+ All Categories
Home > Documents > INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation...

INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation...

Date post: 04-Aug-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 1 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
50
INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE FROM LOAN DEFAULTS IN CHINA * Chun Chang Department of Finance and Accounting China Europe International Business School [email protected] Guanmin Liao School of Accountancy Central University of Finance and Economics [email protected] Xiaoyun Yu Indiana University and Shanghai Advanced Institute of Finance [email protected] Zheng Ni Hanqing Advanced Institute of Economics and Finance Renmin University of China [email protected] This version: August, 2009 * We thank Sumit Agrawal, Utpal Bhattacharya, Martin Brown, Hans Degryse, Nandini Gupta, Charles Kahn, Paolo Emilio Mistrulli, Steven Ongena, Zacharias Sautner, Greg Udell, Marc Umber, and seminar participants at Indiana University, Renmin University, Tsinghua University, Xiamen University, Shanghai Winter Finance Conference, 3 rd CAF-FIC-SIFR Emerging Market Conference (Hyderabad), 2 nd Swiss Conference on Banking and Financial Intermediation (Hasliberg), and European Financial Management Association Annual Meeting (Milan) for helpful comments. We thank Nicholas Korsakov for editorial assistance. This project was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China, Grant # 70773122. Contacting author. Address: Department of Finance, Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, 1309 East 10 th Street, Bloomington, Indiana 47405. Telephone: (812) 855-3521.
Transcript
Page 1: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE

FROM LOAN DEFAULTS IN CHINA*

Chun Chang Department of Finance and Accounting

China Europe International Business School [email protected]

Guanmin Liao

School of Accountancy Central University of Finance and Economics

[email protected]

Xiaoyun Yu† Indiana University and

Shanghai Advanced Institute of Finance [email protected]

Zheng Ni

Hanqing Advanced Institute of Economics and Finance Renmin University of China [email protected]

This version: August, 2009

* We thank Sumit Agrawal, Utpal Bhattacharya, Martin Brown, Hans Degryse, Nandini Gupta, Charles Kahn, Paolo Emilio Mistrulli, Steven Ongena, Zacharias Sautner, Greg Udell, Marc Umber, and seminar participants at Indiana University, Renmin University, Tsinghua University, Xiamen University, Shanghai Winter Finance Conference, 3rd CAF-FIC-SIFR Emerging Market Conference (Hyderabad), 2nd Swiss Conference on Banking and Financial Intermediation (Hasliberg), and European Financial Management Association Annual Meeting (Milan) for helpful comments. We thank Nicholas Korsakov for editorial assistance. This project was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China, Grant # 70773122. † Contacting author. Address: Department of Finance, Kelley School of Business, Indiana University, 1309 East 10th Street, Bloomington, Indiana 47405. Telephone: (812) 855-3521.

Page 2: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE FROM

LOAN DEFAULTS IN CHINA

ABSTRACT

We study the economic role of banks’ soft information, which evolved from repeated lending

relationships, in predicting loan default. Using a proprietary database from one of the largest state-

owned commercial banks in China, we find that the bank’s internal credit rating scores play a

significant role in default prediction. While the internal credit rating incorporates firm-specific hard

information such as financial ratios, it is the soft information component of these ratings that

contributes to the improvement in assessing credit quality. More importantly, the relative

importance of soft information over hard information depends on the depth of the lending

relationship. When evaluating loan delinquency, a sustained lending relationship allows soft

information to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially hard

information that is subject to easy manipulation.

Key words: Debt default, internal credit ratings, credit risk, relationship lending, soft information

JEL Classification: G21, D81, D82, D83, F34

Page 3: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

1

INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE FROM LOAN

DEFAULTS IN CHINA

1. INTRODUCTION

The theoretical literature on financial intermediation has long recognized the superior ability of

banks in acquiring information or knowledge beyond that which is available to ordinary financial market

participants (e.g., Ramakrishnan and Thakor 1984, Diamond 1984, Boyd and Prescott 1986, and Dow and

Gorton 1997). Many researchers emphasize the “soft” nature of this special knowledge in the notion that

soft information is not easily and accurately conveyed, verifiable, or transferable. In contrast to the “hard”

information derived from firms’ financial statements or industrial data, most researchers attribute soft

information to banks’ relationships with borrowing firms (e.g., Peterson 2004). In light of the central role

of the banking system in channeling capital to the real economy, however, few studies have directly

examined the nature and role of this special knowledge in predicting defaults on commercial loans.

In this paper we investigate to what extent this special knowledge can predict loan defaults, and

whether it acts as a complement or a substitute for any particular type of hard information in accessing

credit delinquency. Using a proprietary dataset from a major Chinese state-owned bank containing

information on all loans offered to firms in the five largest manufacturing industries in China from 2003

to 2006, we first document a substantial decline in loan defaults after the implementation of an internal

credit rating system in 2004. Internal credit ratings are significantly related to the commonly used firm-

specific financial ratios in predictable ways, and changes in these financial ratios lead to changes in credit

ratings. These findings suggest that, at least with regard to credit ratings, loan decisions by Chinese banks

are based on commercial principles instead of government policies, which may have contributed to the

overall performance improvement of Chinese banks in recent years.1

1 Since 2002, major state-owned commercial banks in China have embarked on a series of reforms, which have generally gone through the following four stages: financial reorganization, injection of new capital by the state, introduction of foreign strategic investors, and eventual IPOs. Amid the banks’ financial reorganization efforts is the introduction of an internal credit rating system. Concurrently, the average non-performing loan (NPL) ratio of the

Page 4: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

2

Furthermore, our analysis reveals that the bank’s internal credit ratings largely subsume firm-

specific hard information, as the majority of the commonly used financial ratios are no longer significant

in predicting loan defaults after including these ratings. Therefore, we next investigate to what extent the

improvement in loan quality is due to the bank’s soft information arising from extensive

borrowing/lending relationships, instead of relying on firm-specific hard information.

To extract the firm-specific soft information component from the bank’s private credit rating

score, we follow Agarwal and Hauswald (2008) and orthogonalize the credit rating with the firm’s

financial factors. To capture the nature of soft information generated from a repeated lending relationship,

we construct three proxies to identify the depth of banking relationship. Our first proxy is based on how

frequent a firm borrows from the bank. Our second proxy is based on how long a firm has maintained its

relationship with the bank. Our last proxy is based on a firm’s ownership, in which we classify a firm as

either state-owned or non-state-owned. Since a state bank’s lending relationship with state-owned firms is

historically mandated by the Chinese government, this proxy is relatively exogenous and thus mitigates

the endogeneity of matching between a firm and its bank that typically affects such studies (Berger,

Miller, Petersen, Rajan, and Stein 2005).

We find that the bank’s internal credit ratings contain useful information beyond that which is

conveyed by the commonly used financial and industrial variables. This soft information, captured by the

residual component of the internal credit rating that is unpredictable by those variables, is statistically and

economically significant in forecasting loan defaults. Our result thus provides evidence in support of the

theoretical arguments that banks possess special knowledge in assessing credit quality.

More importantly, for firms that borrow more frequently from the bank, have a longer term of

banking relationship, or state-owned firms, the majority of proxies for hard information are no longer

significant in predicting loan default once the soft information component of internal credit rating is

included. By contrast, for firms that borrow less frequently from the bank, have a shorter period of

major commercial banks in China decreased from 17.9% in 2003 to 6.7% in 2007. In a companion paper, we investigate other potential factors responsible for the decline of NPL ratio in Chinese banks.

Page 5: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

3

banking relationship, or are non-state-owned, most proxies for hard information remain significant even

in the presence of the bank’s soft information. Our findings indicate that the extent to which soft

information dominates hard information depends on the depth of the lending relationship, and that an

extensive lending relationship allows soft information to substitute for, rather than complement, the role

of hard information in evaluating loan delinquency.

Interestingly, for firms that maintain a long-term or frequent banking relationship as well as state-

owned firms, it is the hard information that can be easily manipulated by Chinese firms—such as ROA

and cash holding—that is displaced by the bank’s soft information. In contrast, the hard information that

is not subject to easy manipulation remains significant in predicting loan defaults even after the inclusion

of the bank’s soft information. Our analysis on earnings management further confirms the role of soft

information in the presence of less credible firm-specific hard information. The economic impact of soft

information is significantly more pronounced among firms with a higher level of earnings management

than among firms that are less likely to manipulate their earnings.

Our paper contributes to the finance literature that analyzes the role of hard and soft information

in bank lending.2 Most of the existing literature focuses on small business financing, loan underwriting or

pricing (e.g., Petersen and Rajan 1994, Berger and Udell 1995, Scott 2004, Uchida, Udell and Yamori

2007, and Cerqueiro, Degryse and Ongena 2008). Instead, we study the role of soft information in the

context of loan default. Our research design and unique dataset allow us to disentangle the soft

information that is ascertained through repeated lending relationships from that which is driven either by

bank competition and relative size, or by geographical proximity. In addition, we directly assess the

importance of banks’ soft information for large firms and industrial loans, which is usually absent from

the literature.

Our paper is related to Grunert, Norden, and Weber (2005) who find that the combined use of

financial and non-financial factors of credit rating scores predicts loan defaults more accurately by

German firms than the use of either financial or non-financial factors alone, and to Agrawal and 2 See Gorton and Winton (2003) for a survey on this literature.

Page 6: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

4

Hauswald (2008) who document that the soft information component of a credit rating predicts loan

defaults of small firms. Differing from the former, we show that soft information evolved through

extensive lending relationships not only improves default prediction, but also prevails over the effect of

financial factors. Differing from the latter, we establish that soft information plays an important role for

large firms and commercial loans, despite the fact that there tends to be more hard information about large

firms. In addition, we show that the effect of soft information in predicting default varies with the depth

of the lending relationship.

Our paper is also related to the literature analyzing how financial and industrial factors predict

corporate bankruptcy (e.g., Altman 1968). Instead, we focus on loan default. Our findings complement

this literature by indicating that hard information, derived from firm’s financial statements, predicts not

only a firm’s likelihood of bankruptcy but also that of short-term loan delinquency.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 discusses institutional details about

China’s banking system and recent banking reforms, and the uniqueness of our research setting. Section 3

describes our sources of data. Section 4 reports the results on the determinants of loan default and internal

credit rating. Section 5 examines the role of soft information. Section 6 extends to the nature of soft

information and its role in the presence of less credible hard information. Section 7 discusses various tests

for robustness. Section 8 concludes.

2. CHINA’S BANKING SYSTEM AND RESEARCH SETTING

2.1 The Role of the Big Four

In an attempt to emulate the Soviet Union in which a centralized banking system is used to

support a central planning economy, China established the People’s Bank of China (PBOC) in 1948. Prior

to 1978, the PBOC served as both a central bank and a commercial bank.

In 1978, China embarked on a market-oriented economic reform. Accordingly, four state-owned

banks—Agricultural Bank of China, Bank of China, China Construction Bank, and Industrial and

Commercial Bank of China—were established during the period of 1979-1984. The so-called “big four”

Page 7: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

5

were set to serve financing needs of four sectors, respectively: agriculture, foreign trade, infrastructure

construction, and manufacturing industries. After 1984, however, each of the “big four” was allowed to

broaden the scope of their operations into other banks’ sectors amid China’s effort to introduce

competition among banks.

Throughout this time, the firm-bank relationship was mandated by the government instead of

driven by commercial principles. Many of the state-owned banks’ loans were originated to state-owned

enterprises (SOEs) based on political and policy considerations. With the concerns regarding social

instability accompanied with rising unemployment, loans were continuously granted by the banks to pay

workers’ compensation despite the unprofitability and non-competitiveness of SOEs. Consequently, non-

performing loans (NPLs) piled up on banks’ financial statements.

From 1986 to 1996, approximately 11 more banks, including the Bank of Communication, China

Merchants’ Bank, Pudong Development Bank, and Shenzhen Development Bank, were established to

increase the competitiveness of China’s banking industry. These banks are usually jointly owned by

several legal entities, such as local governments and enterprises. Although the legal entities are usually

state-owned, these “joint-stock” banks are smaller, albeit more efficiently run, than the big four state-

owned banks.3

In 1995, China passed the “Central Bank Law” and “Commercial Bank Law”, explicitly

specifying the functions, rights and duties between the central bank (PBOC) and commercial banks. In

2003, China established the Banking Regulatory Commission to take over part of the regulatory duties

previously held by the PBOC. In turn, the PBOC focuses on its macroeconomic and monetary

responsibilities.

China permits foreign banks to conduct business in the mainland China starting 1979. Initially,

most of the foreign banks’ business is restricted to foreign currency exchange. As a precondition to join

3 Prior to 1995, small credit unions also existed, some of which were transformed into city cooperative banks through equity contributions from local governments, enterprises, and local citizens. In 1995, the State Council of China announced that credit unions can no longer be transformed into city cooperative banks through equity contributions.

Page 8: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

6

the WTO, China pledged the commitment to open its domestic currency (RMB) business to all foreign

banks by 2006. Foreign banks were also allowed to take limited equity positions in Chinese banks (see

the next section).

2.2 The Reform of China’s Commercial Banks

Mounting non-performing loans have long plagued the financial statements of China’s

commercial banks, especially the “big four”. In 1997, 30% of all the loans outstanding were NPLs. By

2003, this ratio was still as high as 20%. The high percentage of NPLs was usually attributed to: (1) the

government’s direct or indirect ownership and control of commercial banks to pursue its political and

policy agendas, (2) inefficient operations and soft budget constraints associated with some SOE

borrowers, and (3) ineffectiveness in enforcing the bankruptcy law.

The Chinese government has since initiated a series of reforms to curb the increasing risk

associated with the high level of NPLs. In 1998, 270 billion RMB was injected by the Finance Ministry to

replenish the deteriorating capital of the big four state-owned banks, followed by a transfer of 1.4 trillion

RMB NPLs (at their face value) from these banks to four corresponding newly created Assets

Management Companies in 1999.

As the next step of the reform, the government “corporatized” the state-owned banks by

introducing foreign strategic investors and then listing these banks on the Hong Kong Stock Exchange

and/or the Shanghai Stock Exchange. In late 2003, the government injected $22.5 billion each into the

Bank of China and China Construction Bank as equity capital, and corporatized the two as joint-stock

commercial banks. In 2004, Royal Bank of Scotland, UBS, Bank of America, and TEMASEK took

minority equity positions in these two banks as strategic investors. China Construction Bank went public

in 2005. The state retained a controlling stake (59.12%) of the bank after its listing on the Hong Kong

and Shanghai Stock Exchanges. After the Bank of China’s IPO in both Hong Kong and Shanghai in 2006,

the state’s equity stake was 67.49%.

Page 9: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

7

In 2005, $15 billion were used to capitalize the Industrial and Commercial Bank of China (ICBC),

which was then reorganized and corporatized. Goldman Sachs, Allianz, and American Express bought a

total of 8.45% of its equity as strategic investors. ICBC became publicly traded on the Hong Kong and

Shanghai stock exchanges in 2006. After its IPO, the state controlled 72.47% of the shares.

Many believe that banking reforms since 2003, including bank restructuring, introduction of

strategic investors, and public listings, have fundamentally changed the corporate governance and risk

management practices of Chinese state-owned banks. As a result, loan originations have relied more on

commercial principles instead of government policies, and NPL ratios have declined substantially. By the

beginning of 2008, ICBC overtook Citigroup as the world’s largest bank in terms of market capitalization.

The other two of the “big four”, Construction Bank of China and Bank of China, ranked the 4th and 5th,

respectively.4

2.3 Chinese Banks as a Research Setting

Using Chinese banks as a research setting offers several unique features. First, banks play a

dominating role in China’s financial system (Allen et al., 2008). In 2004 alone, bank loans accounted for

83% of external capital raised by non-financial firms, in comparison with 5% of external capital raised

from the equity market and 12% from the public debt market. Unlike many developed countries where

bank loans are predominant among mostly small businesses, Chinese firms rely mainly on bank financing

regardless of the scope of their businesses and the scale of their operations.

Second, within China’s banking system, the big four state-owned banks dominate the loan market.

By the end of 2004, the “big four” accounted for 55% market share in terms of asset scale (García-

Herrero, Gavilá and Santabárbara, 2006). Since each of the big four banks specializes in a specific

lending area, the impact of competition from other banks within a lending area remained relatively

marginal at the time. This mitigates the issue of bank size and competition that commonly affect such

studies. 4 “ICBC Deposes Citigroup as Chinese Banks Rule in New World Order”, Bloomberg.com, February 4, 2008.

Page 10: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

8

Third, the unique setting of China’s banking system also allows us to concentrate on the nature

and role of firm-specific information obtained by the bank from its long-term and repeated lending

relationships in predicting loan defaults. As discussed later in Section 5, one of our proxies for the depth

of banking relationship is based on whether or not a firm is state-owned.5 Since state banks’ relationships

with state-owned firms were historically mandated by the Chinese government, this proxy is relatively

exogenous and consequently, mitigates the endogeneity of matching between a firm and its bank that

typically affects such studies (Berger, Miller, Petersen, Rajan, and Stein 2005).

Lastly, state-ownership historically mandated the mapping of a nationwide distribution of bank

branches. Since the backbone of our bank’s branch network was originally set up exogenously, instead of

evolving endogenously based on the regional economic development as in previous studies for developed

economies, the soft information in our analysis is less likely to be driven by distance, and more so by

repeated lending.

3. DATA DESCRIPTION

3.1 Data Sources

We obtain a large dataset from one of the big-four state-owned commercial banks in China,

whose lending scope and practices have concentrated on manufacturing industries. The dataset consists of

year-end information on all the outstanding loans made to 15 subcategories of five largest manufacturing

industries from 2003 to 2006.6 The industry classification system used by the bank is similar to the

Industrial Classification for National Economic Activities from the Bureau of Statistics of China.

For each loan outstanding, our dataset contains information on its principal amount, maturity date,

the province in which the loan was originated, interest rate, the borrowing firm’s financial statements,

5 Our paper studies how information arising from long-term or repeated lending relationships affects defaults on outstanding loans. The impact of information on loan approvals or rejections, though an interesting issue, is beyond the scope of the paper. By focusing on the prediction of loan defaults instead of loan approvals, state-ownership as a proxy for lending relationship is not affected by whether loans are granted for political or policy considerations. 6 The five manufacturing industries include: Steel, Automobiles and Transportation Equipment, Paper, Non-ferrous Metals, and Construction Materials and Manufacturing.

Page 11: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

9

ownership classification, and the industry where the firm operates. More importantly, our dataset contains

the repayment status if the loan is due during the year. Specifically, for each loan outstanding, its

repayment status will be noted by the bank at the end of the following year in one of the following three

categories: repaid, unpaid, or written off.

Starting 2004, the bank implemented an internal credit rating system.7 For a given year, the bank

follows an internal set of guidelines and assigns a credit score to a borrowing firm at the time when it

applies for the first loan of that year. The bank then rates the borrower based on its credit score. The credit

rating ranks from one to 12, with one being the lowest (poorest credit quality) and 12 the highest (highest

credit quality). Our dataset thus also contains all the annual rating information between 2004 and 2006. In

Appendix I, we provide a detailed description of this internal credit rating system. As Appendix I

indicates, a borrowing firm’s internal credit rating reflects both the objective and subjective evaluations

from the bank.

Appendix II and Tables A1 and A2 describe the loan characteristics such as size, maturity and

default rates, as well as internal credit ratings for firms of the five manufacturing industries in this dataset.

There is evidence that the introduction of foreign strategic investors and listing on overseas stock

exchange dramatically improves the bank’s performance over time, resulting in a significant decrease in

loan defaults and an increase in credit ratings. In addition, loans originated to the state-owned enterprises

experienced a substantial decline during our sample period. All these suggest that loan decisions over the

sample period gravitate towards commercial principles instead of government policies.

7 Most banks in the United States have had internal credit rating systems since at least the 1980s (see, e.g., English and Nelson (1999) for a description). Note also that internal credit rating differs from credit scoring. Small business credit scoring (SBCS) in the United States was introduced in 1995 and applies to only micro business loans. By basically adapting consumer lending practices to micro business lending, credit scoring is mostly focused on using mercantile ratings and consumer credit bureau reports on the entrepreneur. It is best viewed as a subset of internally rated loans. In the case of SBCS, the entire loan underwriting process is limited to the score. Several studies have shown that the implementation of SBCS improves small business lending (e.g., Frame, Srinivasan, and Wooseley 2001 and Berger, Frame and Miller 2005). China introduced the internal credit rating system to its banks following economic reforms. However, there is still a lack of development of credit scoring for small businesses and consumers.

Page 12: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

10

3.2 Loan Default

To ensure the conservativeness of our analysis, we consider a loan in the default stage if the

principal is unpaid or written off by the due date. Therefore, our definition of loan default is essentially

restricted to whether the loan is repaid on time, which is narrow in the sense that other violations of loan

covenants are not considered as default. Note that loan rollovers are extremely rare in China. This is

because Chinese firms are required to physically repay their loan obligations to their banks before they

can borrow any new loans, even if the principal and terms of the new loan remain exactly the same, which

in fact constitutes a loan rollover. Note also that in China, a loan officer of a state-owned bank bears the

“life responsibility” for loans that he or she originates. That is, the officer bears penalty in the event of

default even if he or she no longer works in loan origination or he or she has transferred to a different

department. Therefore, our definition of loan default is unlikely to underestimate actual default. In

addition, as will become clear later, underestimating default works against us in finding the results.

3.3 Sample Selection

Our dataset contains 40,740 bank loans made to 4,624 Chinese firms from five manufacturing

industries between 2003 and 2006. There are 13 ownership categories for the borrowing firms in our

sample, including state-owned, collectively-owned, state-controlled (in which the state has a controlling

stake), collectively-controlled (in which a collectively-owned entity has a controlling stake), foreign-

owned and joint ventures, privately-owned, proprietorship, and joint-stock companies. We remove 2,667

loans borrowed by collectively-owned and collectively-controlled firms due to their ambiguous nature,8

as well as loans borrowed by firms with missing ownership information.

We begin by extracting a sub-sample of loan data based on the following filtering criteria. Note

that firms borrowing from the bank in 2003 do not have an assigned internal credit rating, and some loans

initiated in 2006 require payment information in 2007 but our loan sample ends in 2006. Therefore, we

8 The ambiguous nature of collectively-owned firms and their unique ownership arrangements are discussed and analyzed in details in Chang and Wang (1994).

Page 13: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

11

remove 22,252 loans to restrict our regression analysis to the sample containing loans originated after

2003, with a maturity date no later than 2006.

We focus on short-term loans (maturity of one year or less). This is because to identify the default

status for medium and long-term loans requires information extended beyond one year. However,

concentrating on short-term loans does not bias our analysis. As Appendix II and Table A1 indicate,

short-term loans constitute the major source of funding for Chinese firms. In fact, 95% of loans in our

overall sample have a maturity of one year or less, accounting for 84% of aggregate outstanding

principals. In addition, for short-term loans, default more likely arises from failing to meet principal

repayment requirements rather than from violating other loan covenants; our definition of loan default—

whether or not the principal is repaid on time—thus matches this focus well.

With only the end-of-year information available in our data, short-term loans made and repaid in

the same calendar year are not included in the database unless there is a default. Therefore, for loans with

a maturity less than one year, we only include those initiated on and after July 1st of years 2004 or 2005

with a maturity of six months or longer, which allows us to identify their default status during the period

of 2005-2006. This approach ensures the conservativeness of our analyses and avoids over-estimating

default rate. These sample restrictions lead to an exclusion of 5,452 short-term and long-term loans.

We further remove 815 firm-year observations (1,727 loans) with missing internal rating scores,

financial statement information, and/or sales growth rate. Our final sample thus contains 8,642 loans from

1,450 firms (2,063 firm-year observations).

Table 1 summarizes the characteristics between firms that defaulted on their loans and those that

did not. The detailed variable descriptions are provided in Appendix III.

From Table 1, there is preliminary evidence that the bank’s internal credit rating predicts loan

default as the rating differs depending on whether or not the loans are in subsequent default stage. For

example, among loans initiated in 2004, those that were in default in 2005 had an average internal credit

score of 5.38, compared to the average score of 8.30 for those that were not in default. Firms defaulting

Page 14: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

12

on their loans also have a significantly higher degree of leverage, poorer profitability (measured by return

on assets, or ROA), lower asset turnover, and smaller cash reserves.

Interestingly, Panels B and C show that the above observed default characteristics are similar

between state-owned firms and non-state-owned firms. This suggests that most of the firm-specific

fundamental factors that affect loan default are relatively universal across Chinese firms.

Lastly, both the average annual book value of total assets and annual number of employees in

Table 1 indicate that our sample is not dominated by small manufacturing firms. For example, firms that

borrowed short-term loans in 2004 and then defaulted in 2005 on average have 1,160 employees and total

assets of RMB 371 million, approximately $46.14 million.9 Unlike small businesses analyzed by the

majority of previous studies, our sample firms have a relatively large operating scale and asset base.

In addition, our sample is not dominated by micro-loans. Although not tabulated, the average

outstanding loan principal per sample firm is RMB 47.036 million ($5.85 million). Our study therefore

sheds light on the characteristics and economic impact of relationship lending associated with commercial

loans and large industrial firms.

4. LOAN DEFAULT AND INTERNAL CREDIT RATING

We now evaluate the economic role of the bank’s information, captured by its private credit

rating score, in the context of predicting loan default. We first identify firm-specific factors that can

potentially affect the incentive to default. We then investigate whether credit rating scores have additional

predictive power after controlling for firm-specific factors known to affect default propensity.

Next, we explore the information content of the bank’s internal credit rating by examining

whether these ratings take into account a firm’s fundamentals, and whether there is any evidence that the

bank possesses additional proprietary information in evaluating credit delinquency. By parsing the rating

score into a “hard” information component and a “soft” information component, based on the predicted

and unpredicted components of credit rating score with respect to a firm’s fundamentals, we examine 9 Based on an average exchange rate between 2003 and 2006 of $1 = RMB 8.04.

Page 15: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

13

whether the soft information component has any predictive power. Since a bank’s soft information

evolves from its lending relationship with the firm, we further investigate whether the role of soft

information differs depending on the depth of lending relationship.

As discussed in Appendix I, a credit rating score is assigned to a borrowing firm when it applies

for its first loan of the year. Since the bank’s internal credit rating is assigned to the borrower instead of to

individual loans, we conduct our regressions at firm-level to ensure the conservativeness of our analysis.

Consequently, for each year, we define a firm as in a loan default stage if at least one of its previously

borrowed short-term loans is written off or unpaid. This definition includes firms that default some, but

not all, of their loans. Among the 2,063 firm-year observations, 172 firm-year observations are classified

as default. 124 out of 172 (72%) involve firms that default all their loans, whereas 28% involves firms

that default some of their loans. In the robustness section, we discuss the results based on the loan-level

analyses and based on alternative definitions of loan default.

4.1 Can Hard Information and Internal Credit Rating Predict Loan Default?

We start with a correlation analysis to identify the relationship between firm-specific hard

information—including fundamental factors derived from their financial statements—and the subsequent

loan defaults. As indicated in Table 2, a high incidence of default is correlated with small asset base, high

leverage, being state-owned, and poor operating performance in terms of ROA, asset turnover, cash

reserve, and sales growth. A high loan default rate is also correlated with a low internal credit rating.

We now explicitly explore this relationship with the following probit regression model:

Pr(Default) =f(firm-specific hard information variables, γindustry, λyear) [1]

Our dependent variable is a dummy equal to one if a firm is in the stage of defaulting its loan, and

zero otherwise. Our independent variables include lagged firm-specific factors that could affect the

default propensity. Specifically, we include a firm’s key financial statement information such as size,

leverage, return on assets, asset turnover, cash reserve, and sales growth. Other characteristics include a

Page 16: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

14

dummy variable equal to one if the firm is state-owned,10 the interaction of the dummy with the firm’s

size, average loan maturity, a dummy equal to one if the firm has previously defaulted on its loans, and a

dummy variable equal to one if the firm is publicly traded. We include log(GDP) to control for potential

clustering of bank branches and borrowing firms based on local economic conditions. Lastly, we control

for both industry and year fixed-effects, industryγ and yearλ .

Table 3 Column 1 presents the results for the probit regression model [1]. Controlling for industry

and year fixed effects, hard information, captured by a firm’s fundamentals, can significantly predict loan

default. Specifically, firms with a larger asset base, lower leverage, higher profitability, larger cash

reserves, and operating in regions of more advanced economic development tend to have a lower

propensity of default. Firms that previously defaulted on their loans also tend to default on current loans.

In addition, the dummy variable for state-owned firms is positive and significant, but the

coefficient for the interaction term between the dummy and size is negatively significant. This suggests

that while state-owned firms tend to have a higher probability of default, this probability declines if such

firms have a large asset base.

To examine whether the bank’s internal credit rating, implemented nation-wide for all its

branches, has any additional predictive power for loan default, we next include the bank’s internal credit

rating score in the regression model [1].

Columns 2 and 3 of Table 3 suggest that internal credit rating is significantly negatively related to

the probability of default, regardless of whether or not the proxies for firm-specific hard information are

included. Specifically, one level increase in the internal credit rating (higher score) leads to a 1.6% lower

probability of default (Column 3).

Since the occurrence of loan default constitutes a relatively rare event for our sample, we evaluate

the overall improvement in prediction accuracy by comparing the fitted probabilities between Columns 1

and 3 with respect to actual default. Among firms that actually default on their loans, we count the

10 In 2005, 12 firms changed their ownership from state-owned to non-state-owned. Excluding these 12 firms does not alter our findings.

Page 17: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

15

number of firms whose predicted probability of default based on Column 3 is greater than the one based

on Column 1. Among firms that actually do not default on their loans, we count the number of firms

whose predicted probability of default based on Column 3 is smaller than the one based on Column 1. We

find that the predicted probability overall improves from Column 1 for 70.14% of sample observations,

after including the internal credit rating variable.

Interestingly, Column 3 reveals that once the internal credit rating is included, most of the proxies

for firm-specific hard information—fundamental factors identified in Column 1 to help predict the

probability of loan default, such as firm size, leverage, profitability, and previous default records—are no

longer statistically significant. This suggests that internal credit rating scores subsume the effect of these

factors.

We also observe from Column 3 that the coefficients associated with the dummy for state-owned

firms and the interaction term are no longer significant after including the internal credit rating variable.

This is in contrast with the results of Column 1 where, in the absence of rating, both coefficients are

significant at the 5% level. This comparison provides preliminary evidence that internal credit rating is

more informative about state-owned firms, with whom the bank tends to have a long-term relationship.

4.2 The Information Content of Internal Credit Rating

The results from Table 3 show that the bank’s internal credit rating scores are significantly related

to the probability of default. Most of the fundamental factors are no longer significant after including

these rating scores, which suggests that internal credit rating scores incorporate the majority, if not all, of

firm-specific hard information.

We next regress internal credit rating scores against these proxies for firm-specific hard

information identified in the probit regression model [1]. The OLS results from Table 4 Panel A presents

evidence that internal credit ratings do take into account firm-specific fundamental factors expected to

affect loan default. Not surprisingly, factors such as larger asset base, lower leverage, greater profitability,

faster asset turnover, higher level of cash reserve and sales growth, and a previous non-default record lead

Page 18: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

16

to better credit quality and a more favorable credit score. While state-owned firms on average are

associated with low credit rating scores, this effect is more pronounced for firms of smaller sizes, as the

coefficient associated with the interaction term is positive and significant.

Table 4 Panel A Column 1 shows that these proxies for firm-specific hard information together

explain approximately 44% of a firm’s internal credit rating score. The adjusted R2s for Columns 2 and 3

indicate that there is a difference between state-owned and non-state-owned firms: for state-owned firms,

firm-specific fundamentals are able to explain over 63% of the internal credit ratings, whereas they can

explain only 38% for firms without state ownership. This suggests that financial information is more

credible for firms that maintain a long-term banking relationship, and therefore is taken into account to a

greater extent by the bank. In contrast, financial information from firms that do not maintain a long-term

banking relationship is less influential when the bank sets its internal credit rating scores.

Table 4 Panel B adopts a difference-in-difference analysis and examines whether a change in

firm-specific hard information such as a firm’s fundamental characteristics leads to a subsequent change

in the internal credit rating. In the OLS regression (Column 1), the dependent variable is the change in the

internal credit rating. In the ordered probit regression (Column 2), the dependent variable takes a value of

1 if a firm’s internal credit rating improves from 2004 to 2005, -1 if it deteriorates, and 0 otherwise.

We observe that a change in asset base, leverage, and operating performance is significantly

related to a subsequent change in internal credit rating. The ordered probit result suggests that an increase

in operating performance measured by ROA leads to a higher internal credit rating, while an increase in

leverage leads to a lower rating.

To summarize, our multivariate regression analysis and difference-in-difference analysis indicate

that the bank’s internal credit rating takes into account firm-specific hard information, such as

fundamental factors previously identified to predict loan default. In addition, these factors matter more if

the firm has a long-term relationship with the bank.

Page 19: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

17

5. THE ROLE OF SOFT INFORMATION

Results from Table 3 indicate that most known fundamental factors are no longer statistically

significantly in predicting loan default once the international rating scores are included in the probit

regression. Table 4 Panel A reveals that, being able to explain less than 44% of the internal credit rating,

firm-specific hard information—captured by firms’ fundamentals—is not sole determinant of the bank’s

internal credit rating. This suggests that the bank possesses superior informational advantage when

evaluating loan defaults.

5.1 Proxies for Soft Information and the Depth of Lending Relationship

We follow an approach similar to Agarwal and Hauswald (2008) and parse the internal credit

rating into a hard information component and a soft information component, which we define statistically

based on the firm-specific fundamental information available during the period the rating score is

assigned. Specifically, for each sample firm we obtain the fitted value and residual of its internal credit

rating score from Table 4 Panel A Column 1. In this respect, Bank Specialty, measured by the residual

component of the internal credit rating, captures the soft information arising from the bank’s own

assessment, monitoring, knowledge and experiences that cannot be predicted by hard information proxies.

If the bank’s firm-specific soft information arises from its lending relationship with the firm, then

the role of Bank Specialty in predicting default may vary between firms that have a sustained banking

relationship and those do not. On the other hand, if Bank Specialty captures omitted firm-specific hard

information instead of the bank’s own information that is not easily verifiable, conveyed, or transferable,

then we should not expect its role to vary with the depth of lending relationship. In Section 7, we also

discuss our robustness tests with respect to omitted hard information.

To identify whether or not the bank’s soft information is pertinent to relationship lending, we

adopt three proxies for the depth of relationship. Our first proxy is based on the borrowing frequency over

the sample period. For each firm, we compute the total number of loans outstanding with the bank over

the sample period. We then classify a firm as an infrequent borrower if its number of loans is less than or

Page 20: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

18

equal to the sample median of 12. A firm is a frequent borrower if its number of loans outstanding is

greater than 12.

Our second proxy is based on the duration of the banking relationship. Starting in 2004, our bank

assigns its annual internal credit rating score at the time when it grants the first loan to the firm. So for

each firm in each year (2004 or 2005), we identify the month when it obtains its first loan. We then trace

back the firm’s loan information prior to this month. The duration variable is then calculated as the

difference between the current month and the earliest recorded time in our database among all the loans

borrowed by the firm prior to the current month. We classify a firm as having a long-term relationship

with the bank if the duration of its banking relationship is more than 23 months (sample median in 2005).

Otherwise, the firm is classified as having a short-term banking relationship.11

Our last proxy is based on whether a firm is owned or controlled by the state. Since the Chinese

government historically mandates the banking relationship with state-owned firms, the bank has more

interactions with state-owned firms than non-state-owned firms. More importantly, this relationship is

forged exogenously and is therefore, not subject to the doubt-matching endogeneity problem commonly

seen in the existing literature. On the other hand, since our focus is loan default instead of loan origination,

the results with respect to this proxy for lending relationship is not affected by whether loans are

originated for commercial principles.

5.2 Soft Information, Relationship Lending, and Loan Default

To examine whether the bank’s soft information matters in predicting loan defaults, we include

Bank Specialty instead of internal credit rating and re-run the probit regression [1] as follows:

11 Alternative cutoff based on sample median of 2004-2005 yields similar results. Note that this proxy is measured against the short sample period; it tends to be noisy in capturing the interaction between the firm and the bank than the other two proxies. A firm might have secured loans from the bank prior to the beginning of our sample period and beyond the records that are traceable, and had little borrowing activities since then. It is possible that such firms are classified as being associated with a short-term banking relationship. However, this type of misclassification works against us in finding the difference between firms of short- and long-term banking relationships. In addition, our focus on short-term lending activities, instead of long-term loans, helps to mitigate this potential misclassification problem.

Page 21: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

19

Pr(Default) =f(Bank Specialty, firm-specific hard information variables, γindustry, λyear) [2]

We run the regression model [2] for the two sub-samples of firms with and without a profound

banking relationship, respectively. Since one of our proxies is state ownership, we remove the State

dummy and its interaction with Size from the set of hard information proxies. Including or excluding the

two variables when estimating [2] for sub-samples classified by borrowing frequency or duration does not

alter our findings. Table 5 presents the probit regression results for all three proxies, respectively.

Bootstrapped standard errors are reported in parentheses.12

Table 5 shows that Bank Specialty is negatively related to default propensity, suggesting that

more favorable soft information leads to a lower probability of default. This relationship is statistically

significant, regardless of a firm’s ownership, borrowing frequency, or length of banking relationship.

On the other hand, the role of soft information relative to hard information also varies depending

on the depth of the lending relationship. Columns (2), (4) and (6) of Table 5 reveal that for frequent

borrowers, firms that begin their banking relationship early, and state-owned firms, the majority of hard

information proxies are no longer significant after including Bank Specialty. This suggests that the bank’s

soft information, arising from a long-term and repeated lending relationship, substitutes most hard

information, and is almost capable of predicting loan defaults alone.

In contrast, Columns (1), (3) and (5) of Table 5 indicates that in the absence of such a profound

lending relationship, Bank Specialty is unable to prevail over most hard information. For infrequent

borrowers, firms that started their banking relationship more recently, and non-state-owned firms, half of

the hard information proxies continue to significantly predict default even in the presence of the bank’s

soft information. This suggests that soft information accumulated through a tenuous lending relationship

is less capable of evaluating loan defaults by itself alone.

12 The probit estimates could potentially be biased due to violations of distributional assumptions under which the regression models are estimated. We therefore apply the bootstrap methodology (Efron, 1979) to determine the statistical significance of the estimated coefficients. The bootstrapped standard errors are based on 500 random draws with replacement. Using robust standard errors instead of bootstrapped standard errors yields the same results. Therefore, these results are not tabulated.

Page 22: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

20

Interestingly, when analyzing what kind of hard information is subsumed by soft information, we

observe from Table 5 that ROA and Cash consistently remain insignificant for firms that have a sustained

banking relationship, but are statistically significant for firms lacking a profound banking relationship.

Relative to other hard information proxies, these two are more difficult to verify and can be easily

manipulated by Chinese firms.13 This highlights the importance of bank’s soft information in replacing

the type of hard information that is subject to easy manipulation.

6. EXTENSIONS

6.1 The Contents of Soft Information and Loan Default Prediction

Table 5 reveals that the bank’s soft information significantly predicts loan default. Intuitively,

loan default occurs when the deterioration in credit quality of the borrowing firm exceeds a certain level.

This implies that the relationship between Bank Specialty and incidence of default may be nonlinear:

when the bank is already very positive about the borrowing firm, more favorable information may not

significantly lead to a substantial decline in default propensity.

To investigate to what extent the bank’s soft information predicts subsequent loan default, we

employ a piecewise linear estimation—a spline.14 A spline specification allows the slope coefficient to

vary with different levels of soft information. We choose the spline cutoff points based on the terciles of

Bank Specialty: -0.387, and 0.902.

Table 6 Column 1 reports the probit regression results for the overall sample and Column 2

reports the spline regression results. Table 6 Column 1 reveals that for the overall sample, Bank Specialty

is negatively related to default propensity after controlling for firm-specific hard information proxies and

year and industry fixed effects, suggesting that more favorable soft information is associated with a lower

incidence of default.

13 From an accounting perspective, cash manipulations are relatively limited compared to the options to manipulate ROAs. Nevertheless, cash manipulations are widespread among Chinese firms, even among publicly traded companies. 14 For a detailed description of spline regression, see Garber and Poirier (1974) and Poirier (1974).

Page 23: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

21

The results from the spline regressions indicate that the overall sample findings are driven by less

favorable soft information. We observe from Table 6 Column 2 that controlling for firm-specific hard

information and year and industry fixed effects, the coefficient estimates for Bank Specialty remain

negative for all three tercile levels. However, the relationship between the bank’s soft information and

default propensity is statistically significant only for the bottom tercile. This suggests that, ceteris paribus,

when the bank’s soft information is already very favorable (the middle and top terciles), an increase in the

bank’s optimism about the borrowing firms does not contribute to a significant decline in the incidence of

default. On the other hand, when the bank’s soft information is relatively negative about the borrower (the

bottom tercile), default propensity decreases significantly if soft information becomes more positive.

6.2 The Economic Impact of Bank Specialty: The Case of Earnings Management

While various proxies for firm-specific hard information capture different dimensions of a firm’s

characteristics, they are not equally precise and credible. Table 5 suggests that soft information can

subsume hard information proxies that are subject to easy manipulation. We now explore the role of soft

information in default prediction from a different but related angle: earnings management. If a firm tends

to manipulate its hard-information and thus its hard information is less credible, then the bank should rely

more on its soft information rather than the firm’s reported hard information.

In this respect, China as a research setting offers a unique advantage. Because of the under-

development of its stock market and constraints on other external financing sources, most Chinese firms,

regardless of their sizes and scopes of business operations, rely on bank financing. In particular, the

majority of Chinese firms are not publicly traded. In contrast to other motives to manipulate earnings

among public firms, the primary purpose of earnings management of the private firms is to obtain or

maintain bank financing capacity and to delay the consequences associated with loan defaults.

To explore the role of soft information in the presence of earnings management, we first remove

publicly traded firms from our sample. Next, we employ three earnings management measures for our

analysis. Our first measure follows Leuz, Nanda, and Wysocki (2003) and uses the magnitude of accruals

Page 24: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

22

as a proxy for the extent to which a firm exercises discretion in reporting earnings. Specifically, we

compute this firm-specific proxy as the ratio of a firm’s absolute value of accruals and the absolute value

of the cash flow from operations, where accruals are calculated as: (Δtotal current assets - Δcash) - (Δtotal

current liabilities- Δshort-term debt - Δtaxes payable) - depreciation expense.

Our second measure is similar to the industry-adjusted non-operating income measure used in

Chen and Yuan (2004), who show that for Chinese firms, earnings management can be detected from

non-operating income that is in excess of industry norms. For each year, we compute each firm’s non-

operating income by scaling its gain and loss from non-operating activities with the total pre-tax profit

and then subtract the industry median to reach its industry-adjusted non-operating come. We obtain

industry median non-operating income from SINOFIN’s Chinese Industrial Enterprises Database.15

Our third measure uses discretionary accruals as a proxy for earnings management. Firm-specific

discretionary accrual is estimated according to the modified Jones model (Dechow, Sloan and Sweeney,

1995). The industry benchmark is again drawn from SINOFIN’s Chinese Industrial Enterprises Database.

For each earnings management proxy, we classify a firm as the one with a low degree of earnings

management if its proxy value falls below the sample median. We then re-estimate regression [2] for both

the high and low earnings management sub-samples. When hard information is subject to easy

manipulation and thus becomes less credible, the bank more likely relies on its soft information. We

should expect that the bank’s soft information plays a more significant role in predicting default among

firms that tend to manipulate their earnings than those that are less likely to misstate their economic

performance.

Table 7 reports the probit regression results for high and low earnings management sub-samples,

and for each of the three earnings management proxies, respectively. Sample size varies due to missing

values for variables required in calculating a specific measure of earnings management. For brevity, only

15 To the best of our knowledge, the Chinese Industrial Enterprises Database is the only database that provides industrial level accounting information that contains non-publicly traded firms. Although untabulated, results are similar if we use sample annual industry median instead.

Page 25: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

23

the coefficient and marginal effect associated with Bank Specialty are presented. Firm-specific variables,

as well as industry and year fixed effects, are included in the probit regression but not tabulated.

Table 7 reveals that while Bank Specialty significantly predicts loan default for both sub-samples,

the economic impact of soft information is more prominent for the high-earnings management sub-sample,

as the magnitude of the marginal effect for Bank Specialty is uniformly larger, regardless of the proxies

used for earnings management. For example, when using the magnitude of accruals as a proxy for

earnings management, a 1% increase in bank specialty leads to a 1.2% reduction in loan default

probability for firms in the low earnings management sub-sample, the decline is almost twice—a 2.0%—

among firms in the high earnings management sub-sample.16

To summarize, we find that the bank’s soft information plays a more prominent role in predicting

loan default when the borrowing firm is more likely to manage its earnings. This result is consistent with

the findings in Table 5, suggesting that the bank relies more on its soft information when hard-

information is less credible.

7. ROBUSTNESS

7.1 Omitted Hard Information

Our proxy for soft information, Bank Specialty, is the residual component from regressing the

bank’s internal credit rating score against a set of firm-specific hard information variables (Table 4 Panel

A Column 1). Intuitively, this proxy represents the part of the internal credit rating that is not predicted by

hard information proxies. However, it is possible that instead of the bank’s soft information, Bank

Specialty reflects firm-specific hard information that is not captured by our existing proxies.

16 In untabulated regressions, we further divide the high earnings management sub-sample based on the depth of lending relationship. We find that the magnitude of marginal effect associated with Bank Specialty is significantly larger for firms that have a sustained relationship with the bank. For example, when using the magnitude of accruals as a proxy for earnings management, a 1% increase in Bank Specialty leads to a 1.7% decrease for non-state-owned firms, but the decline widens to 3.1% for state-owned firms. Using duration of banking relationship instead of state-ownership as a proxy for the depth of lending relationship, the marginal effect is -1.4% for firms that have a short-term banking relationship, compared to -2.6% for firms that have a long-term banking relationship.

Page 26: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

24

As we have discussed before, soft information differs from hard information in that it is not easily

and accurately conveyed, verifiable, or transferable. Therefore, if Bank Specialty were merely a proxy for

omitted firm-specific hard information, then its effect on predicting loan default should not vary with the

depth of lending relationship. Instead, Table 5 shows that to the extent that Bank Specialty displaces hard

information depends on whether the borrowing firm has a profound banking relationship.

Nevertheless, we check the robustness of our results with respect to potential omitted hard

information in three separate sets of tests outlined in sub-sections 7.1.1 through 7.1.3. As these robustness

analyses indicate, we find similar results.

7.1.1 Large firm sub-sample

We restrict our sample to large firms whose assets are greater than or equal to the sample median

of RMB 109.07 million. Compared to small firms, firm-specific hard information for large firms is more

readily available, and the information contents are less noisy. Therefore, Bank Specialty less likely

contains hard information factors that are significantly related to loan default, yet completely orthogonal

to our existing hard information proxies. In addition, the impact of factors other than information about

industry, size, and financial statements to predict default—such as background of senior management—is

less prominent within large firms, and hence less likely drives our findings.

We repeat the analyses (as those in Tables 3-5) for the large firm sub-sample. Although our

overall sample is reduced by half, we find similar results. For example, when re-estimating the results in

Table 5, Bank Specialty continues to be negatively related to loan default for all six sub-samples, and is

statistically significant at 1% except for the sub-sample of state-owned firms, where the coefficient is

negative and significant at 10% (p = 0.053). Cash, a proxy for hard information subject to easy

manipulation, is significantly related to the incidence of loan default only when the borrowing firm does

not have a profound banking relationship. ROA, on the other hand, becomes insignificant regardless of

the depth of lending relationship.

Page 27: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

25

7.1.2 Bank Specialty based on difference-in-difference analysis

In our main analysis, we construct Bank Specialty as the residual component of Table 4 Panel A

Column 1, where the level of internal credit rating score is regressed against a set of firm-specific hard

information proxies. As a robustness check, we replace Bank Specialty using the residual component from

the difference-in-difference analysis in Table 4 Panel B Column 1. This approach helps to mitigate the

impact of the omitted time-invariate hard information on our results. We then re-estimate the regression

model [2].

Since the bank started its internal credit rating system in 2004 and the difference-in-difference

analysis demands at least two years of data, this approach dramatically decreases the number of

observations. With fewer observations making the estimations difficult to converge, we are only able to

estimate regression [2] for frequency-based proxy for the depth of relationship. Nevertheless, we find

similar results: The coefficient estimate (marginal effect) for Bank Specialty is -0.219 (-0.000) for

infrequent borrowers, and is -0.582 (-0.012) for frequent borrowers, significant at 5% and 1% levels,

respectively.

7.1.3 Sensitivity of soft information to omitted hard information

How sensitive is our soft information proxy to omitted hard information? If the magnitude of the

coefficient estimate and marginal effect for Bank Specialty varies significantly across different sets of

hard information proxies, then it is possible that our soft information proxy is sensitive to the choice of

hard information, thus omitted variables could potentially have a significant effect on our results.

As a robustness check, we randomly exclude two variables from our existing set of hard

information proxies each time and re-estimate our main regressions. We then compare the coefficient and

marginal effect associated with Bank Specialty between our main results and the results based on the sub-

set of hard information proxies.

We find that the magnitude and sign of the coefficient and marginal effect for Bank Specialty

does not vary significantly to the change in the set of hard information proxies. For example, in the

Page 28: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

26

analysis where the variables Previous Default and Maturity are excluded, the coefficient estimate

(marginal effect) for Bank Specialty in probit regression model [2] is -0.215 (-0.015) for infrequent

borrowers, and is -0.256 (-0.020) for frequent borrowers; is -0.217 (-0.014) for firms with short banking

relationships, but is -0.250 (-0.017) for firms with long banking relationships. All of the coefficient

estimates are significant at 1% level. In the analysis where hard information variables Asset Turnover and

Sales Growth are excluded, the coefficient for Bank Specialty is -0.211 (-0.014) for infrequent borrowers,

and is -0.257 (-0.019) for frequent borrowers; is -0.255 (-0.015) for non-state-owned firms, and is -0.181

(-0.017) for state-owned firms. In addition, while the coefficients for ROA remain insignificant for firms

with a profound banking relationship, they are now significant at 1% for firms lacking a profound

banking relationship.

Note that the above results are not driven by the potential multicollinearity among hard

information proxies. Multi-collinearity diagnostic test for Table 3 yields a VIF value less than 2.21 for

individual hard information variable (except for State and State×Size)—far below the threshold level of

10—suggesting that our hard information proxies are not highly correlated. In another set of robustness

check, we use alternative specifications for some of the hard information variables (see sub-section 7.2.3

for more details) and find similar results. Together these results suggest that the Bank Specialty variable is

not sensitive to the potential omitted hard information proxies.

7.2 Alternative Variable Specification

7.2.1 Alternative measures for the depth of banking relationship

We repeat the analyses in Table 5 for the following alternative specifications for the depth of

banking relationship proxies: instead of dividing borrowing frequency and duration of banking

relationship based on sample medians, we divide them based on sample terciles. In another alternative

specification, we define a banking-relationship based on a firm’s previous borrowing frequency. Namely,

a firm is classified as a frequent borrower if for its loans originated in 2004 it has borrowed more than 4

times from the bank (the sample median) in 2003, or if for its loans originated in 2005 it has borrowed

Page 29: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

27

more than 5 times (the sample median) during the period of 2003-2004. Our results are robust to these

alternative measures.

7.2.2 Alternative definitions of defaults

The bank of our loan sample assigns its annual internal credit rating score to individual firms

instead of to loans. In addition, 72% of our sample firm-year observations are involved with default of all,

rather than some, short-term loans within a year. Therefore, we conduct our main analyses at firm-level

and define default as occurring when at least one of the short-term loans borrowed by the firm in a given

year is marked by the bank as either written off or unpaid.

We now examine how “partial default”—a firm defaults on some, but not all, of its short-term

loans within a year—affects our results. We first re-estimate our results by excluding firms that partially

default on their loans from our sample. Alternatively, we re-define default as when all the short-term

loans borrowed by the firm in a given year are written off or unpaid. Our results remain unchanged for

both cases.

In another robustness check, we separate between loans that are written off and those that are

unpaid. Among 673 defaulted loans within our sample, 16% are marked as written off, and the rest are

recorded as unpaid. We restrict loan default as unpaid loans only, and re-estimate Tables 4 and 5. Our

results hold.

7.2.3 Alternative variable constructions for firm-specific hard information

As a robustness check, we re-estimate our basic models in Tables 3-5 using several alternative

proxies for hard information. Instead of book value of asset, we use the number of employees per firm as

a proxy for size. In our main regressions, we include log(GDP) to control for the degree of regional

economic development. Alternatively, we replace log(GDP) with regional GDP growth to capture macro-

economic uncertainty. Our results are robust to these variations of firm-specific hard information

measures.

Page 30: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

28

7.3 Alternative Sample Specification

7.3.1 Loan-level analysis

Since our bank assigns the annual internal credit rating score to individual firms, and among our

sample firms that have defaulted on their loans, 72% of them default all of their loans, our main analysis

is conducted at firm-level. To check the robustness of our results, we repeat our analyses at loan-level for

Tables 4 and 5 (for Table 4, standard errors are clustered at firm-level). Thus default is defined as

occurring if a short-term loan is recorded by the bank as written off or unpaid. We find similar results. For

example, when estimating Table 5 at loan-level, Bank Specialty remains negative in predicting loan

default and is highly significant for all three proxies for the depth of lending relationship. In addition, in

the presence of soft information, ROA is significant at 1% for infrequent borrowers, firms with a short

banking relationship, and non-state-owned firms, while remaining insignificant for frequent borrowers

and firms with a long banking relationship. It becomes marginally significant (10%) for state-owned firms.

The results with respect to Cash are a bit weaker: While the coefficient is significant at 1% for firms

lacking a profound banking relationship, it is only insignificant for frequent borrowers and state-owned

firms.

7.3.2 Matched samples for ownership proxy

One of our proxies for the depth of lending relationship is state ownership. Table 1 indicates that

there is a significant difference in number of firms, loan size, assets, and employees between state-owned

and non-state-owned sub-samples. To check the robustness of our results, we re-estimate the last two

columns of Table 5 using a matched sample. Specifically, for each sample year, we match a state-owned

firm with a non-state-owned firm by industry and size. Match is conducted without replacement. We then

compare the role of the bank’s soft information over the two matched sub-samples.

We find that Bank Specialty continues to be negatively and significantly associated with the

propensity of loan default, and that the magnitude of the marginal effect remains smaller among non-

state-owned firms than among state-owned firms. In addition, our previous results about the depth of

Page 31: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

29

lending relationship hold: even for the non-state-owned firms of similar sizes and operating in the same

industries as their matched state-owned firms, nearly half of the firm-specific fundamental factors remain

statistically significant in the presence of Bank Specialty. In contrast, almost all the hard information

proxies become insignificant for state-owned firms.

8. CONCLUSION

In this paper we study the nature and role of banks’ soft information, which evolved from a

sustained lending relationship with firms, in the context of loan default. Using a proprietary database from

one of the largest state-owned commercial banks in China, we first document that proxies for firm-

specific hard information, such as financial ratios derived from firms’ financial statements, are

significantly related to the probability of loan default, and that the bank’s internal credit rating scores play

an important role in predicting default.

Further analysis reveals that while the internal credit rating does incorporate firm-specific hard

information, it is the soft information component of these ratings that contributes to the improvement in

assessing credit quality. In addition, we find that to what extent soft information prevails over hard

information depends on the depth of the lending relationship. When evaluating loan delinquency, a strong

repeated lending relationship allows soft information to substitute, rather than complement, the role of

hard information, especially the hard information that is subject to easy manipulation by Chinese firms.

Our findings also indicate that, at least with regard to credit ratings, loan decisions by Chinese banks are

based on commercial principles instead of government policies, which may have contributed to the

overall performance improvement of Chinese banks in recent years.

Page 32: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

30

REFERENCES Allen, Franklin, Rajesh Chakrabarti, Sankar De, Jun Qian, and Meijun Qian, 2008, The Financial System

Capacities of China and India, Working Paper, Boston College. Agrawal, Sumit, and Robert Hauswald, 2008, Distance and private information in lending. Working

Paper, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago and American University. Altman, Edward, I., 1968, Financial ratios, discriminant analysis and the prediction of corporate

bankruptcy, Journal of Finance 23, 589-609. Berger, Allen, N., W. Scott Frame, and Nathan H. Miller, 2005, Credit scoring and the availability, price,

and risk of small business credit, Journal of Money, Banking, and Credit 37, 191-222. Berger, Allen N., Nathan H. Miller, Mitchell A. Petersen, Raghuram G. Rajan, Jeremy C. Stein, 2005,

Does function follow organizational form? Evidence from the lending practices of large and small banks, Journal of Financial Economics 76, 237-269.

Berger, Allen N., and Gregory F. Udell, 1995, Relationship lending and lines of credit in small firm

finance, Journal of Business 68, 351-381. Boyd, John H., and Edward C. Prescott, 1986, Financial intermediary-coalitions, Journal of Economic

Theory 38, 211-232. Cerqueiro, Geraldo, Hans Degryse, and Steven Ongena, 2008, Rules versus discretion in loan rate setting,

Working Paper, Tilburg University. Chang, Chun, and Yijiang Wang, 1994, The nature of township-village enterprises, Journal of

Comparative Economics 19, 434-452. Chen, Kevin, and Hongqi Yuan, 2004, Earnings management and capital resource allocation: Evidence

from China’s accounting-based regulation of rights issues, Accounting Review 74, 645-665. Czarnitzki, Dirk, and Kornelius Kraft, 2001, Are credit ratings valuable information? ZEW Discussion

Paper No. 04-07, Center for European Economic Research. Dechow, Patricia M., Richard G. Sloan, and Amy P. Sweeney, 1995, Detecting earnings management,

Accounting Review 70, 193-225. Diamond, Douglas, 1984, Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring, Review of Economic

Studies 51, 393-414. Dow, James, and Gary Gorton, 1997, Stock market efficiency and economic efficiency: Is there a

connection? Journal of Finance 52, 1087-1129. Efron, B. 1979, Bootstrap methods: Another look at the jackknife, Annals of Statistics 7, 1-26. English, William B., William R. Nelson, 1999, Bank risk rating of business loans. In Proceedings of the

35th Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition.

Page 33: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

31

Frame, W. Scott, Aruna Srinivasan, and Lynn Wooseley, 2001, The effect of credit scoring on small-business lending, Journal of Money, Banking, and Credit 33, 813-825.

Garber, Steven G., and Dale J. Poirier, 1974, The determinants of aerospace profit rates, Southern

Economic Journal 41, 228-238. Gorton, Gary, and Andrew Winton, 2003, Financial intermediation, In G. Constantinides, M. Harris, and

R. Stulz (eds.), Handbooks in the Economics of Finance, Volume 1A: Corporate Finance, Elsevier Science.

García-Herrero, Alicia, Sergio Gavilá, and Daniel Santabárbara, 2006, China’s banking reform: An

assessment of its evolution and possible impact, CESifo Economic Studies 52, 304-363. Grunert, Jens, Lars Norden, and Martin Weber, 2005, The role of non-financial factors in internal credit

ratings, Journal of Banking and Finance 29, 509-531. Leuz, Christian, Dhananjay Nanda, and Peter D. Wysocki, 2003, Earnings management and investor

protection: An international comparison, Journal of Financial Economics 69, 505-527. Peterson, Mitchell A. 2004. Information: Hard and soft, Working Paper, Northwestern University. Petersen, Mitchell A., and Raghuram G. Rajan, 1994, The benefits of lending relationship: Evidence from

small business data, Journal of Finance 49, 3-37. Poirier, Dale J., 1974. The Econometrics of Structural Change, Amsterdam: North Holland. Ramakrishnan, Ram, T. S., and Anjan V. Thakor, 1984, Information reliability and a theory of financial

intermediation, Review of Economic Studies 51, 415-432. Scott, Jonathan A., 2004, Small business and the value of community financial institutions, Journal of

Financial Services Research 25, 207-230. Uchida, Hirofumi, Gregory F. Udell, and Nobuyoshi Yamori, 2007, SME financing and the deployment

of lending technologies in Japan, Working Paper, Indiana University.

Page 34: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

32

Appendix I. A Description of the Bank’s Internal Credit Rating System

In 2004, our bank implemented an internal credit rating system. Credit rating is done through the

bank’s risk management guidelines, which we describe below. Following these general guidelines, the

officer of the credit and risk management department of the bank uses a rating card to assign a credit

score to a borrowing firm when it applies for the first loan of that year, normally at the beginning of the

year. The rating card contains three general categories: borrower’s financial positions, non-financial

conditions, and financing status. These three categories are further divided into various sub-categories.

To complete the rating card requires information based on the borrower’s financial statements

(including balance sheet, income statement, and cash flow statement), ratio analyses (including short-term

and long-term solvency, and profitability), operating performance and investment, management quality,

internal control system, capital management, corporate strategy, corporate governance, as well as the

officer’s evaluation and forecast on the trend, advantages, risks, and future performance of the borrower.

Some of the categories incorporate the inputs from the loan officer at the local branch where the

borrower submits the loan application. The officer at the credit and risk management department of the

bank then completes the remaining categories with information obtained through his/her independent

research and investigations (including repeated interviews with the borrower), verifies the information

from the local loan officer, and provides his/her own evaluation and forecasts. He/she then rates the

borrower’s quality in each of the three categories.

The general guideline issued by the bank also contains a set of private weights assigned to the

categories of the rating card. These weights are set according to the characteristics of Chinese firms and

past lending experience. The final score is calculated by taking the weighted average.

The bank then rates the borrower based on this credit score. The credit rating ranks from one to

12, with one being the lowest (poorest credit quality) and 12 the highest (highest credit quality). None of

the credit quality information is shared with other banks or sources. The credit rating thus reflects the

bank’s evaluation of the borrower’s overall credit quality. As the above description indicates, the rating

reflects both the objective and subjective estimates from the bank.

Page 35: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

33

Appendix II. Loan Characteristics of the Dataset

In this appendix we provide a general description of loan characteristics for the entire dataset,

rather than for the sample used in the regressions. We include all loans in our dataset that are originated

during a given calendar year with a specific maturity date in a different calendar year. With only the end-

of-year data available, short-term loans made and repaid in the same calendar year are not included in the

sample unless there is a default.

AII.1 Loan Size and Maturity

Table A1 reports the summary statistics for the two main loan characteristics—size and

maturity—over our sample period. We observe that short-term loans constitute the major source of

funding for Chinese firms. In fact, on average, 95% of loans in our sample have a maturity of one year or

less, accounting for 84.45% of the aggregate outstanding principals. By contrast, loans of medium or

long-term maturity, and firms receiving such loans, are much less common. Loans with maturity

exceeding one year account for only 15.54% of total outstanding principal.

Table A1 indicates that, unlike micro loans commonly seen in small business lending practices,

our sample loans are dominated by commercial loans—which are less studied in the literature. For

example, a back-of-the-envelope calculation shows that the average principal of loans with one year

maturity is RMB 47.069 million in 2005 (approximately $5.85 million). For loans with maturity

exceeding one year, the average loan size is even higher: RMB 168.993 million (approximately $21.02

million).

Table A1 also compares the loan characteristics between state-owned and non-state-owned firms.

While the number of non-state-owned firms receiving bank financing far exceeds the number of state-

owned firms, and the number of short-term loans (maturity of one year or less) originated to non-state-

owned firms is higher, state-owned firms receive on average larger principal amount than non-state-

owned firms.

Page 36: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

34

Starting 2004, the year when our bank introduced its internal credit rating system for individual

firms, there has been a steady increase in the number of firms without state background securing short-

term, medium-term, and long-term loans, in the number of loans, as well as principal amount initiated for

this type of firm. On the other hand, there is a steady decrease in both number of firms being funded and

number of loans and principal amount initiated for state-owned firms. Despite the fact that state-owned

firms overall borrow at a larger amount than non-state-owned firms, especially for loans of long-term

maturity, the gap between the two diminishes. In 2006, both types borrow an almost equal amount.

AII.2 Crediting Rating and Loan Default Rate

Table A2 reports the summary statistics for the bank’s internal credit rating scores and the

subsequent short-term loan default rates. Since the bank implemented an internal credit rating system in

2004, we restrict the analysis to the 2004-2006 period. Table A2 reveals that the internal credit rating for

firms borrowing short-term loans generally increases over this period. For example, the average rating for

one-year loans increases from 7.9 in 2004 to 8.4 in 2006. Since short-term loans constitute the majority of

loans outstanding, this indicates an overall improvement in loan quality during the sample period,

probably due to a tougher and more skilled screening process by the bank for the borrowers.

When partitioning the sample into state-owned and non-state-owned sub-samples, it is the state-

owned firms that attribute to this overall improvement in credit quality. At the time when the bank

implemented the internal rating system, state-owned firms on average had significantly lower rating

scores—therefore poorer credit quality—than non-state-owned firms for loans with a maturity of less than

one year (7.377 for state-owned firms versus 7.921 for non-state-owned firms). Over time, however, loans

initiated to state-owned firms are consistently rated higher than those for non-state-owned firms,

especially over longer maturities. For example, the average internal rating score for loans with medium

maturity (more than one year but less than five years) in 2006 is 1.44 higher for state-owned firms

(10.026 for state-owned firms versus 8.587 for non-state-owned firms). The difference is also statistically

significant.

Page 37: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

35

Table A2 reveals that consistent with the improvement in credit rating of short-term loans over

our sample period, there has been a decline in loan defaults for all sample firms. Prior to the

implementation of the internal credit rating system, 14.71% of firms with loans of less than one year

maturity and 16.97% of firms with one year loans originated in 2003 were in default stage by 2004. After

the installment of the internal credit rating system there has been a sharp decline in loan defaults despite

the increase in the number of short-term loans. For example, 13.03% of firms with one year loans

originated in 2004—the year when the internal credit rating system was in place—were in the default

stage by 2005, a 23% drop. Furthermore, only 4.37% of firms with one year loans originated in 2005

were in default in 2006.

Interestingly, the decline is more dramatic for stated-owned firms: 25.7% loans of less than one

year maturities were pass-due in 2004, whereas in 2006 only 3.1% of such loans were pass-due. In

addition, while the default rate on loans originated in 2003 for state-owned firms on average was higher

than for non-state-owned firms, the difference between the two groups of firms is no longer statistically

significant for loans originated in 2005.

Page 38: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

36

Table A1. Loan characteristics for Chinese firms

The sample period is 2003-2006. A firm is classified as stated-owned if it is owned or controlled by the government.

Loan maturity Number of firms Number of loans Total principal amount (billion RMB)

Overall State-owned Non-state-owned Overall State-owned Non-state-owned Overall State-owned Non-state-owned 2003 <1 year 1,860 494 1,366 9,793 4,665 5,128 57.32 35.13 22.19 1 year 806 333 473 3,029 1,692 1,337 32.69 25.03 7.66 >1 & <=5 years 263 91 172 768 367 401 15.11 10.57 4.55 >5 years 16 10 6 54 45 9 2.1 1.93 0.17 2004 <1 year 1,512 287 1,225 4,967 1,471 3,496 45.61 26.25 19.36 1 year 744 225 519 2,783 1,128 1,655 30.6 19.52 11.08 >1 & <=5 years 117 56 61 333 208 125 9.84 8.06 1.78 >5 years 9 8 1 64 62 2 4.54 4.39 0.15 2005 <1 year 1,685 213 1,472 5,156 1,165 3,991 43.37 22.05 21.32 1 year 619 167 452 2,149 847 1,302 29.14 18.73 10.41 >1 & <=5 years 90 35 55 311 164 147 13.68 11.1 2.57 >5 years 7 5 2 58 49 9 2.04 1.86 0.19 2006 <1 year 1,968 175 1,793 5,822 981 4,841 48.7 24.46 24.24 1 year 839 155 684 2,394 867 1,527 33.15 21.21 11.94 >1 & <=5 years 142 38 104 371 142 229 10.23 5.54 4.69 >5 years 6 2 4 21 8 13 1.4 0.45 0.95

Page 39: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

37

Table A2. Internal credit rating and default rate for Chinese firms The sample period is 2003-2006. Internal credit rating starts in 2004. A crediting rating score ranks from 1 to 12, with 1 being the lowest credit quality and 12 the highest. Short-term loan default rate is based on the fraction of short-term (one year or less) loans that are not paid or are written off at the end of the subsequent year. Among loans mature in less than one year, only these with a maturity of more than six months and initiated on and after 1st July are included. A firm is classified as stated-owned if it is owned or controlled by the government. t-statistics testing the difference in mean internal credit rating between state-owned and non-state-owned firms are based on uneven variance. ***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively. Internal credit rating Short-term loan default rate Overall State-owned Non-state-owned

t-statisticsOverall State-owned Non-state-owned

χ2 Obs. Mean Obs. Mean Obs. Mean Obs. Mean Obs. Mean Obs. Mean (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (4) - (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (10) - (12) 2003

<1 year 1,164 14.71% 311 25.70% 853 10.70% 41.219*** 1 year 806 16.97% 333 21.90% 473 13.50% 9.753*** >1 & <=5 years >5 years

2004 <1 year 1,045 7.775 281 7.377 764 7.921 -2.508** 1,059 7.77% 198 14.60% 861 6.20% 16.246*** 1 year 659 7.900 221 7.891 438 7.904 -0.056 744 13.03% 225 14.70% 519 12.30% 0.755 >1 & <=5 years 95 9.547 52 9.750 43 9.302 1.114 >5 years 7 10.429 7 10.429

2005 <1 year 1,641 7.932 209 7.981 1,432 7.925 0.268 1,129 1.90% 160 3.10% 969 1.70% 1.634 1 year 601 8.191 163 8.276 438 8.160 0.515 619 4.37% 167 2.40% 452 5.10% 2.12 >1 & <=5 years 73 9.397 31 10.323 42 8.714 3.531*** >5 years 4 8.250 3 9.000 1 6.000

2006 <1 year 1,966 8.153 175 8.366 1,791 8.132 1.208 1 year 839 8.400 155 8.755 684 8.319 2.158** >1 & <=5 years 142 8.972 38 10.026 104 8.587 4.591*** >5 years 6 9.667 2 10.500 4 9.250 1.263

Page 40: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

38

APPENDIX III. Variable Definitions

Variables Definition Measured as of Year Default A dummy variable that equals one if a firm defaults on

its short-term loans, and equals zero otherwise. Default occurs if the short-term loan is unpaid or written off at the end of the following year.

This variable is measured at one year after the year when the loan is originated.

Rating Bank’s internal credit rating score. The score is 12 for a firm with the highest credit rating, and 11 for the second highest credit rating, and so on. It is 1 for the lowest credit rating.

This variable is measured as of the year when the loan is originated.

Listed Firm A dummy variable equal to one if a firm is publicly traded, and zero otherwise.

Size The natural log of book value of total assets at the end of year.

This variable is measured at one year before the year when the loan is originated.

Leverage Financial leverage, calculated as total liabilities divided by total assets at the end of year.

ROA Return on assets, calculated as net income divided by total assets.

Asset Turnover Asset turnover ratio, calculated as total sales divided by total assets.

Cash Cash reserve ratio, calculated as the sum of cash and short-term investments divided by total assets at the end of year.

Sales Growth Sales growth is calculated as the difference in the natural log of sales between current year and previous year.

Previous Default A dummy variable equal to one if a firm has defaulted loans before, and zero otherwise.

This variable is measured as of the year when the loan is originated.

Maturity Weighted average of short-term loan maturities borrowed by a firm in year. The weight is based on loan principales.

Log(GDP) The natural log of GDP per capita of the province where the loan is originated.

State A dummy variable equal to one if a firm is owned or controlled by the state, and zero otherwise.

Page 41: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

39

Table 1. Descriptive statistics for sample firms Dummy variable Default equals 1 if at least one of the short-term loans borrowed by a firm in a given year is in default stage during the subsequent year, and 0 otherwise. Internal credit rating ranks from one to 12, with one being the lowest credit quality and 12 the highest. Assets are of book value and are in RMB 100 million. Employees are the total number of employees per firm. Other variables are defined in Appendix III. The t-statistics are based on uneven variance. ***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively. 2004 2005

Default = 0 Default = 1 t-statistics Default = 0 Default = 1 t-statisticsPanel A: Overall sample Rating 8.30 5.38 11.009*** 8.40 4.55 7.218*** Assets (in RMB 100 million) 12.40 3.71 4.927*** 12.05 3.00 5.414*** Number of Employees 2,707 1,160 3.667*** 2,252 789 4.274*** Leverage 0.51 0.56 -3.015*** 0.48 0.55 -2.147** ROA 0.07 0.03 8.563*** 0.09 0.05 2.796*** Asset Turnover 1.00 0.80 3.885*** 1.25 0.90 4.004*** Cash 0.07 0.05 5.149*** 0.07 0.04 4.183*** Sales Growth 0.34 0.16 2.803*** 0.33 0.23 1.233 Panel B: State-owned firms Rating 8.23 5.11 6.533*** 8.32 4.38 3.220** Assets (in RMB 100 million) 32.91 7.46 4.920*** 44.33 2.12 6.870*** Number of Employees 7,720 2,467 3.939*** 8,876 893 6.107*** Leverage 0.55 0.62 -2.621** 0.54 0.66 -1.779 ROA 0.04 0.02 3.599*** 0.05 0.01 1.955* Asset Turnover 0.79 0.71 1.175 0.83 0.68 1.639 Cash 0.09 0.06 2.556** 0.09 0.04 3.531*** Sales Growth 0.23 0.22 0.066 0.25 0.15 0.723 Panel C: Non-state-owned firms Rating 8.33 5.53 8.744*** 8.41 4.60 6.346*** Assets (in RMB 100 million) 4.77 1.68 2.753*** 4.25 3.24 0.762 Number of Employees 843 454 4.446*** 653 761 -0.415 Leverage 0.49 0.52 -1.623 0.46 0.52 -1.568 ROA 0.09 0.04 7.317*** 0.10 0.06 2.332** Asset Turnover 1.08 0.86 3.316*** 1.36 0.96 3.722*** Cash 0.07 0.04 5.235*** 0.07 0.03 3.263*** Sales Growth 0.38 0.13 3.217*** 0.35 0.25 1.013

Page 42: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

40

Table 2. Correlation analysis Dummy variable Default equals 1 if a firm defaults on at least one of its short-term loans during the subsequent year, and 0 otherwise. Internal credit rating ranks from 1 to 12, with 1 being the lowest credit quality and 12 the highest. Size is the log of book value of total assets. Other variables are defined in Appendix III. ***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively. Default Rating Size Leverage ROA Asset Turnover Cash Sales Growth State Rating -0.365*** Size -0.057*** 0.323*** Leverage 0.114*** -0.247*** 0.289*** ROA -0.178*** 0.322*** -0.280*** -0.402*** Asset Turnover -0.114*** 0.090*** -0.320*** -0.147*** 0.495*** Cash -0.112*** 0.183*** 0.145*** 0.084*** 0.070*** 0.107*** Sales Growth -0.069*** 0.152*** 0.019 -0.057*** 0.180*** 0.175*** 0.063*** State 0.059*** -0.044** 0.486*** 0.208*** -0.297*** -0.230*** 0.115*** -0.078*** Log(GDP) -0.187*** 0.052** -0.185*** -0.107*** 0.207*** 0.218*** 0.005 0.047** -0.306***

Page 43: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

41

Table 3. Determinants of loan default This table reports the probit regression results. The dependent variable is the dummy variable Default equal to 1 if a firm defaults on at least one of its short-term loans during the subsequent year, and 0 otherwise. Size is the log of book value of total assets. State is a dummy variable equal to 1 if the firm is either owned or controlled by the state government and 0 otherwise. Size, ROA, Cash, and Sales Growth are measured as one year prior to the time the loan was originated and described in Appendix III. Industry classification is based on five manufacturing industries. Robust standard errors are reported in the parentheses. Marginal effects are reported in the square brackets. ***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively. (1) (2) (3) Constant 3.675*** 0.595*** 2.720** (1.17) (0.14) (1.26) Rating -0.229*** -0.227*** (0.02) (0.02) [-0.020] [-0.016] Size -0.148*** 0.034 (0.04) (0.04) Leverage 0.682** -0.385 (0.31) (0.32) ROA -4.049*** -0.163 (1.23) (1.05) Asset Turnover -0.157 -0.047 (0.11) (0.10) Cash -2.725*** -1.891** (0.85) (0.86) Sales Growth -0.034 0.015 (0.08) (0.07) State 2.607** 1.759 (1.10) (1.16) State×Size -0.136** -0.098 (0.06) (0.06) Previous Default 0.524** 0.053 (0.20) (0.23) Maturity 0.110*** 0.106*** (0.03) (0.04) Listed Firm -0.071 -0.051 (0.27) (0.30) log(GDP) -0.330*** -0.380*** (0.09) (0.09) Industry Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Year Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes McFadden’s R2 0.211 0.254 0.293 Wald χ2 174.5*** 268.0*** 298.1*** No. of observations 2,063 2,063 2,063

Page 44: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

42

Table 4. Does internal credit rating incorporate firm-specific hard information? In Panel A, the dependent variable is the internal credit rating, ranking from one to 12, with one being the lowest credit quality and 12 the highest. All the firm-specific hard information variables are described in Appendix III. Industry classification is based on five manufacturing industries. In Panel B, the dependent variable in the OLS regression takes a value of 1 if there is a change in credit rating from 2004 to 2005. In the ordered probit regression the dependent variable takes a value of 1 if a firm’s internal credit rating improves from 2004 to 2005, -1 if it deteriorates, and 0 otherwise. Robust standard errors are reported in the parentheses. ***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively. Panel A Overall sample State Non-state (1) (2) (3) Constant -4.592*** -11.788*** -3.650*** (1.17) (2.28) (1.32) Size 0.816*** 1.040*** 0.797*** (0.03) (0.06) (0.03) Leverage -3.727*** -5.099*** -3.338*** (0.30) (0.69) (0.33) ROA 9.491*** 21.922*** 7.759*** (0.85) (2.18) (0.80) Asset Turnover 0.244*** 1.180*** 0.145** (0.07) (0.26) (0.07) Cash 3.507*** 2.372** 3.517*** (0.52) (1.11) (0.58) Sales Growth 0.249*** 0.116 0.267*** (0.08) (0.11) (0.10) State -4.073*** (1.20) State × Size 0.166*** (0.06) Previous Default -1.689*** -1.440*** -1.729*** (0.32) (0.36) (0.55) Maturity -0.059*** 0.049 -0.095*** (0.02) (0.06) (0.02) Listed Firm 0.209 0.100 -0.199 (0.20) (0.23) (0.48) log(GDP) -0.100 -0.029 -0.117 (0.10) (0.19) (0.11) Industry Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Year Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes R2 0.44 0.64 0.38 Adjusted R2 0.43 0.63 0.38 F 87.31*** 62.22*** 56.55*** No. of observations 2,063 489 1,574

Page 45: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

43

Table 4 continued. Panel B OLS Order Probit (1) (2) Constant -0.462 (1.29) ΔSize 0.452** 0.156 (0.21) (0.19) ΔLeverage -2.358*** -1.760*** (0.70) (0.59) ΔROA 7.455*** 6.913*** (1.42) (1.14) ΔAsset Turnover 0.292 0.093 (0.24) (0.21) ΔCash 0.859 0.784 (0.79) (0.73) ΔSales Growth 0.096 0.076 (0.08) (0.06) State -0.020 -0.210* (0.15) (0.13) Previous Default -1.063*** -0.474** (0.39) (0.21) Maturity -0.043 -0.041 (0.03) (0.03) Listed Firm 0.056 0.112 (0.18) (0.18) log(GDP) 0.069 0.006 (0.12) (0.10) Industry Fixed Effect Yes Yes Year Fixed Effect Yes Yes

R2 0.15 Pesudo R2 0.07 F 5.827*** Wald χ2 78.12*** No. of observations 670 670

Page 46: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

44

Table 5. Bank specialty, relationship lending and loan default The dependent variable of the probit regression is the dummy variable Default equal to 1 if a firm defaults on at least one of its short-term loans during the subsequent year, and 0 otherwise. Bank Specialty is the residual from the OLS regression Table 4 Panel A Column 1. A firm is stated-owned if it is owned or controlled by the state government. A firm is classified as a frequent (infrequent) borrower if it has borrowed from the bank more than (at most) 12 times during the sample period, where 12 is the sample median. For a given firm in a given year, duration is computed as the difference between the month that the firm obtained its first loan in that year and the earliest recorded time of its previous loans prior to that month. A firm is classified as having a long- (short-) term relationship with the bank if the duration is greater than (less or equal to) 23 months. Firm-specific variables are defined in Appendix III. Industry classification is based on five manufacturing industries. For each regression model, we report the coefficient estimates and bootstrapped standard errors (in parentheses). Marginal effects are reported in square brackets. ***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively.

Page 47: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

45

Table 5 continued.

Borrowing frequency

Duration of banking relationship

Firm’s ownership

Infrequent Frequent Short Long

Non-state-owned

State-owned

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) Constant 4.877*** 4.608** 5.103*** 3.074 5.050*** 2.535 (1.84) (2.27) (1.58) (2.51) (1.55) (2.98) Soft information proxy Bank Specialty -0.214*** -0.254*** -0.216*** -0.261*** -0.251*** -0.186*** (0.04) (0.04) (0.03) (0.05) (0.03) (0.05) [-0.014] [-0.019] [-0.013] [-0.015] [-0.015] [-0.017] Hard information proxies Size -0.196*** -0.180*** -0.164*** -0.292*** -0.164*** -0.259*** (0.06) (0.06) (0.04) (0.07) (0.05) (0.07) Leverage 0.608 0.359 0.249 0.949 0.230 1.053 (0.46) (0.52) (0.39) (0.70) (0.36) (0.80) ROA -2.839** -1.140 -2.132** -2.854 -2.452** -2.831 (1.44) (1.35) (1.05) (2.30) (1.09) (3.07) Asset Turnover -0.090 -0.013 -0.044 -0.226 -0.113 -0.059 (0.13) (0.21) (0.12) (0.25) (0.13) (0.29) Cash -3.515*** -1.849 -2.717*** -3.142 -3.403** -1.232 (1.28) (1.51) (0.89) (2.49) (1.41) (1.45) Sales Growth 0.047 -0.284 -0.085 0.159 -0.172 0.162 (0.11) (0.25) (0.09) (0.22) (0.15) (0.18) Previous Default 0.294 0.453 0.430 0.290 0.529 0.215 (0.39) (0.33) (0.36) (0.29) (0.35) (0.42) Maturity 0.110** 0.134* 0.101* 0.175* 0.110** 0.109 (0.06) (0.08) (0.06) (0.09) (0.05) (0.10) Listed Firm -0.227 -0.201 -0.683*** 0.097 -0.112 -0.080 (0.31) (0.40) (0.25) (0.45) (0.36) (0.32) log(GDP) -0.393*** -0.403** -0.448*** -0.084 -0.442*** -0.018 (0.13) (0.17) (0.11) (0.22) (0.11) (0.26) Industry Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Year Fixed Effect Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

McFadden’s R2 0.321 0.279 0.292 0.341 0.315 0.307 Wald χ2 147.80*** 84.37*** 181.00*** 73.53*** 187.60*** 60.98*** No. of observations 1,065 998 1,367 696 1,574 489

Page 48: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

46

Table 6. The content of soft information and loan default The dependent variable of the probit regression is the dummy variable Default equal to 1 if a firm defaults at least one of its short-term loans during the subsequent year, and 0 otherwise. Bank Specialty is the residual from the OLS regression of Table 4 Panel A Column 1. Firm-specific hard information variables are defined in Appendix III. Industry classification is based on five manufacturing industries. Column 1 reports the results from the probit regression. Column 2 reports the results from spline regression, where the spline cutoff points are based on the terciles of Bank Specialty. For each regression model, we report the coefficient estimates and bootstrapped standard errors (in parentheses). Marginal effects are reported in square brackets. ***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively.

Page 49: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

47

Table 6 continued. (1) (2) Constant 4.548*** 4.395*** (1.35) (1.27) Soft information proxy Bank Specialty -0.227*** (0.03) [-0.016] Bank Specialty Spline 1 (lowest) -0.291*** (0.04) [-0.021] Bank Specialty Spline 2 -0.059 (0.13) [-0.004] Bank Specialty Spline 3 (highest) -0.169 (0.14) [-0.012] Hard information proxies Size -0.189*** -0.185*** (0.03) (0.03) Leverage 0.554* 0.498 (0.33) (0.34) ROA -2.435** -2.514*** (0.97) (0.96) Asset Turnover -0.106 -0.105 (0.11) (0.11) Cash -2.808*** -2.795*** (0.92) (0.90) Sales Growth -0.046 -0.046 (0.09) (0.08) Previous Default 0.420* 0.373 (0.23) (0.24) Maturity 0.120*** 0.118*** (0.04) (0.04) Listed Firm -0.189 -0.188 (0.30) (0.32) log(GDP) -0.370*** -0.375*** (0.10) (0.10) Industry Fixed Effect Yes Yes Year Fixed Effect Yes Yes McFadden’s R2 0.289 0.293 Wald χ2 252.5*** 269.00*** No. of observations 2,063 2,063

Page 50: INFORMATION FROM RELATIONSHIP LENDING: EVIDENCE …assets.csom.umn.edu/assets/153167.pdfinformation to substitute for, rather than complement, the role of hard information, especially

48

Table 7. Bank specialty and hard information subject to manipulation: The case of earnings management This table reports the coefficient estimate and marginal effect for Bank Specialty in the probit regression model [2]. The sample contains private firms only. In Panel A, earnings management is based on the magnitude of accruals as in Leuz, Nanda, and Wysocki (2003). In Panel B, earnings management is base on industry-adjusted non-operating income as in Chen and Yuan (2004). In Panel C, earnings management is based on discretionary accruals as in Dechow, Sloan and Sweeney (1995). The dependent variable in the probit regression is the dummy variable Default equal to 1 if at least one of the short-term loans borrowed by the firm is written off or unpaid at the end of the subsequent year, and 0 otherwise. Bank Specialty is the residual from the OLS regression of Table 4 Panel A Column 1. Industry and year fixed effects as well as the same set of firm-specific hard information proxies as those in Table 5 are included in the regression analyses but are not tabulated. Industry classification is based on five manufacturing industries. Bootstrapped standard errors are reported in parentheses. Marginal effects are reported in square brackets. ***, **, and * indicate significance at 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively.

Low Earnings Management High Earnings Management Coefficient No. of obs. Coefficient No. of obs.

Panel A. Magnitude of Accruals

Bank Specialty -0.223*** 982 -0.220*** 981

(0.04) (0.04) [-0.012] [-0.020]

Panel B. Industry-adjusted Non-operating Income

Bank Specialty -0.229*** 951 -0.245*** 950

(0.05) (0.04) [-0.010] [-0.020]

Panel C. Discretionary Accruals

Bank Specialty -0.244*** 983 -0.242*** 983

(0.04) (0.04) [-0.015] [-0.020]


Recommended