+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Date post: 03-Feb-2022
Category:
Upload: others
View: 2 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
42
Market Valuation and Target Horizon in Mergers & Acquisitions Tao Lin University of Hong Kong [email protected] Liyan Miao University of Hong Kong [email protected] First draft: March, 2006 This draft: May, 2006 We are also grateful to Prof. Eric Chang, Qiao Liu, Xianming Zhou and participants at the seminar of the University of Hong Kong. All errors are ours.
Transcript
Page 1: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Market Valuation and Target Horizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Tao Lin

University of Hong Kong [email protected]

Liyan Miao University of Hong Kong

[email protected]

First draft: March, 2006 This draft: May, 2006

We are also grateful to Prof. Eric Chang, Qiao Liu, Xianming Zhou and participants at the seminar of the

University of Hong Kong. All errors are ours.

Page 2: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Market Valuation and Target Horizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Abstract

Under the market-driven acquisition theory, targets tend to be underpaid by rational

acquirers. One of the reasons targets agree to the transaction is that they are short-horizon

oriented. Using a sample of 770 mergers and acquisitions announced between 1993 and

2002, this study empirically shows that targets are more likely to be underpaid when they

have shorter horizon-oriented shareholders and CEOs. Shareholder turnover ratio, CEO

age, tenure, equity-based wealth and incentive to cash out are proxied for horizon.

1

Page 3: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

1. Introduction

Much of the research in corporate finance has focused on the underlying motivation for

mergers and acquisition. Jensen (1988) summarizes that in the long-run, takeovers

generate substantial gains, which result from easier access to resources, transfer to more

highly-valued use of assets, etc. The managerial hubris hypothesis posited by Roll (1986)

suggests a psychological interpretation and implies that managers in bidding firms tend to

overpay for the target. Agency theory focuses on the interest disparity between

shareholders and executives. Grinstein and Hribar (2004) investigate the CEO

compensation package, the alignment of interest between shareholders and executives and

managerial incentives in mergers and acquisitions.

Recent research work tries to explain the observed merger waves and the positive

correlation between market valuation and merger waves. Shleifer and Vishny (2003)

establish a model of mergers and acquisitions which argues that stock market

misvaluation drives acquisitions. According to this model, they posit that the long-run

reason for bidders to takeover the target is the undervaluation of the target. Shareholders

of the acquiring firm will gain from the acquisition if the target is undervalued to

fundamentals in cash acquisitions and relatively undervalued to the bidder in stock

acquisitions. Overvalued firms are more likely to be bidders and undervalued firms are

more likely to be targets. Target shareholder will gain in the short-run. However,

shareholders holding onto shares in an overvalued market will lose in the long-run.

Therefore, target managers will protect long-horizon shareholders’ interest if they resist

the offer. The model predicts that bidders in stock acquisitions either have longer horizon

than targets or pay personal deals to target managers to agree to the acquisition.

Rhodes-Kropf and Viswanathan (2004) propose a different model, which separates

misvaluation into firm-specific component and market-wide component. The model

shows that the potential market valuation deviation from fundamental values impacts

2

Page 4: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

merger activities. Their theory predicts that acquisitions are more likely to occur in

overvalued markets. Because in the more overvalued market, the rational target managers

with limited information will overestimate the firm-specific misvaluation, and thus

overvalue the synergies from the acquisition. Method of payment will contain a higher

fraction of stock in overvalued markets and higher fraction of cash in undervalued

markets.

The follow-up empirical research provides strong support to the theory of Shleifer and

Vishny (2003) and Rhodes-Kropf and Viswanathan (2004). Dong et al. (2003) tests the

hypotheses of misvaluation driven acquisitions. Their study employs two

contemporaneous measures of misvaluation: pre-takeover ratio of book value of equity to

price and pre-takeover ratio of residual income value to price. They find evidence that

bidders are relatively overvalued to targets, bidders are more overvalued in stock

acquisitions than in cash acquisitions, undervalued targets receive higher premium and

are more likely to resist the offer, which is consistent with the predictions by Shleifer and

Vishny (2003). Rhodes-Kropf, Robinson and Viswanathan (2005), based on the theory of

Rhodes-Kropf and Viswanathan (2004), decompose M/B into three components:

firm-specific error, time-series sector error and long-run value to book to measure

misvaluation. The empirical results show that acquirers and targets appear to share the

common misvaluation component of time-series sector. The difference in M/B between

acquirers and targets is mainly attributed to the firm-specific error. High firm-specific

error is positively correlated to the possibility of being involved in a merger as an acquirer

and using stock as method of payment.

Similar to Dong et al. (2003) and Rhodes-Kropf, Robinson, and Viswanathan (2004),

Ang and Cheng (2005) find evidence on the market-driven acquisitions theory. In addition,

they also find some new results which are consistent with the critical assumption made by

Shleifer and Vishny (2003). Shareholders of acquiring firms do not suffer loss in the

3

Page 5: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

long-run compared to those of matching firms. However, former shareholders of target

firms are the losers if they hold shares in a long-term post-merger period.

Although previous empirical research has found evidence on the misvaluation of firms

and the long-run return for the market-driven acquisitions, we still lack evidence on the

reason of targets to accept the acquisition offer which hurts the value of shareholders in

the long-run. Shleifer and Vishny (2003) conjecture that target agrees to the acquisition

because the targets have shorter horizons in the firm or the self-benefited target managers

get private payment from the acquirer.

This study intends to test several empirical predictions under the market-driven

acquisition theory inspired by Shleifer and Vishny (2003). Previous literature shows that

targets are undervalued compared to non-target match firms in cash acquisition and

relatively undervalued compared to bidder in stock acquisition. Although bidders usually

offer premium price, the premium may be not enough to compensate the undervaluation

of targets in cash acquisitions and the overvaluation of bidders in stock acquisitions. It is

expected that underpaid targets shareholders will lose money in the long run. Therefore,

either the shareholders or the managers have short horizons in the firm. Targets with

long-horizon investors and managers will be more likely to resist the offer and thus less

likely to complete the acquisition.

2. Research Design

2.1 Main Hypotheses

Although bidders are blamed for overpayment in mergers and acquisitions, the

overvaluation of bidders and undervaluation of targets is ignored. If taking the

misvaluation into consideration, we may conclude that the premium provided by

acquirers is not huge enough to compensate the undervaluation of target market value in a

cash acquisition and the overvaluation of bidder market value in a stock acquisition.

4

Page 6: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Based on the theory of Shleifer and Vishny (2003), I develop several hypotheses for

empirical test.

First, acquirers will tend to underpay targets in market-driven acquisitions, which

should be found empirically. Second, if targets have shorter horizon-oriented shareholders

and CEOs, they are more likely to be underpaid. Last, it is expected that firm horizon is

also related to the magnitude of underpayment.

2.2 Variable Construction

2.2.1 Measurement of underpayment

Target value should be measured to see whether the deal value offered by acquirer is

appropriate. Two principle valuation approaches are the Price to book (P/B) method and

the Residual Income Model (RIM). P/B is the market-to-book ratio of the stock.1 In the

RIM based on Ohlson (1995), firm value is current period book value of equity plus all

expected future discounted earnings in excess of required return on the equity capital.

Empirically, future earnings are proxied by analyst earnings forecasts (e.g., Lee et al.,

1999). Misvaluation, either overvalued or undervalued, is measured by the difference

between market price and equity book value or fundamental value resulted from RIM.2

The definition of underpayment is based on the theory of Shleifer and Vishny (2003).

Targets are underpaid if the price is less than target’s long-run stand-alone value in cash

acquisitions. In stock acquisitions, targets are underpaid if the price is less than targets’

proportionate value of the short-term post-merger combined firm.

To make it more empirically practical, a slightly different measure of underpayment is

employed. According to the assumption of Shleifer and Vishny (2003), the misvalued

market will return to efficient in the long run. Therefore, the intrinsic value of the target

1 A large amount of literature has demonstrated that P/B ratio is a good proxy to measure mispricing (e.g., Barberis and Huang (2001), Daniel et al. (2001)). 2 Dong et al. (2003) and Ang and Cheng (2005) employ both of RIM and P/B method to measure bidder and target valuation.

5

Page 7: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

can be measured using the long run market to book ratio. In cash acquisitions,

underpayment is the difference between offer price and long-run stand-alone value of the

target. In stock acquisitions, underpayment is measured by the difference between

original target shareholders’ value in the combined firm and the stand-alone value in the

long run. Here three-year term is used for the long-run base.

Since target’s stand alone market performance can hardly be traced once merged,

target’s stand-alone value is measured by the average value of the matching firm without

merger announcement. The definition of matching firms is that firms, within the same

industry according to Fama-French 38 industry classification, have the same quartile of

market-to-book ratio with the target in the quarter prior to the announcement date.

In cash acquisitions, it is straight forward that the price offered by acquirers is the real

value the targets can get, therefore, underpayment is measured by

Underpayment = (P-q)*K, (1)

where P is offering price per unit of capital, q is the average price per unit of capital of

target’s matching firms three years after the acquisition, K is target book equity.

In stock acquisitions, however, acquirers pay targets using their overvalued stocks, the

offered price is even more misleading especially when the target stocks are undervalued,

therefore, the offer price should be adjusted to reflect the real value,

Underpayment = (Pq1/Q1-q)*K, (2)

where P is offering price per unit of capital, q1 is the average price per unit of capital of

combined firm three years after merger completion, Q1 is the market price per unit of

capital of acquirers at the end of quarter prior the announcement. Still, q is the average

price per unit of capital of target’s matching firms three years after the acquisition, K is

target book equity.

If the value of the equation is less than 0, then the target is underpaid, the more

negative the value is, the more underpayment of the target. Otherwise, the target is

6

Page 8: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

overpaid.

2.2.2 Proxies for Shareholder Horizon

Shareholder daily turnover ratio is used to proxy for shareholder horizon. Turnover is

measured as daily trading volume divided by total shares outstanding, multiplying 1000.

It is commonly stated that the larger the turnover ratio is, the shorter horizon shareholders

hold in the firms (e.g. Ang and Cheng (2005), Gaspar et al. (2005)).

Turnover may contain too much information in addition to shareholder horizon. For

example, firms with larger analyst coverage will have a relatively more active trading

pattern. Firms with different size are more likely to attract different groups of investors.

To subtract the noise information from turnover, we use the residual mean of target firms’

turnover ratio after the regression on logarithm of market value of equity,

jijiji MELgTurnover εββ +∗+= )(10 , (3)

where is the turnover ratio of firm j on i days before the announcement,

is the logarithm form of market value of firm j on i days before the

announcement. The shareholder horizon variable mreone for firm j is constructed as

jiTurnover

)( jiMELg

∑=

=395

313651

ijijmreone ε , (4)

where jiε is the residual of the regression (3), the period for the mean of residual is

chosen as one year before one month prior the announcement of the mergers and

acquisitions. We choose the period starting from one month prior the announcement to

exclude the abnormal volatility and trading since the rumors of mergers and acquisitions

of firms usually occur before the official announcement.

2.2.3 Proxies for CEO Horizon

Age: This study employs two methods to proxy age for CEO horizon. The first method

follows Dikolli et al. (2003), which assume that CEO’s horizon is a decreasing and

7

Page 9: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

concave function of the CEO age. The variable Horizon is defined as ( )[ ]210/CEOage− .

In addition, to study the specific impact of different age on CEO horizon in the firm, we

also use several dummy variables to separate age to different groups.3

Tenure: We classify tenure into three groups, no more than 3 years, 3 to 5 years and 5

years more. CEOs with different tenure in their position tend to have different level of

career concerns and equity-based wealth in the firms. We use the cutting points of 3 and 5

year based on the study of Gibbons and Murphy (1992), which states that the CEO tenure

with the highest possibility of stepping down from the position clusters in 4 and 5 years.

It is expected that CEOs with the tenure between 3 to 5 years have the shortest horizons

compared to other two groups. One reason is given out by Gibbons and Murphy (1992),

CEOs with the tenure between 3 to 5 years are most likely to step down. In addition,

CEOs with longer tenure will have more equity-based wealth in their firms. The large

stake in their firm can align the interests of CEOs and shareholders, therefore partly solve

the horizon problem of CEOs with longer tenure.

Equity-based wealth: CEOs’ equity-based wealth in their firms include value of stock

holding, restricted grants money value, in the money unexercised exercisable option

dollar value and in the money unexercised unexercisable option dollar value. The wealth

is held and valued at the end of last fiscal year prior the announcement of the mergers and

acquisitions. Generally, the equity-based wealth, used as a forward-looking compensation

contract, will lead CEOs to have a longer horizon.4

To pair different horizons of CEOs in the acquirer and target, we construct a variable

welredif to measure the difference of horizons between acquirer and target CEOs.

Welredif is the difference of residuals of CEO equity-based wealth after regression wealth 3 Cheng (2001) uses the age of 63 to distinguish different horizons held by CEO. Survey by Murphy (1999) shows that the typical age of retirement is 64 around. Therefore the age of 64 can also be used as a flag to differentiate horizon. 4 Lambert and Larcker (1991) suggest that contract tying managers’ compensation to firm’s market performance can partly solve the problem of managerial myopia.

8

Page 10: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

on size of acquirers and targets. The larger the welredif, the acquirer CEO horizon is

longer than target CEO.

Incentive to cash out: CEOs trapped in the firm by a large holding of restricted stocks

have strong incentive to cash out. Since restrictions on stocks and options are usually

exempted upon a deal of merger and acquisition (Moeller, 2005), we use the ratio of

restricted stock grants value over total equity-based wealth or market value to measure

the incentive to cash out. It is expected that CEOs with larger ratio will have shorter

horizons in their firms.

2.2.4 Control Variables

Several other variables that may affect the transaction are controlled in the tests.

Targets firm size and the relative size to acquirers will affect the deal value.5

To control the industry factor, we include a dummy variable to indicate whether the

merger and acquisition is undertaken by firms in the same industry. The impact of

diversification is ambiguous. It is possible that acquirers will pay higher price to targets

because they lack perfect information and knowledge to value targets. However, we can

also expect that the level of misvaluation is different among industries. Diversified

acquisition occurs between more overvalued industry as acquirer and relatively

undervalued industry as target. Targets are actually receiving lower price and therefore

more likely to be underpaid.

Prior literature addresses that firms with higher valuation are associated with greater

use of stock as a method of payment (Dong et al., 2003). We add an indicator variable of

stock to control the impact of method of payment.

Finally, we also include several market return indicators to control the influence of

broad market environment.

5 Moeller (2005) finds that the larger the target relative to the acquirer, the lower the takeover premium the target receives.

9

Page 11: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

2.3 Sample Selection

The samples are selected from the mergers and acquisitions database of Securities Data

Company (SDC). Transactions with an announcement date between 1993 and 2002 are

included in the sample. We choose the period from 1993 to 2002 because CEO

information from ExecuComp is available from 1992 and complete three year

post-merger market performance from CRSP ends in 2005. In addition, Andrade et al.

(2001) find that merger waves in different decades have different characteristics. The

merger wave in 1990s has notable features distinguished from others. Therefore, here we

only focus on the 1990s merger wave. Both the acquirers and targets are U.S. public firms

listed in NYSE, Amex or Nasdaq. The sample is limited to listed firms so that the market

valuation can be studied. The method of payment is either all cash or all stock. The status

of transaction is either completed or withdrawn. Buyback, exchange offer and

recapitalization are excluded from the sample. SDC database provides data on the value

of transaction, the announcement date, acquirer and target ticker and Standard industrial

classification (SIC) codes and status of transaction.

Daily stock price, trading volume, and number of shares outstanding are obtained from

Center for Research in Securities Prices (CRSP) database. Financial statement

information about acquirers and targets is obtained from Compustat Industrial Quarterly.

Financial information, including stockholders’ equity and number of common shares

outstanding at the end of each quarter and closing price of stock at the 3rd month of each

quarter, is used to calculate market-to-book ratio of firms at the end of quarter. In addition,

we also use all firms registered in Compustat as the base to constructing matching groups.

Information of CEO characteristics and compensation is extracted from ExecuComp

database, which reports CEO name, age, annual compensation and equity-based wealth

including share ownership, restricted grants and options. I also check the proxy

statements and other SEC filings to fill the missing values in ExecuComp database and

10

Page 12: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

collect information on CEO tenure, outside blockholding, etc.

Finally, observations in which targets have more than one transactions recorded in SDC

are excluded. After all the data collection, the final number of observations in the base

sample is 770.

2.4 Descriptive Statistics

Table 1 presents summary statistics for the sample. Of all the observations during 1993

and 2002, most of the transactions cluster in 1996 to 2001, partly subject to data

availability. Generally, in a merger and acquisition, acquirer size is much larger than

target, with an average acquirer market value of 24,287.91 million dollars and target

market value of 1,091.95 million dollars. Mean deal value of transaction is slightly larger

than average target size.

In the sample, 58% of all target firms are underpaid by an average value of 529.41

million dollars. Under the assumption of Shleifer and Vishny (2003), the motivation for

rational acquirer managers to undertake mergers and acquisitions in the misvalued stock

market is to arbitrage by underpaying targets. Therefore, it is expected that empirically

most firms should be underpaid. Result of binomial test shows that percentage of

underpayment is larger than 0.5 at the significance level less than 0.001.

Prior literature has stated a greater use of stock as a method of payment in the 1990s

merger wave (e.g., Dong et al. (2003) and Holmstrom and Kaplan (2001)), the summary

statistics shows the increase of stock payment with a large fall in the 2002. The

percentage of diversification is 32, which means that over two-thirds of transactions in

our sample occur between acquirers and targets in the same industry. This result is

consistent with recent studies (e.g., Andrade et al. (2001) and Gaspar et al. (2005)) which

report an increase of related acquisition in the 1990s.

Finally, table 1 shows that most of the observations in our sample ended with complete.

Although we include both completed and withdrawn transactions, only 7% of the sample

11

Page 13: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

firms are withdrawn acquisitions.

<Insert Table 1 here>

Further study is focused on firm characteristics related to firm horizon. Table 2

summarizes acquirers and targets characteristics and relative difference between them in

different groups classified by underpayment. Panel A and Panel B reports the means of

various variables of targets and acquirers respectively. Our hypotheses predict that targets

with CEOs who have larger equity-based wealth in the firms will be less likely underpaid,

while acquirers with CEOs who have larger equity-based wealth will more likely

underpay targets. Therefore, target CEOs in Underpayment are assumed to have smaller

equity-based compensation, while acquirer CEOs in Underpayment are assumed to have

larger equity-based compensation. The descriptive statistics in Panel A and B show that

most variables on CEO compensation and equity-related variables are larger in group of

Underpayment than in group of Overpayment for both acquirers and targets. It is mainly

due to the reason that firm size has not been controlled in the comparison. Although the

dollar value and number of securities holding are ambiguous, statistics on share

ownership percentage is consistent with hypothesis. Table 2 shows that CEOs’ stock

ownership percentage is lower for targets and higher for acquirers in the group of

Underpayment than Overpayment. The difference for acquirers is significant at 5% level.

Statistics on age and tenure reported in Panel A and B shows involvement of CEOs with

older age and longer tenure in the overpayment. Since age and tenure are expected to

have nonlinear relation with CEO horizon, the implication of group mean difference is

unclear.

To control the firm size effect and impact of acquirer CEO horizon on target decision,

Panel C describes the relative size, age difference and the variable welredif, which is the

difference of residuals after regressing CEOs’ equity-based wealth on firm size between

acquirers and targets. Welredif is constructed to measure difference of CEO horizons

12

Page 14: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

between acquirers and targets. As a result, welredif is positive in Underpayment and

negative in Overpayment, with significant difference between two groups. The result

indicates that targets will accept underpaid offer when their CEOs have relatively shorter

horizon than those of acquirers. However, when targets’ CEOs have longer horizon than

those of acquirers, they will strive for a higher price even resulting in acquirers’

overpayment.

Table 2 reports a summary statistics on all observations in the sample, including both

completed and withdrawn transactions. To check the influence of different status of the

deal, same test is done for the sample with only completed transactions and the results are

similar to Table 2.6

<Insert Table 2 here>

In Table 2, the shareholder horizon variable mreone is significantly higher in targets

underpaid then overpaid, which means that shareholders in underpaid firms have shorter

horizon. This is consistent with the hypothesis.

Table 3 presents a further study on mreone of targets in different classifications. Panel

A categorizes all targets into four groups based on the status and whether they are

underpaid or overpaid. Shareholder horizon is reasonably expected to affect final status of

the transaction. Generally, if an investor has long horizon in the firm and intends to hold

onto shares in a long-term period, he will be less likely to accept a merger offer. Taking

underpayment and overpayment into consideration, long-horizon oriented shareholders of

targets will benefit either by rejecting an underpaid offer or accepting an overpaid offer.

Shareholders are expected short-horizon oriented to accept an underpaid offer, with an

intention to profit from short-term stock price boost around the announcement. For targets

which finally withdraw from transactions with overpaid offer price, shareholders’

horizons are ambiguous. The order of mreone magnitude in four groups reported in Panel 6 Results are available upon request.

13

Page 15: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

A is consistent with expectation. Targets underpaid with status of competed have largest

group mean of mreone, which indicates that their shareholders have shortest horizon.

Targets overpaid and with status of completed and targets which are underpaid but

withdraw from the deal have relatively lower group mean of mreone than the other two

groups. Group mean of targets which withdraw from an overpaid deal is in between.

However, F-statistics for mean difference among the four groups is not significant.

Since the major difference is between Group 1 with underpaid and completed targets

and other groups, Panel B and Panel C report T-test statistics of the difference between

Group 1 and other two groups. It shows that shareholders in targets which competed

underpaid deals have shorter horizon than those in targets which competed overpaid deals

and which withdraw from underpaid deals, both significant at less than 5% level.

<Insert Table 3 here>

Shareholder horizon variable mreone in Table 2 and Table 3 is constructed as mean of

target’s turnover residuals over a period from 31 to 395 days before announcement. To

exclude an impact of extreme values during a specific period, Fig. 1 and Fig. 2 describe

daily residual means of targets’ turnover ratio after the regression on logarithm of firms’

market value of equity over the period of 31 to 395 days prior announcement. By

comparing daily mean of underpaid targets and overpaid targets, Figure 1 presents

consistently higher daily means of shareholder turnover residuals in underpaid targets

than those in overpaid targets in that one year period. It is consistent with our prediction

that shareholders in underpaid targets have shorter horizon than in overpaid targets.

<Insert Figure 1 here>

Figure 2 presents lines of daily mean of shareholder turnover residuals in targets with

different status. With only 54 withdrawn observations in the sample, the difference is not

so obvious as in Fig. 2. Even though mreone of targets with status of withdrawn have

several extreme values in specific days, targets with status of completed still consistently

14

Page 16: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

present higher daily mreone than targets with status of withdrawn.

<Insert Figure 2 here>

3. Regression Analysis

3.1 Target Shareholder horizon and Underpayment

Table 4 presents the relation between shareholder horizon and underpayment using

different regression models. ModelⅠreports logistic regression results of the likelihood

of a target being underpaid based on following model:

iiii ControlsrHorizonShareholdeupob εβββ +++== 210)1(Pr , (5)

where variable up equals 1 if underpayment is less than 0, which denotes that targets

are underpaid. UP equals 0 if underpayment is larger than or equal to 0, which denotes

that targets are overpaid. is the variable measuring target

shareholder horizon of firm i, proxied by mreone. is a group of control

variables including relative size of targets to acquirers, diversification, target equity value,

method of payment and the market environment before announcement. In Model Ⅰ, the

coefficient of mreone is significantly positive, which indicates that the higher the

shareholder turnover, i.e. the shorter the shareholder horizon, the more likely the target is

underpaid. In regard of control variables, it shows that targets are more likely to be

underpaid when acquirers are in different industries. It confirms previous prediction that

diversified acquisitions occur between more overvalued industry as acquirer and

relatively undervalued industry as target. I use logarithm of equity value of target to

control target firm size effect and find significant positive relation with the likelihood of

underpayment. This is consistent with Schwert (2000) and Gaspar et al. (2005) which find

that target premium is negatively related to firm size. Relative size, method of payment,

and market return are not statistically significant.

irHorizonShareholde

iControls

Model Ⅱ in Table 4 uses OLS regression to examine the relation between shareholder

15

Page 17: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

horizon and the magnitude of underpayment based on:

iiii ControlsrHorizonShareholdeUnderpay εβββ +++= 210 . (6)

Dependent variable in Model Ⅱ is underpay, measured by the defined methods. Since

underpay is calculated as multiple of target book value of equity, equity value is

employed as control variable instead of the logarithm form. Although coefficient for

shareholder horizon variable mreone is not significant at 10% level, the sign is as

expected. The negative coefficient between mreone and underpay implies that targets with

shorter-horizon shareholders are more underpaid. Two statistically significant control

variables are rsize and equityvalue. The larger the target size and size relative to acquirer,

the more the target is underpaid. Moeller (2005) reports a negative relation between target

relative size and takeover premium. Measurement of underpayment is partly determined

by takeover premium. Therefore, statistic results of rsize and equityvalue are consistent

with prior empirical research.

Figure 3 plots the magnitude of underpayment and the quantile position in the overall

dataset. Most of the observations gradually increase with the fraction of data and cluster

closely around 0. Extreme values exist and drive the scale of underpayment. To reduce

the impact of the outliers on the estimation, I transform the value of underpay into

cumulative distribution function.7 By using the percentile of underpay instead of its

original value, the scale of underpay is adjusted and more consistent with the independent

variables.

<Insert Figure 3 here>

Model Ⅲ in Table 4 reports estimation of the relation between shareholder horizon

and underpayment. Generalized linear model (GLM) is used to control for potential

econometric problems such as heteroskedasticity:

7 Aggarwal and Samwick (1999) transform variance of returns into cumulative distribution function to measure CEOs’ pay-performance sensitivity.

16

Page 18: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

iii ControlsrHorizonShareholdeunderpayF εβββ +++= 210)( . (7)

Dependent variable F(underpay) is the cumulative distribution function (CDF) of

underpay. The CDF values of zero and one correspond to the minimum and maximum of

underpay in the sample. Mreone is negatively related to the CDF of underpay at 5%

significant level. It shows that in the whole sample, targets with shorter horizon

shareholders are more underpaid compared to other observations. Firm size and market

performance before announcement also impact the level of underpayment. Smaller target

size and higher market return increase the percentile of CDF, which means less

underpayment. Relative size, diversification and method of payment do not have

statistically significant impact on level of underpayment in Model Ⅲ.

<Insert Table 4 here>

3.2 Target CEO horizon and Underpayment

3.2.1 CEO horizon and Probability of Underpayment

To study the relation between CEO horizon and probability of underpayment, similar

logistic regression as model (6) is employed:

iiii ControlsCEOhorizonupob εβββ +++== 210)1(Pr , (8)

where dependent variable is the probability of underpayment, denoted by the dummy

variable of up. is a vector of target CEO horizon in firm i, is a

group of control variables same as those used in estimating the impact of shareholder

horizons.

iCEOhorizon iControls

Different sets of variables are included in Table 5 to measure CEO horizon. Model Ⅰ

employs two age variables of target CEO to indicate CEO horizons. Following the

method of Dikolli et al. (2003) which assume that CEO’s horizon is a decreasing and

concave function of the CEO age, I expect that CEO horizon has nonlinear relation with

age. Therefore, I construct the variable horizon as ( )[ ]210/CEOage− . Since horizon is a

17

Page 19: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

square term of age, variable of age is also added to depict the concave function. In Model

Ⅰ, the coefficients for horizon and age are negative, which demonstrates that there is a

positive quadratic relation between CEO age and probability of underpayment. Either

elder or younger CEOs have shorter horizon and therefore are more likely to accept

underpaid offers. CEOs with age in between have the longest horizon.

Following the results of Model Ⅰ, Model Ⅱ employs two dummy variables of age. It

is expected that the bottom of the curve can be depicted by two cutting points. Consistent

with the results reported in Model Ⅰ, results in Model Ⅱ show that target CEOs with

age in between are least likely to make their firms underpaid. Two cutting points for age

are 65 and 70. The dummy variables age65less and age70up classify CEO age into three

groups and make targets with CEO age between 65 and 70 as a base group. The

coefficients for two dummy variable age65less and age70up are significantly positive,

which denotes that CEOs whose ages are smaller than 65 or elder than 70 are more likely

to agree with underpaid deals.

Cheng (2001) uses age of 63 to distinguish different horizons, CEOs younger than 63

are classified as holding longer horizon. Dikolli et al. (2003) assume decreasing relation

between age and horizon. Model Ⅱ reports different results with prior literature. It is

found that CEO horizon increases with age at first stage, and starts to decrease with age

after reaching a specific range. Empirical results in Model Ⅱ show that CEOs with age

between 65 and 70 have longest horizon in the firm. It is reasoned that CEOs who are

elder than usual retirement age but still hold their positions in the firm may have large

interests or special power in the firms, and therefore may have longer horizon.8 However,

when CEOs are too old, they may concern more about their current financial gains instead

of future careers and long-term interests in the firms.

Model Ⅲ of Table 5 examines tenure as proxy for CEO horizon for the probability of 8 Murphy (1999) shows that the typical age for CEOs retirement is 64 around.

18

Page 20: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

target underpayment. It shows that CEOs with tenure between 3 and 5 years have

significantly higher chance of accepting underpaid offers. This is consistent with the

survey of Gibbons and Murphy (1992). Since CEOs with tenure between 3 and 5 years

are most likely to step down, their career concern is lower. Therefore, they may care more

about current financial gains. CEOs with tenure shorter than 3 years usually lack strong

control of firm decisions. In addition, they are less likely to agree with the deal for their

own career concern9, which forces acquirers to provide a higher offer price. On the other

hand, CEOs that stay in the top position for a very long period either have large stake of

interests in the firm or strong control for career security. Both the large amount of

equity-based wealth and the career concern lead CEOs to make long-horizon oriented

decisions for their firms.

Last column in Table 5 employs both age and tenure variable to measure CEO horizon.

The results of Model Ⅳ are similar to those of models that only include either age or

tenure. Regression results on control variables are consistent across all the models in

Table 6 and also consistent with the logistic regression of shareholder horizons.

<Insert Table 5 here>

Table 6 adds several CEO compensation variables in the logistic regression models. It

is expected that the larger CEOs’ equity-based wealth in the firms, the less likely they will

have their firms underpaid in mergers and acquisitions. However, when CEOs hold a

large percentage of restricted stock grants, they will have strong incentives to cash out

and therefore less reluctant to agree an underpaid offer. Model Ⅰ in Table 6 adds

logarithm of target CEO wealth and ratio of restricted stock grants over target size. The

negative coefficient of target CEO wealth and positive coefficient of restricted ratio

9 According to the survey of Gibbons and Murphy (1992), it is reasonable to expect that CEOs with shorter tenure than typical retiring tenure have longer period left to stay in their position. However, once the firms are acquired, most of target CEOs can not maintain their position in the combined firms. Hartzell et al. (2004) finds that target CEOs experience high turnover rates both at the announcement of and years after the acquisitions.

19

Page 21: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

proves the expectation, even though the coefficients are not statistically significant.

In the negotiation process of merger and acquisition, both the horizons of target and

acquirer CEOs will have impact on the bid price. Long-horizon oriented acquirers and

short-horizon oriented targets are more likely to involve in a transaction underpaying

targets. To control the impact of acquirer CEOs’ horizon, Model Ⅱ employs two variables.

Welredif in Model Ⅱ is the difference between residuals of CEO equity-based wealth

after regressing on firm size of acquirers and targets. Larger welredif indicates that

acquirer CEO has longer horizon than target CEO. As shown in Model Ⅱ, the coefficient

of welredif is significantly positive, which means that the longer of acquirer CEO horizon

than target CEO, the more likely targets are underpaid. Model Ⅲ includes both target

CEO equity-based wealth and acquirer CEO equity-based wealth. It presents that larger

acquirer CEO’s wealth and smaller target CEO’s wealth will increase the probability of

underpayment.

The potential problem of using market value of CEO equity-based wealth is the bias of

misvalution. Under the market driven acquisition, targets tend to be relatively

undervalued while acquirers tend to be overvalued. Therefore, CEO value of equity-based

wealth in the firm based on market price will also be affected. To control the impact of

market misvalution on CEO wealth measurement, Model Ⅳ of Table 6 uses ratio of

wealth to firm size. Variable weltosize is ratio of target CEO equity-based wealth over

target firm size at the end of fiscal year prior the announcement. After dividing wealth by

firm size, market value does not impact the measurement of CEO wealth, only the relative

stake in the firm matters.

The incentive to cash out is proxied by variable of tgresratio, which is measured by

restricted stock grants over target size. Guay (1999) states the difference between stock

options and stocks. Unexercisable stock options with restrictions on selling are expected

to have same effect as restricted grants. The different impact of different kinds of

20

Page 22: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

equity-based wealth on CEO horizon will probably contradict and mitigate each other.

Model Ⅳ adds a new variable of shownpc to separate different effect of stocks from

other equity-based wealth. Shownpc is the percentage of common shares held by target

CEO.

Model Ⅳ reports a significantly positive coefficient for weltosize and negative

coefficient for shownpc. After adding a variable of share percentage owned by CEO, the

relation between target CEO wealth and probability of underpayment is positive, this is

contradictory with previous results on CEO wealth variables. A further study is needed to

investigate the impact of stock ownership and other equity-based wealth. Since wealth is

the sum of all kinds of equity-based equity value, variable weltosize can be regarded as

the sum of share ownership percentage, i.e. shownpc, and stocks underlying options and

restricted stocks as a percentage of total shares outstanding. The impact of common

stocks owned by CEO should be determined by two coefficients for both weltosize and

shownpc. Shownpc is the number of percents. To make the scale of shownpc consistent

with weltosize, the coefficients should be multiplied by 100. Therefore, the total impact

coefficient in the logistic regression for shownpc is (-0.0695*100+6.2937), which is

negatively related to the probability of underpayment. Controlling shares ownership of

CEO, the coefficient for other equity-based wealth including restricted stock grants and

stocks underlying both exercisable and unexercisable options over total shares

outstanding is positive. It shows that CEOs with larger stock ownership are less likely to

undersell their firms, however, CEOs will be more likely to agree with underpaid deals

when they have large stake in other equity-based wealth. The results in Model Ⅳ

denotes that stock ownership can align the interests of shareholders and CEOs and lead

CEOs to make long-term oriented decisions. However, the increasing use of stock options

and restricted stock grants has the opposite effect, which lends CEOs incentive to cash out

and therefore makes them more short-horizon oriented.

21

Page 23: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Variables on CEO age, tenure and control variables present almost same effect in the

logistic regression model as in Table 5.

<Insert Table 6 here>

3.2.2 CEO horizon and Level of Underpayment

Same as for shareholder horizon, two regression models are employed to examine the

relation between CEO horizon and the level of underpayment. Panel A. in Table 7 uses

OLS regression to examine the relation between CEO horizon and the magnitude of

underpayment based on:

iiii ControlsCEOhorizonUnderpay εβββ +++= 210 . (9)

Different sets of CEO horizon variables are included in Panel A. The positive

coefficients of variables horizon and age depict a first increasing and then decreasing

relation between CEO age and underpayment. The larger the value of variable underpay,

the more the target is overpaid. Therefore, targets with CEOs aged in between are most

overpaid; targets with CEOs either elder or younger are more underpaid. CEOs with

tenure between 3 and 5 years make their firms most underpaid. The results are consistent

with those reported in logistic regression. However, CEO age and tenure variables are not

statistically significant in both models of Panel A.

Statistical results on logarithm of target CEO equity-based wealth, acquirer CEO

equity-based wealth and welredif are consistent with those in the logistic regression.

Variable of tgresratio in Panel A reports contradictory sign to expectation. None of these

variables are significant except welredif.

Results of control variables show that relative size of targets to acquirers and target size

will significantly increase the level of underpayment. In addition, targets involved in

diversified transactions, paid by stock and in relatively bearish market are more

underpaid.

22

Page 24: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Panel B. in Table 7 reports regression results of generalized linear model (GLM).

Dependent variable F(underpay) is the cumulative distribution function (CDF) of

underpay.

iii ControlsCEOhorizonunderpayF εβββ +++= 210)( , (10)

Panel B presents consistent results with Panel A and the logistic regression. Using

cumulative distribution function of underpay as dependent variable, Panel B reduces the

impact of outliers and makes the dependent and independent variables more comparable

in scale. Model Ⅲ to Model Ⅴ report significant statistical results on age and tenure

variables.

Target CEO ratio of restricted stock grants in Model Ⅲ and Ⅳ presents expected

sign. CEOs with larger ratio of restricted stock grants will make their firms more

underpaid. Variables on CEO wealth in both targets and acquirers present that larger

acquirer CEO’s wealth and smaller target CEO’s wealth will result in a more underpaid

deal for targets. The larger the difference between acquirer and target CEO’s wealth, the

more the targets are underpaid.

Model Ⅴ employs two variables weltosize and shownpc, same as Model Ⅳ in Table

6. The negative coefficient for weltosize is mainly driven by the impact of stock options

and restricted stock grants, since the coefficient for stock ownership is positive.

<Insert Table 7 here>

3.2.3 Correlation between CEO characteristic variables

When studying CEO horizons, I employ several CEO characteristic variables such as

age, tenure and compensation structures. Since previous literature states that CEO age and

tenure are highly correlated with equity-based compensation,10 Table 8 reports the

correlation between different CEO characteristic variables. Panel A of Table 8 presents

10 Lewellen et al. (1987) find that CEOs who are near retirement have a larger fraction of stock-based compensation. Gibbons and Murphy (1992) present that CEOs with longer tenure are paid more by equity-based compensation.

23

Page 25: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

the correlation matrix among CEO characteristic variables. The magnitudes of

correlations do not suggest the problem of multicollinearity. Statistical results of tenure in

previous regressions present a curved relation with CEO horizon. CEOs with tenure

between 3 and 5 years have the shortest horizons in their firms. Panel B reports mean and

median of CEO compensation variables in different tenure groups. It shows that target

CEO equity-based wealth, either in logarithm form or as relative ratio to firm size,

increases with tenure. Share ownership percentage also increases with tenure. The only

variable which presents different trend across tenure groups is tgresratio, calculated by

target CEO’s value of restricted stock grants over target size. Tgresratio is constructed to

measure level of CEO’s wealth trapped in the firm by restrictions and incentive to cash

out. Group of tenure between 3 and 5 years presents highest mean of tgresratio. The

median of tgresratio is same across all three groups and the group difference is not

significant. Mean and median difference among different tenure groups demonstrates that

the impact of tenure on CEO decision horizons is not driven by compensation structure.

The major determinant for CEOs’ decision horizons in different tenure groups is their

career concern.

<Insert Table 8 here>

3.3 Target horizon and Underpayment

Previous regression models focus either on CEO horizon or on shareholder horizon

alone. Table 9 includes both sets of variables on CEO horizons and shareholder horizons

to examine the relation between target horizon and underpayment. Panel A. reports

logistic regression results of the likelihood of a target being underpaid. Panel B. uses OLS

regression to examine the relation between target horizon and the magnitude of

underpayment. Panel C. reports regression results of generalized linear model (GLM).

Dependent variable F(underpay) is the cumulative distribution function (CDF) of

underpay.

24

Page 26: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Shareholder horizon variable mreone presents expected sign in all the models. However,

none of the coefficients are statistically significant. Statistical results on CEO horizon

variables in Table 9 are quite similar to those in Table 6 and Table 7 that only include

CEO horizon variables. It posits that the relation between target horizon and

underpayment is mainly determined by CEO horizons.

<Insert Table 9 here>

4. Conclusion

This study examines the hypotheses inspired from Shleifer and Vishny (2003). Using a

sample of 770 mergers and acquisitions announced between 1993 and 2002, I find that the

number of targets underpaid in the deals is significantly larger than the number of targets

overpaid.

Target shareholder horizon, denoted by mean of daily turnovers over one year period

before the month of announcement after controlling firm size effect, has negative relation

with probability of underpayment.

CEO horizon is measured by age, tenure in that position, equity-based wealth in the

firm, and incentives to cash out. It is found that CEOs have short horizon when they are

either younger than 65 or older than 70, or when their tenure is between 3 to 5 years.

Equity-based wealth can align the interests of shareholders and CEOs and reduce the

probability of underpayment. However, the overuse of restricted stock grants will induce

CEOs to seek cashing out opportunities and agree with an underpaid offer.

This study mainly focuses on target side horizon. It is based on the assumption that

mergers and acquisitions are a form of arbitrage by rational acquirers’ managers. Since

the benefit of acquirers for the transaction is in long-term, it is reasonable to expect that

acquirers’ horizon also plays an important role in the deal negotiation. Here I only employ

acquirer CEOs’ equity-based wealth to denote acquirer horizon. Further study can be done

25

Page 27: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

by using more proxies for shareholder and CEO horizons in acquiring firms.

26

Page 28: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

References: Andrade, G., Mitchell, M., and Stafford, E., 2001. New evidence and perspectives on mergers. Journal of

Economic Perspectives 15, 103-120.

Ang, J., and Cheng, Y., 2005. Direct evidence on the market-driven acquisition theory. Journal of Financial

Research, forthcoming.

Baker, M., and Wurgler, J., 2000. The equity share in new issues and aggregate stock returns. Journal of

Finance 55, 2219-2258.

Barberis, N., and Huang, M., 2001. Mental accounting, loss aversion, and individual stock returns. Journal

of Finance 56, 1247-1292.

Callahan, T., and Moeller, T., 2002. Who’s cheating whom in mergers and acquisitions? How managerial

preferences influences attitude, target choices, and payoffs. Working paper, University of Texas-Austin.

Cheng, S., 2001. The relation between R&D expenditures and CEO compensation. Working paper,

University of Pittsburgh.

Daniel, K., Hirshleifer, D., and Subrahmanyam, A., 2001. Overconfidence, arbitrage, and equilibrium asset

pricing. Journal of Finance 56, 921-965.

Datta, S., Iskandar-Datta and Raman, K., 2001. Executive compensation and corporate acquisition decisions.

Journal of Finance 56, 2299-2336.

Dikolli, S., Kulp, S., and Sedatole, K., 2003. The role of CEO and investor horizons in the contracting use

of forward-looking performance measures. Harvard NOM research paper No. 03-35.

D’Mello, R., and Shroff, P., 2000. Equity undervaluation and decisions related to repurchase tender offers:

an empirical investigation. Journal of Finance 55, 2399-2424.

Dong, M., Hirshleifer, D., Richardson, S., and Teoh, S., 2003. Does investor misvaluation drive the

takeover market? Working paper, Ohio State University.

Gaspar, J., Massa, M., and Matos, P., 2005. Shareholder investment horizons and the market for corporate

control. Journal of Financial Economics, forthcoming.

Gibbons, R., and Murphy, K., 1992. Optimal incentive contracts in the presence of career concerns: theory

and evidence. Journal of Political Economy 100, 468-505.

Grinstein, Y., and Hribar, P., 2004. CEO compensation and incentives: evidence from M&A bonuses.

Journal of Financial Economics 73, 119-143.

Harford, J., 2005. What drives merger waves? Journal of Financial Economics 77, 483-702.

Hartzell, J., Ofek, E., and Yermach, D., 2004. What’s in it for me? CEOs whose firms are acquired. The

Review of Financial Studies 17, 37-61.

Holmstrom, B., and Kaplan, S., 2001. Corporate governance and merger activity in the U.S.: Making sense

of the 1980s and 1990s. Working paper, MIT.

Holthausen, R., Larcker, D., and Sloan, R., 1995. Annual bonus schemes and the manipulation of earnings.

Journal of Accounting and Economics 19, 29-74.

Jenson, M., 1988. Takeovers: their causes and consequences. Journal of Economic Perspectives 2, 21-48.

27

Page 29: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Lambert, R., and Larcker, D., 1991. Executive compensation, corporate decision making and shareholder

wealth: a review of the evidence. Inc: Grystal, G., (Ed), Executive Compensation, Harvard Business

School Press, MA.

Lee, C., Myers, J., and Swaminathan, B., 1999. What is the intrinsic value of the Dow? Journal of Finance

54, 1693-1741.

Li, J., 2002. CEO compensation, diversification, and incentives. Journal of Financial Economics 66, 29-63.

Loughran, T., and Vijh, A., 1997. Do long-term shareholders benefit from corporate acquisitions? Journal of

Finance 52, 1765-1790.

Moeller, T., 2005. Let’s make a deal! How shareholder control impacts merger payoffs. Journal of Financial

Economics 76, 167-190.

Murphy, K., 1992. Executive compensation. Handbook of Labor Economics (3B). North-Holland,

Amersterdam, Netherlands.

Murphy, K., 1999. Executive compensation. In: Ashenfelter, O., Card, D. (Eds.), Handbook of Labor

Economics (3B). North-Holland, 2485-2563.

Nelson, J., 2005. Corporate government practices, CEO characteristics and firm performance. Journal of

Corporate Finance 11, 197-228.

Ohlson, J., 1995. Earnings, book values, and dividends in equity valuation. Contemporary Accounting

Research 11, 661-687.

Perry, T., and Zenner, M., 2000. CEO compensation in the 1990s: shareholder alignment or shareholder

expropriation? Wake Forest Law Review 35.

Rajan, R., and Zingales, L., 1998. Power in a theory of the firm. Quarterly Journal of Economics 113,

387-432.

Ravenscraft, D. and Scherer, F., 1987. Mergers, sell-offs, and economic efficiency. Brookings Institution,

Washington, DC.

Rhodes-Kropf, M., Robinson, D., and Viswanathan, S., 2005. Valuation waves and merger activity: the

empirical evidence. Journal of Financial Economics 77, 561-603.

Rhodes-Kropf, M., and Viswanathan, S., 2004. Market valuation and merger waves. Journal of Finance 59,

2685-2718.

Roll, R., 1986. The hubris hypothesis of corporate takeovers. Journal of Business 59, 197-216.

Schwert, W., 2000. Hostility in takeovers: in the eyes of the beholder? Journal of Finance 55, 2599-2640.

Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R., 2003. Stock market driven acquisitions. Journal of Financial Economics 70,

295-311.

Useem, M., 1996. Investor capitalism. BasicBooks, New York, NY.

Vives, X., 1995. Short-term investment and the informational efficiency of the market. The Review of

Financial Studies 8, 125-160.

Wulf, J., 2004. Do CEOs of target firms trade power for premiums? Evidence from “mergers of equals”.

Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 20, 60-101.

28

Page 30: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Figure 1

Shareholder Turnover Residuals over 31 to 395 days prior Announcement: Comparison between

Underpaid and Overpaid Targets

LOS

392

373

354

335

316

297

278

259

240

221

202

183

164

145

126

107

88

69

50

31

Mea

n

12

10

8

6

4

2

0

-2

-4

mreup

mreop

Figure 1 describes daily residual means of target firms’ turnover ratio after the regression on logarithm of

market value of equity in two groups: underpaid and overpaid. Mreup is daily mean of shareholder turnover

residuals in underpaid targets. Mreop is daily mean of shareholder turnover residuals in overpaid targets.

Residuals are calculated using equation (3):

( ) jijiji MELgTurnover εββ ++= *10 ,

where is the turnover ratio of firm j on i days before the announcement, jiTurnover ( )jiMELg is the

logarithm form of market value of firm j on i days before the announcement. The mean of targets

shareholder turnover residuals on i days before the announcement is constructed as:

∑=

=m

jjii m

mreup1

1 ε ; ∑=

=n

jjii n

mreop1

1 ε ;

where m is the number of underpaid targets on i days before the announcement, n is the number of overpaid

targets on i days before the announcement. In figure 1, the MEAN on Y-axis measures the value of mreup

and mreop. LOS on X-axis is the number of days before announcement.

29

Page 31: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Figure 2

Shareholder Turnover Residuals over 31 to 395 days prior Announcement: Comparison between

Targets with Status of Completed and Withdrawn

LOS

392

373

354

335

316

297

278

259

240

221

202

183

164

145

126

107

88

69

50

31

Mea

n

30

20

10

0

-10

mrecom

mreuncom

Figure 2 describes daily residual means of target firms’ turnover ratio after the regression on logarithm of

market value of equity in two groups with different status: completed and withdrawn. Mrecom is daily

mean of shareholder turnover residuals in targets with status of completed. Mreuncom is daily mean of

shareholder turnover residuals in targets with status of withdrawn. Residuals are calculated using equation

(3):

( ) jijiji MELgTurnover εββ ++= *10 ,

where is the turnover ratio of firm j on i days before the announcement, jiTurnover ( )jiMELg is the

logarithm form of market value of firm j on i days before the announcement. The mean of targets

shareholder turnover residuals on i days before the announcement is constructed as:

∑=

=m

jjii m

mrecom1

1 ε ; ∑=

=n

jjii n

mreuncom1

1 ε ;

where m is the number of targets with completed status on i days before the announcement, n is the number

of targets with withdrawn status on i days before the announcement. In figure 2, the MEAN on Y-axis

measures the value of mrecom and mreuncom. LOS on X-axis is the number of days before announcement.

30

Page 32: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

0 .25 .5 .75 1Fraction of the data

Figure 3 plots the quantiles of underpayment. X-axis is the fraction of the data. Y-axis is the magnitude of

underpayment. Underpayment is measured by the defined equations. Positive value of underpay means

overpayment, negative value of underpay means underpayment. The larger the value of underpay, the more

the targets are overpaid; the smaller the value of underpay, the more the targets are underpaid. The dots in

Fig. 4 describe the magnitude of underpayment and the quantile position in the overall dataset.

31

-150

000

-100

000

-500

000

5000

0Q

uant

iles

of U

ND

ER

PA

Y

Quantiles of Underpayment

Figure 3

Page 33: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

The Sample of mergers and acquisitions comes from SDC database and has required information from CRSP, Compustat, ExecuComp and SEC Proxy Statement.

Transactions with announcement date between 1993 and 2002 are included. This table reports year of announcement, number of transactions, mean of target and acquirer size,

mean deal value of transaction, mean value of underpayment and percentage of transactions that are underpaid, using all stock as a method of payment, acquirers and targets

from different industries and finally completed. Target and acquirer size is the market value of firm at the end of year prior the announcement, calculated as the multiplication

of stock price and shares outstanding obtained from CRSP. Deal value is obtained from SDC. Underpayment is measured using the defined method. Target size, acquirer size,

deal value and underpay are in millions of dollars.

Year N Target Size Acquirer Size Deal Value Underpay % Underpay % Stock % Diversified % Complete

1993 1 68.26 674.40 30.00 -194.41 1.00 0.00 1.00 1.00

1994

16 462.13 29427.58 612.99 -55.59 0.63 0.25 0.25 0.94

1995 43 1072.62 11504.24 753.37 -1036.09 0.56 0.37 0.28 0.84

1996 59 594.22 16808.68 721.45 404.27 0.44 0.41 0.31 0.97

1997 96 620.58 20317.53 825.36 -844.52 0.58 0.46 0.38 0.93

1998 110 765.46 19654.37 809.39 -236.46 0.60 0.51 0.33 0.95

1999 154 1861.48 40373.40 1367.01 -820.03 0.51 0.49 0.38 0.94

2000 137 1379.76 20314.24 1928.17 -327.10 0.58 0.49 0.36 0.91

2001 103 607.29 23790.16 648.85 -801.87 0.72 0.49 0.23 0.92

2002 51 1375.16 23144.62 1443.91 -491.98 0.69 0.27 0.20 0.94

Total 770 1091.95 24287.91 1127.55 -529.41 0.58 0.46 0.32 0.93

Summary Statistics for Mergers and Acquisitions

Table 1

32

Page 34: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Table 2

Firm Characteristics classified by Underpayment

In table 2 are means of target and acquirer firms’ characteristics and paired variables related to both

acquirers and targets. The statistics are classified by variable of up. If up is 1 then the observation is

classified as underpayment, else is classified as overpayment. Underpayment is measured by the defined

method. Difference in the last column is calculated by the mean of Overpayment group minus mean of

Underpayment group. P-value of standard t-test is given in the parentheses to compare the means of two

groups. Panel A. reports target firms’ characteristics. Mreone is the mean residual of target firms’ turnover

ratio 395 to 31 days before the announcement of mergers and acquisitions after the regression on logarithm

of market value of equity. Tcc is the CEO total current compensation in the last fiscal year. Rstkgrnt is the

value of restricted stock grants in the last fiscal year owned by CEO. Inmonex is value of in the money

unexercised exercisable options held in the last fiscal year. Inmonun is value of in the money unexercised

unexercisable options held by CEO in the last fiscal year. Shrown is the number of shares owned by CEO at

the end of last fiscal year. Shrownpc is the percentage of common stocks to the shares outstanding held by

CEO at the end of last fiscal year. Shrval is the value of common stock holdings at the end of last fiscal year.

Wealth is the sum of value of restricted stock grants, value of common stock holdings, value of in the

money unexercised exercisable and unexercisale options. Exsecop is the number of securities underlying

unexercised exercisable options granted to CEO at the end of last fiscal year. Unsecop is the number of

securities underlying unexercised unexercisable options. Age is the CEO age at the year of mergers and

acquisitions announcement. Tenure is the number of years CEO has stayed in the position till announcement.

Panel B reports acquirer firms’ characteristics. Variables in Panel B are all about CEO characteristics and

have the same meaning with variables in Panel A. Panel C reports relative difference between acquirers and

targets. Rsize equals target size divided by acquirer size. Both target and acquirer size are measured by

multiplication of stock price and shares outstanding at the end of year prior the announcement. Agedif is the

difference of CEO age between acquirers and targets, measured by the mean of difference between acquirer

CEO age and target CEO age in each observation. Welredif is the difference of residuals between acquirers

and targets after regressing CEO wealth on firm size.

33

Page 35: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Table 2 (cont.)

Total Underpayment Overpayment Difference (p

1.64 0.1830

tcc 499416.8 4.9

rnt

07 07 07 12)

Pane quirer Characteristics

51925 471519.6 -47735.28 (0.26)

rstkg 115357.7 148390 68905.98 -79484.06 (0.27)

inmonex 2428763 2669387 2090384 -579003 (0.43)

inmonun 1580944 1468193 1739501 271307.2 (0.63)

shrown 955796 1073696 789998.5 -283698 (0.19)

shrownpc 6.41 5.87 7.14 1.27 (0.16)

shrval 2.60e+ 3.25e+ 1.69e+ -1.56e+07 (0.

wealth 3.01e+07 3.68e+07 2.08e+07 -1.60e+07 (0.13)

exsecop 224211.8 249514 188957.2 -60556.8 (0.098)

unsecop 212709.6 241288.1 172794.8 -68493.34 (0.07)

age 52.79 51.94 54 2.06 (<0.001)

tenure 7.50 7.06 8.12 1.06 (0.05)

l B. Ac

1400689 1310677

aqrsgrnt

08 08 08 2)

Pa rget and Acq

1445713 579152.3 2664313 2085161 (0.31)

aqinex 1.55e+07 1.74e+07 1.28e+07 -4542501 (0.15)

aqinun 9986936 1.02e+07 9662899 -554463 (0.80)

aqshrown 5656307 8211621 2062898 -6148723 (0.02)

aqshownpc 4.57 5.48 3.28 -2.20 (0.05)

aqshrval 5.80e+ 9.18e+ 1.06e+ -8.12e+08 (0.0

aqwealth 6.07e+08 9.46e+08 1.31e+08 -8.15e+08 (0.01)

aquexex 574065.8 554627.2 601401.3 46774.13 (0.72)

aquexun 500584.5 535526.5 451447.4 -84079.14 (0.34)

aqage 54.68 54.19 55.37 1.18 (0.04)

nel C. Ta uirer

0.71 0.67

agedif 1.99 2.25 1.61 -0.64 (0.43)

welredif 08 +08 5) 5816.43 2.46e+ -3.46e -5.93e+08 (0.0

-value)

Panel A. Target Characteristics

mreone 1.04 -1.4592 (0.05)

aqtcc 1363282 -90011.69 (0.54)

rsize 0.69 -.04 (0.92)

34

Page 36: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Table 3

Mreone of Targets ent Classification

able 3 reports mreone of targets in different classifications. Mreone is residual means of target firm’s

Panel A. All Targets classified into 4 groups

in Differ

T

turnover ratio after regressing on logarithm of market value of equity, calculated by equation (3) and (4). N

is the number of observations in that group. Panel A categorizes all targets into four groups based on the

status and whether they are underpayment or overpayment. Group 1 includes underpaid targets with status

of completed. Group 2 includes overpaid targets with status of completed. Group 3 includes underpaid

targets with status of withdrawn. Group 4 includes overpaid targets with status of withdrawn. F-statistics for

the mean difference among the four groups is reported in the last column. Panel B compares underpaid

targets and overpaid targets in all completed transactions. Difference is measured by mreone in group of

Underpayment minus than in group of Overpayment. Panel C compares all underpaid targets with status of

completed and with status of withdrawn. Difference is measured by mreone in group of Completed minus

that in group of Withdrawn. P-value in Panel B and Panel C is obtained from T-test.

Group 1 F-statistics Group 2 Group 3 Group 4

(p-value)

1.74 (0.16)

N 417 299 33 21

Panel l Targets wit tus of Compl B. Al h sta eted

ment Overpayment

(p-value)

1.64 (0.04)

N 417 299

Panel C. All Und Targets erpaid

Withdrawn

(p-value)

2.30 (0.02)

N 417 33

mreone 1.81 0.17 -0.49 0.36

Underpay Difference

mreone 1.81 0.17

Completed Difference

mreone 1.81 -0.49

35

Page 37: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Table 4

Shareholder Hor Underpayment

able 4 reports the regression results for the entire sample. ModelⅠpresents a logistic regression of the

Model Ⅰ Model Ⅱ Model Ⅲ

izon and

T

likelihood of a target being underpaid. The dependent variable in Model Ⅰ is the probability of

underpayment, measured by variable UP. If UP is 1 then the observation is classified as underpayment, else

is classified as overpayment. ModelⅡuses OLS regression to examine the relation between shareholder

horizon and the magnitude of underpayment. Dependent variable in ModelⅡis underpay, measured by the

defined methods. ModelⅢ uses generalized linear model (GLM) to estimate the relation between

shareholder horizon and underpayment. Dependent variable F(underpay) is the cumulative distribution

function of underpay. Mreone is the mean residual of target firms’ turnover ratio 395 to 31 days before the

announcement of mergers and acquisitions after the regression on logarithm of market value of equity. Rsize

equals target size divided by acquirer size. Both target and acquirer size are measured by multiplication of

stock price and shares outstanding at the end of year prior the announcement. Diver is to measure whether

the transaction occurs between different industries. Diver equals 1 if targets and acquirers have different

industry code. Logev is the logarithm of equity value of target at the announcement day. Equityvalue is

targets’ book value of equity at the announcement day. Stock is a dummy variable to measure the method of

payment. Stock equals 1 when targets are paid by all stock, and 0 when by all cash Mvwretd is the average

monthly value-weighted return (including distributions) in three months prior the announcement of a

transaction. * denotes 10% significant level, ** denotes 5% significant level, *** denotes 1% significant

level.

(n=770) (n=770) (n=770)

P(Underp Underpay F(Underp

0.0149* -14.3156 -0.0021**

rsize -0.0043 -104.1902***

**

ue .5447***

.0464 .0197

td *

.00004

diver 0.3276** -139.4161 -0.0299

logev 0.0924* -0.0341*

equityval -1

stock 0 15.6567 0

mvwre -2.8641 1715.42 0.7594*

constant -1.4384 179.1935 1.1146***

Dependent Variable

ay) ay)

mreone

36

Page 38: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Tab 5

CEO characteristics an ility of Underpayment

able 5 reports logistic regression of underpayment and CEO characteristic variables. Probability of

underpayment, else is classified as overpayment. Horizon is measured by – ( ). Age is the CEO

age70up

Dependent Variable = Probability of Underpayment

le

d Probab

T

underpayment is denoted by dummy variable up. If up is 1 then the observation is classified as

2age

age at the year of mergers and acquisitions announcement. Age65less and are two dummy

variables. Age65less equals 1 if target CEO’s age is smaller than 65, 0 otherwise. Age70up equals 1 if target

CEO’s age is larger than or equal to 70, 0 otherwise. Ten3to5 is 1 if target CEO’s tenure in current position

is longer than 3 years and shorter than 5 years. Rsize, diver, logev, stock and mvwretd are defined same as in

Table 5. * denotes 10% significant level, ** denotes 5% significant level, *** denotes 1% significant level.

100/

Mod Model Ⅳ el Ⅰ Model Ⅱ Model Ⅲ

(n=770) (n=770) (n=770) (n=770)

-0.1481** -0.1572**

age -0.1888** -0.1973**

age65less .0299***

.4801** .4547**

.0025 .0044

td

1

age70up 1.1132**

ten3to5 0 0

rsize -0 -0 -0.0034 -0.0021

diver 0.3258** 0.3427** 0.3694** 0.3436**

logev 0.1109** 0.0855* 0.0869* 0.1062**

stock 0.0792 0.0541 0.0938 0.0909

mvwre -2.5983 -2.5767 -2.5728 -2.4844

constant 3.9591* -2.301** -1.4291 4.1584*

horizon

37

Page 39: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Table 6

CEO compensation and ility of Underpayment

Horizon, age, ten3to5, rsize, diver, logev, stock an mvwretd are defined as in Table 5. Logtgwel and

Dependent Variable = Probability of Underpayment

Probab

d

logaqwel are logarithm form of CEO wealth in targets and acquirers. Wealth is the sum of value of

restricted stock grants, value of common stock holdings, value of in the money unexercised exercisable and

unexercisale options at the end of fiscal year prior the announcement. Welredif is the difference of residuals

between acquirers and targets after regressing CEO wealth on firm size. Tgresratio is measured by target

CEO’s value of restricted stock grants over target size. Weltosize is ratio of target CEO equity-based wealth

over target firm size at the end of fiscal year prior the announcement. Shownpc is percentage of common

shares held by target CEO. * denotes 10% significant level, ** denotes 5% significant level, *** denotes

1% significant level.

Mod Model Ⅳ el Ⅰ Model Ⅱ Model Ⅲ

(n=770) (n=770) (n=770) (n=705)

-0.1662** -0.1662** -0.1442* -0.1667**

age -0.2057***

o5

.69e-11*

121.1903 29.699 12.0751

.0016 .0028 .0041

*

td

-0.2078*** -0.1778** -0.2042**

ten3t 0.4354* 0.4538** 0.6737*** 0.4090*

logtgwel -0.0545 -0.1197***

logaqwel 0.1141***

welredif 4

tgresratio 110.7376 1 1

weltosize 6.2937**

shownpc -0.0695***

rsize -0 -0 0 -0.0026

diver 0.3812** 0.3737** 0.2787 0.3103*

logev 0.1419*** 0.1124** 0.1462* 0.1070**

stock 0.1449 0.1045 0.1227 0.1352

mvwre -2.6584 -2.6247 -0.7396 -2.6832

constant 4.4610* 4.3213* 2.5731 4.1859*

horizon

38

Page 40: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Table 7

CEO Horizon derpayment

able 7 examines the relation between CEO horizon variables and level of underpayment. Panel A. uses

Panel A. Underpay Panel B. F(Underpay)

and Un

T

OLS regression to examine the relation between shareholder horizon and the magnitude of underpayment.

Dependent variable in Panel A. is underpay, measured by the defined methods. Panel B. uses generalized

linear model (GLM) to estimate the relation between shareholder horizon and underpayment. Dependent

variable F(underpay) is the cumulative distribution function of underpay. Dependent variables are same as

defined in Table 6.

Model

Model Ⅲ Ⅴ Ⅰ Model Ⅱ

(n=770) (n=770) (n=770)

Model Ⅳ Model

(n=705) (n=705)

53.4331 84.5958 0.0122 0.0166* 0.0153

age 60.3952 101.8556

o5 *

*

.27e-08** .46e-12***

8726.86 .2594

.2736*

15.9819*** .3955*** .0013 .0002

** ** **

alue .5320*** .5046***

.0128 .0118 .0133

*

*

0.0160 0.0213** 0.0199*

ten3t -604.4351 -417.2946 -0.0732* -0.0467 -0.0430

logtgwel 83.5425 0.0040

logaqwel -68.6217 -0.0134*

welredif -6 -5

tgresratio 1 43133.03 -8 -6.0905

weltosize -0

shownpc 0.0025

rsize -1 -107 -0 -0 -0.0002

diver -169.137 -179.3366 -0.0190 -0.0326 -0.0266

logev -0.0340* -0.0351* -0.0361*

equityv -1 -1

stock -171.9826 -46.6475 0 0 0

mvwretd 1536.951 1594.538 0.6015 0.7183* 0.7062*

constant -1391.014 -2713.068 0.7995* 0.4925* 0.5503*

horizon

39

Page 41: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Table 8

Panel A. Correlation Matri Characteristic Variables

Variable age tenure Exec_dir CEO_block shownpc incent tgresratio tgweltosize logtgwel logtcc

x for CEO

age 1 .0000

tenure 1.0 0

ir 1.0 0

k 1.0 0

1.0 0

1.0 0

io 1.0 0

1.0 00

1.0 0

1.0 0

0.3930 00

Exec_d 0.0395 0.0465 00

CEO_bloc 0.0164 0.2796 0.0586 00

shownpc 0.0225 0.2861 0.0434 0.6156 00

incent -0.0781 -0.2306 0.0031 -0.3131 -0.2502 00

tgresrat 0.1038 -0.0069 0.0151 -0.0697 -0.0491 0.1880 00

tgweltosize -0.0050 0.2478 0.0444 0.5556 0.9112 -0.2008 -0.0351 0

logtgwel 0.0287 0.1758 0.1017 0.3146 0.3554 -0.0069 -0.0039 0.3948 00

logtcc 0.1302 0.0510 0.0572 -0.1568 -0.1193 0.1445 0.0425 -0.0553 0.4084 00

Panel B. Mean and Median in Different Tenure Groups

Shorter than 3 yrs 3 to 5 yrs Longer than 5 yrs

Mean Median Mean ian Mean Median Med

logtgwel 5 9 6 14.624 14.8196 15.365 15.4297 15.571 15.6010

tgweltosize

0 59 56

0.041 0.013 0.059 0.032 0.077 0.041

tgresratio 0.0001 0 0.0001 0 0.0001 0

shownpc 3.740 1 5.224 2.74 8.049 3.7

Table 8 reports the correlation between CEO characteristic variables and the mean and median in different

tenure groups. Age is the CEO age at the year of mergers and acquisitions announcement. Tenure is the

number of years CEO has stayed in the position till announcement. Exec_dir is the dummy variable to

denote whether CEO is also director in the board. CEO_block is the dummy variable to denote whether

CEO is a blockholder. Blockholder is defined as shareholder holding no less than 5% shares of total shares

outstanding. Shownpc is percentage of common shares held by target CEO. Incent is measured by (value of

restricted stock grants + value of in the money unexercised unexercisable options )/ wealth. Tgresratio is

measured by target CEO’s value of restricted stock grants over target size. Weltosize is ratio of target CEO

equity-based wealth over target firm size at the end of fiscal year prior the announcement. Logtgwel is

logarithm form of CEO wealth in targets. Logtcc is the logarithm form of target CEO total current

compensation.

40

Page 42: Market Valuation and Target Ho rizon in Mergers & Acquisitions

Table 9

Target Horizon and Underpayment

Panel A. P(Underpay) Panel B. Underpay Panel C. F(Underpay)

Model Ⅰ

(n=770)

Model Ⅱ

(n=770)

Model Ⅲ

(n=705)

Model Ⅳ

(n=770)

Model Ⅴ

(n=770)

Model Ⅵ

(n=705)

Model Ⅶ

(n=770)

Model Ⅷ

(n=770)

Model Ⅸ

(n=705)

mreone 0.0094 0.0096 0.0070 -11.9840 -11.0774 -12.7634 -0.0015 -0.0014 -0.0014

horizon -0.1521** -0.1614** -0.1619** 69.6642 76.7105 61.7793 0.0146 0.0156 0.0143

age -0.1901** -0.2010*** -0.1967** 84.9798 91.2734 77.1717 0.0188* 0.0199* 0.0185*

ten3to5 0.4516** 0.4503** 0.4077* -405.6874 -410.3706 -449.2893 -0.0452 -0.0458 -0.0423

welredif 4.68e-11* -6.19e-08** -5.40e-12***

tgresratio 113.41 40326.34 -6.4494

weltosize 6.2211** 93.9147 -0.2621*

shownpc -0.0690*** -8.4379 0.0023

rsize -0.0024 -0.0031 -0.0031 -105.3318*** -106.8945*** -105.719*** -0.0002 -0.0001 -0.0001

diver 0.3309** 0.3611** 0.2947* -145.6569 -164.2534 -143.4404 -0.0293 -0.0307 -0.0249

logev 0.1061** 0.1122** 0.1089** -0.0355*** -0.0349*** -0.0361***

equityvalue -1.5460*** -1.5064*** -1.5482***

stock 0.0679 0.0816 0.1081 1.9578 -14.6487 -9.5105 0.0182 0.0160 0.0174

mvwretd -2.6283 -2.7753 -2.8327 1517.563 1793.814 1358.622 0.7226** 0.7445** 0.7281*

constant 3.9373* 4.1124* 3.9255* -2249.287 -2390.144 -2000.822 0.5707* 0.5330* 0.5912*

41


Recommended