+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health...

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health...

Date post: 08-Jul-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
32
MEDICARE FOR ALL? LESSONS FROM ABROAD FOR COMPREHENSIVE HEALTH - CARE REFORM REPORT | November 2019 Chris Pope Senior Fellow
Transcript
Page 1: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

MEDICARE FOR ALL? LESSONS FROM ABROAD FOR COMPREHENSIVE HEALTH-CARE REFORM

REPORT | November 2019

Chris PopeSenior Fellow

Page 2: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

2

About the AuthorChris Pope is a senior fellow at the Manhattan Institute. Previously, he was director of policy research at West Health, a nonprofit medical research organization; health-policy fellow at the U.S. House Committee on Energy and Commerce; and research manager at the American Enterprise Institute. Pope’s research focuses on health-care payment policy, and he has recently published reports on hospital-market regulation, entitlement design, and insurance-market reform. His work has appeared in, among others, the Wall Street Journal, Health Affairs, U.S. News & World Report, and Politico.

Pope holds a B.Sc. in government and economics from the London School of Economics and an M.A. and Ph.D. in political science from Washington University in St. Louis.

Page 3: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

3

Contents Executive Summary ..................................................................4

The Interaction of Health-Care Entitlements and Private Insurance ...............................................................5

Models of Public-Private Interaction ..........................................6

The Health-Care Models Assessed: Access, Volume, Quality, and Cost ....................................................................17

Conclusion .............................................................................24

Endnotes ................................................................................26

I.

I I.I II.

Page 4: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

4

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

Executive Summary The “Medicare for All” proposals espoused by various Democratic presidential candidates vary greatly in terms of benefits, provider payment arrangements, and the role of private insurance. In some versions, the government is the sole purchaser of medical services; in others, a publicly financed system would allow individuals to choose between a government plan and competing private insurers; in still others, a publicly managed option would be added to the wide variety of insurance and entitlement programs that already exist. There has also been a lively disagreement about whether individuals should be allowed to purchase private insurance to obtain better care than is available under a publicly financed plan. In their variety, the various Medicare for All proposals reflect the diversity of arrangements by which medical care is financed in the Western world. In order to better evaluate U.S. Medicare for All proposals, this paper ex-amines the varied roles that eight developed countries (including the U.S.) have afforded to private resources and insurance competition within their health-care systems.

There are four broad models: Single payer (Canada and U.K.): the government is the predominant purchaser of medical services.

Dual payer (Australia and France): the government is the primary purchaser of medical services, with widespread private supplemental health insurance.

Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly subsidizes individually purchased health insurance.

Segmented payer (U.S.): a patchwork of employer-sponsored insurance, public entitlements, and individually purchased health insurance.

This report concludes that, across these eight countries, the ability of citizens to obtain expensive medical pro-cedures tends to increase in proportion to their ability to purchase insurance for medical care beyond what public entitlements cover. Single-payer systems, which restrict the ability of individuals to purchase private in-surance, deliver consistently worse access to specialty care or surgical procedures—without reducing individuals’ overall out-of-pocket health-care costs. Relative to countries that restrict private insurance, the U.S. provides good access to high-quality care, but individuals who fall in the gaps between employer-sponsored insurance and public entitlements are at risk of high costs. Systems that seamlessly integrate competitive private insurance with well-targeted public subsidies prove best able to make use of private resources with minimal gaps in coverage.

Page 5: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

5

I. The Interaction of Health-Care Entitlements and Private InsuranceAs Democratic presidential hopefuls debate “Medicare for All” proposals, the key division among them involves private insurance. Should it compete alongside a public option? Should it be allowed to pay for access to medical care over and above the public plan? Should it be prohibited altogether?1

Health care everywhere in the Western world is paid for by a mix of public and private funds, with governments in North America and Western Europe spending 6%–10% of GDP on medical entitlements (the U.S. spends 8.5%). On top of this, private health-care spending in these countries varies from 1% to 9% of GDP (the U.S. spends 8.8%).2

In the mid-20th century, given the limits of medical technology, governments in the developed world could re-alistically purchase all effective medical care for all citizens within reasonable fiscal constraints. Today, in the world of heart transplants, knee replacements, and new immunotherapies becoming available every year, this is no longer the case. That is a consequence of medical progress and is fundamentally a good thing—but as citizens live longer into old age and disease, and more can be done for them when they need treatment, it does mean that every country faces difficult trade-offs and limits in allocating scarce public funds. There are economic, cultural, and political limits to how much the government can raise in taxes—and public funds that are spent on health care reduce the amount that is available to defense, infrastructure, education, and the relief of poverty.

Private health insurance tends to be defined by the shape and limits of public spending. Where the coverage under public entitlements falls short, private insurance will tend to grow to fill the gap. This is true for benefits excluded in public entitlements (prescription drugs in Canada), cost-sharing (coinsurance in France), waiting times (elective surgery in the U.K.), and eligibility restrictions (able-bodied working-age adults in the U.S.).

The debate over the value of private insurance is partly a question of efficiency.3 But it is, above all, a question of whether private access to medical care beyond that funded by public entitlements is to remain a viable and meaningful option—for those other than the very few who are able to spend tens or hundreds of thousands of dollars out-of-pocket for care.

Some argue that private demand risks taking physicians away from public entitlements or driving up the costs of employing them, thus diverting care from those who most need it to those who can most afford to pay for it.4 Physicians and hospitals who can bill privately may choose to see only patients who are easier to treat.5 However, in the long run, preventing doctors from treating privately insured patients may not be the best way to increase their willingness to treat individuals covered by public entitlements and might divert skilled workers from the medical profession altogether.

MEDICARE FOR ALL? LESSONS FROM ABROAD FOR COMPREHENSIVE HEALTH-CARE REFORM

Page 6: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

6

For capital-intensive medical goods, such as hospital capacity or new drugs, increased private spending may likely help reduce average costs for public payers, as overheads can be spread over a larger level of output—with the cost borne by public entitlements and low-in-come patients able to be further reduced by price dis-crimination. However, if most hospital revenue comes from well-insured patients, attempts to attract them may increase the technological intensity and quality of care, which drives up the cost of treatment for all. But differences in the level of intensity of care from hospi-tal to hospital and neighborhood to neighborhood may mitigate this externality.

To the extent that people are able to pay for services privately that would otherwise be provided publicly, a public entitlement program may have more funds to treat those remaining. Universal public entitlements, by contrast, may crowd out private spending, in which case higher taxes are incurred, without greatly expand-ing the provision of medical care.6 Health-care entitle-ments that incorporate an element of means-testing may be more distributionally progressive, as benefits are concentrated on low-income enrollees, and the same value of public spending can be funded without taxes on low- to middle-income citizens. This dynamic may also hold, to some extent, for universal public-ly financed benefits, which provide inferior access to medical care, from which more affluent citizens may opt out.7

The interaction of public and private payers may create an incentive for them to shift costs to each other, con-fusing responsibility and impeding accountability. Mixing public funds and private administration creates a risk that firms will try to privatize profits while social-izing losses. Providing subsidies for individuals to pur-chase private insurance may not save public programs much money if these individuals would purchase in-surance anyway and if they had previously used little care from the public system.8 It may be easier to ensure that public subsidies are focused on advancing public priorities if the government entirely controls their dis-posal through public facilities.9

The incentives created by the interaction of public pro-grams and private insurance are undoubtedly highly sensitive to small details of private market regula-tions and conditions attached to public payments. It is therefore essential to structure public programs and private insurance markets so that each is coordinated to complement the other, and so that organizations are accountable for efficiently delivering care, rather than encouraged to shift costs to each other.

II. Models of Public-Private InteractionHealth-care systems may be understood as operating along a spectrum that ranges from a pure single-pay-er model, where the government directly purchases all medical services, to a pure competing-payer model, where competing private organizations purchase all medical services. The dual-payer model exists as a hybrid, while the segmented-payer model refers to a patchwork of single, dual, and competitive payer models, each applying to different segments of the population. In this paper, the health-care systems of

Glossary• Balance billing: an amount charged to patients by

health-care providers above the government fee schedule

• Capitation: payment per patient treated, rather than according to services provided

• Coinsurance: a proportion of the bill that individuals must pay out-of-pocket

• Copay: a fixed per-service amount that individuals must pay out-of-pocket

• Deductible: an amount of medical costs the individual pays before insurance pays for services

• Dual practice: the right of physicians to work for both public and private payers

• Community rating: the requirement that premiums do not vary with enrollees’ medical risks

• Fee schedule: the government’s list of prices it will pay for medical services

• Global budget: the government’s limit on a hospital’s aggregate annual spending

• Preexisting condition: a medical problem or need that an individual has prior to the purchase of insurance

• Reference price: fixed reimbursement above which patients must pay costs out-of-pocket

• Risk adjustment: redistribution between insurers according to medical needs of enrollees

• Selective contracting: agreements between insurers and providers to join a network of preferred providers

• Underwriting: varying insurance premiums according to enrollees’ medical risks

Page 7: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

7

eight developed countries—for which standardized data are available and collected by the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)—are analyzed and compared:

• Single payer (Canada and U.K.): the government is the predominant purchaser of medical services, with restrictions on private insurance.

• Dual payer (Australia and France): the govern-ment is the primary purchaser of medical services, supplemented by private insurance whose premi-ums are publicly subsidized.

• Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, Switzerland): the government subsidizes the pur-chase of private insurance.

• Segmented payer (U.S.): a patchwork of employ-er-sponsored insurance, public entitlements, and individually purchased insurance.

Canada (single payer)Canada provides a universal entitlement to hospital and physician services funded through general taxation, with no associated out-of-pocket costs. It effectively prohibits the purchase of private health insurance that would improve individuals’ access to medically neces-sary services.

The public entitlement. The Canada Health Act of 1984 requires provinces to administer comprehensive coverage of all hospital and physician services through a uniform and universal entitlement that is portable across provinces and has no out-of-pocket costs for pa-tients.14 Provinces that comply with the Canada Health

Act are eligible for block grants worth 23% of their health-care spending.15 Dollar-for-dollar deductions are made from these federal grants to the extent that patients must incur out-of-pocket costs (such as copays or deductibles) to obtain covered services.16 Almost all revenue for hospital and physician services comes from general taxes, mostly imposed at the provincial level.17 Prescription drugs are not covered, but each province has separate targeted programs to provide drugs to the poor, the elderly, and other needy groups.18

Payments to providers. Provinces each have a single medical plan, with provider payment arrangements and waiting lists varying slightly among them. Canadi-ans cannot seek care from other provinces in order to benefit from shorter waiting lists, but doctors are able to move to provinces where the government fee sched-ule (see the glossary on p.6) is set higher. Hospitals are usually public or nonprofit, and provincial govern-ments establish global budget limits on what they may spend on patient care. Physicians are paid on a fee-for-service basis. Primary-care physicians generally play a gatekeeping role, with specialists paid less for services to patients if there is no referral.19

The Canada Health Act does not prohibit private care delivery, and physicians can opt out of the public system. However, the ability of the national govern-ment to withhold funds from provinces that allow private care that is inconsistent with a comprehensive, universal, and uniform entitlement leads them to find a variety of ways to constrain access to privately financed health care in practice.20 Some provinces ban physi-cians who have opted out of the public program from billing more than their fee schedule, while others pro-hibit patients who see physicians who have opted out of Medicare from receiving publicly funded services.21

Canadian Health Care in a Nutshell

Coverage Population share10

Mandatory spending7.4% GDP 11

Voluntary spending 3.1% GDP12

Medicare 100% Hospital and physician services deemed to be cost-effective are provided without charge.

Out-of-pocket payment for drugs, dental care, rehabilitation services, and transportation by ambulance

Public drug programs 23%13 Prescription drugs are paid for, mostly for low-income individuals.

Supplemental insurance 67% —

Only benefits not provided by Medicare can be covered by private insurance, including prescription drugs, home care, rehabilitation, private hospital rooms, and dental care.

Page 8: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

8

Health care delivered beyond hospital settings, such as prescription drugs, medical devices, and home health, lies beyond the scope of the Canada Health Act, and so its delivery through the private sector is less con-strained.22 This has allowed for the gradual growth in the outpatient provision of publicly covered services by the private sector, such as ambulatory surgery, diagnos-tic services, or rehabilitation care—whose availability through the public system is limited.23 Almost all dental care is privately funded, as is most drug spending.24

Private insurance. The Canada Health Act does not explicitly prohibit private insurance for hospital and physician services. But provinces have been deterred from allowing it because of the risk that the federal government could determine that it threatens compre-hensive, uniform, and universal public access to care—and could withhold their federal subsidy.25 Private insurance for medically necessary services is officially prohibited by the majority of provinces, and only New-foundland lacks any significant constraint on the ability of supplemental insurance to make available access to services nominally covered by Medicare.26

As a result, private insurance is mostly employ-er-sponsored coverage of non-Medicare services such as dentistry or prescription drugs.27 Prescription drug spending is a third publicly funded, a third funded by private insurance, and a third out-of-pocket—roughly the same split as in the United States.28 Some con-cierge-style clinics offer membership fees that provide immediate access to doctors, MRI scans, and other diagnostics without restriction, but these services are priced at levels that would appeal only to those who are very wealthy.29

A 2005 court declared Quebec’s ban on private in-surance at odds with the province’s charter of rights, ruling: “Access to a waiting list is not access to health care.” Although Quebec subsequently legalized private insurance for outpatient surgery, no market

has since emerged, thanks to limitations on covered benefits and the provincial government’s restriction on dual practice.30

United Kingdom (single payer)The United Kingdom (U.K.) provides a universal en-titlement to hospital and physician services funded through general taxation, with no associated out-of-pocket costs. It allows individuals to purchase better access to scheduled medical procedures through un-subsidized private supplemental insurance.

The public entitlement. U.K. residents receive a broad range of hospital and physician services, fully covered by public funds through the National Health Service (NHS), with no associated out-of-pocket costs. There are target limits on waiting times for individuals to obtain different types of care, though these are routinely violated in prac-tice. There is no legally enforceable right for patients to receive any particular treatment.35 Access to care varies greatly by specialty and geographic region.36 Surgical pro-cedures and drugs may also be excluded from coverage if they fail to gain approval for cost-effectiveness.37

Getting an appointment with a specialist requires a re-ferral from a general practitioner. In theory, patients have a free choice of general practitioners; in practice, few accept new patients.38 Prescription drugs deter-mined to be cost-effective are also covered, and in 90% of cases are exempt from copays.39 A range of support-ive services, including post-acute care, home visits by nurses, and some eye and dental care, may also be pro-vided without charge.40

Payments to providers. Public hospitals provide care exclusively for the NHS and are paid according to the diagnoses of patients admitted.41 In recent years, the NHS has paid for some care at privately owned facil-ities—though 94% of spending remains at publicly

British Health Care in a Nutshell

Coverage Population share31

Mandatory spending7.7% GDP32

Voluntary spending 2.0% GDP33

National Health Service (NHS) 100%

Hospital and physician services, post-acute care, and prescription drugs deemed to be cost-effective are covered.

There are prescription drug copays in England for less vulnerable demographic groups.

Supplemental insurance 11%34 —

These plans provide better access to medical procedures through private hospitals, physicians, and clinics.

Page 9: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

9

owned hospitals.42 Private hospitals don’t have emer-gency departments, and clinics tend to concentrate on the areas where gaps in public coverage are the great-est, such as imaging, joint replacements, and cataract surgery.43 There are high barriers to entry for private hospitals, which has caused higher prices that are little constrained by competition from public hospitals.44

Most general practitioners work as NHS contractors and are paid according to a standard contract, nego-tiated collectively with the government, that blends capitation and fee-for-service compensation. Special-ists usually work within hospitals as salaried employ-ees with some private work externally on the side. Dual practice is allowed, but the income earned by NHS-em-ployed specialists from private practice is restricted.45 The share of the specialist workforce seeing some pri-vately funded patients was 55% in 2006 but has de-clined over recent years.46

Private insurance. Individuals buy private insurance generally to circumvent waiting lists, gain broader access to specialists, or be treated in private rooms at hospitals. Insurance plans are mostly employer-spon-sored and designed for acute care rather than ongoing chronic conditions. Private insurance is not available to cover high-cost cancer drugs that may be unavail-able through the NHS.47

The premiums for private insurance are underwritten on initial enrollment and exclude preexisting condi-tions, but the plans can guarantee renewability without later underwriting. Insurers negotiate rates with pro-viders, have their own fee schedules and preferred providers, and may use managed-care techniques; out-of-network providers may balance bill. Employ-er-sponsored supplemental plans were exempt from income taxation for those over age 60 from 1990 on, but this exemption was repealed in 1997.48

Australia (dual payer)

Australia provides a universal entitlement to medical services at public hospitals funded through general taxation, but independent providers of outpatient ser-vices may balance bill. Supplemental insurance to fund broader access to providers is tax-advantaged and pub-licly subsidized for lower-income groups.

The public entitlement. Australia’s Medicare program covers hospital, physician, and prescription drug services for all permanent residents.52 It provides inpatient care at public hospitals with no associated out-of-pocket costs. The entitlement is more limited for outpatient care.53 Specialty care and high-tech services are restricted in public hospitals. A referral from a general practitioner is needed for specialists to get the standard public reimbursement.54

The public drug benefit was initially limited to “life-saving and disease-preventing drugs,” but the list of covered prescription drugs has been expanded over time—with copays varying by income and consump-tion levels. The addition of drugs to the covered list is ad hoc but takes into account the cost-effectiveness of therapies.55

Payments to providers. Australia’s states administer and regulate public hospitals, which are paid according to the diagnoses of patients admitted, with disincentives (reduced reimbursement rates) for increased volumes.56 The national government funds and administers a fee schedule and provides grants to states covering 40% of the costs of public hospitals.57 Public hospitals may not balance bill for inpatient or outpatient services.58

There is little constraint on the private purchase of medical services.59 Private doctors may claim reimbursement from the government fee schedule

Australian Health Care in a Nutshell

Coverage Population share 49

Mandatory spending6.5% GDP50

Voluntary spending 3.1% GDP51

Medicare 100%

Comprehensive coverage of inpatient and physician services is provided at public hospitals. Outpatient services are covered to a more limited extent.

Cost-sharing exists, up to an annual catastrophic threshold, for outpatient services. Balance billing is allowed for outpatient physician services. A standard copay exists for prescription drugs; the copay is lower for needy groups and beyond a catastrophic threshold.

Supplemental insurance 45% Premium subsidies are provided for enrollment. Insurance plans for treatment at private

hospitals are community-rated.

Page 10: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

10

or bill private insurers without restriction.60 Doctors who balance bill are not required to opt out of public funding.61 Complex rules govern dual practice, which varies from state to state.62

Private hospitals, a mix of for-profit and nonprofit fa-cilities, may balance bill.63 About a third of hospital beds are in private facilities, which focus on elective surgeries and patients with less acute medical needs.64 Some 60% of elective admissions are to private hospi-tals, but only 8% are emergency admissions.65 Public and private hospitals are often located close together to facilitate dual practice.66 Public hospitals may profit by supplementing their allowed public income with private patient revenues.67 This gives states an incen-tive to steer costly outpatient cases from public hospi-tals to private doctors who bill Medicare, as it allows them to stretch their grant allocations further.68

Private insurance. The government pays 75% of of-ficial hospital fees for all, including those enrolled in private insurance—with private coverage merely paying additional charges. Private insurance allows patients to avoid waiting lists to see physicians or receive care in public hospitals by getting care at private facilities.69 Private insurance premiums vary greatly, according to the extent of benefits and degree of cost-sharing.70

Private insurance premiums had been allowed to vary only according to age (a modified form of community rating), but this policy encouraged people to wait until after getting sick to sign up.71 In 1999, a refundable tax credit was introduced for the purchase of private in-surance, worth 25%–35% of premiums, depending on age.72 Starting in 2000, private insurance plans may

charge higher premiums to enrollees who have failed to maintain continuous coverage since the age of 30.73 A tax penalty of up to 1.5% of income was also estab-lished on those who failed to purchase private insur-ance.74

France (dual payer)The national government pays for hospital and phy-sician services, funded through payroll taxes, but pa-tients are often subject to substantial coinsurance and balance billing. Supplemental private insurance to cover these out-of-pocket costs is tax-advantaged and subsidized.

The public entitlement. France funds its public en-titlement to medical care mostly through a payroll tax, but it also covers those who have never worked, financed by general taxation.78 Coinsurance is 20% for inpatient hospital care, 30% for outpatient and dental care, 40% for diagnostics, and 70% for specialty care without a referral from a general practitioner.79 Coin-surance for prescription drugs is 0%–85%, depending on assessments of the cost-effectiveness of drugs.80

Covered services are often subject to small copays.81

Those with major chronic conditions, individuals with low incomes, pregnant women, handicapped chil-dren, and military veterans may receive medical care without having to pay coinsurance out-of-pocket.82 Re-ferral from a general practitioner reduces coinsurance for subsequent specialist consultations.83 Public funds cover an average of 89% of inpatient spending and 57% of outpatient spending for those who do not have low incomes or major chronic conditions.84

French Health Care in a Nutshell

Coverage Population share 75

Mandatory spending8.7% GDP 76

Voluntary spending 2.3% GDP 77

Social security funds 100%Hospital, physician, and approved prescription drug services are covered, as is limited dental care, up to fee schedule rates.

The French system includes small copays and substantial coinsurance; a large number of providers practice balance billing. Prescription drug coinsurance tiers vary from 0% to 100% (typically 35%), based on cost-effectiveness.

Complementary insurance 95%

Employers must offer supplemental insurance, for which there are public, income-based subsidies.

Supplemental insurance covering coinsurance and balance billing to varying degrees

Affections de Longue Durée 12% Public payment of coinsurance associated with

the treatment of chronic conditions —

CMU Complémentaire 6% Public payment of coinsurance for low-income individuals —

Page 11: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

11

Payment to providers. A third of French hospitals are publicly owned, a third are privately owned nonprofits, and a third are privately owned for-profit institutions. While public hospitals treat most inpatient cases, about half of outpatient procedures are performed at private hospitals.85 Public hospital capacity, service volumes, available resources, and investments in new equip-ment must secure approval from regional planning groups.86 Public hospitals within a region are required to share resources and infrastructure, and they may be subject to closure if they fail to meet minimum volume requirements.87 Since 2004, hospitals have been paid according to the diagnoses of patients admitted, rather than by global budgets—though lump-sum payments remain for emergency care and transplant operations.88 Private hospitals are not subject to global budgets but do receive lower reimbursement rates from the gov-ernment.89 This site-of-service price disparity is being challenged under European Union competition law.90

Payments for physicians performing procedures are bundled with facility fees for hospitals, except at for-profit facilities, where physician reimbursements are carved out.91 Physicians based in public hospitals are salaried, but independent specialists are paid fee-for-service.92 In France, 40% of physicians are salaried employees of hospitals; the rest work in private prac-tice.93 Dual practice is allowed, but income from private payers is restricted.94 About 25% of doctors balance bill, but only a limited subset of doctors may do so.95

The share of specialists balance billing is higher (42%), with the proportion doing so varying by region and by specialty (19% of cardiologists; 73% of surgeons).96 Balance billing adds an average of 34% to physician incomes.97

Private insurance. Private insurance plans cover coinsurance and pay for access to private providers who balance bill. Coverage for balance billing is often written as paying a percentage of the public fee sched-ule (usually 200%–300%).98 While all private plans cover coinsurance, only 48% of plans include cover-age of balance billing—which is most common among dental providers.99 Copays are not covered by supple-mental insurance, but copays amount to no more than €50 per year.100 Private insurance is designed to com-plement the incentives of the public system—with 0% coinsurance for care approved by gatekeepers.101

As the government held back the rate of growth of payments to public hospitals and more than doubled cost-sharing for outpatient services, private insurance enrollment increased from 30% in the 1960s to 95% in the 2010s. Tax incentives including an employer mandate penalty were also established to encourage firms to purchase supplemental plans for staff, and

44% of insurance is employer-sponsored.102 While the poorest households are exempt from coinsurance, the near-poor receive income-based subsidies to help them purchase supplemental insurance.103

Nonprofit insurers (mutuelles) may vary premiums only by age. For-profit insurers may charge premiums based on underwriting and exclude preexisting con-ditions on enrollment but are subject to a 7% tax on premiums. However, this tax was recently extended to nonprofit plans.104

Germany (competing payer)Germany provides a standard package of medical ben-efits, available through competing “sickness funds” (Krankenkassen), financed largely by a payroll tax. Higher-income individuals may instead purchase private insurance to get better benefits and access to care.The public entitlement. Most Germans are enrolled in one of about 100 quasi-public, nonprofit “sickness funds,” financed through a 15.5% payroll tax on income up to about $50,000.108 Revenues are collected by the central government and distributed to funds according to enrollees’ expected relative medical needs.109 Participation was gradually made mandatory for employees in different sectors of the economy, and individuals have been allowed to choose from competing funds since 1993.110 Individuals can switch funds with two months’ notice, after being enrolled for 18 months.111 Funds may charge small additional income-based premiums to enrollees, or use gatekeeping and networks of preferred providers to generate savings that can be returned to enrollees as supplemental benefits.112 The distinction between “public” sickness funds and “private” insurance was once significant, but sickness funds are now almost as much subject to market forces as private insurance.

Private insurance. Civil servants, the self-employed, and those earning above $55,000 may opt for private insurance instead of coverage through sickness funds.113

About half of private insurers are for-profit.114 Private insurance enrollees are exempt from payroll tax contri-butions to support sickness funds but are still subject to other taxes used to support these funds.115 Plans compete against one another and against sickness funds and may use deductibles to reduce premiums.116

Private insurance is financed by premiums that may be underwritten only at initial enrollment.117 Premiums increase with the age of entry into private insurance, so

Page 12: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

12

there is an incentive for individuals to buy in when they are young.118 Unlike sickness funds, private insurance requires additional premiums to cover other family members.119 Plans must set aside 10% of premiums until age 60, as “aging reserves” that subsidize the pur-chase of plans when individuals grow older.120 Private insurance premiums are supposed to be constant over enrollees’ lifetimes—though growing life expectancy and health costs make this fall short, in practice.121 A Basistarif private plan option was established in 2009 to cover individuals with preexisting conditions. Ba-sistarif plans may adjust premiums only by age, may not have premiums higher than the maximum sickness fund payroll tax, are limited in what they can pay pro-viders, and are eligible for risk-adjustment subsidies financed by a tax on all private plan enrollees.122

An individual mandate penalty was imposed in 2009 on those failing to purchase public or private plans, with payment retrospectively required for premiums that had been missed.123 Insurers may not cancel con-tracts and must pay for many services even if enroll-ees default on their premium payments. Enrollees may return to the public option only if they are under 55 and their earnings fall below a threshold, or if they are civil servants or self-employed.124

Payments to providers. A third of German hospitals are publicly owned, a third are nonprofit, and a third are for-profit—though about half of beds are in public hospitals and only a sixth in for-profit facilities. Over recent decades, the number of private hospitals has increased, while many public facilities have closed.125

Hospitals were once used exclusively for inpatient care but now offer some outpatient procedures.126 Charges for accommodation and meals may be carved out of

hospital bills and agreed to by contract with patients before treatment is carried out.127

State governments determine the capacity of hospitals, which must meet minimum volume thresholds to gain reimbursement for complex procedures.128 Hospitals were allocated global budgets but are increasingly reimbursed according to the diagnoses of patients admitted, subject to spending limits agreed to with sickness funds. Hospitals receive separate subsidies for capital investments if they accept patients from sickness funds, though these subsidies have declined significantly in recent years.129 Physician fees are bundled into payments for inpatient hospital care, and hospital-practicing physicians work as salaried employees. But physicians delivering ambulatory care are paid fee-for-service, with some element of capitation increasingly common.130

Sickness funds pay providers according to a standard fee schedule, with regional spending limits agreed to by physician associations and fund associations.131

Physicians receive lower fees if aggregate spending on their services exceeds a budget target.132 Some 90% of physicians and 91% of hospitals see patients from the public health system.133 Sickness funds may selectively contract with providers or require a referral by general practitioners before individuals can see specialists, but they have only recently begun to do so significantly.134 Physician associations restrict the right of doctors to practice in other regions or in the private sector.135

Private insurers pay at a higher fee schedule, deter-mined by the national government, and physicians may charge private insurers a multiple between 1 and 3.5 times the national fee schedule.136 Physicians treating

German Health Care in a Nutshell

Coverage Population share105

Mandatory spending9.5% GDP 106

Voluntary spending 1.7% GDP 107

Sickness funds 89%Hospital, physician, prescription drugs, and dental services are funded by capped payroll tax through competing risk-adjusted sickness funds.

Patients have copays for physician visits, costlier prescription drugs, medical equipment, and hospital care.

Private insurance(civil servants, self-employed, and high-income employees)

11%

Hospital, physician, prescription drug, and dental services are funded by premiums subject to community rating or one-time underwriting on enrollment. Insurers are required to accumulate transferrable reserves to subsidize coverage for when enrollees grow older.

Patients have copays for physician visits, costlier prescription drugs, medical equipment, and hospital care.

Supplemental insurance 22% — These policies provide access to private hospital

rooms and care by senior physicians.

Page 13: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

13

Page 14: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

14

privately insured patients are not subject to volume re-strictions, allowing enrollees access to superior-quality physicians or hospitals.137

Medical procedures are reviewed by the government for cost-effectiveness before they can be subject to re-imbursement. Prescription drugs are classified into ex-isting therapeutic groups, which may include generics, with reimbursement up to a reference price by sickness funds.138 If drugs offer additional therapeutic benefits, the government sets reimbursement levels according to cost-effectiveness analysis.139 Private insurers may also claim rebates from drug manufacturers.140

The Netherlands (competing payer)The Netherlands allows individuals to choose cover-age from competing insurance plans, largely funded by payroll taxes, with additional mandatory commu-nity-rated premiums that are subsidized for those outside upper-income groups.

The public entitlement. In the Netherlands, 40 private insurers provide competing comprehensive coverage. The plans are funded half through public subsidies and half through community-rated premiums, with funds redistributed between plans, according to the relative medical needs of their enrollees.145

Residents who fail to purchase a plan are assessed a penalty of about 130% of the premium (there are many plans, but most premiums are about the same).146 In-surers may not withhold coverage from individuals who fail to pay premiums, but unpaid premiums are auto-matically deducted from their incomes.147 Two-thirds of households receive additional subsidies, which are provided in advance of their purchase of a plan. These subsidies are based on income levels from the previous year, and then reconciled in tax assessments.148 Pre-

miums for those under age 18 are publicly financed.149

Premium discounts of up to 10% may be obtained in return for the purchase of plans offered by employers, unions, or any other organized group.150

A referral from a general practitioner is required to see a specialist or to obtain an elective hospital proce-dure.151 Insurance coverage is subject to a mandatory deductible, but there are exemptions for primary care and family medicine.152 Plans may offer managed-care or high-deductible options in return for lower premi-ums, but premium reductions are capped.153 Insurers may waive deductibles to encourage patients to go to in-network providers.154

Payments to providers. Most hospitals and clinics are private nonprofits. Prices for elective care (70% of hospital spending) have gradually been deregulated.155 Maximum prices set by the government remain in effect for hospital services that have not been deregulated and for specific services performed by general practitioners.156 Prices for hospital procedures still subject to regulation, along with overall target spending levels, are negotiated between associations of hospitals and insurers, brokered by the government.157 The government has the right to recoup hospital revenues if aggregate hospital spending across the country overruns the permitted rate of growth, but this policy may provide an incentive for each hospital to boost prices in order to better bear the collective punishment.158 A safety-net fund for hospitals was established to facilitate the transition to competitive pricing.159

Selective contracting is permitted for hospitals, so long as insurers include sufficient providers to satisfy demand without waiting lists.160 However, the effectiveness of selective contracting has been hobbled by a court ruling that insurers reimburse 75%–80% of the costs of out-of-network care.161 Nor is selective contracting permitted

Dutch Health Care in a Nutshell

Coverage Population share 141

Mandatory spending8.5% GDP 142

Voluntary spending 2.0% GDP 143

Standard benefit 100%

Coverage is through private insurance plans that are financed by a combination of a payroll tax and community-rated premiums. The plans must cover hospital, physician services, and prescription drugs.

There is a mandatory deductible for inpatient hospitalizations and prescription drugs. Reference pricing is used for prescription drugs.

Supplemental insurance 87% —

Private insurance without guaranteed issue may be purchased for dental care, physiotherapy, medical devices, and coverage abroad.144

Page 15: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

15

for general practitioners, where prices generally reflect maximum amounts permitted by the state.162

Certificate-of-need laws restricting hospital capital investments, which were used to plan and allocate funds for expanded capacity, were abolished to allow facilities to make investments according to market-based calculations.163 For-profit hospitals are currently prohibited, but the parliament has attempted to repeal this ban to encourage investment.164 However, private investors can be paid “a result-related compensation for risk capital,” so long as they are not owners of the hospital.165 For prescription drugs, insurers will often reimburse only the amount needed to cover the lowest-price generics, which reduces patient access to branded drugs.166

Supplemental insurance. Major legislation in 2006 integrated public subsidies and private insurance—replacing the two-tier system of private insurance for the wealthy and a government program that purchased services for the majority of the population.167 The goal was to reduce segmentation, improve equity, and replace government regulation of the provision of medical services with oversight by private managed-care organizations.168

Today, supplemental private insurance covers dental, physical therapy, and other services that are not part of the standard benefit. Yet the appeal of such insurance is declining, as individuals are less willing to pay for insurance to protect themselves from stable routine expenses.169

Switzerland (competing payer)

Switzerland requires its residents to purchase private insurance, largely funded by premiums, with cantons providing additional subsidies to hospitals and low-in-come individuals.

The public entitlement. Residents of Switzerland for more than three months must purchase insurance that covers essential health benefits from private nonprofit organizations.173 The standard benefits package is very broad and even includes alternative medicine, as the result of a series of national referendums. Insurers must be nonprofit, are nationally regulated, are required to set community-rated premiums, and are subject to some redistribution between plans, according to the relative medical needs of enrollees.

Plans may reduce premiums by requiring a referral to see specialists, establishing networks of providers, or increasing deductibles up to a maximum limit—though deductibles must also exceed a set minimum. Coinsurance is 10% above the deductible, up to a catastrophic cap. The coinsurance for branded drugs is 20% where there are generic substitutes.174

Health insurance is mostly funded through mandatory and uniform premiums, rather than income-based taxes. However, the government provides additional subsidies to limit premiums as a share of household income.175 Premiums and subsidies may vary greatly among cantons.176

Payments to providers. Most hospitals are publicly subsidized by cantons, and inpatient care is financed half by insurance, half by direct subsidies.177 Before

Swiss Health Care in a Nutshell

Coverage Population share170

Mandatory spending7.9% GDP 171

Voluntary spending 4.5% GDP 172

Statutory health insurance 100%

Mandatory private insurance covers hospital care, physician services, nonroutine dental care, and prescription drugs. Premiums are community-rated with age bands and risk adjustment. Cantons provide direct subsidies to acute-care hospitals.

Substantial deductibles are mandatory, and high deductibles are very common. There are also copays per inpatient day and coinsurance up to a modest cap.

Premium subsidies 29% Income-based subsidies vary by cantons. —

Supplemental insurance 28% —

For-profit voluntary insurance allows some underwriting and pays for uncovered services, private hospital rooms, and dental care.

Page 16: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

16

2012, cantons paid hospitals to treat their residents. Since then, hospitals have been paid patient-by-patient, according to a national fee schedule, allowing individ-uals to seek treatment beyond their home cantons.178 A third of hospitals are private and ineligible for subsidies from cantons, but they are paid higher rates (by insurers and by individuals with cost-sharing) and may provide better-quality amenities.179

Dual practice is allowed in Switzerland—specialists who are salaried employees of public hospitals may also maintain a private practice.180 Ambulatory-care phy-sicians are paid by a national fee schedule, which is generally the product of negotiations between groups of insurers and groups of physicians. Physicians may not balance bill.181 A “necessity clause” seeks to restrict the establishment and proliferation of new specialists and providers of outpatient care. Drugs are included on formularies according to cost-effectiveness deter-minations, with tiered coinsurance where generics are available.182

Supplemental insurance. Premiums to purchase sup-plemental insurance can be underwritten and may be managed by for-profit insurers. Such plans have long been available to cover services that are exempt from Switzerland’s mandatory benefit package but are pro-hibited from reducing cost-sharing associated with covered services.183 Supplemental plans are neither sub-sidized nor eligible for purchase with pretax funds.184

As mandatory coverage has gradually been expanded, the demand for supplemental insurance has greatly diminished. There was strong political pressure to add drugs to mandatory coverage after they become widespread under voluntary insurance coverage. The reform requiring mandatory plans to cover access to hospitals beyond individuals’ home cantons eliminated the main motivation for them to purchase supplemental insurance. The absence of significant waiting times in Switzerland means that few people purchase supplemental insurance to get preferential treatment.185

United States (segmented payers)The U.S. provides entitlements to medical care through programs for the elderly and low- to middle-income residents, which may be used to purchase privately managed plans. Employer-sponsored insurance is exempt from income taxes, and subsidies are provided for hospitals to deliver care to the uninsured.

The public entitlement. Government health-care en-titlements target discrete sections of the population. The diversity of U.S. publicly financed health-care pro-grams and the aggregate amount spent on them are both as great as those for all the other countries in this paper combined.

U.S. Health Care in a Nutshell

Coverage Population share 186

Mandatory spending8.5% GDP 187

Voluntary spending 8.8% GDP 188

Medicare(age 65+ or disabled) 17%

Coverage of hospital, physician services, and prescription drugs is provided. Some dental coverage is available through privately managed plans.

Premiums paid by individuals cover 25% of the cost of physician services and prescription drugs; substantial coinsurance and deductibles for most medical services, which may be reduced by supplemental insurance.

Medicaid/CHIP(low income) 19%

Comprehensive coverage of hospital, physician, and prescription drug services; some dental care is covered, depending on the state

Copays are nominal.

Individual market 16% Subsidies reduce premiums and cost-sharing for low- to middle-income earners.

Community-rated premiums cover hospital care, physician services, and prescription drugs, usually with substantial cost-sharing.

Employer-sponsored 56% —Coverage of hospital, physician services, prescription drugs, and dental care, often with substantial cost-sharing

Uninsured 9% Subsidies are paid to hospitals to reimburse them for safety-net care.

Hospitals charge patients above charity-care income thresholds.189 Physician and dental services are paid out-of-pocket.

Page 17: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

17

Medicare covers hospital and post-acute care for all elderly and disabled Americans who have made suf-ficient payroll tax contributions. Heavily subsidized coverage of physician services and prescription drugs is available with the payment of additional premiums. Medicare covers three-fourths of medical expenses, and enrollees often purchase supplemental private insurance to further reduce deductibles and coinsur-ance, though balance billing is prohibited. Originally, the federal government purchased medical services directly for all beneficiaries, but a third of enrollees now opt to receive coverage through private insurers (in Medicare Advantage plans) that may contract in-dependently with providers and compete by reducing out-of-pocket costs and providing additional benefits such as dental care.

Medicaid and the Children’s Health Insurance Program (CHIP) cover low-income Americans. They are funded mostly by the federal government but are managed by states. As a condition of receiving funds, states must provide comprehensive coverage of hospital and phy-sician services without significant out-of-pocket costs to defined categories of low-income Americans. States may claim additional federal funds to expand eligibil-ity and provide benefits (such as long-term care, pre-scription drugs, or dental coverage) above Medicaid’s mandatory floor.

While states may make separate health-care expendi-tures, their spending tends to be focused on Medicaid activities, for which they may claim matching funds from the federal government. States may, however, apply for waivers to use Medicare and Medicaid funds to provide coverage in forms that are not specifical-ly prescribed under those programs’ statutes. Recent years have seen an increase in the share of health-care spending that is publicly financed, along with a rise in the proportion of publicly financed health care that is administered by private insurers.190

Payments to providers. Most community hospitals in the U.S. are privately owned nonprofit organiza-tions, but a quarter are for-profit firms, and a sixth are owned by state and local governments.191 Physicians may choose whether to operate in private practice, as employees of hospitals, or in integrated managed-care organizations. The hospital market structure varies significantly from state to state, with the majority regulating capital investments and the expansion of specialty hospitals.192 Similarly, states have much in-fluence over physician certification and the permitted scope of medical practices.

Hospitals must accept patients funded by Medicare or Medicaid and provide uncompensated care to unin-

sured individuals in order to qualify for broad exemp-tions from state and federal taxes. Access to hospitals is broad under both Medicare and Medicaid, but access to physicians under Medicaid may be limited in some states—particularly for specialists. Reimbursement for medical care provided to those who are privately insured may depend on plans’ networks of preferred providers.

Private insurance. Most Americans ineligible for public entitlements receive health insurance purchased by their employers. Employers can provide insurance as compensation to their staff without incurring income or payroll taxes, and larger employers (50 or more employees) incur a penalty if they fail to do so.

Individuals who do not receive health-care coverage through entitlements or employment may purchase coverage directly from private insurers in state-regulated markets. They may sign up at any point of the year to purchase underwritten insurance through the Short-Term Limited Duration market. They may also, during limited enrollment periods, purchase community-rated plans through the Affordable Care Act. Low- to middle-income households may also be eligible for subsidies to assist with the purchase of ACA plans.

III. The Health-Care Models Assessed: Access, Volume, Quality, and CostGreat caution must be exercised in drawing inferences from a comparison of health-care statistics across countries. This is because countries differ in many ways—including national income, medical needs, po-litical systems, wage rates, and other government policies—beyond the influence of differences in their health-care systems.

It is best to focus specifically on factors such as the access, quality, cost, and quantity of medical services available, rather than broad differences in medical outcomes, as medical outcomes may differ for a variety of other reasons. It is also possible to learn from how these factors have changed, as individual countries have altered their policies over time.

Page 18: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

18

*Sources for the charts: IPSOS (2018): “Global Views on Healthcare—2018,” IPSOS Global Advisor, 2018; Commonwealth Fund (2016): “2016 International Survey of Adults,” Commonwealth Fund, 2016; OECD (2015): Health at a Glance 2017, OECD Indicators, 2017; (data is for 2015); OPTN/SRTR (2010): Bertram L. Kasiske et al., “OPTN/SRTR 2011 Annual Data Report: International Data,” American Journal of Trans-plantation 13, no. 1 (January 2013): 199–225; AHRQ (2014): AHRQ (Agency for Health Care and Quality) (2014): (appendectomy chart) Claudia A. Steiner et al., “Surgeries in Hospital-Based Ambulatory Surgery and Hospital Inpatient Settings, 2014,” AHRQ Statistical Brief no. 223, February 2018; AHRQ (2014): (heart bypass chart) Kimberly W. McDermott et al., “Overview of Operating Room Procedures During Inpatient Stays in U.S. Hospitals, 2014,” AHRQ Statistical Brief no. 233, December 2017; Ianchulev et al. (2016): Tsontcho Ianchulev et al., “Office-Based Cataract Surgery,” Opthalmalogy 123, no. 4 (April 2016): 723–728; OECD (2018): Health Spending, OECD.data

Canada (single payer)Canadians have easy access to general practitioners, but getting an appointment to see a specialist is more difficult than in all the other nations studied in this re-port. The Canadian medical system provides the least hospital care, delivers consistently fewer outpatient procedures, and provides much less access to modern diagnostic technology.

The median waiting time for treatment by a special-ist following referral by a general practitioner was 20 weeks in 2018 (4 weeks for oncology, 10 weeks for elective cardiovascular procedures, 21 weeks for gyne-cology, 26 weeks for neurosurgery, and 39 weeks for orthopedic surgery). There were also substantial waiting times for diagnostic tests: 4 weeks for an ultrasound and 11 weeks for an MRI.193 Seven percent report that they were unable to find a regular doctor.194

Canada spends a similar amount on health care as do most other developed nations, though significantly less than the U.S., with which it shares a high-cost labor market. But the average out-of-pocket costs faced by Canadians are similar to those faced by Americans, as many in Canada lack prescription drug coverage—which covers the most common out-of-pocket ex-pense. Access to drugs is often limited: provincial drug plans for low-income Canadians cover an average of 23% of drugs, by comparison with 83% for private drug plans.195

United Kingdom (single payer)Britain’s health-care system requires the fewest out-of-pocket payments from patients but lags behind other nations in funding access to quality medical care. The country faces a constant struggle to reconcile a rapid-ly growing demand for medical care with government

ACCESS

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Percent)0 10 4020 30

Unable to see a specialist within 2 months

Source: Commonwealth Fund (2016)

It’s easy to get an appointment with a local doctor

Source: IPSOS (2018)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Percent agree)0 20 10040 60 80

(data not available)

(data not available)

How the Models Compare*

Page 19: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

19

budget constraints. Private funding has been increas-ingly squeezed out by unsupportive government policy (including restrictions on dual practice).

U.K. hospitals often lack cutting-edge technology, and mortality after major emergency hospitalizations com-pares poorly with that of other nations in this report. Ac-cess to specialists is very limited, and the system falls well short of most other nations in the delivery of outpa-tient surgery.

Annual pay increases for medical staff were capped at 1% during 2015–18.196 Fifty percent of senior physicians are considering reducing their working hours, and 60% of specialists intend to retire at or before age 60.197 There are 100,000 unfilled staffing vacancies, straining the workforce of 1.2 million.198

By November 2018, 4.2 million of the 55 million people in England were on waiting lists for elective care—up from 2.7 million in March 2013, with only 1.3 million receiv-ing treatment each month.199 Median waiting times to receive treatment from specialists range from 5.4 weeks to see a geriatrician to 8.2 weeks for neurosurgeons.200 Of the patients requiring urgent cancer care, 18% do not receive treatment within two months of referral—a pro-portion that rises to as much as 41% in some parts of the country.201 Of the patients needing emergency care, 15% must wait over four hours to be seen—up from 4% in 2013.202

Australia (dual payer)Australia holds an intermediary position between sin-gle-payer and multi-payer health-care systems, as just under half the population has private insurance for hos-pital and physician services. Its system offers good ac-cess to general practitioners but restricted access to care and often high out-of-pocket costs for those who lack private insurance.

Private hospitals enable Australians to obtain surgeries from modern facilities without waiting lists, but there is a growing segmentation of publicly funded patients into public hospitals and privately insured patients into pri-vate hospitals.203 For those reliant on the public system, waiting times for inpatient procedures were similar to those in single-payer countries such as Canada and the U.K.204 Waiting times for many kinds of outpatient sur-gery increased by 50% from 2002 to 2012.205

The establishment of guaranteed renewability without underwriting for individuals who maintained continuous insurance coverage caused enrollment in private in-surance to suddenly increase from 32% to 45% of the population.206 The establishment of subsidies and a tax

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Percent)0 20 10040 60 80

(data not available)

(data not available)

(data not available)

Hip fracture surgery within 2 days

Source: OECD (2015)

Visit OB/GYN at least once in past year

Source: IPSOS (2018)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Percent of women)0 20 10040 60 80

(data not available)

(data not available)

Unable to get elective surgery within 4 months

Source: Commonwealth Fund (2016)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Percent)0 5 2010 15

VOLUME

Hospitalizations

Source: OECD (2015)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Inpatient discharges per 1,000)0 30 12060 90 150 240180 210

Page 20: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

20

penalty on those who failed to purchase private insur-ance had a much smaller impact on enrollment.207 Only 11% of enrollees have first-dollar insurance coverage, suggesting that mandates and incentives may have en-couraged them to purchase thin coverage.208 Out-of-pocket costs are particularly high for prescription drugs, for which public reimbursement levels are low.

The complexity of financial interactions between pub-lic and private payers, and between state and federal governments, has created a myriad of opportunities for cost-shifting between them.209 This has led to frequent political battles passing blame, confusing accountability, and inducing gaps in service.210

France (dual payer)France provides a modest government-funded benefit, but almost everyone has supplemental private insurance. Access to specialists and surgery overall is very good.

The policy accommodating balance billing appears to have encouraged vigorous price competition, as consum-ers are highly price-sensitive at the margin.211 In regions where physicians are scarce, most physicians balance bill, and the growth of private insurance to cover balance bill-ing is associated with significant price increases.212

There is an eightfold difference in the number of special-ists between the highest and lowest regions. In regions with few physicians, most balance bill. Overall, 40% of physicians balance bill and refuse to see patients without private insurance, as these patients cannot be charged more than the government fee schedule.213

The dual-payer system adds some administrative rigidity and waste. Separate insurance to cover cost-sharing means that each medical claim involves two payers, almost doubling overall administrative costs.214 As they do not bear responsibility for the bulk of medical costs and are unable to selectively contract, insurers have little incentive or ability to make the delivery of care more efficient.215

Germany (competing payer)Germany’s system of competing insurance plans pro-vides excellent access to specialty care and surgical ser-vices, with out-of-pocket costs rarely impeding access to care. The amount of care provided on an inpatient ba-sis is unusually high, compared with the other countries in this report, although this is gradually changing. Public hospitals have lower costs, but private hospitals have more investment and shorter waiting lists.216

Knee replacements

Source: OECD (2015)

(Surgeries per 100,000 residents)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

0 50 150100 200 250

Cataracts

(Surgeries per 100,000 residents)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

0 50 200100 150 250 300 350

Hip replacements

Source: OECD (2015)

Source: OECD (2015), Ianchulev et al. (2016)

(Surgeries per 100,000 residents)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

0 200 600400 800 14001000 1200

(data not available)

Source: OECD (2015), AHRQ (2014)

Heart bypass

(Surgeries per 100,000 residents)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

0 15 30 45 7560

Page 21: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

21

Among community-rated sickness funds, there is some evidence of plans selecting against elderly and chron-ically ill enrollees.217 Healthier individuals tend to opt for “private” plans, where they can qualify for lower premi-ums as a result of underwriting, and 80% of private in-surance enrollees opt for plans with higher cost-sharing than is standard through sickness funds.218

Privately insured patients face significantly shorter wait-ing lists for specialty care than enrollees of sickness funds, are more likely to receive innovative drugs, tend to be kept in the hospital longer, and are 50% more like-ly to receive organ transplants, despite being healthier on average.219 Waiting times for a sample of six outpa-tient treatments increased from an average of 27.5 days in 2014 to 30.7 days in 2016 for patients covered by sickness funds, whereas they fell from 13.5 days to 7.8 days for those covered by private insurance.220 Waiting times for primary care were slightly shorter for those covered by private insurance, though residents of the former East Germany faced waits twice as long.221

The Netherlands (competing payer)The Netherlands sought to move away from a segmented two-tier health-care system to help improve access to care for those unable to afford private insurance.222

Market-based mechanisms for insurers and providers have replaced rationing and waiting lists as methods of cost control. This has also increased the autonomy of providers and facilitated the portability of insurance coverage between jobs and across the country.223

As prices for elective care have been deregulated and made subject to competition, they have increased more slowly than prices that remain subject to regulation and set by collective negotiation.224 The number of outpatient specialty facilities has soared from 30 in 2000 to 280 in 2010, and prices in these facilities are 15%–20% lower than in hospitals.225 Following the transition to a competitive system, waiting times for joint replacements, cataracts, and heart surgeries fell to levels much lower than in single-payer countries.226 As the cost of care has fallen, demand has increased, so total spending has not fallen along with costs.227 Spending on specialists increased from €17 billion in 2006 to €27 billion in 2016.228 Single hospital rooms, which had largely disappeared, are reemerging.229

The breadth of eligibility for publicly subsidized premiums makes the Dutch health-care system less progressive.230 Tight regulations on insurance premiums have also caused out-of-pocket costs to increase.231

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Per 100,000 residents)0 30 60 90 120

MRI scans

Source: OECD (2015)

Appendectomy

Source: OECD 2015: AHRO (2014)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Surgeries per 100,000 residents)0 30 60 90 120 150 180

Heart transplants

Source: OPTN/SRTR (2010)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Surgeries per million residents)0 2 4 6 81 53 7

Physician consultations

Source: OECD (2015)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Per resident)0 2 8 1064

(data not available)

Page 22: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

22

They have also limited resources available to the system, and waiting times for outpatient care are beginning to increase again.232

Community rating has encouraged insurance plans to appeal to healthier enrollees, and this incentive has not been entirely mitigated by risk adjustment.233 There is a constant battle to avoid insurers cherry-picking healthi-er enrollees, with “selective marketing” to them by plans recently being prohibited.234 Discounts to groups, such as employers, under community rating, have served only to increase premiums for those left out.235

Switzerland (competing payer)Switzerland does not limit the amount of health-insurance coverage that individuals may purchase, which allows good access to specialists, high volumes of surgeries, and innovative high-quality care. But public hospitals remain highly sheltered from price competition, and insurance-market rules inadvertently impose high out-of-pocket costs on patients.

The combination of community rating and inadequate risk adjustment induces healthy individuals to flock to plans offering the maximum permitted deductibles.236

The share of health-care costs borne out-of-pocket (28%) is the highest in the developed world.237 This reliance on deductibles as a substitute for premiums may reduce the utilization of low-cost preventive care without doing much to limit wasteful utilization of services or encourage the highest-spending patients to seek hospital care from more cost-effective providers.

The delivery of Swiss medical care remains inefficient, with a large number of hospitals for its size and a high average length of stay.238 To some extent, this reflects the absence of significant rationing and substantial direct subsidies to hospitals from cantons. Differences in spending levels among cantons tend to reflect variation in the use of medical services.239

U.S. (segmented payer)American health care delivers high volumes of the highest-quality surgical services, though usually at a very high cost. The system is oriented around the preferences of well-insured individuals with a high willingness to pay for convenient, high-intensity care. Access to specialists and surgical services is good for most Americans who are covered by private insurance or Medicare, though it may be less so for those who are on Medicaid or are uninsured.

The tax exemption of employer-sponsored health in-surance provides half the population with coverage but

QUALITY

Mortality following stroke

Source: OECD (2015)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Percent within 30 days)0 2 4 6 108

Mortality following heart attack

Source: OECD (2015)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Percent within 30 days)0 2 4 6 8

Pulmonary embolism in hip or knee surgery

Source: OECD (2015)

(data not available)

(data not available)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Share of surgeries)0.0% 0.2% 0.4% 0.8%

Postoperative sepsis in abdominal surgery

Source: OECD (2015)

(data not available)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Share of surgeries)0.0% 1% 2% 3%

(data not available)

(data not available)

Page 23: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

23

Out-of-pocket spending

Source: OECD (2015)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Percent of household consumption)0 1 62 3 4 5

insulates the delivery system from direct consumer con-trol and sensitivity to costs. Employer-sponsored health insurance also threatens individuals with the prospect of gaps in coverage if they lose their jobs.

The patchwork of different payment systems inhibits accountability and increases administrative costs, and leaves those in gaps between different sources of cov-erage facing enormous costs. These gaps are often dealt with in a roundabout way—by subsidies for pro-viders to treat the uninsured. Out-of-pocket costs may be extremely high for out-of-network hospital care, but these costs account for only a small fraction of medical bills, and hospitals rarely collect payment from unin-sured low-income patients.

Overall, American health care reflects a system that has been constructed incrementally over 70 years, with problems resulting from inflated costs tending to be addressed by the provision of additional funds rather than through greater accountability and austerity. The gradual privatization of care delivery under Medicare and Medicaid has tended to increase access to care, though it has not reduced public spending.240

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Percent of GDP)0 2 4 6 188 10 12 14 16

Health-care spending

Source: OECD (2018)

COST

Cost prevented needed care in past year

Source: Commonwealth Fund (2016)

USA SwiNedGerFraAusUK

Can

(Percent agree)0 10 4020 30

Page 24: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

24

Out-of-Pocket Spending on Health Care Across Eight Nations*

*Dental and outpatient out-of-pocket spending are pooled in the outpatient category for the U.K. and France.

Source: OECD, “Out-of-Pocket Medical Expenditure”; (U.S.) Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS), “National Health Expenditure Data”

Drugs Goods Dental Dent/Outp Outpatient Inpatient Other

6.0

5.0

4.0

3.0

2.0

1.0

0

Austraila Canada France Germany Netherlands Switzerland UK USA

Shar

e of

hou

seho

ld s

pend

ing

(%)

ConclusionSingle-payer health-care systems, such as those in the U.K. or Canada, are structurally similar, while the in-teraction of multiple payers tends to differ greatly from country to country. Dual-payer and competitive-payer systems blend into each other, according to the extent of the public entitlement in dual-payer countries and the degree to which all options in competitive-pay-er countries are constrained by a common delivery system. For instance, provider compensation may be more market-based in dual-payer France than in com-peting-payer Switzerland.

This means that it is possible to draw general conclu-sions about single-payer health care to an extent that is not possible for any other particular model. Sin-gle-payer systems share the common feature of limiting access to care according to what can be raised in taxes. Government revenues consistently lag the growth in demand for medical services resulting from increased affluence, longevity, and technological capacity. As a result, single-payer systems deliver consistently lower quality and access to high-cost specialty care or surgi-cal procedures without reducing overall out-of-pocket costs. Across the countries in this paper, limitations in access to care are closely tied to the share of the pop-ulation enrolled in private insurance—with those in Britain and Canada greatly limited, Australians facing

moderate restrictions, and those in the other countries studied being more able to get care when they need it.

Waiting lists are inherent to single-payer systems; they are not produced by the very limited role of private in-surance that is allowed to operate around them. The concern that private demand for medical services will deprive public programs of staff and facilities, rather than enable scarce public funds to be supplemented by additional private resources, is ultimately a problem only to the extent that the supply of medical resources is fixed.241 This is most likely to be a problem for skilled labor and is better addressed by expanding its supply, rather than by trying to suppress wages by depriving patients of private access to care.242 Indeed, restrictions on private health-care spending are likely to exacerbate any physician shortage over the long run.

Nonetheless, in dual-payer and segmented-payer systems, public and private payers constantly endeavor to shift costs to each other—an enterprise for which the complexity of health-care payment affords a near-limitless set of opportunities. There is also a continual confusion of responsibility and an absence of accountability. Under employer-sponsored insurance in the U.S., the separation of responsibility between those in charge of procuring care and those responsible for paying for it has led to the development of increasingly expensive sources of care with little

Page 25: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

25

attention to costs.243 The segmented-payer system generates the most funding for health care overall. However, in fully accommodating individuals’ willingness to pay for care, this approach increases the intensity of care to an extent that is painfully expensive for a minority that falls between gaps in entitlements and employer-sponsored insurance.

The competing-payer model ideally gives insurers the freedom and responsibility to procure health-care services in a way that attracts people to their plans by

offering them the best benefits and the lowest medical costs. While all competing-payer systems fall short of this ideal, in practice they consistently offer good access to high-quality medical care with good insurance protection. The competing-payer model is, therefore, best understood as an objective that is sought rather than yet realized—and countries including Germany, the Netherlands, France, and the U.S., which have experienced the most significant health-care reform over recent years, are each moving toward it.

Page 26: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

26

Endnotes1 See Sarah Kliff, “Private Health Insurance Exists in Europe and Canada: Here’s How It Works,” Vox, Feb. 12, 2019. 2 “Health Expenditure in Relation to GDP,” Health at a Glance 2017 (Paris: OECD, 2017). 3 Chris Pope, “Issues 2020: Private Health Insurance Saves Americans Money,” Manhattan Institute, Aug. 1, 2019. 4 Katherine Cuff et al., “Public and Private Health Care Financing with Alternative Public Rationing Rules,” Health Economics 21, no. 2 (February 2012):

83–100. 5 Pedro Pita Barros and Pau Olivella, “Waiting Lists and Patient Selection,” Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 14, no. 3 (Fall 2005): 623–46. 6 Chris Pope, “How to Increase Health-Insurance Coverage by Reducing ACA Crowd-Out,” Manhattan Institute, Jan. 23, 2018. 7 Timothy Besley and Stephen Coate, “Public Provision of Private Goods and the Redistribution of Income,” American Economics Review 81, no. 4

(September 1991): 979–84. 8 Timothy Besley and Miguel Gouveia, “Alternative Systems of Health Care Provision,” Economic Policy 9, no. 19 (Oct. 1, 1994): 199–258. 9 Sandra Hopkins and H. E. Frech, “The Rise of Private Health Insurance in Australia,” Economics and Labour Relations Review 12, no. 2 (December

2001): 225–38. 10 “Social Protection,” Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, OECD.Stat. 11 “Out-of-Pocket Medical Expenditure,” Health at a Glance 2017. 12 Ibid.13 Prescribed Drug Spending in Canada, 2018 (Ottawa: Canadian Institute for Health Information, 2018). 14 Gregory P. Marchildon, “Canada: Health System Review,” Health Systems in Transition 15, no. 1 (2013): 1–179. 15 Kelly Grant, “What You Need to Know About the Canada Health Transfer,” Globe and Mail (Toronto), May 17, 2018. 16 Canada Health Act Annual Report 2017–2018 (Ottawa: Health Canada, 2019). 17 Marchildon, “Canada: Health System Review.”18 Ibid.19 Elias Mossialos et al., eds., “International Profiles of Health Care Systems,” Commonwealth Fund, 2015. 20 Nadeem Esmail and Bacchus Barua, “Is the Canada Health Act a Barrier to Reform?” Fraser Institute, 2018. 21 Colleen M. Flood and Tom Archibald, “The Illegality of Private Health Care in Canada,” Canadian Medical Association Journal 164, no. 6 (March 2001):

825–30.22 Ibid.23 Benedict Irvine, Shannon Ferguson, and Ben Cackett, “Healthcare Systems: Canada,” Civitas, January 2013. 24 Marchildon, “Canada: Health System Review.”25 Esmail and Barua, “Is the Canada Health Act a Barrier to Reform?“26 Flood and Archibald, “Illegality of Private Health Care in Canada.”27 Marchildon, “Canada: Health System Review.”28 Irene Papanicolas, Liana R. Woskie, and Ashish K. Jha, “Health Care Spending in the United States and Other High-Income Countries,” Journal of the

American Medical Association 319, no. 10 (March 2018): 1024–39. 29 Robert Cribb, Vjosa Isai, and Maham Shakeel, “Should the Wealthy Be Allowed to Buy Their Way to Faster Health Care at Private Clinics?” The Star

(Toronto), Mar. 18, 2017. 30 Yanick Labrie, “The Chaoulli Decision and Health Care Reform: A Missed Opportunity,” MEI (Montreal Economic Institute), June 2015. 31 “Social Protection,” OECD.Stat.32 “Out-of-Pocket Medical Expenditure,” Health at a Glance 2017.33 Ibid. 34 “Social Protection,” OECD.Stat.35 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.” 36 Thomas Foubister and Erica Richardson, “United Kingdom,” in Voluntary Health Insurance in Europe, ed. A. Sagan and S. Thomson (Copenhagen:

European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies, 2016).37 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”38 Ibid.39 Kristian Niemietz, “Diagnosis: Overrated: An Analysis of the Structural Flaws in the NHS,” Institute for Economic Affairs, Discussion Paper No. 66,

December 2015. 40 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”41 Ibid. 42 Carolyn Hughes Tuohy, “The Politics of Market-Oriented Reforms,” paper presented at the conference “Two-Tier Care the Future? Private Finance in

Canadian Medicare,” Centre for Health Law, Policy and Ethics, University of Ottawa, Apr. 6–7, 2018.43 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems”; Tuohy, “Politics of Market-Oriented Reforms.” 44 “Private Healthcare Market Investigation: Final Report,” Competition & Markets Authority (U.K.), Apr. 2, 2014. 45 Pedro P. Barros and Luigi Siciliani, “Public and Private Sector Interface,” in Handbook of Health Economics, ed. Mark V. Pauly, Thomas G. Mcguire, and

Pedro P. Barros (Amsterdam: Elsevier, 2011), 2:927–1001. 46 Foubister and Richardson, “United Kingdom”; Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”

Page 27: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

27

47 Foubister and Richardson, “United Kingdom.”48 Ibid.49 “Quarterly Private Health Insurance Statistics,” Australian Prudential Regulation Authority, March 2019. 50 “Out-of-Pocket Medical Expenditure,” Health at a Glance 2017.51 Ibid.52 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”53 Stephen Duckett, “Expanding the Breadth of Medicare: Learning from Australia,” Health Economics, Policy and Law 13, nos. 3–4 (July 2018): 344–68. 54 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems”; Judith Healy, Evelyn Sharman, and Buddhima Lokuge, “Australia: Health System Review,”

Health Systems in Transition 8, no. 5 (2006): 1–178. 55 Duckett, “Expanding the Breadth of Medicare.”56 Ibid.57 Ibid.; Healy, “Australia: Health System Review.”58 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems”; Healy, “Australia: Health System Review.”59 Healy, “Australia: Health System Review.”60 Ibid.61 Duckett, “Expanding the Breadth of Medicare.”62 Jane Hall and Elizabeth Savage, “The Role of the Private Sector in the Australian Healthcare System,” in The Public Private Mix for Health, ed. Alan

Maynard (Oxford: Nuffield Trust, 2005). 63 Duckett, “Expanding the Breadth of Medicare.”64 Healy, “Australia: Health System Review.”65 Duckett, “Expanding the Breadth of Medicare.”66 Hall and Savage, “The Role of the Private Sector in the Australian Healthcare System.”67 Ibid.68 Healy, “Australia: Health System Review.”69 Fiona McDonald and Stephen Duckett, “Regulation, Private Health Insurance, and the Australian Health System,” McGill Journal of Law and Health 11,

no. 1 (2017): S31–S60. 70 Hall and Savage, “The Role of the Private Sector in the Australian Healthcare System.”71 Ibid.72 Ibid. 73 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”74 McDonald and Duckett, “Regulation, Private Health Insurance, and the Australian Health System.”75 “Social Protection,” OECD.Stat.76 “Out-of-Pocket Medical Expenditure,” Health at a Glance 2017.77 Ibid.78 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”79 Karine Chevreul et al., “France: Health System Review,” Health Systems in Transition 17, no. 3 (2015): 1–251. 80 Ibid. 81 David Green and Benedict Irvine (2001; updated by Emily Clarke (2012) and Elliot Bidgood (January 2013)), “Healthcare Systems: France,” Civitas.82 Ibid. 83 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”84 Brigitte Dormont, Pierre-Yves Geoffard, and Jean Tirole, “Rebuilding the Health Insurance System,” Notes du Conseil d’Analyse Économique 2, no. 12

(2012): 1–12. 85 Chevreul, “France: Health System Review.”86 Ibid. 87 Philippe Choné, “Competition Policy for Health Care Provision in France,” Health Policy 121, no. 2 (February 2017): 111–18. 88 Green, “Healthcare Systems: France”; Chevreul, “France: Health System Review.”89 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”90 Choné, “Competition Policy for Health Care Provision in France.”91 Green, “Healthcare Systems: France.”92 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”93 Choné, “Competition Policy for Health Care Provision in France.”94 Barros and Siciliani, “Public and Private Sector Interface.”95 Chevreul, “France: Health System Review.”96 Brigitte Dormont and Mathilde Péron, “Does Health Insurance Encourage the Rise in Medical Prices? A Test on Balance Billing in France,” Health

Economics 25, no. 9 (September 2016): 1073–89. 97 Ibid. 98 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”

Page 28: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

28

99 Dormont and Péron, “Does Health Insurance Encourage the Rise in Medical Prices?”100 Green, “Healthcare Systems: France.”101 Chevreul, “France: Health System Review.”102 Karine Chevreul, Karen Berg Brigham, and Marc Perronnin, “France,” in Voluntary Health Insurance in Europe; “Social Protection,” OECD.Stat.103 Green, “Healthcare Systems: France.”104 Chevreul, Brigham, and Perronnin, “France.”105 “Social Protection,” OECD.Stat.106 OECD, “Out-of-Pocket Medical Expenditure.”107 Ibid.108 David Green, “Healthcare Systems: Germany”; Institute for Quality and Efficiency in Health Care (IQWiG), “Health Care in Germany,” Feb. 8, 2018;

Nadeem Esmail, “Health Care Lessons from Germany,” in Lessons from Abroad: A Series on Health Care Reform, Fraser Institute, May 2014. 109 OECD Secretariat Working Party No. 2 on Competition and Regulation, “Designing Publicly Funded Healthcare Markets,” OECD, Oct. 16, 2018;

Esmail, “Health Care Lessons from Germany.”110 Reinhard Busse et al., “Statutory Health Insurance in Germany,” The Lancet 390, no. 10097 (Aug. 26, 2017): 882–97. 111 Esmail, “Health Care Lessons from Germany.”112 Ibid. 113 Stefan Greß, “Germany,” in Voluntary Health Insurance in Europe.114 Mathias Kifmann, “Competition Policy for Health Care Provision in Germany,” Health Policy 121, no. 2 (February 2017): 119–25. 115 Esmail, “Health Care Lessons from Germany.”116 Kifmann, “Competition Policy for Health Care Provision in Germany.”117 Green, “Healthcare Systems: Germany.”118 Greß, “Germany.”119 Kifmann, “Competition Policy for Health Care Provision in Germany.”120 Esmail, “Health Care Lessons from Germany.”121 Greß, “Germany.”122 Tsung-Mei Cheng and Uwe E. Reinhardt, “Shepherding Major Health System Reforms: A Conversation with German Health Minister Ulla Schmidt,”

Health Affairs 27, no. 1 (2008): 204–13. 123 Green, “Healthcare Systems: Germany.”124 Greß, “Germany”; Cheng and Reinhardt, “Shepherding Major Health System Reforms.”125 Esmail, “Health Care Lessons from Germany.”126 Kifmann, “Competition Policy for Health Care Provision in Germany.”127 IQWiG, “Health Care in Germany.”128 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems”; OECD, “Designing Publicly Funded Healthcare Markets.”129 Green, “Healthcare Systems: Germany.”130 Esmail, “Health Care Lessons from Germany.”131 Ibid.132 Kifmann, “Competition Policy for Health Care Provision in Germany.”133 Esmail, “Health Care Lessons from Germany.”134 Kifmann, “Competition Policy for Health Care Provision in Germany.”135 Green, “Healthcare Systems: Germany.”136 Esmail, “Health Care Lessons from Germany.”137 IQWiG, “Health Care in Germany.”138 Cheng and Reinhardt, “Shepherding Major Health System Reforms.”139 Reinhard Busse, “The German Health System—an Introduction,” presentation in Berlin, European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies,

May 22, 2013. 140 Greß, “Germany.”141 “Social Protection,” OECD.Stat.142 OECD, “Out-of-Pocket Medical Expenditure.”143 Ibid.144 Hans Maarse, “Netherlands,” in Voluntary Health Insurance in Europe. 145 Claire Daley and James Gubb, “Healthcare Systems: The Netherlands,” Civitas, January 2013. 146 Tuohy, “The Politics of Market-Oriented Reforms.” 147 Ewout van Ginneken, Katherine Swartz, and Philip Van der Wees, “Health Insurance Exchanges in Switzerland and the Netherlands Offer Five Key

Lessons for the Operations of US Exchanges,” Health Affairs 32, no. 4 (April 2013): 744–52. 148 Ibid.; Wynand P. M. M. van de Ven and Frederik T. Schut, “Universal Mandatory Health Insurance in the Netherlands: A Model for the United States?”

Health Affairs 27, no. 2 (May/June 2008): 771–81. 149 Hans Maarse, Patrick Jeurissen, and Dick Ruwaard, “Results of the Market-Oriented Reform in the Netherlands: A Review,” Health Economics,

Policy and Law 11, no. 2 (April 2016): 161–78.

Page 29: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

29

150 Ibid. 151 Mossialos “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”152 Maarse, Jeurissen, and Ruwaard, “Results of the Market-Oriented Reform in the Netherlands.”153 Daley and Gubb, “Healthcare Systems: The Netherlands.”154 Frederik T. Schut and Marco Varkevisser, “Competition for Health Care Provision in the Netherlands,” Health Policy 121, no. 2 (February 2017): 126–33. 155 Martin Gaynor and Misja Mikkers, “Are Price Controls the Answer? Netherlands Edition,” Compassionate Economics (blog), Feb. 27, 2013. 156 Maarse, Jeurissen, and Ruwaard, “Results of the Market-Oriented Reform in the Netherlands.”157 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”158 Schut and Varkevisser, “Competition for Health Care Provision in the Netherlands.”159 Maarse, Jeurissen, and Ruwaard, “Results of the Market-Oriented Reform in the Netherlands.”160 Misja Mikkers, The Dutch Healthcare System in International Perspective (Tilburg: Tilberg University, 2016). 161 Maarse, Jeurissen, and Ruwaard, “Results of the Market-Oriented Reform in the Netherlands.”162 Schut and Varkevisser, “Competition for Health Care Provision in the Netherlands.”163 Maarse, Jeurissen, and Ruwaard, “Results of the Market-Oriented Reform in the Netherlands.”164 Ibid. 165 Hans Maarse and Aggie Paulus, “The Politics of Health-Care Reform in the Netherlands Since 2006,” Health Economics, Policy and Law 6, no. 1

(January 2011): 125–34. 166 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”167 Tuohy, “The Politics of Market-Oriented Reforms.” 168 Van de Ven and Schut, “Universal Mandatory Health Insurance in the Netherlands.”169 Maarse, “Netherlands.”170 “Social Protection,” OECD.Stat; Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”171 OECD, “Out-of-Pocket Medical Expenditure.”172 Ibid.173 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”174 Claire Daley and James Gubb, “Healthcare Systems: Switzerland,” Civitas, January 2013. 175 Nikola Biller-Adorno and Thomas Zeltner, “Individual Responsibility and Community Solidarity—the Swiss Health Care System,” New England Journal of

Medicine 373 (Dec. 3, 2015): 2193–97. 176 Van Ginneken, Swartz, and Van der Wees, “Health Insurance Exchanges In Switzerland and the Netherlands.”177 Viktor von Wyl and Konstantin Beck, “Switzerland,” in Voluntary Health Insurance in Europe.178 Daley and Gubb, “Healthcare Systems: Switzerland.” 179 Regina E. Herzlinger and Ramin Parsa-Parsi, “Consumer-Driven Health Care: Lessons from Switzerland,” Journal of the American Medical Association

292, no. 10 (September 2004): 1213–20; Giulia Alessio et al., “The Swiss Healthcare System,” JKU (Johannes Kepler University), Linz, April 2015. 180 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”181 Herzlinger and Parsa-Parsi, “Consumer-Driven Health Care: Lessons from Switzerland.”182 Mossialos, “International Profiles of Health Care Systems.”183 Ibid.; van Ginneken, Swartz, and Van der Wees, “Health Insurance Exchanges in Switzerland and the Netherlands.”184 Von Wyl and Beck, “Switzerland.”185 Ibid. 186 U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Reports, “Health Insurance Coverage in the United States: 2017,” table 1: Coverage Numbers and Rates by

Type of Health Insurance: 2013, 2016, and 2017. 187 OECD, “Out-of-Pocket Medical Expenditure.”188 Ibid. 189 Rebecca M. Sachs, “How Do Hospitals Set Their Charity Care Policies? Evidence from Nonprofit Tax Returns,” poster at Association for Public Policy

Analysis and Management meeting, November 2019. 190 Mark V. Pauly, “Will Health Care’s Immediate Future Look a Lot Like the Recent Past?” American Enterprise Institute, June 2019. 191 “Fast Facts on U.S. Hospitals,” American Hospital Association, 2019. 192 “Certificate of Need State Laws,” National Conference of State Legislatures, Feb. 28, 2019. 193 Bacchus Barua and David Jacques, “Waiting Your Turn: Wait Times for Health Care in Canada,” Fraser Institute, 2018. 194 Esmail and Barua, “Is the Canada Health Act a Barrier to Reform?”195 Brett J. Skinner and Mark Rovere, “Access Delayed, Access Denied: Waiting for New Medicines in Canada: 2012,” Fraser Institute, Apr. 4, 2012. 196 Comptroller and Auditor General, “Sustainability and Transformation in the NHS,” National Audit Office, Jan. 19, 2018. 197 Committee of Public Accounts, “NHS Financial Sustainability: Progress Review,” House of Commons, Mar. 27, 2019. 198 “A Shortage of Staff Is the Biggest Problem Facing the NHS,” The Economist, Mar. 23, 2019. 199 Comptroller and Auditor General, “NHS Waiting Times for Elective Care and Cancer Treatment,” National Audit Office, Mar. 22, 2019. 200 Jessica Morris, “The Growing Problem of Treatment Waiting Times,” Nuffield Trust, May 21, 2018. 201 “Sustainability and Transformation in the NHS,” National Audit Office; “NHS Financial Sustainability: Progress Review,” House of Commons.202 “Sustainability and Transformation in the NHS,” National Audit Office.

Page 30: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive Health-Care Reform

30

203 Hall and Savage, “The Role of the Private Sector in the Australian Healthcare System.”204 Luigi Siciliani, Valerie Moran, and Michael Borowitz, “Measuring and Comparing Health Care Waiting Times in OECD Countries,” OECD Health Working

Papers no. 67, Nov. 18, 2013. 205 Ibid. 206 Hall and Savage, “The Role of the Private Sector in the Australian Healthcare System.”207 McDonald and Duckett, “Regulation, Private Health Insurance, and the Australian Health System.”208 Ibid. 209 Hall and Savage, “The Role of the Private Sector in the Australian Healthcare System.”210 Duckett, “Expanding the Breadth of Medicare: Learning from Australia.”211 Choné, “Competition Policy for Health Care Provision in France.”212 Dormont and Péron, “Does Health Insurance Encourage the Rise in Medical Prices?”213 Green, “Healthcare Systems: France.”214 Dormont, Geoffard, and Tirole, “Rebuilding the Health Insurance System.” 215 Ibid. 216 Esmail, “Health Care Lessons from Germany.” 217 Kifmann, “Competition Policy for Health Care Provision in Germany.”218 Greß, “Germany.”219 Andres Luque Ramos, Falk Hoffmann, and Ove Spreckelsen, “Waiting Times in Primary Care Depending on Insurance Scheme in Germany,” BMC

Health Services Research 18, no. 191 (Mar. 20, 2018). 220 Nils Heinrich, Ansgar Wübker, and Christiane Wuckel, “Waiting Times for Outpatient Treatment in Germany,” Ruhr Economic Papers no. 683 (March

2017). 221 Ramos, Hoffmann, and Spreckelsen, “Waiting Times in Primary Care Depending on Insurance Scheme in Germany.”222 Maarse, Jeurissen, and Ruwaard, “Results of the Market-Oriented Reform in the Netherlands.”223 Daley and Gubb, “Healthcare Systems: The Netherlands.”224 Gaynor and Mikkers, “Are Price Controls the Answer? Netherlands Edition.”225 Romy E. Bes, “Selective Contracting and Channeling Patients to Preferred Providers: A Scoping Review,” Health Policy 121, no. 5 (May 2017): 504–17. 226 Siciliani, Moran, and Borowitz, “Measuring and Comparing Health Care Waiting Times in OECD Countries.”227 Maarse, Jeurissen, and Ruwaard, “Results of the Market-Oriented Reform in the Netherlands.”228 Anna van Poucke, “Wie doet het met wie,” KPMG Health, July 2018. 229 Maarse and Paulus, “The Politics of Health-Care Reform in the Netherlands Since 2006.”230 Maarse, Jeurissen, and Ruwaard, “Results of the Market-Oriented Reform in the Netherlands.”231 Daley and Gubb, “Healthcare Systems: The Netherlands.”232 Poucke, “Wie doet het met wie.” 233 Van de Ven and Schut, “Universal Mandatory Health Insurance in the Netherlands.”234 Maarse, Jeurissen, and Ruwaard, “Results of the Market-Oriented Reform in the Netherlands.”235 Ibid. 236 Wynand P. M. M. van de Ven et al., “Risk Adjustment and Risk Selection in Europe: 6 Years Later,” Health Policy 83, nos. 2–3 (October 2007): 162–79.237 Wilm Quentin and Reinhard Busse, “The Strongly Decentralized Swiss Health System Achieves Good Results,” Health Policy 122, no. 6 (June 2018):

565–67. 238 Alessio, “The Swiss Healthcare System.” 239 Reto Schleiniger, “Health Care Cost in Switzerland: Quantity- or Price-Driven?” Health Policy 117, no. 1 (July 2014): 83–89. 240 Timothy J. Layton et al., “Private vs. Public Provision of Social Insurance: Evidence from Medicaid,” NBER Working Paper 26042 (July 2019). 241 Barros and Siciliani, “Public and Private Sector Interface.”242 Kurt R. Brekke and Lars Sørgard, “Public Versus Private Health Care in a National Health Service,” CESifo (Center for Economic Studies and Ifo

Institute) working paper 1679 (March 2006).243 Chris Pope, “Should We Move Away from Employer-Sponsored Insurance?” e21, Nov. 30, 2018.

Page 31: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

31

Page 32: Medicare for All? Lessons from Abroad for Comprehensive ... · private supplemental health insurance. Competing payer (Germany, the Netherlands, and Switzerland): the government publicly

November 2019


Recommended