+ All Categories
Home > Documents > LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp....

LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp....

Date post: 22-May-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 1 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
43
LABOR ECONOMICS
Transcript
Page 1: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

LABOR ECONOMICS

Page 2: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

LABOR ECONOMICS

Sponsored by a Grant TÁMOP-4.1.2-08/2/A/KMR-2009-0041

Course Material Developed by Department of Economics,

Faculty of Social Sciences, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest (ELTE)

Department of Economics, Eötvös Loránd University Budapest

Institute of Economics, Hungarian Academy of Sciences

Balassi Kiadó, Budapest

Page 3: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.
Page 4: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

LABOR ECONOMICS

Author: János Köllő

Supervised by: János Köllő

January 2011

ELTE Faculty of Social Sciences, Department of Economics

Page 5: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

LABOR ECONOMICS

Week 9

Labor demand – Topics

János Köllő

Page 6: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

• Two factors: capital and labor

• More than two factors

Appendix 1: Demand for labor in the short run

Appendix 2: Scale effect with homogeneous production function

Demand for labor – a formal model

Page 7: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

• The slides draw from P. Cahuc–A. Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193

• We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions. Results for the general case are mentioned without proof.

• We study the two factors case in detail. For the single factor case see Appendix 1. The multifactor case is discussed briefly.

Page 8: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Two factors: capital and labor

Page 9: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Preparations: the production function

Bivariate, homogeneous of degree :

Returns to scale diminish if <1, constant if =1, increasing if >1.

Returns to factors of production are diminishing:

FL>0, FK>0, FLL<0, FKK<0

),(,0),(),( LKLKFLKF

Page 10: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Preparations: cost function

The minimum cost at given output Y is written as

KrLw

The cost function describes minimum cost as a function of w, r and Y:

),,( YrwCC

a) C is homogeneous of degree 1 in prices.

b) C is concave: Cww<0, Crr<0.

c) Satisfies Shepard’s lemma, i.e. optimal factor demands are

given by the partial derivatives of the cost function:

),,(),,( YrwCKésYrwCL rw

Page 11: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Perfect competition is an extreme case. Market power is measured with the

non-positive elasticity of sales price wrt sales [drawn from the inverse

demand function P=P(Y)]

YYP

YPpY

)(

)(

Under perfect competition the firm is price-taker

Under imperfect competition the price varies with Y

0p

Y

0p

Y

Market power is measured with defined as:

11

1p

Y

Under perfect competition the firm has no market power

Under imperfect competition the firm has market power

1

1

Preparations: market power

Page 12: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Preparations: the profit function

When prices change, the optimal size of the firm changes, too.

The profit function is written as:

),,()(),,( YrwCYYPYrw

The FOC from differentiation by Y is given by:

formula above theget toy immediatelyou isfunction demand

inverse theof elasticityoutput that therecalling and P(Y)out gmultiplyinBy

0),,()()(),,(

)P'(Y)Y/P(Yη

YrwCYPYYPYrw

p

Y

YY

)1/(1ahol),,()(p

YY YrwCYP

Note that in the optimum : price=marginal cost*markup

Page 13: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

After these preparation we look

at the following questions

Conditional demand (Optimal choice at given level of output in response to changing factor

prices)

• Conditional demand for labor and capital

• Cross effects

Scale effects (Optimal output in response to changing factor prices)

Unconditional demand

• The substitution and scale effects together

Page 14: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Conditional (compensated) demand for labor diminishes

with the wage and increases with the user cost of capital

0),,( www Cw

LYrwCL

Similarly, the conditional demand for capital decreases with

the price of capital and increases with the wage.

From Shepard’s lemma:

0wrCr

L

Since compensated demand depends only on relative factor

prices, the demand for labor increases if the user cost of

capital goes up:

Page 15: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Cross effects

Cross elasticity: positive, non-symmetric

Kw

Lr

Kw

Lr

w

K

K

w

r

L

L

r,,

Elasticity of substitution: positive and symmetric*

0)/(

)/(

rw

LK

LK

rw

*) This is not necessarily true for more than two factors of production. See later.

Page 16: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Cross effects derived from the cost function

The elasticity of substitution can be derived from the cost function

(Uzawa 1962, Cahuc-Zylberberg 2004, 237–238)

rw

wr

CC

CC

rw

LK

LK

rw

)/(

)/(

rw

wrwrwr

K

wrYYYY

L

r

CC

CC

KL

CC

Kr

C

L

rC

s

L

rC

L

r

r

L

r

L

1

: thatsee torwardstraightfo isit formula above thegConsiderin

log

log

L

r

00

sK is the share of capital in total cost (sK = rK/C = 1–sL = 1–wL/C)

It follows that )1( LKL

r ss

Page 17: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

The compensated price effects thus can be written as:

0)1( LL

rL

w s0)1( LL

r s

r L w L

similarly proceeds of derivation thesymmetry, toThanks

)1( thatfollowsy immediatelIt

and :lemma sShepard' toAccording

/1as capital of share theDefine

)/(:yieldson Substituti

isthat seen that have We

L

w

LK

L

r

rw

LK

rw

L

r

rwwr

rw

wrwr

L

r

ssCL

KLr

KCLC

CKrss

CLCrC

C

CCC

CC

CCandC

L

r

r

L

L

r

Page 18: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

The effect of an exogeneous

change of output Under homogeneous production function

/1/1 )1,(),()1,(),/( YrwKYrwKésYrwLYrwL

If the production function is homogeneous, a rise in Y

(without a change in relative factor prices) increases the

demand for both capital and labor. From homogeneity of

degree and Shepard’s lemma it follows that:

Remark: in the general case the demand for at least

one factor will rise.

Page 19: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Unconditional demand When factor prices change, optimal output (Y*) will change, too.

The firm’s problem is to solve:

),,(max),( YrwrwY

How Y*, C and (as a consequence) L* will change in response to a change in w?

),,()],,()1)(([),( YrwCw

YYrwCYPrw wY

pYw

Under optimality the term in brackets is zero (see Profit function). On the other hand,

Shepard’s lemma states that Cw(w,r,Y*)= L*. So we arrive at Hotelling’s lemma:

KrwésLrw rw ),(),(

Unconditional demands are decreasing in own prices*:

00 rrwwr

Kand

w

L

*) From the concavity of the cost function it follows that the profit function is convex, so the second derivatives are positive

Page 20: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Unconditional demand

– The effects of a change in the wage

The wage has a direct and an indirect effect:

w

YCC

w

LwYww

Multiply throughout with w/L*, and the second term with Y*/Y*

Yw

wYww

LwwYww

L

CYC

L

w

Y

Y

w

YC

L

wC

L

w

L

w

w

L

What is this? The first term is the conditional demand elasticity at output level

Y=Y*

Lwww

ww

LL

w

L

L

wC

L

w

/

/

Page 21: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Unconditional demand

– The effects of a change in the wage

The wage has a direct and an indirect effect:

w

YCC

w

LwYww

Multiply with w/L*, and the second term with Y*/Y*

Yw

wYww

LwwYww

L

CYC

L

w

Y

Y

w

YC

L

wC

L

w

L

w

w

L

What is this? The first component of the second term is the output elasticity of

demand at output level Y=Y* holding relative factor prices constant:

LY

wY

YY

LL

Y

L

L

Y

L

CY

/

/

Page 22: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Unconditional demand

– The effects of a change in the wage

The wage has a direct and an indirect effect:

w

YCC

w

LwYww

Multiply with w/L*, and the second term with Y*/Y*

Yw

wYww

LwwYww

L

CYC

L

w

Y

Y

w

YC

L

wC

L

w

L

w

w

L

From step 1 and step 2 we finally have:

Yw

LY

Lw

Lw

Page 23: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

The total effect of a change in the wage is thus

Yw

LY

Lw

Lw

Own-wage elasticity

Compensated

elasticity

of substitution

(–)

Scale effect

(–)

The negativity of the scale effect is easy to prove if the production function is

homogeneous. See two slides later!

Remark: in the general case it can be proven that the two components of the

second term are differently signed (Cahuc–Zylberberg p. 184. and footnote 5

to Chapter 4)

Page 24: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Employment effect of a change

in the user cost of capital

After similar steps we have:

Yr

LY

Lr

Lr

Cross price

elasticity

(?)

Compensated elasticity

of substitution

(+)

Scale effect

(–)

ssubstitute gross are L andK 0

scomplement gross are L andK 0

L

r

L

r

Page 25: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Own-wage elasticity under homogeneous production function

For the derivation see Appendix 2

θYd

LdYθ)(w,r,L(w,r,Y)LYrwLYrwL

1

ln

lnln11lnln )1,,(),,( 1

)1( :yieldson Substituti. :lemma sShepard' ./

.)/( seen that have We

L

L

rrwL

rw

L

r

rw

wrwr

L

r

sKCésLCCLws

CLCrCCC

CCandC

L

r

r

L

L

r(a)

(b)

(c)

Yw

LY

Lw

Lw

(a)

(b)

(c)

0 ) 1 ( < - - = s L

L w s

q

1 s Y

w

Page 26: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

L

L

wLL

L

w sss or)1(

In these formulas it is easy to observe that*:

a) The demand for labor decreases with the wage.

b) The substitution and scale effects are additive.

c) Demand is more elastic if capital and labor are ‘easy to substitute’ ( is large)

HM–2.

d) The stronger is market power, the weaker the scale effect. If competition is strong

( ) the scale effect is large and the demand for labor is highly elastic HM–1.

e) The elasticity of demand for labor increases with labor’s share in total cost

provided that < /( - ). The validity of HM–4 depends on how the scope for

capital-labor substitution relates to the elasticity of product demand.

*) „The formulas in large measure confirm the laws of demand put forward by Marshall (1920) and Hicks

(1932)” (C–Z 186).

Page 27: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

More than two factors of production (different types of capital and labor, land, raw materials, etc.)

Page 28: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

The firm’s problem is to solve:

YXXFfkXw nin

i

i

XX n),...,(..min 1

1...1

The FOC is essentially identical to that discussed in the two-factors case:

njiw

w

XXF

XXFésYXXF

j

i

nj

nin ,...,1,

),...,(

),...,(),...,(

1

11

The cost function is first order homogeneous in w and

homogeneous of degree 1/ in Y if F(.) is homogeneous of degree

. It is concave and satisfies Shepard’s lemma:

),,...,(

),,...,(

1

1

YwwCX

YwwC

ni

i

n

Page 29: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

The demand for factors of production diminishes with own prices:

niCw

XYwwCX iii

in

ii ,...,10),,...,( 1

But the demand for a given factor does not necessarily increase

if the price of another factor goes up. If the price of factor j goes

up, its employment will fall and the employment of at least one other

factor will rise. However, we cannot predict how the demand for a

particular factor i will change (without knowing the technology).

njiCw

X

w

Xiji

j

j

i

,...,1,

0j

i

w

X i and j are p-subsitutes (Hicks–Allen substitutes)

0j

i

w

X i és j are p-complements (Hicks–Allen complements)

Page 30: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Cross effects Cross elasticity. Ambigously signed, non-symmetric

ji

ijiji

j

i

j

j

iij C

X

w

X

w

w

X

Direct elasticity of substitution. Defined as in the two-factors case:

)/(

)/(

)/(

)/(ji

ij

ij

jiij

XX

ww

ww

XXd

Difficult to interpret: a change in the price of j starts a chain of

substitutions so the demand for i will change for several reasons.

Allen’s partial elasticity of substitution (derivable from the cost

function) tells more:

jij

ij

ji

ij

jj

ij

ij s

CC

CC

Xw

C

Page 31: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

The formula known from the two-factors case

jij

ij s

continues to hold but is ambigously signed (unlike in the two-

factors case).

Corollary: changes in the price of capital, materials and land

may affect the demand for different types of labor in

different ways. Unskilled labor and capital are usually found

to be substitutes, for instance, while skilled labor and capital

are complements according to several estimates (capital-

skill complementarity).

Page 32: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

It also continues to hold that

njiYi

iY

ij

ij ,...,1,

Therefore the sign of the uncompensated elasticity remains an

empirical question :

scomplement gross are and 0

ssubstitute gross are and 0

ji

ji

i

j

i

j

If the production function is homogeneous and the market is not fully

competitive then:

jis ijj

ij ,

If the term in the bracket is positive, a rise in the price of j will

increase the demand for i. If it is negative, the demand for both

factors will fall.

Page 33: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Appendix 1:

Demand for labor in the short run

Page 34: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Demand for labor in the short run

Labor is the only factor of production. The production function can be

written as:

Y=F(L), Y’>0, Y’’<0

The firm may have market power. Market power is measured by the

elasticity, where P(Y) is an isoelastic inverse demand function:

YYP

YPpY

)(

)(

Under perfect competition the firm is price-taker

Under imperfect competition the price is affected by Y

0p

Y

0p

Y

Page 35: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

The profit function is:

wLLFLFPwLYYPL )()()()(

The FOC from differentiation by L is

0)()()()( wYYPYPLFL

Making use of the fact that: PYY

YP

YP

)(

)(

0)1)(()()( wYPLFL PY

So the optimum is at:

11

1where)(

p

YP

wLF

Under perfect competition the marginal product is equal to the wage.

Under imperfect competition the optimal marginal product is higher

(at given w/P) and employment is lower.

Page 36: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

The cost function is

)()( 1 YwFwLYC

Marginal cost is equal to*:

)(/)( LFwYC

*) Note that the derivative of F-1(L) is 1/F’(L)

Recalling that F’(L)= w/P, that is, P= w/F’(L), it follows that:

)()(

YCLF

wP

Under perfect competition ( =1) the product price is equal to marginal

cost. The price-setting firm applies a price markup . Product price is

higher and output end employment are lower.

Prices

Page 37: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

The FOC was:

Let us rearrange the FOC to arrive at the formula below (taking into

account that L is affected by the wage) and look at how the optimal L

varies with w!

P

wLF )(

0})({)( wwLFPwLF

Differentiation by w and re-arranging terms yields:

02 FPPFw

L

(+)(-) (+)(-)

The demand for labor decreases with

the wage.

The size of the effect varies with

technology (F), elasticity of product

demand (P’) and market power ( ).

Effect of the wage on the demand for labor

Page 38: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Appendix 2:

The scale effect under homogeneous

production function (proof)

Page 39: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

The scale effect under homogeneous production function

Prove that if the production function is homogeneous of degree then:

sCZ Yw)21(

The proof can be found on pp. 185-186 of Cahuc-Zylberberg (CZ 2004) but an intermediate

formula above their equation (21) is wrong. We give a more detailed proof by correcting the

formula in question.

Our starting point is optimum condition (CZ 15) which has the form (CZ 15a) if the

production function is homogeneous:

),,()()15(

),,()()15(

YrwY

CYPaCZ

YrwCYPCZ Y

Page 40: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

We shall take into consideration the following definitions:

The indicator of market power ( > , see footnote 4 on CZ, p 814), derived from the inverse

demand function P=P(Y):

(a) 0)(

)(

1

1

YP

YYPwhere p

Yp

Y

Shepard’s lemma:

(b) LCw

The share of labor in total cost:

(c) C

wLs

The output elasticity of demand for labor:

1

log

loglogY1r,1)(w,LlogY)r,(w,Llog )1,,(),,()( 1

Yd

LdYrwLYrwLd

Page 41: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

After these preparations let us start with:

P(Y) = vCY(W, R, Y), where v = 1/(1 + ) and = Y

Important: R is independent of w, v is independent of w, Y varies with w!

LHS: Log differentiating P(Y) by w yields:

RHS:

Following the rules of differentiating multivariate composite functions we have:

(vectorial)

Page 42: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

That is:

This is close to the formula above equation (21) on CZ, p, 185 but the in the book the

last term within the bracket (+1) is missing.

Page 43: LABOR ECONOMICS - regi.tankonyvtar.hu · Zylberberg „Labor Economics” (MIT Press 2004), pp. 171–193 • We restrict ourselves to the case of homogeneous production functions.

Using definitions (a), (b) and (c) and the corrected formula above it is easy to get to

CZ’s equation (21) :

C

L

Y

dwdY

C

CY

C

C

YP

YYP

Y

PY

ww

Y 11/

1)(

)(1

Multiply throughout with w:

sC

wL

wY

dwdY PY

Yw

PY 1

11

1

/

/

Rearrange terms and multiply the right hand side with / :

sPY

Yw

1)1(

and then with (taking into account definition (a)). We have:

sYw


Recommended