+ All Categories

Microfinance

Date post: 16-Aug-2015
Category:
Upload: jeegesh-bhatt
View: 32 times
Download: 3 times
Share this document with a friend
Popular Tags:
96
Table of Contents Sr no. Topic Page no. 1 Synopsis 2 2 Microfinance- An Introduction 4 3 Evolution 7 4 Evolution in India 13 5 Target of Microfinance 17 6 Business Models in Microfinance 19 7 Institutions Model in India 25 8 Business Models in India 27 9 Top Ten Institutions in India 35 10 Microfinance outlook in 2012- Region wise 45 11 Funding Needs 46 12 What in Investors look in MFI’s 50 13 Fund to MFI’s Worldwide 52 14 Securitisation 57 15 Major Deals in Microfinance India 59 16 Recommendations for Growth 63 17 Conclusion 66 18 Webliography 67 1 | Page
Transcript
Page 1: Microfinance

Table of ContentsSr no. Topic Page no.

1 Synopsis 22 Microfinance- An Introduction 43 Evolution 74 Evolution in India 135 Target of Microfinance 176 Business Models in Microfinance 197 Institutions Model in India 258 Business Models in India 279 Top Ten Institutions in India 35

10 Microfinance outlook in 2012- Region wise 4511 Funding Needs 4612 What in Investors look in MFI’s 5013 Fund to MFI’s Worldwide 5214 Securitisation 5715 Major Deals in Microfinance India 5916 Recommendations for Growth 6317 Conclusion 6618 Webliography 67

Synopsis

1 | P a g e

Page 2: Microfinance

Project Title: Microfinance – A New Avenue for Private Equity

Introduction

This project enlightens on how the microfinance business works in India and what are all the funding needs and how the Private Equity have helped them overcome this funding need. The further part of the projects also shows the deals in this sector and most active players who have received how much funding.

Objectives

This project gives highlights about how these microfinance institutions are formed and how they actively perform in the rural market though they are a small bank with differences.

Scope of Study

The scope of the study was to find out the following things

1. When it all did started

2. What is microfinance

3. What business models they have

4. How do they manage their funding

5. Private equity investments in Microfinance

6. What are suggestions

2 | P a g e

Page 3: Microfinance

Identification of the problem

The microfinance sector have an acute shortage of funds due to the delayed cycles of repayment of loan they have to take loan from banks and lend the same to the customers or borrowers. They only serve to poor of the nations and not very poor.

Limitations

The limitations to their funding is they do not have a perfect accounts of lending and their repayment cycle is delayed many a times due to which the availability of funds to them is a big problem and banks do lend them on a mortgage of assets which then becomes a problem for them because they cannot realize wealth on their assets.

Research objectives and procedures

The objective to do the research was to find out about this fast growing sector in India and the investment in this sector is booming from the last 2 financial years although the sector has seen a sharp fall in the last financial year but then it has got a good perspective in future.

The data is being taken from various sites which are as follows:

Vccircle.com

Bellwether.com

Microfinanceindia.com

RBI.org

References from

Times of India

Business Standard

What is Microfinance? - An Introduction

3 | P a g e

Page 4: Microfinance

Microfinance is the provision of financial services to low-income clients or solidarity lending groups including consumers and the self-employed, who traditionally lack access to banking and related services.

More broadly, it is a movement whose object is "a world in which as many poor and near-poor households as possible have permanent access to an appropriate range of high quality financial services, including not just credit but also savings, insurance, and fund transfers." Those who promote microfinance generally believe that such access will help poor people out of poverty.

Microfinance is a broad category of services, which includes microcredit. Microcredit is provision of credit services to poor clients. Although microcredit is one of the aspects of microfinance, conflation of the two terms is endemic in public discourse. Critics often attack microcredit while referring to it indiscriminately as either 'microcredit' or 'microfinance'. Due to the broad range of microfinance services, it is difficult to assess impact, and very few studies have tried to assess its full impact.

Traditionally, banks have not provided financial services, such as loans, to clients with little or no cash income. Banks incur substantial costs to manage a client account, regardless of how small the sums of money involved. For example, although the total gross revenue from delivering one hundred loans worth $1,000 each will not differ greatly from the revenue that results from delivering one loan of $100,000, it takes nearly a hundred times as much work and cost to manage a hundred loans as it does to manage one. The fixed cost of processing loans of any size is considerable as assessment of potential borrowers, their repayment prospects and security; administration of outstanding loans, collecting from delinquent borrowers, etc., has to be done in all cases. There is a break-even point in providing loans or deposits below which banks lose money on each transaction they make. Poor people usually fall below that breakeven point. A similar equation resists efforts to deliver other financial services to poor people.

In addition, most poor people have few assets that can be secured by a bank as collateral. As documented extensively by Hernando De Soto and others, even if they happen to own land in the developing world, they may not have effective

4 | P a g e

Page 5: Microfinance

title to it. This means that the bank will have little recourse against defaulting borrowers.

Seen from a broader perspective, the development of a healthy national financial system has long been viewed as a catalyst for the broader goal of national economic development (see for example Alexander Gerschenkron, Paul Rosenstein-Rodan, Joseph Schumpeter, and Anne Krueger). However, the efforts of national planners and experts to develop financial services for most people have often failed in developing countries, for reasons summarized well by Adams, Graham & Von Pischke in their classic analysis 'Undermining Rural Development with Cheap Credit'.

Because of these difficulties, when poor people borrow they often rely on relatives or a local moneylender, whose interest rates can be very high. An analysis of 28 studies of informal moneylending rates in 14 countries in Asia, Latin America and Africa concluded that 76% of moneylender rates exceed 10% per month, including 22% that exceeded 100% per month. Moneylenders usually charge higher rates to poorer borrowers than to less poor ones. While moneylenders are often demonized and accused of usury, their services are convenient and fast, and they can be very flexible when borrowers run into problems. Hopes of quickly putting them out of business have proven unrealistic, even in places where microfinance institutions are active.

Over the past centuries practical visionaries, from the Franciscan monks who founded the community-oriented pawnshops of the 15th century, to the founders of the European credit union movement in the 19th century (such as Friedrich Wilhelm Raiffeisen) and the founders of the microcredit movement in the 1970s (such as Muhammad Yunus) have tested practices and built institutions designed to bring the kinds of opportunities and risk-management tools that financial services can provide to the doorsteps of poor people. While the success of the Grameen Bank (which now serves over 7 million poor Bangladeshi women) has inspired the world, it has proved difficult to replicate this success. In nations with lower population densities, meeting the operating costs of a retail branch by serving nearby customers has proven considerably more challenging. Hans Dieter

5 | P a g e

Page 6: Microfinance

Seibel, board member of the European Microfinance Platform, is in favor of the group model. This particular model (used by many Microfinance institutions) makes financial sense, he says, because it reduces transaction costs. Microfinance programs also need to be based on local funds. Local Roots

Although much progress has been made, the problem has not been solved yet, and the overwhelming majority of people who earn less than $1 a day, especially in the rural areas, continue to have no practical access to formal sector finance. Microfinance has been growing rapidly with $25 billion currently at work in microfinance loans. It is estimated that the industry needs $250 billion to get capital to all the poor people who need it. The industry has been growing rapidly, and concerns have arisen that the rate of capital flowing into microfinance is a potential risk unless managed well.

As seen in the State of Andhra Pradesh (India), these systems can easily fail, some reasons being lack of use by potential customers, over-indebtedness, poor operating procedures, neglect of duties and inadequate regulations.

Evolution

6 | P a g e

Page 7: Microfinance

The concept of microfinance is not new. Savings and credit groups that have operated for centuries include the "susus" of Ghana, "chit funds" in India, "tandas" in Mexico, "arisan" in Indonesia, "cheetu" in Sri Lanka, "tontines" in West Africa, and "pasanaku" in Bolivia, as well as numerous savings clubs and burial societies found all over the world.

Formal credit and savings institutions for the poor have also been around for decades, providing customers who were traditionally neglected by commercial banks a way to obtain financial services through cooperatives and development finance institutions. One of the earlier and longer-lived micro credit organizations providing small loans to rural poor with no collateral was the Irish Loan Fund system, initiated in the early 1700s by the author and nationalist Jonathan Swift. Swift's idea began slowly but by the 1840s had become a widespread institution of about 300 funds all over Ireland. Their principal purpose was making small loans with interest for short periods. At their peak they were making loans to 20% of all Irish households annually.

In the 1800s, various types of larger and more formal savings and credit institutions began to emerge in Europe, organized primarily among the rural and urban poor. These institutions were known as People's Banks, Credit Unions, and Savings and Credit Co-operatives.

The concept of the credit union was developed by Friedrich Wilhelm Raiffeisen and his supporters. Their altruistic action was motivated by concern to assist the

rural population to break out of their dependence on moneylenders and to improve their welfare. From 1870, the unions expanded rapidly over a large sector of the Rhine Province and other regions of the German States. The cooperative movement quickly spread to other countries in Europe and North America, and eventually, supported by the cooperative movement in developed countries and donors, also to developing countries.

In Indonesia, the Indonesian People's Credit Banks (BPR) or The Bank Perkreditan Rakyat opened in 1895. The BPR became the largest microfinance system in

7 | P a g e

Page 8: Microfinance

Indonesia with close to 9,000 units.

In the early 1900s, various adaptations of these models began to appear in parts of rural Latin America. While the goal of such rural finance interventions was usually defined in terms of modernizing the agricultural sector, they usually had two specific objectives: increased commercialization of the rural sector, by mobilizing "idle" savings and increasing investment through credit, and reducing oppressive feudal relations that were enforced through indebtedness. In most cases, these new banks for the poor were not owned by the poor themselves, as they had been in Europe, but by government agencies or private banks. Over the years, these institutions became inefficient and at times, abusive.

Between the 1950s and 1970s, governments and donors focused on providing agricultural credit to small and marginal farmers, in hopes of raising productivity and incomes. These efforts to expand access to agricultural credit emphasized supply-led government interventions in the form of targeted credit through state-owned development finance institutions, or farmers' cooperatives in some cases, that received concessional loans and on-lent to customers at below-market interest rates. These subsidized schemes were rarely successful. Rural development banks suffered massive erosion of their capital base due to subsidized lending rates and poor repayment discipline and the funds did not always reach the poor, often ending up concentrated in the hands of better-off farmers.

Meanwhile, starting in the 1970s, experimental programs in Bangladesh, Brazil, and a few other countries extended tiny loans to groups of poor women to invest in micro-businesses. This type of microenterprise credit was based on solidarity group lending in which every member of a group guaranteed the repayment of all members. These "microenterprise lending" programs had an almost exclusive focus on credit for income generating activities (in some cases accompanied by forced savings schemes) targeting very poor (often women) borrowers.

• ACCION International, an early pioneer, was founded by a law student, Joseph

8 | P a g e

Page 9: Microfinance

Blatchford, to address poverty in Latin America's cities. Begun as a student-run volunteer effort in the shantytowns of Caracas with $90,000 raised from private companies, ACCION today is one of the premier microfinance organizations in the world, with a network of lending partners that spans Latin America, the United States and Africa.

• SEWA Bank. In 1972 the Self Employed Women's Association (SEWA) was registered as a trade union in Gujarat (India), with the main objective of "strengthening its members' bargaining power to improve income, employment and access to social security." In 1973, to address their lack of access to financial services, the members of SEWA decided to found "a bank of their own". Four thousand women contributed share capital to establish the Mahila SEWA Co-operative Bank. Since then it has been providing banking services to poor, illiterate, self-employed women and has become a viable financial venture with today around 30,000 active clients.

• Grameen Bank. In Bangladesh, Professor Muhammad Yunus addressed the banking problem faced by the poor through a programme of action-research. With his graduate students in Chittagong University in 1976, he designed an experimental credit programme to serve them. It spread rapidly to hundreds of villages. Through a special relationship with rural banks, he disbursed and recovered thousands of loans, but the bankers refused to take over the project at the end of the pilot phase. They feared it was too expensive and risky in spite of his success. Eventually, through the support of donors, the Grameen Bank was founded in 1983 and now serves more than 4 million borrowers. The initial success of Grameen Bank also stimulated the establishment of several other giant microfinance institutions like BRAC, ASA,

9 | P a g e

Page 10: Microfinance

Proshika, etc.

Through the 1980s, the policy of targeted, subsidized rural credit came under a slow but increasing attack as evidence mounted of the disappointing performance of directed credit programs, especially poor loan recovery, high administrative costs, agricultural development bank insolvency, and accrual of a disproportionate share of the benefits of subsidized credit to larger farmers. The basic tenets underlying the traditional directed credit approach were debunked and supplanted by a new school of thought called the "financial systems approach", which viewed credit not as a productive input necessary for agricultural development but as just one type of financial service that should be freely priced to guarantee its permanent supply and eliminate rationing. The financial systems school held that the emphasis on interest rate ceilings and credit subsidies retarded the development of financial intermediaries, discouraged intermediation between savers and investors, and benefited larger scale producers more than small scale, low-income producers.

Meanwhile, microcredit programs throughout the world improved upon the original methodologies and defied conventional wisdom about financing the poor. First, they showed that poor people, especially women, had excellent repayment rates among the better programs, rates that were better than the formal financial sectors of most developing countries. Second, the poor were willing and able to pay interest rates that allowed microfinance institutions (MFIs) to cover their costs.

1990s These two features - high repayment and cost-recovery interest rates - permitted some MFIs to achieve long-term sustainability and reach large numbers of clients.

Another flagship of the microfinance movement is the village banking unit system of the Bank Rakyat Indonesia (BRI), the largest microfinance institution in developing countries. This state-owned bank serves about 22 million microsavers with autonomously managed microbanks. The microbanks of BRI are the product

10 | P a g e

Page 11: Microfinance

of a successful transformation by the state of a state-owned agricultural bank during the mid-1980s.

The 1990s saw growing enthusiasm for promoting microfinance as a strategy for poverty alleviation. The microfinance sector blossomed in many countries, leading to multiple financial services firms serving the needs of microentrepreneurs and poor households. These gains, however, tended to concentrate in urban and densely populated rural areas.

It was not until the mid-1990s that the term "microcredit" began to be replaced by a new term that included not only credit, but also savings and other financial

services. "Microfinance" emerged as the term of choice to refer to a range of financial services to the poor, that included not only credit, but also savings and other services such as insurance and money transfers.

ACCION helped found BancoSol in 1992, the first commercial bank in the world dedicated solely to microfinance. Today, BancoSol offers its more than 70,000 clients an impressive range of financial services including savings accounts, credit cards and housing loans - products that just five years ago were only accessible to Bolivia's upper classes. BancoSol is no longer unique: more than 15 ACCION-affiliated organizations are now regulated financial institutions.

Today, practitioners and donors are increasingly focusing on expanded financial services to the poor in frontier markets and on the integration of microfinance in financial systems development. The recent introduction by some donors of the financial systems approach in microfinance - which emphasizes favorable policy environment and institution-building - has improved the overall effectiveness of microfinance interventions. But numerous challenges remain, especially in rural and agricultural finance and other frontier markets. Today, the microfinance industry and the greater development community share the view that permanent poverty reduction requires addressing the multiple dimensions of poverty. For the international community, this means reaching specific Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) in education, women's empowerment, and health, among others.

11 | P a g e

Page 12: Microfinance

For microfinance, this means viewing microfinance as an essential element in any country's financial system.

12 | P a g e

Page 13: Microfinance

Evolution of Microfinance in India

The genesis of microcredit, and therefore microfinance is credited to Dr. Muhammad Yunus, who founded the Grameen Bank in 1983. In India, however, financial services especially for the rural poor also had a parallel evolution, starting from the earliest cooperative societies in 1890 to the burgeoning microfinance sector of today, dominated by Self Help Groups (SHGs), which have emerged as micro level financial intermediaries.

Prelude The role prescribed for financial sector in India to achieve developmental goals dates to pre independence days. The agriculture credit department was set up in 1935 by the Reserve Bank of India to promote rural credit. In its early days, the government of India sought to promote rural credit by strengthening the cooperative institutions. The need to replace costly informal credit with institutional credit was strongly felt as the All India Rural Credit Survey report of 1954 found that informal sources accounted for 70% of rural credit usage, followed by cooperatives (6.4%) and commercial banks (0.9%).

The “Lead Bank Scheme” was introduced in 1969, thereby starting a process of district credit plans and coordination among the different financial intermediaries. The same year also saw the nationalization of fourteen commercial banks. As a result of these initiatives, the share of formal financial sector in total rural credit usage rose to 30% in 1971. The Regional Rural Banks (RRBs) were conceptualized in 1975 to augment the delivery of financial services in rural areas. This resulted in the creation of a network of banks which is one of the largest in the world even today. Not surprisingly, the All India Survey Debt and Investment Survey of 1981 found that the share of formal financial sector in total credit had risen to over sixty percent.

Preparing the Ground The government initiated the Integrated Rural Development Programme (IRDP) in

13 | P a g e

Page 14: Microfinance

1980-81. The objective of IRDP was to direct subsidized loans to poor self-employed people through the banking sector. The National Bank for Agriculture and Rural Development (NABARD) was established in 1982. In the same year the government established Development of Women and Children in Rural Areas (DWARCA) scheme as a part of IRDP. It was around this time that the first Self Help Groups (SHGs) started emerging in the country mostly as a result of NGO activities. The NGO MYRADA was one of the pioneers of the concept of SHGs in India. It was in 1984-85, when MYRADA started linking SHGs to banks. These SHGs were large enough for the bank to have transactions. The SHGs in turn were also very responsive and flexible to the needs of their members. While MYRADA did not directly intervene in the credit market for the poor, it facilitated “banking with micro institutions established and controlled by the poor”. The SHGs were a step in that direction. Thus, seeds were sown for the modern microfinance sector in India to emerge.

IRDP is estimated to have reached over 55 million poor families until 1999, when it was transformed into Swarnajyanti Gram Swarozgar Yojna (SGSY). The IRDP, in spite of its immense outreach, experienced very low repayment rates and created 40 million defaulters, which coupled with the subsidy component ruled out long term sustainability of the programme.

The formal financial sector has been criticized to be supply driven during this phase (Sriram and Fisher, 2002) . The formal financial sector was characterized by: • A large network of banks including cooperative banks and innovations such as RRBs, • Focused approach on credit, • Lending targeted at the “priority sector” such as agriculture and weaker sections of the population, • Interest rates ceiling, • Subsidies.

14 | P a g e

Page 15: Microfinance

Financial services, were thus, viewed as a social obligation. Given the high rates of default, a formal loan waiver was announced by the government in the year 1989. This had a negative impact on credit discipline, and reinforced the view that lending to the poor was not a profitable business among the mainstream financial institutions.

Economic Reforms and a new Generation of Financial Institutions In the year 1991, India faced a balance of payment crisis. India’s foreign reserve fell to a very low level and the country’s ability to meet foreign debt obligations was seriously impaired. This, however, propelled the government into introducing structural changes in the economy-commonly referred to as the Economic Reforms of 1991. This gradually resulted in greater autonomy to the financial sector. As a result, new generation private sector banks such as UTI Bank, ICICI Bank, IDBI Bank (all established in 1994) and HDFC Bank (early 1995), emerged. The Narsimhan Committee report of 1991 also recommended phasing out of interest rate concessions. At the same time the Brahm Prakash Committee recommended reducing state involvement in cooperative banks.

Microfinance is Borne SHG – Bank linkage programme was formally launched by the NABARD in the year 1992, with it circulating guidelines to banks for financing Self Help Groups (SHGs) under a Pilot Project that aimed at financing 500 SHGs across the country through the banking system. While, the banks had financed about 600 SHGs by March 1993, they continued to finance more and more SHGs in the coming years. This encouraged the Reserve Bank of India (RBI) to include financing to SHGs as a mainstream activity of banks under their priority sector lending in 1996. The Government of India bestowed national priority to the programme through its recognition of microfinance and it found a mention in the Union Budget of 1999. The banking system comprising public and private sector commercial banks, regional rural banks and cooperative banks has joined hands with several organizations in the formal and non-formal sectors to use this delivery mechanism for providing financial services to a large number of poor.

15 | P a g e

Page 16: Microfinance

Concurrently, in 1993, the Rashtriya Mahila Kosh (RMK) to accelerate the flow of self employed women in the unorganized sector. It is worth mentioning that the Sewa Cooperative Bank has been operating in Gujarat with similar objectives since 1974. The bank has been viable right from its inception and is an ideal example of community owned sustainable financial service delivery. Microfinance received greater recognition when the Small Industries Development Bank of India set up a Foundation for Microcredit with initial capital of Rs100 crores in 1998. The same year also saw the formation of Sa-dhan as an apex level association of Community Development Finance Institutions. The passing of Mutually Aided Cooperative Societies Act by Andhra Pradesh in 1995, followed by some other states has also acted as a stimulant as many new microfinance initiatives have come up under the MACS act. In addition to the success of the Nabard-SHG bank linkage programme, alternative microfinance initiative following Grameen and/or SHG methodology or at times individual lending model has also been successful.

Some Recent Developments:

The year 2004 has seen some very important development in the microfinance sector in India. The banking sector led by ICICI bank has shown interest in microfinance as a viable commercial opportunity. The total disbursement of the banking sector to microfinance is put at around Rs1000 crores for the year 2003-04. ICICI Bank plans to build a microfinance portfolio in excess of Rs1000 crores. It has taken a lead in establishing innovative partnerships with microfinance institutions which will allow for risk sharing between the two. ICICI bank has also securitized the microfinance portfolio of Share and Basix, and has potentially opened the doors of capital markets for the microfinance sector. Microfinance sector in India is set to enter a new growth phase in its evolutionary course.

Target of Microfinance

16 | P a g e

Page 17: Microfinance

The fundamental reason behind the Indian microfinance industry’s impressive growth is that it is fulfilling a critical need of its target audience, the low-income population, which has thus far remained unaddressed by the traditional financial services sector. Currently, a total population of 1.1 billion is being served by 50,000 commercial banks, 12,000 co-operative bank offices, 15,000 regional rural banks and 100,000 primary agriculture societies. This density of financial 12 services, however, belies the availability of financial services to low-income households, which make up a significant chunk of the Indian population. Before exploring why financial services have failed to reach this segment of the population, it is necessary to first define their target. The Indian population can be divided into four categories based on household income levels. The Rich who make up 0.4% of the households have an annual household income greater than $20,000.

The Middle Class comprises 11 million households, or 5.9% of the total households, and has an annual household income between $4,000 and $20,000. The Aspirers make up nearly Source: Lok Capital

22% of the households and have an annual household income between $1,800 and $4,000. Lastly, the Deprived segment, the prime target of the microfinance industry, comprises 135 million or 72% of the households and has an annual household income below $1,800.

Despite the density and robustness of the formal Indian financial system, it has failed to reach the deprived segment, leaving approximately 135 million households entirely unbanked. The size of India's unbanked population is one of the highest in the world, second only to that of China. The microfinance sector targets the poorer portion of the Aspirer segment and the mid to richer portion of the Deprived segment. The industry has thus far been able to create a service model and products that are suitable to these segments and these services and

products have proven successful in affecting improvements in the clients’ economic status. The reasons behind the formal financial sector’s failure to reach such a large segment of the Indian population are manifold and operate in a self-reinforcing manner. The principal prohibiting factor is that banks face extremely

17 | P a g e

Page 18: Microfinance

high fixed and variable costs in servicing low income households, resulting in high delivery costs for relatively small transactions. Much of the low income population is located in rural areas that are geographically remote and inaccessible. For this population, the cost of visiting a traditional bank branch is prohibitive due to the loss of wages that would be incurred in the time required. Concurrently, from a bank’s perspective, the cost of operating a branch in a remote location is financially unfeasible due to the low volume and high cost dynamic. Moreover, low income households are not interested in the same products that are usually utilized by the rest of the population because they have different immediate needs, lower financial capacities and variable income streams. The unsuitability of existing credit products for low income households is exacerbated by a general unavailability of collateralizable assets. Additionally, the low income population is often illiterate and lacks financial knowledge, making it nearly impossible for it to even contemplate availing existing financial services, which provide no ancillary support to mitigate these challenges.

In the absence of access to formal financial services, the low income segment has traditionally relied on local moneylenders to fulfill their financial needs. While this money is readily available, it is often exorbitantly priced at 60%-100% annual yields and forces the borrower into a classic debt trap, entrenching her in poverty. Credit from moneylenders has not traditionally acted as a tool for business expansion or enhancement of quality of life, but rather as a lifeline for immediate consumption or healthcare needs.

Microfinance Business Model

18 | P a g e

Page 19: Microfinance

MFI came into existence when the lack of access to credit for the poor is attributable to practical difficulties arising from the discrepancy between the mode of operation followed by financial institutions and the economic characteristics and financing needs of low-income households.

MicroCredit which is an integral part of Microfinance, is the extension of very small loans (microloans) to those in poverty designed to spur entrepreneurship. These individuals lack collateral, steady employment and a verifiable credit history and therefore cannot meet even the most minimal qualifications to gain access to traditional credit. Business Model for getting financially viable

Over the last ten years, however, successful experiences in providing finance to small entrepreneur and producers demonstrate that poor people, when given access to responsive and timely financial services at market rates, repay their loans and use the proceeds to increase their income and assets. This is not surprising since the only realistic alternative for them is to borrow from informal market at an interest much higher than market rates. Community banks, NGOs and grass root savings and credit groups around the world have shown that these microenterprise loans can be profitable for borrowers and for the lenders, making microfinance one of the most effective poverty reducing strategies.

To the extent that microfinance institutions become financially viable, self-sustaining, and integral to the communities in which they operate, they have the potential to attract more resources and expand services to clients. Despite the success of microfinance institutions, only about 2% of world's roughly 500 million small entrepreneurs are estimated to have access to financial services.

The Grameen Bank which is a synonym for Microfinance makes small loans to the impoverished without requiring collateral. Established in 1976, the Grameen Bank (GB) has over 1000 branches (a branch covers 25-30 villages, around 240 groups and 1200 borrowers) in every province of Bangladesh, borrowing groups in 28,000 villages, 12 lakh borrowers with over 90% being women. It has an annual growth rate of 20% in terms of its borrowers. The most important feature is the recovery rate of loans, which is as high as 98%. A still more interesting feature is the

19 | P a g e

Page 20: Microfinance

ingenious manner of advancing credit without any "collateral security". The Grameen Bank lending system is simple but effective. The system of this bank is based on the idea that the poor have skills that are under-utilized. A group-based credit approach is applied which utilizes the peer-pressure within the group to ensure the borrowers follow through and use caution in conducting their financial affairs with strict discipline, ensuring repayment eventually and allowing the borrowers to develop good credit standing.

The Business Model on which most of the Microfinance works is solidarity lending. Solidarity lending is a lending practice where small groups borrow collectively and group members encourage one another to repay. It is an important building block of microfinance. Solidarity lending lowers the costs to a financial institution related to assessing, managing and collecting loans, and can eliminate the need for collateral.

An early pioneer of solidarity lending, Dr. Muhammad Yunus of Grameen Bank in Bangladesh describes the dynamics of lending through solidarity groups this way:

"... Group membership not only creates support and protection but also smooth’s out the erratic behavior patterns of individual members, making each borrower more reliable in the process. Subtle and at times not-so-subtle peer pressure keeps each group member in line with the broader objectives of the credit program.... Because the group approves the loan request of each member, the group assumes moral responsibility for the loan. If any member of the group gets into trouble, the group usually comes forward to help."

The above cited Model helps in minimizing the delinquency rate. The source of income for most of the Microfinance Institutions (MFIs) are the high rate of interest they charge to the borrowers, The real average portfolio yield cited by the a sample of 704 microfinance institutions that voluntarily submitted reports to the MicroBanking Bulletin in 2006 was 22.3% annually. Microfinance institutions can broaden their resource base by mobilizing savings, accessing capital markets, loan funds and effective institutional development support. A logical way to tap capital market is securitization through a corporation that purchases loans made by microenterprise institutions with the funds raised

20 | P a g e

Page 21: Microfinance

through the bonds issuance on the capital market. There is at least one pilot attempt to securitize microfinance portfolio along these lines in Ecuador. As an alternative, BancoSol of Bolivia issued a certificate of deposit which is traded in Bolivian stock exchange. In 1994, it also issued certificates of deposit in the U.S. (Churchill 1996). The Foundation for Cooperation and Development of Paraguay issued bonds to raise capital for microenterprise lending (Grameen Trust 1995). Successful MFIs like Grameen Bank even generate revenue by providing training programs / research programs to journalists or upcoming MFIs.

Another kind of MFI in India is indigenously developed system known as Chit funds; they are the closest thing to a bank in many parts of India. They mobilize huge amounts of small savings and offer the same as some sort of microfinance. Properly used chit funds are an effective tool to meet unplanned, unforeseen and unexpected expenses, especially for the middle class and small businessmen. Chit fund is a dual-purpose instrument for both borrowing and saving. It has no financial intermediation. Each chit group is in a way a self-help group. Members invest a fixed amount every month. This collection is available for borrowing. Auctions are conducted every month. The members who bid for the highest discount win. The dividend at every auction is distributed to the subscribers out of the discount (the difference between the chit amount and the amount bid), after deducting the group foreman's commission. Shriram Chits has more than 22 lakh subscribers.

Proposed Model for MFIs If we consider the fact that MFIs role is to lend loan to impoverished sector of the society so that they raise their living standards and can provide a stable lifestyle to their families, which can be possible only when a group of member can come up with an business idea. But how successful the entity is going to be after its formation and will result in timely repayment of the loan cannot be guaranteed. I personally feel, instead of letting the inexperienced group to decide upon the venture all the time, MFIs or NGO's should set up ventures which can be either be an subsidiary of existing stable company or something which can traded outside the community, guaranteeing the flow of funds. This will bring an stable or regular source of income for many households without the worries of loan. The reason

21 | P a g e

Page 22: Microfinance

behind this though is the criticism behind the Microcredit institutions. Some experts argues that most microcredit institutions are overly dependent on external capital. A study of microcredit institutions in Bolivia in 2003, for example, found that they were very slow to deliver quality microsavings services because of easy access to cheaper forms of external capital.Global data tables from The Microbanking Bulletin show that savings represent a small source of funds for microcredit institutions in most developing nations.

Because field officers are in a position of power locally and are judged on repayment rates as the primary metric of their success, they sometimes use coercive and even violent tactics to collect installments on the microcredit loans. Some loan recipients sink into a cycle of debt, using a microcredit loan from one organization to meet interest obligations from another.

Recent move by indian govt to repay the loan taken by the farmers of certain segment is the result of delinquency. To avoid such incidences again, its better to invest in upbringing of this segment by bringing an regular source of income to the households.

Charity or commerce?

The different structures of microfinance

The term microfinance is used to describe a vast range of business structures and

funding mechanisms. In particular, the roles of charity and commerce within the

world of microfinance vary hugely depending on the organisation and the country of operation.

Commercial microfinance

22 | P a g e

Page 23: Microfinance

Commercial microfinance institutions structure a profitable business model around the principles of microfinance. This does not prevent them from being socially responsible, or “pro-poor” – Compartamos, a Mexican MFI and bank that is part of the ACCION network, describes itself as a “social company”, for example. Similarly, Kenya’s K-REP describes itself as a “commercial bank” with a “social mission”.

Another area in which private investment is playing an increasing role in microfinance is through the capitalisation of MFI loan books. In recent years, investors have begun to create investment funds for the microfinance sector offering a market rate of return. The first widely cited example of this was Profund, a $23m Latin American fund created by a group of investors headed by ACCION in 1995. Large, multinational banks are also now becoming increasingly involved in this area – Citigroup and HSBC both have microfinance divisions providing services such as loan guarantee funds, operational support and commercial wholesale lending to MFIs.

Charitable, and not-for-profit microfinance

Modern microfinance has its roots in non-profit structures. Grameen Bank of Bangladesh, founded by Nobel peace prize winner Mohammad Yunus, is a community bank owned by its clients. Grameen now claims to be sustainable, in that it covers its costs from interest earned on loans, and so does not require donor funding. However, unlike commercial microfinance, profits are reinvested into the business, or what it calls a “Rehabilitation fund”, which is set up to provide support and relief in disaster situations.

Other not-for-profit microfinance institutions do receive external funding, either to support expansion or to help cover costs. These include global organisations such as

23 | P a g e

Page 24: Microfinance

FINCA, BRAC and Opportunity International (which has a UK support base), as well as UK based charities such as the MicroLoan Foundation. Many, though not all, not-for-profit microfinance institutions aim to cover costs, and hence achieve full sustainability (ie non-reliance on donor funds). Sustainability is widely considered desirable, since it ensures that initiatives will be meaningful, scalable and long-lasting. In this model, donor funding is used to fund start-up costs or expansion as opposed to propping up a long-term business plan. However, in many regions, notably sub-Saharan Africa, sustainability is often incompatible with universal access. For example, a rural client who needs a $50 loan and who requires basic business training to set up their first business is far more costly to serve than an urban, educated client taking a $500 loan to finance an existing business venture. At the MicroLoan Foundation, (a UK based microfinance charity operating in sub Saharan Africa) we are therefore committed to becoming sustainable in the long term, both from the interest charged on loans and from ethical trading with our clients. However, it is integral to our approach that sustainability does not come at the expense of the availability of services to those most in need.

24 | P a g e

Page 25: Microfinance

Micro Finance Institutions in India

Those institutions which have microfinance as their main operation are known as micro finance institutions. A number of organizations with varied size and legal forms offer microfinance service. These institutions lend through the concept of Joint Liability Group (JLG). A JLG is an informal group comprising of 5 to 10 individual members who come together for the purpose of availing bank loans either individually or through the group mechanism against a mutual guarantee. The reason for existence of separate institutions i.e. MFIs for offering microfinance are as follows:

High transaction cost – generally micro credits fall below the break-even point of providing loans by banks

Absence of collaterals – the poor usually are not in a state to offer collaterals to secure the credit

Loans are generally taken for very short duration periods

Higher frequency of repayment of installments and higher rate of Default

Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs), Co-operative societies, Section-25 companies, Societies and Trusts, all such institutions operating in microfinance sector constitute MFIs and together they account for about 42 percent of the microfinance sector in terms of loan portfolio. The MFI channel is dominated by NBFCs which cover more than 80 percent of the total loan portfolio through the MFI channel.

25 | P a g e

Page 26: Microfinance

26 | P a g e

Sl. No.

Type of MFI Number Legal Registration

Not-for Profit MFIs

1 NGOs 400-500 Society Registration Act, 1860

Indian Trust Act, 1882

2 Non-Profit companies 20 Section-25 of Indian Companies Act, 1956

Mutual Benefit MFIs

3 Mutual benefit MFIs – Mutually Aided Cooperative Societies (MACS)

200-250 Mutually Aided Co-operative societies, Act enacted by State Governments

For Profit MFIs

4 Non-Banking Financial Companies (NBFCs)

45 Indian companies Act, 1956

Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934

Page 27: Microfinance

Microfinance Business Models in India

Model#1 The Grameen system

Potential clients are asked by the MFI to organise themselves into ‘Groups’ of five members which are in turn organised into ‘Centres’ of around five to seven such Groups. The members make regular savings with the MFI, according to a fixed compulsory schedule, and they also take regular loans. They each have individual savings and loan accounts with the MFI, and the main function of the Groups and Centres are to facilitate the financial intermediation process, through performing tasks such as:

• Holding regular and usually weekly meetings which are supervised by a MFI worker who maintains the records, where savings and repayments are collected and handed over to the MFI worker,

• Organizing contributions to one or a number of group savings funds, which can be used by the group for a number of purposes, usually only with the agreement of the MFI which maintains the group fund accounts,

• Guaranteeing loans to their individual members, by accepting joint and several liability, by raising group emergency funds and by accepting that no members of a Group will be able to take a new loan if any members are in arrears,

• Arising from the above, appraising fellow-members’ loan applications, and ensuring that their fellow-members maintain their regular savings contributions and loan repayments.

27 | P a g e

Page 28: Microfinance

The SHG system

The members form a group of around twenty members. The group formation process may be facilitated by an NGO or by the MFI or bank itself, or it may evolve from a traditional rotating savings and credit group (ROSCA) or other locally initiated grouping. The process of formal ‘linkage’ to an MFI or bank usually goes through the following stages, which may be spread over many years or which may take place within a few months.

• The SHG members decide to make regular savings contributions. These may be kept by their elected head, in cash, or in kind, or they may be banked.

• The members start to borrow individually from the SHG, for purposes, on terms and at interest rates decided by the group themselves.

• The SHG opens a savings account, in the group’s name, with the bank or MFI, for such funds as may not be needed by members, or in order to qualify for a loan from the bank.

• The bank or MFI makes a loan to the SHG, in the name of the Group, which is then used by the Group to supplement its own funds for on-lending to it members.

The SHG need never go through all these stages; it may satisfy its members’ needs quite effectively if it only goes to the second or even to the first stage, saving money and possibly not even withdrawing it (Harper M 2000, pp. 39-42).

The SHG carries out all the same functions as those required by the Grameen system, but they do this on their own behalf, since the SHG is effectively a micro-bank, carrying out all the familiar intermediation tasks of savings mobilisation and lending. The MFI or bank may assist the SHG in record keeping, and they may also demand to know who are the members and impose certain conditions as to the uses of the loan which they make to the SHG, but the SHG is an autonomous financial institution in its own right.

The members have their accounts with the SHG, not with the MFI or bank, and the MFI or bank does not have any direct dealings with the members.

28 | P a g e

Page 29: Microfinance

Model#2

SHG-MCI System

A typical SHG consists of twelve to thirty members (Rutherford, 2000). The group is not merely a savings and loan association, but serves as an “affinity” group that provides a platform for a range of issues (such as watershed development, awareness building, and family planning—see Fernandez, 1994, for a comprehensive description of such SHGs). An SHG meets regularly (often weekly), and in these meetings, R. Srinivasan is professor and coordinator of the Finance & Control Area at the Indian Institute of Management, Bangalore. Members contribute savings and take decisions on loans to members of the group. Group leadership is by rotation. The SHG may initially lend out of its own pool of funds and after gaining some experience with lending (and recovering loans), it may borrow from an MCI for on-lending to members.

Briefly, the SHG-MCI system has financial linkages as follows. Each SHG in the system raises funds from individual members and borrows from the MCI. Each SHG lends to members and saves with the MCI. I will assume that there are no regulatory restrictions4 on the SHG activities. The MCI raises funds from three sources: capital, SHG savings, and borrowings from outside. The MCI lends to SHGs, invests outside, and maintains a cash balance. The MCI may have regulatory restrictions on assets, liabilities, and interest rates.

Financial Model

The spreadsheet financial model5 (created in Microsoft Excel) was developed to analyze possible strategies using what-if analysis. The model generates two sets of outputs: SHG-level and MCI-level projections. The model generates these projections based on input values provided for a number of factors at SHG and MCI level. A stylized description of the functioning of SHGs and the MCI is provided, with the various input assumptions. To simplify computation, a month has been taken as the standard interval. Thus members save monthly, repay in monthly installments, and so on.

29 | P a g e

Page 30: Microfinance

Financial Model Inputs: SHG

• An SHG is formed by an initial set of members and the group remains constant. (Initial membership fees are ignored; they make little difference to the model output.)

• Each member saves a specified amount with the SHG. The SHG pays interest on this amount. The members’ saving should desirably be regular, but in practice it is often irregular (not all members may save in a given month or there may be a shortfall in the individual saving quantum). The model incorporates some irregularity in savings (this is not any implied defense of irregularity).

• A loan cycle represents the repayment period of a loan to members made by the SHG. The model accepts loan cycles ranging from 1 to 24 months. The SHG accumulates savings over the first loan cycle and maintains this with the MCI (i.e., no lending is done in the first loan cycle).

• Thereafter, the SHG lends a fraction of the available funds to members over several loan cycles (referred to as the self-cycle phase). The balance is saved with the MCI. The loan to members is repayable in monthly instalments over the loan cycle period. Interest is paid monthly over the loan cycle. A fraction of the loans are delinquent with members taking three months more than the loan cycle to repay. Of these, a fraction will default; defaulting members pay neither interest nor principal.

• At the end of the self-cycle phase, the SHG raises funds from the MCI and lends a fraction of the total available funds (member savings, surplus retained, and borrowing from MCI) to members. The balance is saved with the MCI. The loan from the MCI can be back-to-back (i.e., identical in tenor to the SHG loan to members), or range for periods from 1 to 24 months.

• The SHG incurs an annual operating cost expressed as a fraction of the common fund (member savings plus accumulated operating surplus).

30 | P a g e

Page 31: Microfinance

• The SHG makes annual profits (losses) that add to (reduce) the accumulated surplus.

Financial Model Inputs: MCI

• The MCI starts with a certain capital base. It can raise a multiplier of this capital and accumulated surplus by borrowing from outside.

• The MCI adds SHGs over a period of five years. The number of SHGs stabilizes thereafter.

• The MCI has to maintain a minimum fraction of its borrowing and SHG savings as cash and maintain another minimum fraction in approved investments. The remaining funds are available for lending to the SHGs. A fraction of the loans to SHGs are delinquent and a smaller fraction default.

• The MCI incurs an annual operating cost expressed as a fraction of its borrowings plus SHG savings.

• The MCI makes annual profits (losses) that increase (reduce)the total accumulated surplus.

The MCI capital is not an input item. The model generates annual capital requirements (consistent with the inputs) as an output.

Financial Model: Output

The model produces the following output at SHG and MCI levels:

• Balance sheets for 10 years.

• Income statements for 10 years and an aggregate income statement for the 10-year period.

• Financial analysis.

• Sensitivity analysis.

31 | P a g e

Page 32: Microfinance

In addition, funds flow statements for 10 years and an aggregate funds flow statement for the 10-year period are produced at the SHG level

Model#3

SHG-Bank Linkage Program in India Review of Models

In India, three types of SHG models have emerged:

1. Bank-SHG-Members: The bank itself acts as a self-help group promoting institution (SHPI).

2. Bank-Facilitating Agency-SHG-Members: Facilitating agencies like NGOs, government agencies, or other community-based organizations form groups.

3. Bank-NGO-MFI-SHG-Members: NGOs act both as facilitators and microfinance intermediaries. First they promote groups, nurture them, and train them, and then they approach banks for bulk loans for lending to the SHGs.

The second model, where SHGs were formed and nurtured by the NGOs, was more popular among the bankers. Banks opened saving accounts and then provided credit directly to the SHGs, while NGOs acted as facilitators. This approach has been widely accepted by the practitioners partly because of the large scale participation of state government through development agencies like the District Rural Development Agency (DRDA), District Women Development Agency (DWDA), and some of the centrally sponsored social sector missions, and also because of special initiatives of NABARD. Sixteen percent of the SHGs were credit linked under the third model where NGOs acted as facilitators as well as microfinance intermediaries. Under this model, NGOs formed SHG federations and then facilitated them to assume the role of MFIs. This model is expected to gain wider recognition with smaller banks venturing into large scale financing of SHGs.

Under the first model SHG linkages were facilitated through NABARD’s policy of converting regional rural banks (RRBs) into self-help promoting institutions

32 | P a g e

Page 33: Microfinance

(SHPIs). The SHG-bank linkage program has been operating in India since 1992–93 but has gained momentum only since 1997–98.

Model#4

ICICI Partnership Model

In 2002, an internal analysis by ICICI Bank revealed that despite consistent evidence of viable demand from clients, access to MFIs was constrained due to the organizationbased financing model adopted until then. Owing to the limited number of rural branches, the SHG--Bank Linkage model was not considered a scaleable route for ICICI Bank. The partnership model pioneered by ICICI Bank attempted to address the following key gaps:

To separate the risk of the MFI from the risk inherent in the microfinance portfolio.

To provide a mechanism for banks to incentivize partner MFIs continuously, especially in a scenario where the borrower entered into a contract directly with the bank and the role of the MFI was closer to that of an agent.

To deal with the inability of MFIs to provide risk capital in large amounts, which limits the advances from banks, despite a greater ability of the latter to provide implicit capital.

The model has been conceptualized and executed with the following key characteristics:

Loan contracts directly between bank and borrower. This feature is similar to the SHG--bank linkage model, and means that the loans are not reflected on the balance sheet of the MFI. The MFI continues to service the loans until maturity, however, so the bank relies on the MFI's field operations for collection and supervision. The key difference, then, between this and the financial intermediation model does not lie in the operating methodology (it is in fact identical), but in the manner in which the financing structure has been designed.

33 | P a g e

Page 34: Microfinance

Alignment of incentives with a firstloss guarantees structure. In order to preserve MFI incentives for portfolio quality in the new scenario where its role is closer to that of an agent, the structure requires the MFI to provide a guarantee (typically a `firstloss default guarantee') through which it shares with the bank the risk of the portfolio, up to a certain defined limit. A firstloss default guarantee (FLDG) makes the provider of the guarantee liable to bear losses up to a certain specified limit, say the first 10 or 20 per cent of loss on the portfolio. It is different from partial guarantees, where the guarantor is liable for a fraction of losses, say 50 per cent of all losses on the portfolio. In terms of incentive compatibility, an FLDG forces the guarantor to prevent any losses at all, as it is affected adversely right from the start. The quantum and pricing of the FLDG will reflect the operating capability and maturity of the MFI

Securitization -- paving the way for capital markets access Microfinance assets originated under the partnership model facilitate participation of a wider investor base. This is achieved through the process of securitization. This may involve sale of portfolio by the originating bank to another bank in the initial phases. When the microfinance pools become larger in size, issuance of securities that are backed by microfinance assets become conceivable. Securitization is a process through which homogeneous illiquid financial assets are pooled and repackaged into marketable securities. Securitization involves isolation of specific risks, evaluation of the same, allocating the risks to various participants in the transaction (based on who is best equipped to mitigate the respective risks), mitigating the risks through appropriate credit enhancement structures and pricing the residual risk borne by the originator.

34 | P a g e

Page 35: Microfinance

List of Top Microfinance Companies in India

SKS Microfinance Ltd (SKSMPL)

Name SKS Microfinance Ltd

Headquarter Secunderabad, Andhra Pradesh

Legal Status Pvt. Ltd. Company (NBFC)

Lending Model JLG

Number of Branches 1,413

Loan Outstanding (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)18,227

Borrowers(As on September 30, 2008)

2,590,950

Net Worth (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)2,395

Portfolio Yield (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008)

23.40

OSS (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008) 126.49

Current Portfolio (%)(As on September 30, 2008)

99.14

Debt to Net Worth (Times) 7.37

35 | P a g e

Page 36: Microfinance

(As on September 30, 2008)

Spandana Sphoorty Financial Ltd (SSFL)

Name Spandana Sphoorty Financial Ltd

Headquarter Hyderabad, Andhra Pradesh

Legal Status Public Ltd. Company (NBFC)

Lending Model JLG, Individual

Number of Branches 696

Loan Outstanding (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)11,987

Borrowers(As on September 30, 2008)

1,668,807

Net Worth (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)1,225

Portfolio Yield (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008)

27.43

OSS (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008) 132.02

Current Portfolio (%)(As on September 30, 2008)

98.88

36 | P a g e

Page 37: Microfinance

Debt to Net Worth (Times)(As on September 30, 2008)

7.04

Share Microfin Limited (SML)

Name Share Microfin Limited

Headquarter Hyderabad, Andhra Pradesh

Legal Status Public Ltd. Company (NBFC)

Lending Model JLG, Individual

Number of Branches 666

Loan Outstanding (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)8,568

Borrowers(As on September 30, 2008)

1,231,556

Net Worth (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)1,448

Portfolio Yield (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008)

27.49

OSS (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008) 152.45

37 | P a g e

Page 38: Microfinance

Current Portfolio (%)(As on September 30, 2008)

99.32

Debt to Net Worth (Times)(As on September 30, 2008)

5.03

Asmitha Microfin Ltd (AML)

Name Asmitha Microfin Ltd

Headquarter Hyderabad, Andhra Pradesh

Legal Status Public Ltd. Company (NBFC)

Lending Model JLG

Number of Branches 363

Loan Outstanding (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)4,944

Borrowers(As on September 30, 2008)

694,350

Net Worth (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)475

Portfolio Yield (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008)

17.43

OSS (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008) 121.04

Current Portfolio (%) 99.80

38 | P a g e

Page 39: Microfinance

(As on September 30, 2008)

Debt to Net Worth (Times)(As on September 30, 2008)

9.92

Shri Kshetra Dharmasthala Rural Development Project (SKDRDP)

NameShri Kshetra Dharmasthala Rural Development Project

Headquarter Dharmasthala, Karnataka

Legal Status Trust

Lending Model SHG

Number of Branches 22

Loan Outstanding (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)4,060

Borrowers(As on September 30, 2008)

612,482

Net Worth (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)157

Portfolio Yield (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008)

12.02

39 | P a g e

Page 40: Microfinance

OSS (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008)

100.46

Current Portfolio (%)(As on September 30, 2008)

99.68

Debt to Net Worth (Times)(As on September 30, 2008)

29.81

Bhartiya Samruddhi Finance Limited (BSFL)

Name Bhartiya Samruddhi Finance Limited

Headquarter Hyderabad, Andhra Pradesh

Legal Status Public Ltd. Company, (NBFC)

Lending Model Diversified

Number of Branches 87

Loan Outstanding (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)3,882

Borrowers(As on September 30, 2008)

457,668

Net Worth (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)317

Portfolio Yield (%) 17.89

40 | P a g e

Page 41: Microfinance

(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008)

OSS (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008) 108.97

Current Portfolio (%)(As on September 30, 2008)

99.00

Debt to Net Worth (Times)(As on September 30, 2008)

11.59

Bandhan

Name Bandhan

Headquarter Kolkata, West Bengal

Legal Status Society

Lending Model JLG

Number of Branches 385

Loan Outstanding (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)3,389

Borrowers(As on September 30, 2008)

851,713

Net Worth (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)435

41 | P a g e

Page 42: Microfinance

Portfolio Yield (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008)

26.32

OSS (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008) 175.40

Current Portfolio (%)(As on September 30, 2008)

99.92

Debt to Net Worth (Times)(As on September 30, 2008)

7.07

Cashpor Micro Credit (CMC)

Name Cashpor Micro Credit

Headquarter Varanasi, Uttar Pradesh

Legal Status Section 25 Company

Lending Model JLG

Number of Branches 247

Loan Outstanding (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)1,431

Borrowers(As on September 30, 2008)

303,935

Net Worth (` Mn) 93

42 | P a g e

Page 43: Microfinance

(As on September 30, 2008)

Portfolio Yield (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008)

28.78

OSS (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008) 109.71

Current Portfolio (%)(As on September 30, 2008)

98.00

Debt to Net Worth (Times)(As on September 30, 2008)

14.72

Grama Vidiyal Micro Finance Pvt Ltd (GVMFL)

Name Grama Vidiyal Micro Finance Pvt Ltd

Headquarter Tiruchirappalli, Tamil Nadu

Legal Status Pvt. Ltd. Company (NBFC)

Lending Model JLG

Number of Branches 126

Loan Outstanding (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)1,316

Borrowers(As on September 30, 2008)

288,311

Net Worth (` Mn) 231

43 | P a g e

Page 44: Microfinance

(As on September 30, 2008)

Portfolio Yield (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008)

32.46

OSS (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008) 141.53

Current Portfolio (%)(As on September 30, 2008)

99.54

Debt to Net Worth (Times)(As on September 30, 2008)

4.95

Grameen Financial Services Pvt Ltd (GFSPL)

Name Grameen Financial Services Pvt Ltd

Headquarter Bangalore, Karnataka

Legal Status Pvt. Ltd. Company (NBFC)

Lending Model JLG

Number of Branches 62

Loan Outstanding (` Mn)

(As on September 30, 2008)1,287

Borrowers(As on September 30, 2008)

153,453

Net Worth (` Mn) 127

44 | P a g e

Page 45: Microfinance

(As on September 30, 2008)

Portfolio Yield (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008)

18.77

OSS (%)(Apr 1-Sep 30, 2008) 106.41

Current Portfolio (%)(As on September 30, 2008)

99.98

Debt to Net Worth (Times)(As on September 30, 2008)

10.51

45 | P a g e

Page 46: Microfinance

46 | P a g e

Page 47: Microfinance

Funding needs of the Microfinance Institutions

FROM WHERE FUNDS COME?

There are mainly two sources for meeting the funding requirements of the MFI’s.

External sources:

Promoters’ contribution, equity capital including investment by private equity fund agencies/ venture capitalists etc. The MFI’s get funds through External commercial debts, grants from various national and international organizations, corporate donors, High Networth Individual (HNI) donors, promotional funds from SIDBI and NABARD etc. Apart from the above the retained earnings from operations are also sources of funds.

Internal Sources:

Income from operations and investment income etc. Ultimately the efficiency of an MFI is decided on the basis of its operational efficiency and its ability to generate sufficient income on a self sustainable basis. In the case of some MFI’s income may flow through fee collected from training etc.

Although there are only this few sources that provides money to Microfinance Institutions (MFI’s) the picture on page 33 shows that India has the growth potential of 20-30% in MFI sector which needs `3000 crore and article supporting that was posted on February 2 2011:

Micro Finance Institutions in India Need Rs 3,000 Crore to Continue Business

Mumbai, Feb. 02: The Micro Finance Institutions (MFIs) require Rs 3,000 crore funding to continue with their business operations. This requirement is for MFIs in states other than Andhra Pradesh, as they are facing shortage of funds since banks blocked funding to MFIs after crisis hit the sector in Andhra Pradesh (AP). As for MFIs in AP which account 30% of the total business of MFIs in country, would require restructuring of loans.

47 | P a g e

Page 48: Microfinance

Banks are avoiding extending loans to MFIs as Indian Banks Association (IBA) and the lenders' forum is currently working on the modalities. Banks have stopped disbursal of loans and now onwards will be more cautious in giving out loans. Banks are also awaiting response of Reserve Bank of India (RBI) towards Malegam Panel's recommendation for MFIs. According to IBA functionary if panel’s recommendation of “removal of priority sector lending to loans given to MFIs would not, in our opinion, be advisable” is accepted banks can resume lending to MFIs.

Now due to this situation in the market and the global turmoil being there in the international markets the major investors in the market are the Private Equity investors who want to anchor their funds in some investment.

The MFI sector showed them a positive sign regarding this as it showed growth of around 150% average annually in the Africa, South and East Asia and also some growth signs in South America.

The Image of the MFI growth on page 33 shows the Asia region and Sub-Saharan Africa shows the maximum growth in the upcoming years due to development of this sectors lending as this regions are poorly developed regions which has a very less access to banks so this institutions thrive in this regions which gives various loans to poor’s without guarantees.

The microfinance shows a well growth but recently the nations are in a spree to regulate this large unregulated sector which is the major thing which the countries financial regulators have come to know.

The Microfinance industry in India is growing at a rate of 100% and its annual CAGR rate is 44% which indicates a good growth among the sector.

48 | P a g e

Page 49: Microfinance

But the Question is the industry is growing also beneficial to the poor’s in it?

How do MFIs’ manage the funds needed to sustain growth?

This are a contradictory questions asked as growing also helps to cater larger number of poor’s across many villages but then the companies sort to many ways of increasing the profits as they cover a larger area in this segment and also succeeding the way in helping the needing

As stated in the above article the microfinance industry faces the lack of funds as they give funds to poor who have a poor capacity to repay and also the returns on investment is very slow as this are customized loans, so measuring the returns on different loans is also a difficult job.

The microfinance institutions have to take the loans from banks and due to less penetration of banks in India the rural people cannot directly access it, the MFIs’ take loans from banks and thus lend to poor so it increases their cost of borrowing.

MFIs’ should allow to gather public deposits so that it will decrease their borrowing cost and thus the benefit of less cost will be passed on to the loan takers’ in the form of less interest and so they can manage the funds easily and lend the poor accordingly.

In India the MFIs’ are not allowed to raise deposits so this creates a pressure on them to rely on their own savings and the loans from banks which proves to be costly and ineffectively in the applicable to rural areas.

Many MFI models failed due to the reason funding which is the most important in this segment of economy. This is where the Private Equity(PE) players, High Networth Individuals(HNI) and Microventure play a major role they play a very important role of funding them as they are the anchor investors who want to invest the funds available over a long term and has a research team to research on the investment and keep track of the investment.

As this investment provides them an annual return of more than 50% they are ready to invest in this. The sector is lucrative but, it comes with a lot of risk as

49 | P a g e

Page 50: Microfinance

these funds are allocated among those poor who borrow for certain purpose but can any time default on the payments. Today in this dynamic macroeconomic environment the MFIs’ have also became very cautious in giving the money they give money but they securities it with the good borrowed from it or they keep a guarantee on that loan which has an impact on poor class.

The PE players want an investment which has a long investment period with a good exit opportunity which is usually an IPO or sell of Stake to other players.

HNIs’ do invest in this because they are individuals having available funds which can be applied to some investment which is a profitable venture and has a potential to grow which will bear future fruits to it.

50 | P a g e

Page 51: Microfinance

What Investors Look While Investing in MFI?

1. Business Model

2. Number of clients

3. Frequency of taking loans

4. Cash Cycle

5. Debt on Books

6. Return on Investment

7. Concentration region

8. Past records

9. Its Operational Modes

10.Its funding needs

11.Its cost management

51 | P a g e

Page 52: Microfinance

12.Borrowing capacity

13.Is it a NBFC

The last point i.e. the microfinance is NBFC or not because an NBFC can also provide many other services such as insurance, loan on different items etc.

52 | P a g e

Page 53: Microfinance

Funding to MFI’s worldwide by PE’s, VC’s and HNI’s

Blue Orchard , a commercial microfinance investment intermediary based in Switzerland, has, through its Private Equity fund, invested Rs 500 million (the equivalent of over USD 10.2 million) in the equity of Asmitha Microfin Limited , a Microfinance Institution (MFI) based in Hyderabad, India. This was announced in a press release available on the Asmitha website. Microcapital covered the relationship between these two organizations in October of 2008 when BlueOrchard made an initial equity investment in Asmitha of USD 5.3 million intended to “expand [the MFI's] capital base and bolster its borrowing capacity” . According to Dr. Vidya Sravanthi, Chairperson and Managing Director of Asmitha, the MFI hopes to use the newest investment to “[expand] its operations deeper into the Indian rural markets and offering its services to many more of the under-served poor in these regions” as well as move toward “growth targets” set by Blue Orchard .

Asmitha was founded in 2002 in an effort to give “rural poor women access to financial resources in the form of collateral free small loans” . In fact, the Mix Market, the microfinance information clearinghouse, shows that 100 percent of Asmitha’s loans are provided for women . Now, according to Dr. Sravanthi, Asmitha has one of the top-five biggest loan portfolios of any MFI in India at USD 165 million (as of July 31, 2009), and “serves over 1.16 million clients” . It was also ranked 29th in a Forbes list of the top 50 MFIs in 2007, a list that was highlighted by MicroCapital in January 2008 . According to the Mix Market, as of March 31, 2009, Asmitha has a 5.33 percent return on assets, a 55.52 percent return on equity, a capital/asset ratio of 10 percent, and a gross loan portfolio to total assets ratio of 61.37 percent .

BlueOrchard’s Private Equity fund was launched at the end of 2007 in an effort to “[forge] long-term partnerships with MFIs worldwide” . Though the parent company is Swiss, the Private Equity fund is registered in Luxemburg, and is managed through BlueOrchard Investments, a subsidiary of BlueOrchard set up to “[invest] in the equity of microfinance institutions and microfinance network funds (family of MFIs)” . According to BlueOrchard’s annual report, the fund has

53 | P a g e

Page 54: Microfinance

raised USD 131.1 million in total assets after just one year of existence, as of December 31, 2008 . These assets have been defined as “committed capital,” or funds to be invested in MFIs and/or network funds .

BlueOrchard also has various other assets under management. These funds were highlighted by Microcapital in June of 2009 in an interview with Jean-Pierre Klumpp, the Chief Executive Officer of BlueOrchard. The largest fund in terms of assets under management is the Dexia Micro-Credit Fund . Founded in 1998 by the Dexia Banque Internationale à Luxembourg , the fund is “the first commercial investment fund designed to refinance microfinance institutions specialised in financial services to small companies in emerging markets” . It is managed by BlueOrchard’s other subsidiary, BlueOrchard Finance, who specialize in providing loans to MFIs. According to Mr. Klumpp, the Dexia Micro-Credit Fund has USD 477 million assets under management as of May 2009, extends to almost 100 MFIs in 30 countries, and reaches over 400,000 clients .

BlueOrchard Finance, along with Edmond de Rothschild Asset Management, “an investment banking subsidiary of LCF Rothschild Group,” also manages The Saint-Honoré Microfinance Fund, which invests in “local and regional investment funds, MFI network funds, cooperatives, etc,” and has assets under management of over USD 14.3 million as of May 2009 .

Additionally, BlueOrchard is an advisor to the portfolio of BBVA Codespa Microfinance Fund , a regional fund in Latin America with assets under management of over USD 40 million as of May 2009 [11]. Microcapital [16] covered the launch of this “microfinance hedge fund”.

There are also three collateralized debt obligations (CDOs), funds backed by securities, that BlueOrchard Finance uses to finance MFIs. These CDOs are BlueOrchard Microfinance Securities , which [offers] US private and institutional investors [an] … opportunity to acquire notes collateralised by MFI debt obligations,” BlueOrchard Loans for Development, which works with Morgan Stanley to “[offer] 5-year funding at fixed rates to 21 fast growing MFIs in 13 countries,” and BlueOrchard Loans For Development , which was the first “significant CDO” to have a joint launch with a major investment bank (Morgan

54 | P a g e

Page 55: Microfinance

Stanley) in order to fund microfinance. As of December 31, 2008, these CDOs have a combined portfolio value of USD 277.4, according to Blue News [, a “social performance report” by BlueOrchard.

Microcapital covered these varied funds in a June 2009 article about a USD 28 million disbursement made by BlueOrchard. Additionally, this article covered the Microfinance Enhancement Facility (MEF) , a facility co-managed by BlueOrchard, ResponsAbility Social Investments , who “combine traditional financial investments with social returns, and Cyrano Management , “a corporation specialized in financial institutions and investment funds that service small businesses”. The facility was started by the International Finance Corporation (IFC) , the investment and advice portion of the World Bank working in the private sector, and KfW Entwicklungsbank , a development bank that has the goals of “reducing poverty, making globalisation fair, conserving natural resources and ensuring peace”. The MEF has undertaken the task of helping MFIs refinance amidst the financial crisis, and had “new investments [totaling] $16.2 billion in fiscal 2008,” according to a press release .

BlueOrchard, as a complete entity, is not listed on the MIX Market. However, from BlueOrchard’s annual review, it is shown that the company’s “partner MFIs” experienced an average asset growth of 45 percent in 2008 and that BlueOrchard funds “reached more than 9 million micro-entrepreneurs, a majority of them women . Additionally, Blue News shows that, as of January 2009, BlueOrchard has “nearly USD 870 million [assets] under management” with returns on these “investment products between 4 and 10 percent – depending on each microfinance investment vehicles’ strategy”

Serial investor Kalpathi Suresh--the founder of SSI Ltd who sold 51% stake in the IT training firm to PVP Global for $140 million in 2007—is no stranger to scripting big-ticket exits.

This time, aided by a raging investor appetite for well-managed microfinance assets, he netted over 12x returns in just about two years by selling his stake in Chennai-based Equitas Micro Finance to Sequoia Capital.

55 | P a g e

Page 56: Microfinance

Last Saturday, the Equitas board ratified the sale of 10% stake held by Kalpathi Investments, an investment arm of Kalpathi Suresh, to Sequoia in a secondary transaction valued at Rs 44 crore. Suresh had invested Rs 3.5 crore in Equitas during 2007-08, without any management rights or board seat. Sequoia appears to have agreed to a deal without significantly altering the contours of the original investment.

This will be Sequoia's third investment in India's microfinance industry in less than three years. In March 2007, it invested $11.5 million in the country's largest microfinance player, SKS Microfinance, opening up a new deal pipeline for the private equity funds who have poured in over $220 million into the sector since then. Sequoia also invested in Ujjivan, a Bangalore-based MFI in late 2008.

Mape Advisory Group arranged the sale for Kalpathi Investments. The RBI approval for the transaction came in December last week after Sequoia struck an initial agreement to purchase the stake in October 2009. Incidentally, Equitas has also hit the market for a fresh fund raise, and the latest secondary transaction could provide the valuation benchmark for the same.

"The deal was signed within three months of initiation and generated strong investor interest despite being a secondary share sale. The very successful exit by a minority investor continues to demonstrate investor interest in well-operated MFIs," says Akshay Dixit, Vice President, Mape Advisory Group. Kalpathi will retain a token number of shares, under 0.5% stake, in Equitas.

Equitas commenced operations in December 2007, and has since grown to 98 branches. The company has cumulatively disbursed Rs 600 crore until September 2009.

Equitas had over 575,000 borrowers and a portfolio outstanding (based on assets under management) of Rs 430 crore in the half year-ended September of the current fiscal. It reported PAT of Rs 10.4 crore on an income of Rs 51 crore during the same six-month period. The company had reported a profit after tax of Rs 2.2 crore on a total income of Rs 34.9 crore for fiscal ended March 2009.

56 | P a g e

Page 57: Microfinance

MFIs continue to hit the market for fresh fund raising as they expand their asset books tapping into a huge market potential. A number of micro finance firms are turning to PEs for fresh equity to grow scale in the business. Several MFIs, initially registered as non-profit firms, have turned into for-profit finance firms for accessing wider funds, with private equity emerging as an attractive channel.

2010 could be significant for this space as SKS is expected to go in for an initial public offering (IPO), testing the interest levels of the capital market and opening up an exit route for PE investors.

Sandstone Capital, Silicon Valley Bank, Columbia Pacific, Kismet Capital, Sequoia Capital, and Legatum have invested in Indian MFIs, though it should be noted that the vast majority of these funds invested in a single MFI – SKS Microfinance. In addition to SKS, Ujjivan and Share Microfin also received investments from the funds mentioned above, and in 2007 Spandana received Rs 40 crore (USD$10 mill.) from the JM Financial India Fund. Moreover, other major private equity funds such as Blackstone and Reliance Capital have actively researched and considered investing in Indian MFIs.

57 | P a g e

Page 58: Microfinance

Securitisation

In microfinance, securitisation of microloans refers to a transaction in which the repayments from a set of microloans from one or more MFIs are packaged into a special purpose vehicle, from which tradable securities are issued.11 For the MFI, there is little practical difference between securitizing a portion of its loan portfolio and selling it off directly to a bank via a portfolio buyout. In both cases, the MFI retains a first loss default guarantee and is obligated to continue to collect repayments on the sold off loans. Similarly, with both securitisations and portfolio buyouts, MFIs can only sell off as much of their portfolio as they have financed through accumulated earnings and equity. The main difference is that securitisations require a rating, while a portfolio buyout does not, and that the ability to re-sell securitised microloans may attract more potential buyers. Proponents of securitisation argue that it holds great potential for decreasing cost of funds to MFIs by allowing for more complex structuring of the underlying product; by providing easier secondary sales of the assets; and by reaching out to new types of potential investors. With portfolio buyouts, there is only one buyer and one seller in each transaction. With securitisation, it is possible (though it has not happened to date), to pool together loans from different MFIs to diversify risk. It is also possible to slice the securitised portfolio up into different tranches with different levels of seniority to cater to the different risk appetites of investors. Further, the standardised nature of the product means it is easier for the original purchases of the security to resell the asset. Lastly, through securitisation, MFIs may be able to tap new sources of investment funds. Certain types of large investors, especially mutual funds, are barred from directly investing or lending to MFIs but not from investing in the securitised microfinance loan, assets.

To date, to the authors’ knowledge, there has been only one true securitisation of microloans in the world. In March 2009, microfinance lender Equitas, in collaboration with IFMR Capital, completed a securitisation of a portion of Equitas’ microloan portfolio worth Rs. 157 million. A key element of the deal was that the securities were divided into two tranches. A senior tranche comprised

58 | P a g e

Page 59: Microfinance

80% of the portfolio and was sold to institutional investors, while a junior tranche consisting of the remaining 20% was sold to IFMR Capital. This arrangement effectively means that IFMR Capital holds the second loss default guarantee for the loans.

Several leading commercial MFIs have return on assets (RoA) in the range of 5 to 8 per cent, far above the banking system anywhere in the world. In contrast, State Bank of India, country’s largest bank, had a RoA of 1.04 per cent in 2008-09 while ICICI Bank had a RoA of 1.13 per cent in 2009-10.

Since 2005, the credit growth of MFI industry has been much higher than the commercial banking system in India. Although bank loans remain the largest funding source for commercial MFIs, several players have been able to raise funds from other sources including private equity funds, hedge funds and angel investors. Since 2007, private equity funds alone have invested close to Rs 20000 million in MFIs. In 2009, there were 11 PE deals worth $178 million involving commercial MFIs. Some MFIs have also raised money through non-convertible debentures and securitization. Of late, commercial MFIs have also emerged as an asset class for institutional investors.

In their quest to grow fast and to serve the insatiable appetite of private equity investors, MFIs pushed inappropriate loans to poor borrowers without looking at the repayment ability of borrowers. The practice of multiple lending, ever-greening of loans and loan recycling (which ultimately increases the debt liability of poor borrower) became widespread. In some ways, lending practices by such commercial MFIs were akin to sub-prime lending in the US. As the defaults became imminent due to high interest rates, MFIs resorted to strong-arm tactics that have led rural poor to commit suicides.

59 | P a g e

Page 60: Microfinance

Major deals in Microfinance India are as follows:

2008 Deals

1. Ujjivan Financial Services received a funding from the below investors of US$18.47 million Bellwether Microfinance Fund, Michael and Susan Dell Foundation, AW Holding Pvt. Ltd., Sequoia Capital India, Lok Capital Group, India Financial Inclusion Fund , Unitus Equity Fund II in 2008.

2. Arohan Financial Services received US$ 1.5 Million Lok Capital Group, Michael and Susan Dell Foundation in 2008.

3. SKS Microfinance received US$ 37 million Sequoia Capital India, Odyssey Capital Llc, SVB India Capital Partners Fund, and Columbia Capital Llc in 2008.

4. A Little World received US$6.5 million from Legatum Capital, Bellwether Microfinance Fund, and India Financial Inclusion Fund in 2008.

5. Equitas Micro Finance India received a US$11.44 million Bellwether Microfinance Fund, India Financial Inclusion Fund, and MVA Ventures.

6. Grameen Financial Services received US$2.3 million from Aavishkaar India Micro Venture Capital Fund, Aavishkaar Goodwell India Microfinance Development Co. Ltd.

7. Jagannatha Financial Service received US$0.79 million from Lok Capital Group.

8. Madura Micro Finance received US$4.52 million from Unitus Equity Fund9. MAS Financial Services received US$10 million from India Advantage Fund

VII (Mezzanine Fund-I)10.Moksha-Yug Access India received US$2 million from Unitus Equity Fund11.Satin Creditcare Network received US$1.25 million from Lok Capital Group12.SKS Microfinance received US$75 million from Sandstone Capital, Kismet,

and SVB

60 | P a g e

Page 61: Microfinance

2009 Deals

1. ESAF Microfinance and Investments received US$2.6 million from Dia Vikas Capital

2. Bhartiya Samruddhi Investments and ConsultingServices received US$ 10 million from Lok Capital Group, Aavishkaar Goodwell India Microfinance Development Co. Ltd., SIDBI Venture Capital Ltd.

3. Navachetna Microfin Services received US$0.38 million from HNIs4. Suryoday Microfinance received US$1.5 million from Aavishkaar Goodwell5. Grama Vidiyal Microfinance received US$4.25 million from MicroVest,

Unitus Equity, Vinod Khosla.6. India Financial Inclusion Fund received US$20 million from CDC Group

2010 & 2011 Deals

1. Intellecap announced this week that it had successfully closed the largest private equity deal in the Indian Microfinance space in 2011, by raising INR 135 crore from International Finance Corporation (IFC) for MFI Bandhan Financial Services Pvt Ltd. The deal marks the single-largest exposure by the World Bank arm to India’s microfinance sector. Significantly, the Bandhan MFI deal follows on the heels of the INR 65 crore third-round funding of Bangalore-based microfinance institution Janalakshmi Financial Services.

2. Swiss company ResponsAbility Social Investments AG (responsAbility) recently reported to MicroCapital that it has made loans to Latin American microfinance institutions (MFIs) Banco Solidario of Ecuador and Interactuar of Colombia. Banco Solidario received a total of USD 2.25 million disbursed through two microfinance investment vehicles (MIVs) managed by ResponsAbility: USD 2 million through the ResponsAbility Global Microfinance Fund (RGMF) and the remaining USD 500,000 through

61 | P a g e

Page 62: Microfinance

responsAbility Mikrofinanz-Fonds (RGMF). Interactuar received the local-currency equivalent of approximately USD 2 million, half of which was disbursed through RGMF and the other half through RGMF.

3. Even though microfinance in India is in turmoil, the private capital is still flowing into the sector. Svasti Microfinance Pvt Ltd, a Mumbai-based microfinance company, has raised its second round of funding of Rs 4.5 crore from Switzerland-based BlueOrchard Private Equity Fund. The investment has been made by a Mauritius based arm of BlueOrchard. The funds will be used by Svasti to expand its branch operations and to develop innovative loan products to service the entrepreneurial low income population in Mumbai, a statement said.Grameen Capital India acted as exclusive advisor to Svasti on this transaction.

4. Bengaluru, 5th January 2011: Bangalore-headquartered Ujjivan Financial Services, a leading microfinance institution with pan-India presence, has raised INR 40 Crores of debt capital through issuance of listed, secured, redeemable, non-convertible debentures (NCDs) to DWM (Cyprus) Limited , a member of the Developing World Markets (DWM) group of companies. Unitus Capital is the exclusive financial advisor and sole arranger of the issue. The NCDs are listed on the Bombay Stock Exchange and have been fully subscribed

5. Microfinance Focus, Aug 4, 2010: World Bank’s International Finance Corporation (IFC) may invest in India’s Ananya Finance For Inclusive Growth Pvt. Ltd. Ananya is expected to raise approx. INR 1.50 billion (approximately $ 32.60 m) in equity to strengthen its capital adequacy and on lend larger amount in the new entity. IFC’s proposed investment in Ananya consists of an equity investment of upto INR 500 million ($ 10 million) up to 20% stake in the company.

62 | P a g e

Page 63: Microfinance

Ananya Finance For Inclusive Growth Pvt. LTD. (Ananya or the Company) is the newly set up Non Banking Finance Company (NBFC), to scale-up microfinance in India by providing financial and non financial services toMicrofinance Institutions (MFIs). Ananya (formerly FWWB), provides an effective channel to reach out the large number of underserved and poor microfinance clients as it works aross 17 states in India with more than 122 Partner Oganizations, who have an outreach of more than 14 million.

6. Microfinance Focus, June 02, 2010: Fusion Microfinance, a Delhi based start-up NBFC-Microfinance today announced equity funding of Rs 4.5 crores (approx USD 952,276) from Incofin, a Belgian microfinance investment company. Incofin which has recently raised a new fund of Euro 100 million called Rural Impulse Fund 2, has been very active in India with three investments in last two years having social impact across the country in more than eight states.Fusion was founded and promoted by Devesh Sachdev, Ashish Tewari and Ankur Singhal . The company started its Greenfield operations in January 2010 and further augmented it by a unique acquisition of the microfinance division of Aajeevika (a not for profit body operating in Delhi). As on date, Fusion has a base of 2,600 clients in 3 states across of 4 branches with a loan book of Rs 22.6 million. Fusion is a NBFC registered with Reserve Bank of India and is operational in the less penetrated North Central part of India (Uttar Pradesh, Uttranchal, Delhi and Madhya Pradesh). In the next five years, the company plans to serve over 500,000 borrowers predominantly living in the rural areas.

With this deals into the pipelines the MFI’s will benefit a lot due to a good funded and structured loans which will help them reach new areas.

63 | P a g e

Page 64: Microfinance

Recommendations for Growth

1. Proper Regulation: The regulation was not a major concern when the microfinance was in its nascent stage and individual institutions were free to bring in innovative operational models. However, as the sector completes almost two decades of age with a high growth trajectory, an enabling regulatory environment that protects interest of stakeholders as well as promotes growth, is needed.

2. Field Supervision: In addition to proper regulation of the microfinance sector, field visits can be adopted as a medium for monitoring the conditions on ground and initiating corrective action if needed. This will keep a check on the performance of ground staff of various MFIs and their recovery practices. This will also encourage MFIs to abide by proper code of conduct and work more efficiently. However, the problem of feasibility and cost involved in physical monitoring of this vast sector remains an issue in this regard.

3. Encourage rural penetration: It has been seen that in lieu of reducing the initial cost, MFIs are opening their branches in places which already have a few MFIs operating. Encouraging MFIs for opening new branches in areas of low microfinance penetration by providing financial assistance will increase the outreach of the microfinance in the state and check multiple lending. This will also increase rural penetration of microfinance in the state.

4. Complete range of Products: MFIs should provide complete range of products including credit, savings, remittance, financial advice and also non-financial services like training and support. As MFIs are acting as a substitute to banks in areas where people don’t have access to banks, providing a complete range of products will enable the poor to avail all services.

5. Transparency of Interest rates: As it has been observed that, MFIs are employing different patterns of charging interest rates and a few are also charging additional charges and interest free deposits (a part of the loan amount is kept as deposit on which no interest is paid). All this make the pricing very confusing and hence the borrower feels incompetent in terms of bargaining power. So a common practice for charging interest should be followed by all MFIs so that it

64 | P a g e

Page 65: Microfinance

makes the sector more competitive and the beneficiary gets the freedom to compare different financial products before buying.

6. Technology to reduce Operating Cost: MFIs should use new technologies and IT tools & applications to reduce their operating costs. Though most NBFCs are adopting such cost cutting measures, which is clearly evident from the low cost per unit money lent (9%-10%) of such institutions. NGOs and Section 25 companies are having a very high value of cost per unit money lent i.e. 15-35 percent and hence such institutions should be encouraged to adopt cost-cutting measures to reduce their operating costs. Also initiatives like development of common MIS and other software for all MFIs can be taken to make the operation more transparent and efficient.

7. Alternative sources of Fund: In absence of adequate funds the growth and the reach of MFIs become restricted and to overcome this problem MFIs should look for other sources for funding their loan portfolio. Some of the ways through which MFIs can raise their fund are:

By getting converted to for-profit company i.e. NBFC: Without investment by outside investors, MFIs are limited to what they can borrow to a multiple of total profits and equity investment. To increase their borrowings further, MFIs need to raise their Equity through outside investors. The first and the most crucial step to receive equity investment are getting converted to for-profit NBFC. Along with the change in status the MFI should also develop strong board, a quality management information system (MIS) and obtain a credit rating to attract potential investors.

Portfolio Buyout: It is when banks or other institutions purchase the rights to future payment stream from a set of outstanding loans granted by MFIs. In such transactions MFIs are responsible for making up any loss in repayment up to a certain percentage of the portfolio and this clause is known as “first loss default guarantee”. The above clause ensures that the MFI retains the correct incentive to collect these loans. To ensure security to the buying institution, MFIs are allowed to sell off as much of the outstanding portfolio as is financed by accumulated earnings or equity.

65 | P a g e

Page 66: Microfinance

Securitization of Loans: This refers to a transaction in which the repayments from a set of microloans from one or more MFIs are packaged into a special purpose vehicle, from which tradable securities are issued. As the loans from multiple MFIs can be pooled together the risk gets diversified. Though securitization of loans and portfolio buyout are similar in many ways like first loss default guarantee clause, limit to the amount of loans that can be sold off etc. The major difference between the two is that securitizations require a rating from a credit rating agency and that it can be re-sold, which makes securitized loans attract more potential buyers. Also unlike portfolio buyout, there can be multiple buyers and sellers for each transaction in case of securitization of loans as compared to single buyer and single seller in portfolio buyout. Through securitization, MFIs can tap new sources of investments because fund of certain types like mutual funds, which are barred from directly investing in MFIs, can invest through securitized loans.

66 | P a g e

Page 67: Microfinance

Conclusion

From the above research and the data available it is seen that the Private Equities are very active in the microfinance sector which gives them the most returns and also fulfills their long gestation investment needs. The investors look for a high return prospect n also want an easy exit route from the investment so MFI serves the both it gives return as high as 200% and also an exit in 3 to 4 years.

So overall the MFI serves all the needs of Private Equity so it has got a boom from the private equity investors, Overall the markets seem to be booming from the 2005 till 2009 but in the starting of 2010 the private equity’s started exit route as the sector in India showed a sign of downfall from the Andhra Pradesh suicides by farmers. The markets seem very favorable to them in the early times of the development but now the sector is looming with crisis as the funding needs of the sector is increasing due to a change in their monthly installments cycle this sector fairly needs a good amount of money which will boost India’s economy in many ways. As major portion of India lives in Rural India the need to boost the rural areas is must and their development is ultimately nation’s development.

67 | P a g e

Page 68: Microfinance

Webliography

Vccircle.com

Management paradise.com

Microfinanceindia.com

RBI.org

References

KPMG report

Business Standard

Times of India

ResponseAbility Social Investments AG Report

NABARD Report

68 | P a g e


Recommended