+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Measuring Smallholder Commercialization Decisions and Interactions in Ethiopia

Measuring Smallholder Commercialization Decisions and Interactions in Ethiopia

Date post: 10-Mar-2016
Category:
Upload: alexander-decker
View: 220 times
Download: 1 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
 
Popular Tags:
12
Journal of Economics and Sustainable Develo ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (O Vol.3, No.13, 2012 Measuring Small Degy 1. School of Agricultural Econo U 2. School of Agricultur 3. School of Agricultur * Email of The study was sponsored by Swed Development Research Institute (ED Abstract This paper measures the market smallholders in rural Ethiopia and employs different relevant econome Tobit model, univariate and seemin land allocation and crop choices b suggesting that production of staple were determined by similar underly strongly and positively correlated, commercialization in the other an determined by common underlying independent and their determinants Key words: Market orientation, cro 1. Introduction Commercial transformation of sub development for many developing c activity. Agricultural commercializ vertical and horizontal market linka 2010). A farm household is assum commodities, allocating a proporti proportion of its agricultural output beyond supplying surplus products and the decision-making behavio Commercialization is not restricted considerable extent. Policy discourses around various di different types of farms growing di and ‘commercial' (Leavy and Poulto as low, medium or semicommercia actually means may give rise to mis commercialized households are targ to the amount of product they wo Production decisions of commerci whereas those of subsistence farm selling only whatever surplus produ three types of commercialization commercialization, commercializati cash economy (von Braun et al., 1 lopment Online) 150 lholder Commercialization Deci Interactions in Ethiopia ye Goshu 1* , Belay Kassa 2 , Mengistu Ketema 3 omics and Agribusiness, Haramaya University; P.O. B University, Ethiopia; Tel: 251 (0)911057147 ral Economics and Agribusiness, Haramaya University ral Economics and Agribusiness, Haramaya University the corresponding author: [email protected] dish International Development Cooperation Agency DRI) in collaboration with Haramaya University. orientation in land allocation, crop choices and estimates their intensity and interaction at agricultur etric estimation techniques including seemingly unrel ngly unrelated bivariate probit models. The results ind between staples and cash crops were strongly and es and cash crops were competing for limited resources ying covariates. Moreover, crop and livestock commer implying that the scale of commercialization in on nd households’ scale of commercialization in the g factors. However, their crop and livestock commer were basically different. op choice, commercialization, SUR model, bivariate pr bsistence agriculture is a crucial policy choice in countries like Ethiopia, where smallholder farming is t zation brings about sustainable food security and age (von Braun 1994; Timmer 1997; Pingali, 1997; G med to be commercialized if it is producing a signi ion of its resources to marketable commodities, or ts (Immink, et al., 1995). However, the meaning of c to markets. It has to consider both the input and outp or of farm households in production and mark only to cash crops as traditional food crops are also fr imensions of agricultural commercialization tend to s ifferent types of crops with simple distinctions made on, 2007). Household commercialization level can be al and high or commercial). Lack of clarity about w isconceptions. The commonly accepted concept of co geting markets in their production decisions, rather tha ould likely sell due to surplus production (Pingali ialized farmers are based on market signals and co mers are based on production feasibility and subsiste uct is left after household consumption requirements n indices at household level can be specified: o ion of the rural economy, and degree of a household 1994). Households in a subsistence production system www.iiste.org isions and Box: 05, Haramaya y, Ethiopia y, Ethiopia (SIDA) and Ethiopian commercialization of ral enterprise levels. It lated regression (SUR), icated that households’ negatively correlated, s but their crop choices rcialization scales were ne enterprise enhanced e two enterprises was rcialization status were robit. economic growth and the dominant livelihood welfare and enhances Gebremedhin and Jaleta, ificant amount of cash selling a considerable commercialization goes put sides of production, keting simultaneously. requently marketed to a separate producers into e between ‘subsistence' e categorized into three what commercialization ommercialization is that an being related simply and Rosegrant, 1995). omparative advantages, ence requirements, and s are met. Accordingly, output and input side d’s integration into the m are characterized by
Transcript
Page 1: Measuring Smallholder Commercialization Decisions and Interactions in Ethiopia

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)Vol.3, No.13, 2012

Measuring Smallholder

Degye Goshu

1. School of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness, Haramaya UniversityUniversity, Ethiopia

2. School of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness, Haramaya University

3. School of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness, Haramaya University, Ethiopia

* Email of the corresponding author

The study was sponsored by Swedish International Development Development Research Institute (EDRI) in collaboration with Haramaya University.

Abstract

This paper measures the market orientationsmallholders in rural Ethiopia and estimates theiremploys different relevant econometric estimation techniques including seemingly unrelated regression (SURTobit model, univariate and seemingly unrelated bivariate probit models. land allocation and crop choices between staples and cash crops were strongly and negatively correlatedsuggesting that production of staplewere determined by similar underlying covariatesstrongly and positively correlated, commercialization in the other and hdetermined by common underlying factorsindependent and their determinants were basically different.

Key words: Market orientation, crop choice

1. Introduction

Commercial transformation of subsistence agriculture is a crucial policy choice in economic growtdevelopment for many developing countriesactivity. Agricultural commercializationvertical and horizontal market linkage (von Braun 1994; 2010). A farm household is assumed to be commercialized if it is producing a significant amount of cash commodities, allocating a proportion of its resources to marketable commoditiesproportion of its agricultural outputs (beyond supplying surplus products to markets. It has to consider both the input and output sides of production, and the decision-making behavior of farm households in production and marketing simultaneously.Commercialization is not restricted only to cash crops as traditional food crops are also frequently marketed to a considerable extent.

Policy discourses around various dimensions of agricultural commercialization tend to separate producers into different types of farms growing different types of crops with simple distinctions made between ‘subsistence' and ‘commercial' (Leavy and Poulton, 2007as low, medium or semicommercial and high or commercialactually means may give rise to misconceptionscommercialized households are targeting markets in their production decisions, rather than being related simply to the amount of product they would likely sell due to surplus production (Pingali and Rosegrant, 1995). Production decisions of commercialized farwhereas those of subsistence farmers are based on production feasibility and subsistence requirements, and selling only whatever surplus product is left after household consumption requirements athree types of commercialization indices at household level can be specified: output and input side commercialization, commercialization of the rural economy, and degree of a household’s integration into the cash economy (von Braun et al., 1994). Households in a subsistence production system are characterized by

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development 2855 (Online)

150

mallholder Commercialization Decisions

Interactions in Ethiopia

Degye Goshu1*, Belay Kassa2, Mengistu Ketema3

School of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness, Haramaya University; P.O. Box: 05, Haramaya University, Ethiopia; Tel: 251 (0)911057147

School of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness, Haramaya University

School of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness, Haramaya University, Ethiopia

mail of the corresponding author: [email protected]

Swedish International Development Cooperation Agency (SIDADevelopment Research Institute (EDRI) in collaboration with Haramaya University.

This paper measures the market orientation in land allocation, crop choices and smallholders in rural Ethiopia and estimates their intensity and interaction at agricultural enterprise levels.employs different relevant econometric estimation techniques including seemingly unrelated regression (SURTobit model, univariate and seemingly unrelated bivariate probit models. The results indicated that h

between staples and cash crops were strongly and negatively correlatedsuggesting that production of staples and cash crops were competing for limited resourceswere determined by similar underlying covariates. Moreover, crop and livestock commercialization scales were strongly and positively correlated, implying that the scale of commercialization in one enterprise enhance

and households’ scale of commercialization in the two enterprises was determined by common underlying factors. However, their crop and livestock commercialization status were

and their determinants were basically different.

orientation, crop choice, commercialization, SUR model, bivariate probit

Commercial transformation of subsistence agriculture is a crucial policy choice in economic growtdevelopment for many developing countries like Ethiopia, where smallholder farming is the dominant livelihood

commercialization brings about sustainable food security and welfare andage (von Braun 1994; Timmer 1997; Pingali, 1997; Gebremedhin and Jaleta,

A farm household is assumed to be commercialized if it is producing a significant amount of cash commodities, allocating a proportion of its resources to marketable commodities, or selling a considerable proportion of its agricultural outputs (Immink, et al., 1995). However, the meaning of commercialization goes beyond supplying surplus products to markets. It has to consider both the input and output sides of production,

making behavior of farm households in production and marketing simultaneously.ommercialization is not restricted only to cash crops as traditional food crops are also frequently marketed to a

ous dimensions of agricultural commercialization tend to separate producers into growing different types of crops with simple distinctions made between ‘subsistence'

and ‘commercial' (Leavy and Poulton, 2007). Household commercialization level can be categorized into three as low, medium or semicommercial and high or commercial). Lack of clarity about what commercialization actually means may give rise to misconceptions. The commonly accepted concept of comme

mercialized households are targeting markets in their production decisions, rather than being related simply to the amount of product they would likely sell due to surplus production (Pingali and Rosegrant, 1995). Production decisions of commercialized farmers are based on market signals and comparative advantages, whereas those of subsistence farmers are based on production feasibility and subsistence requirements, and selling only whatever surplus product is left after household consumption requirements athree types of commercialization indices at household level can be specified: output and input side commercialization, commercialization of the rural economy, and degree of a household’s integration into the

., 1994). Households in a subsistence production system are characterized by

www.iiste.org

Decisions and

P.O. Box: 05, Haramaya

School of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness, Haramaya University, Ethiopia

School of Agricultural Economics and Agribusiness, Haramaya University, Ethiopia

Agency (SIDA) and Ethiopian

commercialization of agricultural enterprise levels. It

employs different relevant econometric estimation techniques including seemingly unrelated regression (SUR), The results indicated that households’

between staples and cash crops were strongly and negatively correlated, s and cash crops were competing for limited resources but their crop choices

rop and livestock commercialization scales were ialization in one enterprise enhanced

ouseholds’ scale of commercialization in the two enterprises was crop and livestock commercialization status were

SUR model, bivariate probit.

Commercial transformation of subsistence agriculture is a crucial policy choice in economic growth and mallholder farming is the dominant livelihood

brings about sustainable food security and welfare and enhances Gebremedhin and Jaleta,

A farm household is assumed to be commercialized if it is producing a significant amount of cash , or selling a considerable

). However, the meaning of commercialization goes beyond supplying surplus products to markets. It has to consider both the input and output sides of production,

making behavior of farm households in production and marketing simultaneously. ommercialization is not restricted only to cash crops as traditional food crops are also frequently marketed to a

ous dimensions of agricultural commercialization tend to separate producers into growing different types of crops with simple distinctions made between ‘subsistence'

zation level can be categorized into three ). Lack of clarity about what commercialization

The commonly accepted concept of commercialization is that mercialized households are targeting markets in their production decisions, rather than being related simply

to the amount of product they would likely sell due to surplus production (Pingali and Rosegrant, 1995). mers are based on market signals and comparative advantages,

whereas those of subsistence farmers are based on production feasibility and subsistence requirements, and selling only whatever surplus product is left after household consumption requirements are met. Accordingly, three types of commercialization indices at household level can be specified: output and input side commercialization, commercialization of the rural economy, and degree of a household’s integration into the

., 1994). Households in a subsistence production system are characterized by

Page 2: Measuring Smallholder Commercialization Decisions and Interactions in Ethiopia

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)Vol.3, No.13, 2012

income and nutritional requirements predominantly generated from own agricultural production compared to those commercial households which purchase their nutritional requirement1995; Pingali, 2001).

Commercial transformation of subsistence agriculture is an indispensable pathway towards economic growth and development for many agriculture dependent developing countries (von Braun 1994; Pinga1995; Timmer 1997). Commercialization enhances the links between the input and output sides of agricultural markets. It is evidenced that policy, technological, organizational and institutional interventions aimed at promoting commercial transformation of subsistence agriculture should follow twoimproving market orientation of smallholders at production level, and facilitating market entry and participation of households in output and input markets (Gebremedhin and Jalesmallholder commercialization in improving income generationbehavior of smallholders and the commercialization scale at which they are operating is question to be addressed since smallholder commercialization policies are usually designed under such conditions. Various studies on smallholder commercialization generally suggest that there is very low scale of commercialization in Ethiopian agricucommercialization decisions (Jaleta2012).

This study was designed to measure market orientationthese decisions to enhance commercial transformation of smallholders in Ethiopia. empirical information on the simultaneous interaction of household decisions of market orientation in resouallocation and their commercial behavior to participate in household welfare in Ethiopia.

2. Research Methodology

2.1. The Data Set and Variables

Agricultural systems in Ethiopia can be classified into fouand valley mixed agriculture, pastoral livestock production of the arid and semiagriculture (Ayele, 1980). Following this clafarming systems of Central and Eastern highlands which cover about 40 percent of the total sedentary farming systems in Ethiopia. The study used primary data collected from four districts representing the two major sedentary farming systems. To account for the problem of heterogeneity in the study arearandom sampling technique was employedproportionately sampled.

The major endogamous variables considered in the analyand cash crops, value of crop and livestock output sales (log), indices (%), and crop and livestock production quotient weighted by the marketability index of each crop aggregated at a farming system level was the percentage measure used to capture the market orientation scale.literature identifies many covariates for market orientation and commercializationBraun et al. (1994), Strasberg et al.and Gardebroek (2008), Adane (2009factors of commercialization in Ethiopia were hypothesized to be availability, farming experience (years)(hectares), quantity of chemical fertilizer used for crop production (quintals), irrigation water use (binary) or proportion of irrigated land (%), livestock holding in tropical livestock unit (TLU), (head count), value of assets owned (farm, noncredit access (binary) or amount of credit receivedcapital (binary), distance to the nearest market as a pronearest road (km) as a proxy for transaction cost, proximity to a major towninformation, distance to development major cash crop like khat (binary), geographical differences of the samples

2.2. Intensity of Market Orientation

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development 2855 (Online)

151

income and nutritional requirements predominantly generated from own agricultural production compared to those commercial households which purchase their nutritional requirements from nonagricultural sources

Commercial transformation of subsistence agriculture is an indispensable pathway towards economic growth and development for many agriculture dependent developing countries (von Braun 1994; Pinga

). Commercialization enhances the links between the input and output sides of agricultural olicy, technological, organizational and institutional interventions aimed at

transformation of subsistence agriculture should follow twoimproving market orientation of smallholders at production level, and facilitating market entry and participation of households in output and input markets (Gebremedhin and Jaleta, 2010). The dynamics and feasibility of smallholder commercialization in improving income generation is an important policy issue. The commercial behavior of smallholders and the commercialization scale at which they are operating is question to be addressed since smallholder commercialization policies are usually designed under such

smallholder commercialization generally suggest that there is very low scale of commercialization in Ethiopian agriculture and try to identify factors determining the market orientation and

Jaleta and Gardebroek, 2008; Adane, 2009; Mamo et al.,

measure market orientation and commercialization decisions and the interactions of these decisions to enhance commercial transformation of smallholders in Ethiopia. The study has generated new empirical information on the simultaneous interaction of household decisions of market orientation in resouallocation and their commercial behavior to participate in the agricultural output markets for

Agricultural systems in Ethiopia can be classified into four as the highland mixed farming systempastoral livestock production of the arid and semi-arid zones, and commercial

Following this classification, the study was conducted in two Eastern highlands which cover about 40 percent of the total sedentary farming

The study used primary data collected from four districts representing the two major o account for the problem of heterogeneity in the study area

random sampling technique was employed and a total of 260 rural households were randomly

The major endogamous variables considered in the analysis include crop market orientation scalevalue of crop and livestock output sales (log), crop and livestock commercialization scale

crop and livestock commercialization status (binary). A household’s conproduction quotient weighted by the marketability index of each crop aggregated at a farming system level was

measure used to capture the market orientation scale. A large body of theoretical and empirical many covariates for market orientation and commercialization measures as reported by

. (1999), Gabre-Madhin et al. (2007), Gebreselassie and 2009), Mamo et al (2009), and Bedaso et al. (2012). Accordingly, t

in Ethiopia were hypothesized to be family size (head count) (years), literacy status of the household head (binary)

quantity of chemical fertilizer used for crop production (quintals), irrigation water use (binary) or livestock holding in tropical livestock unit (TLU), number of oxen owned

assets owned (farm, non-farm and total), ), income (total, agricultural, and nonor amount of credit received (monetary value), civic engagement as a proxy to social

distance to the nearest market as a proxy for market access (kilo meteras a proxy for transaction cost, proximity to a major town (km) as a proxy for market

distance to development station (km) as a proxy for government extension service, , and a dummy for the farming systems to capture agro

of the samples.

and Commercialization

www.iiste.org

income and nutritional requirements predominantly generated from own agricultural production compared to s from nonagricultural sources (Braun,

Commercial transformation of subsistence agriculture is an indispensable pathway towards economic growth and development for many agriculture dependent developing countries (von Braun 1994; Pingali and Rosegrant,

). Commercialization enhances the links between the input and output sides of agricultural olicy, technological, organizational and institutional interventions aimed at

transformation of subsistence agriculture should follow two-pronged approach: improving market orientation of smallholders at production level, and facilitating market entry and participation

ta, 2010). The dynamics and feasibility of is an important policy issue. The commercial

behavior of smallholders and the commercialization scale at which they are operating is also a critical research question to be addressed since smallholder commercialization policies are usually designed under such

smallholder commercialization generally suggest that there is very low scale of market orientation and

et al., 2009; Bedaso et al.,

tion decisions and the interactions of The study has generated new

empirical information on the simultaneous interaction of household decisions of market orientation in resource markets for enhancing

r as the highland mixed farming system, low plateau arid zones, and commercial

two major sedentary sub-Eastern highlands which cover about 40 percent of the total sedentary farming

The study used primary data collected from four districts representing the two major o account for the problem of heterogeneity in the study area, stratified two-stage

total of 260 rural households were randomly and

sis include crop market orientation scale (%) of staples commercialization scales or

A household’s consumption and production quotient weighted by the marketability index of each crop aggregated at a farming system level was

large body of theoretical and empirical measures as reported by

Gebreselassie and Ludi (2007), Jaleta Accordingly, the common

(head count) as a proxy for labor (binary), cultivated land size

quantity of chemical fertilizer used for crop production (quintals), irrigation water use (binary) or number of oxen owned

, income (total, agricultural, and non-farm), civic engagement as a proxy to social

(kilo meter, km), distance to the as a proxy for market

as a proxy for government extension service, production of to capture agro-climatic and other

Page 3: Measuring Smallholder Commercialization Decisions and Interactions in Ethiopia

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)Vol.3, No.13, 2012

The household’s decisions as to whiparticularly land, labor and capital, are limited.depending on their level of commercial behavior. In this case twoconsidered as the major indicators of land allocation behavior produced by households were determined as the consumption and production quotient of each analyzcommodity in the farming systems. If the entire production was intended for the commercial market, the marketability index amounted to zerothe value of one. For surplus products,proportion to the strength of the surplus quantity, while for deficit products, the greater the deficit, the coefficients were over one, which means in proportion with the deficit. Tstands in reciprocal relation with the calculated coefficient.

A crop specific marketability index follows:

=

ki

k

qt

α

where kα is the proportion of crop the total sample households in a farming system. produced for markets usually have αHousehold’s market orientation index in land allocation is computed from the lahousehold weighted by the marketability index of each crop (Gebremedhin and Jaleta, 2010):

imoicr

00 ≤<> ii moicrandtl

where imoicr is market orientation index of household the total crop land cultivated by household

The higher proportion of land a household allocates to the more marketable crops, the more the household is market oriented. The equation for households’ market orwith the equation of market orientation simultaneously estimated by a two-equation SUR model

moic

moist

where imoist and imoic are market orientation scales of staples and cash crops respectively; and 1x and 2x are their respective vectors of factors determining the scale of household market orientation; 1β and 2β are the respective vectors of coeffici

The intensities of households’ commercialization in the tthe same linear SUR combination of

ln

ln 1

i

i

livs

crops

==

2βx

x

where icropsln and ilivsln are log of cropvectors of variables explaining the respective intensity of commercializationvectors of coefficients; and iv1 and

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development 2855 (Online)

152

The household’s decisions as to which crop category to produce are interdependent for the fact that resources, particularly land, labor and capital, are limited. Households decide to allocate their land among different crops, depending on their level of commercial behavior. In this case two crop categories, staples and cash crops, were considered as the major indicators of land allocation behavior of households. Marketability indices of all crops produced by households were determined as the consumption and production quotient of each analyzcommodity in the farming systems. If the entire production was intended for the commercial market, the

ed to zero and if the consumption and production were identical, the . For surplus products, the coefficients ranged from zero up to one and that being reversible in

of the surplus quantity, while for deficit products, the greater the deficit, the , which means in proportion with the deficit. Therefore, the strength of marketability

stands in reciprocal relation with the calculated coefficient.

crop specific marketability index )( kα is computed for each crop produced at farming system level as

.10

;1

≤≤≥

∑=

=

kki

ni

i ki

ki

andqc

qt

qc

α

is the proportion of crop k consumed )( kiqc to the total amount produced (n a farming system. kα takes a value between 0 and 1, inclusive. Crops mainly

kα values closer to 0.

ousehold’s market orientation index in land allocation is computed from the land allocation pattern of the household weighted by the marketability index of each crop )( kα derived from the above equation

;1 i

ikkk

kki tl

lmoicr ∑

=

=

= α

1≤

is market orientation index of household i , ikl is amount of land allocated to crop the total crop land cultivated by household i .

The higher proportion of land a household allocates to the more marketable crops, the more the household is The equation for households’ market orientation scale was assumed to have some correlation

market orientation scales between staples and cash crops. Accordingly, theyequation SUR model (Zellner, 1962; Greene, 2012):

ii

ii

emoic

emoist

2

111

+=+=

22βx

βx

are market orientation scales of staples and cash crops are their respective vectors of factors determining the scale of household market

are the respective vectors of coefficients, and ie1 and ie2 are their random terms.

The intensities of households’ commercialization in the two enterprises (crop and livestock) were estimated by combination of output sales value and their covariates:

,2

111

i

i

v

v

++

2

β

re log of crop and livestock output sales value, respectively; and vectors of variables explaining the respective intensity of commercialization; 1β and

and iv2 are their random terms.

www.iiste.org

for the fact that resources, Households decide to allocate their land among different crops,

crop categories, staples and cash crops, were Marketability indices of all crops

produced by households were determined as the consumption and production quotient of each analyzed commodity in the farming systems. If the entire production was intended for the commercial market, the

and if the consumption and production were identical, the coefficient had and that being reversible in

of the surplus quantity, while for deficit products, the greater the deficit, the herefore, the strength of marketability

is computed for each crop produced at farming system level as

(1)

)( kiqt aggregated over takes a value between 0 and 1, inclusive. Crops mainly

nd allocation pattern of the derived from the above equation

(2)

is amount of land allocated to crop k , and itl is

The higher proportion of land a household allocates to the more marketable crops, the more the household is ientation scale was assumed to have some correlation

. Accordingly, they were

(3)

are market orientation scales of staples and cash crops (%) of household i , are their respective vectors of factors determining the scale of household market

are their random terms.

livestock) were estimated by

(4)

espectively; and 1x and 2x are and 2β are the respective

Page 4: Measuring Smallholder Commercialization Decisions and Interactions in Ethiopia

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)Vol.3, No.13, 2012

Nonetheless, about 44.2% and 49.2livestock output markets. Estimation of output market participation of househhousehold whether or not it is commercializing or selling its outputs into the market. It does not capture the extent to which a household is commercializing. On the other hand, may lead to biased results. If the amount a household sells into the market was negative or very small, all we observe them is selling nothing. commercialization was represented by a censored regresstechnique is the Tobit model which expresses the observed level in terms of an underlying latent variable. intensity of commercialization in each enterprise was, therefore, estimated by the following separmodels (Tobin, 1958; Long, 1997; Cameron and Trivedi, 2009

iy =

+

=0

iyxβ

where iy is the log value of crop or intensity of crop or livestock commercializa

2.3. Market Participation and Commercialization S

The commercial scale of farm households can usually be divided into two binary values or three ordinal scales (as noncommercial, semicommercial, and commercial), depending on the distribution of the commercialization scale (Bedaso et al., 2012; Pingali 2001).commercialization was left-skewed. households had commercialization index less than or equal to 60%, indicating the majority of them to be either semicommercial or noncommercial. To account for this skewed distribution, assumed to be binary (semicommercial or noncommercial). participation and commercialization statusmodel (Maddala, 1983; Long, 1997;

iy += βx'*

where *iy is binary latent variable for c

x ’s are vectors of household specific and other socioeconomic factors determining the respective endogenous variables; β is the respective vector of coefficients

Like the case in simultaneous estimation of intensity of cropmodel, the interdependence of crop seemingly unrelated bivariate probit model

i

i

comls

comst*

*

=

=

x

x

where icomst and icomls are crop and livestock commercialization statustheir respective error terms in the latent variables, observed and unobserved, were specified as:

=

=

0

comsti

i

comlscomls

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development 2855 (Online)

153

49.2% of the sample households didn’t participate, respectively, in cropsEstimation of output market participation of households measures the status of a

household whether or not it is commercializing or selling its outputs into the market. It does not capture the extent to which a household is commercializing. On the other hand, linear SUR estimation of these variables

If the amount a household sells into the market was negative or very small, all we observe them is selling nothing. To account for both of these problems, intensity of farm output commercialization was represented by a censored regression model. The most common censored regression

is the Tobit model which expresses the observed level in terms of an underlying latent variable. intensity of commercialization in each enterprise was, therefore, estimated by the following separ

Cameron and Trivedi, 2009).

iε+xβ

<

>

0

0,*

*

i

ii

yif

yifε

or livestock output sales, and the x ’s are vectors of covariates determining livestock commercialization; and iε is normally distributed error.

Commercialization Status

ommercial scale of farm households can usually be divided into two binary values or three ordinal scales mmercial, and commercial), depending on the distribution of the commercialization Pingali 2001). In this study, the distribution of the sample households’ scale of

. About 93% of crop producers and 92% of livestock owners households had commercialization index less than or equal to 60%, indicating the majority of them to be either semicommercial or noncommercial. To account for this skewed distribution, their commercialization assumed to be binary (semicommercial or noncommercial). Accordingly, the crop

commercialization statuses of households were estimated by the following univariate probit (Maddala, 1983; Long, 1997; Cameron and Trivedi, 2009; Long and Freese, 2005;

iu+

is binary latent variable for crop or livestock market participation or commercialization status; and ’s are vectors of household specific and other socioeconomic factors determining the respective endogenous

ector of coefficients; and iu is the random term.

Like the case in simultaneous estimation of intensity of crop and livestock commercialization by the linear SUR and livestock commercialization status was simultaneously

probit model specified as (Hardin, 1996; De Luca, 2008; Greene, 2012):

i

i

u

u

22'2

11'1

+

+

βx

βx

are crop and livestock commercialization status, respectivelytheir respective error terms in the bivariate probit and assumed to be normally distributedlatent variables, observed and unobserved, were specified as:

>+=

>+=

00

0

0.if0

;0ifvcomst

*

*322

*

*i

*i1i1

'1

*i

i

iii

comlsif

comlsifvcomls

comst

comst

βx

βx

'

www.iiste.org

households didn’t participate, respectively, in crops and olds measures the status of a

household whether or not it is commercializing or selling its outputs into the market. It does not capture the linear SUR estimation of these variables

If the amount a household sells into the market was negative or very small, all we To account for both of these problems, intensity of farm output

The most common censored regression is the Tobit model which expresses the observed level in terms of an underlying latent variable. The

intensity of commercialization in each enterprise was, therefore, estimated by the following separate Tobit

(5)

(6)

’s are vectors of covariates determining

ommercial scale of farm households can usually be divided into two binary values or three ordinal scales mmercial, and commercial), depending on the distribution of the commercialization

sample households’ scale of of livestock owners of the sample

households had commercialization index less than or equal to 60%, indicating the majority of them to be either commercialization status was

he crop and livestock market of households were estimated by the following univariate probit

Greene, 2012):

(7)

commercialization status; and ’s are vectors of household specific and other socioeconomic factors determining the respective endogenous

livestock commercialization by the linear SUR simultaneously estimated by the , 2008; Greene, 2012):

(8)

respectively; iu1 and iu2 are normally distributed. Accordingly, the

(9)

Page 5: Measuring Smallholder Commercialization Decisions and Interactions in Ethiopia

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)Vol.3, No.13, 2012

3. Results and Discussion

The view that households’ commercialization behavior canmarketability of crops was used as awere computed for staples and cash cropsthe land allocation decision of households allocation behavior into commercialization was measured at an enterprise levelCommercialization scale computed for the commercialization scale. The mean commercialization scale of households was 16.5% for crop and 15.6% for livestock outputs, suggesting insignificant difference in the scaHowever, commercialization scale was largely different commercialization was 34% and 4%, respectively, in Eastern and Central highlandscommercialization scale was 21% and 11% in Eastern and Central highlands.Eastern highlands were relatively more commercial. commercialization status was determined by taking 30% as a cutoffthreshold were considered semicommercial and the rest noncommercial. Based on this, about the households were semicommercial, respectively, in their crop

3.1. Intensity of Market Orientation and

The SUR model estimation results estimation results of market orientation scale was strongly significant in the crop choice between staples and cash staples and cash crops had similar underlying determinantsorientation of land allocation was 77% orientation of households in their land allocation decision was 52% for staples and 25% for cash crops production. The results generally signify production of staples and make less marketdecision to produce staples was primnearest market, the farming system and other shocks. They consider their family size, distance to nearest market, the farming system, and other shocks

Crop and livestock commercialization are normally expected to have linear correlation since intencommercialization in one enterprise other enterprises. To account for thcommercialization scales, the two equatiothe residuals from the two equations were strongly 47% and 11% of the variation in intensity of cropcommercialization in the two entyprises was reinforced between each other. commercialization was enhanced by quantity of fertilizer used, total assets, distance to major town (unexpected sign), and production of major cash crop. A unit change in quintals of fertilizer used increased crop commercialization by about 1.3%. However, the largest contribution in households’ crop commercialization wasthat of major cash crop (khat) production ((0.4%), fertilizer used (0.7%), livestock holding (0.2%), and other exogenous shocks (3.7%),affected by size of cultivated land (0.8%), of commercialization was 4.1% for crops and 3.8% for livestock, suggesting that households were noncommercial. However, households with and without in their intensity of commercialization.

Intensity of crop and livestock commercialization reported in Table 2. Accordingly, the residuals from the estimation of intensity of crop commercialization were normally distributed while those of livestock were notcrop commercialization equation suggest that the factors enhancing intensity of crop commercialization were quantity of fertilizer used, value of total assets, distance unit change in the use of fertilizer increased the marketed crops output by about 2.1%. If households were cash crop producers, their marketed crop output exogenous factors negatively affecting intensity of crop commercialization. These shocks were able to reduce the marketed crop output by 5.2%.were 2.5% and 1.3%, respectivelyconsumption. Households in Eastern compared to their counterparts in Central highlands (2%).

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development 2855 (Online)

154

The view that households’ commercialization behavior can be reflected by their land allocation pattern and the marketability of crops was used as an indicator of household market orientation. The market orientation indices

and cash crops. The crop market orientation index was right-the land allocation decision of households was designed for household consumption. The translation of

into commercialization was measured at an enterprise level e computed for the two enterprises were left-skewed since households had low level of

The mean commercialization scale of households was 16.5% for crop and 15.6% for livestock outputs, suggesting insignificant difference in the scale of commercialization between

ommercialization scale was largely different between farming systems. commercialization was 34% and 4%, respectively, in Eastern and Central highlands

as 21% and 11% in Eastern and Central highlands. In both enterprises, households in Eastern highlands were relatively more commercial. Most households were semicommercial commercialization status was determined by taking 30% as a cutoff point. Households falling above this threshold were considered semicommercial and the rest noncommercial. Based on this, about the households were semicommercial, respectively, in their crop and livestock outputs.

t Orientation and Commercialization

estimation results of market orientation and commercialization are reported in Table 1. The estimation results of market orientation scale verified that the negative cross-equation correlation of residuals

crop choice between staples and cash crops implying that the two equations of staples and cash crops had similar underlying determinants. The variation explained

was 77% for staples and 15% for cash crops. The predicted in their land allocation decision was 52% for staples and 25% for cash crops

generally signify that households allocate the largest proportimake less market-oriented land allocation decisions. Households’ market orientation

decision to produce staples was primarily determined by family size, proportion of irrigated land, distance to the farming system and other shocks. They consider their family size, distance to nearest market,

other shocks to produce cash crops.

livestock commercialization are normally expected to have linear correlation since intencommercialization in one enterprise is dependent on the result of household commercialization

To account for the expected cross-equation correlation in crop and livestock equations were simultaneously estimated by a linear SUR model

equations were strongly and positively correlated and the SUR of the variation in intensity of crop and livestock commercialization, respectively.

commercialization in the two entyprises was reinforced between each other. The results suggestcommercialization was enhanced by quantity of fertilizer used, total assets, distance to major town (unexpected

n), and production of major cash crop. A unit change in quintals of fertilizer used increased crop commercialization by about 1.3%. However, the largest contribution in households’ crop commercialization was

production (4.4%). Livestock commercialization was improved by family size (0.4%), fertilizer used (0.7%), livestock holding (0.2%), and other exogenous shocks (3.7%),

cultivated land (0.8%), and distance to development station (0.2%). Thof commercialization was 4.1% for crops and 3.8% for livestock, suggesting that households were noncommercial. However, households with and without major cash crop production were significantly different

alization.

commercialization was estimated by separate Tobit models and the results . Accordingly, the residuals from the estimation of intensity of crop commercialization were

those of livestock were not (interpretation omitted). The Tobit estimation crop commercialization equation suggest that the factors enhancing intensity of crop commercialization were quantity of fertilizer used, value of total assets, distance to major town, and production of major cash crop. A unit change in the use of fertilizer increased the marketed crops output by about 2.1%. If households were

producers, their marketed crop output would be increased by 6.3%. However, there exogenous factors negatively affecting intensity of crop commercialization. These shocks were able to reduce the marketed crop output by 5.2%. The predicted values of intensity of crop and livestock

vely, suggesting that agricultural outputs were generally Eastern highlands were relatively better in their crop commercialization (3.1%),

compared to their counterparts in Central highlands (2%). Households producing major cash crop

www.iiste.org

be reflected by their land allocation pattern and the of household market orientation. The market orientation indices

-skewed, reflecting that designed for household consumption. The translation of this land

(crop and livestock). skewed since households had low level of

The mean commercialization scale of households was 16.5% for crop and 15.6% for le of commercialization between enterprises.

farming systems. The scale of crop commercialization was 34% and 4%, respectively, in Eastern and Central highlands while livestock

In both enterprises, households in ost households were semicommercial when their

point. Households falling above this threshold were considered semicommercial and the rest noncommercial. Based on this, about 23.5% and 20% of

of market orientation and commercialization are reported in Table 1. The equation correlation of residuals

that the two equations of explained in households’ market

for staples and 15% for cash crops. The predicted scale of market in their land allocation decision was 52% for staples and 25% for cash crops

that households allocate the largest proportion of their land to Households’ market orientation

, proportion of irrigated land, distance to the farming system and other shocks. They consider their family size, distance to nearest market,

livestock commercialization are normally expected to have linear correlation since intensity of commercialization decisions in the

in crop and livestock estimated by a linear SUR model. As expected,

model explained about ation, respectively. The scale of The results suggested that crop

commercialization was enhanced by quantity of fertilizer used, total assets, distance to major town (unexpected n), and production of major cash crop. A unit change in quintals of fertilizer used increased crop

commercialization by about 1.3%. However, the largest contribution in households’ crop commercialization was . Livestock commercialization was improved by family size

(0.4%), fertilizer used (0.7%), livestock holding (0.2%), and other exogenous shocks (3.7%), and negatively The predicted intensity

of commercialization was 4.1% for crops and 3.8% for livestock, suggesting that households were production were significantly different

models and the results . Accordingly, the residuals from the estimation of intensity of crop commercialization were

Tobit estimation results for crop commercialization equation suggest that the factors enhancing intensity of crop commercialization were

to major town, and production of major cash crop. A unit change in the use of fertilizer increased the marketed crops output by about 2.1%. If households were major

increased by 6.3%. However, there were other exogenous factors negatively affecting intensity of crop commercialization. These shocks were able to reduce

and livestock commercialization generally used for household

highlands were relatively better in their crop commercialization (3.1%), major cash crop were

Page 6: Measuring Smallholder Commercialization Decisions and Interactions in Ethiopia

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)Vol.3, No.13, 2012

relatively more commercial (6.9%) than nonof livestock commercialization was influenced by family size, cultivated land, fertilizer used, livestock holding, and distance to development station

3.2. Market Participation and Commercialization Status

The expected interdependence of market participation decisions of households in their crop and livestock outputs was estimated by a bivariate pparticipation decisions of households are independent was rejected at 5% level, suggesting that households considered both enterprises to participate in the output marketunderlying covariates. The model results suggestfertilizer used, distance to major town (unexpected sign), production of major cash crop, and oshocks. On the other hand, participation in the livestock market was determined by family size, cultivated land, livestock holding, access to credit, distance to major town and development station. As indicated by the joint marginal effects, the underlying common determinants of market participation decision of smallholders in Ethiopia were family size (3%), cultivated landaccess to credit (18%), distance to development stationwhich were in line with theoretical and empirical expectationsand livestock output markets were 67% and 50%, respectively. The likelihood of househomarkets of both outputs was 37%, markets of outputs from both enterprises.

Households’ commercialization status for both crop and models and the results reported in Table road and major town, production of major cash crop, and other factorsother hand, was influenced by family size, quantity of chemical fertilizer used for crop production, proximity to development station. The signs of the coefficients for both equations were consistent with theory and other results generated in this study.largely improved (15%) by produccommercialize in crops output was very small (only 4%), as compared to their probability to commerciallivestock outputs (16%). These predictions were increased to 33% for crophouseholds produced major cash cropin Central highlands (18%).

4. Conclusion

The market orientation and commercialization scales and statuses of smallholders in rural Ethiopia measured as both continuous and categorical levels. The SUR model estimation results of market orientation scale of households in land allocation between staples and cash crops were suggesting that production of staples and scale of market orientation of households. of staples and their choices were driven by decisions were determined by similar underlying covariates like distance to nearest market, the farming system and other shockscommercialization scales were strongly and positively correlatedin one enterprise enhances commercialization enterprises was determined by common underlying factors including family size, cultivated land, fertilizer used, livestock holding, total assets, and other exogenous shocks. The predicted intensity of commercialization was 4.1% for crops and 3.8% for livestock, suggesting that households

The Tobit model estimation results quantity of fertilizer used, value of total assets, distance to major town, production of major cash cropshocks. Intensity of livestock commercialization was infllivestock holding, and distance to development station.enterprises was very low or subsistencemarkets were positively correlated and commonly determined by similar underlying covariates such as family size, cultivated land, livestock holding, quantity of fertilizer used, access to credit, distance to development station, and production of major cash crop, all of which were theoretically and empirically justifiable. The probabilities to participate in crop and livestock output markets were 67% and 50%, respectively. However, the

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development 2855 (Online)

155

relatively more commercial (6.9%) than non-cash crop producer households (0.6%). On the other hand, intensity of livestock commercialization was influenced by family size, cultivated land, fertilizer used, livestock holding,

with very low intensity (1.3%).

and Commercialization Status

The expected interdependence of market participation decisions of households in their crop and livestock ivariate probit model as reported in Table 3. The null that crop and livestock market

participation decisions of households are independent was rejected at 5% level, suggesting that households both enterprises to participate in the output markets and their decisions were

The model results suggested that crop market participation was determined by quantity of fertilizer used, distance to major town (unexpected sign), production of major cash crop, and oshocks. On the other hand, participation in the livestock market was determined by family size, cultivated land, livestock holding, access to credit, distance to major town and development station. As indicated by the joint

the underlying common determinants of market participation decision of smallholders in , cultivated land (9%), livestock holding (2%), quantity of fertilizer used

, distance to development station (2%), and production of major cash cropwhich were in line with theoretical and empirical expectations. The predicted probabilitiesand livestock output markets were 67% and 50%, respectively. The likelihood of househo

implying that households were less likely to simultaneously participate in both enterprises.

Households’ commercialization status for both crop and livestock outputs was estimated by univariate probit and the results reported in Table 4. The factors determining crop commercialization were distance to

road and major town, production of major cash crop, and other factors. Livestock commercialization, on the family size, quantity of chemical fertilizer used for crop production, The signs of the coefficients for both equations were consistent with theory

and other results generated in this study. The probability of households to commercialize in crop outputroduction of major cash crops like khat. However,

commercialize in crops output was very small (only 4%), as compared to their probability to commerciallivestock outputs (16%). These predictions were increased to 33% for crops and reduced to 14% for livestock if

major cash crops in Eastern highlands. Livestock commercialization was relatively higher

The market orientation and commercialization scales and statuses of smallholders in rural Ethiopia measured as both continuous and categorical levels. The SUR model estimation results of market orientation

ocation between staples and cash crops were strongly and staples and cash crops were competing for limited resources which influence

scale of market orientation of households. Households allocate the largest proportion of their land to production their choices were driven by less market oriented land allocation decisions.

similar underlying covariates like family size, proportion of irrigatdistance to nearest market, the farming system and other shocks. On the other hand, c

scales were strongly and positively correlated, verifying that the scale of commercialization rcialization in the other. Households’ scale of commercialization in the t

enterprises was determined by common underlying factors including family size, cultivated land, total assets, distance to development station, production of major cash crop

The predicted intensity of commercialization was 4.1% for crops and 3.8% for livestock, suggesting that households in rural Ethiopia were generally noncommercial.

tion results indicated that intensity of crop commercialization wquantity of fertilizer used, value of total assets, distance to major town, production of major cash crop

ntensity of livestock commercialization was influenced by family size, cultivated land, fertilizer used, livestock holding, and distance to development station. The predicted intensities of commercialization in both enterprises was very low or subsistence. Households’ decisions to participate in crop anmarkets were positively correlated and commonly determined by similar underlying covariates such as family size, cultivated land, livestock holding, quantity of fertilizer used, access to credit, distance to development

uction of major cash crop, all of which were theoretically and empirically justifiable. The probabilities to participate in crop and livestock output markets were 67% and 50%, respectively. However, the

www.iiste.org

On the other hand, intensity of livestock commercialization was influenced by family size, cultivated land, fertilizer used, livestock holding,

The expected interdependence of market participation decisions of households in their crop and livestock The null that crop and livestock market

participation decisions of households are independent was rejected at 5% level, suggesting that households were determined by similar

that crop market participation was determined by quantity of fertilizer used, distance to major town (unexpected sign), production of major cash crop, and other exogenous shocks. On the other hand, participation in the livestock market was determined by family size, cultivated land, livestock holding, access to credit, distance to major town and development station. As indicated by the joint

the underlying common determinants of market participation decision of smallholders in , quantity of fertilizer used (12%),

, and production of major cash crop (22%), all of ies to participate in crop

and livestock output markets were 67% and 50%, respectively. The likelihood of households to participate in the that households were less likely to simultaneously participate in

imated by univariate probit . The factors determining crop commercialization were distance to

commercialization, on the family size, quantity of chemical fertilizer used for crop production, and The signs of the coefficients for both equations were consistent with theory

of households to commercialize in crop outputs was However, their likelihood to

commercialize in crops output was very small (only 4%), as compared to their probability to commercialize in and reduced to 14% for livestock if

in Eastern highlands. Livestock commercialization was relatively higher

The market orientation and commercialization scales and statuses of smallholders in rural Ethiopia were measured as both continuous and categorical levels. The SUR model estimation results of market orientation

strongly and negatively correlated competing for limited resources which influenced the

largest proportion of their land to production less market oriented land allocation decisions. Their crop choice

family size, proportion of irrigated land, . On the other hand, crop and livestock

that the scale of commercialization Households’ scale of commercialization in the two

enterprises was determined by common underlying factors including family size, cultivated land, quantity of production of major cash crop

The predicted intensity of commercialization was 4.1% for crops and 3.8% for

intensity of crop commercialization was determined by quantity of fertilizer used, value of total assets, distance to major town, production of major cash crop, and other

family size, cultivated land, fertilizer used, The predicted intensities of commercialization in both

to participate in crop and livestock output markets were positively correlated and commonly determined by similar underlying covariates such as family size, cultivated land, livestock holding, quantity of fertilizer used, access to credit, distance to development

uction of major cash crop, all of which were theoretically and empirically justifiable. The probabilities to participate in crop and livestock output markets were 67% and 50%, respectively. However, the

Page 7: Measuring Smallholder Commercialization Decisions and Interactions in Ethiopia

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)Vol.3, No.13, 2012

likelihood of households to participate in the markethand, households’ crop and livestock basically different. Crop commercialization production of major cash crop, and other factorssize, quantity of chemical fertilizer used, and proximity to development station. commercialize in their crops output was very small (only 4%), as compared to their probability to commercialize in their livestock outputs (16%).

a. 5. References

Adane, T. (2009), “Impact of Perennial Cash Cropping on Food Crop Productio1-34.

Ayele, G, (1980), “Agro-climates and Agricultural Systems in Ethiopia”,

Bedaso, T., Wondwosen, T. & Mesfin, K. (2012). “Production: Factors and Challenges behind, Paper prEthiopian Economy, EEA, July 19-21, 2012, Addis Ababa, Ethiopia.

Cameron, C. & Trivedi, T.K. (2009), Microeconometrics Using Stata, StataCorp Ld, USA.

De Luca, G. (2008), “SNP and SML Estimation of UnJournal, 8, 190–220.

Gebremedhin, B & Jaleta, M. (2010), “into Market Participation?” ILRI (International Livestock Research Ins

Gebreselassie, S. & Ludi, E. (2007), “Commercialization of Smallholder Agriculture in Selected TefAreas of Ethiopia”, Ethiopian Journal of Economics

Greene, W. H. (2012), “Econometric Analysis”

Hardin, J. W. (1996), “Bivariate Probit Models”, Stata Technical Bulletin TX: Stata Press.

Immink, M.D.C, Sibrian, R., Alarcon, J.A., & Hahn, H. (1995. “Field and Analytical Methods fCommercialization Studies: Guatemala”, IN: G. J. Scott (ed) Prices, products, and people: analyzing agricultural markets in developing countries, pp 187

Jaleta, M. & Gardebroek, C. (2008), “Crop and MarkEthiopian Journal of Economics, 7(1)

Leavy, J., & Poutlton, C. (2007), “Commercializations in Agriculture”, 3-41.

Long, J.S. & Freese, J. (2005), “ Regressionedition, Stata Press, USA, 527p.

Long, J.S., 1997. Regression Models for Categorical and Limited Dependent Variables Oaks, CA: Sage Press.

Maddala, G. S. (1983), “LimitedCambridge University Press.

Mamo, G., Assefa A. & Degnet A. (2009), “Determinants of Smallholder Crop Farmers’ Decision to Sell and for Whom to Sell: Micro-level Data Evidence from Ethiopia”, In:the Ninth International Conference on the Ethiopian Economy, PP 47

Pingali, P., & Rosegrant, M. (1995), “Agricultural Commercialization and Diversification: Process and Policies”, Food Policy 20(3), 171-185.

Pingali, P.L (1997), “From Subsistence to Commercial Production Systems: The Transformation of Asian Agriculture”, American Journal of Agricultural Economics

Strasberg, P.J., Jayne, T.S., Yamano, T., Karanja, D. & NyoCommercialization on Food Crop Input Use and Productivity in Kenya”, Working Paper No.71.

Timmer, C.P. (1997), “Farmers and Markets: The Political Economy of New Paradigms”, Agricultural Economics, 79, 621-627.

Tobin, J. (1958), “Estimation of Relationships for Limited Dependent Variables”,

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development 2855 (Online)

156

likelihood of households to participate in the markets of both enterprises was less likely (37%).crop and livestock commercialization status were independent and their determinants were

rop commercialization status was determined by distance to road and mproduction of major cash crop, and other factors while livestock commercialization was influenced by family size, quantity of chemical fertilizer used, and proximity to development station. The probability of households to

crops output was very small (only 4%), as compared to their probability to commercialize in their livestock outputs (16%).

Adane, T. (2009), “Impact of Perennial Cash Cropping on Food Crop Production and Productivity”, EJE, 18(1),

climates and Agricultural Systems in Ethiopia”, Agricultural Systems

Bedaso, T., Wondwosen, T. & Mesfin, K. (2012). “Commercialization of Ethiopian Smallholder Farmers Production: Factors and Challenges behind, Paper presented on the Tenth International Conference on the

21, 2012, Addis Ababa, Ethiopia.

Cameron, C. & Trivedi, T.K. (2009), Microeconometrics Using Stata, StataCorp Ld, USA.

De Luca, G. (2008), “SNP and SML Estimation of Univariate and Bivariate Binary-Choice Models”,

Gebremedhin, B & Jaleta, M. (2010), “Commercialization of Smallholders: Does Market OILRI (International Livestock Research Institute), Addis Ababa, Ethiopia.

Gebreselassie, S. & Ludi, E. (2007), “Commercialization of Smallholder Agriculture in Selected TefEthiopian Journal of Economics, 16(1), 57-88.

Econometric Analysis” (7th Edition). New Jersey: Pearson Hall, USA.

Hardin, J. W. (1996), “Bivariate Probit Models”, Stata Technical Bulletin Reprints, 6: 152

Immink, M.D.C, Sibrian, R., Alarcon, J.A., & Hahn, H. (1995. “Field and Analytical Methods fCommercialization Studies: Guatemala”, IN: G. J. Scott (ed) Prices, products, and people: analyzing agricultural markets in developing countries, pp 187-215, Lynne Rienner Publishers, USA.

Jaleta, M. & Gardebroek, C. (2008), “Crop and Market Outlet Choice Interactions at Household Level”. 7(1), 29-47.

Leavy, J., & Poutlton, C. (2007), “Commercializations in Agriculture”, Ethiopian Journal of Economics

Long, J.S. & Freese, J. (2005), “ Regression Models for Categorical Dependent Variables Using Stata”, 2

Regression Models for Categorical and Limited Dependent Variables (RMCLDV), Thousand

Limited-Dependent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics”,

Mamo, G., Assefa A. & Degnet A. (2009), “Determinants of Smallholder Crop Farmers’ Decision to Sell and level Data Evidence from Ethiopia”, In: Getnet A. & Worku G. (eds), Proceedings of

the Ninth International Conference on the Ethiopian Economy, PP 47-76, Addis Ababa, Ethiopia.

Pingali, P., & Rosegrant, M. (1995), “Agricultural Commercialization and Diversification: Process and Policies”,

Pingali, P.L (1997), “From Subsistence to Commercial Production Systems: The Transformation of Asian American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 79, 628-634.

Strasberg, P.J., Jayne, T.S., Yamano, T., Karanja, D. & Nyoro, J. (1999), “Effects of AgriculturalCommercialization on Food Crop Input Use and Productivity in Kenya”, MSU International

Timmer, C.P. (1997), “Farmers and Markets: The Political Economy of New Paradigms”, 627.

Tobin, J. (1958), “Estimation of Relationships for Limited Dependent Variables”, Econometrica,

www.iiste.org

s of both enterprises was less likely (37%). On the other were independent and their determinants were

distance to road and major town, was influenced by family

he probability of households to crops output was very small (only 4%), as compared to their probability to

n and Productivity”, EJE, 18(1),

Agricultural Systems, 5(1), 39-50.

Commercialization of Ethiopian Smallholder Farmers esented on the Tenth International Conference on the

Cameron, C. & Trivedi, T.K. (2009), Microeconometrics Using Stata, StataCorp Ld, USA.

Choice Models”, Stata

Commercialization of Smallholders: Does Market Orientation Translate ), Addis Ababa, Ethiopia.

Gebreselassie, S. & Ludi, E. (2007), “Commercialization of Smallholder Agriculture in Selected Tef-Growing

). New Jersey: Pearson Hall, USA.

Reprints, 6: 152–158, College Station,

Immink, M.D.C, Sibrian, R., Alarcon, J.A., & Hahn, H. (1995. “Field and Analytical Methods for Agricultural Commercialization Studies: Guatemala”, IN: G. J. Scott (ed) Prices, products, and people: analyzing agricultural

et Outlet Choice Interactions at Household Level”.

Ethiopian Journal of Economics, 16(1),

Models for Categorical Dependent Variables Using Stata”, 2nd

(RMCLDV), Thousand

ndent and Qualitative Variables in Econometrics”, Cambridge:

Mamo, G., Assefa A. & Degnet A. (2009), “Determinants of Smallholder Crop Farmers’ Decision to Sell and Getnet A. & Worku G. (eds), Proceedings of

76, Addis Ababa, Ethiopia.

Pingali, P., & Rosegrant, M. (1995), “Agricultural Commercialization and Diversification: Process and Policies”,

Pingali, P.L (1997), “From Subsistence to Commercial Production Systems: The Transformation of Asian

ro, J. (1999), “Effects of Agricultural MSU International Development

Timmer, C.P. (1997), “Farmers and Markets: The Political Economy of New Paradigms”, American Journal of

Econometrica, 31: 24-36.

Page 8: Measuring Smallholder Commercialization Decisions and Interactions in Ethiopia

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)Vol.3, No.13, 2012

von Braun, J. & Kennedy, E. (eds), (1994), “Agricultural commercialization, Economic Development, and Nutrition”, The Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore and London.

von Braun, J. (1995), “Agricultural Commercialization: Impacts on Income, Nutrition, and Implications for Policy”, Food Policy 20(3), 87-202.

Zellner, A. (1962), “Further Properties of EfInternational Economic Review, 3, 300

Table 1: Simultaneous estimation results of market orientation and

Variables

Family size

Literacy status

Farming experience

Land cultivated

Proportion of irrigated land

Quantity of fertilizer

Livestock holding (TLU)

Number of oxen

Value of total assets (log)

Distance to nearest market

Proximity to major town

Distance to nearest roads

Distance to development station

Production of major cash crop

Farming system

Constant

R2

Predicted value (base run)

Predicted value (with khat)

Predicted value (without khat)

Cross-equation correlation of residuals

Breusch-Pagan LM test of independence, ( ))1Pr( 2χ

Note: ***, **, and *, respectively, signify significance levels of 1%, 5% and 10%.

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development 2855 (Online)

157

von Braun, J. & Kennedy, E. (eds), (1994), “Agricultural commercialization, Economic Development, and rition”, The Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore and London.

on Braun, J. (1995), “Agricultural Commercialization: Impacts on Income, Nutrition, and Implications for 202.

Zellner, A. (1962), “Further Properties of Efficient Estimators in Seemingly Unrelated Regression Equations”, 300-313.

: Simultaneous estimation results of market orientation and commercialization scales

Coefficients (Equation

Market orientation scale Commercialization scale

Staples Cash crops Crop

-0.01* 0.01* 0.07

-0.02 0.002

-0.0004 0.0003 0.01

- - -0.30

0.07* -0.04

-0.01 0.01 1.30***

- - -0.001

0.002 0.0004

0.007 -0.003 0.23*

0.007*** -0.01*

0.0003 -0.0003 0.05***

- - -0.06

- - -0.06

- - 4.42***

-0.54*** 0.12*** 0.68

0.70*** 0.20** -0.85

0.77 0.15 0.47

0.52 0.25 4.14

- - 7.26

- - 2.85

equation correlation of residuals -0.67

agan LM test of independence, 0.00

Note: ***, **, and *, respectively, signify significance levels of 1%, 5% and 10%.

www.iiste.org

von Braun, J. & Kennedy, E. (eds), (1994), “Agricultural commercialization, Economic Development, and

on Braun, J. (1995), “Agricultural Commercialization: Impacts on Income, Nutrition, and Implications for

ficient Estimators in Seemingly Unrelated Regression Equations”,

commercialization scales

Coefficients (Equations)

Commercialization scale

Crop Livestock

0.07 0.36***

- -

0.01 -0.01

0.30 -0.84**

- -

1.30*** 0.66**

0.001 0.24**

- -

0.23* -0.07

- -

0.05*** -0.001

0.06 -0.06

0.06 -0.19***

4.42*** -0.25

0.68 -0.71

0.85 3.65**

0.47 0.11

4.14 3.81

7.26 3.63

2.85 3.88

0.18

0.00

Page 9: Measuring Smallholder Commercialization Decisions and Interactions in Ethiopia

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)Vol.3, No.13, 2012

Table 2: Tobit estimation results of intensity of commerciali

Variables

Family size

Farming experience

Land cultivated

Quantity of fertilizer

Livestock holding (TLU)

Value of total assets (log)

Distance to major town

Distance to nearest road

Distance to development station

Production of major cash crop

Farming system

Constant

Sigma

Predicted value (base run)

Predicted value (Hararghe highlands

Predicted value (Central highlands)

Predicted value (with khat)

Predicted value (without khat)

Log likelihood

( ) 211 χLR

Pseudo R2

Left censored observations

Normality test of residuals, 2χ>P

Note: ***, **, and *, respectively, signify significance levels of 1%, 5% and 10

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development 2855 (Online)

158

: Tobit estimation results of intensity of commercialization (%) by enterprises

Coefficients (Equations)

Crop

0.09

0.03

-0.51

2.12***

-0.02

0.40*

0.08***

-0.13

-0.11

6.34***

1.17

-5.24**

4.43

2.45

Hararghe highlands) 3.12

1.95

6.94

0.59

-496.39

145.34

0.13

115

( )22 0.97

Note: ***, **, and *, respectively, signify significance levels of 1%, 5% and 10%.

www.iiste.org

Livestock

0.67***

-0.02

1.73**

1.13*

0.46**

-0.11

-.01

-.07

-.52***

-.32

-1.77

1.49

6.48

1.29

0.27

2.04

1.07

1.38

-527.77

27.63

0.03

128

0.00

Page 10: Measuring Smallholder Commercialization Decisions and Interactions in Ethiopia

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)Vol.3, No.13, 2012

Table 3: Bivariate probit estimation results of crop and livestock market participation

Variables

Family size

Farming experience

Land cultivated

Livestock holding (TLU)

Quantity of fertilizer

Value of total assets (log)

Access to credit

Distance to nearest road

Distance to major town

Distance to development station

Production of major cash crop

Farming system

Constant

Ath rho

Rho

Log psuedolikelihood

Wald ( )242χ

Wald test of 0=ρ , ( )1Pr 2χ>

Predicted probability

Note: ***, **, and *, respectively, signify significance levels of 1%, 5% and 10%.

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development 2855 (Online)

159

: Bivariate probit estimation results of crop and livestock market participation status

Coefficients (Equations) Marginal effects

Crop Livestock Crop Livestock

0.03 0.10** 0.01 0.04**

0.01 -0.003 0.002 -

-0.13 -0.24* -0.05 -

-0.03 0.10*** -0.01 0.04***

0.52*** 0.11 0.19***

0.09 -0.01 0.03 -

0.32 0.44** 0.11 0.17**

-0.02 -0.02 -0.01 -

0.02*** -0.0004 0.01*** -

-0.03 -0.08** -0.01 -0.03***

2.45*** -0.13 0.59***

0.19 -0.11 0.07

-1.59*** -0.23

0.25**

0.24

-274.03

93.57

0.05

0.67

Note: ***, **, and *, respectively, signify significance levels of 1%, 5% and 10%.

www.iiste.org

status

Marginal effects

Livestock Joint effect

0.04** 0.03**

-0.001 0.0001

-0.10* -0.09*

0.04*** 0.02*

0.04 0.12**

-0.003 0.01

0.17** 0.18**

-0.001 -0.01

-0.0002 0.003

0.03*** -0.02**

-0.05 0.22**

-0.04 0.00

0.50 0.37

Page 11: Measuring Smallholder Commercialization Decisions and Interactions in Ethiopia

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development ISSN 2222-1700 (Paper) ISSN 2222-2855 (Online)Vol.3, No.13, 2012

Table 4: Univariate probit estimation results of agricultural commercialization status

Determinants

Family size

Farming experience

Land cultivated

Land allocated to staples

Land allocated to cash crops

Proportion if irrigated land

Quantity of fertilizer

Livestock holding (TLU)

Access to credit

Value of total assets (log)

Social capital

Distance to major town

Distance to nearest market

Distance to nearest road

Distance to development station

Production of major cash crop

Farming system

Constant

Log likelihood

( ) 212,11 χLR

Pseudo R2

Predicted probability (base run)

Probability (Hararghe highlands with

Probability (Hararghe highlands without

Probability (Central highlands with

Probability (Central highlands without

Note: ***, **, and *, respectively, signify significance levels of 1%, 5% and 10%.

Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development 2855 (Online)

160

e probit estimation results of agricultural commercialization status

Coefficients (Equations) Marginal effects

Crop Livestock Crop

0.10 0.11** 0.01

0.02 0.01 0.002

- -0.32 -

-0.30 - -0.03

- 0.41 -

- - -

0.18 0.41*** 0.02

-0.07 -0.07 -0.01

- - -

0.11 -0.07 0.01

- -

-0.05* -0.01 -0.01*

- - -

-0.07* -0.02 -0.01

-0.10 -0.10* -0.01

1.12*** - 0.15*

0.90 -0.15 0.09

-2.51* -0.12 -

-64.51 -114.90

154.27 30.41

0.54 0.12

0.04

Probability (Hararghe highlands with khat) 0.33

Probability (Hararghe highlands without khat) 0.06

Probability (Central highlands with khat) 0.09

Probability (Central highlands without khat) 0.01

te: ***, **, and *, respectively, signify significance levels of 1%, 5% and 10%.

www.iiste.org

Marginal effects

Crop Livestock

0.01 0.03**

0.002 0.001

-0.08

0.03 -

0.10

-

0.02 0.10***

0.01 -0.02

-

0.01 -0.02

-

0.01* -0.002

-

0.01 -0.01

0.01 -0.02**

0.15* -

0.09 -0.04

-

0.04 0.16

0.33 0.14

0.06 0.14

0.09 0.18

0.01 0.18

Page 12: Measuring Smallholder Commercialization Decisions and Interactions in Ethiopia

This academic article was published by The International Institute for Science,

Technology and Education (IISTE). The IISTE is a pioneer in the Open Access

Publishing service based in the U.S. and Europe. The aim of the institute is

Accelerating Global Knowledge Sharing.

More information about the publisher can be found in the IISTE’s homepage:

http://www.iiste.org

CALL FOR PAPERS

The IISTE is currently hosting more than 30 peer-reviewed academic journals and

collaborating with academic institutions around the world. There’s no deadline for

submission. Prospective authors of IISTE journals can find the submission

instruction on the following page: http://www.iiste.org/Journals/

The IISTE editorial team promises to the review and publish all the qualified

submissions in a fast manner. All the journals articles are available online to the

readers all over the world without financial, legal, or technical barriers other than

those inseparable from gaining access to the internet itself. Printed version of the

journals is also available upon request of readers and authors.

IISTE Knowledge Sharing Partners

EBSCO, Index Copernicus, Ulrich's Periodicals Directory, JournalTOCS, PKP Open

Archives Harvester, Bielefeld Academic Search Engine, Elektronische

Zeitschriftenbibliothek EZB, Open J-Gate, OCLC WorldCat, Universe Digtial

Library , NewJour, Google Scholar


Recommended