+ All Categories
Home > Documents > I/Spring 2001 HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH · Maria M. Hofmarcher, Monika Riedel* Summary ... to...

I/Spring 2001 HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH · Maria M. Hofmarcher, Monika Riedel* Summary ... to...

Date post: 26-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: trandieu
View: 213 times
Download: 1 times
Share this document with a friend
24
I/Spring 2001 HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH Supplement of the journal Soziale Sicherheit (Social Security) by the Institute for Advanced Studies / Institut für Höhere Studien (IHS) - IHS HealthEcon Edited by the Hauptverband der österreichischen Sozialversicherungsträger (Federation of Austrian Social Security Institutions) Health expenditure in the EU: No public sector without the private one Focus: The Austrian hospital sector – one system or nine? Maria M. Hofmarcher, Monika Riedel* Summary The health sector in Austria is growing faster than the national economy, the primary example of this being public health expenditure. Price inflation in the privately financed health sector remained constant over the last few years and was slightly below general price growth, which could be explained by rising competition. Health is and remains, however, a good that is highly valued by Austrians, who display consumer behaviour typical of that in industrial countries and thus substantiate the hypothesis that health is a „luxury good“. This is also shown in particular in that private health expenditure is increasing significantly more than public spending with Austrians perhaps favouring private individual payments over expenditure for private health insurance. Hospitals in all of the Länder have been increasing the number of cases they treat and optimising performance points since the introduction of performance-oriented hospital financing (LKF). This behaviour is in accord with international experience and corresponds to supply-induced demand or DRG creep (point maximisation) as indicated in the literature. In addition, the budgeting of the hospital sector shifts the risk onto the owners of the hospitals and thus increases the incentive to behave in such a manner. A further reaction to the budgeting was that – within the legal boundaries – in each Land a specific financing and organisational structure was formed for hospitals. It has turned out that hospital-holdings are a greater burden on Länder budgets than decentralised hospitals. The different forms of LKF-systems in the Länder has, however, led to the system being exploited to varying degrees. The further structuring of the financing system should therefore either take this into consideration or measures should be taken to standardise the systems. *We would like to thank Gerald Röhrling for his assistance.
Transcript

I/Spring 2001

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH Supplement of the journal Soziale Sicherheit (Social Security) by

the Institute for Advanced Studies / Institut für Höhere Studien (IHS)

- IHS HealthEcon

Edited by the Hauptverband der österreichischen

Sozialversicherungsträger (Federation of Austrian Social Security Institutions)

Health expenditure in the EU: No public sector without the private one

Focus: The Austrian hospital sector – one system or

nine?

Maria M. Hofmarcher, Monika Riedel*

Summary

The health sector in Austria is growing faster than the national economy, the primary

example of this being public health expenditure. Price inflation in the privately financed

health sector remained constant over the last few years and was slightly below general price

growth, which could be explained by rising competition. Health is and remains, however, a

good that is highly valued by Austrians, who display consumer behaviour typical of that in

industrial countries and thus substantiate the hypothesis that health is a „luxury good“. This

is also shown in particular in that private health expenditure is increasing significantly more

than public spending with Austrians perhaps favouring private individual payments over

expenditure for private health insurance.

Hospitals in all of the Länder have been increasing the number of cases they treat and

optimising performance points since the introduction of performance-oriented hospital

financing (LKF). This behaviour is in accord with international experience and corresponds

to supply-induced demand or DRG creep (point maximisation) as indicated in the literature.

In addition, the budgeting of the hospital sector shifts the risk onto the owners of the

hospitals and thus increases the incentive to behave in such a manner. A further reaction to

the budgeting was that – within the legal boundaries – in each Land a specific financing and

organisational structure was formed for hospitals. It has turned out that hospital-holdings are

a greater burden on Länder budgets than decentralised hospitals. The different forms of

LKF-systems in the Länder has, however, led to the system being exploited to varying

degrees. The further structuring of the financing system should therefore either take this into

consideration or measures should be taken to standardise the systems.

*We would like to thank Gerald Röhrling for his assistance.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 2

Public health expenditure in the EU is flowing more sluggishly than ever

During the 1990s the share of total health expenditure attributed to the public sector fell on

average in Europe (1990: 78.0 per cent; 1998: 75.2 per cent). This share was 70.5 per cent

in Austria in 1998, a decline of around 3 percentage points since 1990. The decline in the

proportion of public health expenditure between 1990 and 1998 in Austria corresponds

exactly to the decline in the 12 countries that form the European currency union, although

the level of the proportion in Austria (70.5 per cent) is around 3 percentage points lower than

the EU-12 average (73.6 per cent). The public share of total health expenditure in the 13

accession countries converged in the 1990s and in 1998 it was only 5 per cent higher than

the EU-15 mean. The central and Eastern European countries applying for EU membership

had a share of 82.2 per cent and in 1998 were nine per cent above the EU average (see

table A5).

The share of public spending on health in Austria is comparatively low: Only four EU-

countries have a lower level of public sector health expenditure as a proportion of total health

expenditure than Austria, only one of these (the Netherlands) can be classified as a social

insurance country. For Austria the data shown in the OECD data bank from October 2000 in

fact indicate a further slight decline in the proportion of public health expenditure (1990: 73.5

per cent, 1998: 70.5 per cent). According to the most recent values calculated by Statistik

Austria the public share of health expenditure has, after a slight decline, virtually reached the

level that it was at in 1995 (1995: 72.3 per cent, 1999: 72.1 per cent). But even according to

these figures public health expenditure in Austria forms a below average share when

compared to the EU.

Internationally, per capita health expenditure is the most common measurement used to

compare expenditure levels between countries. In contrast to the figures for ‘health

expenditure as a percentage of GDP‘, Austria is above the weighted EU average when

average per capita health expenditure is considered (see table A3). A position above the

EU-average for per capita health expenditure is logically consistent for Austria because: As a

net contributor Austria is one of the richer EU countries and the literature points frequently to

a positive relationship between income and demand for health services. 1 In terms of per

capita GDP Austria occupies 5th place within the EU and is eleven per cent above the

weighted average (see table A2).

1 e.g. Gerdtham U., J. Sogaard, B. Jönsson, F. Andersson (1992): A pooled cross-section analysis of the health care expenditures of the OECD countries. Zweifel P., H. E. Frech (eds.): Health Economics Worldwide. Kluwer. 1992; also cf. HSW I/1999.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 3

The health service in Austria is growing faster than the national economy.

In 1999 nominal total health expenditure was ATS 221.6 billion. Compared to 1997 this

represented a growth of 10.9 per cent, nominal general government expenditure rose by 7.5

per cent and GDP grew by 7.9 per cent.

Table 1: Trend in health expenditure 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999

Billion ATS

Health expenditure, total 202.64 212.87 199.79 210.06 221.63

Consumption expenses of private households, health

49.70 53.11 52.61 54.65 56.61

Public health expenditure 146.5 150.95 142.67 150.78 159.65

General government expenditure, consolidated

1.355.77 1.386.68 1.353.48 1.417.47 1.455.00

Gross Domestic Product (GDP) 2.370.73 2.449.96 2.513.48 2.614.66 2.712.03

Per capita, at 1995 prices in ATS

Health expenditure, total1) 25.182 25.997 24.850 25.952 26.991

% change 3.2 -4.4 4.4 4.0

Consumption expenses of private households, health2)

6.177 6.493 6.624 6.848 6.984

% change 5.1 2.0 3.4 2.0

Public expenditure on health 3) 18.205 18.381 17.127 17.930 18.798

% change 1.0 -6.8 4.7 4.8

General government expenditure4) 168.481 169.834 163.471 169.802 172.015

% change 0.8 -3.7 3.9 1.3

Gross Domestic Product (GDP) 4) 294.610 300.059 303.574 313.215 320.626

% change 1.8 1.2 3.2 2.4

In percent of GDP

Health expenditure, total 8.5 8.7 7.9 8.0 8.2

Consumption expenses of private households, health

2.1 2.2 2.1 2.1 2.1

Public expenditure on health 6.2 6.2 5.7 5.8 5.9

Federal government expenditure 57.2 56.6 53.8 54.2 53.6

Public expenditure on health

In percent of total health expenditure 72.3 70.9 71.4 71.8 72.1

In percent of public expenditure 10.8 10.9 10.5 10.6 11.0

Source: Statistik Austria, January 2001, IHS HealthEcon calculations 2001.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 4

Nominal GDP and nominal private health expenditure grew around 14 per cent between

1995 and 1999, public health expenditure increased nine per cent.

In terms of annual, real per capita expenditure it can be observed that the health service

grew significantly more than GDP between 1998 and 1999. While economic growth was 3.2

per cent in 1997, the health sector grew by 4.4 per cent and thus by 1.2 percentage points

more than real per capita GDP. As a result of the more subdued GDP growth in 1998, this

margin increased to 1.6 percentage points although the per capita growth of the health

service fell from 4.4 per cent to four per cent.

With a decline in the growth of private per capita expenditure from 3.4 per cent in 1998 to 2.0

per cent in 1999, the growth dynamics of private consumption appear to be in line with

economic growth.

National economic inflation was more dynamic over the last two years than inflation in the

health service. However, this may only have been the case for private consumption.

Economic growth and the growth of public health expenditure drifted apart significantly: The

decline in economic growth from 3.2 per cent in 1998 to 2.4 per cent in 1999 was

accompanied by an acceleration in growth in the public health sector, which reached 4.7 per

cent in 1998 and 4.8 per cent in 1999.

Total health expenditure as a proportion of GDP was 8.2 per cent in 1999, 0.3 percentage

points below the 1995 level; the proportion of public health reached 5.9 per cent.

With regard to health expenditure in relation to GDP, Austria (with 8.2 per cent) was below

the European average (8.7 per cent, see table A4) in 1998. The Austrian value is the ninth

highest or seventh lowest in the EU. Of the six social insurance countries (Bismarck type) in

the EU, only Luxembourg spent a lower share on health than Austria. The rates of the other

Bismarck countries (D, F, B, NL) are all higher than that of Austria.

Despite declining spending on private health insurance, private health expenditure is growing strongly…

Privately financed health expenditure grew 29 per cent between 1995 and 1999. In 1999

health expenditure financed by contribution revenues was 13 per cent above the 1995 level.

(figure 1) The share financed by private health insurance fell by three per cent.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 5

Chart 1: Growth dynamics of health expenditure, 1995-1999

1 2 9

1 0 2

8 3

1 1 3

9 7

0

5 0

1 0 0

1 5 0

Out of pocket spendings of privatehouseholds

Taxes

Private health insuranceContributions

Other f inancing sources

1995=100

1999

Source: Statistik Austria, January 2001, IHS HealthEcon Calculations 2001.

......and the proportion of health expenditure financed by them is growing

The share of privately financed health expenditure increased from 14.1 per cent of total

health expenditure in 1995 to 16.6 per cent in 1999 and thus by 2.5 percentage points. The

increasing financial burden on private households primarily goes hand in hand with lower

financing volumes from private health insurance and other sources of finance.

Supplementary private health insurance financed 7.1 per cent of health expenditure in 1999

and roughly eight per cent in 1995 (figure 2).

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 6

Chart 2: Sources of Finance in the Austrian health sector, 1995 and 1999 shares in percent

45.9

5.77.9

14.1

26.4

4.37.1

16.6

24.7

47.3

Contributions

Taxes

Out of pocket spendings ofprivate households

Private health insurance

Other financing sources

1995

1999

Source: Statistik Austria, January 2001, IHS HealthEcon Calculations 2001.

Although the share of health expenditure that was financed publicly remained fairly constant

between 1995 and 1999 (see table 1), there was a slight shift in the financing shares within

public expenditure: The share of health expenditure financed by taxes decreased from 26.4

per cent in 1995 to 24.7 per cent in 1999; the share financed by contributions increased from

45.9 per cent to 47.3 per cent2.

Public health expenditure is mainly financed by social health insurance contributions.

While 62 per cent of public health expenditure was financed by contributions from enrollees

in 1995, the share was 65.7 per cent in 1999. The share of health expenditure financed by

contributions as a proportion of GDP was 3.9 per cent in 1999, an increase of around 0.2

percentage points since 1997.

Total expenditure financed by social health insurance was ATS 133.4 billion in 1999 and

exceeded the 1995 level 18 per cent (see figures 1 and 3).

2 Including the contribution of social health insurance to hospital financing, which since 1995 has been entered into the national accounts according to ESVG95 as a transfer between public legal representatives and therefore no longer appears explicitly.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 7

Chart 3: Development of revenues and expenditures of social health insurance, nominal 1995=100

114107 109

118112

118111

168

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

Gro

ss D

omes

ticP

rod

uct

Pu

blic

exp

en

ditu

re

He

alth

exp

en

ditu

re,

tota

l

Re

ven

ue

s, to

tal

Re

ven

ue

s:co

ntr

ibu

tion

s, in

sure

d

Exp

en

ditu

re, t

ota

l

Pharm

ace

utic

als

Adm

inis

tratio

n a

nd

cle

ari

ng

exp

en

se

In A

TS

, 1995=

100

1996

1997

1998

1999

Sources: HVSV, Statistik Austria, January 2001, IHS HealthEcon 2001.

94 per cent of total health insurance expenditure is health-related insurance benefits which is

mostly inkind benefits. Of the insurance benefits expenditure around 30 per cent is used for

the hospitals sector, 26 per cent for primary care and 20 per cent for medicines. Expenditure

on medicines (+68 per cent) and therapeutic products / medical aid (+41 per cent) grew the

most during the observation period of 1995 to 1999.

Administrative expenditure was 3.6 per cent of total health insurance spending in 1999 and

was 11 per cent higher then than in 1995. This increase was three percentage points below

the GDP growth of 14 per cent and 7 percentage points below the increase in health

insurance expenditure (+18 per cent).

Revenues from insurance contributions increased 12 per cent during the same time period;

this growth was two percentage points below GDP growth and one percentage point above

the growth in administrative expenditure. Co-payments and user charges have been the

strongest growing sources of revenues since 1995 and in 1999 were 69 per cent greater

than the 1995 level. Total revenues including that from co-payments and other sources grew

18 per cent.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 8

The Austrian hospital service – one system or nine?

The allocation of legal responsibility in the health sector

As in all social insurance countries the health service in Austria is characterised by financing

pluralism. The Austrian Constitution stipulates that responsibilities for almost all areas of the

health care system - with a few exceptions in legislation and implementation – lie with the

Federal Government. In so far as the Länder are also allocated responsibilities, the Federal

Government and the Länder (states) have agreed to ensure health care delivery within

statutory agreements (Article 15a agreements) which outline the scope of their respective

responsibilities.

In the hospital sector the Federal Government is responsible for basic law; responsibility for

enacting legislation and for implementation lies with the nine Länder. The last so-called

Article 15a Agreement, which regulated the first four years of the new performance-oriented

hospital financing system (LKF-System), ran out on 31.12.2000.

Within the framework of this focus contribution the diversity of a supposedly standardised

system shall be illustrated and substantiated with figures using the example of the hospital

sector in order to then ask the question of whether this diversity is justified in a country with

scarcely more than 8 million inhabitants.

News from the financing of hospitals – is there any?

For around 45 per cent of all hospitals, the so-called fund hospitals, performance-related

invoicing came into effect as a result of the 1997 Article 15a Agreement. Around 70 per cent

of bed capacity and around 80 per cent of hospital personnel are concentrated in fund

hospitals.

The follow-up ruling agreed in December 2000 for the Article 15a Agreement for the time

period 01.01.01 - 31.12.04 adopted the regulations of the old agreement in many aspects.

However, from this point on the objectives associated with the LKF-system were

incorporated into the agreement. In the negotiations the Länder could not reach a unified

agreement on the financing volume of the regional funds or on a predominant distribution

mechanism of the available regional funds according to an unweighted nationwide LKF-core

system3. Precisely these measures were, however, recommended in a report from the audit

division4. Under the new regulations the possibility remains for the individual Länder, within

the framework of the LKF-system, to continue to organise their financing differently. These

3 The budget committee’s report on the government bill (395 of the supplements): Agreement according to Art. 15a B-VG about the restructuring of the health service and the financing of hospitals together with enclosed article number 410 of the supplements to the Stenographischen Protokollen des Nationalrates XXI. GP. 4 Observation report from the audit division about the reform of the health service and hospital financing, 12 July 2000, pp.12.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 9

differences concern the delimitation between the core system and the fund control system5,

the distribution of methods of control to the individual hospitals, the compensation for the

activities of hospital out-patient departments as well as covering possible hospital losses.

Table 2 shows the minimum resources of the state funds, which are then distributed

according to defined quotas. In 1999 those minimum resources financed around 51 per cent

of the final costs6 of the fund hospitals.

Table 2: Funding of hospitals (minium required amounts in Mio ATS)

In percent of

1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 in % 2001

VAT-volume

Contributions by federal government 6.119 6.185 6.333 6.407 6.584 12.7

VAT-share 1.416 2.788 2.855 3.003 3.077 3.254 6.3

a) Flat amount so far acc. art.12 (4) 2 330 330 330 330 330 0.6

b) Flat amount additional acc. art.12 (4) 3 1.250 1.250 1.250 1.250 1.250 2.4

c) Flat amount additional acc. art.12 (4) 4 1.750 1.750 1.750 1.750 1.750 3.4

Local government 0.949 1.869 1.913 2.013 2.062 2.181 4.2

Communities 0.642 1.264 1.294 1.362 1.395 1.475 2.8

Social insurance 36.923 37.892 39.230 40.235 41.650 80.3

a) Flat amount 36.503 37.467 38.800 39.800 41.200 79.4

(final) (final) (pre-liminary)

(pre- liminary)

(estimated)

b) Copayments and user charges 420 425 430 435 450 0.9

Total 46.245 47.284 48.938 50.099 51.890 100.0

Source: HiT-Austria 2001, Stenographic protocols, IHS HealthEcon 2001.

Around four fifths of the minimum resources of the regional funds come from social health

insurance funds. This amount is an annually indexed flat rate which is supplemented by co-

payments. The indexing of the flat rate depends on the development of the social health

insurance revenues. In 1999 around 41 per cent of the final costs of fund hospitals were

financed by the social health insurance flat rate.

The Länder, depending on their respective regional regulations, put further resources into the

state funds, for example to cover surplus spending. The structure for raising minimum funds

has been relatively constant since the introduction of the new financing method: the

structural fund contributes just 13 per cent to the resources of the state funds and is pooled

from Federal funds, roughly half from defined flat rates in accordance with Article 12 § 4 of

the Article 15-a agreement and half from a fixed share of 1.416 per cent of the VAT tax

5 Within the framework of the core system individual diagnosis groups are assigned standard flat rate point values nationwide. The control system is arranged by states and allows for consideration of state specific requirements by considering criteria specific to the structure (type of hospital, personnel factor, technical equipment, building sturcture, utilization of capacity and hotel components). For an explanation of the LKF-system cf. BMSG, Leistungsorientierte Krankenanstaltenfinanzierung (LKF) - Modell 2001 and descriptions from previous years. 6 Final costs inclusive of depreciation, final costs are adjusted for cost reductions and in-house settlements; cost reductions occur for example when non-medical services which are produced by a hospital for a demand external to the hospital are performed.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 10

revenue. Länder (0.949 per cent) and local authorities (0.642 per cent) likewise make their

(minimum) contribution to the state funds in the form of a fixed share of VAT tax revenue.

Due to the budgeting of the resources from social health insurance the risk of expenditure

development now rests solely with the owners of the hospitals or with the regional

administrative bodies. In Carinthia, for example, the province’s share of the fund resources

tripled in the first two years of the LKF-system, but while the contribution from social insurers

did increase by ATS 20 million, from a relative perspective it fell from 81 per cent to 67 per

cent7.

Further contributions to hospital financing from Federal funds are stipulated in the Federal

Hospitals Act (KAG) or in the Health and Social Sector Contribution Act (GSBG). The

Federal Government thus makes a targeted contribution towards the operational deficit of a

maximum of 18.75 per cent of the total surplus operating costs (§57 KAG). Under the title of

Clinical Additional Expenditure the Federal Government reimburses university hospitals for

the additional expenses that arise from construction, decorating and expansion as well as for

work that is necessary for teaching (§55 KAG). The cost of this was still estimated at ATS

5,000 million for the year 2000.

All expenditure that is above the level of the minimum funds allocated to the hospitals (the

so-called ‚operational deficit‘) must be borne by the legal holder/owner of the hospital, by the

Land, by the municipality and by the hospital district (in essence the local authorities in the

hospital’s catchment area). What share of the deficit the individual bodies concerned must

bear is subject to provincial legislation; the combined shares from the holders, the

municipality and the hospital district must, however, cover at least half of the “deficit” (§34

KAG). When the Land is also the owner of the hospital, the burden of the “deficit” is

correspondingly greater.

Länder management in hospitals

When all details are taken into consideration each Land can be seen to have its own system

of hospital financing8. These differences are presented here systematically. The first

criterion to be considered is the delimitation between the core system and the fund control

system.

7 Observation report from the Carinthia audit division 2000/2, issued 28th July 2000. 8 Dienesch S., G. Heitzenberger, Krankenanstaltenfinanzierung 9 mal anders, Österreichische Krankenhauszeitung 38, 12/1997, pp. 5-8; Rauner M. S., M. M. Schaffhauser-Linzatti, Evaluation of the new Austrian inpatient reimbursement system, In De Angelis, Ricciardi, Storchi (eds.), Monitoring, evaluation, planning health services. 1998, various observation reports from the Austrian audit division about the reform of the health service and hospital financing.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 11

Features of LKF-financing

• Marginal / No consideration of the control system: In Upper Austria the

opportunity to allocate resources according to qualitative criteria is not made use of

at all. In Lower Austria only two per cent of resources are distributed according to

this type of criteria, the type of hospital being the decisive factor in determining this.

• Fixed shares for the fund control and core system: In Voralberg, Tyrol and

Burgenland there is a fixed percentage distribution of resources for the core and

control system. In Voralberg this is 15 per cent and in Tyrol and Burgenland it is 30

per cent.

• Weighting of LKF-points according to criteria in the control system: Carinthia,

Styria and Vienna have not set a fixed percentage delimitation of the resources from

the core and control sector, instead they multiply the obtained points by a control

factor before the resources are distributed. Carinthia and Styria assign the

weighting factors to the types of hospitals in different ways, Vienna constructs

weights from a multiplied combination of a personnel factor and additional costs

factor.

• In Salzburg a mixture of fixed delimitation and weighting is used. The total

resources are divided into sections of which 75 per cent of the resources from the

first section (social insurance and KRAZAF funds) are to be distributed unweighted

according to care levels and 25 per cent weighted according to care levels. 40 per

cent of the resources from the second section (Land and local authority section) are

allocated according to past “operational deficits” and 60 per cent according to

weighted LDF points. As a result of the method of division used in Salzburg an

average proportion of 56 per cent was allocated to the core sector and 44 per cent to

the control sector in 1997 and 1998 according to the audit division’s report. As such

Salzburg has the largest control system by far in relative terms.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 12

Table 3: Structure of hospital financing arrangements in the Länder

Source: Rechnungshof 2000, IHS HealthEcon 2001.

Features of self-financing

To what extent and in what form the Länder finance their hospitals is regulated according by

Länder. In Burgenland, Lower Austria and Tyrol all resources are put into the funds, no

resources are retained outside of the funds. In all of the Länder except Carinthia and Styria9

self-financing restrictions are provided for by the Länder. The budgeting assures the

incentive for hospital holders to avoid spending surpluses. Thus for example in Salzburg,

Tyrol and Lower Austria there were no spending surpluses in 1997 and 1998.

In Upper Austria, Voralberg and in part in Vienna “operational deficits” are allocated on a

percentage basis, which slightly weakens the incentive to operate economically. For

example, in Voralberg the state and the local authorities each bear 40 per cent of the deficit

and the remaining 20 per cent is borne by the legal holders of the hospitals. Of the hospitals’

deficit 50 per cent was transferred to a balancing fund that exists within the fund and 50 per

cent of any deficits were settled from this. The legal holders had to pay for the remaining

deficit themselves.

9 In Styria an upper limit or minimum contribution was agreed on, deviating from this, however, the province then made resources corresponding to the then requirement available. Cf. Audit division report for Styria 2000/3, pp. 6.

Feature Burgen= land

Carinthia Lower Austria

Upper Austria

Salz= burg

Styria Tyrol Vorarl= berg

Vienna

Fund raising in the state funds. Raising of all resources for the fund incl. owner shares?

yes no yes no no no yes no* no

Limited to covering the net operating deficit?

yes no yes yes: % yes yes yes: % partial:%

Distribution of the resources for in-patients Allocation between core and control sector

70: 30 G1 98: 2 100: 0 G2, % G1 70: 30

85: 15 G1

Allocation of the control resources to individual hospitals

% G2 G2 G2, G3

G2 G2 G4 G5

Out-patient department reimbursement (according to audit division reports) Out-patient reimbursement

A P L** P P P L P P

%... fixed percentage basis G1... Weighting of LKF-Points, no separation between core and control system G2... Weighting according to type of hospital G3... Weighting according to the previous year’s operating deficits G4... Weighting according to personnel factor G5... Weighting according to a personnel factor and additional costs factor which are multiplied together. A... financed by compensation payments L... performance based P... flat rate sum * until 1999 funds were raised to a small extent outside the fund. ** Since 1999

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 13

In Lower Austria there has not been any deficit cover since the LKF came into effect. The

funds were balanced with the total budget made available, which also included the indexed

owners‘ shares of the province that were granted before the LKF. In Burgenland hospitals

that produce surpluses can put these into reserves. This can also be regarded as an

incentive to operate efficiently.

Financing hospital out-patient departments

Compensation for the activities of hospital out-patient departments is still carried out in the

form of lump sums in most Länder, although the introduction of an LKF system for out-patient

department activities is planned. The fact that expenditure-related compensation of the

service volumes in out-patient departments has still not been introduced was criticised in

reports from the audit division.

In Burgenland out-patient departments are partially financed by means of compensation from

a balancing funds. So far, only in Tyrol and since 1999 in Lower Austria is an LKF-system

already used for hospital out-patient departments.

From an economic point of view, however, the creation of performance-related compensation

geared exclusively towards out-patient departments distorts the optimal allocation of

resources. If a financing system based on flat rates for diagnoses is applied (as the LKF

should after all represent) then the goal of putting resources to their most efficient use can

only be fulfilled if the remuneration for the treatment of a standardised diagnosis is uniform.

Different flat rates for the same diagnosis in out-patient departments and in the in-patient

sector are contrary to the underlying intention10.

Do hospital companies place a greater burden on Länders‘ budgets?

A high net burden11 on Länder budgets appears to exist in those Länder in which a

substantial share of the hospitals are centrally amalgamated as is the case in Vienna, Styria

and Carinthia12. It is noticeable that although the net burden of individual Länder fluctuates

over time, the difference in levels between the Länder remains constant relatively

persistently13. Due to investment-related fluctuations Figure 4 shows the average burdens

for the available years (1994-1998).

10 Stepan A., M. Sommersguter-Reichmann, Analyse des neuen Leistungsorientierten Krankenanstalten-Finanzierungssystems in Österreich. Arbeitspapier, 2001, pp. 9. 11 Net burden = net expenditure for hospitals as a proportion of the total state budget. Net expenditure = balance from the comparison of expenditure relevant to appropriation and quantity from the ordinary and extraordinary budget with income. 12 The correlation between average net burden and the share of beds among centrally held hospitals is 76, the correlation between average net burden and the share of beds among centrally held hospitals is 63 (delimitation of the variables as in figure 4 and table 4). 13 In the last few years there have been major fluctuations in the burdens of Länder budgets as a result of hospital expenditure, which the audit division puts down to differing levels of investment activity.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 14

Chart 4: Average net burden of the state housholds 1994 – 1998

Source: Rechnungshof 2000, IHS HealthEcon 2001.

In Vienna the burden on the Land budget (an average of 8 percent) is double that in

Voralberg (4 per cent). The burdens of the other Länder fall significantly behind those of

Vienna, Styria and Carinthia. In the three Länder named up to 75 per cent of beds are

concentrated in hospitals which belong to the state´s hospital association or company. (see

table 4). In Voralberg on the other hand the hospital landscape is organised on a smaller

scale. There is a multitude of hospitals with fewer beds and furthermore practically no

amalgamations under a central holders‘ organisation. In Lower Austria, where the burden of

the state budget is likewise small, many hospitals have certainly amalgamated but with a

series of regional associations rather than with one central association.

0,0

1,0

2,0

3,0

4,0

5,0

6,0

7,0

8,0

9,0

Vie

nna

Sty

ria

Car

inth

ia

Bur

genl

and

Low

erA

ustr

ia

Tyr

ol

Upp

erA

ustr

ia

Sal

zbur

g

Vor

arlb

erg

In p

erce

nt

of

the

ove

rall

bu

dg

et

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 15

Table 4: Hospitals and beds according to owner 1998

Source: BMSG 2000, IHS HealthEcon 2001.

An increaAn increasing number of cases being treated and point maximisation sing number of cases being treated and point maximisation appears obvious but undesirableappears obvious but undesirable

It is interesting for health policy to determine whether LKF-financing has led to behavioural

changes on the part of the decision-makers in the hospital sector. Firstly, it is relevant

whether the number of cases is increasing and secondly whether evidence exists of a

change in coding habits triggered by the new form of financing14. In addition, it is interesting

to establish whether any possible behavioural changes differ between Länder, especially as

each Land is organising their financing in a different way.

Remuneration systems based on flat rates for cases have been repeatedly criticised. This

criticism is not based solely on theoretical considerations15 but rather is supported by

observations made during the introduction of such systems in other countries16. As long as

the diagnosis is decisive for the payment then the incentive exists to exploit the scope of

interpretation in favour of more highly valued diagnoses (DRG creep). This has already

been experienced internationally17 and a similar mechanism could also take effect in Austria.

In Lower Austria, for example, the sanction mechanism was used in accordance with a

networked data evaluation for a third of the cases invoiced because of point optimisation;

around 8.5 million points (point value in 1998 = ATS 0.986) were deducted. In Tyrol it was

established within the framework of safeguards for data and medical quality that the use of

14 It should, however, be noted that coding habits are certainly not only caused by economic incentives but rather, for example, also caused by the commitment of the local controllings and those reponsible for quality assurance and the safeguarding of data. 15 e.g. Stepan A., M. Sommersguter-Reichmann, 2001, op. cit. 16 Lauterbach K., M. Arnold, Über die Vor- und Nachteile einer leistungsbezogenen Vergütung der stationären Versorgung. Lehren aus den USA für das deutsche Krankenhaus. In Arnold, Paffrath: Krankenhaus-Report '95, Gustav Fischer Verlag, pp. 167-175. 17 Hofmarcher M.M., E. Orosz, Resource Allocation and Purchasing in Hungary, The World Bank 2001.

share sharetotal central unique central, % total central unique central, %

Vienna 56 30 26 53.6 19.514 14.594 4.920 74.8Carinthia 22 9 13 40.9 5.154 3.398 1.756 65.9Styria 53 20 33 37.7 11.130 6.888 4.242 61.9Burgenland 7 4 3 57.1 1.637 936 701 57.2Tyrol 19 4 15 21.1 4.761 2.198 2.563 46.2Vorarlberg 46 3 43 6.5 3.282 1.360 1.922 41.4Salzburg 30 3 27 10.0 4.933 2.028 2.905 41.1Upper Austria 39 15 24 38.5 10.566 4.135 6.431 39.1Lower Austria 49 5 44 10.2 10.739 1.811 8.928 16.9

Total 321 93 228 29.0 71.716 37.348 34.368 52.1

Comment: If no hospital association is established the respective office of the state government was treated as the central holder.

Number of hospitals Number of beds

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 16

an optimisation programme had resulted in supplementary point correction totalling around

7.25 million points or ATS 5.4 million18.

The error rate for Salzburg was only slightly lower than for Lower Austria. In Salzburg the

proportion of cases that were incorrectly coded even increased between 1997 (28 per cent)

and 1998 (37 per cent) and fell again to around the initial level (27 per cent) in 1999. The

1998 increase should, however, also be seen in context with the new, more detailed

intensive documentation and with the stricter checking procedures. Of the cases queried in

1999 too many services were coded in roughly a quarter and false diagnoses had been

made in 17 per cent19.

An increasing number of cases being treated: how great is the prevalence of supplier -induced demand?

As the individual case being treated now forms the basis of hospital revenue rather than the

hospital day as was the case previously20, economically rational behaviour (with the

assumption of short-term fixed input costs) results in a maximisation of the number of cases

treated each with a shorter length of stay. Under the old system, on the other hand, it was

economically optimal to maximise the number of hospital days, which were charged at a flat

rate. Correspondingly it was to be expected that when the system changed there would be

an increase in the number of cases and a fall in the duration of stay.

A marked increase in the number of in-patients cases occurred in almost all Länder,

frequently followed by a further, similarly large increase in the second year of the LKF. Only

Burgenland showed no obvious increase in the number of cases and in Voralberg the

increase in cases was apparently already anticipated in 1996. The pattern of hospital stay

durations is more ambiguous: viewed over the entire time period from 1994 – 1999 the

average length of stay fell in all Länder except for Vienna. However, on examination of the

individual years, 1997 stands out as having featured a conspicuously large decline in

duration of stays in Upper and Lower Austria.

18 Observation report from the audit division, Lower Austria 2000/10, pp. 22, Tyrol 2000/3, pp. 23. 19 Salzburger Krankenanstaltenfinanzierungsfonds, Report on the Salzburg hospital financing fund (SAKRAF) concerning 1999, Salzburg, April 2000. 20 In the current system the hospital care day is useful only when maximum or minimum values for the duration of stay are exceeded or not reached, and is then organised degressively. It is therefore economically unattractive to extend the duration of stay beyond the upper limit.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 17

Chart 5: Changes in the number of inpatient cases

-2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

Aus

tria

Bur

genl

and

Car

inth

ia

Low

erA

ustr

ia

Upp

erA

ustr

ia

Sal

zbur

g

Sty

ria

Tyr

ol

Vor

arlb

erg

Vie

nna

% c

han

ge

ove

r p

revi

ou

s ye

ar

1995

1996

1997

1998

Source: Statistik Austria, IHS HealthEcon 2001.

Point maximisation or morbidity?

The hospital discharge statistics show that the frequency of individual diagnoses made

significant leaps when the LKF system came into effect. An example of this is the diagnoses

from the births and complications of gravidity sector (ICD630-676). In 1994 normal births

(ICD650) nationwide were coded around twice as frequently as complications of gravidity,

birth or puerperal fever (ICD640-648, 651-676). By 1996 the proportion of complications

grew to the cost of the proportion of normal births, the ratio of complications to normal births

was 0.59:1. In 1997 this ratio then shifted sharply to 1.12:1, thus significantly more

complications were coded than normal births. In 1998 the number of complications coded

then fell again to slightly below the number of normal births.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 18

Chart 6: Childbirths and complications of gravidity

Source: Hospital discharge statistics according to annual health statistics, current years, IHS HealthEcon.

The decline in the birth rate between 1994 and 1998 was roughly 12 per cent, the decline in

births coded as normal, however, was almost 29 per cent. It therefore appears probable that

the increase in the proportion of complications coded was not caused solely by an increase

in complications during or after pregnancy but rather was also a result of a change in coding

practices.

In the current diagnostic key (model 2000) the flat rate for a normal birth is 19,290 points,

per/postpartale complications are worth 19,998 points and serious peri/postpartale

complications are worth 20,900 points. Without further investigation, however, a more

precise explanation for the change in diagnostic behaviour cannot be given. One possibility

could be that birth complications were previously neglected in the documentation if no further

(financial) consequences were dependent on it and that this neglect has now been

eradicated. It is, however, just as conceivable that the scope for diagnostic interpretation is

now being systematically exploited to gain higher point values. The aforementioned

frequency of false coding in several Länder is grounds for the assumption that there exists a

certain degree of freedom to exploit the system. In the individual Länder the statistics for

1997 likewise show a sharp increase in complications in most cases, the increase is most

pronounced in Upper Austria. There are conspicuous deviations in Voralberg and Vienna:

the proportion of complications increased here to a significantly higher level than the

nationwide average but rather than decreasing again in 1998 it actually increased slightly

more. A growing frequency of complications was registered in Styria in 1997 and 1998 but

the initial level in this Land was so far below the national average that although it doubled,

0,00

0,20

0,40

0,60

0,80

1,00

1,20

1,40

1,60

1,80

Aus

tria

Bur

genl

and

Car

inth

ia

Low

erA

ustr

ia

Upp

erA

ustr

ia

Sal

zbur

g

Sty

ria

Tyr

ol

Vor

arlb

erg

Vie

nna

Rat

io o

f co

mp

licat

ion

s to

no

rmal

ch

ildb

irth

s 19941995199619971998

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 19

the frequency of complications relative to normal births in 1998 was still lower than in any

other state. In 1994 in Styria around three times more normal births were coded than

complications. Styria (0.30:1) therefore already deviated conspicuously in 1994 from the

ratios of the other Länder which ranged from 0.47:1 (Voralberg) to 0.63:1 (Vienna).

The frequent diagnosis of complications in connection with gravidity, birth and puerperal

fever could also explain why the average length of stay in Vienna is relatively low in the case

of both normal births (1998 Austria 6.0; Vienna 5.3) and complications (1998 Austria 6.2;

Vienna 5.5). A similar argument can be made in Styria where complications are diagnosed

comparatively rarely and the duration of hospital stay for normal births is the second highest

in the country after Voralberg.

Appendix: Prognosis for the Austrian economy

The symptoms of a cooling-off of the world economy have further intensified. The expected

weakening of the USA economy has set in but is greater than anticipated. Last autumn the

European Commission predicted an economic growth rate of 3.3 per cent for 2001 and 3 per

cent for 2002; at present, however, analysts are questioning whether a growth rate of even 3

per cent will be attainable in the current year. This estimation is supported by the data that

has meanwhile become available. The clear weakening of the American growth rate is

spreading to Europe.

Austria forms no exception to this picture of the economy. For Austria, however, more recent

forecast values can be presented in table A1 than for the USA and the EU, the data are

therefore not directly comparable. Economic growth in Austria will be almost one percentage

point lower in 2001 than last year but could increase again slightly as early as 2002. The

trend in real wages remained significantly behind the trend in work productivity in the year

2000; Austria’s unemployment rate according to the EUROSTAT definition also continues to

remain below half the level of the comparative EU figure. As work force supply will scarcely

increase it can be assumed that despite the weakening economy unemployment will

decrease further.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 20

1998 1999 2000 2001 2002Austria 3.3 2.8 3.2 2.3 2.5EU-15 2.7 2.5 3.4 3.1 3.0EU-12 2.8 2.5 3.5 3.2 3.0United States 4.4 4.3 5.1 3.3 3.0

Austria 0.8 0.5 1.9 1.8 1.6EU-151) 1.3 1.2 2.1 2.0 1.8EU-121) 1.1 1.1 2.3 2.2 1.9United States n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a

Austria 2.3 1.7 2.3 1.8 2.0EU-15 1.2 0.8 1.8 1.8 1.8EU-12 1.1 0.7 1.6 1.7 1.6United States 2.1 2.3 3.6 2.4 2.3

Austria 0.9 1.1 0.9 0.5 0.5EU-15 1.6 1.6 1.6 1.3 1.2EU-12 1.6 1.8 1.8 1.5 1.4United States 2.2 1.9 1.5 0.9 0.7

Austria 4.5 4.0 3.7 3.6 3.4EU-15 9.9 9.2 8.4 7.8 7.3EU-12 10.8 9.9 9.0 8.5 7.9United States 4.5 4.2 4.1 4.3 4.7

Austria -2.3 -2.1 -1.1 -0.7 0EU-15 -1.5 -0.7 1.2 0.2 0.3EU-12 -2.1 -1.3 0.3 -0.5 -0.3United States 0.3 1.0 1.9 2.4 2.6

1) Real annual change in percent.2) Taking into account the definition of EUROSTAT on the basis of labour force data.Source: Austria: Forecast of the Austrian economy 2001-2002, Institute For Advanced Studies, March 2001; EU, USA and HVPI Austria: European Economy, Directorate General of the European Commission Economics and Finance, Supplement A: Economic Analyses No. 10/11 - October/November 2000.

Table A1: Economic Forecast

Gross Domestic Product, at constant prices (percentage changes relative to the previous year)

Inflation (harmonised consumer price index HCPI)(percentage changes relative to the previous year)

Labour productivity (Real GDP per employed person) (percentage changes relative to the previous year)

Number of employees

(in percent of GDP)

(percentage changes relative to the previous year)

Number of unemployed (in percent of the persons in civilian employment)2

Finance surplus/-deficit of the general government

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 21

Table A2: Per capital Gross Domestic Product, US Dollar, purchasing power parity Index EU15=100

1990 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 1990 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999

Austria 16783 21124 22031 22904 23872 24541 105 108 110 111 112 111 Belgium 16746 21807 22215 22820 23566 24289 105 112 111 111 110 110 Denmark 17096 22939 24203 24642 25588 26425 107 118 121 120 120 120 Germany 18351 21357 21570 22232 22951 23616 115 110 108 108 108 107 Finland 16442 18861 19408 20471 21741 22807 103 97 97 99 102 103 France 17655 20640 20731 20884 21721 22465 111 106 103 101 102 102 Greece 9239 12834 13367 13560 14095 14740 58 66 67 66 66 67 United Kingdom 16055 18705 20052 20959 21675 22459 101 96 100 102 102 102 Ireland 11388 17761 18528 20444 22587 24769 71 91 92 99 106 112 Italy 16257 20188 20846 20865 21312 21844 102 104 104 101 100 99 Luxembourg 22655 33532 34137 36009 37613 39636 142 172 170 175 176 179 Netherlands 15921 21224 21914 23189 24119 25162 100 109 109 113 113 114 Portugal 9598 13643 14117 15056 15787 16433 60 70 70 73 74 74 Sweden 17654 19210 19726 20079 20867 21930 111 99 98 98 98 99 Spain 11734 15227 15836 16376 17257 18162 74 78 79 80 81 82 EU 15* 15954 19473 20045 20587 21338 22090 100 100 100 100 100 100 EU 12* 15859 19570 19980 20458 21210 21946 99 101 100 99 99 99 Switzerland 21488 25684 25160 26261 26782 27407 135 132 126 128 126 124 United States 22266 26786 27975 29297 30625 31935 140 138 140 142 144 145 Bulgaria 4700 4875 4597 4370 4517 4749 29 25 23 21 21 21 Estonia 6438 5608 6124 7079 7518 7682 40 29 31 34 35 35 Latvia 6457 4288 4656 5291 5589 5786 40 22 23 26 26 26 Lithuania 4913 4856 5297 5899 6259 6169 31 25 26 29 29 28 Malta 8732 13316 n/a 13180 16447 n/a 55 68 n/a 64 77 n/a Poland 4899 5664 6224 6889 7287 7806 31 29 31 33 34 35 Romania 2800 5630 6108 5967 5703 5682 18 29 30 29 27 26 Slovakia 6690 2) 7730 8525 9371 9828 10279 42 40 43 46 46 47 Slovenia 9156 1) 11324 12185 13246 13908 14964 57 58 61 64 65 68 Czech Republic 11532 11001 12011 12342 12186 12498 72 56 60 60 57 57 Turkey 4691 5216 5643 6124 6360 5881 29 27 28 30 30 27 Hungary 8359 8119 8590 9350 9899 10705 52 42 43 45 46 48 Cyprus n/a 13829 14524 15259 16033 17082 n/a 71 72 74 75 77 Accession13* 5319 6082 6547 6998 7217 7236 33 31 33 34 34 33 CEE10* 5640 6506 7026 7443 7645 8007 35 33 35 36 36 36

* population weighted average; 1) 1991, 2) 1992; CEE10: entry touting countries without Malta, Turky, Cyprus Sources: OECD Health Data, Oct. 2000; Progress Reports 2000 for all entry touting countries 1995-1999; WHO Health for all database, January 2001 for all entry touting countries 1990 and Malta 1990-1999; IHS HealthEcon 2001.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 22

Table A3: Per capita health expenditure, US Dollar, purchasing power parity Index EU15=100

1990 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 1990 1995 1996 1997 1998

Austria 1209 1875 1967 1886 1968 2039 96 111 112 106 107 Belgium 1246 1793 1911 1973 2081 n/a 99 107 109 111 113 Denmark 1442 1887 2006 2032 2133 2202 115 112 114 114 116 Germany 1602 2178 2288 2325 2424 2476 128 130 130 131 131 Finland 1292 1421 1486 1491 1502 n/a 103 84 85 84 81 France 1545 2006 2007 1987 2055 2130 123 119 114 112 111 Greece 706 1059 1114 1157 1167 n/a 56 63 63 65 63 United Kingdom 964 1301 1410 1406 1461 1583 77 77 80 79 79 Ireland 796 1314 1333 1432 1436 n/a 63 78 76 80 78 Italy 1321 1608 1691 1754 1783 1839 105 96 96 98 97 Luxembourg 1485 2113 2181 2147 2215 n/a 118 126 124 121 120 Netherlands 1403 1889 1937 2004 2070 n/a 112 112 110 113 112 Portugal 614 1051 1090 1151 1237 n/a 49 62 62 65 67 Sweden 1548 1622 1716 1712 1746 n/a 123 96 98 96 95 Spain 811 1068 1119 1154 1218 n/a 65 64 64 65 66 EU 15* 1256 1682 1756 1781 1845 n/a 100 100 100 100 100 EU 12* 1304 1755 1821 1852 1919 n/a 104 104 104 104 104 Switzerland 1782 2477 2549 2697 2794 n/a 142 147 145 151 151 United States 2755 3716 3855 3998 4178 4390 219 221 219 224 226 Bulgaria+ 220 223 197 205 193 n/a 18 13 11 12 10 Estonia+ 606 1) 465 480 477 492 n/a 48 28 27 27 27 Latvia+ 789 1) 320 324 344 366 n/a 63 19 18 19 20 Lithuania+ 247 2) 292 477 521 533 n/a 20 17 27 29 29 Malta+ 621 1) n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a 49 n/a n/a n/a n/a Poland** 258 420 473 448 496 508 21 25 27 25 27 Romania** 79 133 128 112 147 n/a 6 8 7 6 8 Slovakia+ 507 575 604 640 655 n/a 40 34 34 36 35 Slovenia** 311 975 1030 1086 1101 n/a 25 58 59 61 60 Czech Republic** 575 902 917 930 930 993 46 54 52 52 50 Turkey** 171 189 227 255 309 n/a 14 11 13 14 17 Hungary** 510 678 662 672 705 n/a 41 40 38 38 38 Cyprus+ 546 1) 664 2) n/a n/a n/a n/a 43 39 n/a n/a n/a Accession13* 259 341 369 376 414 n/a 21 20 21 21 22 CEE10* 303 427 453 448 478 n/a 24 25 26 25 26

*population weighted average; 1) 1991, 2) 1993; CEE10: entry touting countries without Malta, Turky, Cyprus Sources: OECD Health Data, Oct. 2000; **WHO Health for all database, January 2001; +World Development Indicators 2000; IHS HealthEcon 2001.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 23

Table A4: Health expenditure in percent of GDP Index EU15=100

1990 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 1990 1995 1996 1997 1998

Austria 7.2 8.9 8.9 8.2 8.2 8.3 92 103 102 95 95 Belgium 7.4 8.2 8.6 8.6 8.8 n/a 94 95 98 99 102 Denmark 8.4 8.2 8.3 8.2 8.3 8.3 107 95 95 95 96 Germany 8.7 10.2 10.6 10.5 10.6 10.5 111 118 121 121 122 Finland 7.9 7.5 7.7 7.3 6.9 n/a 100 87 88 84 80 France 8.8 9.7 9.7 9.5 9.5 9.5 112 112 111 110 110 Greece 7.6 8.3 8.3 8.5 8.3 n/a 97 96 95 98 96 United Kingdom 6.0 7.0 7.0 6.7 6.7 7.0 76 81 80 78 77 Ireland 7.0 7.4 7.2 7.0 6.4 n/a 89 86 82 81 74 Italy 8.1 8.0 8.1 8.4 8.4 8.4 103 93 92 97 97 Luxembourg 6.6 6.3 6.4 6.0 5.9 n/a 84 73 73 69 68 Netherlands 8.8 8.9 8.8 8.6 8.6 n/a 112 103 100 99 99 Portugal 6.4 7.7 7.7 7.6 7.8 n/a 81 89 88 88 90 Sweden 8.8 8.4 8.7 8.5 8.4 n/a 112 97 99 98 97 Spain 6.9 7.0 7.1 7.0 7.1 n/a 88 81 81 81 82 EU 15* 7.9 8.6 8.8 8.6 8.7 n/a 100 100 100 100 100 EU 12* 8.2 9.0 9.1 9.1 9.1 n/a 104 104 104 105 105 Switzerland 8.3 9.6 10.1 10.3 10.4 n/a 106 111 115 119 120 United States 12.4 13.9 13.8 13.6 13.6 13.7 158 161 158 157 157 Bulgaria+ 4.1 4.0 3.9 4.3 4.0 n/a 52 46 44 50 46 Estonia 4.5 2) 6.2 6.1 5.5 5.9 6.9 57 72 70 64 68 Latvia 2.5 4.2 4.5 4.5 3.9 4.4 32 49 51 52 45 Lithuania 3.3 4.9 4.7 5.1 5.3 n/a 42 57 54 59 61 Malta n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a 8.3 n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a Poland 5.3 6.0 6.4 6.2 6.4 6.3 67 69 73 72 74 Romania 2.8 3.0 2.8 2.6 2.6 n/a 36 35 32 30 30 Slovakia 5.4 6.4 7.6 7.5 7.2 n/a 68 74 87 87 83 Slovenia 5.6 7.8 7.8 7.7 7.7 7.7 72 90 89 89 89 Czech Republic 5.0 7.3 7.0 7.1 7.2 7.6 64 84 80 82 83 Turkey 3.6 3.3 3.8 4.0 4.8 n/a 46 38 43 46 55 Hungary 6.1 7.6 7.2 6.9 6.8 n/a 78 88 82 80 78 Cyprus+ 4.3 1) 4.5 3) n/a n/a n/a n/a 54 52 n/a n/a n/a Accession13* 4.4 5.0 5.2 5.2 5.5 n/a 56 58 59 60 64 CEE10* 4.7 5.8 5.8 5.8 5.9 n/a 59 67 67 67 68

* GDP-weigthed average; 1) 1991, 2) 1992, 3) 1993; CEE10: entry touting countries without Malta, Turky, Cyprus Sources: OECD Health Data, Oct. 2000; WHO Health for all database, January 2001 for all entry touting countries ; +World Development Indicators 2000; IHS HealthEcon 2001.

HEALTH SYSTEM WATCH 1/2001 24

Table A5: Public expenditure on health in percent of total health expenditure Index EU15=100 1990 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 1990 1995 1996 1997 1998 Austria 73.5 71.9 70.5 70.9 70.5 71.6 94 94 92 93 94 Belgium 88.9 88.7 88.8 89.3 89.7 n/a 114 116 116 118 119 Denmark 82.6 82.6 82.4 82.4 81.9 82.1 106 108 108 109 109 Germany 76.2 78.1 78.3 76.9 74.6 75.3 98 102 103 101 99 Finland 80.9 75.5 75.9 76.1 76.3 n/a 104 99 99 100 101 France 76.9 76.3 76.3 76.4 76.4 76.6 99 100 100 101 102 Greece 62.7 58.7 58.7 57.7 56.8 n/a 80 77 77 76 75 United Kingdom 84.2 84.9 83.7 83.7 83.7 84.2 108 111 110 110 111 Ireland 71.7 72.7 72.5 75.0 75.8 n/a 92 95 95 99 101 Italy 78.1 67.4 67.4 67.5 67.3 n/a 100 88 88 89 89 Luxembourg 93.1 92.4 92.8 92.5 92.3 n/a 119 121 122 122 123 Netherlands 68.7 72.5 67.7 69.6 70.4 n/a 88 95 89 92 94 Portugal 65.5 65.3 66.7 67.1 66.9 n/a 84 85 87 88 89 Sweden 89.9 85.2 84.8 84.3 83.8 n/a 115 111 111 111 111 Spain 78.7 78.3 78.5 76.5 76.9 n/a 101 102 103 101 102 EU 15* 78.0 76.6 76.3 75.9 75.2 n/a 100 100 100 100 100 EU 12* 76.5 75.0 74.8 74.3 73.6 n/a 98 98 98 98 98 Switzerland 68.4 72.3 74.5 73.2 73.4 n/a 88 94 98 97 98 United States 39.6 45.1 45.5 45.4 44.7 44.2 51 59 60 60 59 Bulgaria 100.0 100.0 n/a n/a n/a n/a 128 131 n/a n/a n/a Estonia n/a n/a 88.0 87.0 87.0 84.0 n/a n/a 115 115 116 Latvia 100.0 95.0 88.0 85.0 78.9 n/a 128 124 115 112 105 Lithuania 90.0 90.0 90.0 90.0 90.0 n/a 115 118 118 119 120 Malta n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a 51.1 n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a Poland 91.7 75.8 76.5 74.1 73.3 72.2 118 99 100 98 97 Romania 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 n/a 128 131 131 132 133 Slovakia 100.0 94.2 92.5 91.1 91.7 n/a 128 123 121 120 122 Slovenia 100.0 89.7 89.1 88.3 88.0 86.0 128 117 117 116 117 Czech Republic 96.2 92.7 92.5 91.7 91.9 91.8 123 121 121 121 122 Turkey 61.0 70.8 71.2 72.8 71.9 n/a 78 92 93 96 96 Hungary 100.0 76.2 76.5 75.3 76.5 n/a 128 100 100 99 102 Cyprus n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a n/a Accession13* 88.0 81.8 80.9 80.0 79.3 n/a 113 107 106 105 105 CEE10* 96.3 84.7 83.7 82.4 82.2 n/a 123 111 110 109 109 *Average weighted on total health expentiture; CEE10: entry touting cauntries without Malta, Turky, Cyprus Sources: OECD Health Data, Oct. 2000; WHO Health for all database, January 2001 for all entry touting countries; IHS HealthEcon 2001.


Recommended