+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Institutional similarity, Institutions™ quality and trade.

Institutional similarity, Institutions™ quality and trade.

Date post: 02-Apr-2022
Category:
Upload: others
View: 3 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
28
1 Institutional similarity, Institutions quality and trade. Emmanuelle LavallØe EURIsCO UniversitØ Paris Dauphine Place du MarØchal de Lattre de Tassigny 75016 PARIS Mail : [email protected] RESUME : This paper uses a gravity model to assess the impact on trade of the proximity and the quality of institutions. A new index of institutional similarity is proposed. It is computed on the basis of data on national legal traditions. The model includes 145 countries and is estimated with panel data over the period 1984-2002. The estimation results clearly show that institutional proximity increases bilateral trade. However, this paper leads to reconsider the impact of bad governance, and especially of corruption on international trade. Indeed, the results show that the consequences on trade of institutions quality are more complex than the recent literature has suggested it.
Transcript

1

Institutional similarity, Institutions� quality and trade.

Emmanuelle Lavallée

EURIsCO

Université Paris Dauphine

Place du Maréchal de Lattre de Tassigny

75016 PARIS

Mail : [email protected]

RESUME :

This paper uses a gravity model to assess the impact on trade of the proximity and the quality

of institutions. A new index of institutional similarity is proposed. It is computed on the basis

of data on national legal traditions.

The model includes 145 countries and is estimated with panel data over the period 1984-2002.

The estimation results clearly show that institutional proximity increases bilateral trade.

However, this paper leads to reconsider the impact of bad governance, and especially of

corruption on international trade. Indeed, the results show that the consequences on trade of

institutions� quality are more complex than the recent literature has suggested it.

2

I INTRODUCTION

A recent literature suggests that the quality and the kind of national institutions matter to

international trade. Anderson & Van Wincoop (2004, p.6) assert that �Poor institutions and

poor infrastructure penalize trade, differentially across countries�, and that �Trade costs are

richly linked to economic policy. Direct policy instruments (tariffs, the tariff equivalents of

quotas and trade barriers associated with the exchange rate system) are less important than

other policies� and particularly the quality of national institutions (p.1). At the same time,

some studies imply that similar institutions foster trade (Rose, 2000). Indeed, institutional

proximity must partly explain why a former colony still trade more than predicted by the

gravity equation with its ex-colonizer, and why two countries having had the same colonizer

have larger than expected bilateral trade flows.

However, analyses on the consequences of bad governance on international trade are

relatively scarce (Anderson & Marcouiller, 2002; Anderson & Young, 1998) and the impact

on trade of institutional similarity has not been explored further. As regard institutional

similarity, no different proxies than a common colonial past have been proposed. As regard

the quality of institutions, the main study is the one of Anderson & Marcouiller (2002). It

shows that insecurity related to imperfect contract enforcement and corruption acts as a

hidden tax on trade, and then substantially reduces its volume. Few empirical studies have

gone deeper into this issue. Yet, the progress realised in the measure of institutional quality

allows both to increase the sample and to add a time dimension to it.

The purpose of this paper is three fold. Firstly, it combines the literatures about the

consequences on the international trade of institutional proximity and of the quality of

national institutions. It proposes a new indicator of institutional similarity computed on the

basis of the data of La La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer et Vishny (1999) that classify

countries according to their legal origin. Secondly, it tests whether, as supposed by Anderson

& Marcouiller (2002), bad governance is an obstacle to international trade, and more

particularly whether corruption acts as a hidden tax or tariff. To do so, I use the recent

developments in the specification of the gravity equation and the proper econometric

techniques, notably when the traditional cross section formulation is augmented in order to

include a time dimension. Indeed, I apply the Hausman Taylor estimator to a specification of

3

the gravity equation extracted from Anderson and Van Wincoop (2003, 2004) which

explicitly includes a trade cost function inspired by Anderson & Marcouiller (2002). Thirdly,

I propose an alternative vision of the consequences of bad governance on international trade

which allows the interaction between corruption and the others aspects of governance. This

specification intends to assess second best theories that consider corruption as way to bypass

rigidities imposed by governments.

Section two presents the recent literature on the impact on trade of institutional similarity and

of the quality of national institutions. Section three explains the specification of the gravity

equation and the estimation technique. Section four present our first results. Section five tests

an alternative view of the consequences of weak national institutions on trade. Section six,

concludes.

II NATIONAL INSTITUTIONS AND INTERNATIONAL TRADE

The sort and the quality of national institutions appear to impact dramatically international

trade.

According to Disdier & Mayer (2005), the kind of national institutions and more specifically

similarity between institutional frameworks can explain the important and robust impact of

colonial links on bilateral exchanges1. Such institutions involve legal rules and administrative

systems. Sharing similar institutional frameworks can ease international trade by improving

contract enforcement and reducing transaction costs. However, the colonial relationship

captures other phenomenon. Indeed, it also reveals the existence of formal or informal

networks. Colonizers have usually established trade networks in their colonies, and those

networks can persist even after the decolonization. The explanatory power of international

migration patterns should not be neglected either. Lastly, colonial links don�t exhaust every

case of institutional similarity. Indeed, countries having had no colonial relationship can have

the same institutional framework. As such, national laws are fine examples. They are typically

not written from scratch, but rather transplanted from a few legal families or traditions

(Waston,1974; La Porta, Lopez de Silanes, Shleifer & Vishny). Those families or traditions

1 Rose (2000) shows that, for the year 2000, that, everything else equal, the colonial link increases trade by a factor 5.75, while having had a common colonizer raises countries bilateral trade by 80%.

4

have spread around the world through a combination of conquest, colonisation, imitation or

voluntary adoption. That is why this article investigates the consequences on international

trade of institutional similarity with new indicator. It is computed on the basis of the data of

La Porta, Lopez de Silanes, Shleifer & Vishny (1999) on countries� legal origin. It

distinguishes five national commercial legal traditions: common law, French civil law,

German civil law, Scandinavian law and socialist law. The variable of institutional similarity

takes the value of one if the national laws of the trading partners have the same legal origin

and zero otherwise.

Anderson and Marcouiller (2002) first demonstrate the importance of strong institutions on

international trade. They build a model of import demand in an insecure world. They show

that predation by thieves or by corrupt officials generates a price mark-up equivalent to a

hidden tax or tariff, which extent depends on the quality of institutions for the defence of

trade. This price mark-up significantly constrains trade by two channels: a substitution effect

between traded goods and non traded goods, and a real income effect. Anderson and

Marcouiller�s structural model is quite singular. Indeed, they use a variant of the traditional

gravity model: they divide imports of j from i by k imports from i, which cancels the exporter

price index. The importer relative price index is approximated with a Törnqvist index.

Working on relative imports addresses a specification error that plagues many empirical

studies, i.e. the estimation of highly non linear specific exporter and importer price indexes.

In order to estimate their model, the authors use data provided by the World Economic Forum

(WEF) to evaluate the strength of national institutions for the defence of trade. They test the

model for the year 1996 for a sample of 48 importing countries, half of them being developed

countries. They find that trade increases dramatically when it is supported by strong

institutions. They conclude that: �If the seven Latin American countries of the sample were to

enjoy the same transparency and enforceability scores as the mean scores of the members of

the European Union, predicted Latin American imports volume would rise by 30%� (p349).

However, this literature leaves out �second best� theories which regard corruption as a

�beneficial grease� for trade. Indeed, �second best� analysis see corruption as a way to bypass

rigidities imposed by governments. Bhagwati (1982, p. 993) suggests that corruption must be

analysed as a Directly Unproductive Profit-seeking activity (DUP), that is to say a way �of

making profits by undertaking activities that are directly unproductive�(p989). In the area of

international trade, corruption can be compared to others DUP activities such as tariff evasion

or smuggling. As long as these activities occur in initially distorted situations, second best

5

analysis applies and DUP should enhance welfare. Although, such theories do not directly

study the effect of corruption on the volume of international trade, they present corruption as a

mean of greasing the wheels of commerce.

Next section�s objective is to specify gravity models so as to test just as well Anderson &

Marcouiller�s view, as �second best� theories. To do so, I use the recent developments in the

specification of the gravity equation and the proper econometric techniques, notably when the

traditional cross section formulation is augmented in order to include a time dimension.

Indeed, our gravity models include 144 countries and are estimated with panel data over the

period 1984-2002.

III SPECIFICATION OF THE GRAVITY EQUATION AND DATA

A Trade barriers and gravity equation

I use the specification of the gravity equation of Anderson & Van Wincoop (2003, 2004).

Anderson & Van Wincoop demonstrate that, in a one sector economy, when consumers have

CES preferences with common elasticity among all goods, the gravity equation can be written

as:

σ−

ΠΠ=

1

jP

i

ijt

wY

jY

iY

ijX (1)

j1ij

tii

1i

1j

P ∀σ−θ∑ −σΠ=σ− (2)

σ−∑ θ−σ=σ−Π 1ij

tj j

1j

P1i

(3)

Where Yi et Yj are levels of GDP, Yw is world GDP, et θi is income share of country i, et tij is

trade costs. With symmetry of trade costs (tij = tji), then Пi=Pi, and equation (1) then becomes:

σ−

=

1

jP

iP

ijt

wY

jY

iY

ijX (4)

6

Where Pi and Pj are « multilateral resistance » terms. They summarize the average trade

resistance between a country and its trading partners. Two ways have been suggested to

model multilateral resistance: a complex nonlinear estimation technique of Pi and Pj (see

Anderson & Van Wincoop, 2003) and the introduction of country fixed effects (see Rose and

Van Wincoop, 2003; Feenstra, 2004). Both approach lead to consistent estimates of the

gravity model parameters (see Anderson & Van Wincoop, 2003; Feenstra, 2004). However,

both suggestions don�t seem relevant in time series cross sections estimations2. Hence, I

introduce the following remoteness indicators (Remotnessi,j) as proxies of multilateral

resistance terms:

∑=π

∑≠

π=

k ktrade

jtrade

j

)ij

cetandisln(ij ji

motnessRe

(5a)

∑=π

∑≠

π=

k ktrade

itrade

i

)ij

cetandisln(ji ij

motnessRe

(5b)

With k the countries of the world and trade the sum of exports and imports

I model the barrier-to-trade function, between countries i and j, in two ways.

Firstly, following Anderson & Marcouiller (2002), I model the next barrier-to-trade function.

8j

S7i

SijRTA

6ijSIMILARITY

5ijCOL

4ijL

3ijB

2e1ij

Dij

t∂∂

∂++∂∂+∂+∂∂= (6)

With :

- Dij the distance between the countries i and j ;

- Bij, dummy variable indicating a common frontier between i and j;

2 The model is estimated over the period 1984-2002 and a sample of 145 exporting countries and 144 importing countries.

7

- Lij a dummy variable that takes the value of one if the two trading partners share a

common language and zero otherwise;

- COLij is a binary variable which is equal unity if i ever colonized j and vice versa.

- SIMILARITYij is a dummy variable equals to one if the trading partners have

similar institutions and zero otherwise ;

- RTAij dummy variable indicating a common belonging to a preferential trade

agreement (RTAij).

- Si(j) the quality of institutions of country i(j).

In this formulation, weak national institutions raise trade costs. Increasing distance between

trading partners increase transport costs. However, if the importer and the exporter share a

common border, a common language, a colonial past or similar institutions that encourage

familiarity and may enhance the importer and the exporter�s skills in using the institutions of

its partner and then decrease transactions costs. Lastly, the belonging to a common

preferential trade agreement may reduce trade costs.

Secondly, in order to test specifically �second best� theories, I introduce the following

barrier-to-trade function. In comparison with the previous formulation, it has the distinctive

feature of allowing interactions between the corruption and the other elements of governance.

)j

Sln109

(

jCOR

)i

Sln87

(

iCOR

ijRTA

6ijSIMILARITY

5ijCOL

4ijL

3ijB

2e1ij

Dij

t

∂+∂×

∂+∂×

∂++∂∂+∂+∂∂=

(7)

Where :

- CORi(j) the level of corruption in country i(j) ;

- Si(j) the quality of institutions (without corruption)in country i(j) ;

- Other variables are defined as in equation (7)

Substituting equation (6) into (4) and taking logs,

ijw

jSln

12iSln

11ijRTA

10

ijSIMILARITY

9ijCOL

8ijL

7ijB

6ijDln

5

jmotnessRe

4imotnessReln

3jYln

2iYln

10ijXln

+β+β+β+

β+β+β+β+β+

β+β+β+β+β=

(8)

8

Where the world GDP is absorbed in the constant error term, wij is the error term, and with

the expected signs3 :

( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( ) 0

81

12;0

71

11;0

61

10

;05

19

;04

18

;03

17

;02

16

;01

15

;04

;03

;02

;01

>∂σ−=β>∂σ−=β>∂σ−=β

>∂σ−=β>∂σ−=β>∂σ−=β

>∂σ−=β>∂σ−=β<β<β>β>β

Similarly, substituting equation (7) into (4) and taking logs, the gravity equation becomes:

ijw

jCORln)

jSln

1413(

iCORln)

iSln

1211(

ijRTA

10

ijSIMILARITY

9ijCOL

8ijL

7ijB

6ijDln

5

jmotnessRe

4imotnessReln

3jYln

2iYln

10ijXln

+β+β+β+β+β+

β+β+β+β+β+

β+β+β+β+β=

(9)

The expected signs of parameters β1 to β10 are the same as in equation (8). One the other hand,

the �grease the wheels hypothesis� will not be rejected if β11 and β13 are positive and β12 and

β14 are negative. Indeed, under the �grease the wheels� hypothesis corruption shall have a

positive impact on trade if the quality of governance if very law. Law quality of governance

implies lnSi(j) close to zero. With lnSi(j) close to zero, β11(13) must be positive for corruption to

have a positive impact on bilateral trade. With high quality of governance the impact of

corruption will become negative. In order to get such impact, β12(14) must be negative.

B Panel specification

In order to take into account exports flows� heterogeneity, I estimate my gravity equation with

panel data model. They enable to identify the country pair specific effect and to isolate them4.

The model (8) specified for panel data becomes:

ijtv

ijijtRERln

12ijCOL

11ijRTA

10

ijL

9ijB

8ijDln

7jSln

6iSln

5

jmotnessRe

4imotnessReln

3jYln

2iYln

1t0ijXln

+µ+α+α+α+

α+α+α+α+α+

α+α+α+α+α+α=

(10)

3The model proposed by Anderson & van Wincoop (2003) imposes the constraint, 1

21=β=β . But, here, this

constraint is relaxed. 4 A model with three specific effects: exporter, importer and time is only a restricted version of the more general model which allows country pair heterogeneity adopted here ( Carrère, 2005; Cheng & Wall, 1999; Endoh, 1999)

9

The model (9) specified for panel data becomes:

ijtv

ijijtRERln

14ijCOL

13ijRTA

12

ijL

11ijB

10ijDln

9jCORln)

jSln

87(

iCORln)

iSln

65(

jmotnessRe

4imotnessReln

3jYln

2iYln

1t0ijXln

+µ+α+α+α+

α+α+α+α+α+α+α+

α+α+α+α+α+α=

(11)

Where :

− α0 effect common to all year and pairs of countries;

− αt effect specific to year t but common to all pairs of countries ;

− µij specific effect to each pairs of countries and common to all years;

− vijt an error term.

I introduce the bilateral real exchange rate (RERijt) so as to capture the evolution of

competitiveness (Soloaga & Winters, 2001; Bayoumi & Eichengreen, 1997). An increase in

the bilateral exchange rate reflecting a depreciation of the importing country currency against

that of the exporting country, the expected sign of 14

α is positive.

C Econometric issues

The first issue is the choice of the specification of the individual effects and then of the

estimation method of the gravity equations. Remind that my purpose is to assess the impact

on international trade flows of institutions� quality and similarity. The institution similarity

variable is time invariant. Therefore, we can not use the fixed effects model that treats the

individual specific effects as fixed and gives unbiased parameters estimates for time varying

variables, since it does not allow the estimation of the effects of variables constant in their

time dimension.

A way to deal with this issue is to model individual effects as random variables, in other

words use the random effects model. However, when there is correlation between the

explanatory variables and the individual effects, the estimations produce by the random

effects model are not consistent. Here, the Hausman test (1978), based on differences between

the estimators of the fixed effects model and the random effects one, confirms that parameters

estimated with the random effects models are biased.

10

So as to tackle this problem, I use the Hausman Taylor estimator5(HT). Hausman & Taylor

(1978) propose an instrumental variable estimator that enables to estimate the parameters of

time invariant variables, and where some explanatory variables are correlated with individual

specific effects. The Hausman & Taylor estimator allows the estimation of consistent

parameters for time varying and time invariant explanatory variables. The definition of

independent variables as exogenous or endogenous is tested by a Hausman test of over-

identification, based on the comparison of the Hausman Taylor estimator and the within

estimator (estimator of the fixed effects model).

The second issue is the existence of zero export flows which can lead to selection bias6. Many

approaches have been suggested in the literature: replace them by small values, use TOBIT

models, use (1 + Xijt) rather than Xijt as trade measure. Here, I use a method applied by

Carrere (2005) to test and to correct a potential selection bias. This method, proposed by

Nijman & Verbeek (1992), approximates the Heckman correction term by adding variables

that reflects the presence of each country pair in the sample. The flowing variables are added:

• PRES: number of year of presence of the pair ij in the sample;

• DD: dummy variable that takes the value of one if the pair ij is observed during the

entire period, and zero otherwise;

• PAt: dummy variable that takes the value of one if ij was present in t-1, and zero

otherwise.

D Data7

Data on governance are extracted from the International Country Risk Guide�s (IRCG). They

are available over the period 1984-2002. More precisely, we use three IRCG ratings:

�corruption�, �Bureaucratic Quality�, �Law and Order�. All range in value from 0-6, with

higher values indicating �better� ratings, i.e. less corruption, better bureaucratic quality, etc�.

The Corruption index relates to the abuse of public office for private gains. Specifically,

lower scores indicate "high government officials are likely to demand special payments" and

that "illegal payments are generally expected throughout lower levels of government" in the

5 See Carrere (2005) for details on the Hausman-Taylor estimator in the context of gravity panel estimation. 6 I.e. the probability of a pair of countries being included in the sample is not independent of the model error, and particularly to the individual effects. 7 Annex 1 exposes the data and their computation.

11

form of "bribes connected with import and export licenses, exchange controls, tax assessment,

police protection, or loans." To avoid awkwardness in interpreting the coefficients, I recode

the ��corruption�� measure in this paper so that a high number reflects a high level of

corruption: ICRG here equals 7 minus the original ICRG index.

For the Bureaucratic Quality index, high scores indicate "an established mechanism for

recruitment and training," "autonomy from political pressure," and "strength and expertise to

govern without drastic changes in policy or interruptions in government services" when

governments change.

Last, �Law and Order� is an assessment of the strength and impartiality of the legal system, as

well as a measure of popular observance of the law.

We use these variables individually, but following Knack (1999), we also compute an overall

indicator of governance by taking the simple average of the corruption, the rule of law, and

the bureaucratic quality original indicators.

The institutional similarity is computed on the basis of the data of La Porta, Lopez de

Silanes, Shleifer & Vishny (1999) on countries� legal origin.

Data on 1984-2002 exports in current US dollars are taken from the Direction of Trade

Statistics (DOTS) published by the International Monetary Fund. Exports flows are deflated

by the American Consumer Price Index (World Development Indicators, 1995=100). Data on

GDP in constant US dollars (1995=100) are taken from the World Bank�s World

Development indicators (WDI). The real exchange rates are computed on the basis of IFS

data. Distances from capital city to capital city on the basis of geographical coordinates are

taken from the CEPII database as well as the adjacency and common language dummies. I

compose dummy variables so as to capture common membership in a preferential trade

agreement, and a colonial relationship.

12

IV IS BAD GOVERNANCE A BARRIER TO INTERNATIONAL TRADE?

First I estimate equation (10) using the overall governance indicator as a measure of

institutional quality. Table 1 reports the estimation of equation (10) with the Hausman Taylor

estimator as well as various sensitivity tests. Table 2 summarizes the main steps followed in

the estimation and the results of the appropriated statistical tests to justify the choice of this

�final� regression. It considers as endogenous the variables of GDP, distance, remoteness,

governance and real exchanges rate. My comments are based on this �final� regression

corrected of the selection bias (Table 1, column 2).

Concerning the traditional gravity variables, coefficients have the expected sign and are

significant at the 1% level. Exports volumes from i to j increase with GDP and parameters

estimates are close to unity as suggested by the theory. The elasticity of bilateral trade to

distance is -0.86 and the coefficients for the remoteness variables are significantly negative.

Sharing a common border raises bilateral exports by a factor 2.23 (e0.8), and speaking a

common language increase trade by 180% (e1.03-1). A common belonging to a preferential

trade agreement raises trade by a factor 1.4 (e0.36). Lastly, a real depreciation of the currency

of the exporting country leads to an increase of its exports.

Institutional similarity has a positive impact on bilateral exports. Indeed, its parameter

estimate is positive and significant at the 1% level. The fact that two countries share the same

institutional framework increases bilateral exports by 60% (e0.47-1).

The consequences of institutional quality on international trade are questionable, particularly

as far as the quality of governance in the importing country is concerned. Indeed, the

coefficient of the exporter quality of institution variable is positive and significant, indicating

that an increase in quality of governance in the exporting country raises bilateral trade. The

parameter estimate of the quality of governance in the importing country is also positive and

significant at the 10% threshold. But, the robustness checks (table 1 columns 3 and 4) shows

that this result is very sensitive to sample size variations. When the sample size is reduced the

coefficient of the importer governance is not significantly different of zero. Nevertheless,

coefficient estimates of the institutional similarity and of the exporter quality of governance

appear quite robust. Parameter estimates remain positive and highly significant.

13

Table 1: Institutional similarity, governance quality and international trade

1a 2b 3c 4d

LnGDPit 1,35*** 1,15*** 1,14*** 1,09***[0,01] [0,02] [0,02] [0,02]

LnGDPjt 1,06*** 0,86*** 0,86*** 0,84***[0,01] [0,02] [0,02] [0,02]

Remotnessit -0,74*** -0,91*** -0,91*** -1,01***[0,10] [0,10] [0,10] [0,09]

Remotnessjt -1,62*** -1,81*** -1,78*** -1,74***[0,11] [0,11] [0,10] [0,10]

Lndistanceij -0,80*** -0,86*** -0,83*** -0,78***[0,09] [0,09] [0,08] [0,09]

LnRERijt 0,02*** 0,02*** 0,02*** 0,02***[0,00] [0,00] [0,00] [0,00]

LnGovernanceit 0,17*** 0,19*** 0,18*** 0,10***[0,03] [0,03] [0,03] [0,02]

LnGovernancejt 0,02 0,05* 0,04 0,03[0,03] [0,03] [0,03] [0,02]

Contiguityij 0,93*** 0,80*** 0,82*** 1,12***[0,23] [0,22] [0,22] [0,23]

Comon languageij 1,34*** 1,03*** 1,04*** 1,08***[0,10] [0,10] [0,10] [0,10]

RTAijt 0,40*** 0,36*** 0,37*** 0,38***[0,04] [0,04] [0,04] [0,04]

Colonyij -0,17 -0,03 -0,03 -0,08[0,25] [0,24] [0,24] [0,24]

Similarityij 0,58*** 0,47*** 0,47*** 0,49***[0,06] [0,06] [0,06] [0,06]

PRESij _ 0,07*** 0,06*** 0,04***_ [0,01] [0,01] [0,01]

DDij _ 0,06 0,08 0,12_ [0,08] [0,08] [0,08]

PAijt _ 0,13*** 0,14*** 0,13***_ [0,02] [0,02] [0,02]

Number of observations 135988,00 135988,00 135600,00 129927,00Number of pairs 11537,00 11537,00 11511,00 11189,00

Time specific effects 680,14 690,51 697,78 756,69Prob>chi2 0,00 0,00 0,00 0,00

***, **, and * significant at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively. Standard errors reported into brackets under coefficients. The time dummy variables and the constant are not reported to save space. a HT5 :endogenous variables: lnGDPit, lnGDPjt, lnDistanceij, lnGovernanceit, lnGovernancejt, remotnessit, remotnessjt et lnRERijt b HT5 : Addition of PRES, DD, PAt c ,d Values of the dependant variable that are respectively three and two standard deviations away from the mean are discarded.

14

Tabl

e 2:

Inst

itutio

nal s

imila

rity

, gov

erna

nce

qual

ity a

nd in

tern

atio

nal t

rade

, mod

el H

T5 se

lect

ion

EFEA

HT1

a H

T2b

HT3

cH

T4d

HT5

e Ln

GD

P it

1,18

***

1,20

***

1,33

***

1,36

***

1,35

***

1,28

***

1,35

***

[0

,02]

[0,0

1][0

,01]

[0

,01]

[0,0

1][0

,02]

[0,0

1]

LnG

DP j

t 0,

89**

*0,

91**

*1,

04**

* 1,

07**

*1,

06**

*0,

99**

*1,

06**

*

[0,0

2][0

,01]

[0,0

1]

[0,0

1][0

,01]

[0,0

2][0

,01]

R

emot

ness

it -0

,95*

**-0

,12*

**-0

,35*

**

-0,4

4***

-0,8

2***

-0,9

5***

-0,7

4***

[0,1

1][0

,04]

[0,0

7]

[0,0

7][0

,10]

[0,1

1][0

,10]

R

emot

ness

jt -1

,91*

**-0

,34*

**-0

,71*

**

-0,7

9***

-1,5

4***

-1,7

9***

-1,6

2***

[0,1

1][0

,04]

[0,0

7]

[0,0

7][0

,10]

[0,1

1][0

,11]

Ln

dist

ance

ij _

-1,1

2***

-0,4

7***

-0

,29*

**-0

,81*

**-0

,20

-0,8

0***

_[0

,03]

[0,0

8]

[0,0

9][0

,09]

[0,2

5][0

,09]

Ln

RER

ijt

0,02

***

0,01

***

0,01

***

0,01

***

0,01

***

0,02

***

0,02

***

[0

,00]

[0,0

0][0

,00]

[0

,00]

[0,0

0][0

,00]

[0,0

0]

LnG

over

nanc

e it

0,18

***

0,31

***

0,17

***

0,18

***

0,17

***

0,17

***

0,17

***

[0

,03]

[0,0

3][0

,03]

[0

,03]

[0,0

3][0

,03]

[0,0

3]

LnG

over

nanc

e jt

0,04

0,07

***

-0,0

1 0,

020,

020,

030,

02

[0

,03]

[0,0

3][0

,03]

[0

,03]

[0,0

3][0

,03]

[0,0

3]

Con

tigui

tyij

_0,

82**

*1,

80**

* 2,

11**

*0,

93**

*2,

18**

*0,

93**

*

_[0

,11]

[0,2

3]

[0,2

4][0

,23]

[0,5

7][0

,23]

C

omon

Lan

guag

e ij

_0,

70**

*1,

10**

* 1,

21**

*1,

34**

*1,

49**

*1,

34**

*

_[0

,06]

[0,1

1]

[0,1

1][0

,10]

[0,1

7][0

,10]

R

TAijt

0,

34**

*0,

42**

*0,

45**

* 0,

48**

*0,

40**

*0,

35**

*0,

40**

*

[0,0

5][0

,04]

[0,0

4]

[0,0

4][0

,04]

[0,0

4][0

,04]

C

olon

y ij

_1,

22**

*0,

43

0,20

-0,1

6-0

,22

-0,1

7

_[0

,16]

[0,2

7]

[0,2

7][0

,25]

[0,4

1][0

,25]

Si

mila

rity i

j _

0,28

***

0,43

***

0,47

***

0,58

***

0,59

***

0,58

***

_

[0,0

4][0

,07]

[0

,07]

[0,0

6][0

,10]

[0,0

6]

Num

ber o

f obs

erva

tions

13

5988

,00

1359

88,0

013

5988

,00

1359

88,0

013

5988

,00

1359

88,0

013

5988

,00

Num

ber o

f pai

rs

1153

7,00

1153

7,00

1153

7,00

11

537,

0011

537,

0011

537,

0011

537,

00

Tim

e sp

ecifi

c ef

fect

s 34

,06

407,

7352

5,83

55

7,91

680,

4269

1,54

680,

14

Prob

>F

0,00

__

__

__

Prob

>chi

2 _

0,00

0,00

0,

000,

000,

000,

00

Bila

tera

l Fix

ed E

ffec

ts

18,5

2_

_ _

__

_

15

Prob

>F

0,00

__

__

__

Hau

sman

test

fixe

d vs

rand

om e

ffec

tsf

_15

6,94

_ _

__

_ Pr

ob>c

hi2

_0,

00_

__

__

Hau

sman

HT

vs ra

ndom

eff

ects

g _

_53

8,62

56

5,23

270,

1525

,12

281,

79

Prob

>chi

2 _

_0,

00

0,00

0,00

0,00

0,00

Su

riden

tific

atio

n te

sth

__

303,

26

284,

8714

,16

0,00

0,00

Pr

ob>c

hi2

__

0,00

0,

000,

081,

001,

00

***,

**,

and

* si

gnifi

cant

at t

he 1

%, 5

% a

nd 1

0% le

vels

resp

ectiv

ely.

Sta

ndar

d er

rors

repo

rted

into

bra

cket

s und

er c

oeff

icie

nts.

The

time

dum

my

varia

bles

and

th

e co

nsta

nt a

re n

ot re

porte

d to

save

spac

e.

a HT1

:end

ogen

ous v

aria

bles

: lnG

DP i

t, ln

GD

P jt a

nd ln

Dist

ance

ij. b H

T2 :

endo

geno

us v

aria

bles

: lnG

DP i

t, ln

GD

P jt,

lnD

istan

ceij,

lnG

over

nanc

e it a

nd ln

gove

rnan

cejt

c HT3

: en

doge

nous

var

iabl

es: ln

GD

P it,

lnG

DP j

t, ln

Dist

ance

ij, ln

Gov

erna

nce it

, lnG

over

nanc

e jt, r

emot

ness

it et r

emot

ness

jt d H

T4 :

endo

geno

us v

aria

bles

: lnG

DP i

t, ln

GD

P jt,

lndi

stan

ceij,

lnG

over

nanc

e it, l

nGov

erna

nce jt

, rem

otne

ssit,

rem

otne

ssjt e

t RTA

ijt

e HT5

: en

doge

nous

var

iabl

es: ln

GD

P it,

lnG

DP j

t, ln

Dist

ance

ij, ln

Gov

erna

nce ij

t, ln

Gov

erna

nce jt

, rem

otne

ssit,

rem

otne

ssjt e

t lnR

ERijt

f Th

is te

st is

app

lied

to th

e di

ffer

ence

s bet

wee

n th

e fix

ed e

ffec

ts m

odel

and

the

rand

om e

ffec

ts m

odel

est

imat

es w

ithou

t tak

ing

into

acc

ount

the

coef

ficie

nt o

f tim

e ef

fect

s.

g H

auss

man

test

app

lied

to th

e di

ffer

ence

s bet

wee

n th

e ra

ndom

eff

ects

mod

el a

nd th

e H

T es

timat

ors,

with

out t

ime

effe

cts.

h Hau

sman

test

app

lied

to th

e di

ffer

ence

s bet

wee

n th

e fix

ed e

ffec

ts a

nd th

e H

T es

timat

ors,

with

out t

ime

effe

cts.

16

The previous results lead to change the barrier-to-trade function so as to introduce the various

aspects of governance, that is to say corruption, the quality of bureaucracy and the quality of

the judicial system. The column 2 of table 3 reports the estimation results with the Hausman

Taylor estimator and corrected of selection bias. Table 4 summarizes the main steps followed

in the estimation and the results of the appropriated statistical tests to justify the choice of this

�final� regression.

Concerning the traditional gravity variables, coefficients have the expected sign and are

significant at the 1% level again. The coefficient of the institutional similarity variable is

positive and highly significant. Besides, the parameter is close to the previous one.

However, institutional quality variables estimates are not conclusive. Indeed, neither

corruption, nor the judicial system quality, nor the bureaucracy quality of the importing

country have an impact of bilateral trade. Indeed, the coefficients of those variables are not

significantly different from zero. As regards the quality of governance in the exporting

country, estimation results shows that it impacts the exports volumes. The coefficient of the

corruption variable is positive and significant, indicating that an increase in corruption level

decreases bilateral trade. The parameters estimates of the bureaucracy and the judicial system

qualities are positive and significant, indicating that improvements in the qualities of the

judicial system and of the bureaucracy raise trade. Except for bureaucracy quality, these

results appear relatively robust to sample variations (table 4 columns 3 and 4)

17

Table 3 : Various aspects of governance and international trade

1a 2b 3c 4d

LnGDPit 1,35*** 1.15*** 1.14*** 1.09*** [0,01] [0.02] [0.02] [0.02]

LnGDPjt 1,06*** 0.86*** 0.86*** 0.84*** [0,01] [0.02] [0.02] [0.02]

Remotnessit -0,74*** -0.91*** -0.92*** -1.00*** [0,10] [0.10] [0.10] [0.09]

Remotnessjt -1,62*** -1.81*** -1.78*** -1.73*** [0,11] [0.11] [0.10] [0.10]

Lndistanceij -0,80*** -0.85*** -0.83*** -0.77*** [0,09] [0.09] [0.09] [0.09]

LnRERijt 0,02*** 0.02*** 0.02*** 0.02*** [0,00] [0.00] [0.00] [0.00]

LnCorruptionit -0,11*** -0.09*** -0.10*** -0.09*** [0,02] [0.02] [0.02] [0.02]

LnBureaucracyQualityit 0,10*** 0.11*** 0.10*** 0.08*** [0,02] [0.02] [0.02] [0.02]

LnLawandOrderit 0,02 0.05** 0.05** 0.01 [0,02] [0.02] [0.02] [0.02]

LnCorruptionjt -0,04* -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 [0,02] [0.02] [0.02] [0.02]

LnBureaucracyQualityjt 0,02 0.03 0.03* 0.03* [0,02] [0.02] [0.02] [0.02]

LnLawandOrderjt -0,05** -0.02 -0.02 -0.03 [0,02] [0.02] [0.02] [0.02]

Contiguityij 0,93*** 0.81*** 0.83*** 1.14*** [0,23] [0.22] [0.22] [0.23]

Common Languageij 1,34*** 1.03*** 1.05*** 1.09*** [0,10] [0.10] [0.10] [0.10]

RTAijt 0,39*** 0.36*** 0.37*** 0.37*** [0,04] [0.04] [0.04] [0.04]

Colonyij -0,19 -0.03 -0.03 -0.09 [0,25] [0.24] [0.24] [0.24]

Similarityij 0,60*** 0.48*** 0.48*** 0.50*** [0,06] [0.06] [0.06] [0.06]

PRESij _ 0.07*** 0.06*** 0.04*** _ [0.01] [0.01] [0.01]

DDij _ 0.04 0.07 0.10 _ [0.08] [0.08] [0.08]

PAijt _ 0.13*** 0.14*** 0.13*** _ [0.02] [0.02] [0.02]

Number of observations 135988,00 135988 135600 129927Number of pairs 11537,00 11537 11511 11189

Time Specific Effects 682,20 686.78 695.23 758.75Prob>chi2 0,00 0.00 0.00 0.00

***, **, and * significant at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively. Standard errors reported into brackets under coefficients. The time dummy variables and the constant are not reported to save space. a HT5 :endogenous variables: lnGDPit, lnGDPjt, lndistanceij, lnGovernanceit, lnGovernancejt, remotnessit, remotnessjt et lnRERijt b HT5 : addition of PRESij, DDij, PAijt c, d Values of the dependant variable that are respectively three and two standard deviations away from the mean are discarded.

18

Tabl

e 4:

Var

ious

asp

ects

of g

over

nanc

e an

d in

tern

atio

nal t

rade

, mod

el H

T5 se

lect

ion

EF

EAH

T1a

HT2

bH

T3c

HT4

dH

T5e

LnG

DP i

t 1,

18**

*1,

19**

*1,

32**

* 1,

36**

*1,

35**

*1,

28**

*1,

35**

* [0

,02]

[0,0

1][0

,01]

[0

,02]

[0,0

1][0

,02]

[0,0

1]

LnG

DP j

t 0,

89**

*0,

91**

*1,

03**

* 1,

07**

*1,

06**

*0,

99**

*1,

06**

* [0

,02]

[0,0

1][0

,01]

[0

,02]

[0,0

1][0

,02]

[0,0

1]

Rem

otne

ssit

-0,9

5***

-0,0

9**

-0,3

1***

-0

,42*

**-0

,81*

**-0

,95*

**-0

,74*

**

[0,1

1][0

,04]

[0,0

7]

[0,0

7][0

,10]

[0,1

1][0

,10]

R

emot

ness

jt -1

,92*

**-0

,35*

**-0

,72*

**

-0,8

1***

-1,5

6***

-1,8

0***

-1,6

2***

[0

,11]

[0,0

4][0

,07]

[0

,07]

[0,1

0][0

,11]

[0,1

1]

Lndi

stan

ceij

_-1

,12*

**-0

,54*

**

-0,2

8***

-0,8

0***

-0,1

7-0

,80*

**

_[0

,03]

[0,0

8]

[0,0

9][0

,09]

[0,2

5][0

,09]

Ln

RER

ijt

0,02

***

0,01

***

0,01

***

0,01

***

0,01

***

0,01

***

0,02

***

[0,0

0][0

,00]

[0,0

0]

[0,0

0][0

,00]

[0,0

0][0

,00]

Ln

Cor

rupt

ion it

-0

,09*

**-0

,11*

**-0

,10*

**

-0,1

1***

-0,1

2***

-0,1

1***

-0,1

1***

[0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0,0

2]

LnBu

reau

crac

yQua

lity it

0,

10**

*0,

15**

*0,

10**

* 0,

10**

*0,

10**

*0,

10**

*0,

10**

* [0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0,0

2]

LnLa

wan

dOrd

erit

0,05

**0,

09**

*0,

04

0,03

0,02

0,03

0,02

[0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0,0

2]

LnC

orru

ptio

n jt

-0,0

20,

010,

00

-0,0

2-0

,03

-0,0

3-0

,04*

[0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0,0

2]

LnBu

reau

crac

yQua

lity jt

0,

030,

05**

*0,

01

0,02

0,02

0,02

0,02

[0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0,0

2]

LnLa

wan

dOrd

erjt

-0,0

2-0

,01

-0,0

5**

-0,0

5**

-0,0

6**

-0,0

4*-0

,05*

* [0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0,0

2]

Con

tigui

tyij

_0,

83**

*1,

68**

* 2,

13**

*0,

93**

*2,

24**

*0,

93**

* _

[0,1

1][0

,23]

[0

,24]

[0,2

3][0

,56]

[0,2

3]

Com

mon

Lan

guag

e ij

_0,

70**

*1,

07**

* 1,

21**

*1,

34**

*1,

50**

*1,

34**

* _

[0,0

6][0

,11]

[0

,11]

[0,1

0][0

,17]

[0,1

0]

RTA

ijt

0,33

***

0,41

***

0,44

***

0,47

***

0,39

***

0,35

***

0,39

***

[0,0

5][0

,04]

[0,0

4]

[0,0

4][0

,04]

[0,0

4][0

,04]

C

olon

y ij

_1,

21**

*0,

46*

0,18

-0,1

9-0

,26

-0,1

9 _

[0,1

6][0

,27]

[0

,27]

[0,2

5][0

,40]

[0,2

5]

19

Sim

ilarit

y ij

_0,

28**

*0,

43**

* 0,

48**

*0,

60**

*0,

61**

*0,

60**

* _

[0,0

4][0

,06]

[0

,07]

[0,0

6][0

,10]

[0,0

6]

Num

ber o

f obs

erva

tions

1359

88,0

013

5988

,00

1359

88,0

0 13

5988

,00

1359

88,0

013

5988

,00

1359

88,0

0 N

umbe

r of p

airs

1153

7,00

1153

7,00

1153

7,00

11

537,

0011

537,

0011

537,

0011

537,

00

Tim

e Sp

ecifi

c Ef

fect

s33

,97

403,

3651

8,36

55

6,63

682,

4769

5,19

682,

20

Prob

>F0,

00_

_ _

__

_ Pr

ob>c

hi2

_0,

000,

00

0,00

0,00

0,00

0,00

Bi

late

ral F

ixed

Eff

ects

18

,44

__

__

__

Prob

>F0,

00_

_ _

__

_ H

ausm

an te

st fi

xed

vs ra

ndom

eff

ects

f_

185,

47_

__

__

Prob

>chi

2_

0,00

_ _

__

_ H

ausm

an H

T vs

rand

om e

ffec

tsg

__

497,

32

2456

,70

261,

9122

,07

265,

42

Prob

>chi

2_

_0,

00

0,00

0,00

0,00

0,00

Su

riden

tific

atio

n te

sth

__

251,

95

273,

3911

,26

0,00

0,00

Pr

ob>c

hi2

__

0,00

0,

000,

511,

001,

00

***,

**,

and

* si

gnifi

cant

at t

he 1

%, 5

% a

nd 1

0% le

vels

resp

ectiv

ely.

Sta

ndar

d er

rors

repo

rted

into

bra

cket

s und

er c

oeff

icie

nts.

The

time

dum

my

varia

bles

and

th

e co

nsta

nt a

re n

ot re

porte

d to

save

spac

e.

a HT1

:end

ogen

ous v

aria

bles

: lnG

DP i

t, ln

GD

P jt a

nd ln

Dist

ance

ij. b H

T2 :

endo

geno

us v

aria

bles

: lnG

DP i

t, ln

GD

P jt,

lnD

istan

ceij,

lnC

orru

ptio

n it, l

nBur

eauc

racy

Qua

lity it

, lnL

awan

dOrd

erit,

lnC

orru

ptio

n jt, l

nBur

eauc

racy

Qua

lity j

t, an

d ln

Law

andO

rder

jt. c H

T3 :

endo

geno

us v

aria

bles

: lnG

DP i

t, ln

GD

P jt,

lnD

istan

ceij,

lnC

orru

ptio

n it, l

nBur

eauc

racy

Qua

lity it

, lnL

awan

dOrd

erit,

lnC

orru

ptio

n jt, l

nBur

eauc

racy

Qua

lity j

t, ln

Law

andO

rder

jt, re

mot

ness

it and

rem

otne

ssjt

d HT4

: en

doge

nous

var

iabl

es: ln

GD

P it,

lnG

DP j

t, ln

dist

ance

ij, ln

GD

P it,

lnG

DP j

t, ln

Dist

ance

ij, ln

Cor

rupt

ion it

, lnB

urea

ucra

cyQ

ualit

y it, l

nLaw

andO

rder

it, ln

Cor

rupt

ion jt

, lnB

urea

ucra

cyQ

ualit

y jt, l

nLaw

andO

rder

jt,, re

mot

ness

it, re

mot

ness

jt and

RTA

ijt

e HT5

: en

doge

nous

var

iabl

es: ln

GD

P it,

lnG

DP j

t, ln

Dist

ance

ij, ln

GD

P it,

lnG

DP j

t, ln

Dist

ance

ij, ln

Cor

rupt

ion it

, lnB

urea

ucra

cyQ

ualit

y it, l

nLaw

andO

rder

it, ln

Cor

rupt

ion jt

, lnB

urea

ucra

cyQ

ualit

y jt, l

nLaw

andO

rder

jt, re

mot

ness

it, re

mot

ness

jt and

lnR

ERijt

f Th

is te

st is

app

lied

to th

e di

ffer

ence

s bet

wee

n th

e fix

ed e

ffec

ts m

odel

and

the

rand

om e

ffec

ts m

odel

est

imat

es w

ithou

t tak

ing

into

acc

ount

the

coef

ficie

nt o

f tim

e ef

fect

s.

g H

auss

man

test

app

lied

to th

e di

ffer

ence

s bet

wee

n th

e ra

ndom

eff

ects

mod

el a

nd th

e H

T es

timat

ors,

with

out t

ime

effe

cts.

h Hau

sman

test

app

lied

to th

e di

ffer

ence

s bet

wee

n th

e fix

ed e

ffec

ts a

nd th

e H

T es

timat

ors,

with

out t

ime

effe

cts.

20

These first results clearly show that institutional similarity noticeably eases bilateral exports. Indeed,

the fact that two countries share the same institutional framework increases bilateral exports

by 60% (e0.47-1).

These results do not confirm Anderson & Marcouiller�s view according to which bad

governance is a barrier to trade. Institutional quality seems to play a more complex part in

international trade. Indeed, the estimations show that the quality of governance of the

exporting country matters for trade, on the contrary of the one of the importing country.

These first results lead to change the barrier-to-trade function in order to take into account the

interactions between the different aspects of governance. This new formulation of the barrier-

to-trade function enables to test the �second best� theories that see corruption as a way to

grease the wheels of commerce.

V DOES CORRUPTION �GREASE THE WHEELS� OF COMMERCE?

�Second best� theories consider corruption as a way to �grease� the wheels of commerce,

because it compensates the consequences of a defective bureaucracy or bad policies. Testing

empirically these theories requires a measure of these distortions. The Fraser institute

Economic Freedom index seems the more appropriate. Indeed, it measures the degree to

which the policies and institutions of countries are supportive of economic freedom, that is to

say personal choice, voluntary exchange, freedom to compete, and security of privately

owned property. However, that indicator because has been produced yearly only since the

year 2000. That is why; I prefer using the IRCG rating on bureaucracy quality.

Remind that, the �second best� theories will be confirmed, if the coefficients of corruption

variables are positive and the ones of interactions variables negative.

The first column of Table 5 reports the estimation of equation (11) with the Hausman Taylor

estimator and corrected of a selection bias. Table 6 explains the choice of the endogenous

variables. Again, coefficients of the traditional gravity variables have the expected sign and

are significant at the 1% level again. Again, institutional similarity has a positive and

significant impact on exports volumes.

As regard the variables of interest, the coefficients of the corruption variables are negative and

significant at the 1% level for the exporting country and at 10% one for the importing

country. Moreover, parameters estimates of the interaction variables are positives and highly

21

significant. Hence, these estimation results invalidate totally the predictions of �second best�

theories. They show that corruption in the importing country as well as in the exporting

country is a barrier to bilateral exports, and that it is even more harmful to trade when the

quality of bureaucracy is weak.

The columns 2 and 3 of table 5 present estimations of HT5 on samples where extreme values

of the dependant variable have been discarded. The sign and the significance level of

coefficients of the variables of interest are not change by these sample variations.

Since corruption can lead to fallacious data on international trade, equation (11) is estimated

on a sample made of Northern countries as exporters8, and Southern countries as importers.

Indeed, widespread corruption and poor governance seem to be an issue specific to southern

countries. As economic distance could have an ambiguous effect on North South trade, I add

to the traditional gravity equation a relative economic distance index9 and it square. Indeed,

on the one hand, it captures distance in standard of living likely to decrease trade of

horizontally differentiated goods. On the other hand, it reflects differences in capitalistic

intensities which favour inter industry trade linked to differences in factor endowments.

Estimations of equation (11) on a North South sample are reported in columns (4) and (5) of

table (5). In those estimations, the bilateral specific effects are treated as fixed because I

failed to obtain sufficiently strong instruments among the set of explanatory variables to

apply a Hausman Taylor estimator. Again, the gravity equation performs well. The

coefficients have the expected signs. For instance, GDP increases trade whereas remoteness

reduces it. The existence of a non linear effect for economic distance is confirmed. Indeed,

difference in standard of living appears as a good proxy both for similarity of supply and

demand structures, and for distance in capitalistic intensities. As regard the variables of

interest, estimations show again that corruption in the importing country as well as in the

exporting country is a barrier to bilateral exports, and that it is even more harmful to trade

when the quality of bureaucracy is weak.

8 Northern countries correspond to the 22 high income OECD countries and Southern countries to 122 developing countries. I adopt a broad definition of South since I group together countries belonging to Eastern Europe, Middle East, Latin America or Sub Saharan Africa. 9 1 It is calculated from a formula inspired by Balassa and Bauwens (1987) which gives an index contained between 0 (standard of living equality) and 1 (maximal difference in standard of living):

2ln2)z2ln()z2(zlnzdeco −−+= with

=

jty;ityMax

jty;ityMinz where yit and yjt are respectively the real

income per capita of the exporter and of the importer at time t.

22

Table 5: Does corruption �grease the wheels� of commerce?

1a 2b 3c 4d 5d

LnGDPit 1,16*** 1,15*** 1,09*** 0,85*** 0,85*** [0,02] [0,02] [0,02] [0,04] [0,04]

LnGDPjt 0,87*** 0,86*** 0,84*** 0,72*** 0,71*** [0,02] [0,02] [0,02] [0,03] [0,04]

Economic Distanceijt _ _ _ 2,10** 2,09** _ _ _ [0,95] [0,95]

Sqare of Economic Distanceijt _ _ _ -6,96*** -7,07*** _ _ _ [1,81] [1,81]

Remotnessit -0,92*** -0,92*** -1,01*** -0,49*** -0,46*** [0,10] [0,10] [0,09] [0,11] [0,11]

Remotnessjt -1,79*** -1,76*** -1,71*** -3,99*** -4,00*** [0,11] [0,10] [0,10] [0,23] [0,23]

Lndistanceij -0,86*** -0,83*** -0,77*** _ _ [0,09] [0,09] [0,09] _ _

LnRERijt 0,02*** 0,02*** 0,02*** 0,03*** 0,03*** [0,00] [0,00] [0,00] [0,00] [0,00]

LnCorruptionit -0,19*** -0,19*** -0,15*** _ -0,66*** [0,02] [0,02] [0,02] _ [0,20]

LnCorruption*lnBureaucracyQualityit 0,06*** 0,06*** 0,04*** _ 0,32** [0,01] [0,01] [0,01] _ [0,12]

LnCorruptionjt -0,04* -0,03* -0,03* -0,13*** -0,13*** [0,02] [0,02] [0,02] [0,03] [0,03]

LnCorruption*lnBureaucracyQualityjt 0,02** 0,02** 0,02** 0,06*** 0,06*** [0,01] [0,01] [0,01] [0,01] [0,01]

Contiguityij 0,80*** 0,83*** 1,14*** _ _ [0,22] [0,22] [0,23] _ _

Common Languageij 1,04*** 1,05*** 1,09*** _ _ [0,10] [0,10] [0,10] _ _

RTAijt 0,36*** 0,37*** 0,37*** 0,50*** 0,49*** [0,04] [0,04] [0,04] [0,09] [0,09]

Colonyij -0,04 -0,04 -0,09 _ _ [0,24] [0,24] [0,24] _ _

Similarityij 0,48*** 0,48*** 0,50*** _ _ [0,06] [0,06] [0,06] _ _

PRESij 0,07*** 0,06*** 0,04*** _ _ [0,01] [0,01] [0,01] _ _

DDij 0,04 0,06 0,11 _ _ [0,08] [0,08] [0,08] _ _

PAijt 0,13*** 0,14*** 0,13*** _ _ [0,02] [0,02] [0,02] _ _

Number of observations 135988,00 135600,00 129927,00 30403,00 30403,00Number of pairs 11537,00 11511,00 11189,00 2081,00 240,00

Time Specific Effects 710,87 717,51 770,58 27,10 8,95Prob>F 0,00 0,00 0,00 0,00 0,00

***, **, and * significant at the 1%, 5% and 10% levels respectively. Standard errors reported into brackets under coefficients. The time dummy variables and the constant are not reported to save space. a HT5 :endogenous variables: lnGDPit lnGDPjt lnDistanceij lncorruptionit Remotnessit Remotnessjt lnRERijt lnCorruption*lnBureaucracyQualityit lnCorruptionjt lncorrruption*lnBureaucraticQualityjt. b c Values of the dependant variable that are respectively three and two standard deviations away from the mean are discarded. d Only North South exports are used. A fixed effects model is used.

23

Tabl

e 6:

Doe

s cor

rupt

ion

�gre

ase

the

whe

els�

of c

omm

erce

? H

T5 m

odel

sele

ctio

n

EF

EAH

T1a

HT2

bH

T3c

HT4

dH

T5e

LnG

DPi

t 1,

19**

*1,

20**

*1,

33**

* 1,

36**

*1,

35**

*1,

29**

*1,

35**

*

[0,0

2][0

,01]

[0,0

1]

[0,0

1][0

,01]

[0,0

2][0

,01]

Ln

GD

Pjt

0,90

***

0,91

***

1,03

***

1,07

***

1,06

***

1,00

***

1,06

***

[0

,02]

[0,0

1][0

,01]

[0

,01]

[0,0

1][0

,02]

[0,0

1]

Rem

otne

ssit

-0

,96*

**-0

,12*

**-0

,33*

**

-0,4

3***

-0,8

3***

-0,9

6***

-0,7

5***

[0,1

1][0

,04]

[0,0

7]

[0,0

7][0

,10]

[0,1

1][0

,10]

R

emot

ness

jt

-1,9

0***

-0,3

5***

-0,7

1***

-0

,80*

**-1

,53*

**-1

,78*

**-1

,61*

**

[0

,11]

[0,0

4][0

,07]

[0

,07]

[0,1

0][0

,11]

[0,1

1]

LnD

istan

ceij

_

-1,1

2***

-0,5

2***

-0

,28*

**-0

,80*

**-0

,18

-0,8

0***

_[0

,03]

[0,0

8]

[0,0

9][0

,09]

[0,2

5][0

,09]

Ln

RER

ijt

0,02

***

0,01

***

0,01

***

0,01

***

0,01

***

0,01

***

0,02

***

[0

,00]

[0,0

0][0

,00]

[0

,00]

[0,0

0][0

,00]

[0,0

0]

LnC

orru

ptio

nit

-0,1

9***

-0,2

6***

-0,1

9***

-0

,19*

**-0

,20*

**-0

,19*

**-0

,19*

**

[0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0,0

2]

LnC

orru

ptio

n*ln

Bure

aucr

acyQ

ualit

yit

0,06

***

0,09

***

0,06

***

0,06

***

0,05

***

0,05

***

0,05

***

[0

,01]

[0,0

1][0

,01]

[0

,01]

[0,0

1][0

,01]

[0,0

1]

LnC

orru

ptio

njt

-0,0

4*-0

,04*

*0,

00

-0,0

3-0

,03

-0,0

4*-0

,04*

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0,0

2]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

[0,0

2][0

,02]

Ln

Cor

rupt

ion*

lnBu

reau

crac

yQua

lityj

t 0,

02*

0,04

***

0,02

0,

02*

0,01

0,02

0,01

[0,0

1][0

,01]

[0,0

1]

[0,0

1][0

,01]

[0,0

1][0

,01]

C

ontig

uity

ij

_0,

82**

*1,

71**

* 2,

13**

*0,

93**

*2,

23**

*0,

93**

*

_[0

,11]

[0,2

3]

[0,2

4][0

,23]

[0,5

6][0

,23]

C

omm

on L

angu

agei

j _

0,70

***

1,09

***

1,21

***

1,34

***

1,50

***

1,34

***

_

[0,0

6][0

,11]

[0

,11]

[0,1

0][0

,17]

[0,1

0]

RTA

ijt

0,33

***

0,41

***

0,45

***

0,47

***

0,40

***

0,35

***

0,40

***

[0

,05]

[0,0

4][0

,04]

[0

,04]

[0,0

4][0

,04]

[0,0

4]

Col

onyi

j _

1,21

***

0,43

0,

19-0

,18

-0,2

6-0

,19

_

[0,1

6][0

,27]

[0

,27]

[0,2

5][0

,40]

[0,2

5]

Sim

ilarit

yij

_0,

28**

*0,

43**

* 0,

48**

*0,

59**

*0,

61**

*0,

59**

*

_[0

,04]

[0,0

7]

[0,0

7][0

,06]

[0,1

0][0

,06]

N

umbe

r of o

bser

vatio

ns

1359

88,0

013

5988

,00

1359

88,0

0 13

5988

,00

1359

88,0

013

5988

,00

1359

88,0

0 N

umbe

r of p

airs

11

537,

0011

537,

0011

537,

00

1153

7,00

1153

7,00

1153

7,00

1153

7,00

24

Tim

e Sp

ecifi

c Ef

fect

s 35

,20

417,

8153

1,10

56

3,25

687,

4070

7,29

687,

08

Prob

>F

0,00

__

__

__

Prob

>chi

2 0,

000,

000,

00

0,00

0,00

0,00

0,00

Bi

late

ral F

ixed

Eff

ects

18

,58

__

__

__

Prob

>F

0,00

__

__

__

Hau

sman

test

fixe

d vs

rand

om e

ffec

tsf

_17

5,03

_ _

__

_ Pr

ob>c

hi2

_0,

00_

__

__

Hau

sman

HT

vs ra

ndom

eff

ects

g _

_59

9,31

56

2,57

312,

8622

,33

321,

85

Prob

>chi

2 _

_0,

00

0,00

0,00

0,00

0,00

Su

riden

tific

atio

n te

sth

__

223,

19

254,

1412

,20

0,00

0,00

Pr

ob>c

hi2

__

0,00

0,

000,

271,

001,

00

***,

**,

and

* si

gnifi

cant

at t

he 1

%, 5

% a

nd 1

0% le

vels

resp

ectiv

ely.

Sta

ndar

d er

rors

repo

rted

into

bra

cket

s und

er c

oeff

icie

nts.

The

time

dum

my

varia

bles

and

th

e co

nsta

nt a

re n

ot re

porte

d to

save

spac

e.

a HT1

:end

ogen

ous v

aria

bles

: lnG

DP i

t, ln

GD

P jt a

nd ln

Dist

ance

ij. b H

T2 :

end

ogen

ous

varia

bles

: ln

GD

P it,

lnG

DP j

t, ln

Dist

ance

ij, ln

Cor

rupt

ion it

, ln

Cor

rupt

ion*

lnBu

reau

crac

yQua

lity it

, ln

Cor

rupt

ion j

t, an

d ln

Cor

rupt

ion*

ln

Bure

aucr

acyQ

ualit

y jt.

c H

T3 :

endo

geno

us

varia

bles

:

lnG

DP i

t, ln

GD

P jt,

lnD

istan

ceij,

lnG

DP i

t, ln

GD

P jt,

lnD

istan

ceij,

lnC

orru

ptio

n it,

lnC

orru

ptio

n*ln

Bure

aucr

acyQ

ualit

y it,

lnC

orru

ptio

n jt, l

nCor

rupt

ion*

lnBu

reau

crac

yQua

lity jt

, rem

otne

ssit a

nd re

mot

ness

jt d

HT4

: en

doge

nous

va

riabl

es:

ln

GD

P it,

lnG

DP j

t, ln

dist

ance

ij, ln

GD

P it,

lnG

DP j

t, ln

Dist

ance

ij, ln

GD

P it,

lnG

DP j

t, ln

Dist

ance

ij, ln

Cor

rupt

ion it

, ln

Cor

rupt

ion*

lnBu

reau

crac

yQua

lity i

t, ln

Cor

rupt

ion jt

, lnC

orru

ptio

n* ln

Bure

aucr

acyQ

ualit

y jt, r

emot

ness

it, re

mot

ness

jt and

RTA

ijt

e H

T5 :

endo

geno

us

varia

bles

:

lnG

DP i

t, ln

GD

P jt,

lnD

istan

ceij,

lnG

DP i

t, ln

GD

P jt,

lnD

istan

ceij,

lnG

DP i

t, ln

GD

P jt,

lnD

istan

ceij,

lnC

orru

ptio

n it,

lnC

orru

ptio

n*ln

Bure

aucr

acyQ

ualit

y it,

lnC

orru

ptio

n jt, l

nCor

rupt

ion*

lnBu

reau

crac

yQua

lity jt

, rem

otne

ssit,

rem

otne

ssjt a

nd ln

RER

ijt

f This

test

is a

pplie

d to

the

diff

eren

ces

betw

een

the

fixed

eff

ects

mod

el a

nd th

e ra

ndom

eff

ects

mod

el e

stim

ates

with

out t

akin

g in

to a

ccou

nt th

e co

effic

ient

of

time

effe

cts.

g H

auss

man

test

app

lied

to th

e di

ffer

ence

s bet

wee

n th

e ra

ndom

eff

ects

mod

el a

nd th

e H

T es

timat

ors,

with

out t

ime

effe

cts.

h Hau

sman

test

app

lied

to th

e di

ffer

ence

s bet

wee

n th

e fix

ed e

ffec

ts a

nd th

e H

T es

timat

ors,

with

out t

ime

effe

cts.

25

VI CONCLUSION

Estimations clearly show that institutional similarity eases bilateral trade. The fact that two

countries have the same institutional framework increases export volumes by 60%.

Nevertheless, the consequences on international trade appear to be more complex than what

has suggested a recent literature. My results do not confirm either �second best� theories that

see corruption is a way to bypass rigidities imposed by governments. Thank to a barrier to

trade function which enables interaction between corruption and other aspects of governance,

this paper shows that corruption in the importing country as well as in the exporting country is

a barrier to bilateral exports, and that it is even more harmful to trade when the quality of

bureaucracy is weak. In a North-South approach, testing the impact of corruption and poor

governance on the exports of various types of goods and especially capital goods appears of

great interest because for developing countries exports from industrialised ones are a way to

acquire new goods.

References :

Anderson, J.E. & Marcouiller, D. (2002) �Insecurity and the pattern of trade : an empirical investigation�. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 84, 2, 342-52.

Anderson, J.E. & van Wincoop, E. (2003) �Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puzzle�. American Economic Review, 93, 1, 170�92.

Anderson, J. E., & van Wincoop, E. (2004) �Trade Costs�. Journal of Economic Literature, forthcoming.

Anderson, J. E., & Young, L. (1999) �Trade and Contract Enforcement�. Boston College Mimeograph.

Baghwati, J. N. (1982) �Directly Unproductive, Profit-seeking Activities� Journal of Political Economy, 90, 5, 988-1002.

Balassa, B. & Bauwens, L. (1987) �Intra-Industry Specialization in a Multi-Country and Multilateral Framework�. The Economic Journal, 97, 923-39.

Bayoumi, T. & Eichengreen, B. (1997) �Is regionalism simply a diversion? Evidence from the evolution the EC and the EFTA�. In: Ito, T., Krueger, A. (Eds.), Regionalism Versus Multilateral Trade Arrangements, Vol.6, Chapter 6. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

Chong, A. & Zanforlin, L. (2000) �Law Tradition and Institutional Quality: Some Empirical Evidence�. Journal of International Development, 12, 8, 1057-68.

Carrere, C. (2004) �Revisiting the effects of regional trading agreements on trade flows with proper specification of the gravity model�. European Economic Review, forthcoming.

Disdier, A-C & Mayer, T. (2005) �Je t�aime, moi non plus: bilateral opinion and international trade� CEPR Discussion Paper No:4928.

Egger, P. (2000) �A note on the proper specification of the gravity equation�. Economics Letters, 66, 1, 25-31.

Egger, P (2002) �An econometric view on the estimation of gravity models and the calculations of trade potentials�. The World Economy, 25, 2, 297-312.

26

Egger, P. and Pfaffermayr, M. (2003) �The proper econometric specification of the gravity equation: A three way model with bilateral interaction effects�. Empirical Economics, 28, 3, pp.571-81.

Feenstra, R. (2004) Advanced International Trade: Theory and Evidence, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Guillotin, Y. & Sevestre, P. (1994) �Estimations de fonctions de gains sur données de panel: Endogeneité du capital humain et effets de sélection�. Economie et Prévision 116, 119-135

Hausman, A. & Taylor, E. (1981) �Panel data and unobservable individuals effects�. Econometrica 49, 1377-1398.

Knack, S. & Keefer, P. (1995) �Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative Institutional Measures�. Economics and Politics, 7, 3, 207-27.

Nijman, T. & Verbeek, M. (1992) �Incomplete panels and selection bias� In: Matyas, L., Sevestre, P.(Eds), The Econometrics of Panel Data. Kluwer, Dordrecht, pp 262-302.

Rose, A.K. (2000) �One Money One Market: The Effect of Common Currencies on Trade�. Economic Policy, 30, 9�45.

Soloaga, I. & Winters, A. (2001) �How has regionalism in the 1990�s affected trade? North American Journal of Economics and Finance 12, 1-29.

Watson, A. (1974). Legal Transplants. Charlottesville, VA: University of Virginia Press.

Wei, S.J. (1996) �Intra-National Versus International Trade: How Stubborn are Nations in Global Integration?� NBER Working Paper, No. 5531 (Cambridge, MA: NBER).

ANNEXE 1: LIST OF COUNTRIES IN THE SAMPLE. Albania Ecuador Lebanon Spain Algeria Egypt Lithuania Sri Lanka Angola El Salvador Macedonia, FYR Sudan Argentina Equatorial Guinea Madagascar Sweden Australia Estonia Malawi Switzerland Austria Ethiopia Malaysia Syrian Arab Republic Azerbaijan Fiji Mali Tajikistan Bahamas, The Finland Malta Tanzania Bahrain, Kingdom of France Mauritania Thailand Bangladesh Gabon Mauritius Togo Barbados Gambia, The Mexico Trinidad and Tobago Belarus Georgia Moldova Tunisia Belgium Germany Mongolia Turkey Belize Ghana Morocco Turkmenistan Benin Greece Nepal Uganda Bolivia Grenada Netherlands Ukraine Brazil Guatemala New Zealand United Kingdom Bulgaria Guinea Niger United States Burkina Faso Guinea-Bissau Nigeria Uruguay Burundi Guyana Norway Uzbekistan Cambodia Haiti Oman Venezuela, Rep Bol Cameroon Honduras Panama Vietnam Canada Hungary Papua New Guinea Yugoslavia, SFR Cape Verde Iceland Paraguay Zambia Central African Rep India Peru Zimbabwe Chad Indonesia Philippines Chile Iran, IR of Poland China,PR: Mainland Ireland Portugal

27

Colombia Israel Romania Congo, Dem Rep of Italy Russia Congo, Republic of Jamaica Rwanda Costa Rica Japan Samoa Côte d'Ivoire Jordan Saudi Arabia Croatia Kazakhstan Senegal Cyprus Kenya Sierra Leone Czech Republic Korea Singapore Denmark Kuwait Slovak Republic Djibouti Kyrgyz Republic Slovenia Dominica Lao People's DemRep South Africa Dominican Republic Latvia

ANNEXE 2 : VARIABLES DESCRIPTION. Variable Name: Bilateral exports (Xij) Description: Bilateral exports of the country i to the country j, in F.O.B terms and in U.S. $ deflated by the American Consumer Price Index (1995=100), years 1984-1997. Source: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics. Variable Name: GDPi(j) Description: Total Gross Domestic Product in constant U.S. $.(1995=100) Source: World Bank, World Development Indicators on line Variable Name: Bilateral Distance (Dij) Description: Great arc circle kilometric distance between the two capitals of countries i and j. Source: CEPII data base, http://www.cepii.fr/francgraph/bdd/bdd.htm Variable Name: Common Languageij Description: Dummy variable equals 1 if countries i and j share the same language. Source: CEPII data base, http://www.cepii.fr/francgraph/bdd/bdd.htm Variable Name: Adjacencyij Description: Dummy variable equals 1 if countries i and j share a common border. Source: CEPII data base, http://www.cepii.fr/francgraph/bdd/bdd.htm Variable Name: Colonyij Description: Dummy variable equals 1 if countries i and j share a common border. Source: author data base. Variable Name: RTAijt Description: Dummy variable equals 1 if countries i and j are both members of the same free trade agreement Source: Authors computation on the basis of the World Trade Organisation�s website , http://www.wto.org/ Variable Name: Corruptionit Description: Level of corruption in the importing country, lowest values stand for high level of corruption Source: ICRG data.

Variable Name: LawandOrderit Description: quality of the judicial system in the importing country Source: ICRG data.

Variable Name: BureaucracyQualityit Description: quality of the bureaucracy in the importing country, lowest values stand for high level of corruption Source: ICRG data.

28

Variable Name: Corruptionjt Description: Level of corruption in the exporting country Source: ICRG data.

Variable Name: LawandOrderjt Description: quality of the judicial system in the exporting country Source: ICRG data.

Variable Name : BureaucracyQualityjt Description: quality of the bureaucracy in the exporting country Source: ICRG data.

Variable Name: Governanceit Description: Quality of governance in the exporting country Source: author calculation on the basis ICRG data..

Variable Name: Governancejt Description: Quality of governance in the importing country Source: author calculation on the basis ICRG data.

Variable Name: RERijt Description: RERijt = (CPIjt/CPIit)(NERit/$/NERjts/$) Source: the nominal exchange rates for each currency against the US $ (NER, country i�s currency value of one US $) are extrated from IFS dataset. The consumption price indexes (CPI) are taken from the World Development Indicators. If the CPI is not available for a country, the GDP deflator is used (World Development Indicators).


Recommended