+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Labor Immobility and Exchange Rate Regimes: An … · Labor Immobility and Exchange Rate ......

Labor Immobility and Exchange Rate Regimes: An … · Labor Immobility and Exchange Rate ......

Date post: 24-Aug-2018
Category:
Upload: dangbao
View: 231 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
47
Labor Immobility and Exchange Rate Regimes: An alternative Explanation for the Fall of the Interwar Gold Exchange Standard David Khoudour-Castéras [email protected] Universidad Externado de Colombia May 2006 Abstract Beyond the respective functioning of the classical gold standard and the interwar gold exchange standard, one of the main differences between both periods lay on the degree of labor mobility. While the pre-1914 world was characterized by massive migration flows, the interwar years were marked by a dramatic fall in labor movements, owing to the adoption of restrictive immigration policies in the main receiving countries and the implementation of social safety nets in several western and northern European countries. As a result, labor mobility could not play anymore the role of adjustment mechanism that it had during the classical gold standard. Indeed, the existence of a number of adjustment constraints, including wage rigidities and factor immobility, led the countries with fixed exchange rates to adopt counterproductive adjustment mechanisms, such as trade protectionism, that resulted in both internal and external imbalances. Against this background, the return to flexible exchange rates was the only credible option. JEL Classification: F22, F33, N10 Keywords: Gold Exchange Standard, International Adjustment, Labor Mobility
Transcript

Labor Immobility and Exchange Rate Regimes:

An alternative Explanation for the Fall of the Interwar Gold

Exchange Standard

David Khoudour-Castéras

[email protected]

Universidad Externado de Colombia

May 2006

Abstract

Beyond the respective functioning of the classical gold standard and the interwar gold exchange standard, one of the main differences between both periods lay on the degree of labor mobility. While the pre-1914 world was characterized by massive migration flows, the interwar years were marked by a dramatic fall in labor movements, owing to the adoption of restrictive immigration policies in the main receiving countries and the implementation of social safety nets in several western and northern European countries. As a result, labor mobility could not play anymore the role of adjustment mechanism that it had during the classical gold standard. Indeed, the existence of a number of adjustment constraints, including wage rigidities and factor immobility, led the countries with fixed exchange rates to adopt counterproductive adjustment mechanisms, such as trade protectionism, that resulted in both internal and external imbalances. Against this background, the return to flexible exchange rates was the only credible option. JEL Classification: F22, F33, N10 Keywords: Gold Exchange Standard, International Adjustment, Labor Mobility

1

Labor Immobility and Exchange Rate Regimes: An alternative Explanation

for the Fall of the Interwar Gold Exchange Standard

“It is easy to sum up the conventional wisdom that quickly emerged in response to the problems of the global economy. Everything that was moving across national boundaries – whether capital, goods, or people – really had no business to be doing that and should be stopped. If it could not be stopped, it should be controlled, in accordance with a definition of national interest.”

Harold James (2001: 187)

Introduction

The two decades that separated the First from the Second World War are also known

as the period of the “end of the globalization” (James, 2001): trade flows significantly slowed

down in comparison with the pre-war years, capital mobility was strongly constrained,

barriers to international labor mobility increased, and all the attempts to stabilize currencies

failed. Even though the 1929 crash and the Great Depression that followed it sparked off the

globalization backlash, they are not the only responsible. The adoption, during the 1920s, of

several protectionist measures probably induced – and sped up – the crisis of the 1930s, while

the widespread renunciation of fixed exchange rates after 1931 was in keeping with the non-

cooperative policies at that time. In that sense, the international trade and monetary

cooperation that marked the classical gold standard period was replaced by a logic of strong

economic nationalism

In fact, the protectionist temptation, which went well beyond trade measures, appeared

with the first significant restrictions on immigration put into place in the United States at the

beginning of the 1920s. Such border controls marked a turning point compared to the pre-war

years, characterized by massive population movements between the European countries and

the New World. It is also likely that they contributed, at least indirectly, to the fall of the gold

standard, or more precisely of the gold exchange standard adopted during the 1922 Genoa

conference. Indeed, maintaining fixed exchange rate regimes implies the existence of a

number of adjustment mechanisms – more or less automatic – that enables to offset, in the

event of disequilibria, exchange rate rigidity. Labor mobility, as shown by Mundell (1961),

plays an important role in this adjustment process.

2

In that regard, the classical gold standard period represents a perfect illustration of the

importance of migration flows in the success of fixed exchange rate regimes. At that time,

international migration was free and the countries that chose to peg their currency to gold

could transfer the adjustment burden on labor mobility (Khoudour-Castéras, 2005a). To the

contrary, the gold exchange standard had to face a number of constraints that seriously limited

adjustment possibilities. In addition to the hindrances to workers’ mobility, the interwar

period was also different from the gold standard years on account of an environment of higher

wage rigidities and lower capital mobility. Therefore, the costs of maintaining the exchange

rate stability were high, which explains that, confronted with the Great Depression of the

1930s, most of the nations that joined the Genoa International Monetary System opted for the

abandon of fixed exchange rates and the return to monetary policy autonomy.

In order to show how the end of labor mobility could have been at the origin of the fall

of the gold exchange standard, the remainder of the paper is organized as follows. First,

Section I presents the evolution of international migration policies. The goal is notably to

understand the mechanisms that led the United States as well as most of the countries that

were traditionally open to immigration to implement restrictive measures. Then, Section II

underscores the fact that the contraction of migration flows after World War I was not only

due to the barriers that immigration countries put into place, but also to specific changes in the

European nations that entailed a reduction in labor exports. This section emphasizes in

particular the impact of social policies on the slowdown in European emigration. Next,

Section III shows that the decrease in international migration brought about a disconnection

between business cycles and migration movements, that is, that labor mobility could not play

anymore its role of adjustment mechanism. Lastly, Section IV tries to establish how the lack

of labor mobility could have been harmful to the gold exchange standard: the existence of a

number of adjustment constraints, including wage rigidities and factor immobility, led the

countries with fixed exchange rates to adopt counterproductive adjustment mechanisms, such

as trade protectionism, that resulted in both internal and external imbalances. Against this

background, retiring from the gold exchange standard was the only credible option.

I – The Implementation of Restrictive Immigration Policies

The pass-through from a world with free labor mobility to a closed world did not

occur suddenly: “Contrary to the conventional wisdom, there was not one big regime switch

around World War I from free (and often subsidized) immigration to quotas, but rather an

3

evolution toward more restrictive immigration policy in the New World. Attitudes changed

slowly and over a number of decades rather than all at once.” (O’Rourke and Williamson,

1999: 186). Yet, the most drastic measures were adopted during the interwar years, putting an

end to the mass migration phenomenon that characterized the pre-1914 era. Under the double

pressure of trade unions and political movements, most of the receiving countries closed their

door to migrants. What is remarkable in this process is that it chiefly cropped up before the

Great Depression, that is, in a context of relatively good economic health.

Protectionist temptation and nativist influence in the United States

American trade union organizations played a driving role in the process that led to the

adoption of restrictive measures against foreign workers: "The nationalisation of labour

unions, that is their growth and institutionalisation in a national, and even international

(many of them included Canadian branches) dimension, provided a new scale of intervention.

[...] They came to define what was the American standard of wages, and by the same token

also imposed a national vision of the American workers' life style. They also established

centralised decision-making and bureaucratic structures that placed them in a position to

create a broad movement and publicise their demands." (Collomp, 2003: 240). It was in this

context that first waves of protest against foreign labor appeared. Initially confined to the

West Coast, they targeted Chinese workers. These arrived at the time of the Gold Rush and

were used for laborious work in the fields or the mines, and rail laying operations. When the

building of the transcontinental railways ended, a large number of them moved to San

Francisco, where they were considered as rivals by local active population. Discriminatory

measures and riots against Chinese increased, all the more because some of them were used as

strike breakers by the manufacturers.

Then, it was the turn of the Japanese to face the fire of criticism and to suffer riots.

Like the Chinese, they were employed to do the badly paid jobs. Hence the creation in 1905,

by American trade unions, of the Japanese and Korean Exclusion League, whose goal was to

stop the immigration of persons who accepted to work for wages that were considered as too

low. Afterwards, the “new migrants” from central and southern Europe were accused of

putting downward pressure on American wages. Unskilled workers were especially targeted:

“The pressure to stop immigration had little to do with the war. It was a result of the surge of

immigration in 1900-1910, which had a discernible impact on the wages of less skilled

workers.” (James, 2001: 173). This affirmation is partly confirmed by Williamson (1996),

4

according to whom the course of American real wages between 1870 and 1910 would have

been 15% higher than their actual level, if immigration had not occurred. Actually, while the

American GDP increased, in real terms, by 102.3% between 1870 and 1910, that is, an

average annual growth of 1.8%, real wages, as for them, only raised by 47.3%, i.e. less than

1% yearly. The examination of Figure 1 corroborates the existence, during the period 1870-

1910, of a growing gap between the increase in GDP per capita and the rise in wages.

Figure 1

GDP per capita and real wages in the United States: 1870-1910

147,3

202.3

0

50

100

150

200

250

1870

1872

1874

1876

1878

1880

1882

1884

1886

1888

1890

1892

1894

1896

1898

1900

1902

1904

1906

1908

1910

GDP/capita Wages

Note: 1870 = 100. Sources: GDP per capita: Maddison (2003); real wages: Williamson (1995).

This is the reason why the Dillingham Commission, formed in 1907 by the American

senate to study the origins and consequences of immigration, thought that immigrants

represented significant competition for national workers and considered that it was necessary

to limit entries (United States Immigration Commission, 1911). This position was widely

accepted by the American society, and by both the Democrat and Republican parties. Yet, the

main laws on immigration were not adopted during recession periods, as it would be

5

expected, but rather during the growing years that followed World War I, which indicates that

the protection of American workers was not the sole motive for refusing admission to

immigrants.

Thus, nativism was a political movement that advocated for a racial view of America

and, therefore, opposed immigration, in particular migration proceeding from “non-Nordic”

countries. This opposition to the American melting pot began to develop about the middle of

the nineteenth century, with the creation of several political parties (Native American Party,

Know Nothing, Order of the Sprangled Banner…) engaged in a desperate struggle against the

Irish “papists”, who arrived in large numbers after the famine that ravaged their country.

Then, the xenophobic agitation, especially on the West Coast, focused on the Chinese and

Japanese, whose customs appeared to represent a social threat, and who seemed unable to

integrate into the American society. In parallel with this opposition to Asian immigration,

“new migrants”, from western and southern Europe, were stigmatized by the “old migrants”

who came, as for them, from western and northern Europe.

American employers and politicians especially dreaded the spread of extreme left

ideas. In that sense, the 1886 Haymarket affair1 in Chicago marked the starting point of an

important wave of repression against “anarchists”, which were associated with the Jews

proceeding from eastern Europe. Restrictions against Jews were hence enacted in some

professions as well as in universities. After the October Revolution in Russia, the “Red Scare”

quickly expanded, and the arrests and deportations of foreigners increased. World War I also

contributed to strengthen the feeling of external threat, in particular from Americans of

German extraction, and gave rise to a strong Americanization movement that brought about,

for instance, the spread of English classes for immigrants.

It was in this context that the Immigration Restriction League, established in 1894 to

provide a political platform for theories on the superiority of the Nordic races, undertook,

along with the Ku Klux Klan, an active campaign against mass immigration. Most of the

American legislation on border controls actually followed from this activism, and all means

were good to exclude undesirable people: literacy tests, entry quotas, laws against the

anarchists or the poor… The twentieth century definitely meant the end of mass migration to

the United States.

1 While Chicago workers had been demonstrating since may 1st in favor of the eight-hour day, and had been violently opposed to the police, a bomb exploded in the middle of the policemen in Haymarket Square, on May 4, 1886. The police answered by shooting at the crowd, killing seven or eight demonstrators and wounding about a hundred of persons. Seven anarchists, most of them of German extraction, were sentenced to death, even though there was no proof of their implication in the attack.

6

American laws on immigration

The first restrictive law on immigration was enacted in 1882. The Chinese community

was specifically concerned since the Chinese Exclusion Act, initially enacted for a ten-year

period and then renewed in 1892, made the immigration of Chinese workers illegal. They

were also denied American citizenship, which did not allow them to have access to a number

of reserved jobs. Then, the Japanese were targeted: “So long as the Japanese remained

willing to perform agricultural labor at low wages, they remained popular with California

ranchers. But… many Japanese began to lease and buy agricultural land for farming on their

own account. This enterprise has the two-fold result of creating Japanese competition in the

produce field and decreasing the number of Japanese farmhands available.” (Light, 1972: 9).

American and Japanese governments adopted in 1907 a gentlemen’s agreement aiming at the

limitation of Japanese immigration in the United States. Moreover, several western States,

including California, restricted Japanese land acquisition.

Besides these racial measures, several individual categories were denied access to the

American territory. From 1882, lunatics and the mentally handicapped were concerned by

these restrictions. Next, an 1891 act excluded carriers of contagious or pestilential diseases,

polygamists and the destitute, while a 1903 act tackled beggars, prostitutes, epileptics, and

above all anarchists, especially feared since the assassination, two years earlier, of President

Mc Kinley by Leon Czolgoz. Another act of 1907 referred to criminals and tubercular

patients. The same year, children below sixteen years old not accompanied by one of their

parents were also denied access to the United States in order to try to put an end to child

labor.

But it was really after World War I that the fight against immigration took on new

dimensions. In 1917, after many fruitless attempts and despite President Wilson’s veto, the

literacy test was finally adopted: all the foreigners who wished for settling in the United States

had to demonstrate that they were able to read between thirty and eighty words, in the

language of their choice. Furthermore, new migrants had to pay an eight-dollar tax. The 1917

legislation mainly targeted citizens from eastern and southern Europe, where literacy rates

were low and poverty was high. Then, in 1921, the first act on quotas was enacted and

immigration became a function of the previous settlement of national communities on the

American soil: only 3% of the number of nationals already established in the United States

during the 1910 census could enter. Moreover, from 1922, the candidates to immigration had

7

to pay nine dollars to obtain a visa (which had to be added to the 1917 tax). But these

measures were not considered as restrictive enough and, in 1924, a second law on quotas was

adopted. The reference year became 1890, which favored northern and western Europeans

who had mainly arrived before this date. Besides, the new quota was 2% of established

nationals during the 1890 census.

Table 1

American immigration quotas by country

Origin country Number of immigrants (1921)

Annual quota of immigration (1924) Variation

“Old Europe” Belgium Denmark France Germany Netherlands Norway Sweden Switzerland United Kingdom and Ireland

138,551 6,166 6,260 9,552 6,803 6,493 7,423 9,171 7,106 79,577

125,653 1,304 1,181 3,086 25,957 3,153 2,377 3,314 1,707 83,574

-9% -79% -81% -68% +282% -51% -68% -64% -76% +5%

“New Europe” Austria Bulgaria Czechoslovakia Estonia Finland Greece Hungary Italy Latvia Lithuania Poland Portugal Romania Russia Spain Turkey Yugoslavia

520,654 4,947 585 40,884

- 3,795 28,502 7,702 222,260

- -

95,089 19,195 25,817 6,398 23,818 18,126 23,536

24,048 1,413 100 2,874 116 569 307 869 5,802 236 386 6,524 440 377 2,712 252 226 845

-95% -71% -83% -93%

- -85% -99% -89% -97%

- -

-93% -98% -99% -58% -99% -99% -96%

Total 664,099 150,501 -77% Source: Kirk (1946).

8

With the notable exception of Germany, the United Kingdom and Ireland, which

benefited from the quota legislation, most of the European countries were affected by the

1924 quotas (Table 1). Logically, countries with recent emigration to the United States, that

is, eastern and southern European countries, were particularly hard hit by the implementation

of these quantitative restrictions. On the contrary, the changes did not affect Latin-American

workers who, like their Canadian counterpart, were not subject to the quota laws. Indeed,

landowners of southwestern American States, who started to use Mexican labor force during

the first world conflict, opposed them. Furthermore, such a preferential treatment was in

keeping with the political logic of pan-Americanism: The restrictive immigration laws […]

were essentially an expression of American revulsion from the Old World; and since, as a

consequence of its isolationism, the United States tended to draw closer to other American

countries, it was natural to place immigration from them upon a special footing.” (Jones,

1992: 248). Yet, the so-called “good neighborhood” policy did not prevent the United States

from implementing, in 1924, a border police along the Rio Grande in order to stop illegal

immigration from Mexico (Mariage-Strauss, 2002).

With the beginning of the Great Depression, controls became stricter. The financial

standing of immigrants was deeply analyzed and American consulates were in charge of

medical visits in sending countries. Besides, close relations had to commit themselves, if

necessary, to financially help the immigrant. Finally, with the crisis, a great number of

workers were denied the right to practice their profession in the US, inter alia lawyers,

doctors and teachers (Jones, 1992).

The worldwide extension of border controls

As in the United States, the first restrictive measures adopted by Canada and Australia

in terms of immigration targeted Asian populations. Thus, in 1885, the Canadian Parliament

introduced a lump sum tax of fifty dollars for all Chinese immigrants. In 1900, the amount of

the tax came to one hundred dollars, then five hundred dollars in 1905 (Daniels, 1995). In

other respects, Canadian authorities promulgated a decree, in 1908, forbidding the entry on its

territory of every immigrant who had put into port during her arrival journey. Without saying

it, this decision was directed at Indian immigrants who, due to the lack of a direct shipping

line between India and Canada, was forced to transfer through Japan or Hong Kong to go to

Canada (Buchignani and al., 1985). Australia, as for it, enacted in 1901 a law aiming at

limiting the entry of Asian immigrants through a literacy test: when immigration agents

9

required it, candidates for migration had to take a dictation test of fifty words, but only in a

European language (Markus, 1979).

In a general way, measures adopted before 1914 did not affect European immigration,

even though British colonies tended to privilege immigrants proceeding from Great Britain.

On the contrary, the nationalism that followed World War I, combined with the economic

problems of the interwar period, brought about the strengthening of border controls in most of

the immigration countries. Thus, in 1923, Canada enacted a law that formally banned Chinese

immigration. Then, in 1933, Canadian authorities decided to limit the entry of southern and

eastern Europeans, who only could have access to farm and domestic work (James, 2001). On

the other hand, natives from Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Netherlands, Sweden and

Switzerland belonged to the “preferred countries” list and had the same advantages than

British subjects. In the same way, Australia promulgated in 1925 a law that restricted the

entry of non-British migrants into its territory, through the adoption of citizenship and

occupation criteria. The Queensland Province went farer, by forbidding foreigners to buy

lands or to work in certain industries (de Lepervanche, 1975). Such policies reflect the

atmosphere at the time against immigrants, in particular these coming from southern Europe:

“Southern Europeans who came to Australia in the 1920s were treated with suspicion.

Immigrant ships were refused permission to land and there were ‘anti-Dago’ riots in the

1930s.” (Castles and Miller, 1998: 62).

Faced with the upsurge of border controls in Anglo-Saxon countries, candidates for

migration headed for Latin America. Thus, although not reaching the pre-war levels, the

immigration volume remained high in Argentina: 140,000 immigrants on annual average

during the decade 1921-1930 as against 177,000 between 1901 and 1910 (239,000 during the

decade 1904-1913). Brazil, as for it, received more immigrants after World War I (84,000

entries on annual average during the decade 1921-1930) than during the decade 1901-1910

(70,000 entries). Mexico and Uruguay also drew a larger number of immigrants during the

1920s (46,000 and 17,000 average entries, respectively, for Mexico and Uruguay during the

decade 1921-1930) than at the beginning of the century (respectively, 40,000 and 11,000

entries for the period 1904-1913).

Similarly, the few European nations open to immigration became more attractive as

the rest of the world closed its doors. Eastern and southern Europeans, in particular, for whom

it had become difficult to move overseas, opted for Belgium or France. The latter recorded a

migratory net balance of about two millions of persons during the 1920s, whereas it was only

250,000 during the decade 1900-1910 (Bairoch, 1997). At the end of the decade, France

10

hence succeeded the United States as the main receiving countries in terms of European

migration. A private institution, the Société Générale d’Immigration (SGI), was in charge of

recruiting abroad, mainly for the farming and mining sectors, and of establishing contracts

between foreign workers and domestic firms (Castles et Miller, 1998). Belgium, as for it,

received about 140,000 foreigners during the 1920s. Italians and Polish, followed by

Spaniards and, in a lesser extent, by Portuguese, Czechoslovaks and Yugoslavs represented

most of the migrants within the European continent (Kirk, 1946).

But, the 1930s crisis gave rise to a new series of border control policies that put a

definitive end to the free movement of persons on a worldwide scale. Thus, in 1930, South

Africa decided to ban the entry on its territory to the citizens coming from the “non-preferred”

countries, that is, the non-Anglo-Saxon ones. Latin America countries, particularly affected

by the shock wave of the Great Depression, also decided to restrict immigration, while

European nations began to strengthen their own migration policy. Switzerland, for instance,

began to require, after 1932, that the candidates for immigration fulfill several financial

conditions. The same year, France implemented a quota system with the goal of reducing the

number of foreign workers in French firms. Afterwards, French government authorized the

layoffs of immigrants in sectors affected by the crisis and chose to deport part of them (Weil,

1991). Hitler’s Germany, as for it, adopted a strict border control policy by limiting

recruitment possibilities of foreign workers, by opting for the “national preference” in terms

of employment, by punishing the firms that resorted to clandestine work, and finally, by

deporting the undesirable foreigners (Dohse, 1981).

Finally, it is noteworthy that after World War I, several countries put into place exit

control measures. Former Soviet Union, for instance, expressly prohibited, with some

exceptions, emigration of its nationals. In the same way, Mussolini’s Italy tried to control

migration outflows by giving permission to expatriate only to labor contract holders or to the

persons who could be hosted by a close relative.

II –The Impact of Social Policies on European emigration

Although the increase in worldwide border controls was largely accountable for the

decrease in European emigration, it was not the only responsible for it. As a matter of fact, the

quota system adopted by the United States in the 1920s played a great part in the reduction of

inflows from Europe. Yet, during the 1930s, not one of the European nations, not even the

southern and eastern ones, fulfilled its quota: “In the decade of the 1930s, the quotas became

11

non-binding. From 1930 to 1931, quota immigration dropped by 62 percent. In 1933 only

8,220 quota immigrants out of a permissible total of 153,879 were admitted. No immigrant

category fulfilled its quota for any year in the decade. Southern and eastern European nations

did reach nearly 90 percent of their quota, but only in one year, 1939, as refugee emigrants

fled Europe. No other sources reached more than 41 percent of their quotas.” (Gemery, 1994:

180). It seems therefore necessary to look for the internal determinants of the European

emigration decline. It that sense, the introduction of an embryonic Welfare State in several

European nations might have contributed to the decrease in emigration.

The internal determinants of the European emigration slowdown

First and foremost, international migration flows were interrupted by World War I.

European armies had overwhelming needs of “cannon fodder” and about 8.6 million soldiers

and 6 million civilians were killed during the war (Bairoch, 1997). Besides, 1918 and 1919

were marked by an epidemic of “Spanish flu”, which is estimated to have taken more than 20

million lives all over the world (ibid). The potential number of migrants was thereby affected

for many years. But, beyond this double demographic catastrophe, there was a long-term

trend of decrease in the population growth, related to the demographic transition in most of

the European countries. As a matter of fact, despite an upturn in the post-war birth rate, the

1920s and 1930s were characterized by a natural growth rate of the European population

below its pre-1914 level and above all its nineteenth century level (Kirk, 1946). In northern

and western European countries, notably, demographic growth rates fell rapidly, while the

impulse continued to be high in southern and eastern nations. This difference in demographic

behavior partly explains why migration candidates during the interwar years were more

numerous in the latter countries. In addition to these demographic changes, the economic

progress in European countries played a significant role. Employment opportunities increased

as towns developed and trade and industry grew, while European labor markets contracted

under the influence of the war and the slowdown in demographic growth. As a result, the

wage convergence process initiated before World War I should have increased after the

conflict. However, wage differentials remained high during the interwar years, at least

between Europe and the United States.

12

Figure 2

Real wage differentials: 1870-1913

37

6371

78

143154

132

94

797575696766

545042

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

Italy

Portu

gal

Spai

n

Nor

way

Fran

ce

Swed

en

Den

mar

k

Bra

zil

Net

herla

nds

Ger

man

y

Irel

and

Arg

entin

a

Bel

gium

Gre

at-B

ritai

n

Aus

tralia

Uni

ted-

Stat

es

Can

ada

Note: Wages correspond to the average of real international wages (100 = British wages in 1905). Source: author’s calculations based on Williamson (1995).

Figure 3

Real wage differentials: 1920-1939

2735

4554 56

7287

96104

110 111 115124 127

134

153

188

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

200

220

Portu

gal

Bra

zil

Bel

gium

Italy

Spai

n

Fran

ce

Ger

man

y

Arg

entin

a

Gre

at B

ritai

n

Irel

and

Swed

en

Nor

way

Can

ada

Net

herla

nds

Aus

tralia

Den

mar

k

Uni

ted

Stat

es

Note: Wages correspond to the average of real international wages (100 = British wages in 1927) Source: author’s calculations based on Williamson (1995)

13

Figures 2 and 3 represent, respectively, the average of real international wages during

the periods 1870-1913 and 1920-1939. It appears that some European countries, in particular

Scandinavian nations, the British islands and the Netherlands, partly caught up the wage rates

of overseas countries after World War I, and stood at the same level than Argentina, or even

Canada and Australia. But lots of European nations, notably the southern ones (and probably

the eastern ones too) stayed far behind these countries. Above all, it seems obvious that the

convergence between European and American salaries had not occurred yet during the

interwar years. The existence of such a wage gap between European countries and the United

States, or even between Latin European countries and Argentina, hence invalidates the wage

convergence hypothesis, according to which the main reason for the slowdown in

international labor mobility is due to the reduction in wage differentials between sending and

receiving countries (Hatton and Williamson, 1994). It is particularly striking to notice that the

two countries that recorded the highest emigration rates during the 1930s, i.e. the Netherlands

(5.5‰) and Denmark (2.7‰), also offered the highest average real wages in Europe, which is

not consistent with the traditional idea that the lower the wage gap, the lower the emigration

rate. Consequently, it seems necessary to look elsewhere for the origins of the drop in

European emigration, and in particular in the development of social safety nets during the

interwar period.

Social Welfare and European Migration

The introduction of social insurance systems in Europe began at the end of the

nineteenth century. But it was really after World War I, and above all with the crisis of the

1930s, that the majority of the population had access to new social insurance mechanisms. As

a matter of fact, all levels of the society were identically affected by both the conflict and the

economic depression, which fostered the emergence of new forms of national solidarity. The

need for collective insurance entailed the adoption of compulsory social systems in many

European countries (Table 2). Health and pension insurance particularly expanded during the

interwar years. But, the real novelty of the period lies on the implementation of

unemployment benefits. Despite the criticism expressed by liberal economists, like Rueff

(1931) in France, who considered that unemployment insurance (the dole) actually fueled

unemployment on account of the discrepancy between actual and equilibrium wages, several

countries opted for following the United Kingdom by adopting compulsory unemployment

14

insurance. The result was that at the dawn of World War II, around half the European

employees benefited from old age and unemployment insurance (Flora and Alber, 1981).

Table 2

The implementation of social insurance mechanisms in Europe before World War II

Industrial accident insurance

Health insurance

Pension insurance

Unemployment insurance

Austria 1887 1888 1927 1920

Belgium (1903) (1894) 1924 (1900) (1920)

Denmark 1916 (1898)

1933 (1892)

1921/1922 (1891) (1907)

Finland 1895 / 1937 (1917)

France (1898) 1930 (1898)

1910 (1895) (1905)

Germany 1884 (1871) 1833 1889 1927

Italy 1898 1928 (1886)

1919 (1898) 1919

Netherlands 1901 1929 1913 (1916)

Norway 1894 1909 1936 1938 (1906)

Sweden 1916 (1901) (1891) 1913 (1934)

Switzerland 1911 (1881) (1891) / (1924)

United Kingdom (1897) 1911 1925 (1908) 1911

Note: The numbers in parentheses refer to subsidized voluntary insurance; the other numbers correspond to compulsory insurance. The interwar years are in bold. Source: Flora (1983).

The question now is to know to what extent the development of social policies had an

influence on the course of European emigration after World War I. Thus, Table 3 shows that

there was a strong negative correlation between social expenditures as a percentage of GDP

and emigration rates in at least six countries (the United Kingdom, France, Ireland, Norway,

Italy and Sweden); the correlation was less significant for Germany and Austria, but it was

15

still negative. Belgium, as for it, recorded a strong positive correlation (but only five years are

available).

Table 3

Correlation coefficients between social expenditures and emigration rates

Country Period Correlation coefficient

United Kingdom 1920-1938 -0.88

France 1920-1938 -0.80

Ireland 1927-1939 -0.79

Norway 1925-1939 -0.79

Italy 1920-1939 -0.65

Sweden 1920-1939 -0.63

Germany 1925-1935 -0.47

Austria 1924-1934 -0.43

Netherlands 1920-1939 0.06

Belgium 1934-1938 0.72 Sources: Author’s calculations based on Flora (1983) for social expenditures, and Mitchell (2003) and Maddison (2003) for emigration rates.

Beyond this inverse relationship between social expenditures and emigration rates, it is

important to notice the existence of structural breaks that correspond to the adoption of such

and such social measures, in particular in terms of unemployment benefits. Thus, the average

annual emigration rate in Germany was 1.2‰ between 1923 and 1927, but, after the

introduction of the unemployment insurance system in 1927, it went down to 0.5‰ during the

period 1928-1932 (-58%). Of course, it was the time of the Great Depression and

opportunities in other countries were limited. Yet, the “coincidence” is striking. By the same

token, the implementation of unemployment benefits in Switzerland in 1924 brought about a

decrease in the emigration rate that went down from 1.6‰ in 1920-1924 to 1.2‰ in 1925-

1929 (-25%). The adoption of the pension insurance system in Belgium in 1924 was also

accompanied by a fall in the emigration rate: 4.6‰ in 1920-1924, 4‰ in 1925-1929 (-13%);

while the introduction of health insurance in 1933 triggered a similar drop in Denmark: 3‰ in

1929-1933 and 2.5‰ in 1934-1938 (-17%).

16

Figure 4

Social expenditures and emigration rates in Europe: 1920-1939

Belgium

AustriaGermany

Sweden

United Kingdom

Norway

Italy

Netherlands

Denmark

SwitzerlandFrance

-1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14

Social expenditures/GDP (%)

Em

igra

tion

rat

e (‰

)

Notes: Horizontal axis represents the average of social expenditures as a percentage of GDP; vertical axis corresponds to the average of emigration rates. Periods for each country are the same than in Table 3. There are only data for two years in Denmark (1929 and 1938) and one year in Switzerland (1938). The correlation coefficient is -0.54. Sources: Author’s calculations based on Flora (1983) for social expenditures, and Mitchell (2003) and Maddison (2003) for emigration rates.

Eventually, there was also an inverse relationship between the average of the social

expenditures as a percentage of GDP and the average of the emigration rates for the European

countries taken as a whole. This relationship is illustrated by Figure 4. The countries that

presented the highest emigration rates, like the Netherlands, Italy or Denmark, were also the

countries with the lowest social expenditures levels. On the contrary, Germany, that led

European countries in terms of social expenditures, had very low levels of emigration rates. In

that sense, the “paradox” of Denmark and the Netherlands, which recorded the highest wages

in Europe (Figure 3) and, at the same time, the highest emigration rates (see Table 6), is not

anymore a puzzle, since these two nations also had the lowest level of social expenditures

before 1940.

17

In total, it appears that the implementation of social insurance mechanisms in most of

the European countries after World War I fostered the decrease in labor mobility that occurred

during the interwar period. As shown in a previous work (Khoudour-Castéras, 2005b), this is

due to the fact that candidates for migration look not only into the wage gap between sending

and receiving countries, but also into the differential in “indirect wages”, that is, the

differences in terms of social benefits. Indeed, these benefits represent a form of social

remuneration that mitigates the impact of low wage earnings in sending countries.

III – The End of Labor Mobility as an Adjustment Mechanism

As seen previously, the slump in international migration after World War I was the

joint result of the adoption of restrictive migration policies in the main receiving countries, the

demographic decline in Europe, and the implementation of social insurance mechanisms in

several western European nations. The interwar period hence became a world of “labor

immobility” or, at least, of very imperfect mobility. The upshot was a disconnection between

business cycles and migration flows.

A new world of labor immobility

The implementation of the literacy test had little impact on the U.S. immigration, since

only 1,450 persons were rejected on account of their illiteracy (Mariage-Strauss, 2002). On

the contrary, the quota legislation was not long in making its influence felt (Figure 5). Thus,

after the adoption of the 1921 act, the number of immigrants dropped by 61.6% between 1921

(805,228 entries) and 1922 (309.556 entries). Then, it increased until the restrictive 1924 act,

which dramatically reduced the entries on the American soil. Between 1924 and 1925, the

number of immigrants fell by 58.4%. Afterwards, the entries became stable, with a mean of

about 304,000 between 1925 and 1929. Finally, with the crisis and the development of border

controls during the 1930s, the number of immigrants still reduced: 70,000, on annual average,

during the period 1930-1940.

18

Figure 5

Immigration to the United States: 1918-1940

111141

430

805

310

523

707

294 304335

307280

242

97

36 23 29 35 36 50 68 83 71

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

800

90019

18

1919

1920

1921

1922

1923

1924

1925

1926

1927

1928

1929

1930

1931

1932

1933

1934

1935

1936

1937

1938

1939

1940

Thou

sand

s of

imm

igra

nts

Source: Mitchell (2003).

But, the main impact of quotas was in terms of geographic origin of immigrants. The

restrictions, combined with internal European factors, reduced the importance of European

immigration (Table 4). While representing 92% of total immigration at the beginning of the

century, the number of Europeans was only 60% during the decade 1921-1930 and 66%

between 1931 and 1940. Then, the other inhabitants of the American hemisphere, who were

not concerned by quotas, succeeded them. Thus, Mexicans, who did not even represent 1% of

immigrants to the United States during the period 1901-1910, were 11% of the total between

1921 and 1930. Likewise, the share of Canadians in total immigration went up from 2%

during the decade 1901=1910 to 22% between 1921 and 1940.

19

Table 4

Number of immigrants to the United States by decade

Origin region “Old Europe” “New Europe” Total Europe All countries

1901-1910 1.910.035

22% 24%

6.146.005 70% 76%

8.056.040 92%

100%

8.795.386 100%

1911-1920 997.438

15% 23%

3.324.449 60% 77%

4.321.887 75%

100%

5.735.811 100%

1921-1930 1.283.296

31% 52%

1.179.898 29% 48%

2.463.194 60%

100%

4.107.209 100%

1931-1940 197.964

38% 57%

149.602 28% 43%

347.566 66%

100%

528.431 100%

Note: “Old Europe” refers to traditional immigration countries, that is, western and northern European countries: Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Ireland, the Netherlands, Norway, Sweden, Switzerland and the United Kingdom. “New Europe” includes recent immigration countries, i.e. eastern and southern Europe: Austria, Czechoslovakia, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Russia, Spain, Yugoslavia, etc. Source: U.S. Immigration and Naturalization Service (2003).

In other respects, quota laws resulted in a reallocation of migration in favor of “old

Europe” citizens. These, who represented less than a quarter of European immigration during

the first two decades of the twentieth century, became the majority again in the 1920s and

1930s. Not really because of a significant increase in the number of immigrants originating

from western and northern Europe, but rather due to the fall in immigration from eastern and

southern Europeans. Thus, whereas the number of immigrants proceeding from the “old

Europe” increased by 29% between the decades 1911-1920 and 1921-1930, the number of

“new Europeans” dropped by 65%; meanwhile, total immigration fall by 28%. By the same

token, the 1930s were marked by a drastic reduction of the immigration to the United States,

but eastern and southern Europeans were especially affected, with a drop by 87% between the

decade 1921-1930 and the following one. They then represented 43% of immigrant cohorts

coming from Europe and only 28% of total immigration.

In total, border control measures implemented by American authorities achieved their

twofold purpose: first of all, to reduce total immigration; second of all, to specifically affect

southern and eastern European countries. “Discrimination exerts its effects. Countries such as

20

Great Britain, Ireland, Germany, which benefit from a significant quota, do not fulfill it. In

Greece, in Italy, in eastern Europe, lines grow longer in front of American consulates in

order to obtain the precious visa. When the Nazi persecution pounces on the Jews, the State

Department declares itself bound by the quota legislation and sparingly allowed those

threatened by the worst extermination to enter.” (Kaspi, 1986: 19).

Outside the United States, immigration increased slightly during the 1920s, mainly as

a consequence of American restrictions, but strongly decreased during the 1930s (Figures 6

and 7). While the number of immigrants was, on average, 140,000 in Argentina, 123,000 in

Canada and 84,000 in Brazil during the decade 1921-1930, it only was 31,000; 16,000 and

39,000, respectively, during the years 1931-1940. Likewise, Australian immigration

dramatically fall during the second half of the 1920s, with a drop of the immigration rate by

86% between 1927 and 1932). The number of entries thus went down from 42,000 on annual

average during the decade 1921-1930 to 14,000 between 1931 and 1940.

Figure 6

The course of immigration in Argentina, Brazil and Canada: 1900-1940

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

1900

1902

1904

1906

1908

1910

1912

1914

1916

1918

1920

1922

1924

1926

1928

1930

1932

1934

1936

1938

1940

Thou

sand

s of

Imm

igra

nts

Argentina Brazil Canada

Source: Mitchell (2003).

21

Figure 7

The course of immigration in Australia: 1921-1940

24

12

18

40

67

9.4

0

10

20

30

40

50

60

70

1921

1922

1923

1924

1925

1926

1927

1928

1929

1930

1931

1932

1933

1934

1935

1936

1937

1938

1939

1940

Thou

sand

s of

imm

igra

nts

Source: Mitchell (2003).

Figure 8

The course of emigration in Europe: 1900-1940

1937

1930

1925

1923

1921

1920

1918

1913

1911

1908

1907

1904

1933

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

1900

1902

1904

1906

1908

1910

1912

1914

1916

1918

1920

1922

1924

1926

1928

1930

1932

1934

1936

1938

1940

Thou

sand

s of

em

igra

nts

Note: The figure includes emigrants from Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Czechoslovakia, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Rumania, Russia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, the United Kingdom and Yugoslavia. Sources: Author’s calculations based on Ferenczi and Willcox (1929), and Mitchell (2003).

22

The change in migration patterns was also remarkable on the emigration countries

side. While the average annual number of European emigrants was around 1.6 millions

between 1901 and 1913, there were 857,000 average annual departures in the 1920s, and

hardly 356,000 in the 1930s (see figure 8). At the national level, the decline was very

impressive too. Indeed, with the notable exception of Denmark, which recorded a slight

increase in emigration rate during the 1930s, emigration dropped in all European countries

after World War I. Thus, Table 5 shows that between the periods 1900-1913 and 1930-1939

the emigration rate decreased by more than 40% in most of the European countries.

Scandinavian and Central European countries were the first affected by this phenomenon

since the emigration rate in these regions was below 0.5‰ after 1930. In that sense, the

implementation of quotas in the United States particularly hit countries like Austria and

Hungary.

Table 5

The course of emigration rates in Europe: 1900-1939

(a)

1900-1913

(b)

1920-1929

(c)

1930-1939

(d) % change

(b)/(a)

(e) % change

(c)/(b)

(f) % change

(c)/(a) Austria 17.61 0.97 0.37 -94.5 -61.6 -97.9

Hungary 6.47 0.65 0.20 -90.0 -69.4 -96.9

Norway 7.17 3.23 0.31 -54.9 -90.5 -95.7

Finland 5.33 1.83 0.34 -65.6 -81.4 -93.6

Sweden 4.52 2.21 0.46 -51.0 -79.3 -89.9

United Kingdom 7.16 3.85 0.80 -46.2 -79.3 -88.8

Ireland 7.82 7.39 0.91 -5.5 -87.7 -88.4

Spain 7.71 4.05 0.95 -47.5 -76.4 -87.6

Italy 17.05 7.58 2.13 -55.5 -71.9 -87.5

France 0.18 0.14 0.03 -22.2 -78.6 -83.3

Portugal 7.09 5.88 1.66 -17.0 -71.8 -76.6

Switzerland 1.40 1.49 0.47 +6.0 -68.6 -66.7

Belgium 4.21 4.34 2.18 +2.9 -49.6 -48.2

Germany 0.44 0.84 0.26 +88.6 -68.3 -40.3

Netherlands 5.64 6.19 5.50 +9.8 -11.1 -2.4

Denmark 2.64 2.31 2.68 -12.5 +15.7 +1.2 Note: Columns a, b and c represent the average annual emigration rate. Columns d, e and f show the total change in percent, respectively, between the periods 1920-1929 and 1900-1913, between the periods 1930-1939 and 1920-1929, and between the periods 1930-1939 and 1900-1913. Source: Author’s calculations based on Ferenczi and Willcox (1929), and Mitchell (2003).

23

The end of the relationship between labor mobility and business cycles

The combined action of restrictive migration policies in the New World and social

reforms in Europe had the effect of reducing international migration flows. As a result, labor

mobility stopped playing the role of adjustment mechanism that it had before World War I.

Thus, in the United States, while the correlation coefficient between the GDP growth rate and

the immigration growth rate was 0.7 for the period 1891-1913 (the growth of the GDP

entailed a rise in immigration), it was only -0.3 for 1920-1940. The correlation coefficient

between unemployment and immigration growth rates, as for it, was -0.6 for the first period

(an increase in the unemployment rate brought about a fall in the immigration rate), and 0.2

for the second one.

The consequences of migration barriers were also felt by European countries,

especially by those that tried to maintain both the stability and the convertibility of their

currency, especially the “gold bloc” countries. Table 6 shows that when the members of the

interwar gold exchange standard were affected by an economic crisis, the emigration rate did

not follow the expected pattern. Indeed, instead of increasing, as it did during the gold

standard period, emigration in Europe tended to fall after a depression. Thus, a drop in the

GDP was followed by a decrease in the emigration rate in 30 out of 37 cases (81% of the

cases), while an increase in the unemployment rate was accompanied by a fall in the

emigration rate in 21 out of 27 cases (78% of the cases).

24

Table 6

Depression and emigration during the interwar gold exchange standard

Country GES years Depression

years (year t)

GDP growth rate

(year t)

Unemployment growth rate

(year t)

Emigration growth rate (year t+1)

Austria 1923-1931 1923 1930 1931

-1.0% -2.8% -8.0%

n.a. +27.3% +38.6%

-82.6% -38.3% -19.5%

Belgium 1925-1935

1929 1930 1931 1932 1934

-0.9% -1.0% -1.8% -4.5% -0.8%

+33.3% +175.0% +209.1% +75.0% +11.3%

+0.8% -35.2% -5.9%

-12.0% -12.7%

France 1928-1936

1930 1931 1932 1934 1935

-2.9% -6.0% -6.5% -1.0% -2.6%

n.a.

-50.7% -53.3% -33.1% +23.6% -7.1%

Germany 1924-1931 1929 1930 1931

-0.4% -1.4% -7.6%

+56.0% +16.8% +52.3%

-24.0% -64.0% -22.3%

Hungary 1925-1931 1926 1930 1931

-4.2% -2.2% -4.8%

n.a. -5.9%

-76.0% -47.0%

Italy 1927-1936

1927 1930 1931 1933

-2.2% -4.9% -0.6% -0.7%

n.a. +47.1% +72.0% +1.7%

-30.2% -17.2% -32.5% -24.9%

Netherlands 1925-1936

1930 1931 1932 1933 1934

-0.2% -6.1% -1.4% -0.2% -1.8%

+35.3% +87.0% +93.0% +16.9% +1.0%

-35.0% +1.6% +6.0% +5.9% +7.6%

Norway 1928-1931 1931 -7.8% +34.3% -50.3%

Sweden 1924-1931 1931 -3.6% +45.5% -30.3%

Switzerland 1925-1936

1930 1931 1932 1935

-0.6% -4.2% -3.4% -0.4%

+75.0% +71.4%

+133.3% +27.3%

-53.1% -23.9% -8.1%

+53.4%

United Kingdom 1925-1931

1926 1930 1931

-3.7% -0.7% -5.1%

+11.4% +53.4% +34.8%

-8.2% -63.0% -21.7%

Sources: author’s calculations based on Mitchell (2003) for emigration, Maddison (1991) for unemployment rates, and Maddison (2003) for population and GDP. The gold exchange standard years are given by Eichengreen (1992).

25

Eventually, this is a confirmation of the fact that labor mobility can play a role of

safety valve in fixed exchange rate regimes only if there are enough employment

opportunities in at least one country. It is because the New World in general and the United

States in particular were able – and eager – to absorb a large amount of labor before World

War I that European workers could settle abroad when domestic conditions worsened. But, it

was not until 1938 that the American GDP attained again its 1929 level; and the

unemployment rate was 18.3%, on annual average, between 1930 and 1939, which clearly

meant that foreign workers were not welcome in the United States, as confirmed by a

discourse made by Franklin Roosevelt during the 1932 presidential campaign: “Our last

frontier has long since been reached, and there is practically no more free land. More than

half of our people do not live on the farms or on lands and cannot derive a living by

cultivating their own property. There is no safety valve in the form of a Western prairie to

which those thrown out of work by the Eastern economic machines can go for a new start. We

are not able to invite the immigration from Europe to share our endless plenty. We are now

providing a drab living for our own people.” (Roosevelt, 1932).

IV - On the Impact of Labor Immobility on the Fall of the Interwar Gold Exchange

Standard

It is likely that the success of the classical gold standard before World War I was

indirectly the result of the labor shortage in New World countries. Their development

potential was constrained by the lack of labor force and they generally had very active

immigration policies in order to fill the fields and the factories with foreign manpower. To the

contrary, the nineteenth century population explosion in Europe brought about a huge labor

surplus that could only be solved thanks to the departure of a large number of workers for the

far shores of the Americas or Oceania. This migration process was made easier by the

existence of significant wage differentials between sending and receiving countries. Besides,

labor movements were strongly sensitive to business cycles and changes in employment

conditions: a rise in the foreign economic activity and/or a decrease in the domestic economy

entailed a surge in migration, whereas a recession in the receiving countries and/or an

expansion at home resulted in fewer movements. Then, the countries that belonged to the gold

standard could rest on labor mobility to mitigate the effects of exchange rate stability

(Khoudour-Castéras, 2005a). But, after World War I, when labor turned out to be surplus in

26

the main host countries, potential migrants had to stay at home, with the consequence that the

adjustment became more difficult. The gold exchange standard could not withstand this new

situation.

Labor mobility and the adjustment problem of the gold exchange standard

One of the main problems of the gold exchange standard lay in the inability of public

authorities to cope with economic disturbances and to restore their current account

equilibrium: “Weak-currency countries like Britain were saddled with chronic balance-of-

payments deficits and hemorrhaged gold and exchange reserves, while strong-currency

countries like France remained in persistent surplus.” (Eichengreen, 1998: 48). This situation

was the result of the lack of efficiency of the adjustment mechanism that was supposed to

govern the prevailing international monetary system. In that regard, Figure 9 shows how the

current account was expected to return to its equilibrium position after an initial deficit or

surplus. Two countries are considered: the United Kingdom, which suffers from a deficit, and

the United States, which runs a surplus. As a consequence of the disequilibrium, gold and

exchange reserves move from the United Kingdom to the United States, which entails a drop

in the British money supply and a rise in the American one. Therefore, both prices and

demand expenditure decrease in the United Kingdom, while they increase in the United

States. The upshot is a change in the respective real exchange rates (by definition, the

participation to the gold exchange standard means that nominal exchange rates remain

constant) and then in competitiveness positions, which fosters the return to the balance-of-

payments equilibrium. This mechanism, which is an extension of the price-specie-flow

mechanism (the impact of changes in money supply on demand expenditure has been added

to the Hume mechanism), implies that governments do not have to intervene in the current

account adjustment process. But in reality, the automatic adjustment mechanism did not work

during the interwar gold exchange standard (and it is not sure that it worked either during the

classical gold standard).

27

Figure 9

The current account adjustment in theory

United Kingdom United States

demand for American products > demand for

British products

current account deficit current account

surplus

reserve outflows

reserve flows reserve inflows

↓ money supply ↑ money supply

↓ prices ↓ demand ↑ prices ↑ demand

↓ imports ↑ exports

↑ imports

↓ exports

current account

equilibrium

28

There are many – and contradictory – explanations for the failure of the adjustment

process during the gold exchange standard. One of the most common lies on the existence of

wage and price rigidities, which would have prevented current accounts to return to their

equilibrium position. Actually, the interwar period was characterized by downward wage

rigidities, not only in Europe, where the improvement in working conditions that followed

World War I implied nominal wage guarantees in labor contracts, but also in the United

States, where employers themselves considered that they had a role to play to avoid the

propagation of crises: “Manufacturing firms became convinced following the trauma of 1920-

1922 that maintaining wage rates during a downturn was necessary if precipitous sales

declines were to be avoided.” (O’Brien, 1989: 729). The problem with this argument is that it

does not explain why the countries that ran a current account surplus, for instance France or

the United States, maintained their surplus despite significant wage increases (since wages

were not rigid upward). It does not allow either to understand why the countries with current

account deficits did not restore the situation through a reduction in aggregate demand. As

illustrated by Figure 9, even though wages were rigid, the deficit should have induced a drop

in money supply and then in domestic expenditure, which in turn should have affected

imports. Likewise, a current account surplus should have been offset by an increase in

imports, originated by the rise in money supply and domestic demand. But: “The persistence

of external deficits indicated that the predicted adjustment of nominal spending was not

taking place. Something was preventing balance-of-payments deficits from reducing domestic

money supplies and thereby compressing domestic expenditure.” (Eichengreen, 1992: 204).

One of the reasons put forward for this adjustment problem is that the convertibility of

the currencies into gold only concerned external convertibility, whereas internal convertibility

was subject to numerous restrictions. The lack of real constraint in terms of internal

convertibility hence implied that market mechanisms were not in a position to play their

adjustment role, in particular since the gold exchange standard allowed credit movements to

be disconnected from gold movements (Rueff, 1964). Thus, the United States could export

capital to Europe and maintain at the same time their gold at home. European countries, as for

them, benefited from international lending, which permitted them to avoid deflation policies

in the event of a deficit. Eventually, international credit fostered the increase in world money

supply, which encouraged speculative movements. Although this explanation is convenient

for deficit countries, which tried to avoid the implementation of restrictive policies, costly in

terms of output and employment, it does not suit surplus countries. Actually, according to the

29

lack-of-constraint logic, the U.S. money supply should have increased since capital outflows

were not accompanied by gold outflows.

Therefore, the explanation for persistent disequilibria has to be sought elsewhere and

most probably in the intervention of the monetary authorities on capital markets (Eichengreen,

1992). Thus, Figure 10 represents the counterproductive effects of sterilization policies during

the interwar gold standard. As in Figure 9, the United Kingdom runs a deficit and the United

States a surplus. The main cause of such a disequilibrium is considered to be the

overvaluation of the pound vis-à-vis the dollar2. Contrary to the theoretical case described

previously, the monetary authorities now decide to offset the impact of the movements of gold

and exchange reserves on money supply: the British central bank buys government securities

so that it can increase the domestic money supply, whereas the Federal Reserve uses open

market sales to lower the American money supply. By sterilizing reserve flows, the latter tries

to avoid inflation pressures caused by the increase in money supply, while the former aims at

fighting both deflation and unemployment3. It is noteworthy that the adoption of a restrictive

monetary policy in the United States comes with an increase in real interest rate, which

contributes to the attraction of foreign capital; to the contrary, the fall in the British real

interest rate tends to drive capital out of the country. The additional flows of capital compel

both central banks to use new sterilization policies, which deter even more the adjustment

process. Indeed, in the United Kingdom, the actual money supply stands above its “optimal”

level, that is, the level that would allow the return to the balance-of-payments equilibrium.

Then, domestic prices and national expenditure are also above their “optimal” level and the

United Kingdom remains with its deficit. In the United States, the inverse process occurs.

Finally, the impossibility for prices and demand to adjust explains why current

account disequilibria could not be solved during the gold exchange standard years. Obviously,

the breaking of the “rules of the game” undermined the credibility of the system and the only

question was eventually to know how long the gold exchange standard would resist the lack

of international cooperation and the structural adjustment problem.

2 Following the return of the United Kingdom to the gold standard, Keynes (1925) maintained that the pound was overvalued by 10% at the pre-1914 parity of 4.86 dollars. Although there have been many debates on this issue, there is today a consensus on the overvaluation of the pound, but not yet on its magnitude or even its impact. 3 Eichengreen (1990) shows that during the interwar gold standard sterilization policies were as frequent in deficit countries than in surplus countries.

30

Figure 10

The gold exchange standard in practice

United Kingdom United States

overvaluation of the pound/dollar

demand for American products > demand for

British products

current account deficit current account surplus

reserve outflows

reserve flows reserve inflows

capital flows

capital

outflows

capital inflows

expansive monetary

policy sterilization

policies

restrictive monetary

policy

↓ real interest

rate ↑ real interest

rate

actual money supply > “optimal” money supply actual money supply <

“optimal” money supply

actual prices >

equilibrium prices

actual demand >

equilibrium demand

actual prices <

equilibrium prices

actual demand <

equilibrium demand

deficit

persistent

disequilibria surplus

31

In total, among the many explanations for the adjustment problem of the gold

exchange standard, the most pertinent seems to be the frequent use of sterilization policies by

the interwar monetary authorities. Yet, it is also conceivable that the lack of labor mobility

during that period added to the balance-of-payments problem. As a matter of fact, the reason

why deficit countries chose to implement sterilization policies, that is, expansive monetary

policies, was the recessive impact of the automatic adjustment mechanism. The return to the

equilibrium position indeed lay on the fall in domestic prices. But the fact that wages were

rigid downwards slowed down the adjustment process and brought about an increase in

unemployment, worsened by the fall in national spending that followed the current account

deficit. The countries that enjoyed surpluses, as for them, aimed at reducing inflation

pressures that came with the increase in money supply caused by the current account surplus.

If migration movements would have been free, as they were before World War I, it is likely

that the increase in emigration would have reduced the need to use sterilization policies.

Thus, Figure 11 shows the possible repercussions of labor flows in the adjustment

process of the interwar gold exchange standard. As previously, the United Kingdom and the

United States run current account imbalances and international reserves moves from the

former to the latter. But now, British workers have the option to migrate to the United States.

The first upshot of the migration process is an increase in the British wage level, owing to less

competition in the labor market. As a result, prices increase, which offsets the deflationary

impact of the reduction in the money supply. Moreover, the departure of part of the labor

force originates a decrease in aggregate demand that is added to the impact of the fall in

money supply. But, labor outflows contribute to reducing British unemployment, and then the

repercussions of the decrease in demand are not as important as before. The consequence is

that monetary authorities do not have to worry about deflation and unemployment since the

effects of capital and labor outflows on prices cancel each other out, and the fall in demand is

compensated (and also caused) by emigration. Therefore, the use of sterilization policies

seems useless, or at least less necessary than without migration movements. By the same

token, labor inflows in the United States would probably help to avoid inflation thanks to a

higher degree of competition on the labor market, which allows the Fed not to interfere on

capital markets. Then, demand expenditure could increase thanks to the rise in money supply

and the arrival of immigrants. Consequently, imports grow in the United States whereas they

decrease in the United Kingdom, which means that the demand for British products increases

while the demand for American products fells, fostering the return to the current account

equilibrium in both nations.

32

Figure 11

The role of labor mobility in the adjustment process of the gold exchange standard

United Kingdom United States

overvaluation of the pound/dollar

demand for American products > demand for

British products

current account deficit current account surplus

reserve flows reserve

outflows

reserve

inflows

labor

outflows

labor flows labor

inflows

↓ money

supply

↑ money

supply

↑wages ↓ wages

↓ prices ↓ demand ↑prices ↓ prices ↑ demand ↑ prices

↓ imports

↑ imports

↑ exports

↓ exports

current account equilibrium

33

The limits of capital as an alternative adjustment mechanism

Capital mobility theoretically represents an alternative to international migration in the

current account adjustment process: short-term capital flows enable the financing of

imbalances in deficit countries, while long-term movements contribute to boosting the

production capacity and the technological progress of the receiving countries, thereby

enhancing the competitiveness of their external sector. Thus, before World War I, capital

mobility was high and then took an active part in the smooth functioning of the classical gold

standard. On the contrary, the interwar period was marked by the existence of low levels of

capital mobility, which constituted a strong impediment to the stability of the gold exchange

standard. Actually, while the correlation coefficient between domestic saving and investment

was, on average, 0.50 during the period 1880-1913 (0.37 during the decade 1904-1913), it

was 0.81 between 1918 and 1939, which according to the financial integration indicator

designed by Feldstein and Horioka (1980) is a confirmation of the strong movement of

“financial disintegration” (Flandreau and Rivière, 1999) that occurred after World War I,

especially during the 1930s (Figure 12).

Figure 12

Financial integration: 1880-1939

1933

1937

1931

1927

1921

1918

1913

1911

1903

1893

18911881

1889

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

1880

1883

1886

1889

1892

1895

1898

1901

1904

1907

1910

1913

1916

1919

1922

1925

1928

1931

1934

1937

Cor

rela

tion

coe

ffic

ient

Note: Financial integration is measured by the correlation coefficient between domestic saving and investment. The lower the correlation coefficient, the higher the degree of capital mobility. Source: Flandreau and Rivière (1999).

34

This breakdown in the financial integration process was fundamentally due to the

implementation of capital control policies after 1914. France and Germany, in particular,

tried, from the beginning of the conflict, to prevent gold withdrawals from their territory. This

is the reason why public authorities of both belligerent countries not only suspended the

convertibility of their currency into gold, but also, in the image of Great Britain, forbade gold

outflows. With the spread of the conflict and notably with the entry of the United States into

the war, capital controls (and not only on gold exports) increased: European countries aimed

to avoid the worsening of their currency depreciation, while the American government saw a

way to prevent that international lending finance the enemy’ war effort. At the end of the war,

heavily indebted countries were subject to the temptation of using seignoriage, which

produced speculative movements that the European governments tried to stop by

strengthening the controls.

The stabilization of most of the European economies a few years after the end of the

war and the return of the main currencies in the gold standard system in the middle of the

1920s furthered the progressive elimination of capital controls and then the recovery of

financial flows on an international scale (Obstfeld et Taylor, 1998). But, the American stock

exchange crash in 1929 had international repercussions that entailed the implementation of

new barriers to capital mobility: “The world economy went from globalized to almost autarkic

in the space of a few decades. Capital flows were minimal, international investment was

regarded with suspicion, and international prices and interest rates fell completely out of

synchronization. Global capital (along with finance in general) was demonized, and seen as a

principal cause of the world depression of the 1930s.” (Obstfeld and Taylor, 2003: 125).

Actually, the liberalization of capital flows itself originated the rapid transmission of the crisis

worldwide: American authorities reacted to the perturbations that affected Wall Street by

increasing their interest rates, which forced other countries, concerned about maintaining the

stability of their currency, to rise their own interest rates in order to avoid massive capital

outflows.

But, faced with the extent of speculative movements on both sides of the Atlantic and

after the international exchange crisis that followed the collapse of the Austrian Credit-Anstalt

in 1931, capital controls were established in most of the occidental countries and first of all in

Germany. The international conference held in London in July 1931 in order to prevent a new

depreciation of the mark had indeed formed the “Standstill Committee”, whose mission

consisted in studying the feasibility of a project aiming at immobilizing capitals in Germany:

“The decision to set up the Standstill Committee was to have unforeseen, far-reaching

35

consequences. It was to represent a definite turning point in the development of Western

civilization, which so far had been based on respect for contracts and monetary freedom; and

it would be possible to follow an internal inflationary policy without depreciating the

currency. In fine, it was the first step toward the institution of exchange control.”(Rueff,

1964: 11-12).

These measures then spread because the governments at the time did not consider

other riposte to capital flight than financial movement controls: “As in the past, applied

controls consist in defending or stabilizing exchange rate quotation, in having an influence on

foreign loans, etc. But, control policies also aim to isolate the domestic economy in order to

be able to implement recovery measures. […] National policies aiming at steering investment

flows by sectors therefore come with controls that permit to keep significant interest

differentials. Thus, governments can apply autonomous objectives. This is the ‘Big

Transformation’.” (Flandreau and Rivière, 1999: 25).

Resurgence of protectionism and rise in unemployment

In view of the impossibility for public authorities to cope with economic disturbances

and current account imbalances, most of the countries decided to compensate the lack of labor

and capital mobility by resorting to trade protectionism. Against this backdrop, the signature

of the Smoot-Hawley Act by President Hoover, on the 17th of June of 1930 constituted the

starting point of the resurgence of protectionism on a world scale. Actually, whereas

American tariffs represented, on average, 31.3% of total imports during the period 1920-1925

and 40.3% in 1926-1930, they came to 55.3% during the years 1931-1933 (59.1% in 1932).

Such a rise ran counter to the conclusions of the international conference held in Geneva on

May 1927, in the course of which participating countries committed themselves to a “tariff

peace” (Bairoch, 1997). American trade partners felt betrayed and decided, as a reprisal, to

increase their own tariffs and/or to implement quotas on some American products (Jones,

1934).

Spain represents one of the most significant examples of the international reaction to

the Smoot-Hawley tariff, since it adopted the Wais tariff on July 22, that is, barely one month

after the American tariff. Car imports were primarily targeted: 473 American cars were

imported in 1932, as against 7,415 in 1920, which corresponds to a drop by 94%. In the same

way, Italy intended to protect the Fiat company by adopting a tariff on American cars, whose

price hence increased by about 135%. Canada, as for it, implemented on September 17, 1930

36

the Canadian Emergency Tariff that brought about a rise by 50% of most of the tariffs. The

upshot was a decrease by half of the imports proceeding from the United States. Finally,

Switzerland launched a boycott campaign that entailed a significant reduction in imports of

American products. After this first wave of reprisals, international trade was already seriously

hit, but the entry of France and the United Kingdom in the trade war precipitated the

international crisis. Actually, the former opted for a quota policy that aimed more specifically

at American firms, while the latter increased its tariffs and developed an “Imperial

Preference” policy. At the same time, several countries, including France and Spain,

transformed cereal imports into State monopoly. In that respect, agricultural protectionism

was one of the most important at the time, which contributed to worsening the situation of the

main cereal-exporting countries, i.e. primarily Argentina and the United States. The

consequences of such protectionist policies are well known: international trade considerably

dropped (see Figure 13) and the economic crisis grew worse.

Figure 13

International trade: January 1929 – March 1933

1932 1933193119301929

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

3500

Janu

ary

Apr

il

July

Oct

ober

Janu

ary

Apr

il

July

Oct

ober

Janu

ary

Apr

il

July

Oct

ober

Janu

ary

Apr

il

July

Oct

ober

Janu

ary

Note: The y-axis represents monthly total imports for 75 countries in millions of American dollars. Source: Kindleberger (1986).

37

At the same time that the international crisis and the protectionist policies developed,

unemployment raised in most of the western countries. Indeed, the development of border

controls and the slowdown in international movements meant that unemployed persons had to

stay in their home country, which furthered the excess labor supply. It is also likely that the

implementation of unemployment insurance mechanisms in some European countries during

the interwar period contributed to raising the unemployment rate (see Section II), as in

England where the amount of unemployed persons was permanently above one million

between 1919 and 1940. This would explain non only the increase in cyclical unemployment

during economic crises, but also the development of structural unemployment from the

beginning of the 1920s (Table 7): “It is normal that the two countries where the 1920s were

negative on the economic level, that is, Germany and the United Kingdom, were

characterized by higher unemployment than before the war. But, what is significant is that the

phenomenon affected many countries. In fact, in addition to the case of the United States, a

‘low unemployment country’, only Belgium and Switzerland escaped from the appearance of

what it is possible to call structural unemployment.” (Bairoch, 1997: 48).

Table 7

The evolution of the average unemployment rate

1920-1929 1930-1938

Austria 5.91 12.8 Belgium 1.52 8.7 Denmark 8.1 10.9 Finland 1.6 4.1 France 1.73 3.54 Germany 3.9 8.8 Italy 1.75 4.8 Netherlands 2.3 8.7 Norway 5.62 8.1 Sweden 3.2 5.6 Switzerland 0.45 3.0 United Kingdom 7.5 11.5 United States 4.8 18.2 Notes: 1: 1924-1929; 2: 1921-1929; 3: 1921, 1926 and 1929; 4: 1931, 1936 and 1938; 5: only 1929. Source: Maddison (1991).

38

Of course, the 1929 crisis and the use of non-cooperative policies that came with it

contributed to strongly increase unemployment in affected countries. Thus, the American

unemployment rate was 8.7% in 1930, as against 3.6%, on average, during the period 1923-

1929. After the collapse of the economy at the beginning of the 1930s (-8.9% in 1930, -7.7%

in 1931, and -13.2% in 1932), it reached 23.6% in 1932 and 24.7% in 1933 (its historic

record). In the same way, many European countries registered unemployment rates above

10% during the years 1931-1933: 10.2% in Norway (1931), 11.9% in Belgium (1932), 15.3%

in the United Kingdom (1932), 16% in Denmark (1932), 16.3% in Austria (1933), 17.2% in

Germany (1932)… Australia (19.1% in 1932) and Canada (19.3% in 1933) were also affected

by the increase in world unemployment. As a result, contrary to the three or four decades that

preceded World War I, when mass migration permitted to absorb surplus labor, the Great

Depression did not offer many alternatives to job searchers, who came up against the anti-

migration legislations implemented all over the planet after 1918.

The fall of the gold exchange standard

Since the moment when the absorption capacity of the American labor market

vanished, labor mobility lost its regulation function and the stability of exchange rates became

a more difficult objective to reach. At the same time, wage flexibility and capital mobility,

which represents traditional substitutes to labor mobility in the adjustment process of fixed

exchange rate regimes, were strongly limited. To deal with the Great Depression, many

countries that tried to maintain the stability of their currency opted for protectionist policies,

but the only result was the worsening of the international crisis. Consequently, unemployment

rates dramatically increased and the defense of the gold exchange standard was economically,

socially and politically untenable. Obviously, the triggering of the crack of 1929 sped up the

decay process of the interwar international monetary system.

Thus, after the first attacks against Wall Street in October 1929 and the bursting of the

speculative bubble on American markets, European markets became affected and 1931,

notably, was a year of bank runs and massive capital withdrawals. Faced with speculation

movements, several Central Banks were induced to suspend the international convertibility of

their currency. The Bank of England, in particular, had to abandon the convertibility of the

pound on September 21, 1931, which caused ipso facto the depreciation of the British

currency. Afterwards, some twenty other countries opted for giving up the stability of the

exchange rate. When, in 1933, the new elected American President, Franklin Roosevelt,

39

decided to devaluate the dollar, the trade partners of the United States, including the “gold

bloc” countries, had no other option than to renounce to the prevailing monetary system. In

1937, the gold exchange standard did not exist anymore (Figure 14).

Figure 14

Number of countries in the gold exchange standard: 1921-1937

68

10

13

24

28

37

4446 45

23

14

108

6

0

47

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

45

50

1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 1928 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937

Sources: Eichengreen (1992 and 1998).

Faced with the impossibility of absorbing the shock of the Great Depression through

labor and capital mobility, public authorities preferred to abandon the objective of exchange

rate stability rather than to look for a concerted international solution. As a matter of fact,

flexible exchange rates helped to release the constraint that rested on the shoulders of Central

Banks. They also contributed to improving economic conditions in concerned countries, as

shown by Table 8, which presents economic performances of the United States and the main

European nations one year before the end of the convertibility, the year itself, and three years

after.

40

1

Table 8

End of the gold exchange standard and economic performance

End GES GDP growth rate Unemployment rate

Year t t-1 t t+1 t+2 t+3 t-1 t t+1 t+2 t+3

United States 1933 -13.2 -2.1 7.7 7.6 14.2 23.5 24.7 21.6 20.0 16.8

Austria 1933 -10.3 -3.3 0.9 1.9 3.0 13.7 16.3 16.1 15.2 15.2

Belgium 1935 -0.8 6.2 0.7 1.3 -2.3 11.8 11.1 8.4 7.2 8.7

Denmark 1931 5.9 1.1 -2.6 3.2 3.0 7.0 9.0 16.0 15.4 11.0

France 1936 -2.5 3.8 5.8 -0.4 7.2 - 4.5 - 3.7 -

Germany 1931 -6.1 -10.2 -9.3 10.5 7.7 9.5 13.9 17.2 14.8 8.3

Italy 1934 -0.7 0.4 9.6 0.2 6.8 5.9 5.6 - - 5.0

Netherlands 1936 3.7 6.3 5.7 -2.4 6.8 11.2 11.9 10.5 9.9 -

Norway 1931 7.4 -7.8 6.7 2.4 3.2 6.2 10.2 9.5 9.7 9.4

Sweden 1931 2.1 -3.6 -2.7 1.9 7.6 3.3 4.8 6.8 7.3 6.4

Switzerland 1936 -0.4 0.3 4.8 3.8 -0.1 4.2 4.7 3.6 3.3 -

UK 1931 -0.7 -5.1 0.8 2.9 6.6 11.2 15.1 15.6 14.1 11.9

Sources: End gold exchange standard (GES): Eichengreen (1992); GDP growth rate: author’s calculations based on Maddison (2003); Unemployment rate: Maddison (1991) and Bairoch (1997).

In most of the cases, the return to flexible exchange rates came with a higher GDP

growth rate the same year (seven countries out of twelve) and/or the year that followed the

adoption of the measure (nine countries out of twelve). Sometimes, the change was dramatic

as in the United States (-13.2% in 1932, -2.1% in 1933; +7.7% in 1934) or in Norway (-7.8%

in 1931, +6.7% in 1932). Three years after the first devaluation, almost all the countries

(Belgium and Switzerland being the exception) had recovered positive growth rates. The

return to flexible exchange rates was also beneficial to unemployment rates, since they

noticeably decreased in the two or three years that followed the end of the gold exchange

standard. In fact, only Danish and Swedish unemployment rates were, three years after, above

the level they had the year of the devaluation. Yet, the unemployment level in most of the

countries was still quite high (in general, above 8%), which confirms that it had then became

more structural.

41

Even though, this improvement in economic performances is partly related to the

adoption of internal recovery policies, in particular the New Deal in the United States, the

return to exchange rate flexibility probably played a key role, since it fostered the return to the

equilibrium: “The problem was not that devaluation took place; it was that the practice was

not more widespread and that it did not prompt the adoption of even more expansionary

policies. Abandoning the gold standard allowed countries to regain their policy

independence. And by devoting some of that independence to policies of leaning against the

wind in currency markets, they were able to do so without allowing the foreign exchanges to

descend into chaos.” (Eichengreen, 1998: 90).

Conclusion

The brief experience of the gold exchange standard during the interwar period seems

to confirm the existence of a trade-off between labor mobility and exchange rate fluctuations

in the balance-of-payments adjustment process. The countries that opt for fixed exchange

rates need adjustment mechanisms to offset the loss of the exchange rate instrument. In the

absence of wage flexibility and capital mobility, international migration constitutes an

appropriate mechanism for solving both internal and external imbalances. In sending

countries, labor outflows contribute to reducing unemployment and also further the reduction

of current account deficits, since they imply a decrease in aggregate demand and then in

imports. In receiving countries, immigration enables to curb inflationary pressures at the same

time that it stimulates demand and thereby imports. The countries with flexible exchange

rates, as for them, can rely on the exchange rate flexibility to make the adjustment process

easier.

In that sense, the development of border controls after World War I, joint with the

adoption of social policies in many European nations, did not allow labor flows to play their

role of adjustment mechanism in the countries that chose to defend the stability of their

currency. Since during this period wage flexibility and capital mobility were also limited, the

economies that suffered the effects of the Great Depression had no other option, in a context

of economic war and increasing unemployment, than to abandon their fixed exchange rate

policy. In fact, trade protectionism was first used as an alternative to factor mobility, but the

outcome of such a strategy was counterproductive since it eventually resulted in a severe

contraction of the world trade and a dramatic rise in unemployment rates. On the contrary, the

42

return to the exchange rate flexibility fostered the return to growth and contributed to

lowering unemployment levels.

Does it mean that if labor had been freer to move the gold exchange standard would

have survived longer? It is rather difficult to answer this question since the crash of 1929

represents a chock that it is not easy to put aside in a counterfactual analysis. Yet it is possible

to provide some elements of response. First and foremost, it has been underscored in this

paper that many restrictive immigration policies were not adopted in a context of economic

recession, but rather of expansion. As a result, border controls produced a misallocation of

factors that probably slowed down the world economic development. Besides, the

underconsumption problem that partly led to the Great Depression of the 1930s could

probably have been mitigated by the increase in demand that traditionally comes with more

immigration. Moreover, labor flows, as seen in Section IV, would have saved the monetary

authorities from having to resort to counterproductive sterilization policies. Indeed, by

intervening on capital markets, central banks try to avoid inflation when there is a current

account surplus, and deflation in case of a deficit. Well, labor movements have precisely this

effect: emigration from deficit countries prevent wages and then prices from falling, since

there is less competition on the domestic labor market; conversely, labor inflows in surplus

countries contributes to reducing wage pressures, that is, inflation pressures. In addition, labor

mobility causes changes in aggregate demand that induce variations in imports and exports,

hence in current account positions. Finally, all the money that migrants send home also takes

part in the adjustment process, since remittances help to finance the current account deficit. In

that respect too, higher levels of international migration would have certainly made the

balance-of-payments adjustment easier and would have improved the functioning of the

interwar gold exchange standard.

43

References

Akerman, Sune (1976). “Theories and Methods of Migration Research.” From Sweden to America: A History of the Migration. Eds. Runblom, Harald and Hans Norman. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press. Bairoch, Paul (1997). Victoires et déboires: Histoire économique et sociale du monde du XVIe siècle à nos jours. Tome 3. Paris: Gallimard. Buchinagni, Norman and al. (1985). Continuous journey: A Social History of South Asians in Canada. Toronto: McClelland & Stewart. Castles, Stephen and Mark Miller (1998). The Age of Migration: International Population Movements in the Modern World. London: Macmillan Press. Collomp, Catherine (2003). “Labour Unions and the Nationalisation of Immigration Restriction in the United States, 1880-1924”. Migration Control in the North Atlantic World: The Evolution of State Practices in Europe and the United States from the French Revolution to the Inter-War Period. Eds. Fahrmeir, Andreas; Olivier Faron and Patrick Veil. New York, Oxford: Berghahn Books: 237-252. Daniels, Roger (1995). “The Growth of Restrictive Immigration Policies in the Colonies of Settlement”. The Cambridge Survey of World Migration. Ed. Cohen, Robin. Cambridge: University Press: 39-43. Dohse, Knuth (1981). Ausländische Arbeitnehmer und bürgerlicher Staat. Königstein: Hain. Eichengreen, Barry (1998). Globalizing Capital: A History of the International Monetary System. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Eichengreen, Barry (1992). Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression, 1919-1939. New York, Oxford: Oxford University Press. Eichengreen, Barry (1990). “International Monetary Instability Between the Wars: Structural Flaws or Misguised Policies?” The Evolution of the International Monetary System: How Can Efficiency and Stability Be Attained? Eds. Suzuki, Yoshio; Junichi Miyake and Mitsuaki Okabe. Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press: 71-116. Feldstein, Martin and Charles Horioka (1980). “Domestic Saving and International Capital Flows”. The Economic Journal 90.358: 314-329. Flandreau, Marc and Chantal Rivière (1999). “La Grande ‘Retransformation’ ? Contrôles de capitaux et intégration financière internationale, 1880-1996.” Economie internationale 78: 11-58. Flora, Peter (1983). State, Economy, and Society in Western Europe, 1815-1975. Vol I: The Growth of Mass Democracies and Welfare States. Frankfurt: Campus Verlag.

44

Gemery, Henry (1994). “Immigrants and Emigrants: International migration and the US labor market in the Great Depression”. Migration and the International Labor Market : 1850-1939. Eds. Hatton, Timothy and Jeffrey Williamson. Londres, New York: Routledge: 175-199. Hanes, Christopher (1993). “The Development of Nominal Wage Rigidity in the Late 19th Century.” American Economic Review 83.4: 732-756. Hatton, Timothy and Jeffrey Williamson (1994). “What Drove the Mass Migrations from Europe in the Late Nineteenth Century?” Population and Development Review 20.4: 533-559. James, Harold (2001). The End of Globalization: Lessons from the Great Depression. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. Jones, Joseph (1934). Tariff Retaliation : Repercussions of the Smooth-Hawley Bill. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press. Jones, Maldwyn Allen (1992). American Immigration. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press. Kaspi, André (1986). “Qu’est-ce qu’un Américain?” L’Histoire 91: 10-25. Keynes, John Maynard (1925). The Economic Consequences of Mr. Churchill. London: Hogarth Press. Khoudour-Castéras, David (2005a). “International Adjustment under the Classical Gold Standard: The Migration Nexus.” Mimeo, University of California, Berkeley. Khoudour-Castéras, David (2005b). “The Impact of the Bismarck’s Social Legislation on German Emigration before World War I.” Mimeo, University of California, Berkeley. Khoudour-Castéras, David (2002). “Taux de change fixes et migrations internationales : L’étalon-or à l’aune de la théorie des zones monétaires optimales.” Revue de l’OFCE 82: 82-116. Kindleberger, Charles (1986). The World in Depression, 1929-1939. Berkeley, Los Angeles: University of California Press. Kirk, Dudley (1946). Europe’s Population in the Interwar Years. New York: Gordon and Breach. de Lepervanche, Marie (1975). “Australian immigrants, 1788-1940: Desired and Unwanted.” Eds. Wheelwright, Edward and Ken Buckley. Essays in the Political Economy of Australian Capitalism. Volume I. Sydney: Australia and New Zealand Book Company. Light, Ivan (1972). Ethnic Enterprise in America: Business and Welfare Among Chinese, Japanese, and Blacks. Berkeley: University of California Press. Maddison, Angus (1991). Dynamic Forces in Capitalist Development: A Long-Run Comparative View. Oxford, New York: Oxford University Press.

45

Maddison Angus (1995). L'économie mondiale 1820-1992 : analyse et statistiques. Paris: Center for development studies, OECD. Mariage-Strauss, Annie (2002). Les Etats-Unis face à l’immigration. Paris: Ellipses. Markus, Andrew (1979). Fear and Hatred: Purifying Australia and California, 1850-1901. Sydney: Hale & Iremonger. Mitchell, Brian (2003a). International Historical Statistics: Europe, 1750-2000. London: Macmillan Reference Ltd, 5th ed. Mitchell, Brian (2003b). International Historical Statistics: The Americas, 1750-2000. London: Macmillan Reference Ltd, 5th ed. Mitchell, Daniel (1985). “Wage Flexibility: Then and Now.” Industrial Relations 24.2: 266-79. Mundell, Robert (1961). “A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas.” American Economic Review 51.4: 657-665. Nurkse, Ragnar (1944). International Currency Experience. Geneva: League of Nations. O’Brien, Anthony Patrick (1989). “A Behavioral Explanation for Nominal Wage Rigidity during the Great Depression.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 104.4: 719-35. Obstfeld, Maurice and Alan Taylor (2003). “Globalization and Capital Markets.” Eds. Bordo, Michael; Alan Taylor and Jeffrey Williamson. Globalization in Historical Perspective. Chicago, London: The University of Chicago Press: 121-187. Obstfeld, Maurice and Alan Taylor (1998). “The Great Depression as a Watershed: International Capital Mobility over the Long Run.” Eds. Bordo, Michael; Claudia Goldin and Eugene White. The Defining Moment: The Great Depression and the American Economy in the Twentieth Century. Chicago, London: The University of Chicago Press: 353-402. O’Rourke, Kevin and Jeffrey Williamson (1999). Globalization and History. Cambridge, Massachussets and London, England: The MIT Press. Palyi, Melchior (1972). The Twilight of Gold, 1914-1936. Chicago: Henry Regnery Company. Roosevelt, Franklin (1932). Commonwealth Club Address. San Francisco, September 23: http://www.americanrhetoric.com/speeches/fdrcommonwealth.htm. Rueff, Jacques (1964). The Age of Inflation. Chicago: Gateway Editions. Henry Regnery Company. Timmer, Ashley and Jeffrey Williamson (1998). “Immigration Policy Prior to the Thirties: Labor Markets, Policy Interactions and Globalization Backlash.”

46

United States Department of Commerce (1925-1941). Statistical Abstract of the United States. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office. United States Immigration Commission (1911). Reports. 61st Congress, 3rd Session, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office. United States Immigration and Naturalization Service (2003). Statistical Yearbook of the Immigration and Naturalization Service, 2002. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office. Weil, Patrick (1991). La France et ses étrangers: l'aventure d'une politique de l'immigration de 1938 à nos jours. Paris: Calmann-Lévy. Williamson, Jeffrey (1996). “Globalization, Convergence and History”. Journal of Economic History 56.2: 277-306.


Recommended