+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Kasus Final CH06

Kasus Final CH06

Date post: 27-Jan-2016
Category:
Upload: anonymous-nr4abp1w0u
View: 9 times
Download: 1 times
Share this document with a friend
Popular Tags:
103
1 Decision Decision Models Models Decision Theory ( Ch 6) Decision Theory ( Ch 6)
Transcript
Page 1: Kasus Final CH06

1

Decision ModelsDecision Models

Decision Theory ( Ch 6)Decision Theory ( Ch 6)

Page 2: Kasus Final CH06

Decision Under uncertainty Decision Under uncertainty dan dan

Under RiskUnder Risk• Dalam under Risk kita kenal ada 3 Kriteria ,

yakni :

a. Expected Value=Expected Profit= Expected Pay off

b. Expected Loss=Expected Opportunity loss

c.Expected Profit With perfect information

2

Page 3: Kasus Final CH06

Lanjutan Lanjutan

• Dalam Decision Under Uncertainty, dikenal kriteria sbb:

a. Criteria MAXIMAX b Criteria MAXIMIN c. Criteria Realism ( Hurwiczt ) d. Criteria Simple Average ( Laplace) dan c. Criteria Regreet/ Loss opportunity

3

Page 4: Kasus Final CH06

Dalam Kasus2 DecisionDalam Kasus2 Decision

• Dalam contoh kasus kadang Ada data2 yang ditampilkan dalam tabel Pay off( SEPERTI DALAM ch 6 ini ). Sementara dalam kasus yang lain ( Kasus ikan BARONANG Bab 7 ) kita diminta menghitung dan mengisi data tabel pay Off melalui perkiraan2 baik dengan logika2 dan maupun juga dengan menggunakan formula2 perkiraan matematis .

• Baik tersedia data atau tidak, yang terpenting bagi kita dalam Decision Theory adalaha bagaimana kita bisa memahami kasus, memformulasi kasus ,dan selanjutnya menggunakan Logika, Decision Analysis untuk mencari S olusi atas suatu problem.

4

Page 5: Kasus Final CH06

Soal FinalSoal Final• Dua soal dikerjakan di rumah dan dikumpulkan

bersama final di klas, yaitu soal pada bab 5 Buku Iqbal Hasan, N0.8 dan 9 hal 73-74

• Sementar satu soal dikerjakan di klas pada ruang kuliah tanggal 6 ,yaitu soal berdasarkan contoh kasus chapter enam (ch 6) ini. Pelajari kasus decision under Under Uncertainty

5

Page 6: Kasus Final CH06

6

6.1 6.1 Introduction to Decision AnalysisIntroduction to Decision Analysis

• The field of decision analysis provides a framework for making important decisions.

• Decision analysis allows us to select a decision from a set of possible decision alternatives when uncertainties regarding the future exist.

• The goal is to optimize the resulting payoff in terms of a decision criterion.

Page 7: Kasus Final CH06

7

• Maximizing the decision maker’s utility

function is the mechanism used when risk

is factored into the decision making

process.

• Maximizing expected profit is a common

criterion when probabilities can be

assessed.

6.1 6.1 Introduction to Decision AnalysisIntroduction to Decision Analysis

Page 8: Kasus Final CH06

8

6.26.2 Payoff Table AnalysisPayoff Table Analysis

• Payoff Tables

– Payoff table analysis can be applied when:• There is a finite set of discrete decision alternatives.• The outcome of a decision is a function of a single future event.

– In a Payoff table -• The rows correspond to the possible decision alternatives.• The columns correspond to the possible future events.• Events (states of nature) are mutually exclusive and collectively

exhaustive.• The table entries are the payoffs.

Page 9: Kasus Final CH06

9

TOM BROWN INVESTMENT DECISIONTOM BROWN INVESTMENT DECISION

• Tom Brown has inherited $1000.• He has to decide how to invest the money for one

year.• A broker has suggested five potential investments.

– Gold– Junk Bond– Growth Stock– Certificate of Deposit– Stock Option Hedge

Page 10: Kasus Final CH06

10

• The return on each investment depends on the (uncertain) market behavior during the year.

• Tom would build a payoff table to help make the investment decision

TOM BROWNTOM BROWN

Page 11: Kasus Final CH06

11

S1 S2 S3 S4

D1 p11 p12 p13 p14

D2 p21 p22 p23 P24

D3 p31 p32 p33 p34

• Select a decision making criterion, and apply it to the payoff table.

TOM BROWN - SolutionTOM BROWN - Solution

S1 S2 S3 S4

D1 p11 p12 p13 p14

D2 p21 p22 p23 P24

D3 p31 p32 p33 p34

Criterion

P1P2P3

• Construct a payoff table.

• Identify the optimal decision.

• Evaluate the solution.

Page 12: Kasus Final CH06

12

Decision States of Nature

Alternatives Large Rise Small Rise No Change Small Fall Large Fall

Gold -100 100 200 300 0Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600C/D account 60 60 60 60 60Stock option 200 150 150 -200 -150

The Payoff TableThe Payoff Table

The states of nature are mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive.

Define the states of nature.

DJA is down more than 800 points

DJA is down [-300, -800]

DJA moveswithin [-300,+300]

DJA is up [+300,+1000]

DJA is up more than1000 points

Page 13: Kasus Final CH06

13

Decision States of Nature

Alternatives Large Rise Small Rise No Change Small Fall Large Fall

Gold -100 100 200 300 0Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600C/D account 60 60 60 60 60Stock option 200 150 150 -200 -150

The Payoff TableThe Payoff Table

Determine the set of possible decision alternatives.

Page 14: Kasus Final CH06

14

Decision States of Nature

Alternatives Large Rise Small Rise No Change Small Fall Large Fall

Gold -100 100 200 300 0Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600C/D account 60 60 60 60 60Stock option 200 150 150 -200 -150

The stock option alternative is dominated by the bond alternative

250 200 150 -100 -150

-150

The Payoff TableThe Payoff Table

Page 15: Kasus Final CH06

15

6.3 6.3 Decision Making CriteriaDecision Making Criteria

• Classifying decision-making criteria

– Decision making under certainty.• The future state-of-nature is assumed known.

– Decision making under risk.• There is some knowledge of the probability of the states of

nature occurring.– Decision making under uncertainty.

• There is no knowledge about the probability of the states of nature occurring.

Page 16: Kasus Final CH06

16

• The decision criteria are based on the decision maker’s attitude toward life.

• The criteria include the– Maximin Criterion - pessimistic or conservative approach.– Minimax Regret Criterion - pessimistic or conservative approach.– Maximax Criterion - optimistic or aggressive approach.– Principle of Insufficient Reasoning – no information about the

likelihood of the various states of nature.

Decision Making Under UncertaintyDecision Making Under Uncertainty

Page 17: Kasus Final CH06

17

Decision Making Under Uncertainty - Decision Making Under Uncertainty - The Maximin CriterionThe Maximin Criterion

Page 18: Kasus Final CH06

18

• This criterion is based on the worst-case scenario. – It fits both a pessimistic and a conservative decision

maker’s styles.

– A pessimistic decision maker believes that the worst

possible result will always occur.

– A conservative decision maker wishes to ensure a guaranteed minimum possible payoff.

Decision Making Under Uncertainty - Decision Making Under Uncertainty - The Maximin CriterionThe Maximin Criterion

Page 19: Kasus Final CH06

19

TOM BROWN - The Maximin CriterionTOM BROWN - The Maximin Criterion

• To find an optimal decision

– Record the minimum payoff across all states of nature for

each decision.

– Identify the decision with the maximum “minimum payoff.”

The Maximin Criterion Minimum

Decisions Large Rise Small rise No Change Small Fall Large Fall Payoff

Gold -100 100 200 300 0 -100Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150 -150Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600 -600C/D account 60 60 60 60 60 60

The Maximin Criterion Minimum

Decisions Large Rise Small rise No Change Small Fall Large Fall Payoff

Gold -100 100 200 300 0 -100Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150 -150Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600 -600C/D account 60 60 60 60 60 60

The optimal decision

Page 20: Kasus Final CH06

20

=MAX(H4:H7)

* FALSE is the range lookup argument in the VLOOKUP function in cell B11 since the values in column H are not in ascending order

=VLOOKUP(MAX(H4:H7),H4:I7,2,FALSE)

=MIN(B4:F4)Drag to H7

The Maximin Criterion - spreadsheetThe Maximin Criterion - spreadsheet

Page 21: Kasus Final CH06

21

To enable the spreadsheet to correctly identify the optimal maximin decision in cell B11, the labels for cells A4 through A7 are copied into cells I4 through I7 (note that column I in the spreadsheet is hidden).

I4

Cell I4 (hidden)=A4Drag to I7

The Maximin Criterion - spreadsheetThe Maximin Criterion - spreadsheet

Page 22: Kasus Final CH06

22

Decision Making Under Uncertainty - Decision Making Under Uncertainty - The Minimax Regret CriterionThe Minimax Regret Criterion

Page 23: Kasus Final CH06

23

• The Minimax Regret Criterion– This criterion fits both a pessimistic and a

conservative decision maker approach.– The payoff table is based on “lost opportunity,” or

“regret.”– The decision maker incurs regret by failing to choose

the “best” decision.

Decision Making Under Uncertainty - Decision Making Under Uncertainty - The Minimax Regret CriterionThe Minimax Regret Criterion

Page 24: Kasus Final CH06

24

• The Minimax Regret Criterion– To find an optimal decision, for each state of nature:

• Determine the best payoff over all decisions.• Calculate the regret for each decision alternative as the

difference between its payoff value and this best payoff value.

– For each decision find the maximum regret over all states of nature.

– Select the decision alternative that has the minimum of these “maximum regrets.”

Decision Making Under Uncertainty - Decision Making Under Uncertainty - The Minimax Regret CriterionThe Minimax Regret Criterion

Page 25: Kasus Final CH06

25

The Payoff TableDecision Large rise Small rise No change Small fall Large fallGold -100 100 200 300 0Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600C/D 60 60 60 60 60

The Payoff TableDecision Large rise Small rise No change Small fall Large fallGold -100 100 200 300 0Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600C/D 60 60 60 60 60

TOM BROWN – Regret TableTOM BROWN – Regret Table

Let us build the Regret Table

The Regret TableDecision Large rise Small rise No change Small fall Large fallGold 600 150 0 0 60Bond 250 50 50 400 210Stock 0 0 100 500 660C/D 440 190 140 240 0

The Regret TableDecision Large rise Small rise No change Small fall Large fallGold 600 150 0 0 60Bond 250 50 50 400 210Stock 0 0 100 500 660C/D 440 190 140 240 0

Investing in Stock generates no regret when the market exhibits

a large rise

Page 26: Kasus Final CH06

26

The Payoff TableDecision Large rise Small rise No change Small fall Large fallGold -100 100 200 300 0Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600C/D 60 60 60 60 60

The Payoff TableDecision Large rise Small rise No change Small fall Large fallGold -100 100 200 300 0Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600C/D 60 60 60 60 60

The Regret Table MaximumDecision Large rise Small rise No change Small fall Large fall RegretGold 600 150 0 0 60 600Bond 250 50 50 400 210 400Stock 0 0 100 500 660 660C/D 440 190 140 240 0 440

The Regret Table MaximumDecision Large rise Small rise No change Small fall Large fall RegretGold 600 150 0 0 60 600Bond 250 50 50 400 210 400Stock 0 0 100 500 660 660C/D 440 190 140 240 0 440

Investing in gold generates a regret of 600 when the market exhibits

a large rise The optimal decision

500 – (-100) = 600

TOM BROWN – Regret TableTOM BROWN – Regret Table

Page 27: Kasus Final CH06

27

The Minimax Regret - spreadsheetThe Minimax Regret - spreadsheet

=MAX(B$4:B$7)-B4Drag to F16

=VLOOKUP(MIN(H13:H16),H13:I16,2,FALSE)

=MIN(H13:H16)

=MAX(B14:F14)Drag to H18

Cell I13 (hidden) =A13Drag to I16

Page 28: Kasus Final CH06

28

• This criterion is based on the best possible scenario.It fits both an optimistic and an aggressive decision maker.

• An optimistic decision maker believes that the best possible outcome will always take place regardless of the decision made.

• An aggressive decision maker looks for the decision with the highest payoff (when payoff is profit).

Decision Making Under Uncertainty - Decision Making Under Uncertainty - The Maximax CriterionThe Maximax Criterion

Page 29: Kasus Final CH06

29

• To find an optimal decision.– Find the maximum payoff for each decision

alternative.– Select the decision alternative that has the maximum

of the “maximum” payoff.

Decision Making Under Uncertainty - Decision Making Under Uncertainty - The Maximax CriterionThe Maximax Criterion

Page 30: Kasus Final CH06

30

TOM BROWN -TOM BROWN - The Maximax CriterionThe Maximax Criterion

The Maximax Criterion MaximumDecision Large rise Small rise No change Small fall Large fall PayoffGold -100 100 200 300 0 300Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150 200Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600 500C/D 60 60 60 60 60 60

The optimal decision

Page 31: Kasus Final CH06

31

• This criterion might appeal to a decision maker who is neither pessimistic nor optimistic.– It assumes all the states of nature are equally likely to

occur.– The procedure to find an optimal decision.

• For each decision add all the payoffs.• Select the decision with the largest sum (for profits).

Decision Making Under Uncertainty - Decision Making Under Uncertainty - The Principle of Insufficient ReasonThe Principle of Insufficient Reason

Page 32: Kasus Final CH06

32

TOM BROWNTOM BROWN - - Insufficient ReasonInsufficient Reason

• Sum of Payoffs– Gold 600 Dollars– Bond 350 Dollars– Stock 50 Dollars– C/D 300 Dollars

• Based on this criterion the optimal decision alternative is to invest in gold.

Page 33: Kasus Final CH06

33

Decision Making Under Uncertainty – Decision Making Under Uncertainty – Spreadsheet templateSpreadsheet template

Payoff Table

Large Rise Small Rise No Change Small Fall Large FallGold -100 100 200 300 0Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600C/D Account 60 60 60 60 60d5d6d7d8Probability 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.1 0.1

Criteria Decision PayoffMaximin C/D Account 60Minimax Regret Bond 400Maximax Stock 500Insufficient Reason Gold 100EV Bond 130EVPI 141

RESULTS

Page 34: Kasus Final CH06

34

Decision Making Under RiskDecision Making Under Risk

• The probability estimate for the occurrence of

each state of nature (if available) can be

incorporated in the search for the optimal

decision.

• For each decision calculate its expected payoff.

Page 35: Kasus Final CH06

35

Decision Making Under Risk –Decision Making Under Risk –The Expected Value CriterionThe Expected Value Criterion

Expected Payoff = (Probability)(Payoff)Expected Payoff = (Probability)(Payoff)

• For each decision calculate the expected payoff as follows:

(The summation is calculated across all the states of nature)

• Select the decision with the best expected payoff

Page 36: Kasus Final CH06

36

TOM BROWN -TOM BROWN - The Expected Value CriterionThe Expected Value Criterion

The Expected Value Criterion ExpectedDecision Large rise Small rise No change Small fall Large fall ValueGold -100 100 200 300 0 100Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150 130Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600 125C/D 60 60 60 60 60 60Prior Prob. 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.1 0.1

EV = (0.2)(250) + (0.3)(200) + (0.3)(150) + (0.1)(-100) + (0.1)(-150) = 130

The optimal decision

Page 37: Kasus Final CH06

37

• The expected value criterion is useful generally in two cases:– Long run planning is appropriate, and decision

situations repeat themselves.– The decision maker is risk neutral.

When to use the expected value When to use the expected value approachapproach

Page 38: Kasus Final CH06

38

The Expected Value Criterion - The Expected Value Criterion - spreadsheetspreadsheet

=SUMPRODUCT(B4:F4,$B$8:$F$8)Drag to G7

Cell H4 (hidden) = A4Drag to H7

=MAX(G4:G7)

=VLOOKUP(MAX(G4:G7),G4:H7,2,FALSE)

Page 39: Kasus Final CH06

39

6.4 6.4 Expected Value of Perfect InformationExpected Value of Perfect Information

• The gain in expected return obtained from knowing with certainty the future state of nature is called:

Expected Value of Perfect Information Expected Value of Perfect Information

(EVPI)(EVPI)

Page 40: Kasus Final CH06

40

The Expected Value of Perfect Information Decision Large rise Small rise No change Small fall Large fallGold -100 100 200 300 0Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600C/D 60 60 60 60 60Probab. 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.1 0.1

If it were known with certainty that there will be a “Large Rise” in the market

Large rise

... the optimal decision would be to invest in...

-100 250

500 60

Stock

Similarly,…

TOM BROWN -TOM BROWN - EVPIEVPI

Page 41: Kasus Final CH06

41

The Expected Value of Perfect Information Decision Large rise Small rise No change Small fall Large fallGold -100 100 200 300 0Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600C/D 60 60 60 60 60Probab. 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.1 0.1

-100 250

500 60

Expected Return with Perfect information = ERPI = 0.2(500)+0.3(250)+0.3(200)+0.1(300)+0.1(60) = $271

Expected Return without additional information = Expected Return of the EV criterion = $130

EVPI = ERPI - EREV = $271 - $130 = $141

TOM BROWN -TOM BROWN - EVPIEVPI

Page 42: Kasus Final CH06

42

6.5 6.5 Bayesian Analysis - Decision Making Bayesian Analysis - Decision Making with Imperfect Informationwith Imperfect Information

• Bayesian Statistics play a role in assessing additional information obtained from various sources.

• This additional information may assist in refining original probability estimates, and help improve decision making.

Page 43: Kasus Final CH06

43

TOM BROWN – Using Sample InformationTOM BROWN – Using Sample Information

• Tom can purchase econometric forecast results for $50.

• The forecast predicts “negative” or “positive” econometric growth.

• Statistics regarding the forecast are: The Forecast When the stock market showed a... predicted Large Rise Small Rise No Change Small Fall Large Fall

Positive econ. growth 80% 70% 50% 40% 0%Negative econ. growth 20% 30% 50% 60% 100%

When the stock market showed a large rise the Forecast predicted a “positive growth” 80% of the time.

Should Tom purchase the Forecast ?

Page 44: Kasus Final CH06

44

• If the expected gain resulting from the decisions made with the forecast exceeds $50, Tom should purchase the forecast.

The expected gain =

Expected payoff with forecast – EREV• To find Expected payoff with forecast Tom should

determine what to do when: – The forecast is “positive growth”,– The forecast is “negative growth”.

TOM BROWN – SolutionTOM BROWN – SolutionUsing Sample InformationUsing Sample Information

Page 45: Kasus Final CH06

45

• Tom needs to know the following probabilities– P(Large rise | The forecast predicted “Positive”) – P(Small rise | The forecast predicted “Positive”) – P(No change | The forecast predicted “Positive ”) – P(Small fall | The forecast predicted “Positive”)– P(Large Fall | The forecast predicted “Positive”) – P(Large rise | The forecast predicted “Negative ”)– P(Small rise | The forecast predicted “Negative”)– P(No change | The forecast predicted “Negative”)– P(Small fall | The forecast predicted “Negative”)– P(Large Fall) | The forecast predicted “Negative”)

TOM BROWN – SolutionTOM BROWN – SolutionUsing Sample InformationUsing Sample Information

Page 46: Kasus Final CH06

46

• Bayes’ Theorem provides a procedure to calculate these probabilities

P(B|Ai)P(Ai)

P(B|A1)P(A1)+ P(B|A2)P(A2)+…+ P(B|An)P(An)P(Ai|B) =

Posterior ProbabilitiesProbabilities determinedafter the additional infobecomes available.

TOM BROWN – SolutionTOM BROWN – SolutionBayes’ TheoremBayes’ Theorem

Prior probabilitiesProbability estimatesdetermined based on current info, before thenew info becomes available.

Page 47: Kasus Final CH06

47

States of Prior Prob. Joint PosteriorNature Prob. (State|Positive) Prob. Prob.Large Rise 0.2 0.8 0.16 0.286Small Rise 0.3 0.7 0.21 0.375No Change 0.3 0.5 0.15 0.268Small Fall 0.1 0.4 0.04 0.071Large Fall 0.1 0 0 0.000

X =

TOM BROWN – SolutionTOM BROWN – SolutionBayes’ TheoremBayes’ Theorem

The Probability that the forecast is “positive” and the stock market shows “Large Rise”.

• The tabular approach to calculating posterior probabilities for “positive” economical forecast

Page 48: Kasus Final CH06

48

States of Prior Prob. Joint PosteriorNature Prob. (State|Positive) Prob. Prob.Large Rise 0.2 0.8 0.16 0.286Small Rise 0.3 0.7 0.21 0.375No Change 0.3 0.5 0.15 0.268Small Fall 0.1 0.4 0.04 0.071Large Fall 0.1 0 0 0.000

X =0.16 0.56

The probability that the stock market shows “Large Rise” given that the forecast is “positive”

• The tabular approach to calculating posterior probabilities for “positive” economical forecast

TOM BROWN – SolutionTOM BROWN – SolutionBayes’ TheoremBayes’ Theorem

Page 49: Kasus Final CH06

49

States of Prior Prob. Joint PosteriorNature Prob. (State|Positive) Prob. Prob.Large Rise 0.2 0.8 0.16 0.286Small Rise 0.3 0.7 0.21 0.375No Change 0.3 0.5 0.15 0.268Small Fall 0.1 0.4 0.04 0.071Large Fall 0.1 0 0 0.000

X =

TOM BROWN – SolutionTOM BROWN – SolutionBayes’ TheoremBayes’ Theorem

Observe the revision in the prior probabilities

Probability(Forecast = positive) = .56

• The tabular approach to calculating posterior probabilities for “positive” economical forecast

Page 50: Kasus Final CH06

50

States of Prior Prob. Joint PosteriorNature Prob. (State|negative) Probab. Probab.Large Rise 0.2 0.2 0.04 0.091Small Rise 0.3 0.3 0.09 0.205No Change 0.3 0.5 0.15 0.341Small Fall 0.1 0.6 0.06 0.136Large Fall 0.1 1 0.1 0.227

TOM BROWN – SolutionTOM BROWN – SolutionBayes’ TheoremBayes’ Theorem

Probability(Forecast = negative) = .44

• The tabular approach to calculating posterior probabilities for “negative” economical forecast

Page 51: Kasus Final CH06

51

Posterior (revised) ProbabilitiesPosterior (revised) Probabilitiesspreadsheet templatespreadsheet template

Bayesian Analysis

Indicator 1 Indicator 2

States Prior Conditional Joint Posterior States Prior Conditional Joint Posteriorof Nature Probabilities Probabilities Probabilities Probabilites of Nature Probabilities Probabilities Probabilities Probabilites

Large Rise 0.2 0.8 0.16 0.286 Large Rise 0.2 0.2 0.04 0.091Small Rise 0.3 0.7 0.21 0.375 Small Rise 0.3 0.3 0.09 0.205No Change 0.3 0.5 0.15 0.268 No Change 0.3 0.5 0.15 0.341Small Fall 0.1 0.4 0.04 0.071 Small Fall 0.1 0.6 0.06 0.136Large Fall 0.1 0 0 0.000 Large Fall 0.1 1 0.1 0.227s6 0 0 0.000 s6 0 0 0.000s7 0 0 0.000 s7 0 0 0.000s8 0 0 0.000 s8 0 0 0.000

P(Indicator 1) 0.56 P(Indicator 2) 0.44

Bayesian Analysis

Indicator 1 Indicator 2

States Prior Conditional Joint Posterior States Prior Conditional Joint Posteriorof Nature Probabilities Probabilities Probabilities Probabilites of Nature Probabilities Probabilities Probabilities Probabilites

Large Rise 0.2 0.8 0.16 0.286 Large Rise 0.2 0.2 0.04 0.091Small Rise 0.3 0.7 0.21 0.375 Small Rise 0.3 0.3 0.09 0.205No Change 0.3 0.5 0.15 0.268 No Change 0.3 0.5 0.15 0.341Small Fall 0.1 0.4 0.04 0.071 Small Fall 0.1 0.6 0.06 0.136Large Fall 0.1 0 0 0.000 Large Fall 0.1 1 0.1 0.227s6 0 0 0.000 s6 0 0 0.000s7 0 0 0.000 s7 0 0 0.000s8 0 0 0.000 s8 0 0 0.000

P(Indicator 1) 0.56 P(Indicator 2) 0.44

Page 52: Kasus Final CH06

52

• This is the expected gain from making decisions based on Sample Information.

• Revise the expected return for each decision using the posterior probabilities as follows:

Expected Value of Sample Expected Value of Sample InformationInformation

EVSIEVSI

Page 53: Kasus Final CH06

53

The revised probabilities payoff tableDecision Large rise Small rise No change Small fall Large fall

Gold -100 100 200 300 0

Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150

Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600

C/D 60 60 60 60 60P(State|Positive) 0.286 0.375 0.268 0.071 0

P(State|negative) 0.091 0.205 0.341 0.136 0.227

EV(Invest in……. |“Positive” forecast) = =.286( )+.375( )+.268( )+.071( )+0( ) =

EV(Invest in ……. | “Negative” forecast) =

=.091( )+.205( )+.341( )+.136( )+.227( ) =

-100 100 200 300 $840GOLD

-100 100 200 300 0

GOLD

$120

TOM BROWN – Conditional Expected ValuesTOM BROWN – Conditional Expected Values

Page 54: Kasus Final CH06

54

• The revised expected values for each decision:Positive forecast Negative forecastEV(Gold|Positive) = 84 EV(Gold|Negative) = 120EV(Bond|Positive) = 180 EV(Bond|Negative) = 65EV(Stock|Positive) = 250 EV(Stock|Negative) = -37 EV(C/D|Positive) = 60 EV(C/D|Negative) = 60

If the forecast is “Positive”Invest in Stock.

If the forecast is “Negative”Invest in Gold.

TOM BROWN – Conditional Expected ValuesTOM BROWN – Conditional Expected Values

Page 55: Kasus Final CH06

55

• Since the forecast is unknown before it is purchased, Tom can only calculate the expected return from purchasing it.

• Expected return when buying the forecast = ERSI = P(Forecast is positive)(EV(Stock|Forecast is positive)) + P(Forecast is negative”)(EV(Gold|Forecast is negative)) = (.56)(250) + (.44)(120) = $192.5

TOM BROWN – Conditional Expected ValuesTOM BROWN – Conditional Expected Values

Page 56: Kasus Final CH06

56

• The expected gain from buying the forecast is:EVSI = ERSI – EREV = 192.5 – 130 = $62.5

• Tom should purchase the forecast. His expected gain is greater than the forecast cost.

• Efficiency = EVSI / EVPI = 63 / 141 = 0.45

Expected Value of Sampling Expected Value of Sampling Information (EVSI)Information (EVSI)

Page 57: Kasus Final CH06

57

TOM BROWN – SolutionTOM BROWN – SolutionEVSI spreadsheet templateEVSI spreadsheet template

Payoff Table

Large Rise Small Rise No Change Small Fall Large Fall s6 s7 s8 EV(prior) EV(ind. 1) EV(ind. 2)Gold -100 100 200 300 0 100 83.93 120.45Bond 250 200 150 -100 -150 130 179.46 67.05Stock 500 250 100 -200 -600 125 249.11 -32.95C/D Account 60 60 60 60 60 60 60.00 60.00d5d6d7d8Prior Prob. 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.1 0.1Ind. 1 Prob. 0.286 0.375 0.268 0.071 0.000 #### ### ## 0.56Ind 2. Prob. 0.091 0.205 0.341 0.136 0.227 #### ### ## 0.44Ind. 3 Prob.Ind 4 Prob.

RESULTSPrior Ind. 1 Ind. 2 Ind. 3 Ind. 4

optimal payoff 130.00 249.11 120.45 0.00 0.00optimal decision Bond Stock Gold

EVSI = 62.5EVPI = 141Efficiency= 0.44

Page 58: Kasus Final CH06

58

6.6 6.6 Decision TreesDecision Trees

• The Payoff Table approach is useful for a non-sequential or single stage.

• Many real-world decision problems consists of a sequence of dependent decisions.

• Decision Trees are useful in analyzing multi-stage decision processes.

Page 59: Kasus Final CH06

59

• A Decision Tree is a chronological representation of the decision process.

• The tree is composed of nodes and branches.

Characteristics of a decision treeCharacteristics of a decision tree

A branch emanating from a state of nature (chance) node corresponds to a particular state of nature, and includes the probability of this state of nature.

Decision node

Chance node

Decision 1

Cost 1Decision 2Cost 2

P(S2)

P(S 1)

P(S3 )

P(S2)

P(S 1)

P(S3 )

A branch emanating from a decision node corresponds to a decision alternative. It includes a cost or benefit value.

Page 60: Kasus Final CH06

60

BILL GALLEN DEVELOPMENT COMPANYBILL GALLEN DEVELOPMENT COMPANY

– BGD plans to do a commercial development on a property.

– Relevant data• Asking price for the property is 300,000 dollars.• Construction cost is 500,000 dollars.• Selling price is approximated at 950,000 dollars.• Variance application costs 30,000 dollars in fees and expenses

– There is only 40% chance that the variance will be approved.– If BGD purchases the property and the variance is denied, the property

can be sold for a net return of 260,000 dollars.– A three month option on the property costs 20,000 dollars, which will

allow BGD to apply for the variance.

Page 61: Kasus Final CH06

61

– A consultant can be hired for 5000 dollars.– The consultant will provide an opinion about the

approval of the application • P (Consultant predicts approval | approval granted) = 0.70• P (Consultant predicts denial | approval denied) = 0.80

• BGD wishes to determine the optimal strategy– Hire/ not hire the consultant now,– Other decisions that follow sequentially.

BILL GALLEN DEVELOPMENT COMPANYBILL GALLEN DEVELOPMENT COMPANY

Page 62: Kasus Final CH06

62

BILL GALLEN - SolutionBILL GALLEN - Solution

• Construction of the Decision Tree – Initially the company faces a decision about hiring the

consultant.

– After this decision is made more decisions follow regarding • Application for the variance.• Purchasing the option.• Purchasing the property.

Page 63: Kasus Final CH06

63

BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree

Let us consider the decision

to not hire a consultant

Do not hire consultant

Hire consultantCost = -5000

Cost = 0

Do nothing

0Buy land-300,000Purchase option

-20,000

Apply for variance

Apply for variance

-30,000

-30,000

03

Page 64: Kasus Final CH06

64

Approved

Denied

0.4

0.6

12

Approved

Denied

0.4

0.6

-300,000 -500,000 950,000

Buy land Build Sell

-50,000

100,000

-70,000

260,000Sell

Build Sell950,000-500,000

120,000Buy land and apply for variance

-300000 – 30000 + 260000 =

-300000 – 30000 – 500000 + 950000 =

Purchase option andapply for variance

BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree

Page 65: Kasus Final CH06

65

60

Do not hire consultant

Hire consultantCost = -5000

Cost = 0

Do nothing

0

Buy land-300,000Purchase option

-20,000

Apply for variance

Apply for variance

-30,000

-30,000

0

61

12

-300,000 -500,000 950,000

Buy land Build Sell

-50,000

100,000

-70,000

260,000Sell

Build Sell950,000-500,000

120,000Buy land and apply for variance

-300000 – 30000 + 260000 =

-300000 – 30000 – 500000 + 950000 =

Purchase option andapply for variance

This is where we are at this stage

Let us consider the decision to hire a consultant

BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree

Page 66: Kasus Final CH06

66

Do not hire consultant

0

Hire consultant-5000 Predic

t

Approval

Predict

Denial

0.4

0.6

-5000

Apply for variance

Apply for variance

Apply for variance

Apply for variance

-5000

-30,000

-30,000

-30,000

-30,000

BILL GALLEN – BILL GALLEN – The Decision Tree The Decision Tree

Let us consider the decision to hire a consultant

Done

Do Nothing

Buy land-300,000

Purchase option-20,000

Do Nothing

Buy land-300,000

Purchase option-20,000

Page 67: Kasus Final CH06

67

BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree

Approved

Denied

Consultant predicts an approval

?

?

Build Sell950,000-500,000

260,000Sell

-75,000

115,000

Page 68: Kasus Final CH06

68

BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree

Approved

Denied?

?

Build Sell950,000-500,000

260,000Sell

-75,000

115,000

The consultant serves as a source for additional information about denial or approval of the variance.

Page 69: Kasus Final CH06

69

?

?

BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree

Approved

Denied

Build Sell950,000-500,000

260,000Sell

-75,000

115,000

Therefore, at this point we need to calculate theposterior probabilities for the approval and denial

of the variance application

Page 70: Kasus Final CH06

70

BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree

22

Approved

Denied

Build Sell950,000-500,000

260,000Sell

-75,000

27

25115,000

23 24

26

The rest of the Decision Tree is built in a similar manner.

Posterior Probability of (approval | consultant predicts approval) = 0.70Posterior Probability of (denial | consultant predicts approval) = 0.30

?

?

.7

.3

Page 71: Kasus Final CH06

71

• Work backward from the end of each branch.

• At a state of nature node, calculate the expected value of the node.

• At a decision node, the branch that has the highest ending node value represents the optimal decision.

The Decision TreeThe Decision Tree Determining the Optimal Strategy Determining the Optimal Strategy

Page 72: Kasus Final CH06

72

22

Approved

Denied

27

2523 24

26-75,000

115,000115,000

-75,000

115,000

-75,000

115,000

-75,000

115,000

-75,00022

115,000

-75,000

(115,000)(0.7)=80500

(-75,000)(0.3)= -22500

-22500

80500

80500

-22500

80500

-22500

58,000?

?0.30

0.70

Build Sell950,000-500,000

260,000Sell

-75,000

115,000

With 58,000 as the chance node value,we continue backward to evaluate

the previous nodes.

BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree Determining the Optimal Strategy Determining the Optimal Strategy

Page 73: Kasus Final CH06

73

Predicts approvalHire

Do nothing

BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree Determining the Optimal Strategy Determining the Optimal Strategy

.4

.6

$10,000

$58,000

$-5,000

$20,000

$20,000

Buy land; Apply for variance

Predicts denial

Denied

Build,Sell

Sell land

Do not

hire

$-75,000

$115,000

.7

.3

Appr

oved

Page 74: Kasus Final CH06

74

BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree Excel add-in: Tree Plan Excel add-in: Tree Plan

Page 75: Kasus Final CH06

75

BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree BILL GALLEN - The Decision Tree Excel add-in: Tree Plan Excel add-in: Tree Plan

Page 76: Kasus Final CH06

76

6.7 6.7 Decision Making and UtilityDecision Making and Utility

• Introduction– The expected value criterion may not be appropriate

if the decision is a one-time opportunity with substantial risks.

– Decision makers do not always choose decisions based on the expected value criterion.

• A lottery ticket has a negative net expected return.• Insurance policies cost more than the present value of the

expected loss the insurance company pays to cover insured losses.

Page 77: Kasus Final CH06

77

• It is assumed that a decision maker can rank decisions in a coherent manner.

• Utility values, U(V), reflect the decision maker’s perspective and attitude toward risk.

• Each payoff is assigned a utility value. Higher payoffs get larger utility value.

• The optimal decision is the one that maximizes the expected utility.

The Utility ApproachThe Utility Approach

Page 78: Kasus Final CH06

78

• The technique provides an insightful look into the amount of risk the decision maker is willing to take.

• The concept is based on the decision maker’s preference to taking a sure payoff versus participating in a lottery.

Determining Utility ValuesDetermining Utility Values

Page 79: Kasus Final CH06

79

• List every possible payoff in the payoff table in ascending order.

• Assign a utility of 0 to the lowest value and a value of 1 to the highest value.

• For all other possible payoffs (Rij) ask the decision maker the following question:

Determining Utility ValuesDetermining Utility Values Indifference approach for assigning utility valuesIndifference approach for assigning utility values

Page 80: Kasus Final CH06

80

• Suppose you are given the option to select one of the following two alternatives:– Receive $Rij (one of the payoff values) for sure, – Play a game of chance where you receive either

• The highest payoff of $Rmax with probability p, or

• The lowest payoff of $Rmin with probability 1- p.

Determining Utility ValuesDetermining Utility Values Indifference approach for assigning utility valuesIndifference approach for assigning utility values

Page 81: Kasus Final CH06

81

Rmin

What value of p would make you indifferent between the two situations?”

Determining Utility ValuesDetermining Utility Values Indifference approach for assigning utility valuesIndifference approach for assigning utility values

Rij

Rmax

p

1-p

Page 82: Kasus Final CH06

82

Rmin

The answer to this question is the indifference probability for the payoff Rij and is used as the utility values of Rij.

Determining Utility ValuesDetermining Utility Values Indifference approach for assigning utility valuesIndifference approach for assigning utility values

Rij

Rmax

p

1-p

Page 83: Kasus Final CH06

83

Determining Utility ValuesDetermining Utility Values Indifference approach for assigning utility valuesIndifference approach for assigning utility values

d1

d2

s1 s1

150

-50 140

100

Alternative 1A sure event

Alternative 2 (Game-of-chance)

$100$150

-50p1-p

• For p = 1.0, you’ll prefer Alternative 2.• For p = 0.0, you’ll prefer Alternative 1.• Thus, for some p between 0.0 and 1.0 you’ll be indifferent between the alternatives.

Example:

Page 84: Kasus Final CH06

84

Determining Utility ValuesDetermining Utility Values Indifference approach for assigning utility valuesIndifference approach for assigning utility values

d1

d2

s1 s1

150

-50 140

100

Alternative 1A sure event

Alternative 2 (Game-of-chance)

$100$150

-50p1-p

• Let’s assume the probability of indifference is p = .7. U(100)=.7U(150)+.3U(-50) = .7(1) + .3(0) = .7

Page 85: Kasus Final CH06

85

TOM BROWNTOM BROWN - - Determining Utility ValuesDetermining Utility Values• Data

– The highest payoff was $500. Lowest payoff was -$600.– The indifference probabilities provided by Tom are

– Tom wishes to determine his optimal investment Decision.

Payoff -600 -200 -150 -100 0 60 100 150 200 250 300 500

Prob. 0 0.25 0.3 0.36 0.5 0.6 0.65 0.7 0.75 0.85 0.9 1

Page 86: Kasus Final CH06

86

TOM BROWNTOM BROWN – – Optimal decision (utility)Optimal decision (utility)

Utility Analysis Certain Payoff Utility-600 0

Large Rise Small Rise No Change Small Fall Large Fall EU -200 0.25Gold 0.36 0.65 0.75 0.9 0.5 0.632 -150 0.3Bond 0.85 0.75 0.7 0.36 0.3 0.671 -100 0.36Stock 1 0.85 0.65 0.25 0 0.675 0 0.5C/D Account 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.6 0.6 60 0.6d5 0 100 0.65d6 0 150 0.7d7 0 200 0.75d8 0 250 0.85Probability 0.2 0.3 0.3 0.1 0.1 300 0.9

500 1

RESULTSCriteria Decision ValueExp. Utility Stock 0.675

Page 87: Kasus Final CH06

87

Three types of Decision MakersThree types of Decision Makers

• Risk Averse -Prefers a certain outcome to a chance outcome having the same expected value.

• Risk Taking - Prefers a chance outcome to a certain outcome having the same expected value.

• Risk Neutral - Is indifferent between a chance outcome and a certain outcome having the same expected value.

Page 88: Kasus Final CH06

88Payoff

UtilityThe Utility Curve for a Risk Averse Decision Maker

1000.5

2000.5

150

The utility of having $150 on hand…The utility of having $150 on hand…

U(150)

…is larger than the expected utilityof a game whose expected valueis also $150.

…is larger than the expected utilityof a game whose expected valueis also $150.

EU(Game)

U(100)

U(200)

Page 89: Kasus Final CH06

89Payoff

Utility

1000.5

2000.5

150

U(150)EU(Game)

U(100)

U(200)

A risk averse decision maker avoidsthe thrill of a game-of-chance,whose expected value is EV, if he can have EV on hand for sure.

A risk averse decision maker avoidsthe thrill of a game-of-chance,whose expected value is EV, if he can have EV on hand for sure.

CE

Furthermore, a risk averse decision maker is willing to pay a premium…

Furthermore, a risk averse decision maker is willing to pay a premium…

…to buy himself (herself) out of the game-of-chance.

…to buy himself (herself) out of the game-of-chance.

The Utility Curve for a Risk Averse Decision Maker

Page 90: Kasus Final CH06

90

Risk Neutral D

ecision Maker

Payoff

UtilityRisk Averse Decision Maker

Risk Taking Decision Maker

Page 91: Kasus Final CH06

91

6.8 6.8 Game TheoryGame Theory

• Game theory can be used to determine optimal decisions in face of other decision making players.

• All the players are seeking to maximize their return.

• The payoff is based on the actions taken by all the decision making players.

Page 92: Kasus Final CH06

92

– By number of players• Two players - Chess• Multiplayer – Poker

– By total return• Zero Sum - the amount won and amount lost by all

competitors are equal (Poker among friends)• Nonzero Sum -the amount won and the amount lost by all

competitors are not equal (Poker In A Casino)– By sequence of moves

• Sequential - each player gets a play in a given sequence.• Simultaneous - all players play simultaneously.

Classification of GamesClassification of Games

Page 93: Kasus Final CH06

93

IGA SUPERMARKETIGA SUPERMARKET

• The town of Gold Beach is served by two supermarkets: IGA and Sentry.

• Market share can be influenced by their advertising policies.

• The manager of each supermarket must decide weekly which area of operations to discount and emphasize in the store’s newspaper flyer.

Page 94: Kasus Final CH06

94

• Data– The weekly percentage gain in market share for IGA,

as a function of advertising emphasis.

– A gain in market share to IGA results in equivalent loss for Sentry, and vice versa (i.e. a zero sum game)

Sentry's EmphasisMeat Produce Grocery Bakery

IGA's Meat 2 2 -8 6Emphasis Produce -2 0 6 -4

Grocery 2 -7 1 -3

IGA SUPERMARKETIGA SUPERMARKET

Page 95: Kasus Final CH06

95

IGA needs to determine an advertising emphasis that will maximize its expected change in market share regardless of Sentry’s action.

Page 96: Kasus Final CH06

96

IGA SUPERMARKET - SolutionIGA SUPERMARKET - Solution

• To prevent a sure loss of market share, both IGA and Sentry should select the weekly emphasis randomly.

• Thus, the question for both stores is:What proportion of the time each area should be emphasized by each store?

Page 97: Kasus Final CH06

97

IGA’s Linear Programming ModelIGA’s Linear Programming Model

• Decision variables– X1 = the probability IGA’s advertising focus is on meat.– X2 = the probability IGA’s advertising focus is on

produce.– X 3 = the probability IGA’s advertising focus is on

groceries.

• Objective Function For IGA– Maximize expected market increase regardless of

Sentry’s advertising policy.

Page 98: Kasus Final CH06

98

• Constraints– IGA’s market share increase for any given advertising

focus selected by Sentry, must be at least V.• The model

Max VS.T.

Meat 2X1 – 2X2 + 2X3 VProduce 2X1 – 7 X3 VGroceries -8X1 – 6X2 + X3 VBakery 6X1 – 4X2 – 3X3 VProbability X1 + X2 + X3 = 1

IGA’s PerspectiveIGA’s Perspective

IGA’s expected change in market share.

Sentry’sadvertisingemphasis

Page 99: Kasus Final CH06

99

Sentry’s Linear Programming ModelSentry’s Linear Programming Model

• Decision variables– Y1 = the probability Sentry’s advertising focus is on meat.

– Y2 = the probability Sentry’s advertising focus is on produce.

– Y 3 = the probability Sentry’s advertising focus is on groceries.

– Y4 = the probability Sentry’s advertising focus is on bakery.

• Objective Function For SentryMinimize the changes in market share in favor of IGA

Page 100: Kasus Final CH06

100

• Constraints– Sentry’s market share decrease for any given advertising

focus selected by IGA, must not exceed V.• The Model

Min VS.T.2Y1 + 2Y2 – 8Y3 + 6Y4 V-2Y1 + 6Y3 – 4Y4 V 2Y1 – 7Y2 + Y3 – 3Y4 V Y1 + Y2 + Y3 + Y4 = 1

Y1, Y2, Y3, Y4 are non-negative; V is unrestricted

Sentry’s perspectiveSentry’s perspective

Page 101: Kasus Final CH06

101

• For IGA– X1 = 0.3889; X2 = 0.5; X3 = 0.1111

• For Sentry– Y1 = .3333; Y2 = 0; Y3 = .3333; Y4 = .3333

• For both players V =0 (a fair game).

IGA SUPERMARKET – Optimal SolutionIGA SUPERMARKET – Optimal Solution

Page 102: Kasus Final CH06

102

Worksheet: [IGA.xls]Sheet1

Adjustable CellsFinal Reduced Objective Allowable Allowable

Cell Name Value Cost Coefficient Increase Decrease$A$2 X1 0.388888889 0 0 4 6$B$2 X2 0.5 0 0 4 2$C$2 X3 0.111111111 0 0 1.5 2$D$2 V -6.75062E-29 0 1 1E+30 1

ConstraintsFinal Shadow Constraint Allowable Allowable

Cell Name Value Price R.H. Side Increase Decrease

$E$4 -1.11022E-16 -0.333333333 0 0 1E+30$E$5 6.75062E-29 0 0 0 1E+30$E$6 3.88578E-16 -0.333333333 0 1E+30 0$E$7 -2.77556E-16 -0.333333333 0 1E+30 0$E$8 1 0 1 0.000199941 1E+30

IGA Optimal Solution - worksheetIGA Optimal Solution - worksheet

Page 103: Kasus Final CH06

103

Copyright John Wiley & Sons, Inc. All rights reserved. Reproduction or translation of this work beyond that named in Section 117 of the United States Copyright Act without the express written consent of the copyright owner is unlawful. Requests for further information should be addressed to the Permissions Department, John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Adopters of the textbook are granted permission to make back-up copies for their own use only, to make copies for distribution to students of the course the textbook is used in, and to modify this material to best suit their instructional needs. Under no circumstances can copies be made for resale. The Publisher assumes no responsibility for errors, omissions, or damages, caused by the use of these programs or from the use of the information contained herein.


Recommended