+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones...

Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones...

Date post: 24-Sep-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 5 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
36
Life and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36
Transcript
Page 1: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Life and Growth

Charles I. Jones

Stanford GSB

Life and Growth – p.1/36

Page 2: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

“Certain events quite within the realm of possibility, such as a major

asteroid collision, global bioterrorism, abrupt global warming —

even certain lab accidents— could have unimaginably terrible

consequences up to and including the extinction of the human

race... I am not a Green, an alarmist, an apocalyptic visionary, a

catastrophist, a Chicken Little, a Luddite, an anticapitalist, or even a

pessimist. But... I have come to believe that what I shall be calling

the ‘catastrophic risks’ are real and growing...”

Life and Growth – p.2/36

Page 3: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Should we switch on the Large Hadron Collider?

• Physicists have considered the possibility that collidingparticles together at energies not seen since the Big Bangcould cause a major disaster (mini black hole, strangelets).

• Conclude that the probability is tiny.

• But how large does it have to be before we would not takethe risk?

• As economic growth makes us richer, should our decisionchange?

Life and Growth – p.3/36

Page 4: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Growth involves costs as well as benefits

• Benefits | Costs

◦ Nuclear power | Nuclear holocaust

◦ Biotechnology | Bioterror

◦ Nanotechnology | Nano-weapons

◦ Coal power | Global warming

◦ Internal combustion engine | Pollution

◦ Radium, thalidomide, lead paint, asbestos

• Technologies (new pharmaceuticals, medical equipment,airbags, pollution scrubbers) can also save lives

How do considerations of life and death affect the theory of

economic growth and technological change?

Life and Growth – p.4/36

Page 5: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

The “Russian Roulette” Model

New ideas raise consumption,

but a tiny probability of a disaster...

Life and Growth – p.5/36

Page 6: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Simple Model

• Single agent born at the start of each period

• Endowed with stock of ideas ⇒ consumption c, utilty u(c)

• Only decision: to research or not to research

◦ Research:

With (high) probability 1− π, get a new idea thatraises consumption by growth rate g.

But, with small probability π, disaster kills the agent.

◦ Stop: Consumption stays at c, no disaster.

Life and Growth – p.6/36

Page 7: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

• Expected utility for the two options:

UResearch = (1− π)u(c1) + π · 0 = (1− π)u(c1), c1 = c(1 + g)

UStop = u(c)

• Taking a first-order Taylor expansion around u(c), agent

undertakes research if

(1− π)u′(c)gc > πu(c)

• Rearranging:

g >π

1− π·u(c)

u′(c)c

Life and Growth – p.7/36

Page 8: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Three Cases

• Consider CRRA utility:

u(c) = u+c1−γ

1− γ

u is a key parameter

• Three cases:

◦ 0 < γ < 1

◦ γ > 1

◦ log utility (γ = 1)

Life and Growth – p.8/36

Page 9: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Case 1: 0 < γ < 1

g >π

1− π·u(c)

u′(c)c

• The value of life relative to consumption:

u(c)

u′(c)c= ucγ−1 +

1

1− γ.

• u not important, so set u = 0

⇒u(c)

u′(c)c= 1/(1− γ)

Exponential growth, with rare disasters.

Life and Growth – p.9/36

Page 10: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Case 2: γ > 1

• Notice that we’ve implicitly normalized the utility from deathto be zero (in writing the lifetime expected utility function)

◦ So flow utility must be positive for consumer to prefer life

• But γ > 1 implies u(c) negative if u = 0:

u(c) = u+c1−γ

1− γ

Example: γ = 2 implies u(c) = −1/c.

• Therefore u > 0 is required in this case.

Life and Growth – p.10/36

Page 11: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Case 2: γ > 1 (continued)

g >π

1− π·u(c)

u′(c)c

• With γ > 1, the value of life rises relative to consumption!

u(c)

u′(c)c= ucγ−1 +

1

1− γ.

Eventually, people are rich enough that the risk to life of

Russian Roulette is too great and growth ceases.

Life and Growth – p.11/36

Page 12: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

The Research Decision when γ > 1

Consumption, c

Utility

0

(1 − π)u

u

U research = (1 − π)u(c(1 + g))

U stop = u(c)

c∗

Continue research Stop research

Life and Growth – p.12/36

Page 13: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Case 3: log utility (γ = 1)

• Flow utility is unbounded in this case

• But the value of life relative to consumption still rises

u(c)/u′(c)c = u+ log c

• So growth eventually ceases in this case as well.

Life and Growth – p.13/36

Page 14: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Microfoundations

in a Growth Model

Hall and Jones (2007) meetAcemoglu (Direction TechChg)

Life and Growth – p.14/36

Page 15: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Production Ct = (∫ At

0x1/αit di)α, Ht = (

∫ Bt

0z1/αit di)α

Ideas At = aSλatA

φt , Bt = bSλ

btBφt

RC (labor) Lct + Lht ≤ Lt, Lct ≡∫ At

0xitdi, Lht ≡

∫ Bt

0zitdi

RC (scientists, pop) Sat + Sbt ≤ St, St + Lt ≤ Nt

Mortality δt = h−βt , ht ≡ Ht/Nt

Utility U =∫∞0

e−ρtu(ct)Mtdt, Mt = −δtMt

Flow util. u(ct) = u+ c1−γ

t

1−γ , ct ≡ Ct/Nt

Pop growth Nt = nNt

Life and Growth – p.15/36

Page 16: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Allocating Resources

• 14 unknowns, 11 equations (not counting utility)

◦ Ct,Ht, ct, ht, At, Bt, xit, zit, Sat, Sbt, St, Lt, Nt, δt

• Three allocative decisions to be made

◦ (st) Scientists: Sat = stSt

◦ (ℓt) Workers: Lct = ℓtLt

◦ (σt) People: St = σtNt

• Rule of Thumb allocation: st = s, ℓt = ℓ, and σt = σ

Life and Growth – p.16/36

Page 17: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

BGP under the Rule of Thumb

PROPOSITION 1: As t → ∞, there exists an asymptoticbalanced growth path such that growth is given by

g∗A = g∗B =λn

1− φ

δ∗ = 0

g∗c = g∗h = αg∗A = αg∗B = g ≡αλn

1− φ.

Life and Growth – p.17/36

Page 18: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

The Optimal Allocation

max{st,ℓt,σt}

U =

∫ ∞

0

Mtu(ct)e−ρtdt s.t.

ct = Aαt ℓt(1− σt)

ht = Bαt (1− ℓt)(1− σt)

At = asλt σλt N

λt A

φt

Bt = b(1− st)λσλ

t Nλt B

φt

Mt = −δtMt, δt = h−βt

Life and Growth – p.18/36

Page 19: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Hamiltonian

• In solving, useful to define

H = Mtu(ct) + patasλt σ

λt N

λt A

φt + pbtb(1− st)

λσλt N

λt B

φt

−vtδtMt

• Co-state variables:

◦ pat: shadow value of a consumption idea

◦ pbt: shadow value of a life-saving idea

◦ vt: shadow value of an extra person

Life and Growth – p.19/36

Page 20: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Optimal Growth with γ > 1 + β

PROPOSITION 2: Assume γ > 1 + β. There is an asymptoticbalanced growth path such that ℓt and st both fall to zero atconstant exponential rates, and

g∗s = g∗ℓ =−g(γ − 1− β)

1 + (γ − 1)(1 + αλ1−φ)

< 0

g∗A =λ(n+ g∗s)

1− φ, g∗B =

λn

1− φ> g∗A

g∗δ = −βg, g∗h = g

g∗c = αg∗A + g∗ℓ = g ·1 + β(1 + αλ

1−φ)

1 + (γ − 1)(1 + αλ1−φ)

Life and Growth – p.20/36

Page 21: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Intuition

At = asλt σλt N

λt A

φt and Bt = b(1− st)

λσλt N

λt B

φt .

• 1− st → 1, but st falls exponentially, slowing growth in At.

• Why? The FOC for allocating ℓt is

1− ℓtℓt

= βδtvt

u′(ct)ct= δtvt

where vt is the shadow value of a life, from the Hamiltonian.

• Numerator is extra lives that can be saved, denominator isextra consumption that can be produced

• Race!

Life and Growth – p.21/36

Page 22: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Optimal Growth with γ < 1 + β

PROPOSITION 3: Assume 1 < γ < 1 + β. There is an asymptotic

balanced growth path such that ℓt ≡ 1− ℓt and st ≡ 1− st bothfall to zero at constant exponential rates, and

g∗A =λn

1− φ, g∗B =

λ(n+ g∗s)

1− φ< g∗A

g∗c = g, g∗δ = −βg∗h.

g∗s = g∗ℓ=

−g(β + 1− γ)

1 + β(1 + αλ1−φ)

< 0

g∗h = g∗c ·

(

1 + (γ − 1)(1 + αλ1−φ)

1 + β(1 + αλ1−φ)

)

< g∗c .

Life and Growth – p.22/36

Page 23: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Optimal Growth with γ = 1 + β

PROPOSITION 4: Assume 1 < γ = 1 + β. There is an asymptoticbalanced growth path such that ℓt and st settle down toconstants strictly between 0 and 1, and

g∗A = g∗B =λn

1− φ

g∗c = g∗h = g, g∗δ = −βg.

Life and Growth – p.23/36

Page 24: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Empirical Evidence

Life and Growth – p.24/36

Page 25: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Empirical Evidence

• γ − 1 versus β

◦ γ > 1 is the “normal” case

◦ Evidence from health “production functions” suggests βis relatively small

• Trends in R&D: Toward health

• Quantifying the “growth slowdown”

Life and Growth – p.25/36

Page 26: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Evidence on β (Recall: δt = h−βt )

• Plausible upper bound compares trends in mortality totrends in health spending

◦ Attributes all decline in mortality to real health spending

◦ Minimal quality adjustment reinforces “upper bound”view for β

• Numbers for 1960 – 2007

◦ Age-adjusted mortality rates fell at 1.2% per year

◦ CPI-deflated health spending grew at 4.1% per year

⇒ β upper bound ≈ 1.24.1 ≈ .3

• Hall and Jones (2007) more careful analysis along theselines finds age-specific estimates of between .10 and .25.

Life and Growth – p.26/36

Page 27: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Evidence on γ

• Risk aversion evidence suggests γ > 1◦ Asset pricing (Lucas 1994), Labor supply (Chetty 2006)

• Intertemporal substitution elasticity 1/γ◦ Traditional view is EIS<1 ⇒ γ > 1 (Hall 1988)

◦ Careful micro work supporting this view: Attanasio andWeber (1995), Barsky et al (1997), Guvenen (2006), Hall(2009)

◦ Other recent work finds some evidence for EIS>1⇒ γ < 1 (Vissing-Jorgensen and Attanasio 2003,Gruber 2006)

• Mixed evidence.

Life and Growth – p.27/36

Page 28: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Evidence on the Value of Life

• Same force as in Hall and Jones (2007) on health spending

◦ Consumption runs into sharply diminishing returns: u′(c)

◦ While life becomes increasingly valuable: u(c)

• Evidence on value of life?

◦ Nearly all is cross sectional

◦ Costa and Kahn (2004), Hammitt, Liu, and Liu (2000)

• Other evidence? Safety standards?

Life and Growth – p.28/36

Page 29: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

The Changing Composition of U.S. R&D Spending

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 20100

5

10

15

20

25

30

Year

Health Share of R&D (percent)

Non−commercial health research (CMMS)

NIH estimates

CMMS + NSF IRIS

CMMS + NSF Recent

Life and Growth – p.29/36

Page 30: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

The Changing Composition of OECD R&D Spending

1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 20060

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

20

22

Year

Health Share of R&D (percent)

U.S.

OECD

Life and Growth – p.30/36

Page 31: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Fraction of Patents for Medical Eq. or Pharma

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 20002

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

Year

Percent

U.S. only

Total

Source: Jeffrey Clemens

Life and Growth – p.31/36

Page 32: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

An Income Effect in Health Spending

1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 20102

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

Year

Health spending (percent of GDP)

United States

GermanyFrance

U.K.

Japan

Life and Growth – p.32/36

Page 33: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Health and Consumption

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

100

200

400

800

1600

Year

Real quantity per person (1950=100)

Health (pce)4.67%

Health (official)

3.10%

pceNon−health consumption ( ,official)

2.05%1.84%

Life and Growth – p.33/36

Page 34: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

The Growth Drag: Ratio of gc to gh

β = .25 β = .10αλ1−φ γ = 1.5 γ = 2 γ = 1.5 γ = 2

0.50 0.79 0.55 0.66 0.46

1.00 0.75 0.50 0.60 0.40

2.00 0.70 0.44 0.52 0.33

Life and Growth – p.34/36

Page 35: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

A Future Slowdown?

• Calibration to past growth suggests αλ1−φ < 2, so that g < 2%.

◦ Therefore growth in h must slowdown significantly fromits 4 + % rate.

◦ And gc ≈1

2gh < 1% suggests a slowdown of

consumption growth as well.

• Intuition: h has been growing much faster than its steadystate rate because of the rising share of research devoted tolife-saving technologies.

Life and Growth – p.35/36

Page 36: Life and Growth - Stanford Universitychadj/lifeslides300.pdfLife and Growth Charles I. Jones Stanford GSB Life and Growth – p.1/36. R. Posner (2004) Catastrophe: Risk and Response

Conclusions

• Including “life and death” considerations in growth modelscan have first order consequences.

• For a large class of preferences, safety is a luxury good.

◦ Diminishing returns to consumption on any given daymeans that additional days of life become increasinglyvaluable.

◦ R&D may tilt toward life-saving technologies and awayfrom standard consumption goods.

◦ Consumption growth may be substantially slower thanwhat is feasible, possibly even slowing all the way tozero.

Life and Growth – p.36/36


Recommended