amount of housing services (given the household demographic characteristics) and thereby avoid potential “noise” in focusing on the actual housing unit that one occupies (i.e., omitting possible under- and over-consumption of housing). This exercise is, however, beyond the scope of this study. 6 The interest in studying housing affordability of homeowners is threefold. First, as homeowners comprise a dominant share of the housing market, examining their incomes and the values of dwelling units (thus studying their housing affordability status) indicates the likelihood of non-owners attaining ownership. Also, it particularly indicates the potential of homeowners to filter-up in the housing market. Finally, examining a time-series of housing affordability figures of homeowners allows policymakers to draw conclusions with respect to the time-varying level of housing prices in income terms (see, among others,  Fingleton, 2008; Fisher et al., 2009).

Page 5: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

5  

evidence on housing affordability inequality is robust to replacing the Gini coefficient

method with the Atkinson index approach.

The main contribution of the research is twofold. First, we propose and

implement a novel approach for assessing the state of housing affordability inequality

based on the Gini coefficient methodology. Moreover, by exploring the factors that

correlate with the level of inequality and specifying the population segments that

particularly contribute to the level of inequality, we provide decision makers

regulating housing prices and housing welfare with a toolbox and practical evidence

that can motivate the design of effective policies aimed at promoting housing

affordability where it is especially needed.

The organization of the paper is as follows. The next section describes the

methodology, while Section 3 presents the data, including variable definitions and

related summary statistics. Section 4 presents related statistical results on the

correlation between housing affordability inequality and average housing prices, and

Section 5 assesses the robustness of the outcomes to the Gini coefficient specification.

Section 6 examines socio-demographic segmentation in housing affordability, and,

finally, Section 7 provides a summary and concluding remarks.

2 METHODOLOGY

Given the individual household net income variable, we first compute the quarterly

net income Gini coefficient (denoted by GW) for the period 1992–2011. We then

compute the quarterly housing affordability Gini coefficient (GH) based on household

i net income-to-housing price ratio (Wi/Pi). In deriving the housing affordability Gini

coefficient, we adapt the method of computing the income Gini coefficient by

substituting the individual net income variable with the individual net income-to-

housing price ratio. Inequality in the net income-to-housing price variable essentially

indicates inequality in the share of a household’s own housing unit that the individual

household can afford, given its individual periodic net income.7

                                                                                                                         7 Formally, the housing affordability Gini coefficient is then computed as follows: , where and The weighted average of all surveyed household housing affordability is estimated with: , where is the observation weight of household (percentage weight), is the number of members in household , is household i’s net income-to-housing price ratio, and is the number of households surveyed (in a given quarter). For more on the Gini coefficient computation, see Araar and Duclos (2013).

Page 6: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

6  

Following the derived time-series of GW and GH coefficients, we can write

(1)

𝐺𝐻𝑡 =  𝛼! + 𝛼!×𝐺𝑊𝑡 + 𝛼!× 𝑃𝑊 𝑡

+ 𝛼!×𝐶𝑂𝑁𝑇𝑅𝑂𝐿𝑆𝑡 + 𝑢𝑡,

where t is a time period index (in quarters), GW and GH are net income and housing

affordability Gini coefficients, respectively, P/W is the average housing price-to-net

income ratio (across all households at time t), CONTROLS is a matrix of

macroeconomic variables, including gross domestic product (GDP), housing

construction ends (HE), housing construction starts (HS), unemployment rate (UR),

long-term (20–25-year) price-level-adjusted mortgage rate (MR), short-term (1-year)

nominal bond rate (BR), construction price index (CI), and new Israeli sheqel-to-

dollar exchange rate (EX). Also, 𝛼! − 𝛼! are parameters, 𝛼! is a vector of parameters,

and u is a random disturbance term.

According to equation (1), time-varying inequality of housing affordability not

only associates with net-income inequality, but also may correlate with the average

housing price (in net income terms, i.e., average housing price-to-net income ratio) as

well as changes in macroeconomic indicators. (For more on the correlation between

macroeconomic indicators and housing prices see, for example, Adams and Füss,

2010; Kim and Cho, 2010; Schnure, 2005; Ortalo-Magné and Rady, 2006; Case and

Quigley, 2008; Sutton, 2002; and Poterba, 1984. On the correlation between

macroeconomic indicators and income inequality, see, for example, Achdut, 1996;

Blejer and Guerrero, 1990; Milanovic, 2002; Heshmati, 2004; and Jäntti and Jenkins,

2010. On the correlation between macroeconomic indicators and housing affordability

see, for example, Malpezzi, 1999; Mostafa et al., 2006; and Ben-Shahar and

Warszawski, 2011.)

In the last part of our study, we stratify the household sample by socio-

demographic and locational characteristics. We then decompose the derived housing

affordability Gini coefficient (GH) into within-segment, between-segment, and overlap

components of inequality. In other words, for a given stratification, we compute (a)

the weighted-average of the housing affordability Gini coefficient by segments (the

within-segment component); (b) the weighted-average Gini coefficient if   each

household in a segment had maintained the segment average housing affordability

level (the between-segment component); and (c) the sample Gini coefficient net of the

within- and between-segments, that is, the residual part (the overlap component)—

Page 7: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

7  

following Yitzhaki (1994), the overlap component is a measure for segmentation in

the population. (For a complete discussion on the properties of the overlap component,

see Frick et al., 2006.)

3 DATA

Data for this study come from three sources. First, 156,583 micro-level observations

on individual household socio-economic, demographic, and dwelling unit

characteristics are provided by the Household Income and Expenditure Surveys

conducted by the Israel Central Bureau of Statistics for the years 1992–2011. Each

quarterly independent cross-section sample has between 1,041 and 2,921 observations

and is representative of all households in Israel (see Central Bureau of Statistics,

1993–2012). Table 1 shows the number of cross-sectional observations per quarter for

the 1992–2011 period. Table 2 presents the household socio-demographic and

dwelling unit characteristics in the dataset and the 1992 and 2011 shares of each

characteristic within the sample. Socio-demographic characteristics include family

status, the household head’s gender, the number of members in the household, the

household head’s years of education, last formal education, and age, the number of

household income providers, and the household head’s working status, occupation,

and industry. Dwelling unit characteristics include the number of rooms and location.

Another source of data is all housing transactions in Israel for the period

1992–2011, recorded by the Israel Tax Authority—a total of 729,505 observations of

transacted dwelling unit prices and attributes. Based on this data, we generate a

quality-adjusted price for the dwelling unit of each household in the Household

Income and Expenditure Surveys. (A detailed description of the procedure by which

we produce the quality-adjusted price that is “matched” to each household is provided

in the appendix.)

A final source of data includes macroeconomic indicators for the period 1992–

2011 obtained from the Bank of Israel and the Israel Central Bureau of Statistics.

These include the Gross Domestic Product in dollars (GDP), number of housing

construction ends (HE), change in the unemployment rate (ΔUR), change in the

mortgage rate (ΔMR), change in the rate of change in the construction index (ΔCI),

Page 8: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

8  

change in the one-year bond rate (ΔBR), change in the new Israeli sheqel-to-dollar

exchange rate (ΔEX), and change in the number of housing construction starts (ΔHS).8

Table 3 presents summary statistics for household net income, net income-to-

housing price ratio, housing price-to-net income ratio, and the macroeconomic

variables. It follows that the mean monthly net income was 2,053 dollars, with a

standard deviation equal to 554 dollars (1USD ≈ 4 New Israeli Sheqels). The mean

housing price-to-net income and net income-to-housing price were about 112 and

0.0144, respectively, with standard deviations equal to 10.97 and 0.00134,

respectively. (See Table 3 for summary statistics of the macroeconomic variables.)

Exhibit 1 displays the sample quarterly average and deciles of the housing

price-to-net-income ratio (P/W) over the period 1992–2011.9 Interestingly, the

average ratio approximately overlaps the seventh decile (note that a higher decile

associates with a greater housing price-to-net income ratio, i.e, a lower level of

affordability). Moreover, while the top decile of the housing price-to-net income

ratios (10% of the population with greatest affordability) ranges from 31 to 46 over

the examined period, the lowest decile (lowest 10%) experiences equivalent figures in

the 181–286 range. Namely, had households earmarked their entire net income for

purchase of a housing unit, the top (bottom) housing affordability decile would have

needed 31-46 (181–286) months to complete the purchase. At the same time, the

housing price-to-net income ratio of the third, fifth, and seventh deciles ranges in the

48–71, 69–100, and 99–145 figures, respectively.

Exhibit 2 shows the time-varying series of the sample quarterly average

housing price-to-net income ratio over the period 1992–2011. Interestingly, the

average price-to-net income ratio not only exhibits a positive slope over the examined

period (as seen by the linearized trend); in addition, it experiences a sizable shift from

the 100–110 levels in the 2000–2007 years to the 115–135 levels in the post-2007

period. Note in particular the sharp increase from a level of 98 in 2008Q1 to 137 in

                                                                                                                         8 The unit root hypothesis could not statistically be rejected for the time-series of the unemployment rate (UR), mortgage rate (MR), rate of change in the construction index (CI), the one-year bond rate (BR), the new Israeli sheqel-to-dollar exchange rate (EX), and the number of housing construction starts (HS). We thus specified these non-stationary control variables in first difference terms (difference between their time t and t-1 values) for which the unit root hypothesis was statistically rejected. 9  In the derivation of the average housing price-to-net income ratio, the lowest and highest 0.5 percent of the observations were omitted to mitigate the effect of outliers. Results, however, are robust to the inclusion of these outliers (available by request).

Page 9: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

9  

2011Q4. In the next section, we examine the relationship between this phenomenon

and the attained level of inequality in housing affordability.

4 RESULTS

Based on the series of individual household net income W and net income-to-housing

price ratio W/P, we first compute the annual net income Gini and housing

affordability Gini coefficients, GW and GH respectively, for the period 1992–2011 (see

Table 4 for summary statistics of GW and GH). Exhibit 3 shows the computed housing

affordability and net income Gini coefficients for the years 1992–2011. Note that the

level of housing affordability inequality has not only experienced an upward trend

since the year 2000, peaking in 2008 with a Gini coefficient of 0.352, but also that its

increase has exceeded that of the net income Gini coefficient in the post-2000 decade.

Columns (1) and (2) in Table 5 present the outcomes from the estimation of

equation (1) (full model and stepwise regression, respectively). Results show that the

housing affordability Gini coefficient is, as expected, positively correlated to a high

degree with the net income Gini.10 Interestingly, however, the housing affordability

Gini is also positively correlated with average housing price-to-net income ratio at the

5% significance level (t-value equals 2.36). As the standard deviation of the housing

affordability Gini coefficient equals 0.0174 (see Table 4), the estimated coefficient on

the housing price-to-net income variable indicates that a ten-unit increase in the

housing price-to-net-income ratio associates with a rise in the housing affordability

Gini coefficient equal to just over 10% of its standard deviation. Put differently, the

sharp rise in the average price-to-net income ratio over the 2008–2011 period (from

98 in 2008Q1 to 137 in 2011Q4—see, once again, Exhibit 3) associates with an

increase in housing affordability Gini coefficient equal to 40% of its standard

deviation.11 Finally, concerning the control variables, it follows that the housing

affordability Gini negatively correlates with the number of housing construction ends                                                                                                                          

10 Also note that the computed Pearson correlation between W and W/P is equal to 0.65 and between W and P is equal to 0.45. 11 Note that, while the derived Gini coefficient is based on the individual household net-income and housing price, it does not immediately follow that the level of the inequality measure should correlate (either positively and or negatively) with the average housing price-to-net income ratio. Interestingly, however, as described above, our findings indicate that, when average housing price-to-net income rises, households at the lower tail of the housing affordability distribution are adversely affected at a greater degree than those at the higher tail of the distribution.

Page 10: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

10  

and the change in the new Israeli sheqel-to-dollar exchange rate at the 1% and 10%

significance levels, respectively, and positively correlates with the level of gross

domestic product with a five-period lag at the 1% significance level.12

5 ROBUSTNESS TEST: HOUSING AFFORDABILITY ATKINSON INDEX

In this section we assess the robustness of our findings by generating and estimating

an alternative to the housing affordability Gini coefficient. Specifically, we derive a

housing affordability Atkinson index and re-estimate the model in (1).

Recall that the Atkinson index had originally been developed to measure

income inequality (see Atkinson, 1970), allowing for varying levels of inequality

intolerance. It was later adapted to measure inequality of, for example, ecological

entitlements (Ruitebeek, 1996) and the geographical distribution of general

practitioners (Gravelle and Sutton, 2001). Also, Robinson et al. (1985) applied the

Atkinson index method to measure inequality in housing consumption.13

Similar to our derived housing affordability Gini coefficient, we derive an

Atkinson index of housing affordability inequality—AH(ε), where ε is an inequality

aversion parameter—based on the net income-to-housing price ratio.14 In the context

of housing affordability, the Atkinson index can be interpreted as the share of

individual housing affordability (in W/P terms) that may be disposed so as to generate

the same level of social welfare that could be achieved if the mean level of W/P were

to be equally distributed among all households.15

                                                                                                                         12 While other lags in the level of Gross Domestic Product were found to correlate with the housing affordability Gini coefficient, the highest statistical significance was obtained for the five-period lag reported above. Results obtained for other lags are available from the authors upon request. Also, based on macro-level data, Ben-Shahar and Warszawski (2011) find a negative correlation between the average housing price-to-net income ratio and lagged unemployment rate (also see Jäntti and Jenkins, 2010). 13 As noted by Robinson et al. (1985), the Atkinson index “is particularly important in the case of a commodity such as housing which is widely regarded as a ‘necessity’ and, as such, the plight of those at the bottom end of the distribution is likely to be of special concern” (p. 251). 14 Formally, the housing affordability Atkinson index is computed as follows: , where and and where ε is an inequality-aversion parameter. All other variables are as described above. For more on the Atkinson index computation, see Araar and Duclos (2013). 15 Recall that according to Yitzhaki (1983), we have , where is the average income, is the equally-distributed-equivalent income, and is the Atkinson index as a function of the level of inequality-aversion parameter, ε.

Page 11: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

11  

In accordance with equation (1), we then estimate

(2)

𝐴𝐻𝑡 =  𝛽! + 𝛽!×𝐴𝑊𝑡 + 𝛽!×𝑃𝑊 𝑡

+ 𝛽!×𝐶𝑂𝑁𝑇𝑅𝑂𝐿𝑆𝑡 + 𝑣𝑡,

where t once again denotes a time-period index (in quarters), 𝐴𝐻 and 𝐴𝑊 are the

derived housing affordability and net income Atkinson indices, respectively, for

ε=0.5,16 𝛽! − 𝛽! are estimated parameters, 𝛽! is a vector of parameters,  𝑣 is a random

disturbance term, and the remaining variables are as described above.

Similar to equation (1), in equation (2) we focus on estimating the correlation

between housing affordability inequality (this time estimated by the housing

affordability Atkinson index) and the average housing price (in net income terms).

Again, we control for changes in net income inequality and time-varying

macroeconomic conditions.

Outcomes are robust to the Atkinson specification. In particular, Exhibit 4

shows the computed housing affordability and net income Atkinson indices over the

period 1992–2011. A couple of points are worth noting. First, while in 2000Q4 the

housing affordability Atkinson index equaled 0.074, its level rose by about 27% to

equal 0.094 in 2011Q4. Following Atkinson (1970), the latter implies that all

households could have disposed 7.4% and 9.4% of the total net income-to-housing

price W/P in 2000Q4 and 2011Q4, respectively, so as to generate the same level of

social welfare that could have been achieved if the mean level of W/P had been

equally distributed among all households (see, for example, Yitzhaki, 1983).

Moreover, the pattern previously observed with the Gini coefficient now repeats with

the Atkinson index. That is, the sharp increase in the housing affordability Atkinson

index in the last decade led it to generally exceed the equivalent increase in the level

of the net income Atkinson index.

Further, columns (3) and (4) in Table 5 present the outcomes from the

estimation of equation (2) (full model and stepwise regression, respectively). Results

indicate that the housing affordability Atkinson index is positively correlated not only

with the net income Atkinson index but also with average housing price (in net

income terms)—both at the 1% significance level. Specifically, a ten-unit change in

                                                                                                                         16  Empirical studies commonly focus on the inequality-aversion parameter ε ranging between 0.5 and 2.5 (e.g., Biewen and Jenkins, 2006). Consistent with the literature, we compute AH for ε=0.5. Unreported results are qualitatively robust to increasing the level of ε.  

Page 12: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

12  

the average housing price-to-net income ratio corresponds to a change in the housing

affordability Atkinson index equal to about 21% of its standard deviation. Results

further show that the housing affordability Atkinson index negatively correlates with

the number of housing construction ends and the change in the new Israeli sheqel-to-

dollar exchange rate at the 1% and 10% significance levels, respectively, and

positively correlates with gross domestic product (with a five-period lag) at the 1%

significance level.

6 SEGMENTATION IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY

We stratify the household sample by socio-demographic characteristics and

decompose the derived housing affordability Gini coefficient into within-segment,

between-segment, and overlap components (see Yitzhaki and Lerman, 1991; Lambert

and Aronson, 1993; Cowell, 2000). A relatively low overlap component in the

decomposition of the Gini coefficient implies a relatively heterogeneous population

(i.e., high level of segmentation) across the stratified characteristic. Table 6 shows the

decomposed components of the housing affordability Gini coefficient by socio-

demographic segments and the computed housing affordability Gini coefficient and

the average housing price-to-net income ratio by segments for the years 1992 and

2011.17

It follows that in 1992 and 2011, a relatively high level of segmentation (i.e.,

low overlap component) persists for the household head gender stratification,18

household family status (divides into married, divorced, widowed, single, and living

separately), the household head working status (divides into wage-employee, self-

employed, and non-worker), the number of household providers (divides into zero-,

one-, two-, three-, and four-provider segments), and the geographical region where

the household resides (divides into nine regions as determined by the Israel Central

Bureau of Statistics—see regions in Table 2).

It also follows that male-headed households experience a sharp increase in the

average housing price-to-net income ratio during the examined period (from 79 in

                                                                                                                         17 On social inequality in the context of homeownership in Israel, see, for example, Lewin-Epstein et al. (2004). 18 Household head gender is generally determined by the gender of the person who is the main income provider in the household. See Israel Central Bureau of Statistics (2013a) for further details.

Page 13: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

13  

1992 to 116 in 2011) that is accompanied by an increasing housing affordability Gini

coefficient (from 0.30 to 0.34, respectively). Also, the traditional discrepancy in the

price-to-net income ratio between male- and female-headed households maintains

over the examined period, where female-headed household figures rise from 125 in

1992 to 139 in 2011.19

While experiencing an increased average housing price-to-net income ratio

from 77 to 116 over the 1992–2011 period, married households capture the top spot in

housing affordability among the family status segments. The divorced segment

experiences increasing levels of inequality and average housing price-to-net income

ratio (from 0.32 and 113, respectively, in 1992, to 0.34 and 137, respectively, in

2011).20 The share of single household heads in the population almost doubles from

7% to over 13% over the 1992–2011 period (see Table 2), while both its housing

affordability Gini and average housing price-to-net income ratio sharply increase

(from 0.31 to 0.37 and from 100 to 206, respectively).

With respect to household head working status, average housing price-to-net

income rises over the 1992–2011 period from 65 to 106 for wage employees, from 77

to 119 for the self-employed, and from 148 to 221 for non-workers. These are coupled

with an increased housing affordability Gini coefficient, most notably for the non-

worker segment rising from 0.31 in 1992 to 0.37 in 2011, while the wage-employee

and self-employed segments increase from 0.26 and 0.29 to 0.32 and 0.34,

respectively, during that period.

Note the considerable difference among the zero-, one-, and two or more

provider segments. The two or more provider subgroup maintains not only the lowest

level of average housing price-to-net income ratio (at 37–54 and 61–86 in 1992 and

2011, respectively), but also a relatively low level of housing affordability inequality

                                                                                                                         19 Compare to the findings of Laux and Cook (1994), and Saegert and Clark (2006), who show that female-headed households in the U.S. exhibit both lower levels of housing affordability and greater income inequality (also see Edwards, 2001). 20 Weiss (1984) and others find that income drops considerably after marital dissolution and maintains its low level some five years following the dissolution, while expenditures at the same time maintain their pre-dissolution levels. For more on single-parent household housing consumption see, for example, Saegert and Clark (2006).

Page 14: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

14  

(Gini coefficient of 0.25–0.28 in 2011).21 In contrast, as expected, the no-provider

household segment experiences the greatest levels of both average housing price-to-

net income ratio and housing affordability inequality, reaching figures of 221 and

0.37, respectively, in 2011. Correspondingly, in 2011, the one-provider segment

attains an average price-to-net income ratio of 150 and a housing affordability Gini of

0.33.

Interestingly, inequality in housing affordability among geographical regions

has dramatically increased over the 1992–2001 period (the overlap component in the

decomposition of the Gini coefficient has decreased from 53% to 38% over this

twenty-year period). While in 2011 the North and Krayot regions maintain the

greatest level of affordability with an average housing price-to-net income ratio equal

to 73 and 69, respectively (up from 58 and 67, respectively, in 1992), Jerusalem and

Tel Aviv sit at the bottom of the list with an average ratio equal to 206 and 182 (up

from 108 and 111, respectively, in 1992). The sharp increase in the average housing

price-to-net income ratio in Jerusalem and Tel Aviv (as compared to North and

Krayot) can be attributed, among other possible reasons, to the sharp rise in real estate

prices in those specific regions since 2007.22 Jerusalem and Tel Aviv further lead all

regions in the level of inequality with a Gini coefficient of 0.32 in 2011.

Several final points are worth noting. First, a relatively low level of

segmentation is found for the number of members in household and the household

head’s age, years of education, last formal education, occupation, and industry.

Further, for some of these household stratifications, we find that segmentation has

somewhat diminished (the overlap component has increased) during the 1992–2011

period (the exceptions are the household head years of education, last formal

education, and the number of members in household, whose overlap component

experienced a marginal decline). These trends are nonetheless generally accompanied

by a sharp increase in segments’ average housing price-to-net income ratio. Finally, it

should be stressed that the segmentation in affordability analysis proposed here allows

                                                                                                                         21 This outcome is consistent with the assertion of Cancian and Reed (1998), Heathcote et al. (2010), and others that the net effect of the increased participation of females in the labor force reduces overall inequality. 22 Specifically, while average housing prices increased in the Krayot and North regions by 40% and 57%, respectively, over the period 2006–2011, in Tel Aviv and Jerusalem they increased by 80% and 61%, respectively (Israel Central Bureau of Statistics, 2006–2012).

Page 15: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

15  

for the identification of population subgroups (according to socio-demographic and

locational characteristics) that particularly “contribute” to the level of housing

affordability inequality and may thus provide policymakers with high-resolution

information on where policy measures that promote equal housing affordability

opportunities are to be implemented.

7 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS

Housing is commonly the single largest expenditure item for most households and

generally demands more than half the income of poor and near-poor families. In this

study, we develop measures (for the first time, to the best of our knowledge) by which

the state of housing affordability inequality could be summarized and examined.

Particularly, we adapt the Gini coefficient and Atkinson index methods for

estimating income inequality to the context of housing affordability and estimate the

factors that associate with the time-varying housing affordability inequality measures

in Israel over the period 1992–2011.

Results show that the time-varying household housing affordability Gini

coefficient and Atkinson index are positively correlated with average housing price

(in net income terms), controlling for changes in net income inequality and

macroeconomic conditions. Further, we detect considerable segmentation in housing

affordability for household head gender, household family status, household head

working status, number of household providers, and household geographical

residence.

As the state of housing affordability is a constant source of political interest,

our developed method for estimating housing affordability inequality and the

outcomes on its positive correlation with average housing prices and, further, its

capacity to identify socio-demographic segmentation in housing affordability may

assist policymakers in designing policies that would increase housing affordability

where it is particularly needed, thereby effectively reducing inequality and

segmentation in housing affordability.

Several major tasks face future researchers in this area. Methodologically, the

estimation of housing affordability potentially suffers from a bias caused by

household over- and under- consumption of housing. Refined measures of housing

affordability inequality may attempt to address this possible bias. Further, while there

exist various approaches for computing housing affordability, none of the prevailing

Page 16: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

16  

methods points to a formally derived threshold (benchmark) below which a household

is categorized as sub-affordable. Finally, empirically, a panel analysis of housing

affordability Gini coefficient across different economies may shed light on the

regimes and specific policies that are most effective in promoting housing

affordability equality.

Page 17: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

17  

References Achdut, L. (1996). Income inequality, income composition and macroeconomic trends: Israel, 1979–93. Economica, S1–S27. Adams, Z., & Füss, R. (2010). Macroeconomic determinants of international housing markets. Journal of Housing Economics, 19(1), 38–50. Alderson, A. S., and Nielsen, F. (2002). Globalization and the great U-turn: Income inequality trends in 16 OECD countries. American Journal of Sociology, 107(5), 1244–1299. Araar, A., and Duclos, J.Y. (2013). DASP: Distributive Analysis Stata Package User Manual. Université Laval PEP, CIRPÉE and World Bank. http://dasp.ecn.ulaval.ca/modules/DASP_V2.3/DASP_MANUAL_V2.3.pdf Audretsch, D. B., and Feldman, M. P. (1996). R&D spillovers and the geography of innovation and production. American Economic Review, 86(3), 630–640. Ben-Shahar, D., and Warszawski, J. (2011). Partly cloudy to clear: The Israeli economy and the local housing market under the storm of the world financial crisis. In Bardhan, A., Edelstein, R., and Kroll, C. (Eds.), Global housing markets: Crises, policies, and institutions. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley. Biewen, M., and Jenkins, S. P. (2006). Variance estimation for generalized entropy and Atkinson inequality indices: The complex survey data case. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 68(3), 371–383. Blejer, M. I., and Guerrero, I. (1990). The impact of macroeconomic policies on income distribution: an empirical study of the Philippines. Review of Economics and Statistics, 414–423. Bogdon, A. S., and Can, A. (1997). Indicators of local housing affordability: Comparative and spatial approaches. Real Estate Economics, 25(1), 43–80. Buckley, R. M., and Gurenko, E. N. (1997). Housing and income distribution in Russia: Zhivago’s legacy. World Bank Research Observer, 12(1), 19–32. Cancian, M., and Reed, D. (1998). Assessing the effects of wives’ earnings on family income inequality. Review of Economics and Statistics, 80(1), 73–79. Case, K. E., and Quigley, J. M. (2008). How housing booms unwind: Income effects, wealth effects, and feedbacks through financial markets. International Journal of Housing Policy, 8(2), 161–180. Central Bureau of Statistics (1993–2012). Statistical Abstract of Israel, publication number 42–63, Jerusalem, Israel. Central Bureau of Statistics (2008). Peripherality index of local authorities 2004—New development. Press Release, Jerusalem, Israel.

Page 18: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

18  

Central Bureau of Statistics (2013a). Income survey 2011, publication number 1524, Jerusalem, Israel. Central Bureau of Statistics (2013b). Characterization and classification of geographical units by the socio-economic level of the population 2008. Publication number 1530, Jerusalem, Israel. Chen, J., Hao, Q., & Stephens, M. (2010). Assessing housing affordability in post-reform China: A case study of Shanghai. Housing Studies, 25(6), 877–901. Cowell, F. A. (2000). Measurement of inequality. In Atkinson, A. B., and Bourguignon, F. (Eds.), Handbook of income distribution. Amsterdam & New York: Elsevier. Cowell, F. A. (2009). Measuring inequality. Part of the series LSE Perspectives in Economic Analysis, published by Oxford University Press. Dewilde, C. (2011). The interplay between economic inequality trends and housing regime changes in advanced welfare democracies: A new research agenda. Amsterdam, AIAS, GINI Discussion paper 18. Dewilde, C., and Lancee, B. (2012). Income inequality and access to housing in Europe: A new research agenda. Amsterdam, AIAS, GINI Discussion paper 32. Edwards, M. E. (2001). Home ownership, affordability, and mothers’ changing work and family roles. Social Science Quarterly, 82(2), 369–383. Fingleton, B. (2008). Housing supply, housing demand, and affordability. Urban Studies, 45(8), 1545–1563. Fisher, L. M., Pollakowski, H. O., and Zabel, J. (2009). Amenity-­‐based housing affordability indexes. Real Estate Economics, 37(4), 705–746. Földvári, P., and van Leeuwen, B. (2011). Should less inequality in education lead to a more equal income distribution? Education Economics, 19(5), 537–554. Frank, M. W. (2009). Inequality and growth in the United States: Evidence from a new state-­‐level panel of income inequality measures. Economic Inquiry, 47(1), 55–68. Frick, J. R., Goebel, J., Schechtman, E., Wagner, G. G., and Yitzhaki, S. (2006). Using analysis of Gini (ANOGI) for detecting whether two subsamples represent the same universe the German Socio-Economic Panel Study (SOEP) experience. Sociological Methods & Research, 34(4), 427–468.  Gravelle, H., and Sutton, M. (2001). Inequality in the geographical distribution of general practitioners in England and Wales 1974–1995. Journal of Health Services Research & Policy, 6(1), 6–13. Heathcote, J., Perri, F., and Violante, G. L. (2010). Unequal we stand: An empirical analysis of economic inequality in the United States, 1967–2006. Review of Economic

Page 19: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

19  

Dynamics, 13(1), 15–51. Henley, A. (2003). Changes in the distribution of housing wealth in Great Britain, 1985-­‐91. Economica, 65(259), 363–380. Heshmati, A. (2004). Regional income inequality in selected large countries (No. 1307). IZA Discussion paper series. Jäntti, M., and Jenkins, S. P. (2010). The impact of macroeconomic conditions on income inequality. Journal of Economic Inequality, 8(2), 221–240. Jovanovic, B. (1982). Selection and the evolution of industry. Econometrica, 649–670. Kim, K., and Cho, M. (2010). Structural changes, housing price dynamics and housing affordability in Korea. Housing Studies, 25(6), 839–856. Kutty, N. K. (2005). A new measure of housing affordability: Estimates and analytical results. Housing Policy Debate, 16(1), 113–142. Lambert, P. J., and Aronson, J. R. (1993). Inequality decomposition analysis and the Gini coefficient revisited. Economic Journal, 103(420), 1221–1227. Landis, J. D., Elmer, V., and Zook, M. (2002). New economy housing markets: Fast and furious—but different? Housing Policy Debate, 13(2), 233–274. Laux, S. C., and Cook, C. C. (1994). Female-headed households in nonmetropolitan areas: Housing and demographic characteristics. Journal of Family and Economic Issues, 15(4), 301–316. Leigh, A. (2007). How closely do top income shares track other measures of inequality? Economic Journal, 117(524), F619–F633. Lerman, R. I., and Yitzhaki, S. (1989). Improving the accuracy of estimates of Gini coefficients. Journal of Econometrics, 42(1), 43–47. Lewin-Epstein, N., Adler, I., and Semyonov, M. (2004). Home ownership and social inequality in Israel. In Kurz and Blossfeld (Eds.), Home ownership and social inequality in comparative perspective, Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press. Malpezzi, S. (1999). A simple error correction model of house prices. Journal of Housing Economics, 8, 27–62. Matlack, J. L., and Vigdor, J. L. (2008). Do rising tides lift all prices? Income inequality and housing affordability. Journal of Housing Economics, 17(3), 212–224. Meen, G. (2011). A long-run model of housing affordability. Housing Studies, 26(7–8), 1081–1103.

Page 20: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

20  

Milanovic, B. (2002). True world income distribution, 1988 and 1993: First calculation based on household surveys alone. Economic Journal, 112(476), 51–92. Mostafa, A., Wong, F. K., & Hui, C. M. (2006). Relationship between housing affordability and economic development in mainland China—Case of Shanghai. Journal of Urban Planning and Development, 132(1), 62–70. Norris, M., and Winston, N. (2012a). Home ownership and income inequalities in Western Europe: Access, affordability and quality. Amsterdam, AIAS, GINI Discussion Paper 41. Norris, M., and Winston, N. (2012b). Home-ownership, housing regimes and income inequalities in Western Europe. Amsterdam, AIAS, GINI Discussion Paper 42. Ortalo-Magné, F., and and Rady, S. (2006). Housing market dynamics: On the contribution of income shocks and credit constraints. Review of Economic Studies, 73, 459–485. Papathanasopoulou, E., and Jackson, T. (2009). Measuring fossil resource inequality—A case study for the UK between 1968 and 2000. Ecological Economics, 68(4), 1213–1225. Poterba, J. M. (1984). Tax subsidies to owner-occupied housing: An asset market approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 99(4), 729–752. Quigley, J. M., and Raphael, S. (2004). Is housing unaffordable? Why isn’t it more affordable? The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 18(1), 191–214. Robinson, R., O’Sullivan, T., and Le Grand, J. (1985). Inequality and housing. Urban Studies, 22(3), 249–256. Ruitenbeek, H. J. (1996). Distribution of ecological entitlements: Implications for economic security and population movement. Ecological Economics, 17(1), 49–64. Saegert, S., and Clark, H. (2006). Opening doors: What a right for housing means for women. In Bratt, Stone, and Hartman (Eds.), A right to housing: Foundation for a new social agenda. Philadelphia, PA: Temple University Press. Sastry, N., and Pebley, R. (2010) Family and neighborhood sources of socioeconomic inequality in children’s achievement. Demography, 47(3), 777–800. Sayag, D. (2012). Measuring the local house price movements and estimating the price elasticity. Israel Economic Review, 10(1), 39–94 Schnure, C. (2005). Boom-bust cycles in housing: The changing role of financial structure. International Monetary Fund. Stone, M. E. (2006). Housing affordability: One-third of a nation shelter-poor. In Bratt, Stone, and Hartman (Eds.), A right to housing: Foundation for a new social agenda. Philadelphia, PA:  Temple University Press.

Page 21: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

21  

Sutton, G. D. (2002, September). Explaining changes in house prices. BIS Quarterly Review, 46–55. Thalmann, P. (1999). Identifying households which need housing assistance. Urban Studies, 36(11), 1933–1947. Tilly, C. (2006). The economic environment of housing: Income inequality and insecurity. In Bratt, Stone, and Hartman (Eds.), A right to housing: Foundation for a new social agenda. Philadelphia, PA:  Temple University Press.  Weiss, R. S. (1984). The impact of marital dissolution on income and consumption in single-parent households. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 115–127. Whitehead, C. M. (1991). From need to affordability: An analysis of UK housing objectives. Urban Studies, 28(6), 871–887. Yitzhaki, S. (1983). On an extension of the Gini inequality index. International Economic Review, 24(3), 617–628. Yitzhaki, S. (1994). Economic distance and overlapping of distributions. Journal of Econometrics, 61(1), 147–159.  Yitzhaki, S., and Lerman, R. I. (1991). Income stratification and income inequality. Review of Income and Wealth, 37(3), 313–329.

Page 22: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

22  

Exhibit 1: Housing Price-to-Net Income Ratio by Deciles, 1992–2011

Exhibit 2: Average Housing Price-to-Net Income Ratio, 1992–2011

Note: The dashed line in Exhibit 2 represents the regression line obtained from estimating 𝑃

𝑊𝑡= 𝑎! +

𝑎!×𝑡 + 𝑒𝑡, where t is a time period, 𝑎! and 𝑎! are parameters, and 𝑒𝑡 is a random disturbance term.

10  

60  

110  

160  

210  

260  

Price-­‐to-­‐Net  Income  Ra

:o

10%   30%   50%   70%   90%   Average  

75  

85  

95  

105  

115  

125  

135  

145  

Price-­‐to-­‐Net  Income  Ra

:o

Average  P/W   Regression  Line  (Average  P/W)  

Page 23: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

23  

Exhibit 3: Housing Affordability Gini and Net Income Gini Coefficients, 1992–2011

Exhibit 4: Housing Affordability Atkinson and Net Income Atkinson Indices, 1992–2011

0.29  

0.3  

0.31  

0.32  

0.33  

0.34  

0.35  Gini  Coe

fficien

t

Housing  Affordability  Gini   Net  Income  Gini  

0.07  

0.075  

0.08  

0.085  

0.09  

0.095  

0.1  

0.105  

Atkinson

 Inde

x

Housing  Affordability  Atkinson   Net  Income  Atkinson  

Page 24: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

24  

Exhibit 1: Housing Price-to-Net Income Ratio by Deciles, 1992–2011

Exhibit 2: Average Housing Price-to-Net Income Ratio, 1992–2011

Note: The dashed line in Exhibit 2 represents the regression line obtained from estimating 𝑃

𝑊𝑡= 𝑎! +

𝑎!×𝑡 + 𝑒𝑡, where t is a time period, 𝑎! and 𝑎! are parameters, and 𝑒𝑡 is a random disturbance term.

10  

60  

110  

160  

210  

260  

Price-­‐to-­‐Net  Income  Ra

:o

10%   30%   50%   70%   90%   Average  

75  

85  

95  

105  

115  

125  

135  

145  

Price-­‐to-­‐Net  Income  Ra

:o

Average  P/W   Regression  Line  (Average  P/W)  

Page 25: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

25  

Exhibit 3: Housing Affordability Gini and Net Income Gini Coefficients, 1992–2011

Exhibit 4: Housing Affordability Atkinson and Net Income Atkinson Indices, 1992–2011

0.29  

0.3  

0.31  

0.32  

0.33  

0.34  

0.35  Gini  Coe

fficien

t

Housing  Affordability  Gini   Net  Income  Gini  

0.07  

0.075  

0.08  

0.085  

0.09  

0.095  

0.1  

0.105  

Atkinson

 Inde

x

Housing  Affordability  Atkinson   Net  Income  Atkinson  

Page 26: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

26  

Table 1: Number of Observations on Individual Household Socio-Demographic Characteristics Quarters, 1992–2011

Notes: Observations indicated in Table 1 come from Household Income and Expenditure Surveys conducted by the Israel Central Bureau of Statistics. The 1994 data has been omitted because of a surveying error made by the Israel Central Bureau of Statistics in that year, where non-wage employed household heads were omitted from the survey. The original total number of observations over the 1992–2011 period was 246,015. Because of missing observations, the final sample included a total of 156,583 observations

TotalQ4Q3Q2Q15,004 1,230 1,203 1,309 1,262 19924,474 1,206 1,041 1,100 1,127 19935,095 1,305 1,262 1,244 1,284 19955,152 1,292 1,261 1,338 1,261 19968,088 2,018 1,996 2,036 2,038 19978,524 2,243 1,985 2,216 2,080 19988,702 2,256 2,033 2,162 2,251 19998,596 2,264 2,064 2,083 2,185 20008,657 2,413 2,140 2,099 2,005 20019,357 2,700 2,232 2,425 2,000 20029,476 2,817 2,297 2,241 2,121 20039,443 2,666 2,217 2,339 2,221 20049,204 2,567 2,281 2,248 2,108 20059,260 2,615 2,222 2,293 2,130 20069,084 2,695 2,225 2,119 2,045 20079,166 2,598 2,311 2,183 2,074 20089,828 2,668 2,400 2,477 2,283 20099,808 2,921 2,360 2,488 2,039 20109,665 2,810 2,284 2,328 2,243 2011

156,58343,28437,81438,728 36,757 Total

Number of Observations (households in survey)Year

Page 27: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

27  

Table 2: Household Socio-Demographic and Dwelling Unit Characteristics and Their Share in the Sample

Share in the Population Category

Household and Dwelling Unit Characteristics

2011 1992 74% 84% Married

Household Family Status

7% 4% Divorced 4% 5% Widowed

13% 7% Single 2% 1% Living separately

61% 87% Male Household Head Gender 39% 13% Female

18% 14% 2

Number of Members in the

Household

16% 14% 3 21% 22% 4 17% 22% 5

9% 12% 6 5% 5% 7

14% 11% Other 8% 14% 9-10 Years

Household Head Years of Education

31% 31% 11-12 Years 27% 17% 13-15 Years 26% 20% 16+ Years

8% 18% Other 8% 18% Primary and/or middle school

Household Head Last Formal Education

17% 28% Professional high school 21% 16% Humanistic high school

4% 5% “Yeshiva” (religious high school) 18% 10% Post high-school (non-academic) 32% 23% Academic

5% 3% 18-24

Household Head Age

22% 22% 25-34 28% 33% 35-44 20% 20% 45-54 14% 11% 55-64

10% 10% 65+

16% 19% No provider

Number Household Providers

31% 35% 1 provider 40% 37% 2 providers

9% 7% 3 providers 4% 2% 4 providers

73% 64% Wage employee Household Head Working Status

9% 12% Self employed 16% 19% Not working

1% 5% Other  

Page 28: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

28  

Table 2 (continued): Household Socio-Demographic and Dwelling Unit Characteristics and Their Share in the Sample

Share in the Population Category

Household and Dwelling Unit Characteristics 2011 1992

12% 10% Academic profession

Household Head Occupation

12% 10% Technical 5% 6% Managers

13% 10% Office workers 16% 13% Agents, sales workers, and service workers

1% 28% Skilled agriculture workers 17% 5% Skilled industrial and construction workers

6% 10% Unskilled workers

18% 9% Other 1% 1% Agriculture

Household Head Industry

13% 23% Manufacturing 1% 1% Electricity and water supply 5% 7% Construction

11% 11% Wholesale and retail trade, and repairs 3% 2% Accommodation services and restaurants 6% 7% Transport, storage, and communications 3% 3% Banking, insurance, and other financial institutions

12% 7% Business activities 3% 5% Public administration

11% 7% Education 8% 5% Health, welfare, and social work services 4% 4% Community, social, personal, and other services 1% 9% Services for households by domestic personnel

18% 8% Other 14% 5% 5

Number of Rooms in a Dwelling Unit

2% 2% 4.5 30% 22% 4

6% 7% 3.5 33% 39% 3

5% 10% 2.5 9% 15% 2

11% 9% Jerusalem

Geographical Region of

Dwelling Unit

10% 14% Tel-Aviv 7% 7% Haifa

15% 19% Gush Dan 19% 19% Center 15% 12% South 11% 11% Sharon

9% 6% North 3% 3% Krayot

Note: Segments with an insignificant share in the sample (below 1%) are excluded from the table.

Page 29: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

29  

Table 3: List of Variables, Definitions, and Summary Statistics  

Max Min Std Mean Definition Variable 3,040 893 554 2,053 Per quarter average monthly net

income (in dollars) W

137.48 92.39 10.97 112.29 Per quarter average housing price-to-net income

P/W

0.0168 0.0117 0.00134 0.0144 Per quarter average net income-to-housing price

W/P

55,887 9,662 12,324 32,857 Quarterly level of gross domestic product (in millions of dollars)

GDP

20,500 6,770 3,099 10,226 Per quarter number of housing construction ends

HE

1.4 -1.93 0.613 -0.051 The difference between two consecutive quarters of unemployment rate

ΔUR

1.28 -0.9 0.366 -0.019 The difference between two consecutive quarters of mortgage rate

ΔMR

5.2 -7.8 2.43 -0.02 The difference between two consecutive quarters of the rate of change of the construction index

ΔCI

3.6 -2.3 1.064 -0.132 The difference between two consecutive quarters of the 12-month bond rate

ΔBR

0.386 -0.375 0.15 0.018 The difference between two consecutive quarters of the new Israeli Sheqel-to-dollar exchange rate.

ΔEX  

8310 -6140 1776 4.05 The difference between two consecutive quarters of housing construction starts

ΔHS

Note: Table 3 presents variable description and summary statistics for net income (W), housing price-to-net income ratio (P/W), net income-to-housing price ratio (W/P), and macroeconomic variables in equations (1) and (2). Testing for unit roots, we could not reject the hypothesis of a unit root in UR, MR, CI, BR, EX, and HS. We thus compute the first difference (between period t and t-1) for these variables and substitute those into the estimation of equations (1) and (2).

Page 30: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

30  

Table 4: Summary Statistics of Housing Affordability and Net Income Gini Coefficients and Atkinson Indices

Max Min Std Mean Definition Inequality Measure

0.352 0.294 0.0174 0.32 Housing affordability Gini coefficient GH 0.35 0.311 0.011 0.327 Net income Gini coefficient GW

0.101 0.070 0.0087 0.083 Housing affordability Atkinson index for ε=0.5

AH

0.1017 0.0789 0.0055 0.0873 Net income Atkinson index for ε=0.5 AW

Page 31: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

31  

Table 5: Outcomes Obtained from the Estimation of Equation (1)  

Notes: Table 5 reports OLS regression results from estimating equation (1). The first column reports outcomes obtained from estimating the full model, while the second column reports outcome of stepwise procedure with 10% significance threshold. The t-values are in parentheses below the coefficients. Significant values at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels are marked with one, two, and three asterisks, respectively.

Dependent Variable

(1) (2) (3) (4)Full Model Step-Wise Full Model Step-Wise

Constant 0.0474 0.045 0.0076 0.0072(1.44) (1.49) (0.92) (0.92)

0.754*** 0.759***(6.98) (7.72)

0.7113*** 0.7111***(6.96) (7.57)

0.00018** 0.000195** 0.000096** 0.00011***(2.02) (2.36) (2.14) (2.56)

GDP(- 5) 1.46e-7 *** 1.43e-7*** 7.63e-8*** 7.43e-8***(5.25) (5.54) (5.55) (5.81)

HE -1.20e-6*** -1.29e-6*** -6.25e-7*** -6.85e-7***(-2.73) (-3.20) (-2.84) (-3.38)

ΔUR 0.000108 -5.87e-6(0.07) (-0.01)

ΔMR -0.00172 -0.000731(-0.77) (-0.65)

ΔCI -0.00026 -0.00015(-0.74) (-0.85)

ΔBR 0.00065 0.00039(0.78) (0.93)

ΔEX -0.0089 -0.0086* -0.00421* -0.0042*(-1.74) (-1.77) (-1.64) (-1.70)

ΔHS 3.6e-7 1.61e-7(0.81) (0.72)

N 71 71 71 71R 2 0.89 0.88 0.89 0.89F-statistic 49.23 102.75 49 101.75

𝑮𝑯𝒕 𝑮𝑯𝒕 𝑨𝑯𝒕 𝑨𝑯𝒕

𝐺&

𝐴&

𝑃 𝑊⁄

Page 32: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

32  

Table 6: Gini Coefficient, Price-to-Income Ratio, and Gini Decomposition According to Socio-Demographic Subgroups, 1992 Versus 2011

20111992201119922011199258%71%Within=116770.330.30Married14%14%Between=1371130.340.32Divorced28%15%Overlap=1411610.340.38Widowed

2061000.370.31Single1531260.320.38Living separately

53%78%Within=116790.340.30Male12%12%Between=1391250.340.33Female35%10%Overlap=15%16% Within=2091770.360.36128%25% Between=1291040.330.32257%59% Overlap=108870.320.313

99710.300.284103720.310.295134790.350.286125630.380.297143750.350.288

24%20%Within=1891040.370.335-8 Years17%17%Between=141860.340.319-10 Years59%63%Overlap=121770.330.2811-12 Years

116780.330.2913-15 Years111770.340.3116+ Years

21%18%Within=1921030.380.33Primary and middle

23%25%Between=114770.310.29High professional

56%57%Overlap=134820.340.29High theoretical1911350.310.32Yeshiva

116730.330.29Tertiary education

104710.320.29Academic22%21%Within=1451240.360.2918-2415%22%Between=127860.340.3025-3465%57%Overlap=116730.330.2835-44

112720.340.2945-54116820.330.3155-641701310.360.3565+

26%24%Within=2211540.370.31No provider48%55%Between=150880.330.271 provider26%21%Overlap=86540.280.232 providers

74500.250.223 providers61370.250.174 providers

Household Head Age

Relative Contribution to

GiniDecomposition

Component

Housing Price-to-Net Income Ratio

Housing Affordability

GiniCategoryHousehold

Characteristic

Household Family Status

Household Head Gender

Number of Members in

the Household

Household Head Years of

Education

Household Head Last

Formal Education

Number of Household Providers

Page 33: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

33  

Table 6 (continued): Gini Coefficient, Price-to-Income Ratio, and Gini Decomposition According to Socio-Demographic Subgroups, 1992 versus 2011

20111992201119922011199258%44%Within=106650.320.26Wage employee22%36%Between=119770.340.29Self employed20%20%Overlap=2211480.370.31Not working

13%14% Within=90610.300.23Academicprofession

31%42% Between=112770.330.28Technical56%44% Overlap=84600.280.26Managers

108800.310.26Office workers

120910.320.27Agents, sales workers and service workers

1771010.400.31Skilled agriculture workers

110780.320.27Skilled industrialand construction workers

1311010.330.29Unskilledworkers

1991690.390.31Unknown9%10% Within=166880.340.28Agriculture

36%37% Between=80750.280.27Manufacturing

55%53% Overlap=71470.270.18Electricity and water supply

149760.360.27Construction

108890.300.26Wholesale and retail trade, and repairs

127870.340.26Accommodation services and restaurants

105780.310.28Transport, storage and communications

97770.280.26

Banking, insurance and other financial institutions

Relative Contribution to

GiniDecomposition

Component

Housing Price-to-Net Income Ratio

Housing Affordability

GiniCategoryHousehold

Characteristic

Household Head Working

Status

Household Head

Occupation

Household Head Industry

Page 34: INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION · 2016-06-21 · 1 ! INEQUALITY IN HOUSING AFFORDABILITY: MEASUREMENT AND ESTIMATION Danny Ben-Shahar and Jacob Warszawski*

 

 

34  

Table 6 (continued): Gini Coefficient, Price-to-Income Ratio, and Gini Decomposition According to Socio-Demographic Subgroups, 1992 versus 2011

Note: Data on household head industry and occupation have been collected only since 1995. Hence, Gini coefficients for the household head industry and occupation that appears in the 1992 column represents 1995 figures.

201119922011199220111992

102750.300.28Business activities

90630.300.23Public administration

130810.340.26Education

115790.340.28Health, welfare and social work services

1191000.330.30

Community, social, personal and other services

1421440.310.28

Services for households by domestic personnel

2161700.360.31Unknown12%12%Within=2061080.320.30Jerusalem50%34%Between=1821110.320.32Tel Aviv38%53%Overlap=95750.310.28Haifa

140950.310.29Gush Dan103810.270.29Center92710.310.31South96620.270.26Sharon73580.290.26North69670.280.26Krayot

Geographical Region of

Dwelling Unit

Relative Contribution to

GiniDecomposition

Component

Housing Price-to-Net Income Ratio

Housing Affordability

GiniCategoryHousehold

Characteristic

Household Head Industry - (continued)


Recommended