+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return...

Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return...

Date post: 29-Jul-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 1 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
67
Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return Predictability Suresh Kumar Oad-Rajput a,* , Jianguo Chen a and Udomsak (Jeff) Wongchoti a a School of Economics and Finance, Massey University, Private Bag 11-222, Palmerston North, New Zealand Abstract We examine the interactions of the balance sheet growth information using factor analysis. We find that optimal corporate financing decisions embedded in multiple balance sheet accounts are five latent factors that are fundamental to the business value. The identified decisions are Financial Flexibility, Short-term Credit, Long-term Capital Investment, Convertible Debt Usage, and Preferred Stock Usage. Our evidence suggests that the other observed proxies of the corporate financing decision types suffer from missing variable bias. During the 1985-2009 research period, the new factors are robust predictors of future stock returns, firm profitability, and firm value. Predictability is complementary to the market controls but conflicting with the accounting controls and hold when controlling for global financial crises falling in our sample period. This draft: March, 2013 JEL classification: C38; G12; G32 Keywords: Asset Pricing Models, Multifactor Models, Accounting growth, Factor analysis, Cross-section stock returns, Corporate Finance Policies _____________ * Corresponding author is at: School of Economics and Finance, Massey University, Private Bag 11-222, Palmerston North, New Zealand. Tel.: +64 6 3569099, ext.:7368. E-mail: [email protected]
Transcript
Page 1: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and

Return Predictability

Suresh Kumar Oad-Rajputa,*

, Jianguo Chena and Udomsak (Jeff) Wongchoti

a

a School of Economics and Finance, Massey University, Private Bag 11-222, Palmerston North, New Zealand

Abstract

We examine the interactions of the balance sheet growth information using factor analysis. We find that

optimal corporate financing decisions embedded in multiple balance sheet accounts are five latent factors

that are fundamental to the business value. The identified decisions are Financial Flexibility, Short-term

Credit, Long-term Capital Investment, Convertible Debt Usage, and Preferred Stock Usage. Our evidence

suggests that the other observed proxies of the corporate financing decision types suffer from missing

variable bias. During the 1985-2009 research period, the new factors are robust predictors of future stock

returns, firm profitability, and firm value. Predictability is complementary to the market controls but

conflicting with the accounting controls and hold when controlling for global financial crises falling in

our sample period.

This draft: March, 2013

JEL classification: C38; G12; G32

Keywords: Asset Pricing Models, Multifactor Models, Accounting growth, Factor analysis, Cross-section

stock returns, Corporate Finance Policies

_____________

* Corresponding author is at: School of Economics and Finance, Massey University, Private Bag 11-222,

Palmerston North, New Zealand. Tel.: +64 6 3569099, ext.:7368. E-mail: [email protected]

Page 2: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

1

1. Introduction

What are the optimal corporate financing decisions? The investigation of this question is directed to the

large body of literature on investment and financing decision that depart from a perfect capital markets

setting of Modigliani and Miller (1958). A large part of this literature consists of static models that study

the corporate financing decision in a single point in time and dynamic models that give indirect inferences

by studying only outcome of the decision process. Besides, there is some effort targeted at behavioral

aspects (use of survey or clinical methods) and interaction among decision types.1 Overall these models

suggest many forms of the corporate financing decisions, such as operational investments, long-term

investments, debt-to-equity ratio, equity structure issues, and financial flexibility. Of note, these

theoretical frameworks and their supporting empirical evidences are conflicting and even differ from real

world settings. Thus, our understanding remains incomplete and conflicting, and it requires more

attention.

The objective of this paper is to offer new insights into firms’ financing and investment decisions by

recognizing that the outcomes of these decisions are reflected in the shifts of their financial positions (the

balance sheet).2 The real challenge lies in the identification of the interactive relations of the shifts in the

accounting numbers to decipher the optimal number and type of corporate financing decision they

represent. In order to understand more accurately the corporate financing decisions, we seek to address

certain questions. How the balance sheet information content interact? Does this interaction help to

identify some common movements? How to decompose the information content based on observed

1 See, for example, Myers (1974), Jensen and Meckling (1976), Myers (1977), Myers and Majluf (1984), Dotan and

Ravid (1985), Dammon and Senbet (1988), Parrino and Weisbach (1999), Barclay and Smith (1995b), Mehran et al.

(1999), Rajan and Zingles (1995), Mello and Parsons (1992), Mello et al. (1995), Fries et al. (1997), Ericsson

(2000), Mauer and Ott (2000), Goldstein et al. (2001), Parrino et al. (2005), Baker and Wurgler (2002), Ju et al.

(2003), Welch (2004), Morellec (2004), Leary and Roberts (2005), Mauer and Sarkar (2005), Flannery and Rangan

(2006), Brennan and Schwartz (1984), Mauer and Triantis (1994), Leland (1998), Moyen (2007), Titman and

Tsyplakov (2007), La Porta et al. (1998; Porta et al., 1997), Graham et al. (2001), and Tuffano (2001), among

others. 2 refer the Statement of Financial Accounting Concept No. 1 that defines objectives of the financial reporting and

identifies the balance sheet statement being the important feature of the financial reporting.

Page 3: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

2

commonalities into basic corporate financing decision types? Finally, how do these decision types align

with the theoretical models?

We depart from the literature that seek to find the determinants of the corporate financing decisions and

provide a way forward to overcome the problem of limited attention that arise with sub-optimal use of

observed accounting information as proxy for certain corporate financing decisions (Hirshleifer et al.,

2004). In fact, we assume that a single or pre-determined lump of accounting items cannot be

representative of certain decision type. Because, when we make a decision and the result of

implementation could be recorded in many accounts of an accounting book. The double entry

bookkeeping makes the information about a certain dimension buried in multiple accounting balances. On

the other hand, one account could be used to keep track of many different business activities. For

example, a cash account balance is influenced by the net business profits, it may also be caused by the net

investment activities. We have also noticed that the double entry accounting rule may produce some

additional information by separating the cash balance into different components. If the component of cash

account change is always moving together with the operating business incomes (Owner’s Equity), it

might be an indication of business profits. And, if another part of the cash balance change is always

moving together with the change of working capital or fixed assets that may be a good signal of

investment expenditure. These types of moving together regularly or most of times may be a good

indication of the business decision types we discussed above. If that is the case then the individual

decision type be represented by multiple accounting items and all items are expected to follow the similar

movements and represent same decision across the time.

In order to find these basic types of business activities we have used an ideal tool which is called factor

analysis. The factor analysis model takes into account the common variance and has been widely used in

finance literature (Abarbanell et al., 2003; Bushee, 1998; Pinches and Mingo, 1973; Sorensen, 2000).3 To

provide further guidance on the use of factor analysis, we know that all of the business activities are

3 See., section 2 for detailed discussion on factor analysis.

Page 4: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

3

recorded in a business accounting book, and the accounting balance changes contain all of the business

information. If we found that a group of accounting ratios are stably (in a reasonably long period) moving

together, we may categorize this group as the result of a certain type of business decision. Factor analysis

is such a mathematical technique to identify the “most” important common movements among a long list

of variables.

We see no data mining concern in this research due to manifold reasons: First, we only apply factor

analysis on the balance sheet growth variables (X terms) not on market values or potential dependent

variables (Y terms). Second, the factor analysis is used to produce annual factors instead of whole period

factors that remove any data mining concerns in subsequent analysis that use the identified decision types

as independent variables. Third, subsequent return predictability test, the models are built on publicly

available information about all common stocks. Finally, there is no selection bias in selecting the balance

sheet growth items as inputs to the model as we follow strictly the basic assumptions of the model.4

One of the key findings to use of factor analysis on all the accounting ratios shown in the balance sheet

and in supplementary balance sheet statements for a period of 1985 to 2009 is that five factors (common

movements) contain about 70% of all of the accounting ratio changes.5 In another word, the information

shown by the five resulting factors is equivalent to the information shown in whole balance sheet ratios

(plus some supplementary statements). Making the result more interesting is the resulting five factors are

well aligned with the major corporate financing decisions shown in prior theoretical and empirical

literature. The identified decision types are Financial Flexibility (FIN_FLEX), Short-term Credit

(ST_CREDIT), Long-term Capital Investment (LT_INV), Convertible Debt Usage (CVT_DEBT) and

Preferred Stock Usage (PSK_USE).6

4 See., section 2 for detailed discussion on research method.

5 We convert the level balance sheet items to growth variables for our research following Chen et al. (2011) and

Lyandres et al. (2008). 6 For simplicity, in subsequent discussion the identified coporate decision types are written as the ‘new factors’.

Page 5: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

4

We label an individual factor based upon the first several accounting ratios included in the list of the

factor, it is highly possible that the other less important (less loads) accounting ratios have the function

finely tuning the measure of the particular factor. The argument is supported by the observation that most

accounting ratios included in a factor could easily be explained by the factor decision. It is also supported

by the factor analysis that the annual factors produced are very stable, the top five components of first and

second factor are always same and top three components of other factors are always same in nature

throughout the whole sample period. The only difference is the ranking position of the second to fifth

factor could be different, the first factor is always the same.7

Specifically, FIN_FLEX comprises mainly of shifts in common equity financing along with cash and

equivalents and invested capital. The components of FIN_FLEX proxy for both investment and financing

flexibility, the close substitutes (Gamba and Triantis, 2008) and offer an integrated measure of financial

flexibility.8 The ST_CREDIT is comprised of shifts in short-term financing (current liabilities and debt in

current liabilities) that proxy for the firm’s operating business growth. The LT_INV factor consists of

changes in the long-term capital investment (e.g. Fixed assets, long-term debt, and deferred taxes and

investment credit) and are considered to be the strongest investment growth measures (Cooper et al.,

2008; Titman et al., 2010). The next factor, CVT_DEBT represents the shifts in the convertibility of bond

and equity and may proxy for firms’ operational risk. The firms with high agency cost of debt due to the

presence of long-term debt and lower credit quality use these securities (Bodie and Taggart, 1978; Doukas

and Pantzalis, 2003). Finally, PSK_USE refers to the shifts in issuance of preferred stock, the measure

may relate to firms with poor profitability and high debt ratios (Howe and Lee, 2006). It is possible that

firms issue preferred stocks to avoid common equity issuance or breach their debt capacity.

7 See, section 3 for detailed discussion on the new five factors.

8 Denis (2011) argues that “financial flexibility refers to the ability to respond in a timely and value-maximizing

manner to unexpected changes in the firm’s cash flows or investment opportunity set.” Marchica and Mura (2010)

argue “since there is no well-defined measure of flexibility in the literature, this is an unobservable factor that

depends largely on managers’ assessment of future growth options.”

Page 6: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

5

To provide further guidance on the role of the new factors, we examine separately the relation between

these factors with future stock returns, firm value, and firm profitability. We extend the particular line of

research that document that accounting variable can predict the stock returns and offer a number of

interesting results.9 This large body of literature documents that on aggregate the accounting variables

negatively predict stock returns and the firms that invest more earn lower future stock returns (Baker et

al., 2003; Polk and Sapienza, 2009; Titman et al., 2004). The focus of our empirical analysis is not about

the potential explanations of negative relation or earning lower stock returns, but mainly on the ability of

our new factors for return predictability. It is critical to note that the above factors are not governed by

stock returns in their construction. We also make sure that the information about the new factors is

available prior the return predictability tests.

This article uses data from listed common stocks in the U.S. from 1985 to 2009 to run Fama and MacBeth

(1973) cross-sectional regressions and finds that for the whole sample except PSK_USE all new factors

show the significant negative relation with the future stock returns. The preferred stock growth

(PSK_USE) factor shows the positive but insignificant relation with future stock returns. We further find

that the factors’ return predictability remains strong even after controlling for risk (size and book-to-

market variables), return momentum, profitability, and other corporate capital investment measures (the

total asset growth, the cumulative accruals, accounting accruals, and investment-to-assets). These results

hold even after controlling for all the financial crisis falling in our research period.

For potential size effect, following Fama and French (2008) we run Fama and MacBeth (1973) cross-

sectional regressions for large, small, and micro stock portfolios. Consistent with Fama and French (2008)

and Titman et al., (2010) we find weak return predictability by total asset growth and our latent growth

factors for large stock as compared to small and micro stocks. The PSK_USE appears to be highly

9 Ou and Penman (1989), Holthausen and Larcker (1992), Lev and Thiagarajan (1993), Abarbanell and Bushee

(1997), Piotroski (2000), Sloan (1996), Spiess and Affleck-Graves (1999), Richardson and Sloan (2003), Fairfield,

Whisenant, and Yohn (2003), Hirshleifer, Hou, Teoh, and Zhang (2004), Titman, Wei, and Xie (2004), Daniel and

Titman (2006), Bradshaw, Richardson, and Sloan (2006), Lyandres, Sun, and Zhang (2008), Fama and French

(2008), Pontiff and Woodgate (2008), Xing (2008), Cooper, Gulen, and Schill (2008), Chen, Novy-Marx, and Zhang

(2011).

Page 7: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

6

significantly positive related to subsequent future returns for large and micro firms but significant

negative relation to small stocks. The size effect tests suggest that whole period the negative relationship

between these new factors and the future stock returns is size specific. Among five factors only

FIN_FLEX and LT_INV are able to maintain the relationship. Collectively, our return predictability

evidence for different size firms implies that the value impact of managers’ choice of corporate financing

policies differs with firm size.

In our trading strategy based upon buying the lowest Latent Factors decile and selling short the highest

Latent Factors decile, the FIN_FLEX is profitable in 20 years, the ST_CREDIT is profitable in 17 years,

the LT_INV is profitable in 19 years, the CVT_DEBT is profitable in 14 years, and PSK_USE is

profitable in 13 out of the 25 years in the sample. The mean annual or monthly abnormal returns on

CVT_DEBT and PSK_USE ranked extreme decile is quite similar so their hedge (low-minus-high)

almost converges to zero. This is probably due to the similar level of positive profitability and firm size

across two extreme deciles. The mean equal-weighted annual buy-and-hold returns spread for

FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT, LT_INV, CVT_DEBT, and PSK_USE for whole sample are 15.2%, 6.1%,

10.1%, -1.5%, and -1.4% respectively.10

We also show the mean equal (value) weighted monthly

abnormal returns for two extreme decile portfolios and their hedge (low minus high) portfolio for first,

second, and third year for three capitalization (large, small, and micro) portfolios and a portfolio that does

not contain micro stocks (All but Micro).

In our further robustness test, we find that the industry returns are better explained by latent growth

factors than other compatible factors. The latent factors are important in certain industries; most of the

other accounting factors can be replaced by the latent factors. Similar to capitalization based regression

results the negative relationship between the latent factors (including other accounting measures) and

future returns is not stable across industries and even vary across annual cross-sections. Finally, in other

robustness tests we find the new latent factors as robust determinants of firm profitability and firm value.

10

In table 5 we present results for capitalization based portfolios but not for whole sample.

Page 8: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

7

Overall, our empirical results suggest that the newly identified factors are optimal proxies of corporate

finance decisions that represent the most of the variation in the complete balance sheet information

content. These factor decisions can better capture the variations in the firms’ stock returns than the

predetermined accounting growth measures. Conventional accounting growth measures such as total asset

growth, cumulative accruals and accounting accruals suffer from missing variable bias. For example, the

ASSETG measure is the aggregate of the major items in the balance sheet but miss out other associated

items. This results in the missing variable bias.11

To this we argue that each individual latent growth

factor in our analysis is an aggregation of all associated aspects relating to specific types of corporate

financing policies. For the same reason, our first three factors (FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT, and LT_INV)

present true decomposition of the so called overall asset investment growth measure (ASSETG). Besides,

we find that financial flexibility measure (FIN_FLEX) appears to be the most important component of the

ASSETG in its return generating effects.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we discuss the data and methodology, where

the present account of data samples, descriptive statistics, and research method. Section 3 provide

discussion on the new factors. Section 4 presents the results for growth rates, and returns to growth

portfolios in event time, annual buy-and-hold returns by year, and cross-sectional tests of return

predictability. Section 5 reports the further robustness tests including industry effect, time effect, firm

profitability and firm value. Section 6 concludes.

2. Data and methodology

2.1. Data Sample

Our research is solely US based and includes all firms listed on AMEX, NYSE and NASDAQ. There

are two data sources for the empirical analysis of this paper. The fiscal year balance sheet and income

11

Fama-French (2008) argue that the total asset growth effect is of secondary importance as it cannot be observed in

large cap firms. At the same time, Chan et al., (2007) show that asset growth takes a variety of forms like growth in

cash, current assets, or long-term assets. And, Cao (2011) shows that, cash and operating liabilities do not contribute

to the total asset growth effect.

Page 9: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

8

statement data is obtained from the COMPUSTAT database for all firms. The market data for prices,

returns, trading volume, permno numbers, sic codes, and shares outstanding is obtained from the CRSP

database for listed stocks. Our COMPUSTAT data cover the twenty five year period from 1985 to 2009.

In case of balance sheet data, firms having no total-asset data are excluded from the analysis. Information

embedded within database codes is re-estimated using accounting formulas for calculation of particular

items and replaced accordingly. Similarly, income statement data are subject to availability for Sales

(Net). In case of CRSP data, we download monthly data for the 1984 to 2011 period.

The datasets obtained from both sources are merged by using PERMNO and CUSIP. In order to

construct the growth of individual asset/liability item of balance sheet, we require the firms to have at

least two years of observations. The growth rates are estimated for fiscal years “t-2” to “t-1”. Following

the general practice in investment literature, we exclude the financial and utilities firms from our data

sample (e.g. Stocks with four digits SIC Code 6000-6999 and 4900-4999).12

We calculate the market

equity at June of “t-1” for the firm size. The market equity at December is estimated for calculating book-

to-market ratio at the end of year “t-1”. For estimation of book value we follow Fama and French (1992).

Thus, the final data sample contains 821736 firm-month observations that are quite large for our research

period. Before factor analysis all variables are winsorized at 1st and 99th percentiles to mitigate the

potential outliers affects.13

2.2. Research method

2.2.1. Data construction

Suppose there are N=f {I1, I2, I3, …, In} business decision types and each business decision type In=f

{b1, b2, b3, b3, …, bn} is a function of bn the balance sheet elements. The every bn item of In decision types

is expected to have significant correlation with every other candidate item to be representative of

particular business decision type. Alternatively, the elements of a balance sheet that proxy certain

12

The cases where shares outstanding are negative or zero are also excluded. In order to calculate the book equity

for book-to-market ratio, we delete the firms with negative and zero book equity. 13

For winsorization of 1% at both tails, we follow Butler, Cornaggia, Grullon, and Weston (2011), Baxamusa (2011), Sullivan and Zhang (2011), and Teoh, Welch and Wang (1998) and many other in literature.

Page 10: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

9

decision type are expected to follow the same movements or movements in systematic shifts across the

time. Thus, the consistency of membership makes each individual business decision type independent or

orthogonal.

The individual bn item is further converted into growth variable Xi, t that is the ratio of change in bn items

from time ‘t’ and time ‘t-1’ and the lagged total assets (Total Assett-1).

Xi, t = (bi, t - bi, t-1) /Total Assett-1. (1)

Where, bi, t stands for the balance sheet item i at time t and bi, t-1 is the lagged balance sheet item

for the same firm. We winsorized the Xi, t at 99 percentile and 1 percentile to remove outliers and to make

the data smooth. These growth variables are then standardized by fixing their mean at zero and standard

deviation as one. The purpose of standardization is to align all the variables to same scale. This removes

any doubt of mistake that may arise of different units of the variables (Jobson, 1992). In further regression

analysis, standardized variables help to compare the relation of each independent variable on the

dependent variable (Joseph F. Hair et al., 1998).

2.2.2. Factor analysis model

2.2.2.1. Model characteristics and relevant literature

Subsequent to standardization we employ factor analysis to growth variables that helps to reduce

the dimensional space by identifying the common movements into few representative factors. Factor

analysis determines groupings of objects of interest without prior associations and brings high internal

homogeneity (within the group) and high external heterogeneity (between groups) (Pinches et al., 1975).

Tsay (2005) observes that the number of factors is more well-defined in statistical factor models than the

way three factors obtained using Fama-French (1993) approach. According to Fabozzi and Markowitz

(2011) the latent (unobserved) factors are preferred because the “… observed factors may be measured

with errors or have been already anticipated by investors… factor analysis… explain complex

phenomena through a small number of basic factors”. They further mention that under arbitrage pricing

Page 11: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

10

theory (APT) framework given by Ross (1976), “ the return covariance matrix formula hold regardless of

whether the factors are observable or latent”, whereas, for orthogonally rotated new factors, we have to

have identity covariance matrix.

The motivation for using factor analysis stems from our assumption cum objective that there are

certain optimal corporate financing decisions that are embedded in several balance sheet entries (due to

the double entry bookkeeping) who share the common variance and if their movement identified correctly

can produce the basic decision types that are fundamental to the business. For the similar objective the

researchers have applied the factor analysis in a variety of financial research settings. It has been applied

to to predict the industrial bond ratings (Pinches and Mingo, 1973). To investigate the institutional

investor’s influence on the R&D investment behavior of corporate managers (Bushee, 1998). Author use

factor analysis for grouping up the nine variables into three factors, to be used for subsequent analysis.

Similarly, for investigating the institutional investor preferences and price pressures around spin-offs

(Abarbanell et al., 2003). They employ factor analysis to aggregate the 15 variables that describe the

investment preferences of institutional investors into 4 factors. Then, for investigating the characteristics

of firms that involve in mergers and acquisition (Sorensen, 2000). He uses factor analysis to group up

twenty two ratio variables into three factors. Additionally, the factor analysis processes employ the

correlational structure of the potential input information that coincides with the Subrahmanyam (2010)

argument that researchers needs to employ correlational structure amongst the variables in predicting the

stock returns.

2.2.2.2. The data mining concerns

Moreover, this technique may not pose any data mining concern as the research does not fall

under the definitions of data mining given by Black (1993). According to him, the researcher is doing

data mining, if he reports the t-statistics of only few significant variables, when majority of others do not

have the same significance. Then, the researcher is also doing data mining, if he chooses not to report all

results of analysis. Similarly, if researcher starts research by choosing topic to work on and follows the

Page 12: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

11

others in similar areas for the method. Finally, researcher finds any pattern in past security returns and

then designs his research. We see no data mining concern in this research due to manifold reasons: First,

we only apply factor analysis on the balance sheet growth variables (X terms) not on market values or

potential dependent variables (Y terms). Second, the factor analysis is used to produce annual factors

instead of whole period factors that remove any data mining concerns in subsequent analysis that use the

identified decision types as independent variables. Third, subsequent return predictability test, the models

are built on publicly available information about all common stocks. Finally, there is no selection bias in

selecting the balance sheet growth items as inputs to the model as we follow strictly the basic

assumptions of the model.

The factor analysis assumptions include small partial correlations among the input variables;

sampling adequacy of around 0.60 and a correlation cutoff of 0.45 (Joseph F. Hair et al., 1998). The

sampling adequacy of 0.50 is suggested for both the overall test and individual variable and 0.60 for

successful factor analysis. Even, correlations below 0.30 make factor analysis inappropriate (Joseph F.

Hair et al., 1998). Following above literature’s recommendation, variables which do not meet above

criteria are discarded from the analysis. Thus, final set of growth variables includes thirty seven variables.

This removal of variables is followed by the identification of a number of factors.

2.2.2.3. The basic model assumptions

The number of factors is generally obtained by looking at EIGENVALUES equal to one and

above one or by looking at the SCREE plot. But, this is not certain that we get an accurate number of

factors following above practice so it also depends on the researcher skills to get correct structure. The

correct factor structure requires at least three variables group together with distinct loadings for individual

factor. Then, selected factors are given orthogonal rotation with a principle component factor analysis

method to create final factor structure. Finally, we label factors based on the highest loadings of factor

constituent growth rates.

Page 13: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

12

3. Preliminary results on the factor analysis

The factor analysis results are given in Table 1, the model produces the five latent factors that

proxy for five optimal corporate financing decision types that are labelled as, FIN_FLEX (financial

flexibility), ST_CREDIT (short-term credit), LT_INV (long-term capital investment), CVT_DEBT

(convertible debt usage), and PSK_USE (preferred stock usage). These five latent factors together can

capture 70% of the common variation in the aggregate balance sheet (including supplementary items)

growth variable. The factors are extracted annually instead of the whole sample period for their suitability

for subsequent financial analysis. Any increase in the number of factors is not suitable for our data sample

because first it is adding no more than 3 to 5% in the explanatory power of each additional factor

annually. Second, the additional factor does not meet the basic assumptions of the model discussed above.

Finally, the scree plot indicates the five factors are adequate. The details of these new factors are

discussed in the following sub-section.

[Insert Table 1]

3.1. Discussion on the latent growth factors

The five factors and their component loads are shown in Table 1. In this section, we discuss the

construction of each factor to understand why the components have high loadings on that particular factor

and to get economic meaning out of that factor. Understanding of the components would help us to label

the factors. The labels should be able to convey the underlying economic meaning of the each factor. In

fact, we check the factor component values across each factor sorted deciles for strengthening the point

that components have a linear association with their factor and nonlinear to other factors. In turn we may

be able to relate each factor to known growth measures and other determinants of stock returns.

Subsequently, we also check the stability of each of the factors. For stability the component membership

needs to be stable across the time period for each factor.

Page 14: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

13

3.1.1. Financial Flexibility (FIN_FLEX)

From table 1, first factor FIN_FLEX has the highest weight on common equity-total, common

equity-liquidation, cash and equivalents, common equity-tangible (with weighting loads above 0.84), the

other important elements are current assets-total, invested capital, total assets, cash, and capital surplus

(with weighting loads above 0.45). The factor analysis helps to identify and aggregate all the associated

components of the financial flexibility so that there may be no missing variable bias. The dominant

components of common equity, current liquid assets, and invested capital growth indicates that they

represent the aggregate financial flexibility of a firm. The measure can offer important insights into the

corporate capital investment literature. It appears that managers seek the both equity and cash balances to

meet liquidity requirements to finance growth options with positive NPV. This possible fact may explain

the why cash holdings and common equity are highly correlated.

We think that finding of the FIN_FLEX makes it the important contribution to literature on

financial flexibility and capital structure. This measure has all possible attributes required to fit the ad-hoc

definition of financial flexibility. Denis (2011) argues that “financial flexibility refers to the ability to

respond in a timely and value-maximizing manner to unexpected changes in the firm’s cash flows or

investment opportunity set.” Marchica and Mura (2010) argue “since there is no well-defined measure of

flexibility in the literature, this is an unobservable factor that depends largely on managers’ assessment of

future growth options.” In fact, FIN_FLEX’s associated attributes are the financial slack or cash holding,

positive relation with the future investment opportunities, and it is unobserved in nature.

Further, FIN_FLEX is the always first factor almost in all the annual factor analysis models and

also explains the large part of the common variations of the balance sheet information content as

compared to other four factors. This finding is consistent with the Graham and Harvey (2001) that

financial flexibility is the most important determinant of capital structure. Although, it is not our quest but

FIN_FLEX may help address the DeAngelo and DeAngelo (2007) argument that financial flexibility is

missing link that is important to connect the capital structure theory with observed firm behavior observed

Page 15: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

14

by Graham and Harvey (2001). In fact, this factor offers the integrated measure of both financial and

investment flexibility, that are reported to be close substitutes (Faulkender and Wang, 2006; Gamba and

Triantis, 2008)).

Besides, FIN_FLEX may be linked to stock financing sub-component of the asset growth given

in Cooper, et al. (2008). But, it differs from stock financing that it does not take into account the preferred

stock’s growth, because preferred stocks and common equity have insignificant correlation (-0.05). The

preferred stock is represented by separate factor. Similarly, FIN_FLEX include liquid assets as major

components due to their strong association to common equity. Conversely, Cooper, et al. (2008) considers

the financial assets as separate components of the total asset growth.

3.1.2. Short-term credit (ST_CREDIT)

The short-term credit (ST_CREDIT) makes our second factor that has the highest weight on the

current liabilities-total, followed by liabilities-total and debt in current liabilities (with loads above 0.70).

The remaining elements are accounts payable, accounts receivable, total debt, notes payable, total assets,

current liabilities-others, inventory-total and current assets-total (all have weighting loads above 0.45).

The second factor is linked to the level of firms’ operating business growth thus consists of all

associated aspects of the short-term financing making it well-defined. According to Diamond (1991),

Chung (1993), and Doukas and Pantzalis (2003) large firms have higher short-term debt borrowing than

small firms, because higher-credit ratings of the larger firms have easier access to short-term borrowing

than smaller firms. Similarly, Easterwood and Kadapakkam (1994), Barclay and Smith (1995a), and

Doukas and Pantzalis (2003) find that larger firms have high information asymmetries that cause them to

issue more short-term debt. In further financial research this factor may help us to identify credible firms

to be part of investment portfolios.

Next, we find that ST_CREDIT factor differs from Cooper, et al. (2008)’s debt financing growth

component in construction. ST_CREDIT encompasses the Noncash current asset growth (∆CurAsset),

Debt financing growth (∆Debt), and operating liabilities growth (∆OpLiab), thus one factor represents the

Page 16: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

15

overall operating business growth of the firm. Moreover, Cooper, et al. (2008) combines the growth both

in debt in current liabilities and long-term debt, but we find an insignificant correlation (-0.03) among

them. This is why factor analysis puts them in separate factors. This shows the fundamental difference

between Cooper and our result. Cooper tried to explain the asset growth variable by analyzing the link of

the total to the subcomponents. Among other constituents of ST_CREDIT, there are also significant loads

on accounts payable, notes payable and accounts receivables growth. Hence, makes this factor possibly

well-defined to reflect on the business credibility.

3.1.3. Long-term capital investment (LT_INV)

The long-term capital investment (LT_INV) makes third factors and its most important

components are deferred taxes and investment credit, plant, property, & equipment-gross and net (with

weighting loads above 0.71). The remaining influential elements are long-term debt, invested capital and

total assets (all have a load greater than 0.45). This factor represents is one of the major components of

the overall corporate capital investment (Titman et al., 2010) but it offers a more comprehensive measure

than other similar measures. The other observed measure of long-term capital investment does not

consider the associated components of the investment in fixed assets that are hidden in different balance

sheet items may be helpful in fine tuning the measure.

Among the components the deferred taxes show timing differences in financial reporting for tax

purposes. Likewise, investment tax credit is generated due to new capital investment (include long-term

debt, preferred stock, minority interest and common equity). Deferred taxes in most companies are

generated by the depreciation of fixed assets, and thus, creates deferred tax liability. And it is because of

timing difference that there is more book income than tax income (Young, 1997). Generally, depreciation

methods for financial reporting and for tax purposes are different due to timing differences between

taxable income and accounting income that can be inferred from changes in deferred tax balance.

Moreover, this factor may help infer issues relating to investment tax shields and debt tax shields

(Trezevant, 1992). Literature suggests that long-term debt borrowings are mainly done by small firms that

Page 17: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

16

have low credit rating and high agency cost of debt (Chung, 1993; Diamond, 1991; Doukas and Pantzalis,

2003). LT_INV is comparable but it appears to be more comprehensive to Property, plant, and equipment

growth (∆PPE) sub-component given in Cooper, et al. (2008) as considering all associated aspects of

long-term investment.

3.1.4. Convertible debt usage (CVT_DEBT)

The convertible debt usage (CVT_DEBT), the fourth factor has the highest weights of debt

convertible-total and debt convertible-preferred stock (with loads greater than 0.80). The others are debt

convertible and subordinated and long-term debt (with loads about 0.64). Firms that circumvent financial

risks by raising capital from long-term sources of capital like debt convertible and subordinated are

represented by our fourth factor. The factor possibly reflects on the financing and investment constraints

of firms like weak capital structure and financial distress. In such a situation firms avoid issuing stocks

and resort to use convertible bonds, notes, debentures, and subordinated debt and preferred stock to raise

equity. These are called as hybrid securities and can be helpful in minimizing the higher costs of external

financing.

The convertible debt is a fraction of long-term debt, firms use to avoid long-term debt in the

presence of agency costs (Bodie and Taggart, 1978; Doukas and Pantzalis, 2003). Firms that use this type

of debt are small and micro firms with lower credit ratings, low information asymmetries, and high

agency costs of debt. According to Hovakimian et al., (2001) convertible debt issuance is second largest

after equity issuance, on an average firms show poor performance subsequent to issuance of convertible

debt (Lewis et al., 2001; Stein, 1992). Further, we find that the convertible debt usage (CVT_DEBT) is

not part of the total asset growth decomposition done by Cooper, et al. (2008). Moreover, CVT_DEBT

constituent variables have insignificant low correlation with the total asset growth (ASSETG) that makes

them orthogonal. In fact, we find this factor as measure of the operational risk arising from the

convertibility of bond and equity.

Page 18: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

17

3.1.5. Preferred stock usage (PSK_USE)

Finally, Fifth factor PSK_USE constitutes of purely preferred stock-total, liquidation and

nonredeemable (with loads greater than 0.62) (i.e., compustat item #A130, A209 & A10) and also lower

cross-loading of the total long-term debt convertible. According to Weston and Copeland (1992) and

Howe and Lee (2006) preferred stocks are hybrid security with features similar to bonds (as it has a par

value due in the event of liquidations and preferred dividends) and common stocks (equity to bondholders

and debt to stockholders and in the balance sheet reported as “preferred stock” or “preferred equity”). The

preferred stock is considered better than debt, as firms cannot be forced into bankruptcy on the failure of

dividend payments. At the same time, the common stockholders are not liable to share the success of the

firm with preferred stockholder due to their fixed preferred dividends. On the contrary, preferred stock

holders have priority claim than the common stockholders.

Houston and Carol Houston (1990) find that firm issuing preferred stock have a propensity for

lower tax rates and firms investing in preferred stock are likely to have higher tax rates. Further, they find

that industrial firms not utilities issue the majority of preferred stocks; and major use is in the merger

market by both target and acquiring firms. Target firms use it as antitakeover device and Acquirer for tax

benefits. Houston and Carol Houston (1990) also discuss the literature that integrates preferred stock into

the capital structure framework for example Fooladi and Roberts (1986), Miller (1977), Elmer (1988),

and DeAngelo and Masulis (1980). Hovakimian et al., (2001) document that preferred stock issuers

realize lower return compared to non-issuers. Howe and Lee (2006) find that in long-run preferred

issuers’ underperformance is transient and confined to small firms, such firms have poor profitability and

high debt ratios, thus they use preferred stock to offset the other expensive securities.

3.2. Summary statistics

In Table 2, we report the mean (median) values for some well-know accounting and market

characteristics for two extreme decile portfolios ranked on the five latent growth factors. For financial

flexibility ranked portfolios, the lowest decile stocks have lower mean (median) values for total asset

Page 19: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

18

growth, cumulative accruals growth, accounting accrual growth, profitability, and are smaller in size; and

have relatively higher values for investment-to-asset growth, leverage, and the book-to-market ratio

characteristics as compared to the highest decile portfolios.

For short-term credit ranked portfolios, the lowest decile stocks have lower mean (median) values

for the total asset growth, cumulative accrual growth, accounting accruals, lower leverage and are smaller

in size; and have relatively higher profitability, higher investment-to-asset growth, and higher book-to-

market ratios as compared to the highest decile portfolios. For long-term capital investment ranked

portfolios, the lowest decile stocks have lower mean (median) values for all accounting characteristics,

have lower profitability, and are smaller in size but have relatively higher book-to-market ratios as

compared to the highest decile portfolios.

Then, for debt convertible usage, the lowest decile stocks have similar mean (median) values for

the total asset growth, cumulative accruals growth, investment-to-asset growth, size, and book-to-market

ratio as compared to highest decile stocks. However, we find differences across the other characteristics

for example leverage and the accounting accrual growth have lower values and profitability of these

stocks is higher than the highest decile stocks. Finally, the preferred stock usage ranked portfolios, the

except the total asset growth the lowest decile stocks have higher mean (median) values for all other

characteristics as compared to highest decile stocks.

Overall, we are able to find clear distinctive patterns observing these characteristics when ranked

on individual new factor. In table 3, report the Pearson and Spearman correlations for five latent growth

factors and the other characteristics discussed above. The the latent growth factors appear to be having no

significant correlations because of the orthogonality induced during the factor analysis process. However,

there exist significant correlation between the total asset growth and our first latent factors showing that

the true decomposition of the total asset growth.

[Insert Table 2 and 3]

Page 20: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

19

3.3. Latent growth stability check

Finally, we also make check for factor stability across time. Factor components are checked in 25

annual factor model and found consistently appearing in the same factor. The top five components of the

financial flexibility and the short-term credit are always the same in the list of their components. The top

four components of the other three factors are always same in the list of their components. However, we

find that except financial flexibility the ranking of the other four factors does change across the 25 years.

Based upon this evidence we may say that the factor structure is stable. In other stability check we find all

the components that are linearly related to its factor and non-linearly to other factors.

The stability of the identified factors suggests some real economic forces that explain the

movement of the firms. A natural prediction of the understanding is that these factors have predictive

power for the equity return rates, the results of testing the prediction could be an important evidence for

the existence of these latent factors. In the next section, we provide the testing results.

4. Results

4.1. Portfolio analysis

4.1.1. Time trends in profitability and returns for extreme latent growth factor ranked deciles

Following Cooper, et al. (2008) we report in the figure 1a to 1e the long-run profitability and

return effects for two extreme decile portfolios. We first sort and rank the data sample on the lagged latent

growth factors into decile growth portfolios every t year at the end of June over 1985 t0 2009. Using the

June t growth cutoffs, we form portfolios that are held for one year from July of t year to June of t+1 and

then rebalanced. When sorted on latent growth factors. In this figure we plot the mean monthly

profitability values and mean monthly raw returns at equal-weighted basis to decile latent growth

portfolios at event time (5-year prior and 5-years after portfolio formation). The profitability is measured

as net income divided by the total assets. The returns are accumulated monthly raw returns starting four

months after the fiscal year end.

Page 21: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

20

Fig. 1a plots the time series means of firm profitability and mean monthly raw returns for extreme

(deciles 1 and 10) FIN_FLEX deciles. The profitability of lowest financial flexibility decile firms is

always lower and negative as compared to the highest financial flexibility decile firms in 5-years prior

and 5-years post ranking period. The high FIN_FLEX decile firms appear to earn higher mean monthly

returns in 5-years prior to ranking year, but we see a crossover after ranking period, when high

FIN_FLEX earns lower mean monthly returns. The trend shows that despite the firms in post ranking

period are more profitable than prior years but are unable to sustain abnormal returns. Alternatively, we

may say that firms that have lower financial flexibility and have negative profitability produce a

significant mean monthly return at least for next three years as compared to firms that are large with high

level of financial flexibility and positive profitability.

In a similar way for ST_CREDIT ranked extreme deciles, the firm profitability is positive for

both deciles in before and after the event year. Overall, except year -5, -4, and -3 the high ST_CREDIT

decile firms are more profitable than low decile firms. In terms of mean monthly returns generating

capabilities, the high ST_CREDIT decile firms earn higher returns in 5-prior event years as compared to

post-ranking years. However, the in post ranking year the return spread is marginal. Then for LT_INV

ranked extreme decile portfolios mean profitability and mean monthly returns plotted in fig 1c, the high

LT_INV firms are always positively profitable as compared to low LT_INV firms. Where low decile

firms have actually negative profitability only in year -1. And, in case of returns there is a crossover in

year -1, the high LT_INV firms earn higher returns prior to -1 and lower return in later years until they

converge in the year 4. It appears that despite of high profitability levels the high LT_INV firms are

unable to sustain the higher return generation in post event years. Our evidence for LT_INV is quite

consistent with the NOA (net operating assets) evidence (Hirshleifer et al., 2004).

Next from fig. 1d, we can say that the low CVT_DEBT decile firms are way profitable than the

high CVT_DEBT decile firms. However, the low CVT_DEBT decile firms earn higher mean monthly

returns than high CVT_DEBT decile firms prior to the year 1, but later year the spread is meaningless

may be owing to the similar level of capital investment, firm size, and the book-to-market ratios. Finally,

Page 22: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

21

for PSK_USE ranked extreme deciles (see, fig. 1e), the low PSK_USE decile firms have always higher

and positive profitability than the high PSK_USE decile firms. In case of high PSK_USE decile the

profitability is negative in year -2 and -1. However, we do not see any clear pattern of mean monthly

returns on the PSK_USE ranked deciles.

[Insert Figure 1a-1e]

4.1.2. Abnormal returns by Latent Growth Variable deciles

In table 4 we report the average monthly abnormal returns for five latent growth factors sorted

extreme decile portfolios in subsequent 1, 2, and 3 years after portfolio formation. For the period of July

1985 to October 2009, we formed monthly decile portfolios by ranking on the last year Latent Factor.

There is a 4-month lag between the fiscal year end and the portfolio formation month. The time-series

average of monthly equal (value) weighted abnormal returns (the abnormal returns are the difference

between the stock returns and size, book-to-market, and momentum matched benchmark portfolio

returns) are reported for each decile and hedge portfolio. The hedge portfolio is created by going long in

the lowest ranked Latent Factor portfolio and short in the highest ranked Latent Factor portfolio.

Comparatively, we also control for risk (size and book-to-market) and other important return anomalies

and report the alpha estimates (t-statistics) for CAPM, Fama and French (1993) three factor model, and

Carhart (1997) four factor model for both equal- and value-weighted hedge portfolios. We report the

results for four capitalization ranked portfolios following Fama and French (2008), the stocks under 20th

percentile of market cap at the end of the June each year are grouped as micro stock. The stocks that are

between 20th and 50

th percentile are grouped as small stocks and above median are grouped as large

stocks. In All but Micro firm portfolios we only exclude the micro stocks. Although not reported here but

we also obtain the similar results for the whole sample period.

The results for characteristic adjusted hedge returns and controlling for the pricing factors are

similar. In panel A of table 4 we report results at equal-weighted basis when firms are ranked by

FIN_FLEX, we indicate that for a large firm, the average monthly hedge returns for year t+1, t+2, and t+3

Page 23: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

22

are -0.01%, -0.28%, and -0.57% with t-statistics of -0.17, -3.67,-6.77 respectively. For small stocks, the

average monthly hedge returns for year t+1, t+2, and t+3 are 0.20%, 0.19%, and 0.27% with t-statistics of

3.16, 2.24, and 2.80 respectively. For micro stocks, the average monthly hedge returns for year t+1, t+2,

and t+3 are 0.60%, 0.75%, and 0.86% with t-statistics of 8.2, 8.26, and 9.67 respectively.We find no

significant variation in results when controlling for pricing factors and also obtain similar results at a

value-weighted basis. For a whole period there is an obvious size effect but within size groups there exists

no size effect. It appears that firms that lacks financial flexibility earn greater average monthly abnormal

returns as compared to firms that has higher financial flexibility.

In case of ST_CREDIT ranked portfolios, the panel B results indicate that on an equal-weighted

basis the low-minus-high hedge portfolio the mean monthly abnormal returns for large stocks at year t+1,

t+2, and t+3 are -0.16%, -0.50%, and -0.71% with t-statistics of -4.21, -8.19,-10.02 respectively. For

small stocks, the average monthly hedge returns for the subsequent three years are -0.22%, -0.28%, and -

0.39% with t-statistics of -3.20, -2.88, and -3.87 respectively. Then, for micro stocks, the average monthly

hedge returns for the subsequent three years are 0.17%, 0.39%, and 0.50% with t-statistics of 2.77, 5.60,

and 7.17 respectively. Similar to financial flexibility, the results are similar when controlling for pricing

factors and when results are obtained at value-weighted basis.

Then for LT_INV ranked portfolios, the panel C results indicate that on an equal-weighted basis

the mean monthly abnormal returns for large stock hedge portfolios in three subsequent years are not

significant except year t+1 with returns of 0.11% and t-statistics of 2.69. However, at value-weighted

basis the first two years offer significant abnormal returns of 0.15% and 0.24% with t-statistics of 3.27

and 3.63. For small stocks, we also notice the negative returns spread in year t+2 and t+3 are significant

both equal- and value-weighted basis. Then, for micro stocks, the average monthly hedge returns for the

subsequent three years are 0.45%, 0.76%, and 0.82% with t-statistics of 8.21, 9.52, and 8.63 respectively.

Next, in case of CVT_DEBT ranked portfolios, in panel D, the results indicate that large firms

earn mean monthly positive abnormal returns significant at equal-weighted basis for year t+1, t+2, and

t+3 are 0.08%, 0.2%, and 0.27% with t-statistics of 1.83, 5.09, and 3.99 respectively. The results for large

Page 24: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

23

stocks are more pronounce at value-weighted basis. However, for small and micro firms we find negative

and insignificant abnormal returns.

Finally, PSK_USE ranked portfolios, the panel E results indicate that on an equal-weighted basis

the low-minus-high hedge portfolio the mean monthly abnormal returns for large stocks at year t+1, t+2,

and t+3 are -0.13%, -0.30%, and -0.41% with t-statistics of -2.28, -4.74,-5.40 respectively. For small

stocks, the average monthly hedge returns for the subsequent three years are 0.13%, 0.15%, and 0.22%

with t-statistics of 2.33, 1.70, and 2.42respectively. Then, for micro stocks, the average monthly hedge

returns for the subsequent three years are -0.07%, -0.30%, and -0.36% with t-statistics of -1.29, -4.03, and

-4.96 respectively. The results are similar when controlling for pricing factors and when results are

obtained at value-weighted basis.

[Insert Table 4]

4.1.3. Annual buy-and-hold returns

In Table 5 we report the average annual buy-and-hold returns for Low and High latent growth

portfolios for the period of 1986 to 2010. We also report the low-minus spread of means for the same time

period. We obtain both equal- and value-weighted portfolios returns for three capitalization levels and all

but micro stocks (excludes the micro stocks) portfolios. The capitalization levels are constructed

following NYSE capitalization break points as defined in Fama and French (1992).

In our trading strategy based upon buying the lowest Latent Factors decile and selling short the

highest Latent Factors decile, the FIN_FLEX is profitable in 20 years, the ST_CREDIT is profitable in 17

years, the LT_INV is profitable in 19 years, the CVT_DEBT is profitable in 14 years, and PSK_USE is

profitable in 13 out of the 25 years in the sample. The mean annual abnormal returns on CVT_DEBT and

PSK_USE ranked extreme decile is quite similar so their hedge (low-minus-high) almost converges to

zero. This is probably due to the similar level of positive profitability and firm size across two extreme

deciles. The mean equal-weighted annual buy-and-hold returns spread for FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT,

Page 25: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

24

LT_INV, CVT_DEBT, and PSK_USE for whole sample are 15.2%, 6.1%, 10.1%, -1.5%, and -1.4%

respectively.

The above buy-and-hold returns based upon each latent factor suggest that these factors could be

important in explaining the market performance of the stocks; a better test is to put these factors in a

controlled model to control their unique contribution to the market returns. For this purpose we have

implemented Fama-Macbeth models in the following sub-section.

[Insert Table 5]

4.2. Cross-sectional regression results

At individual stock level analysis, we employ Fama-MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regression

framework to test the future return predictability of the latent growth factors for a period of nineteen years

(July, 1993 to June 2011). The latent growth factors’ return predictive power is further tested by

introducing the other well-known return determinants in regression models. Prior literature documents the

negative return-asset growth relationship. Sloan (1996) document negative accruals (ACCR) -return

relationship; Titman, et al. (2004) report negative capital investment (CI) -return relationship; Hirshleifer,

et al. (2004) document the negative association of the cumulative accruals (NOATA), and recently

Cooper, et al. (2008) show that total asset growth (ASSETG) earns negative future returns. Similarly, this

research documents the strong negative and significant association of all latent growth factors except

PSK_USE that have mixed association with future stock returns.

The new latent factors are created from our systematic search method and which has the potential to

synthesize all of the elements relative to a fundamental mechanism. For example, a company’s investment

policy is usually separated by long-term consideration and short-term consideration. Even within the

long-term consideration type the result could be shown in several accounting variables. We argue that the

latent factors created by the factor analysis have this characteristic, and they are better represented than

the simple Asset Growth used in the previous literature. We employ following regression models:

(2)

Page 26: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

25

(3)

The LatentGrowth in regression model given in equation (2) refers to the set of new latent factors

(FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT, LT_INV, CVT_DEBT, and PSK_USE) measured at the end of fiscal year t-1.

The dependent return variable starts from July of year t to June of t+1. The FIN_FLEX growth measure is

the latent growth score obtained via factor analysis procedures and it proxy for financial flexibility.

Similar is the construction of other latent growth factors. The ST_CREDIT latent growth measure is a

proxy for short-term credit. The LT_INV latent growth is a proxy for long-term capital investments. The

CVT_DEBT latent growth measure is a proxy for convertible debt usage. Then, the PSK_USE latent

growth measure represents preferred stock usage.

Following the standard literature on accounting growth and cross-section of expected returns, the

regression model in equation (2) is further augmented with established return determinants given in

equation (3). These determinants include LSIZE is the log market value of equity at June and LBTM is

the log book equity to market equity following Fama and French (1992) and Li and Sullivan (2011).

BHRET6 is the 6-month buy-and-hold returns over January (t) to June (t) and BHRET36 is the 3-year

buy-and-hold returns over July (t-3) to June (t). The ASSETG is a measure of the total asset growth that is

the year-to-year change in total assets (Cooper et al., 2008). ACCR (accruals) equals the change in

accounts receivables plus the change in inventories plus the change in the other current assets minus the

change in account payable minus the change in other current liabilities minus depreciation and scaled by

lagged total assets as defined by Polk and Sapienza (2009). NOATA represents cumulative accruals as

defined by Hirshleifer et al. (2004). The measure of profitability (ROA) is net income (COMPUSTAT

item A178) divided by the total assets (COMPUSTAT item A6). Next, in this section, we investigate the

return predictive power of the latent growth rates for all stocks, of three size groupings and of two

periodic sub-samples by employing Fama-Macbeth (1973) regression framework.

[Insert Table 6]

Page 27: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

26

4.2.1. Full sample

For full sample, in Panel A, Table 6, evidence shows that all latent growth factors but PSK_USE

have significant negative associations with future returns. The coefficients (t-statistics) of FIN_FLEX,

ST_CREDIT, LT_INV and CVT_DEBT growth measures in a model (1) without controls are -0.065 (-

11.17), -0.013 (-2.95), -0.030 (-9.56), and -0.010 (-7.96) respectively. For a whole market sample, the

control variables are unable to subsume return predictability of the latent factors. However, among

controls variables except ASSETG and BHRET6 all other variables persist in explaining the subsequent

returns.

The empirical results support our argument that the newly created latent variables are better

represented than the simple Asset Growth used in the previous literature. We further need to test the size

effect, if any in our all firm results. In subsequent sub-sections we follow Fama and French (2008) to test

the size effect.

4.2.2. Size groups

For cross-sectional regressions the results for large stocks are reported in Panel B, Table 6, the

results are consistent with the growth effect seen in decile portfolio returns. Among latent growth factors

except ST_CREDIT and CVT_DEBT, the FIN_FLEX, LT_INV, and PSK_USE have significant

coefficients (t-statistics) -0.028 (-2.94), -0.014 (-4.61), and -0.038 (-5.84) respectively. However, among

other control variable, except ACCR, I_A, and LSIZE all other variables significantly explain future stock

return. In regression model which include all latent growth measures, when augmented by ASSETG, the

PSK_USE is the only that persist and others are found sensitive to ASSETG.

For small stocks cross-sectional regression results in Panel C, Table 5 suggests that the

FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT, CVT_DEBT, and PSK_USE significantly predict future returns, their

coefficient (t-statistics) estimates are -0.043 (-7.1), -0.016 (-2.69), -0.009 (-5.18) and -0.032 (-4.27)

respectively. Among the other control variables the ACCR, ROA, BHRET36 are able to explain the

future returns. Overall, results for small stocks suggest that return prediction power of financial

Page 28: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

27

flexibility, short-term credit growth, debt convertible, and preferred stock usage is independent

phenomena.

Then micro firm cross-sectional results in Panel D, Table 6 show that FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT,

LT_INV, and CVT_DEBT are significant negative predictors of the future stock returns. The relative

coefficients (t-statistics) for FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT, LT_INV, and CVT_DEBT are -0.066 (-11.6), -

0.017 (-3.54), -0.032 (-8.55), and -0.015 (-5.89) respectively. The PSK_USE has positive and significant

relation with future stock returns with the coefficient (t-statistics) of 0.204 (3.96). Among other control

variables, the ASSETG, I_A, and BHRET6 becomes flat. Besides, the NOATA subsumes effect of the

ST_CREDIT but the rest of the latent factors remain significant. It appears that the return predictive

power of latent growth factors is prevalent in micro stocks robustly with no substantial influence of the

control variables.

Overall size effect on the latent growth factors’ return predictability suggest that the results for full

sample are not solely influenced by the small to micro stocks. The financial flexibility, long-term capital

investment, and preferred stock usage are persistent for large stock return prediction. It appears that

apparent return predictability of total asset growth for large stock is mainly driven by financial flexibility

and the long-term investment, and the preferred stock is an additional phenomena. Specifically, the

FIN_FLEX and PSKK_USE are found to be robust in explaining the future stock returns of all three size

groups.

4.2.3. Sub-samples

Under this section we divide the data period in two sub-samples. The first sub-sample constitutes of

fiscal year Nov-1985 to the Oct-1997, and second sub-sample constitutes of fiscal year Nov-1997 to June-

2009. The construction of regression models remains same. For first sub-sample the cross-sectional

results are given in Panel E in Table 5, the latent factor regression models show significant coefficients (t-

statistics) for FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT, LT_INV, CVT_DEBT, and PSK_USE are -0.042 (-11.69), -

0.016 (-5.68), -0.043 (-19.43), -0.009 (-6.61), and 0.014 (3.91) respectively.

Page 29: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

28

Compared to first sub-sample, in Panel F, Table 6 report that the significance of the latent growth

effect is reduced significantly in the base regression model, only FIN_FLEX, LT_INV, and CVT_DEBT

are significant in explaining future stock returns in the second sub-sample. The coefficients (t-statistics)

for these latent factors are -0.088 (-8.21), -0.018 (-3.16), and -0.012 (-5.43) respectively. Among control

variables except ASSETG and LBTM all other control variables are also significant in explaining the

future returns of the second sub-sample.

5. More robustness tests

5.1. Industry effect

In this section, we investigate the industry effect on the five latent growth factors and other asset

growth and investment measures. Firms within the same industry are expected to be homogeneous and

heterogeneous with the firms in other industries. Homogeneity within the industry is induced due to

similar business operation behaviors and accounting choices; regulatory requirements; sensitivity to

macroeconomic shocks; and similar supply and demand variations (Zhang, 2005). The investment and

financing behaviors are expected to be consistent for firms within the industry than across the industry.

Under this test, we intend to see how new five factors are able to explain future returns of the most

prominent industries as compared to overall market future returns. Additionally, based on nature of

factors, we expect that different industries are represented by a different set of latent growth factors.

Because, management’s corporate financing decisions may vary across industries. Thus, we perform

robustness tests for industry effect and use SIC codes to construct the ten industry groups from our overall

market data sample for the period 1985 to 2009.

Firms are grouped in ten industries as defined by Kenneth French’s web page

(http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/). Among these, NoDur represent consumer non-

durables industry group that includes food, tobacco, textiles, apparel, leather, and toy industries. Durbl

represent the consumer durable industry group that includes cars, TV’s, furniture, and household

appliances. Manuf represents a manufacturing industry group that includes machinery, trucks, planes,

Page 30: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

29

office furniture, paper, and commercial printing industries. Energy includes oil, gas, and coal extraction

and products industries. Chems includes chemicals and allied products industries. BusEq represents a

business equipment industry group that includes computers, software, and electronic equipment

industries. Telcm includes telephone and television transmission industries. Shops include wholesale,

retail, and some services (laundries, repair shops) industries. Hlth include healthcare, medical equipment,

and drug industries. And, Others include mines, construction, building material, transportation, hotels,

business service, and entertainment industries. However, we exclude the Money group, as we have

already taken out the financial firms from the data sample.

We run Fama-Macbeth (1973) cross-sectional regressions of annual compounding geometric

future returns on two groups of the independent variables across ten industry samples. We run two models

of following form.

(4)

(5)

Where, represents the new latent factors (FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT,

LT_INV, CVT_DEBT, and PSK_USE) and refers to the other accounting growth

measures (include ASSETG, NOATA, I_A, and ACCR). The represents the market variables

that include the LSIZE is the log of market equity, LBTM is the log book-to-market ratio and two price

momentum variable (BHRET6 and BHRET36). However, In Table 7, we only report the coefficients with

relevant significance based on t-statistics estimate for seven models for each of ten industries. The t-

statistics in boldface show significance below 5% level. Equation (4) provides results for our base model

1 in case of all industries and equation (5) introduces each control factor to base model separately.

The test provides evidence of the existence of the new latent factors across industries with

relevant comparison with other well-known factors. We find that FIN_FLEX is the important to nine out

ten industries with significance in more than six out of seven models. The ST_CREDIT determines the

future stock returns of more than five industries in more than four out of seven models. The LT_INV and

Page 31: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

30

CVT_DEBT can significantly predict the future returns of six industries in more than six models. Finally,

PSK_USE growth is important in more than five industries and significant in more than five models. For

compatible factors, ASSETG and I_A can explain four industry returns; NOATA and LSIZE can explain

eight industry returns; ACCR and ROA can explain six industry returns; LBTM explain nine industry

returns; BHRET6 explains two industry returns; and BHRET36 is able to explain all industry returns.

Results suggest that any one or two latent growth factors are not enough to capture all industry

returns. Each of the five new factors finds its importance in certain industries; we cannot ignore any of

them. The most of the other accounting variables could be replaced by the latent factors. However, the

market variables are complementary and show additional explanation of the future stock returns.

[Insert Table 7]

5.2. Annual cross-sectional regression

Under this section we investigate the return predictive power of the latent growth factors in the

annual cross-sections across the research period of 1985-2009. Before running simple OLS regressions,

we divide the overall data sample into 25 annual sub-samples. The motivation for this robustness analysis

is to check for any time effect in regressions, in order to be sure that the return predictive power is not

mere manifestations of a particular year. The dependent variable is the annual compounding geometric

future returns. For simplicity, we run regressions of following form.

(6)

(7)

Table 8 reports the results for two regression models given in equation (6) and (7). First model

includes five latent growth factors as independent variables and the second model is augmented with the

total asset growth measure (ASSETG). Although not reported here, but we run similar regressions with

controls of cumulative accruals (NOATA), accounting accruals (ACCR), firm profitability (ROA),

investment-to-assets (I_A), firm market size (LSIZE), book-to-market ratio (LBTM), the past six months

buy-and-hold returns (BHRET6), and last three years buy-and-hold returns (BHRET36).

[Insert Table 8]

Page 32: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

31

From Table 8, the coefficients (t-statistics) of FIN_FLEX are significant for all fiscal years but

three 1993, 1996, 2002, and 2006. The association of FIN_FLEX growth and future stock returns is

consistently negative almost across all fiscal years. In case of ST_CREDIT growth the coefficients (t-

statistics) are significant in 22 out of 25 fiscal years. It is negatively related to future stock returns for 15

years out of 25 years. Then for LT_INV growth has a robust negative relationship with future stock

returns across all fiscal year except six years (2002 to 2007), when a relationship gets positive.

Next, the CVT_DEBT growth has a significant negative relationship with future stock returns

across in 18 of 25 years, also significantly explain stock returns in 18 annual cross-sections. Lastly, the

PSK_USE growth found significantly explaining the future stock returns across 19 fiscal years, whereas,

the relationship is mostly positive. Out of 18 annual periods, PSK_USE has the negative relation in 10

fiscal years. In case of the total asset growth (ASSETG) has a significant negative relationship with future

stock returns only for 12 out of 25 fiscal years. The total asset growth measure does subsume some of the

return effects of the latent growth factors but not all. Conversely, the total asset growth either gets

subsumed or change the sign when included with latent factors.

In summary, from the Table 8, we are able to document five latent growth measures are found persistent

in predicting future stock returns in annual cross-sections. Thus, we observe no time effect in their return

predictive power. During the 1987 financial crisis, except financial flexibility all other latent factors

survive. Then, during the dotcom boom and bust period of 1999 to 2002 almost all latent factors survive.

Finally, for last financial crisis periods, in 2007 Financial flexibility and short-term credit robustly explain

the stock return and in 2008 except short-term credit all other factors persist in explaining the future stock

returns.

5.3. Determining firm profitability

In this section, we investigate the relationship between the profitability and the latent growth factors

for understanding their applications and implications. In turn further provide support to our claim that

these factors are well defined and are not manifestation of any other observed variable. Here, we establish

Page 33: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

32

that latent factors are independent and are able to explain profitability as well. The measure of

profitability is net income (COMPUSTAT item A178) divided by the total assets (COMPUSTAT item

A6). For this robustness check we estimate standard clustered error regressions using ordinary least

squares (OLS) approach in order to avoid the presence of correlation in error terms across same firms in

different years. The t-statistics are computed with these standard errors and are reported in Table 8 along

with parameter coefficients. The numbers of clusters are 7687 for the period of 1985 to 2009 with firm-

month observations of 821736.

[Insert Table 9]

In Table 9 we report six multiple regression results. In each model, we have five latent growth

measures (FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT, LT_INV, CVT_DEBT, and PSK_USE), and other variables like

LSIZE, LBM, BHRET6, and BHRET36 as base variables. In model 1, we have only base variables, and

in subsequent models we add the other growth measures like ASSETG, NOATA, I_A, and ACCR, and

leverage (LEV) measure as controls being one of the main determinants of firm profitability. Among the

latent growth measures the FIN_FLEX, and LT_INV has a positive association with firm profitability, the

inclusion of controls have not affect on financial flexibility but long-term investment is sensitive to

inclusion of NOATA. The t-statistics range for FIN_FLEX is 2.28 to 16.07; and for LT_INV -15.96 to

17.76. From the results, we infer that firms’ profitability improves with an increase in financial flexibility

and when firms are profitable they overreact and increase long-term capital investment in fixed assets

(Titman et al., 2004). ST_CREDIT, CVT_DEBT, and PSK_USE are having a negative association with

the firm profitability, and this association is also not reduced when controls are included. The t-statistics

range for ST_CREDIT is -1.66 to 5.58, for CVT_DEBT is -7.80 to -15.77, and for PSK_USE are -3.41 (-

5.80). These relations indicate that with the increase in the use of these three sources of financing, the

corresponding operating performance of firm will decline (Doukas and Pantzalis, 2003; Howe and Lee,

2006; Lewis et al., 2001).

Then, among other base variables LSIZE, LBM, and BHRET36 possess positive persistent

association with the profitability; and only BHRET6 has consistently negative relation across all models.

Page 34: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

33

Subsequently, among controls, ASSETG and ACCR have negative associations with firm profitability.

Both other base and control variables are able significantly explain the firm profitability. The adjusted R-

square for Model 1 to 6 is 14%, 15%, 20%, 14%, 15%, and 14%.

5.4. Determining firm value

In further robustness tests, we extend investigation latent growth factors’ relationship to firm value.

The Tobin’s Q is used as a proxy for the market value of the firm that is market equity plus total assets

minus book equity and divided by total assets as defined in Hou and Robinson (2006). In fact we need to

see the extent of new five factors’ contribution in explaining the value of the firm and their persistence

under comprehensive controls. Similar to profitability regressions, we report in Table 10 the standard

clustered error OLS cross-sectional regression results for Tobin’s Q as dependent variables. The study

period is spread over 18 years that is 1985 to 2009 with 821736 firm-year observations for non-financial

firms. In results we report the parameter estimates and t-statistics. There are 7685 numbers of clusters.

[Insert Table 10]

The construction of five multiple regression models is similar to profitability regression models

with the same number of base variables and controls except LBTM, which is excluded as being highly

correlated with our firm value measure.

From Table 9, among latent growth measures, FIN_FLEX and ST_CREDIT have a positive

relationship with the firm value. This association gets no influence with the inclusion of the controls

except the ST_CREDIT. The FIN_FLEX t-statistics vary from 1.91 to 12.18 and the ST_CREDIT t-

statistics vary -2.24 to 5.54. The LT_INV, CVT_DEBT, and PSK_USE have a negative relationship with

the firm value. The LT_INV is robust to the inclusion of the controls except NOATA and the t-statistics

range between -3.03 to 10.30. CVT_DEBT has a significant negative association with firm value in all

models except model 3 and model 5 where we add NOATA and leverage (LEV) as a control. The t-

statistics for CVT_DEBT has ranged between -1.80 to 3.58. The PSK_USE is a significant negative

predictor of the firm value in all models except model 3, where we include NOATA as a control. He

PSK_USE t-statistics range between -1.45 to -2.26. Then, among other base variables LSIZE, BHRET6,

Page 35: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

34

and BHRET36 possess positive persistent association with the firm value across all models. With respect

to controls, the NOATA, I_A, and LEV have a significant negative association with the firm value, and

ASSETG and ACCR are positively related to the firm value. The adjusted R-square for Model 1 to Model

6 is 13%, 13%, 15%, 13%, 15% and 14%.

This robustness test exhibits that the both the latent asset growth factors and other growth

measures are robust determinants of the firm's value. Moreover, the latent growth factors are robust to

controls of total asset growth (ASSETG), cumulative accruals (NOATA), and accounting accruals

(ACCR).

6. Conclusion

What are the optimal corporate financing decisions? In this study, we seek to address this

question. Owing to the nature of double entry bookkeeping practice we assume that the information about

the optimal decision types is embedded in multiple balance sheet accounts thus, provides additional

information to classify the rich balance sheet information content. We also recognize that the outcomes of

the firms’ corporate financing decisions are reflected in the shifts of their accounting numbers and

identification of their common interactive movements may also help to classify information.

Our results suggest that the complete balance sheet (including supplementary items) information

content can be optimally decomposed into the five latent factors mimicking basic corporate financing

decision types that are fundamental to the business value. More specifically, we find that these five

factors contain about 70% of all the accounting ratio changes. The identified decision types are Financial

Flexibility (FIN_FLEX), Short-term Credit (ST_CREDIT), Long-term Capital Investment (LT_INV),

Convertible Debt Usage (CVT_DEBT) and Preferred Stock Usage (PSK_USE). They appear to be well

aligned with the major decision type given in theory.

Furthermore, our results indicate that the extracted factors are superior in predicting future returns

than other well-established factors known in the literature such as firm size, book-to-market, momentum,

and accounting growth measures (including total asset growth). The results suggest that other accounting

Page 36: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

35

measure can be replaced with the new latent factors. The firm size, book-to-market ratio, and price

momentum factors appears to be complementary, as our factors represent the fundamentals of the

business and they represent the market information, business size, and investor behavior issues. We

observe that our regression results hold after controlling for the financial crisis periods falling in our

research period.

Finally, our integrated analyses reveal the complex relationship between changes in corporate

financing decisions and subsequent stock returns among different size and industry groups. Both among

size and industry groups, the new latent factors can better capture variations in future returns than other

compatible factors. Furthermore, industry tests find that except market variables the other accounting

determinants of subsequent returns can be replaced by latent factors.

References

Abarbanell, J. S., Bushee, B. J., 1997. Fundamental analysis, future earnings, and stock prices. Journal of

Accounting Research 35, 1-24.

Abarbanell, Jeffery S., et al., 2003. Institutional investor preferences and price pressure: The case of

corporate spin-offs. The Journal of Business 76, 233-261.

Baker, M., et al., 2003. When does the market matter? Stock prices and the investment of equity-

dependent firms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 118, 969-1005.

Baker, M., Wurgler, J., 2002. Market timing and capital structure. The Journal of Finance 57, 1-32.

Barclay, M. J., Smith, C. W., 1995a. The maturity structure of corporate debt. The Journal of Finance 50,

609-631.

Barclay, M. J., Smith, C. W., 1995b. The priority structure of corporate liabilities. The Journal of Finance

50, 899-917.

Baxamusa, M., 2011. How well do market timing, catering, and classical theories explain corporate

decision? Journal of Financial Research 34, 217-239.

Black, F., 1993. Estimating expected return. Financial Analysts Journal, 36-38.

Bodie, Z., Taggart, R. A., 1978. Future investment opportunities and the value of the call provision on a

bond. The Journal of Finance 33, 1187-1200.

Page 37: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

36

Bradshaw, M. T., et al., 2006. The relation between corporate financing activities, analysts’ forecasts and

stock returns. Journal of Accounting and Economics 42, 53-85.

Brennan, M. J., Schwartz, E. S., 1984. Optimal financial policy and firm valuation. The Journal of

Finance 39, 593-607.

Bushee, B. J., 1998. The influence of institutional investors on myopic r&d investment behavior. The

Accounting Review 73, 305-333.

Butler, A. W., et al., 2011. Corporate financing decisions, managerial market timing, and real investment.

Journal of Financial Economics 101, 666-683.

Cao, S. S., 2011. The total asset growth anomaly: Is it incremental to the net operating asset growth

anomaly? SSRN eLibrary.

Carhart, M. M., 1997. On persistence in mutual fund performance. The Journal of Finance 52, 57-82.

Chan, L. K. C., et al., 2007. Industry classifications and return comovement. Financial Analysts Journal

63, 56-70.

Chen, L., et al., 2011. An alternative three-factor model. Available at SSRN 1418117.

Chung, K. H., 1993. Asset characteristics and corporate debt policy: An empirical test. Journal of

Business Finance & Accounting 20, 83-98.

Cooper, M. J., et al., 2008. Asset growth and the cross-section of stock returns. Journal of Finance 63,

1609-1651.

Dammon, R. M., Senbet, L. W., 1988. The effect of taxes and depreciation on corporate investment and

financial leverage. The Journal of Finance 43, 357-373.

Daniel, K., Titman, S., 2006. Market reactions to tangible and intangible information. The Journal of

Finance 61, 1605-1643.

DeAngelo, H., DeAngelo, L., 2007. Capital structure, payout policy, and financial flexibility. Marshall

School of Business Working Paper No. FBE, 02-06.

DeAngelo, H., Masulis, R. W., 1980. Optimal capital structure under corporate and personal taxation.

Journal of Financial Economics 8, 3-29.

Denis, D. J., 2011. Financial flexibility and corporate liquidity. Journal of Corporate Finance 17, 667-674.

Diamond, D. W., 1991. Debt maturity structure and liquidity risk. The Quarterly Journal of Economics

106, 709-737.

Page 38: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

37

Dotan, A., Ravid, S. A., 1985. On the interaction of real and financial decisions of the firm under

uncertainty. The Journal of Finance 40, 501-517.

Doukas, J. A., Pantzalis, C., 2003. Geographic diversification and agency costs of debt of multinational

firms. Journal of Corporate Finance 9, 59-92.

Easterwood, J. C., Kadapakkam, P. R., 1994. Agency conflicts, issue costs, and debt maturity. Quarterly

Journal of Business and Economics, 69-80.

Ericsson, J., 2000. Asset substitution, debt pricing, optimal leverage and maturity.

Fabozzi, F. J., Markowitz, H. M., 2011. The theory and practice of investment management: Asset

allocation, valuation, portfolio construction, and strategies: Wiley.

Fairfield, P. M., et al., 2003. Accrued earnings and growth: Implications for future profitability and

market mispricing. The Accounting Review 78, 353-371.

Fama, E. F., French, K. R., 1992. The cross-section of expected stock returns. The Journal of Finance 47,

427-465.

Fama, E. F., French, K. R., 1993. Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and bonds. Journal of

Financial Economics 33, 3-56.

Fama, E. F., French, K. R., 2008. Dissecting anomalies. The Journal of Finance 63, 1653-1678.

Fama, E. F., MacBeth, J. D., 1973. Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests. Journal of Political

Economy 81, 607-636.

Faulkender, M., Wang, R., 2006. Corporate financial policy and the value of cash. The Journal of Finance

61, 1957-1990.

Flannery, M. J., Rangan, K. P., 2006. Partial adjustment toward target capital structures. Journal of

Financial Economics 79, 469-506.

Fooladi, I., Roberts, G. S., 1986. On preferred stock. Journal of Financial Research 9, 319-324.

Fries, S., et al., 1997. Debt in industry equilibrium. Review of Financial Studies 10, 39-67.

Gamba, A., Triantis, A., 2008. The value of financial flexibility. The Journal of Finance 63, 2263-2296.

Goldstein, R., et al., 2001. An ebit‐ based model of dynamic capital structure*. The Journal of Business

74, 483-512.

Page 39: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

38

Graham, J. R., Harvey, C. R., 2001. The theory and practice of corporate finance: Evidence from the

field. Journal of Financial Economics 60, 187-243.

Hirshleifer, D., et al., 2004. Do investors overvalue firms with bloated balance sheets? Journal of

Accounting and Economics 38, 297-331.

Holthausen, R. W., Larcker, D. F., 1992. The prediction of stock returns using financial statement

information. Journal of Accounting and Economics 15, 373-411.

Hou, K., Robinson, D. T., 2006. Industry concentration and average stock returns. The Journal of Finance

61, 1927-1956.

Houston, A. L., Jr., Carol Olson, H., 1990. Financing with preferred stock. Financial Management 19, 42-

54.

Hovakimian, A., et al., 2001. The debt-equity choice. The Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis

36, 1-24.

Howe, J. S., Lee, H., 2006. The long-run stock performance of preferred stock issuers. Review of

Financial Economics 15, 237-250.

Jensen, M. C., Meckling, W. H., 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and

ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, 305-360.

Jobson, J. D., 1992. Applied multivariate data analysis: Springer Nueva York.

Joseph F. Hair, J., et al., 1998. Multivariate data analysis. New Jersey: Prentice-Hall, Inc.

Ju, N., et al., 2003. Horses and rabbits? Optimal dynamic capital structure from shareholder and manager

perspectives.

Leary, M. T., Roberts, M. R., 2005. Do firms rebalance their capital structures? The Journal of Finance

60, 2575-2619.

Leland, H. E., 1998. Agency costs, risk management, and capital structure. Journal of Finance 53, 1213-

1243.

Lev, B., Thiagarajan, S. R., 1993. Fundamental information analysis. Journal of Accounting Research 31,

190-215.

Lewis, C. M., et al., 2001. The long-run performance of firms that issue convertible debt: An empirical

analysis of operating characteristics and analyst forecasts. Journal of Corporate Finance 7, 447-474.

Page 40: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

39

Li, X., Sullivan, R., 2011. The limits to arbitrage revisited: The accrual and asset growth anomalies.

Financial Analysts Journal 67.

López de Silanes, F., et al., 1998. Law and finance. Journal of Political Economy 106, 1113-1155.

Lyandres, E., et al., 2008. The new issues puzzle: Testing the investment-based explanation. The Review

of Financial Studies 21, 2825-2855.

Marchica, M. T., Mura, R., 2010. Financial flexibility, investment ability, and firm value: Evidence from

firms with spare debt capacity. Financial Management 39, 1339-1365.

Mauer, D. C., Ott, S. H., 2000. Agency costs, underinvestment, and optimal capital structure: The effect

of growth options to expand. Project Flexibility, Agency, and Competition (Oxford University Press,

Oxford).

Mauer, D. C., Sarkar, S., 2005. Real options, agency conflicts, and optimal capital structure. Journal of

banking & Finance 29, 1405-1428.

Mauer, D. C., Triantis, A. J., 1994. Interactions of corporate financing and investment decisions: A

dynamic framework. The Journal of Finance 49, 1253-1277.

Mehran, H., et al., 1999. Ceo ownership, leasing, and debt financing. Financial Management, 5-14.

Mello, A. S., Parsons, J. E., 1992. Measuring the agency cost of debt. The Journal of Finance 47, 1887-

1904.

Mello, A. S., et al., 1995. An integrated model of multinational flexibility and financial hedging. Journal

of International Economics 39, 27-51.

Miller, M. H., 1977. Debt and taxes. The Journal of Finance 32, 261-275.

Modigliani, F., Miller, M. H., 1958. The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment.

The American Economic Review 48, 261-297.

Morellec, E., 2004. Can managerial discretion explain observed leverage ratios? Review of Financial

Studies 17, 257-294.

Moyen, N., 2007. How big is the debt overhang problem? Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 31,

433-472.

Myers, S. C., 1974. Interactions of corporate financing and investment decisions-implications for capital

budgeting. The Journal of Finance 29, 1-25.

Myers, S. C., 1977. Determinants of corporate borrowing. Journal of Financial Economics 5, 147-175.

Page 41: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

40

Myers, S. C., Majluf, N. S., 1984. Corporate financing and investment decisions when firms have

information that investors do not have. Journal of Financial Economics 13, 187-221.

Ou, J. A., Penman, S. H., 1989. Financial statement analysis and the prediction of stock returns. Journal

of Accounting and Economics 11, 295-329.

Parrino, R., et al., 2005. Measuring investment distortions when risk‐ averse managers decide whether to

undertake risky projects. Financial Management 34, 21-60.

Parrino, R., Weisbach, M. S., 1999. Measuring investment distortions arising from stockholder–

bondholder conflicts. Journal of Financial Economics 53, 3-42.

Pinches, G. E., et al., 1975. The hierarchical classification of financial ratios. Journal of Business

Research 3, 295-310.

Pinches, G. E., Mingo, K. A., 1973. A multivariate analysis of industrial bond ratings. The Journal of

Finance 28, 1-18.

Piotroski, J. D., 2000. Value investing: The use of historical financial statement information to separate

winners from losers. Journal of Accounting Research 38, 1-41.

Polk, C., Sapienza, P., 2009. The stock market and corporate investment: A test of catering theory. The

Review of Financial Studies 22, 187-217.

Pontiff, J., Woodgate, A., 2008. Share issuance and cross-sectional returns. The Journal of Finance 63,

921-945.

Porta, R., et al., 1997. Legal determinants of external finance. The Journal of Finance 52, 1131-1150.

Rajan, R. G., Zingales, L., 1995. What do we know about capital structure? Some evidence from

international data. The Journal of Finance 50, 1421-1460.

Richardson, S., Sloan, R., 2003. External financing and future stock returns. Rodney L. White Center for

Financial Research Working Paper.

Ross, S. A., 1976. The arbitrage theory of capital asset pricing. Journal of Economic Theory 13, 341-360.

Sloan, R. G., 1996. Do stock prices fully reflect information in accruals and cash flows about future

earnings? The Accounting Review 71, 289-315.

Sorensen, D. E., 2000. Characteristics of merging firms. Journal of Economics and Business 52, 423-433.

Spiess, D. K., Affleck-Graves, J., 1999. The long-run performance of stock returns following debt

offerings. Journal of Financial Economics 54, 45-73.

Page 42: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

41

Stein, J. C., 1992. Convertible bonds as backdoor equity financing. Journal of Financial Economics 32, 3-

21.

Subrahmanyam, A., 2010. The cross-section of expected stock returns: What have we learnt from the past

twenty-five years of research? European Financial Management 16, 27-42.

Sullivan, M., Zhang, A., 2011. Are investment and financing anomalies two sides of the same coin?

Journal of Empirical Finance 18, 616-633.

Teoh, S. H., et al., 1998. Earnings management and the underperformance of seasoned equity offerings.

Journal of Financial Economics 50, 63-99.

Titman, S., Tsyplakov, S., 2007. A dynamic model of optimal capital structure. Review of Finance 11,

401-451.

Titman, S., et al., 2004. Capital investments and stock returns. Journal of Financial and Quantitative

Analysis 39, 677-700.

Titman, S., et al., 2010. Unexpected investment, overinvestment, and stock returns: Working paper,

University of Texas at Austin.

Trezevant, R., 1992. Debt financing and tax status: Tests of the substitution effect and the tax exhaustion

hypothesis using firms' responses to the economic recovery tax act of 1981. The Journal of Finance 47,

1557-1568.

Tsay, R. S., 2005. Analysis of financial time series: Wiley-Interscience.

Tufano, P., 2001. Hbs-jfe conference volume: Complementary research methods. Journal of Financial

Economics 60, 179-185.

Welch, I., 2004. Capital structure and stock returns. Journal of Political Economy 112, 106-132.

Weston, J. F., Copeland, T. E., 1992. Financial theory and corporate policy: Addison Wesley.

Xing, Y., 2008. Interpreting the value effect through the q-theory: An empirical investigation. The

Review of Financial Studies 21, 1767-1795.

Young, D., 1997. Economic value added: A primer for european managers. European Management

Journal 15, 335-343.

Zhang, Y., 2005. Net operating assets as a predictor for future stock returns–an industry analysis: Ohio

State University.

Page 43: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

42

Table 1: Latent Growth Factor Pattern

This table presents the factor structure as the outcome of the application of the annual factor analysis model on the balance sheet growth rates for the period of 1985-2009.

We estimate 37 balance sheet growth rates using the following formula Xi, t = (bi, t - bi, t-1) /Total Assett-1. Where, bi, t stands for the balance sheet item i at time t and

bi, t-1 is the lagged balance sheet item for the same firm. For each of new latent growth factors we present constituent variable names and their codes. The five factors

are also given a label that reflects the constituent items that have higher loading on that particular factor.

FACTOR 1 FACTOR 2 FACTOR 3 FACTOR 4 FACTOR 5

Variable Code Variable Code Variable Code Variable Code Variable Code

Common Equity L18 Total Current Liabilities L6 Deferred Taxes and investment credit

L10 Debt convertible preferred stock BS5 Preferred Stock L15

Common equity liquidation BS1 Total Liabilities L14 Plant, Property, & Equipment-

Gross A10 Total long term debt convertible BS4 Preferred Stock-Liquidation BS10

Cash and Equivalents A1 Debt in current liabilities L1 Plant, Property, & Equipment-

Net A7 Debt convertible and subordinated BS8 Preferred Stock Nonredeemable L17

Common equity tangible BS2 Accounts payable L3 Long-Term Debt L7 Long-term Debt L7 Total long term debt convertible BS4

Total current assets A6 Accounts receivable A17 Invested Capital BS9 CVT_DEBT

Invested Capital BS9 Total Debt L8 Total Assets A14 Total Assets A14 Notes Payable L2 LT_INV Cash A2 Total Assets A14

Capital Surplus L20 Current Liabilities Others L5

Common shares outstanding BS3 Total Inventory A4

FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT

Page 44: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

43

Table 2

Mean (Median) values of selected characteristics for decile portfolios sorted by Latent Factors (FIN_FLEX,

ST_CREDIT, LT_INV, CVT_DEBT, PSK_USE). LBTM is a log book to market ratio, before taking the log book to

market ratio follow the Fama and French (1992) construction. LSIZE is the log of the market value of equity that is

price times the common stocks outstanding at the June of year t-1. ACCR (accruals) equals the change in accounts

receivables plus the change in inventories plus the change in the other current assets minus the change in account

payable minus the change in other current liabilities minus depreciation and scaled by lagged total assets as defined

by Polk and Sapienza (2009). NOATA represents cumulative accruals as defined by Hirshleifer, et al. (2004).

ASSETG is the year-to-year change in total assets [(TASSETSt-TASSETSt-1)/TASSETSt-1] as defined by Cooper,

et al. (2008). The measure of profitability (ROA) is net income (COMPUSTAT item A178) divided by the total

assets (COMPUSTAT item A6). LEV is the sum of long-term debt and debt in current liabilities, scaled by total

assets as defined by Cooper, et al. (2008). I_A is the sum of change in inventories and change in gross property,

plant, and equipment (PPE) scaled by lagged total assets.The FIN_FLEX growth measure is the latent growth score

obtained via factor analysis procedures and is constituted of year to year change in balance sheet items including

common equity-total, invested capital, cash, cash & equivalents, capital surplus, etc. Similar is the construction of

other latent growth factors. The ST_CREDIT growth measure is constituted of items like current liabilities-total,

total liabilities, accounts payable, accounts receivable, total debt, and notes payable. LT_INV growths’ constituting

items are deferred taxes and investment ST_CREDIT; deferred taxes-balance sheet; plant, property, and equipment-

net; and Depreciation. The CVT_DEBT growth measure is comprised of debt convertible-preferred stock, total long

term debt convertible, debt convertible and subordinated, and long-term debt. The PSK_USE growth measure is

comprised of items like preferred stock, preferred stock-liquidation, and preferred stock-nonredeemable. For The

five factors, original input variables are estimated by ratio of change in balance sheet variables to lagged total assets

before processing through the factor analysis model.

FIN_FLEX Rank FIN_FLEX ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LEV LSIZE LBTM

Low Mean -0.597 0.070 0.585 -0.286 -0.162 5.932 0.224 4.161 0.444

Median -0.547 -0.136 0.450 -0.243 -0.087 -0.016 0.167 4.027 0.377

High Mean 1.296 1.420 0.851 0.048 0.027 3.636 0.091 5.022 0.314

Median 0.869 0.952 0.726 0.022 0.086 -0.021 0.023 4.944 0.259

ST_CREDIT Rank ST_CREDIT ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LEV LSIZE LBTM

Low Mean -0.755 0.361 0.729 -0.210 0.035 6.990 0.210 4.415 0.492

Median -0.659 0.025 0.648 -0.189 0.090 0.005 0.178 4.203 0.420

High Mean 0.840 0.870 0.919 -0.075 0.027 6.725 0.261 4.612 0.418

Median 0.683 0.450 0.826 -0.068 0.081 0.008 0.246 4.380 0.344

LT_INV Rank LT_INV ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LEV LSIZE LBTM

Low Mean -0.825 0.390 0.504 -0.203 -0.006 6.392 0.209 4.494 0.492

Median -0.729 -0.025 0.508 -0.193 0.063 -0.009 0.171 4.397 0.411

High Mean 1.664 1.016 1.245 -0.170 0.083 11.352 0.305 5.191 0.443

Median 1.291 0.613 1.129 -0.140 0.108 0.414 0.305 5.086 0.388

CVT_DEBT Rank CVT_DEBT ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LEV LSIZE LBTM

Low Mean -0.887 0.643 0.904 -0.185 0.063 9.562 0.221 5.097 0.429

Median -0.585 0.243 0.792 -0.161 0.108 0.168 0.191 4.990 0.362

High Mean 1.270 0.685 0.819 -0.139 0.015 9.475 0.307 5.045 0.439

Median 0.460 0.295 0.732 -0.117 0.078 0.061 0.310 4.943 0.370

PSK_USE Rank PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LEV LSIZE LBTM

Low Mean -0.513 0.678 0.909 -0.125 0.023 9.950 0.292 5.033 0.429

Median -0.281 0.354 0.825 -0.107 0.091 0.091 0.291 4.906 0.370

High Mean 0.450 0.835 0.761 -0.124 0.004 6.809 0.172 4.847 0.388

Median 0.253 0.347 0.664 -0.118 0.074 0.001 0.103 4.722 0.315

Page 45: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

44

Table 3

Pearson (Spearman) correlation coefficients between Latent Accounting Factors and other characteristics

FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE NOATA ASSETG ACCR ROA I_A LEV LSIZE LBTM MTB

FIN_FLEX 1 0.02005 -0.20465 0.03817 0.2149 0.07722 0.46622 0.27167 0.26404 -0.02038 -0.19403 0.12721 -0.16757 0.2102

ST_CREDIT 0.08387 1 -0.04687 0.01842 -0.03604 0.07994 0.27901 0.15342 -0.00955 -0.00952 0.06451 -0.01987 -0.07954 0.04666

LT_INV -0.06706 0.03981 1 -0.21918 -0.16921 0.39848 0.39325 0.05842 0.12061 0.11536 0.11763 0.13286 -0.07644 0.0692

CVT_DEBT 0.04754 -0.00153 -0.0035 1 -0.22483 -0.09258 -0.07251 -0.00172 -0.1147 -0.02739 0.10917 -0.06936 0.09866 -0.12295

PSK_USE 0.10303 -0.02447 -0.06163 -0.06731 1 -0.07508 0.02775 -0.01361 0.05741 -0.03611 -0.1557 -0.01241 -0.07312 0.08142

NOATA 0.20009 0.18928 0.56987 0.05922 0.00023 1 0.48256 0.14615 0.24693 0.11213 0.39349 0.00512 0.1017 -0.09499

ASSETG 0.72566 0.29339 0.41925 0.10978 0.05929 0.55216 1 0.40733 0.26435 0.03706 -0.02076 0.17118 -0.27589 0.27768

ACCR 0.34148 0.17014 0.05294 0.06959 -0.01102 0.16337 0.37994 1 -0.05452 -0.08208 -0.09519 0.01668 -0.17361 0.16158

ROA 0.05167 -0.01191 0.06346 -0.04052 -0.00983 0.25394 0.02589 -0.00414 1 0.18717 0.04104 0.34791 -0.15007 0.18632

I_A -0.05938 -0.01916 0.04901 -0.00534 -0.01039 0.03119 -0.03660 -0.08105 0.12480 1 0.36521 0.00691 0.15984 -0.14035

LEV -0.19621 0.09586 0.18621 0.16053 -0.06546 0.3103 -0.03306 -0.07311 0.09722 0.31144 1 0.01206 0.15797 -0.27547

LSIZE 0.02903 -0.04114 0.0689 0.00961 -0.01689 0.00558 0.0552 0.02618 0.28839 0.0078 -0.00521 1 -0.33467 0.35981

LBTM -0.1595 -0.07128 -0.06267 -0.02744 -0.02386 0.04351 -0.18991 -0.15255 0.02266 0.09872 0.13366 -0.3493 1 -0.84955

MTB 0.14586 0.02916 -0.01017 -0.00433 0.0011 -0.07226 0.1471 0.10815 -0.2026 -0.09808 -0.1733 0.14688 -0.37521 1

Page 46: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

45

Fig. 1a. Mean Profitability (A) and Mean monthly returns (B).

The figures show the mean profitability measured as net income divided by the total assets and the average

monthly raw returns for FIN_FLEX sorted portfolios 5 years prior the ranking year and 5 year post ranking period.

Returns are accumulated monthly raw returns starting 4 months after fiscal year end. We first sort and rank the data

sample on the lagged financial flexibility growth (FIN_FLEX) rate into decile growth portfolios every t year at the end

of June over 1985 to 2009. Using the June t asset growth cutoffs, we form portfolios that are held for one year from

July of t year to June of t+1 and then rebalanced.

-0.20

-0.15

-0.10

-0.05

0.00

0.05

0.10

-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 4 5

Me

an R

OA

Sorting Year

A Lowest FIN_FLEX Decile Highest FIN_FLEX Decile

0.00

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 4 5

Me

an M

on

thly

Re

turn

Sorting Year

B Lowest FIN_FLEX Decile Highest FIN_FLEX Decile

Page 47: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

46

Fig. 1b. Mean Profitability (A) and Mean monthly returns (B).

The figures show the mean profitability measured as net income divided by the total assets and the average

monthly raw returns for ST_CREDIT sorted portfolios 5 years prior the ranking year and 5 year post ranking period.

Returns are accumulated monthly raw returns starting 4 months after fiscal year end. We first sort and rank the data

sample on the lagged financial flexibility growth (ST_CREDIT) rate into decile growth portfolios every t year at the

end of June over 1985 to 2009. Using the June t asset growth cutoffs, we form portfolios that are held for one year

from July of t year to June of t+1 and then rebalanced.

0.00

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 4 5

Me

an R

OA

Sorting Year

A Lowest ST_CREDIT Decile Highest ST_CREDIT Decile

0.00

0.01

0.01

0.02

0.02

0.03

0.03

-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 4 5

Me

an M

on

thly

Re

turn

s

Sorting Year

B Lowest ST_CREDIT Decile Highest ST_CREDIT Decile

Page 48: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

47

Fig. 1c. Mean Profitability (A) and Mean monthly returns (B).

The figures show the mean profitability measured as net income divided by the total assets and the average

monthly raw returns for LT_INV sorted portfolios 5 years prior the ranking year and 5 year post ranking period.

Returns are accumulated monthly raw returns starting 4 months after fiscal year end. We first sort and rank the data

sample on the lagged financial flexibility growth (LT_INV) rate into decile growth portfolios every t year at the end of

June over 1985 to 2009. Using the June t asset growth cutoffs, we form portfolios that are held for one year from July

of t year to June of t+1 and then rebalanced.

-0.04

-0.02

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.10

0.12

-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 4 5

Me

an R

OA

Sorting Year

A Lowest LT_INV Decile Highest LT_INV Decile

0.00

0.01

0.01

0.02

0.02

0.03

0.03

-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 4 5

Me

an M

on

thly

Re

turn

s

Sorting Year

B Lowest LT_INV Decile Highest LT_INV Decile

Page 49: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

48

Fig. 1d. Mean Profitability (A) and Mean monthly returns (B).

The figures show the mean profitability measured as net income divided by the total assets and the average

monthly raw returns for CVT_DEBT sorted portfolios 5 years prior the ranking year and 5 year post ranking period.

Returns are accumulated monthly raw returns starting 4 months after fiscal year end. We first sort and rank the data

sample on the lagged financial flexibility growth (CVT_DEBT) rate into decile growth portfolios every t year at the

end of June over 1985 to 2009. Using the June t asset growth cutoffs, we form portfolios that are held for one year

from July of t year to June of t+1 and then rebalanced.

-0.02

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.10

-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 4 5

Me

an R

OA

Sorting Year

A Lowest CVT_DEBT Decile Highest CVT_DEBT Decile

0.00

0.01

0.01

0.02

0.02

0.03

0.03

-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 4 5

Me

an M

on

thly

Re

turn

s

Sorting Year

B Lowest CVT_DEBT Decile Highest CVT_DEBT Decile

Page 50: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

49

Fig. 1e. Mean Profitability (A) and Mean monthly returns (B).

The figures show the mean profitability measured as net income divided by the total assets and the average

monthly raw returns for PSK_USE sorted portfolios 5 years prior the ranking year and 5 year post ranking period.

Returns are accumulated monthly raw returns starting 4 months after fiscal year end. We first sort and rank the data

sample on the lagged financial flexibility growth (PSK_USE) rate into decile growth portfolios every t year at the end

of June over 1985 to 2009. Using the June t asset growth cutoffs, we form portfolios that are held for one year from

July of t year to June of t+1 and then rebalanced.

-0.04

-0.02

0.00

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 4 5

Me

an R

OA

Sorting Year

A Lowest PSK_USE Decile Highest PSK_USE Decile

0.00

0.01

0.01

0.02

0.02

0.03

0.03

0.04

0.04

-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 1 2 3 4 5

Me

an M

on

thly

Re

turn

s

Sorting Year

B Lowest PSK_USE Decile Highest PSK_USE Decile

Page 51: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

50

Table 4

Average monthly abnormal returns for Latent Factors (FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT, LT_INV, CVT_DEBT, PSK_USE) ranked extreme decile portfolios and hedge portfolio in 1, 2 and 3 years after portfolio formation are given in this table. For period of July 1985 to October 2009, we form monthly decile portfolios by ranking on

last year Latent Factor. There is 4-month lag between fiscal year end and the portfolio formation month. The time-series average of monthly equal (value) weighted

abnormal returns (the abnormal returns are the difference between the stock returns and size, book-t-market, and momentum matched benchmark portfolio returns) are reported for each decile and hedge portfolio with respective t-statistics. Hedge portfolio is created by going long in the lowest ranked Latent Factor portfolio and short

in the highest ranked Latent Factor portfolio. Comparatively, we report the alpha estimates (t-statistics) for CAPM, Fama and French (1993) three factor model, and

Carhart (1997) four factor model for both equal and value weighted hedge portfolios. The bold numbers indicate significance at less than 5% level.

Panel A: FIN_FLEX ranked portfolios

Equal weighted

t-values (Equal weighted)

Value weighted

t-values (Value weighted)

Large Firms raw (t+1) Adj(t+1) Adj(t+2) Adj(t+3) Raw( t+1) Adj(t+1) Adj(t+2) Adj(t+3)

Lowest 0.0112 -0.0004 -0.0016 -0.0037

11.54 -1.63 -4.39 -7.99

0.0110 -0.0002 -0.0010 -0.0021

12.03 -0.65 -2.10 -4.05

Highest 0.0116 -0.0003 0.0012 0.0019

8.24 -0.57 1.93 3.21

0.0110 0.0001 0.0016 0.0036

7.64 0.12 2.02 4.39

Hedge (L-H) -0.0004 -0.0001 -0.0028 -0.0057 -0.43 -0.17 -3.67 -6.77 0.0000 -0.0003 -0.0026 -0.0057 -0.02 -0.38 -2.55 -5.10

CAPM α -0.0003 0.0000 -0.0026 -0.0055

-0.31 -0.02 -3.42 -6.58

0.0001 -0.0001 -0.0023 -0.0055

0.11 -0.14 -2.28 -4.89

Three Factor α -0.0008 -0.0003 -0.0030 -0.0058

-0.90 -0.56 -3.80 -6.87

-0.0004 -0.0004 -0.0029 -0.0058

-0.40 -0.61 -2.80 -5.16

Four Factor α -0.0007 -0.0002 -0.0027 -0.0055 -0.77 -0.36 -3.40 -6.34 -0.0003 -0.0004 -0.0026 -0.0056 -0.27 -0.50 -2.47 -4.82

Small Firms

Lowest 0.0136 0.0014 0.0021 0.0028

11.30 4.05 4.33 5.19

0.0132 0.0012 0.0019 0.0030

11.18 3.43 3.86 5.67

Highest 0.0114 -0.0006 0.0002 0.0000

8.24 -1.16 0.28 0.04

0.0113 -0.0006 -0.0002 -0.0004

8.23 -1.29 -0.28 -0.48

Hedge (L-H) 0.0022 0.0020 0.0019 0.0027 2.41 3.16 2.24 2.80 0.0019 0.0018 0.0021 0.0035 2.05 2.78 2.29 3.17

CAPM α 0.0022 0.0019 0.0020 0.0027

2.42 3.10 2.26 2.74

0.0020 0.0018 0.0021 0.0035

2.06 2.75 2.32 3.15

Three Factor α 0.0017 0.0017 0.0017 0.0025

1.87 2.64 1.94 2.46

0.0016 0.0016 0.0018 0.0032

1.60 2.35 1.90 2.83

Four Factor α 0.0017 0.0017 0.0017 0.0025 1.80 2.63 1.91 2.46 0.0015 0.0016 0.0017 0.0032 1.48 2.27 1.85 2.77

Micro Firms

Lowest 0.0241 0.0051 0.0065 0.0078

12.56 8.35 8.86 9.54

0.0178 0.0035 0.0037 0.0048

10.01 5.64 4.86 5.24

Highest 0.0150 -0.0009 -0.0011 -0.0009

8.98 -2.32 -2.07 -1.58

0.0123 -0.0006 -0.0005 0.0000

7.95 -1.62 -1.09 0.05

Hedge (L-H) 0.0090 0.0060 0.0075 0.0086 10.46 8.24 8.26 9.67 0.0054 0.0041 0.0042 0.0048 6.57 5.71 4.68 4.98

CAPM α 0.0090 0.0060 0.0076 0.0086

10.35 8.13 8.22 9.55

0.0090 0.0060 0.0076 0.0086

10.35 8.13 8.22 9.55

Three Factor α 0.0089 0.0059 0.0078 0.0089

10.00 7.87 8.23 9.64

0.0089 0.0059 0.0078 0.0089

10.00 7.87 8.23 9.64

Four Factor α 0.0090 0.0061 0.0079 0.0088 9.87 7.86 8.13 9.32 0.0090 0.0061 0.0079 0.0088 9.87 7.86 8.13 9.32

All but Micro

Lowest 0.0127 0.0008 0.0009 0.0005

11.54 2.99 2.90 1.34

0.0113 0.0002 -0.0003 -0.0011

11.75 0.65 -0.72 -2.17

Highest 0.0111 -0.0005 0.0004 0.0006

8.39 -1.12 0.75 1.09

0.0115 0.0007 0.0029 0.0054

8.13 1.30 4.46 7.69

Hedge (L-H) 0.0016 0.0012 0.0005 -0.0001 1.99 2.45 0.91 -0.14 -0.0002 -0.0005 -0.0033 -0.0064 -0.19 -0.72 -3.78 -6.94

CAPM α 0.0016 0.0012 0.0006 0.0000

2.06 2.49 1.05 -0.06

-0.0001 -0.0004 -0.0031 -0.0062

-0.12 -0.57 -3.52 -6.71

Three Factor α 0.0011 0.0009 0.0002 -0.0004

1.38 1.87 0.41 -0.66

-0.0006 -0.0007 -0.0037 -0.0068

-0.59 -0.99 -4.29 -7.40

Four Factor α 0.0010 0.0009 0.0003 -0.0003 1.28 1.81 0.45 -0.44 -0.0006 -0.0007 -0.0035 -0.0067 -0.60 -0.98 -4.02 -7.11

Panel B: ST_CREDIT ranked portfolios

Equal weighted

t-values (Equal weighted)

Value weighted

t-values (Value weighted)

Large Firms raw (t+1) Adj(t+1) Adj(t+2) Adj(t+3)

Raw( t+1) Adj(t+1) Adj(t+2) Adj(t+3)

Lowest 0.0113 -0.0006 -0.0015 -0.0032

11.30 -2.30 -4.00 -7.38

0.0118 -0.0002 -0.0019 -0.0030

11.58 -0.52 -4.24 -5.78

Highest 0.0127 0.0010 0.0035 0.0039

12.03 4.28 8.53 7.27

0.0110 0.0004 0.0019 0.0032

10.85 1.54 4.45 5.65

Hedge (L-H) -0.0014 -0.0016 -0.0050 -0.0071 -2.47 -4.21 -8.19 -10.02 0.0008 -0.0006 -0.0038 -0.0062 1.41 -1.55 -6.42 -9.13

CAPM α -0.0013 -0.0016 -0.0047 -0.0069

-2.34 -3.99 -7.90 -9.75

0.0007 -0.0006 -0.0037 -0.0061

1.22 -1.55 -6.23 -8.91

Three Factor α -0.0014 -0.0016 -0.0049 -0.0074

-2.40 -3.97 -8.08 -10.35

0.0006 -0.0006 -0.0039 -0.0065

1.12 -1.66 -6.52 -9.46

Four Factor α -0.0013 -0.0015 -0.0050 -0.0073 -2.24 -3.76 -7.91 -10.04 0.0006 -0.0007 -0.0040 -0.0065 1.01 -1.87 -6.40 -9.22

Small Firms

Lowest 0.0112 -0.0015 -0.0016 -0.0028

9.73 -3.95 -2.76 -4.75

0.0111 -0.0015 -0.0017 -0.0035

9.66 -3.82 -2.88 -5.51

Highest 0.0127 0.0006 0.0012 0.0011

10.08 1.55 2.21 1.77

0.0129 0.0008 0.0012 0.0020

10.38 1.94 2.15 3.29

Hedge (L-H) -0.0015 -0.0022 -0.0028 -0.0039 -1.97 -3.20 -2.88 -3.87 -0.0018 -0.0023 -0.0029 -0.0055 -2.45 -3.40 -3.05 -5.58

CAPM α -0.0015 -0.0023 -0.0028 -0.0039

-1.95 -3.27 -2.90 -3.84

-0.0018 -0.0024 -0.0030 -0.0055

-2.41 -3.45 -3.07 -5.52

Three Factor α -0.0016 -0.0023 -0.0029 -0.0042

-2.01 -3.27 -2.87 -3.96

-0.0019 -0.0025 -0.0031 -0.0058

-2.50 -3.48 -3.14 -5.74

Four Factor α -0.0014 -0.0021 -0.0026 -0.0040 -1.73 -2.93 -2.60 -3.71 -0.0017 -0.0023 -0.0029 -0.0057 -2.17 -3.17 -2.87 -5.44

Micro Firms

Lowest 0.0189 0.0000 0.0008 0.0008

12.40 -0.10 1.99 1.93

0.0137 -0.0006 -0.0003 -0.0004

9.42 -1.17 -0.50 -0.67

Highest 0.0165 -0.0018 -0.0031 -0.0042

10.52 -4.34 -5.79 -7.98

0.0125 -0.0019 -0.0028 -0.0036

8.36 -4.46 -4.56 -5.35

Hedge (L-H) 0.0024 0.0017 0.0039 0.0050 3.54 2.77 5.60 7.17 0.0013 0.0013 0.0025 0.0032 1.62 1.83 2.94 3.60

CAPM α 0.0023 0.0016 0.0038 0.0049

3.34 2.56 5.43 6.98

0.0012 0.0012 0.0025 0.0033

1.56 1.75 2.91 3.67

Three Factor α 0.0024 0.0018 0.0039 0.0049

3.43 2.77 5.53 6.90

0.0015 0.0015 0.0027 0.0033

1.81 2.12 3.05 3.64

Four Factor α 0.0024 0.0017 0.0039 0.0048 3.33 2.60 5.38 6.60 0.0015 0.0015 0.0028 0.0034 1.77 2.00 3.08 3.67

All but Micro

Lowest 0.0115 -0.0009 -0.0011 -0.0022

10.96 -3.47 -3.07 -6.50

0.0116 -0.0002 -0.0015 -0.0024

11.52 -0.64 -3.84 -4.84

Highest 0.0127 0.0009 0.0023 0.0023

11.22 3.08 5.62 4.91

0.0115 0.0006 0.0019 0.0031

11.33 2.40 4.62 5.58

Hedge (L-H) -0.0012 -0.0018 -0.0034 -0.0046 -2.07 -3.90 -5.26 -6.78 0.0001 -0.0008 -0.0034 -0.0055 0.18 -2.09 -6.18 -7.55

CAPM α -0.0012 -0.0018 -0.0033 -0.0045

-2.01 -3.87 -5.10 -6.59

0.0000 -0.0008 -0.0033 -0.0054

0.07 -2.07 -6.01 -7.36

Three Factor α -0.0013 -0.0018 -0.0034 -0.0048

-2.08 -3.83 -5.14 -6.91

0.0000 -0.0009 -0.0035 -0.0058

0.03 -2.10 -6.15 -7.85

Four Factor α -0.0012 -0.0017 -0.0033 -0.0047 -1.84 -3.52 -4.86 -6.61 0.0000 -0.0009 -0.0035 -0.0057 0.04 -2.20 -5.97 -7.56

Page 52: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

51

Panel C: LT_INV ranked portfolios

Equal weighted

t-values (Equal weighted)

Value weighted

t-values (Value weighted)

Large Firms raw (t+1) Adj(t+1) Adj(t+2) Adj(t+3)

Raw( t+1) Adj(t+1) Adj(t+2) Adj(t+3) Lowest 0.0112 -0.0004 -0.0014 -0.0024

10.79 -1.66 -3.94 -5.48

0.0100 -0.0006 -0.0014 -0.0027

10.64 -2.06 -3.43 -5.16

Highest 0.0104 -0.0015 -0.0019 -0.0025

9.48 -4.57 -3.87 -4.72

0.0084 -0.0021 -0.0038 -0.0031

8.10 -5.49 -6.55 -4.74

Hedge (L-H) 0.0008 0.0011 0.0005 0.0000 1.60 2.69 0.81 0.06 0.0016 0.0015 0.0024 0.0004 2.73 3.27 3.63 0.50

CAPM α 0.0008 0.0011 0.0006 0.0001

1.63 2.73 0.97 0.15

0.0017 0.0016 0.0026 0.0006

2.86 3.48 3.87 0.67

Three Factor α 0.0007 0.0010 0.0004 0.0000

1.40 2.52 0.59 0.07

0.0016 0.0015 0.0023 0.0004

2.68 3.24 3.39 0.48 Four Factor α 0.0007 0.0010 0.0004 0.0000 1.31 2.44 0.58 -0.02 0.0015 0.0014 0.0024 0.0004 2.35 3.00 3.41 0.50

Small Firms

Lowest 0.0121 -0.0003 -0.0009 -0.0023

10.49 -0.98 -1.87 -3.45

0.0123 -0.0001 -0.0011 -0.0021

10.83 -0.35 -2.06 -2.80

Highest 0.0117 -0.0005 0.0018 0.0019

10.23 -1.33 3.32 3.28

0.0117 -0.0003 0.0021 0.0027

10.28 -0.93 3.89 4.40

Hedge (L-H) 0.0004 0.0002 -0.0027 -0.0042 0.53 0.31 -3.18 -4.12 0.0006 0.0002 -0.0032 -0.0048 0.87 0.38 -3.65 -4.37

CAPM α 0.0002 0.0000 -0.0028 -0.0044

0.27 0.05 -3.28 -4.25

0.0004 0.0001 -0.0033 -0.0049

0.60 0.13 -3.76 -4.51

Three Factor α 0.0003 0.0000 -0.0029 -0.0044

0.37 0.03 -3.23 -4.17

0.0006 0.0001 -0.0032 -0.0048

0.74 0.19 -3.60 -4.31

Four Factor α 0.0002 -0.0001 -0.0030 -0.0046 0.23 -0.15 -3.25 -4.27 0.0004 0.0000 -0.0034 -0.0051 0.54 -0.07 -3.67 -4.42

Micro Firms

Lowest 0.0207 0.0015 0.0026 0.0027

13.66 5.02 5.51 5.15

0.0161 0.0013 0.0029 0.0031

10.90 3.66 5.48 5.04

Highest 0.0135 -0.0030 -0.0051 -0.0055

9.59 -8.37 -10.41 -9.97

0.0107 -0.0026 -0.0045 -0.0046

8.08 -6.54 -8.71 -7.71

Hedge (L-H) 0.0072 0.0045 0.0076 0.0082 10.77 8.21 9.52 8.63 0.0054 0.0039 0.0074 0.0077 7.33 6.31 8.77 7.79

CAPM α 0.0072 0.0045 0.0075 0.0081

10.59 8.07 9.33 8.49

0.0054 0.0038 0.0073 0.0076

7.23 6.23 8.59 7.63

Three Factor α 0.0071 0.0044 0.0073 0.0079

10.22 7.69 8.88 8.10

0.0055 0.0039 0.0071 0.0074

7.22 6.17 8.21 7.30

Four Factor α 0.0068 0.0042 0.0073 0.0080 9.70 7.18 8.65 7.98 0.0052 0.0036 0.0070 0.0074 6.67 5.61 7.91 7.06

All but Micro

Lowest 0.0113 -0.0006 -0.0013 -0.0024

10.52 -2.68 -4.17 -5.75

0.0095 -0.0011 -0.0015 -0.0033

9.69 -3.51 -3.06 -6.01

Highest 0.0107 -0.0011 -0.0003 -0.0004

9.99 -3.84 -0.81 -1.03

0.0085 -0.0018 -0.0034 -0.0020

8.70 -5.12 -5.83 -3.03

Hedge (L-H) 0.0006 0.0005 -0.0010 -0.0020 1.15 1.26 -1.73 -2.93 0.0010 0.0006 0.0019 -0.0013 1.96 1.55 3.28 -1.61

CAPM α 0.0005 0.0004 -0.0010 -0.0020

0.92 1.02 -1.81 -2.98

0.0009 0.0006 0.0020 -0.0012

1.82 1.53 3.42 -1.44

Three Factor α 0.0005 0.0004 -0.0011 -0.0020

0.87 0.94 -1.93 -2.91

0.0008 0.0005 0.0017 -0.0014

1.62 1.24 2.90 -1.75

Four Factor α 0.0004 0.0003 -0.0012 -0.0022 0.79 0.81 -2.00 -3.08 0.0008 0.0005 0.0018 -0.0014 1.50 1.13 2.87 -1.69

Panel D: CVT_DEBT ranked portfolios

Equal weighted

t-values (Equal weighted)

Value weighted

t-values (Value weighted)

Large Firms raw (t+1) Adj(t+1) Adj(t+2) Adj(t+3)

Raw( t+1) Adj(t+1) Adj(t+2) Adj(t+3) Lowest 0.0115 0.0000 0.0004 -0.0002

10.19 -0.14 1.02 -0.48

0.0103 -0.0003 0.0018 0.0027

9.14 -0.66 3.18 4.31

Highest 0.0102 -0.0009 -0.0025 -0.0029

10.27 -3.06 -5.84 -5.51

0.0087 -0.0016 -0.0035 -0.0037

9.05 -5.16 -7.13 -6.57

Hedge (L-H) 0.0013 0.0008 0.0029 0.0027 2.61 1.83 5.09 3.99 0.0016 0.0013 0.0053 0.0065 2.37 2.41 7.90 8.90

CAPM α 0.0014 0.0008 0.0029 0.0027

2.59 1.81 5.03 4.02

0.0016 0.0012 0.0052 0.0064

2.34 2.26 7.69 8.72

Three Factor α 0.0014 0.0009 0.0031 0.0029

2.71 1.95 5.28 4.19

0.0016 0.0012 0.0051 0.0063

2.38 2.22 7.37 8.36

Four Factor α 0.0014 0.0009 0.0032 0.0029 2.53 1.82 5.24 4.20 0.0015 0.0013 0.0051 0.0063 2.20 2.19 7.23 8.16

Small Firms

Lowest 0.0118 -0.0005 0.0000 -0.0002

10.43 -1.25 0.10 -0.33

0.0116 -0.0007 0.0001 -0.0001

10.06 -1.60 0.16 -0.11 Highest 0.0118 0.0002 0.0009 0.0016

10.10 0.65 2.02 3.13

0.0115 0.0001 0.0004 0.0011

9.87 0.24 0.88 1.91

Hedge (L-H) 0.0000 -0.0007 -0.0008 -0.0018 0.04 -1.24 -1.25 -2.33 0.0000 -0.0008 -0.0003 -0.0011 0.05 -1.25 -0.42 -1.32

CAPM α 0.0000 -0.0007 -0.0007 -0.0017

0.07 -1.15 -1.15 -2.19

0.0001 -0.0007 -0.0002 -0.0010

0.13 -1.12 -0.26 -1.16

Three Factor α 0.0001 -0.0007 -0.0006 -0.0017

0.08 -1.17 -0.91 -2.12

0.0001 -0.0008 0.0000 -0.0009

0.14 -1.20 -0.04 -1.02

Four Factor α 0.0003 -0.0005 -0.0004 -0.0014 0.44 -0.83 -0.57 -1.79 0.0003 -0.0006 0.0002 -0.0007 0.47 -0.89 0.22 -0.82

Micro Firms

Lowest 0.0166 -0.0009 -0.0001 -0.0004

10.95 -2.39 -0.25 -0.69

0.0133 -0.0007 -0.0003 -0.0013

9.25 -1.84 -0.53 -2.13

Highest 0.0180 -0.0001 0.0000 -0.0003

11.93 -0.22 -0.02 -0.69

0.0140 -0.0001 0.0001 0.0008

9.74 -0.22 0.27 1.29

Hedge (L-H) -0.0015 -0.0008 -0.0001 -0.0001 -2.87 -1.81 -0.21 -0.16 -0.0008 -0.0006 -0.0004 -0.0021 -1.43 -1.27 -0.67 -2.78

CAPM α -0.0014 -0.0008 0.0000 0.0000

-2.73 -1.70 -0.06 -0.02

-0.0008 -0.0006 -0.0003 -0.0020

-1.43 -1.22 -0.50 -2.62

Three Factor α -0.0013 -0.0007 0.0001 0.0001

-2.44 -1.45 0.11 0.19

-0.0008 -0.0007 -0.0004 -0.0020

-1.48 -1.37 -0.68 -2.62

Four Factor α -0.0013 -0.0007 0.0000 0.0001 -2.45 -1.44 0.01 0.20 -0.0007 -0.0005 -0.0003 -0.0018 -1.20 -1.04 -0.54 -2.31

All but Micro

Lowest 0.0115 -0.0004 -0.0001 -0.0004

10.63 -1.87 -0.26 -1.07

0.0098 -0.0007 0.0014 0.0023

8.88 -1.70 2.59 3.79

Highest 0.0109 -0.0002 -0.0005 -0.0002

10.36 -0.88 -1.68 -0.66

0.0087 -0.0013 -0.0034 -0.0033

9.13 -4.33 -6.32 -5.69

Hedge (L-H) 0.0006 -0.0003 0.0004 -0.0002 1.55 -0.82 0.91 -0.35 0.0011 0.0006 0.0048 0.0056 2.09 1.41 7.58 8.50

CAPM α 0.0006 -0.0002 0.0004 -0.0001

1.60 -0.73 0.95 -0.20

0.0012 0.0006 0.0047 0.0055

2.12 1.35 7.43 8.39

Three Factor α 0.0006 -0.0002 0.0006 0.0000

1.69 -0.62 1.34 0.04

0.0013 0.0007 0.0047 0.0055

2.23 1.43 7.25 8.14

Four Factor α 0.0007 -0.0001 0.0008 0.0002 1.90 -0.38 1.60 0.37 0.0013 0.0007 0.0048 0.0056 2.25 1.57 7.25 8.12

Page 53: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

52

Panel E: PSK_USE ranked portfolios

Equal weighted

t-values (Equal weighted)

Value weighted

t-values (Value weighted)

Large Firms raw (t+1) Adj(t+1) Adj(t+2) Adj(t+3)

Raw( t+1) Adj(t+1) Adj(t+2) Adj(t+3) Lowest 0.0110 -0.0004 -0.0011 -0.0022

11.14 -1.43 -2.64 -3.95

0.0110 0.0003 -0.0007 -0.0005

11.12 0.79 -1.17 -0.74

Highest 0.0125 0.0009 0.0019 0.0019

9.38 1.97 4.01 3.77

0.0120 0.0006 0.0023 0.0027

8.99 1.12 3.71 4.51

Hedge (L-H) -0.0015 -0.0013 -0.0030 -0.0040 -1.91 -2.28 -4.74 -5.40 -0.0010 -0.0002 -0.0030 -0.0033 -1.06 -0.33 -3.51 -3.25

CAPM α -0.0015 -0.0013 -0.0029 -0.0040

-1.87 -2.30 -4.66 -5.33

-0.0009 -0.0002 -0.0029 -0.0032

-1.00 -0.34 -3.40 -3.17

Three Factor α -0.0016 -0.0013 -0.0030 -0.0040

-2.02 -2.38 -4.69 -5.20

-0.0009 -0.0001 -0.0028 -0.0029

-0.94 -0.18 -3.22 -2.85

Four Factor α -0.0015 -0.0012 -0.0030 -0.0041 -1.90 -2.14 -4.57 -5.18 -0.0008 -0.0002 -0.0028 -0.0031 -0.85 -0.25 -3.08 -2.89

Small Firms

Lowest 0.0128 0.0005 -0.0004 0.0000

10.54 1.45 -0.72 -0.07

0.0125 0.0005 -0.0001 0.0003

10.42 1.53 -0.30 0.56

Highest 0.0116 -0.0008 -0.0018 -0.0023

9.35 -2.21 -3.78 -4.58

0.0116 -0.0009 -0.0019 -0.0022

9.21 -2.21 -3.56 -3.80

Hedge (L-H) 0.0012 0.0013 0.0014 0.0022 1.76 2.43 1.67 2.49 0.0009 0.0014 0.0017 0.0025 1.31 2.47 1.99 2.73

CAPM α 0.0012 0.0013 0.0015 0.0022

1.77 2.33 1.70 2.42

0.0010 0.0014 0.0019 0.0025

1.38 2.46 2.11 2.71

Three Factor α 0.0009 0.0010 0.0010 0.0016

1.24 1.86 1.20 1.81

0.0005 0.0011 0.0012 0.0017

0.77 1.90 1.38 1.90

Four Factor α 0.0009 0.0012 0.0010 0.0016 1.24 2.02 1.08 1.69 0.0007 0.0013 0.0012 0.0017 0.89 2.16 1.32 1.81

Micro Firms

Lowest 0.0167 -0.0007 -0.0015 -0.0014

10.55 -1.86 -2.99 -2.72

0.0128 -0.0010 -0.0016 -0.0016

8.92 -2.94 -3.15 -2.57

Highest 0.0173 0.0000 0.0015 0.0022

10.83 -0.05 2.90 4.35

0.0130 -0.0006 0.0003 0.0009

8.34 -1.61 0.56 1.55

Hedge (L-H) -0.0006 -0.0007 -0.0030 -0.0036 -0.89 -1.29 -4.03 -4.96 -0.0001 -0.0004 -0.0019 -0.0024 -0.26 -0.82 -2.85 -3.02

CAPM α -0.0005 -0.0007 -0.0029 -0.0036

-0.76 -1.19 -3.87 -4.88

-0.0001 -0.0004 -0.0019 -0.0025

-0.16 -0.75 -2.77 -3.02

Three Factor α -0.0007 -0.0007 -0.0028 -0.0036

-0.99 -1.31 -3.72 -4.85

-0.0002 -0.0004 -0.0019 -0.0025

-0.39 -0.83 -2.68 -3.04

Four Factor α -0.0008 -0.0008 -0.0031 -0.0038 -1.07 -1.36 -3.96 -5.02 -0.0003 -0.0005 -0.0022 -0.0028 -0.56 -1.01 -3.02 -3.29

All but Micro

Lowest 0.0120 0.0002 -0.0006 -0.0012

11.09 0.89 -1.65 -2.74

0.0110 0.0004 -0.0005 -0.0003

10.92 1.09 -0.98 -0.53

Highest 0.0113 -0.0005 -0.0005 -0.0005

9.14 -1.41 -1.17 -1.19

0.0113 -0.0002 0.0013 0.0015

8.11 -0.32 1.92 2.45

Hedge (L-H) 0.0007 0.0007 -0.0001 -0.0007 1.19 1.62 -0.16 -1.05 -0.0004 0.0006 -0.0018 -0.0019 -0.38 0.86 -2.22 -2.09

CAPM α 0.0007 0.0006 -0.0001 -0.0006

1.19 1.50 -0.09 -1.00

-0.0003 0.0006 -0.0018 -0.0018

-0.32 0.82 -2.14 -2.01

Three Factor α 0.0004 0.0004 -0.0004 -0.0010

0.67 1.02 -0.57 -1.54

-0.0003 0.0006 -0.0017 -0.0016

-0.27 0.95 -2.03 -1.76

Four Factor α 0.0004 0.0005 -0.0004 -0.0011 0.62 1.12 -0.67 -1.65 -0.0003 0.0005 -0.0018 -0.0018 -0.35 0.71 -2.03 -1.93

Page 54: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

53

Table 5: Annual buy-and-hold returns by year

This table reports the time series mean of annual buy and hold returnsfor two extreme latent factors

(FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT, LT_INV, CVT_DEBT, PSK_USE) ranked decile portfolios and their spread

portfolio (Low-minus-High) for the period of 1986 to 2010. We obtain both equal- and value-weighted

portfolios returns for three capitalization levels and all stock (excludes the micro stocks) portfolios. The

capitalization levels are constructed following NYSE capitalization break points as defined in Fama and

French (1992). The sorting latent factors are defined in header of table 2. The annual returns are given in

percentages.

Equal-weighted FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE

All but

Micro

Low 11.0% 8.5% 9.8% 7.2% 7.9%

High 4.0% 6.2% 5.9% 7.2% 6.8%

Low minus High 7.0% 2.3% 4.0% -0.1% 1.0%

LARGE

Low 14.3% 10.6% 10.4% 9.0% 9.6%

High 7.9% 9.0% 7.9% 8.7% 9.6%

Low minus High 6.5% 1.6% 2.4% 0.4% 0.0%

SMALL

Low 8.3% 7.1% 9.6% 6.0% 6.6%

High 1.5% 4.7% 5.1% 6.2% 5.2%

Low minus High 6.9% 2.4% 4.5% -0.1% 1.4%

MICRO

Low 22.7% 16.1% 21.1% 12.1% 12.2%

High 6.8% 10.0% 7.7% 15.2% 13.2%

Low minus High 15.9% 6.1% 13.3% -3.1% -1.1%

Value-weighted FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE

All but

Micro

Low 14.2% 9.1% 7.3% 8.8% 10.8%

High 5.7% 10.3% 7.2% 7.8% 12.4%

Low minus High 8.5% -1.1% 0.0% 1.1% -1.6%

LARGE

Low 14.0% 10.1% 8.3% 10.1% 11.4%

High 9.8% 10.9% 8.7% 8.3% 12.0%

Low minus High 4.1% -0.8% -0.5% 1.8% -0.5%

SMALL

Low 8.6% 7.3% 9.5% 5.9% 5.7%

High 1.8% 4.6% 5.1% 5.2% 5.6%

Low minus High 6.8% 2.7% 4.5% 0.7% 0.2%

MICRO

Low 13.9% 8.8% 13.9% 8.5% 7.4%

High 3.0% 5.0% 4.9% 8.7% 7.6%

Low minus High 11.0% 3.8% 9.0% -0.2% -0.2%

Page 55: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

54

Table 6: Fama-MacBeth Regressions of Annual Stock Returns on Asset Growth Rates and Other Variables

In this table, the annual geometric compounding future returns are regressed on the observed Latent growth measures and the other growth measures. For every year for period of

1985 to 2009 we run Fama-MacBeth (1973) cross-sectional regressions at the individual stock level. We run regressions for two types of model.

(1)

(2)

The first model is labeled as a base regression model; and in second model the base regression model is augmented by control variables. FIN_FLEX growth measure is the latent

growth score obtained via factor analysis procedures and it proxy for financial flexibility. Similar is the construction of other latent growth factors. ST_CREDIT growth measure

proxy for short-term credit of firms. LT_INV growths proxy for long-term capital investment. CVT_DEBT growth measure proxy for convertible debt usage asset. PSK_USE

growth measure for preferred stock usage. For The five factors, original input variables are estimated by ratio of change in balance sheet variables to lagged total assets before

processing through the factor analysis model. LSIZE is the log market value of equity at June of year t-1. LBTM is the log book equity to market equity (Fama and French, 1992).

BHRET6 is the 6-month buy-and-hold returns over January (t) to June (t). BHRET36 is the 3-year buy-and-hold returns over July (t-3) to June (t). In case of controls we have

ASSETG as a measure of the total asset growth that the year-to-year change in total assets [(TASSETSt-TASSETSt-1)/TASSETSt-1] (Cooper, et al. 2008). ACCR (accruals)

equals the change in accounts receivables plus the change in inventories plus the change in the other current assets minus the change in account payable minus the change in other

current liabilities minus depreciation and scaled by lagged total assets as defined by Polk and Sapienza (2009). NOATA represents cumulative accruals as defined by Hirshleifer et

al. (2004). The measure of profitability (ROA) is net income (COMPUSTAT item A178) divided by the total assets (COMPUSTAT item A6). I_A is the sum of change in

inventories and change in gross property, plant, and equipment (PPE) scaled by lagged total assets. The table shows average slope coefficients and t-statistics with

significance as boldface below 5%.

Panel A: Full Sample

Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.1676 -0.0649 -0.0129 -0.0302 -0.0104 0.0053

0.009

9.95 -11.17 -2.95 -9.56 -7.96 1.52

Model 2 0.1766 -0.0487 -0.0130 -0.0270 -0.0088 0.0029 0.0013

0.010

10.67 -5.26 -2.51 -5.57 -6.51 0.80 0.14

Model 3 0.2259 -0.0511 -0.0013 -0.0005 -0.0081 0.0049

-0.0830

0.014

8.84 -8.05 -0.24 -0.10 -5.29 1.45

-4.62

Model 4 0.1559 -0.0551 -0.0079 -0.0288 -0.0089 0.0033

-0.0582

0.012

8.78 -9.50 -1.88 -8.97 -6.98 0.96

-6.41

Model 5 0.1753 -0.0588 -0.0187 -0.0274 -0.0119 -0.0003

-0.1201 -0.0001

0.021

9.38 -13.02 -5.50 -9.80 -8.52 -0.09

-3.12 -1.95

Model 6 0.2637 -0.0492 -0.0112 -0.0189 -0.0074 0.0040

0.0683 -0.0260

0.028

7.34 -10.60 -2.88 -6.07 -5.68 1.20

4.16 -7.76

Model 7 0.1496 -0.0667 -0.0110 -0.0322 -0.0072 0.0112

-0.0330 -0.0150 0.019

10.34 -13.46 -2.62 -11.13 -4.96 2.11 -6.99 -0.90

Panel B: Large Sample

Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.1192 -0.0277 0.0047 -0.0144 0.0020 0.0378

0.027

9.98 -2.94 0.82 -4.61 0.84 5.84

Model 2 0.1560 0.0660 0.0457 0.0387 0.0113 0.0376 -0.1061

0.033

12.15 4.20 6.15 4.73 4.30 5.88 -6.29

Model 3 0.1707 -0.0208 0.0103 0.0121 0.0053 0.0321

-0.0740

0.033

9.74 -2.02 1.76 1.88 2.04 5.54

-5.65

Model 4 0.1164 -0.0237 0.0070 -0.0158 0.0027 0.0393

-0.0207

0.034

Page 56: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

55

9.04 -2.78 1.30 -5.07 1.21 6.08

-1.95

Model 5 0.0999 -0.0256 0.0041 -0.0134 0.0025 0.0393

0.0787 0.0002

0.037

7.06 -2.87 0.74 -4.31 1.13 5.99

2.90 4.90

Model 6 0.1015 -0.0169 0.0050 -0.0134 0.0017 0.0353

0.0384 0.0012

0.051

3.41 -1.93 0.88 -4.53 0.72 5.75

2.33 0.44

Model 7 0.1053 -0.0126 0.0103 -0.0125 0.0018 0.0193

-0.0064 0.0658 0.060

10.08 -1.06 1.83 -4.65 0.74 2.59 -2.13 3.14

Panel C: Small Sample

Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.1173 -0.0429 -0.0159 -0.0066 -0.0090 -0.0317

0.017

8.68 -7.15 -2.69 -1.74 -5.18 -4.27

Model 2 0.1274 -0.0210 -0.0158 0.0044 -0.0078 -0.0383 -0.0140

0.020

9.75 -1.74 -1.80 0.77 -3.94 -5.11 -1.08

Model 3 0.1347 -0.0406 -0.0117 0.0004 -0.0089 -0.0347

-0.0190

0.024

7.64 -5.58 -1.96 0.08 -4.73 -4.29

-1.45

Model 4 0.1102 -0.0364 -0.0098 -0.0057 -0.0083 -0.0318

-0.0386

0.022

7.68 -7.38 -1.63 -1.49 -4.73 -4.43

-3.35

Model 5 0.0993 -0.0441 -0.0115 -0.0096 -0.0068 -0.0353

0.1354 0.0002

0.033

6.48 -8.12 -2.01 -2.58 -3.91 -4.50

4.65 3.99

Model 6 0.1352 -0.0372 -0.0141 -0.0053 -0.0091 -0.0314

0.0285 -0.0048

0.026

3.89 -7.87 -2.35 -1.36 -5.14 -4.31

1.68 -1.19

Model 7 0.1033 -0.0233 -0.0143 -0.0057 -0.0085 -0.0323

-0.0121 0.0326 0.034

8.71 -2.19 -2.21 -1.85 -4.06 -3.06 -4.94 1.76

Panel D: Micro Sample

Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.2044 -0.0664 -0.0165 -0.0321 -0.0153 0.0204

0.006

10.11 -11.63 -3.54 -8.55 -5.81 3.96

Model 2 0.2093 -0.0587 -0.0175 -0.0338 -0.0147 0.0178 0.0093

0.007

10.36 -5.80 -2.84 -6.14 -5.40 3.52 0.92

Model 3 0.2765 -0.0472 -0.0012 0.0036 -0.0148 0.0223

-0.1033

0.012

8.99 -8.25 -0.20 0.55 -5.44 4.33

-4.90

Model 4 0.1905 -0.0558 -0.0117 -0.0299 -0.0138 0.0172

-0.0681

0.009

9.07 -9.33 -2.54 -7.97 -5.23 3.25

-7.30

Model 5 0.2042 -0.0592 -0.0210 -0.0297 -0.0178 0.0119

-0.1044 0.0003

0.017

10.09 -14.04 -5.22 -8.97 -6.08 2.41

-2.74 2.73

Model 6 0.4031 -0.0427 -0.0136 -0.0183 -0.0151 0.0128

0.0659 -0.0657

0.024

10.24 -8.18 -2.97 -4.90 -5.67 2.52

3.77 -14.34

Model 7 0.1750 -0.0840 -0.0168 -0.0353 -0.0114 0.0294

-0.0565 -0.0246 0.016

10.29 -15.92 -3.40 -10.18 -3.81 3.59 -8.31 -1.43

Panel E: Sub-Sample (Nov-1985 to Oct-1997)

Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.1423 -0.0418 -0.0159 -0.0425 -0.0085 0.0136

0.006

9.17 -11.61 -5.68 -19.43 -6.61 3.91

Model 2 0.1457 -0.0429 -0.0198 -0.0454 -0.0087 0.0111 0.0171

0.007

9.36 -4.32 -3.50 -10.14 -6.10 3.10 1.29

Page 57: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

56

Model 3 0.1913 -0.0288 -0.0061 -0.0218 -0.0074 0.0182

-0.0695

0.009

9.55 -5.70 -1.72 -6.20 -5.68 5.55

-5.54

Model 4 0.1329 -0.0313 -0.0116 -0.0406 -0.0073 0.0125

-0.0463

0.009

7.78 -7.34 -4.96 -17.65 -5.49 3.50

-3.67

Model 5 0.1650 -0.0445 -0.0222 -0.0423 -0.0084 0.0128

-0.0551

-

0.00003

0.015

8.40 -11.94 -8.15 -18.91 -5.03 3.19

-1.32 -0.33

Model 6 0.1543 -0.0319 -0.0126 -0.0353 -0.0087 0.0133

0.0865 -0.0133

0.021

4.71 -9.62 -5.14 -15.96 -6.86 3.77

5.15 -4.16

Model 7 0.1437 -0.0641 -0.0167 -0.0398 -0.0069 0.0278

-0.0152 0.0449 0.012

9.39 -17.10 -5.37 -16.51 -4.78 6.95 -6.10 4.87

Panel F: Sub-Sample (Nov-1997 to June-2010)

Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.1926 -0.0876 -0.0099 -0.0181 -0.0122 -0.0029

0.011

6.49 -8.21 -1.21 -3.16 -5.43 -0.49

Model 2 0.2071 -0.0544 -0.0063 -0.0088 -0.0089 -0.0052 -0.0143

0.012

7.16 -3.49 -0.73 -1.06 -3.88 -0.85 -1.12

Model 3 0.2599 -0.0730 0.0034 0.0204 -0.0088 -0.0082

-0.0962

0.019

5.57 -6.46 0.34 2.00 -3.19 -1.46

-2.87

Model 4 0.1786 -0.0784 -0.0043 -0.0171 -0.0105 -0.0057

-0.0698

0.014

5.77 -7.56 -0.53 -2.95 -4.84 -0.98

-5.38

Model 5 0.1833 -0.0698 -0.0160 -0.0159 -0.0146 -0.0104

-0.1699 -0.0002

0.027

6.22 -9.49 -2.84 -3.59 -6.98 -2.03

-2.84 -2.19

Model 6 0.3717 -0.0662 -0.0099 -0.0027 -0.0061 -0.0051

0.0503 -0.0384

0.034

5.95 -7.89 -1.34 -0.50 -2.68 -0.90

1.79 -6.78

Model 7 0.1555 -0.0692 -0.0054 -0.0247 -0.0075 -0.0052

-0.0505 -0.0741 0.026

6.34 -7.58 -0.70 -4.78 -2.99 -0.54 -5.72 -2.36

Page 58: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

57

Table 7: Asset Growth Rates and Industry Effect.

This table reports industry effect in the return predictability of the latent growth factors and other growth measures. The dependent annual compounding geometric future returns

are regressed on the base variables for the period of 1985 to 2009. The data set is partitioned into 11 industry sub-samples.

(1)

(2)

Model 1 includes only latent asset growth factors as independent variables and Model 2 includes other accounting growth variables (ASSETG, NOATA, ROA), log of market size,

and log book-to-market ratio (see, table 2 header for construction of these variables). The 10 Fama-French Industry groups are defined on the Ken French's website,

http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data_library.html). NoDur represent consumer non-durables that include food, tobacco, textiles, apparel, leather, and toys

industries. Durbl represent consumer durables that include cars, TV’s, furniture, and household appliances. Manuf represents manufacturing that includes machinery, trucks,

planes, office furniture, paper, and commercial printing industries. Energy includes oil, gas, and coal extraction and products industries. Chems includes chemicals and allied

products industries. BusEq represents business equipment that includes computers, software, and electronic equipment industries. Telcm includes telephone and television

transmission industries. Utils represents utilities. Shops include wholesale, retail, and some services (laundries, repair shops) industries. Hlth include healthcare, medical

equipment, and drug industries. Others include mines, construction, building material, transportation, hotels, business service, and entertainment industries. The table shows

average slope coefficients and t-statistics with significance as boldface below 5%.

Panel A: NODUR Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.1116 -0.1001 -0.0226 -0.0462 -0.0238 -0.0300

0.015

7.63 -7.89 -1.86 -7.98 -4.08 -1.83

Model 2 -0.0413 -0.0134 -0.0189 -0.0273 -0.0157 -0.0292 0.1351

0.018

-1.41 -0.66 -0.60 -1.60 -2.20 -1.76 7.73

Model 3 0.1509 -0.0973 -0.0100 -0.0276 -0.0224 -0.0266

-0.0515

0.018

9.93 -6.85 -0.83 -2.86 -3.45 -1.65

-3.00

Model 4 0.0904 -0.0766 -0.0123 -0.0411 -0.0216 -0.0317

-0.1029

0.022

6.14 -5.70 -1.01 -6.80 -3.77 -1.94

-7.06

Model 5 0.1135 -0.0994 -0.0202 -0.0483 -0.0338 -0.0336

-0.0590 0.0003

0.030

6.91 -7.84 -1.64 -8.16 -5.54 -2.00

-1.25 2.47

Model 6 0.1299 -0.0901 -0.0276 -0.0369 -0.0225 -0.0303

0.0630 -0.0105

0.037

5.61 -6.75 -2.39 -6.90 -3.91 -1.92

4.07 -4.08

Model 7 0.0928 -0.1305 -0.0346 -0.0504 -0.0222 -0.0599

-0.0313 -0.0338

0.033 6.84 -5.59 -2.45 -6.62 -3.53 -2.69 -8.27 -1.18

Panel B: DURBL Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.1218 -0.1423 0.1028 -0.0178 -0.0025 0.2060

0.021

5.76 -5.91 2.67 -1.49 -0.22 3.26

Page 59: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

58

Model 2 0.1630 -0.0013 0.2062 0.0899 0.0144 0.2755 -0.3409

0.024

4.89 -0.02 4.36 2.66 1.14 3.86 -4.33

Model 3 0.2023 -0.1165 0.1230 0.0153 -0.0041 0.2027

-0.1027

0.024

6.45 -4.90 3.44 0.91 -0.35 3.46

-4.07

Model 4 0.1166 -0.1653 0.1075 -0.0197 -0.0056 0.2390

-0.0076

0.023

5.59 -5.49 2.79 -1.54 -0.46 3.41

-0.31

Model 5 0.0945 -0.2378 0.1083 -0.0161 -0.0061 0.2725

0.1229 0.0002

0.040

4.49 -7.64 2.76 -1.24 -0.55 3.66

2.65 1.32

Model 6 0.1220 -0.1326 0.0990 -0.0098 -0.0027 0.1886

0.0643 -0.0055

0.042

3.67 -5.70 2.60 -0.83 -0.23 3.05

3.13 -1.71

Model 7 0.0507 -0.1916 0.1225 -0.0091 0.0416 0.3065

-0.0367 -0.0003

0.048 2.97 -4.48 3.57 -0.65 3.32 3.38 -2.63 -0.01

Panel C: MANUF Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.1505 -0.0862 -0.0206 -0.0325 -0.0113 0.0647

0.011

9.72 -6.87 -2.33 -8.38 -2.42 5.62

Model 2 0.1814 -0.0074 0.0086 0.0150 -0.0035 0.0584 -0.0758

0.012

10.05 -0.28 0.66 1.13 -0.73 4.82 -2.68

Model 3 0.1600 -0.0906 -0.0117 -0.0311 -0.0137 0.0627

-0.0092

0.016

6.54 -6.40 -1.25 -4.25 -2.74 5.62

-0.43

Model 4 0.1424 -0.0715 -0.0127 -0.0286 -0.0103 0.0672

-0.0455

0.014

8.50 -5.36 -1.43 -6.93 -2.22 5.71

-3.49

Model 5 0.1623 -0.0873 -0.0157 -0.0349 -0.0132 0.0619 -0.0806 -0.0001 0.021

8.95 -7.29 -1.84 -8.97 -2.74 5.04 -1.78 -1.02

Model 6 0.1892 -0.0587 -0.0173 -0.0205 -0.0108 0.0574

0.1029 -0.0183

0.030

7.30 -5.07 -1.92 -5.21 -2.36 5.01

7.78 -7.24

Model 7 0.1303 -0.0737 0.0003 -0.0339 -0.0135 0.0488

-0.0519 0.0122

0.027 9.20 -4.33 0.03 -9.16 -3.23 3.47 -7.29 0.70

Panel D: ENERGY Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.2104 -0.1098 0.0457 -0.0277 -0.0231 0.0504

0.017

10.75 -10.07 3.23 -6.38 -4.10 4.04

Model 2 0.2227 -0.1001 0.0447 -0.0236 -0.0214 0.0439 0.0002

0.018

11.16 -5.06 2.62 -2.36 -3.60 3.52 0.01

Model 3 0.1649 -0.1157 0.0485 -0.0473 -0.0244 0.0457

0.0695

0.022

10.28 -8.36 3.33 -6.08 -4.20 3.72

3.43

Model 4 0.2145 -0.1134 0.0412 -0.0254 -0.0224 0.0603

0.0090

0.024

10.42 -9.53 2.95 -5.61 -3.93 4.82

0.66

Model 5 0.2309 -0.1130 0.0381 -0.0297 -0.0203 0.0470

-0.1197 -0.0004

0.031

9.82 -10.97 2.64 -6.92 -3.41 3.74

-2.23 -4.25

Model 6 0.3012 -0.1061 0.0371 -0.0242 -0.0210 0.0418

0.1027 -0.0256

0.042

Page 60: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

59

9.64 -10.24 2.53 -5.66 -4.12 3.45

6.02 -8.02

Model 7 0.1693 -0.1185 0.0092 -0.0273 -0.0122 0.0193

-0.0276 -0.0481 0.039

9.10 -7.11 0.76 -5.60 -2.64 1.29 -5.11 -1.98

Panel E: CHEMICALS Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.1367 -0.0217 0.0055 -0.0282 0.0875 0.0607

0.053

9.30 -0.97 0.30 -2.76 4.94 2.23

Model 2 0.1216 -0.0517 0.0198 -0.0028 0.0645 0.0606 -0.0579

0.061

5.36 -0.75 0.67 -0.10 3.15 2.11 -0.81

Model 3 0.0849 -0.0258 0.0080 -0.0442 0.0829 0.0553

0.0830

0.058

4.85 -1.04 0.45 -4.03 4.76 2.19

3.57

Model 4 0.1175 -0.0055 0.0157 -0.0244 0.0844 0.0615

-0.0754

0.057

7.66 -0.23 0.84 -2.31 4.83 2.28

-5.07

Model 5 0.1267 -0.0414 -0.0024 -0.0336 0.0808 0.0462

0.0109 -0.0001

0.085

7.48 -1.80 -0.13 -3.39 4.47 1.58

0.25 -1.16

Model 6 0.0751 0.0056 0.0139 -0.0179 0.0907 0.0653

0.1057 0.0030

0.092

2.64 0.24 0.74 -1.76 4.89 2.52

4.07 1.07

Model 7 0.1279 -0.0095 0.0705 -0.0348 0.0668 0.0993

-0.0328 -0.0407

0.077 9.28 -0.38 3.35 -3.54 3.45 2.73 -4.37 -1.47

Panel F:BusEq Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.2053 -0.0691 -0.0278 -0.0323 -0.0036 -0.0116

0.010

8.12 -7.72 -2.84 -6.02 -1.49 -1.37

Model 2 0.2178 -0.0487 -0.0297 -0.0258 -0.0016 -0.0149 0.0117

0.013

8.71 -2.83 -2.69 -2.55 -0.60 -1.71 0.53

Model 3 0.2498 -0.0560 -0.0207 -0.0102 -0.0037 -0.0086

-0.0738

0.013

8.68 -6.43 -2.06 -1.77 -1.44 -1.03

-5.87

Model 4 0.1908 -0.0569 -0.0239 -0.0284 -0.0028 -0.0155

-0.0834

0.012

7.67 -6.61 -2.48 -5.29 -1.15 -1.83

-8.20

Model 5 0.2109 -0.0548 -0.0367 -0.0289 -0.0044 -0.0187

-0.1419 -0.00002

0.018

7.95 -7.58 -4.10 -5.73 -1.81 -2.16

-3.73 -0.14

Model 6 0.3005 -0.0474 -0.0168 -0.0182 -0.0009 -0.0100

0.0961 -0.0289

0.028

7.20 -6.43 -1.77 -3.40 -0.37 -1.19

5.67 -7.82

Model 7 0.1749 -0.0797 -0.0196 -0.0453 0.0000 0.0216

-0.0342 -0.0610

0.020 8.11 -10.33 -2.58 -6.36 0.01 1.87 -6.09 -3.16

Panel G: TELCM Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.1776 -0.1323 -0.0748 -0.0309 -0.0627 -0.0545

0.045

8.91 -7.09 -3.35 -3.08 -4.58 -2.72

Model 2 0.2527 0.0563 0.0168 0.0955 -0.0378 -0.0218 -0.2968

0.050

7.79 1.07 0.52 3.75 -2.41 -0.68 -4.76

Page 61: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

60

Model 3 0.2575 -0.1335 -0.0497 -0.0061 -0.0476 -0.0623

-0.1213

0.056

7.09 -7.45 -2.14 -0.38 -3.45 -2.90

-3.92

Model 4 0.1699 -0.1481 -0.0870 -0.0287 -0.0606 -0.0545

-0.0076

0.060

7.08 -8.17 -3.74 -2.94 -4.53 -2.72

-0.25

Model 5 0.2207 -0.0769 -0.0371 -0.0212 -0.0690 -0.0676

-0.4025 -0.0003

0.086

8.00 -5.38 -1.68 -2.05 -5.30 -3.37

-4.25 -1.72

Model 6 0.3403 -0.1165 -0.0380 -0.0184 -0.0587 -0.0306

0.0456 -0.0313

0.088

7.60 -6.60 -2.10 -1.87 -4.88 -1.46

1.76 -6.53

Model 7 0.0904 -0.2178 -0.0356 -0.0620 -0.0500 -0.0537

-0.0624 -0.0343

0.105 5.57 -6.07 -1.14 -6.07 -3.41 -1.72 -3.83 -0.82

Panel H: SHOPS

Intercept

FIN_FLE

X

ST_CREDI

T

LT_IN

V

CVT_DEB

T

PSK_US

E

ASSET

G

NOAT

A ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE

BHRET3

6

BHRE

T6

Adj R-

Sq

Model 1 0.1406 -0.0788 -0.0155 -0.0754 -0.0117 -0.0239

0.015

9.24 -7.94 -1.72 -8.76 -2.01 -1.84

Model 2 0.1440 -0.0860 -0.0221 -0.0854 -0.0125 -0.0330 0.0273

0.017

9.38 -2.58 -1.52 -4.62 -2.62 -2.10 0.93

Model 3 0.2092 -0.0604 0.0011 -0.0480 -0.0092 -0.0288

-0.0926

0.016

10.25 -5.73 0.12 -5.22 -1.57 -2.20

-6.84

Model 4 0.1382 -0.0727 -0.0093 -0.0763 -0.0090 -0.0258

-0.0250

0.017

8.60 -6.49 -0.98 -8.83 -1.56 -1.99

-1.68

Model 5 0.1683 -0.0703 -0.0277 -0.0640 -0.0175 -0.0283

-0.2532 -0.00001

0.026

9.22 -6.81 -3.23 -8.26 -3.35 -2.23

-2.23 -0.07

Model 6 0.1721 -0.0395 -0.0153 -0.0512 -0.0128 -0.0210

0.1056 -0.0171

0.038

6.50 -5.19 -1.66 -6.57 -2.25 -1.64

6.89 -5.98

Model 7 0.1298 -0.0644 0.0030 -0.0864 -0.0160 -0.0307

-0.0398 0.0143

0.032 9.51 -4.98 0.28 -8.27 -2.17 -2.17 -6.07 0.60

Panel I: HLTH Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.2080 -0.0735 -0.0198 -0.0100 -0.0107 0.0098

0.010

9.21 -11.09 -1.88 -1.36 -3.60 0.99

Model 2 0.2059 -0.0788 -0.0266 -0.0228 0.0101 -0.0115 0.0110

0.010

9.46 -3.37 -2.15 -1.92 0.96 -3.25 0.57

Model 3 0.2383 -0.0697 -0.0121 0.0109 -0.0080 0.0133

-0.0516

0.019

7.14 -9.20 -1.11 1.00 -2.62 1.20

-2.33

Model 4 0.1990 -0.0611 -0.0171 -0.0058 -0.0089 0.0043

-0.0760

0.011

9.10 -9.60 -1.68 -0.83 -2.92 0.43

-4.02

Model 5 0.2091 -0.0747 -0.0125 -0.0094 -0.0098 0.0061

-0.0103 -0.0005

0.034

9.81 -11.31 -1.25 -1.42 -3.53 0.59

-0.28 -3.80

Model 6 0.2940 -0.0526 -0.0055 0.0031 -0.0021 0.0138

0.1745 -0.0302

0.039

5.97 -9.91 -0.55 0.43 -0.77 1.34

7.59 -6.00

Page 62: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

61

Model 7 0.2049 -0.0674 -0.0403 -0.0027 -0.0098 0.0189

-0.0336 -0.0077

0.027 9.56 -9.59 -3.97 -0.28 -2.73 1.44 -6.86 -0.46

Panel J: OTHERS Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG NOATA ACCR ROA I_A LBTM LSIZE BHRET36 BHRET6 Adj R-Sq

Model 1 0.1487 -0.0538 -0.0131 -0.0259 -0.0073 -0.0156

0.015

9.67 -8.54 -1.29 -4.94 -2.84 -1.82

Model 2 0.1567 -0.0416 -0.0142 -0.0287 -0.0059 -0.0160 0.0074

0.016

10.07 -3.16 -1.29 -4.15 -2.28 -1.94 0.51

Model 3 0.2170 -0.0388 -0.0032 0.0118 0.0007 -0.0157

-0.0965

0.022

9.11 -5.58 -0.28 1.40 0.22 -1.87

-5.17

Model 4 0.1292 -0.0398 -0.0072 -0.0260 -0.0042 -0.0199

-0.1025

0.020

8.19 -6.33 -0.71 -4.97 -1.62 -2.24

-7.39

Model 5 0.1497 -0.0462 -0.0184 -0.0234 -0.0073 -0.0056

-0.0928 0.0003

0.029

8.94 -8.61 -1.96 -4.53 -2.62 -0.64

-2.29 3.54

Model 6 0.2376 -0.0373 -0.0141 -0.0148 -0.0042 -0.0190

0.0753 -0.0265

0.027

7.26 -6.31 -1.44 -2.90 -1.49 -2.32

5.47 -8.30

Model 7 0.1340 -0.0668 -0.0002 -0.0303 -0.0011 0.0140

-0.0216 0.0011 0.028

9.24 -7.43 -0.02 -6.95 -0.42 1.16 -4.46 0.06

Page 63: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

62

Table 8: Annual Cross-sectional Regressions

Table reports the results for OLS regressions of annual future stock returns across annual cross-sections starting from 1985 to

2009 on latent growth and the total asset growth measure (ASSETG).

(1)

(2)

The LatentGrowth include FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT, LT_INV, CVT_DEBT, and PSK_USE (see, table 2 header for construction

of these variables). The similar results are also obtained with controls like log market size, log book-to-market ratio, accounting

accruals, cumulative accruals, and profitability measure (not reported here). Table shows annual average slope coefficients with

significance (*** for 1%, ** for 5% and * for 10%) based on t-statistics.

Panel A: Full Sample

Intercept FIN_FLEX ST_CREDIT LT_INV CVT_DEBT PSK_USE ASSETG Adj R-Sq

M1-1985 0.0154 -0.0248 -0.0344 -0.0437 -0.0038 0.0271

0.006

0.28 -5.46 -5.92 -5.66 -1.63 4.72

M2-1985 0.0052 -0.0537 -0.0497 -0.0662 -0.0068 0.0199 0.0567 0.006

0.10 -7.35 -4.65 -4.53 -2.22 4.57 3.01

M1-1986 0.0698 -0.0247 -0.0300 -0.0113 -0.0120 0.0099

0.002

1.42 -5.23 -15.33 -2.73 -12.20 3.04

M2-1986 0.0613 -0.0471 -0.0421 -0.0232 -0.0145 0.0089 0.0259 0.002

1.23 -3.66 -7.68 -2.78 -13.85 2.72 2.28

M1-1987 0.1120 -0.0051 -0.0415 -0.0090 -0.0148 -0.0150

0.001

4.78 -1.55 -5.80 -3.43 -8.30 -3.15

M2-1987 0.0712 -0.1153 -0.0991 -0.0688 -0.0262 -0.0173 0.1486 0.003

3.96 -6.26 -15.17 -6.16 -8.03 -3.56 6.32

M1-1988 -0.0424 -0.0144 -0.0371 -0.0282 0.0072 0.0654

0.004

-1.08 -2.26 -6.96 -6.05 1.75 11.08

M2-1988 -0.0300 0.0226 -0.0134 0.0003 0.0118 0.0736 -0.0719 0.004

-0.75 2.02 -1.96 0.04 2.86 11.46 -6.47

M1-1989 0.3993 -0.0682 0.0321 -0.0476 -0.0140 0.0144

0.002

6.87 -5.21 2.01 -9.05 -2.65 3.13

M2-1989 0.4012 -0.0626 0.0367 -0.0432 -0.0136 0.0169 -0.0112 0.002

6.63 -1.57 1.45 -2.24 -2.00 2.82 -0.21

M1-1990 0.1787 -0.0445 -0.0428 -0.0313 -0.0094 0.0535

0.004

11.60 -7.50 -8.22 -3.25 -2.76 5.42

M2-1990 0.1377 -0.2271 -0.1408 -0.1433 -0.0179 0.0368 0.3658 0.011

9.11 -11.26 -12.21 -9.26 -6.28 3.76 7.64

M1-1991 0.2586 -0.1254 -0.0190 -0.0649 0.0112 0.0321

0.016

10.36 -14.40 -2.33 -9.59 6.09 3.05

M2-1991 0.2341 -0.2227 -0.0510 -0.0956 0.0100 0.0393 0.1169 0.016

8.96 -15.21 -4.10 -13.93 5.83 3.69 7.02

M1-1992 0.0506 -0.0754 -0.0172 -0.0553 -0.0064 -0.0594

0.016

3.48 -15.11 -6.03 -38.11 -2.42 -10.87

M2-1992 0.0647 -0.0281 -0.0050 -0.0338 -0.0033 -0.0607 -0.0538 0.016

4.40 -2.32 -1.62 -7.52 -1.09 -10.96 -5.96

M1-1993 0.3451 0.0020 -0.0010 -0.0753 -0.0253 -0.0387

0.004

17.89 0.29 -0.26 -12.41 -10.12 -4.36

M2-1993 0.3827 0.1041 0.0371 -0.0356 -0.0227 -0.0447 -0.1178 0.004

23.73 6.55 5.83 -4.78 -8.14 -4.58 -5.01

M1-1994 0.1520 -0.0589 -0.0311 -0.0504 0.0016 0.0142

0.008

5.38 -14.01 -7.12 -21.73 0.27 1.75

M2-1994 0.1744 -0.0028 -0.0086 -0.0204 0.0051 0.0127 -0.0790 0.008

5.95 -0.37 -2.24 -8.11 0.87 1.56 -10.23

M1-1995 0.2487 -0.0526 0.0105 -0.0372 -0.0207 0.0407

0.005

9.05 -5.38 2.31 -12.38 -4.57 5.78

M2-1995 0.2786 0.0205 0.0380 -0.0052 -0.0156 0.0362 -0.0832 0.006

9.81 1.11 4.01 -0.50 -4.88 4.81 -3.51

M1-1996 -0.0803 -0.0099 0.0207 -0.0559 -0.0159 0.0190

0.006

-2.44 -0.93 3.24 -13.98 -8.00 4.92

M2-1996 -0.0331 0.0974 0.0604 -0.0101 -0.0102 0.0111 -0.0923 0.008

Page 64: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

63

-0.97 4.68 8.33 -1.32 -5.22 2.55 -8.84

M1-1997 0.4490 0.0666 0.0022 -0.0859 -0.0105 -0.0137

0.003

5.45 2.05 0.29 -8.38 -1.67 -0.79

M2-1997 0.4712 0.1174 0.0222 -0.0553 -0.0054 -0.0143 -0.0547 0.003

6.41 5.74 2.07 -2.19 -0.78 -0.85 -1.70

M1-1998 0.1347 -0.0451 -0.1035 -0.0866 -0.0071 -0.0058

0.009

2.00 -3.70 -9.67 -2.96 -0.91 -0.24

M2-1998 0.1686 0.0341 -0.0740 -0.0259 0.0001 0.0049 -0.0995 0.010

2.25 1.06 -16.58 -1.57 0.02 0.19 -3.84

M1-1999 0.0576 -0.2320 0.0448 0.0018 -0.0428 -0.0207

0.020

1.36 -14.49 5.70 0.27 -14.31 -1.85

M2-1999 0.1311 -0.0230 0.0740 0.0662 -0.0329 -0.0332 -0.1283 0.024

3.31 -2.43 10.35 11.28 -11.34 -3.10 -20.26

M1-2000 -0.0955 -0.1336 0.0217 -0.0714 -0.0367 -0.0065

0.034

-4.48 -6.24 2.55 -8.03 -12.76 -1.45

M2-2000 -0.0390 0.0145 0.0590 -0.0164 -0.0167 -0.0194 -0.1142 0.038

-1.50 1.60 7.65 -5.69 -6.96 -5.91 -5.17

M1-2001 0.8368 -0.3702 0.1991 -0.0957 -0.0136 0.0487

0.024

9.51 -10.35 6.24 -7.55 -0.91 2.00

M2-2001 0.8072 -0.5167 0.0781 -0.1983 -0.0315 0.0447 0.2778 0.024

9.44 -11.68 1.70 -14.07 -1.86 1.80 6.29

M1-2002 0.1883 0.0056 -0.0478 0.0134 -0.0113 0.0596

0.003

5.18 0.34 -2.11 1.24 -4.29 13.84

M2-2002 0.2012 0.0723 0.0002 0.0712 -0.0062 0.0597 -0.1326 0.004

5.98 2.29 0.01 2.97 -2.56 13.66 -4.30

M1-2003 0.2061 -0.0528 0.0318 0.0444 -0.0059 -0.0097

0.004

7.86 -15.22 2.44 9.11 -1.36 -0.91

M2-2003 0.2067 -0.0510 0.0332 0.0451 -0.0056 -0.0095 -0.0021 0.004

8.09 -6.58 2.12 6.24 -1.16 -0.86 -0.27

M1-2004 0.1144 -0.0772 0.0298 0.0311 -0.0269 0.0490

0.008

7.57 -10.72 1.48 6.20 -6.85 4.65

M2-2004 0.1833 0.1224 0.1209 0.0958 0.0051 0.0509 -0.1641 0.010

10.79 6.45 5.02 12.39 0.86 4.78 -11.61

M1-2005 0.0049 -0.0397 -0.1034 0.0538 -0.0210 -0.1319

0.012

0.11 -11.77 -4.73 8.22 -4.66 -10.01

M2-2005 -0.0174 -0.1009 -0.1292 0.0106 -0.0301 -0.1313 0.0686 0.014

-0.54 -2.49 -8.04 0.37 -8.40 -10.01 1.60

M1-2006 -0.3577 -0.0107 -0.0915 0.0049 0.0050 0.0572

0.009

-9.33 -1.05 -8.02 0.30 2.11 4.99

M2-2006 -0.3606 -0.0185 -0.0962 0.0011 0.0041 0.0564 0.0067 0.009

-8.95 -1.00 -13.16 0.05 2.53 4.60 0.73

M1-2007 0.4789 -0.0888 -0.0841 0.0098 0.0101 0.0072

0.004

3.30 -2.76 -5.05 0.45 1.02 0.62

M2-2007 0.4508 -0.1668 -0.1164 -0.0259 0.0018 0.0086 0.0707 0.005

2.97 -6.02 -6.03 -0.79 0.20 0.73 2.53

M1-2008 0.2734 -0.0800 -0.0100 -0.0344 0.0097 -0.0769

0.005

12.05 -5.47 -1.16 -3.38 3.84 -13.47

M2-2008 0.2623 -0.1444 -0.0391 -0.0740 0.0068 -0.0906 0.1118 0.006

11.55 -4.09 -2.54 -3.17 2.17 -11.40 2.98

M1-2009 0.0155 -0.0477 0.3153 -0.0308 0.0483 -0.0602

0.006

4.00 -30.79 4.97 -5.73 19.40 -3.70

M2-2009 0.3237 -0.0039 -0.0572 -0.0074 0.0158 0.0554 -0.0843 0.004

5.34 -0.23 -3.75 -0.55 3.99 11.45 -2.92

Page 65: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

64

Table 9: Profitability Standard Clustered Error Regression

The table reports the standard clustered error regressions of Profitability measure (ROA) on latent

growth measures and other firm growth measures and related characteristics. The study period

spread over 25 years that is 1985 to 2009 with 821736 firm-month observations for non-financial

data sample.

(1)

(2)

The header of Table 2 defines the both LatentGrowth (include FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT, LT_INV,

CVT_DEBT, and PSK_USE) and Controls (include LSIZE, LBTM, ASSETG, NOATA, ACCR,

LEV, BHRET6, and BHRET36). We report standard clustered errors along with their parameter

estimates and t-statistics for each variable. There are 7685 numbers of clusters. Standard errors are

clustered by firms.

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

Intercept -0.112*** -0.096*** -0.201*** -0.115*** -0.125*** -0.110***

(-13.76) (-11.78) (-20.31) (-14.31) (-14.48) (-13.53)

FIN_FLEX 0.027*** 0.069*** 0.007** 0.029*** 0.032*** 0.027***

(8.89) (16.07) (2.28) (9.46) (10.35) (8.92)

ST_CREDIT -0.005** 0.014*** -0.027*** -0.003* -0.009*** -0.005***

(-2.45) (5.58) (-12.66) (-1.66) (-4.68) (-2.59)

LT_INV 0.016*** 0.041*** -0.034*** 0.017*** 0.012*** 0.016***

(12.38) (17.76) (-15.96) (12.63) (9.53) (12.26)

CVT_DEBT -0.012*** -0.008*** -0.018*** -0.012*** -0.016*** -0.012***

(-12.50) (-7.80) (-17.75) (-12.11) (-15.77) (-12.57)

PSK_USE -0.016*** -0.011*** -0.019*** -0.016*** -0.015*** -0.016***

(-4.74) (-3.41) (-5.80) (-4.83) (-4.49) (-4.75)

ASSETG

-0.059***

(-13.91)

NOATA

0.157***

(24.61)

ACCR

-0.016***

(-3.01)

LEV

0.087***

(11.59)

I_A

0.000***

(3.14)

LBTM 0.103*** 0.102*** 0.074*** 0.102*** 0.096*** 0.102***

(15.17) (15.06) (12.71) (15.02) (14.76) (15.08)

LSIZE 0.027*** 0.027*** 0.027*** 0.027*** 0.026*** 0.026***

(34.12) (34.18) (35.04) (34.26) (34.02) (32.40)

BHRET36 0.017*** 0.018*** 0.015*** 0.017*** 0.017*** 0.017***

(11.01) (11.56) (10.69) (11.04) (11.03) (11.01)

BHRET6 -0.032*** -0.034*** -0.026*** -0.033*** -0.033*** -0.032***

(-15.12) (-15.93) (-13.16) (-15.27) (-15.45) (-14.94)

Adj R-Sq 0.140 0.146 0.202 0.141 0.147 0.140

Page 66: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

65

Table 10: Firm Value Standard Clustered Error Regression

The table reports the standard clustered error regressions of firm value proxy by Tobin’s Q. It is the market

value of the firm that is market equity plus total assets minus book equity and divided by total assets as

defined in Hou and Robinson (2006).

(1)

(2)

The header of Table 2 defines the both LatentGrowth (include FIN_FLEX, ST_CREDIT, LT_INV,

CVT_DEBT, PSK_USE) and Controls (include LSIZE, ASSETG, NOATA, ACCR, LEV, BHRET6,

BHRET36). The study period spread over 25 years that is 1985 to 2009 with 821736 firm-month

observations for non-financial data sample. We report standard clustered errors along with their parameter

estimates and t-statistics for each variable. There are 7685 numbers of clusters. Standard errors are clustered

by firms.

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5 Model 6

Intercept 1.143*** 1.028*** 2.193*** 1.262*** 1.646*** 1.028***

(25.95) (20.39) (26.87) (27.70) (32.28) (23.24)

FIN_FLEX 0.451*** 0.139* 0.627*** 0.380*** 0.296*** 0.425***

(8.81) (1.91) (12.18) (7.23) (5.69) (8.30)

ST_CREDIT 0.020 -0.116** 0.224*** -0.025 0.133*** 0.0280

(0.53) (-2.24) (5.54) (-0.65) (3.49) (0.74)

LT_INV -0.169*** -0.353*** 0.309*** -0.181*** -0.059*** -0.158***

(-8.39) (-7.86) (10.30) (-9.03) (-3.03) (-7.92)

CVT_DEBT -0.033* -0.064*** 0.016 -0.043** 0.066*** -0.033*

(-1.80) (-3.27) (0.88) (-2.36) (3.58) (-1.84)

PSK_USE -0.122* -0.154** -0.096 -0.112* -0.149** -0.121*

(-1.83) (-2.26) (-1.45) (-1.69) (-2.24) (-1.81)

ASSETG

0.439***

(4.73)

NOATA

-1.480***

(-16.69)

ACCR

0.491***

(6.11)

LEV

-2.473***

(-23.50)

I_A

-0.010***

(-18.25)

LSIZE 0.142*** 0.143*** 0.130*** 0.140*** 0.143*** 0.185***

(15.76) (15.84) (14.58) (15.86) (16.59) (19.02)

BHRET36 0.468*** 0.458*** 0.476*** 0.463*** 0.449*** 0.459***

(13.06) (12.81) (13.19) (12.97) (12.85) (12.97)

BHRET6 0.638*** 0.652*** 0.612*** 0.652*** 0.676*** 0.637***

(13.35) (13.54) (12.94) (13.47) (13.60) (13.23)

Adj R-Sq 0.130 0.132 0.151 0.132 0.151 0.137

Page 67: Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance Policies, and Return …econfin.massey.ac.nz/school/documents/seminarseries/... · 2013-06-30 · Latent Accounting Growth, Corporate Finance

66


Recommended