Date post: | 19-Feb-2020 |
Category: | Documents |
View: | 3 times |
Download: | 0 times |
1
Ingredient Branding Strategies in an Assembly Supply Chain:
Models and Analysis
Juan Zhang, Qinglong Gou, Liang Liang
School of Management, University of Science & Technology of China,
Hefei, Anhui, 230026, P.R.China
[email protected], [email protected], [email protected]
Xiuli He
Belk College of Business, University of North Carolina at Charlotte,
Charlotte, NC 28223-0001
mailto:[email protected]
2
Abstract
We consider a supply chain in which an original equipment manufacturer (OEM)
procures a key component from a supplier. We consider an ingredient branding strategy under
which the supplier and the OEM form a brand alliance. Specifically, the supplier invests in
ingredient branding to build up her goodwill and additionally she shares a portion of the
OEM’s advertising cost through a cooperative advertising program. Under a differential game
framework, we obtain the equilibrium advertising efforts of the supplier and OEM, and the
supplier’s equilibrium subsidy rate for the cooperative advertising program. We further
extend the model to the case in which the OEM procures two complementary components
from two suppliers. We consider three different scenarios of supplier interaction, i.e., the
suppliers are (I) independent, (II) allied and keep two brands, and (III) allied and keep one
brand. We demonstrate how the different interactions between suppliers affect the channel
members’ advertising efforts, goodwill levels, and their profits.
Keywords: Ingredient Branding, Cooperative advertising, Goodwill, Differential game
models
3
1. Introduction
Owing to the Intel’s huge success in its “Intel Inside” program, Ingredient Branding, as a
special brand alliance form which emphasizes on identification of components in the final
product, is picking up in popularity in recent years. According to Kotler and Pfoetsh (2010),
Ingredient Branding is the brand policy concerning a branded object of materials,
components, or parts (raw materials, component materials, or component parts) that
represents a brand for the respective target group. Besides Intel, a number of companies from
different industries have successfully used Ingredient Branding strategy. Examples include
DuPont, Dolby Laboratories, Tetra Pak, Microban and so on.
According to the motivation behind it, Ingredient Branding can be manufacturer- initiated
or supplier-initiated one (Norris, 1992). In manufacturer-initiated Ingredient Branding, the
Original Equipment Manufacturer (OEM) usually chooses an existing ingredient brand with
strong brand awareness and promotes the fact that this ingredient is part of his final products.
Supplier-initiated Ingredient Branding occurs when a component supplier promotes her
ingredient to final users in efforts to build up brand awareness.
Combing the two kinds of Ingredient Branding together, Luczak et al. (2007) proposed a
new concept of InBranding, which is shown in Figure 1. To create the brand awareness of her
ingredient brand, the ingredient/component supplier forms an alliance with an OEM in a
supply chain framework. Under the alliance, the component supplier leaps the OEM and
communicates to final users directly (supplier-initiated Ingredient Branding), whereas the
OEM labels the ingredient brand logos in his final products, trying to persuade final users that
his products have certain positive attributes which are related to this ingredient brand
(manufacturer-initiated Ingredient Branding).
4
Figure 1. InBranding framwork
InBranding strategy could create a win-win situation (Luczak et al., 2007). For the
component suppliers, such a strategy enables them to communicate their product offerings
and performance directly to end consumers and hence increase their brand equity.
Accordingly, the component suppliers gain greater bargaining power as the brand awareness
of suppliers will result in the consumers’ request or pulling the ingredient brands from the
OEMs. Furthermore, the good brand image built in consumers makes the component
suppliers escape the anonymity and substitutability of supplying a part or component by
competitors easily. For the downstream OEMs, incorporating a reliable supplier’s component
may enhance the image of their end products and increase demand due to the superior
performance of a key component.
Doyle (1989) argues that advertising is central to the process by informing consumers of
inherent product benefits and positioning the brand in the mind of the consumer. Our model
focuses on advertising decisions for InBranding and tries to answer the following questions:
Ingredient
Supplier
OEM
Final user
Cooperative
advertising program
Manufacturer-Initiated
Ingredient Branding
Advertising efforts
Demand Supply
Supply Demand
Supplier-Initiated
Ingredient Branding
Advertising efforts
5
(i) When a component supplier implements her InBranding strategy, what are her optimal
advertising efforts directly to final users? (ii) What are the OEM’s optimal advertising
efforts?
Furthermore, noting that Intel has launched one of the largest cooperative advertising
program in the world to stimulate computer OEMs to label the “Intel Inside” logos in their
computers for its InBranding strategy, we also incorporate cooperative advertising decisions
in our model, trying to illustrate: (iii) Whether and under what condition should a component
supplier offer a cooperative advertising program to her OEM when she implements an
InBranding strategy? (iv) And if so, what is the supplier’s optimal subsidy rate under a
cooperative advertising program?
To answer the above questions, we consider a supply chain in which an OEM procures a
key component from a supplier. To implement the InBranding strategy, the supplier not only
builds up her goodwill through advertising, which is just the same as the OEM, but also
shares a portion of the OEM’s advertising cost via a cooperative advertising program. Noting
that building a brand is a long-term process and must be regarded as an investment in the
future (Meenaghan, 1995), we model the impact of advertising efforts on the goodwill of the
two channel members in a Nerlove-Arrow framework. Specifically, the goodwill of the OEM
depends on his own advertising and the supplier’s goodwill level whereas the supplier’s
goodwill depends on her own ingredient branding efforts and the OEM’s advertising efforts.
The sales of the final products are expressed as a function of the OEM’s advertising efforts
and goodwill. Under a Stackelberg-Nash game framework, we calculate out the equilibrium
advertising efforts of the supplier and OEM, as well as the supplier’s optimal subsidy rate for
her cooperative advertising program.
Main findings include the following. First, the component supplier shares the OEM’s
advertising cost only when her profit margin exceeds a threshold. Second, the supplier will
not advertise directly to final users if the OEM does not label her component brand logos in
his final products. Third, the supplier’s decisions on her own advertising efforts and subsidy
rate of the cooperative advertising program can be made separately. That is to say, the
6
supplier’s optimal subsidy rate of the cooperative advertising program does not depend on
whether the supplier implements an supplier-initiated Ingredient Branding strategy (i.e., the
supplier advertises directly to the final users), it is just influenced by the relative magnitude
of the OEM’s and the supplier’s profit margins.
In practice, there are usually multiple component suppliers for OEMs and the marginal
profit threshold plays a key role when a firm decides whether to offer a cooperative
advertising program to its partner (Huang and Li, 2001; Jørgensen et al., 2000; 2001; Li et al.,
2002). We extend our model to the case in which the OEM procures two complementary
components from two suppliers in three different scenarios in which the suppliers are (I)
independent, (II) allied and keep two brands, and (III) allied and keep one brand. We attempt
to address the following questions: How does a complementary component supplier affect a
supplier’s ingredient branding strategy? Whether the two suppliers should cooperatively offer
a cooperative advertising program when they implement ingredient branding strategies?
Analysis of the extended models result in the following findings: (i) Whether or not a
supplier should offer the OEM a cooperative advertising program depends on the supplier’s
own profit margin and not on the other supplier’s profit margin; (ii) Suppliers will share a
part of the OEM’s advertising costs when their profit margins exceed a threshold level; (iii) If
both share the OEM’s co
Click here to load reader