+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Murat Besnek - La Trobe Universityarrow.latrobe.edu.au › store › 3 › 5 › 0 › 5 › 4 ›...

Murat Besnek - La Trobe Universityarrow.latrobe.edu.au › store › 3 › 5 › 0 › 5 › 4 ›...

Date post: 07-Jul-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 2 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
169
Petroleum Retailing, Station Level Demand and the Retail Price Cycles Submitted by Murat Besnek B.Ec (Hons1) La Trobe University 2005 A thesis submitted in total fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy (Economics) At School of Economics Faculty of Law and Management La Trobe University Bundoora, Victoria 3086 Australia November 2012
Transcript

Petroleum Retailing, Station Level Demand and the Retail Price Cycles

Submitted by

Murat Besnek B.Ec (Hons1) La Trobe University 2005

A thesis submitted in total fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of

Doctor of Philosophy

(Economics)

At

School of Economics Faculty of Law and Management

La Trobe University

Bundoora, Victoria 3086 Australia

November 2012

ii

Dedicated to my father, Fuat, and my mentor, Said Nursi.

iii

Contents

List of Tables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . viii

List of Figures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . x

Abstract . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xii

Acknowledgments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xiv

1. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1

2. Retailing of Petrol, Diesel and LPG in Australia . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

2.2 Dataset and Service Stations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

2.2.1 Dataset . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7

2.2.2 Pricing strategy of the owner of the service stations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9

2.2.3 Service stations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11

2.3 Australian Petroleum Industry . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

2.3.1 Refining . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 16

2.3.2 Distributing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

2.3.3 Retailing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21

2.4 Consumer and Service Station Decision Making . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23

2.5 Retailing of Petrol . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26

iv

2.5.1 Price cycles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26

2.5.2 Service stations that choose not to follow the price cycles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

2.5.3 Decreases in profits . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29

2.5.4 Limited variation in the sales of service stations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31

2.5.5 Price increases . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32

2.5.6 Signalling . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

2.5.7 Price increases that are not the start of a price cycle . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36

2.5.8 Recurring cycle lengths . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38

2.5.9 Cycle amplitudes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40

2.5.10 Price decreases . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42

2.5.11 Weekly Quantity Cycle . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43

2.6 Retailing of Diesel . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45

2.6.1 Prior information . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 45

2.6.2 Profits from the diesel market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 46

2.6.3 Price matching and the absence of price cycles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47

2.6.4 Price increases and price decreases . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50

2.6.5 Unpredictability of the day in which price increases occur . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51

2.7 Retailing of LPG . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52

2.7.1 Prior information . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52

v

2.7.2 Price cycles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53

2.7.3 Discontinuation of the price cycles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55

2.7.4 Price increases and price decreases . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59

2.8 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 60

3. Station Level Demand for Diesel and LPG in Metropolitan Melbourne. . . . . . . . 65

3.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65

3.2 Dataset . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66

3.2.1 Dataset . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66

3.2.2 Dates and noteworthy shocks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68

3.2.3 Descriptive statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68

3.3 Service Stations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71

3.4 Demand Functions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76

3.4.1 Demand functions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 76

3.4.2 Specifications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77

3.4.3 Caveat . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79

3.5 Diagnostic Tests and Omitted Variables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81

3.5.1 Diagnostic tests . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 81

3.5.2 Omitted variables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82

3.6 Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83

vi

3.6.1 Demand estimates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83

3.6.2 Price elasticities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 88

3.6.3 Summary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90

3.7 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 92

Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94

4. Competition or Price Discrimination? The Price Cycles in Petrol Retailing . . . . . 98

4.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98

4.2 Edgeworth Cycles Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 101

4.2.1 Edgeworth cycles model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 102

4.2.2 Predictions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103

4.3 Price Discrimination Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104

4.3.1 Price discrimination model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105

4.3.2 Extension . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106

4.3.3 Predictions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108

4.4 Differences in the Two Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109

4.4.1 Differences in the Predictions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109

4.4.2 Structural difference . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 112

4.6 Dataset and Service Stations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116

4.6.1 Dataset . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 116

vii

4.6.2 Dates and noteworthy shocks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117

4.6.3 Descriptive statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118

4.6.4 Service stations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119

4.7 Distance from Closest Competitor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 124

4.8 Demand Function for Petrol . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126

4.8.1 Demand function . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 126

4.8.2 Specification . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 127

4.8.3 Caveat . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 129

4.9 Diagnostic Tests and Omitted Variables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131

4.9.1 Diagnostic tests . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131

4.9.2 Omitted variables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132

4.10 Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132

4.10.1 Demand estimates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132

4.10.2 Price elasticities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 135

4.10.4 Comparison with Wang’s (2009a) estimates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 137

4.11 Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 138

Appendixes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 142

5. Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152

viii

List of Tables

Table 2.2.1 Sales of Petrol between 3pm on Friday and 3pm on Monday . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 29

Table 2.2.2 Weekly Sales of Petrol between 30/01/2006 and 17/06/2006 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32

Table 2.2.3 Average Cycle Amplitudes Arranged by Date . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41

Table 2.2.4 Average Cycle Amplitudes Arranged by Cycle Lengths . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41

Table 2.2.5 Number of Price Increases and Price Decreases for Petrol . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 43

Table 2.3.1 Number of Price Increases and Price Decreases for Diesel . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50

Table 2.3.2 Average Value of Price Increases and Price Decreases for Diesel . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51

Table 2.4.1 Number of Price Increases and Price Decreases for LPG . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57

Table 2.4.2 Average Value of Price Increases and Price Decreases for LPG . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58

Table 3.1.1 Descriptive Statistics for Diesel . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69

Table 3.1.2 Descriptive Statistics for LPG . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70

Table 3.3.1 Results for Diesel (Log-Log) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 84

Table 3.3.2 Results for LPG between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 (Log-Log) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85

Table 3.3.3 Results for LPG between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006 (Log-Log) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 86

Table 3.3.4 Price elasticities of Diesel . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89

Table 3.3.5 Price elasticities of LPG between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89

Table 3.3.6 Price elasticities of LPG between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 89

Table 3.4.1 Results for Diesel (Reciprocal) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 94

ix

Table 3.4.2 Results for Diesel (Linear) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95

Table 3.4.3 Results for LPG between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 (Reciprocal) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96

Table 3.4.4 Results for LPG between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 (Linear) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97

Table 4.1.1 Predictions of the Edgeworth Cycles Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104

Table 4.1.2 Propositions from Conlisk et al. (1984) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106

Table 4.1.3 Propositions from Sobel (1984) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108

Table 4.1.4 Theoretical Predictions of the Price Discrimination Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 108

Table 4.1.5 Differences in the Predictions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109

Table 4.2.1 Descriptive Statistics for Petrol . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 118

Table 4.2.2 Distance from Closest Competitor . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 125

Table 4.2.3 Results for Petrol between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 (Log-Log) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 133

Table 4.2.4 Results for Petrol between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006 (Log-Log) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134

Table 4.2.5 Price elasticities of Petrol between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 136

Table 4.2.6 Price elasticities of Petrol between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 136

Table 4.3.1 Results for Petrol between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006 (Linear) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150

Table 4.3.2 Results for Petrol between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006 (Reciprocal) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 151

x

List of Figures

Figure 2.1.1 Market Structure of Service Station (A) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 12

Figure 2.1.2 Market Structure of Service Station (B) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13

Figure 2.1.3 Market Structure of Service Station (C) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14

Figure 2.1.4 Market Structure of Service Station (D) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

Figure 2.2.1 Retail Prices of Petrol in December 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

Figure 2.2.2 Retail Prices of Petrol in December 2005 (Multiple) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27

Figure 2.2.3 Retail Prices of Petrol in August 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28

Figure 2.2.4 Coefficient of Variation of Price Increases . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33

Figure 2.2.5 Price Increases for Petrol between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

Figure 2.2.6 Price Increases for Petrol between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

Figure 2.2.7 Retail Prices of Petrol in August 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37

Figure 2.2.8 Retail Prices of Petrol in November 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38

Figure 2.2.9 Lengths of the Price Cycles for Petrol . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 39

Figure 2.2.10 Weekly Quantity Cycle between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44

Figure 2.2.11 Weekly Quantity Cycle between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44

Figure 2.3.1 Retail Prices of Diesel in January 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 47

Figure 2.3.2 Retail Prices of Diesel in September 2004 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49

Figure 2.3.3 Retail Prices of Diesel in May 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49

xi

Figure 2.3.4 Price Increases for Diesel . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52

Figure 2.4.1 Retail Prices of LPG in November 2004 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54

Figure 2.4.2 Retail Prices of LPG in February 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 54

Figure 2.4.3 Price Increases for LPG during the Cycling Phase . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55

Figure 2.4.4 Retail Prices of LPG in December 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56

Figure 2.4.5 Retail Prices of LPG in November 2005 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 57

Figure 2.4.6 Price Increases for LPG with Cost Based Pricing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58

Figure 3.2.1 Market Structure of Service Station (A) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72

Figure 3.2.2 Market Structure of Service Station (B) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73

Figure 3.2.3 Market Structure of Service Station (C) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 74

Figure 3.2.4 Market Structure of Service Station (D) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75

Figure 4.1.1 Local Market with One Service Station . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114

Figure 4.1.2 Local Market with Multiple Service Stations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115

Figure 4.2.1 Market Structure of Service Station (A) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 120

Figure 4.2.2 Market Structure of Service Station (B) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121

Figure 4.2.3 Market Structure of Service Station (C) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 122

Figure 4.2.4 Market Structure of Service Station (D) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 123

xii

Petroleum Retailing, Station Level Demand and the Retail Price Cycles

By

Murat Besnek

Submitted to the Faculty of Law and Management on 31st of November, 2012, in total fulfilment of the

requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

Abstract

In this dissertation, we present three papers that directly or indirectly deal with the question of why

retail prices of petrol cycle.

In the first paper, we explain how petrol, diesel and LPG are retailed in Australia. Using (1) our

experience as a service station operator and worker for more than three years in five sites; (2)

meetings with an owner of a company that manages more than thirty service stations; (3) interviews

from four service station operators; and (4) micro-level price and quantity data, we analyse when

service stations change their prices and how this affects their sales. Furthermore, we examine if

retail prices of petrol, diesel or LPG cycle. We estimate cycle lengths and amplitudes, and identify

when service stations choose not to follow the cycles. Some of the findings that are of interest to

current research include the consistency of cycle lengths, limited variation in the sales of service

stations, tendency of service stations to match their competitors prices, presence of cycles in the

LPG market and differences in the way service stations set their prices in markets without cycles.

In the second paper, we provide station level demand estimates for diesel and LPG in four service

stations that operate in metropolitan Melbourne. Given that there is no information on how elastic

or inelastic demand for diesel or LPG is in Australia, these estimates fill a significant gap in the

current literature. The estimates show that the short-run price elasticities of diesel range from

to and of LPG from to . The diesel price elasticities are lower than the

petrol price elasticities for Australia, which is consistent with expectations. What is striking about the

LPG price elasticities is that they are low in comparison to both petrol and diesel. The low price

elasticities of LPG suggest that the ongoing tax raises on LPG will not have significant effects on the

sales of service stations.

In the third paper, we identify differences in the predictions of the Edgeworth cycles model (Maskin

& Tirole 1988) and the price discrimination model (Conlisk et al. 1984) that can be empirically

analysed. Furthermore, the Edgeworth cycles model and the current explanations for the price

xiii

cycles in petrol retailing predict price differences across service stations. To date, there has been no

empirical evidence in any literature to support this prediction. We present the first piece of empirical

evidence to reject this prediction as we find similar price elasticities of petrol in four service stations

that operate in metropolitan Melbourne. The similar price elasticities in local markets that have

different levels of competition indicate that service stations match each other’s prices and not

undercut. Thus, suggesting that the cycles are more in line with the price discrimination model than

the Edgeworth cycles model.

xiv

Acknowledgments

When writing this dissertation, I benefited from the input and support of many people.

I would like to begin by thanking my principal supervisor David Prentice and co-supervisor Laszlo

Konya. Without David’s input and sacrifice this dissertation would not have been possible. Not only

was David directly involved with the construction of the idea that price cycles may be used to price

discriminate between consumers, but also was the sole contributor to any of the ideas developed in

this dissertation. I would like to thank Laszlo Konya for his help with organising my data, clarifying

certain econometric techniques and correcting the final copy of my dissertation.

Along with my two supervisors, I would like to thank La Trobe University for offering me a

candidature and providing me financial support for three years. I was the beneficiary of excellent

facilities and rewards like attending the 40th Australian Conference of Economist as a presenter.

Special thanks to Stephen King for his encouragement and comments as my discussant at the 2011

Ph.D. conference.

Outside of the academic scene, I would like thank my family and wife Dilek for supporting me

through the numerous years I have been attending La Trobe University. My father, Fuat, has been

supporting me financially for as long as I can remember. It was not until my early twenties that I first

joined the workforce, as my father had outlawed me from working as he was afraid it would

intervene with my studies. I can only appreciate today what he was trying to achieve through his

actions and I cannot find any words to be able express my gratitude. All I can say is thank you and I

hope I have done you proud.

I would also like to thank a number of people who have in some way contributed to my work in this

dissertation. I would like to thank Matt Harrison, Said Nursi, Michael Schneider and Peter de Been.

Murat Besnek

xv

Statement of Authorship

Except where reference is made in the text of the thesis, this thesis contains no material published

elsewhere or extracted in whole or in part from a thesis submitted for the award of any other degree

or diploma.

No other person’s work has been used without due acknowledgement in the main text of this thesis.

This thesis has not been submitted for the award of any degree or diploma in any other tertiary

institution.

Signature of Candidate:

1

1. Introduction

This dissertation contains three chapters that study the retail petroleum industry. The retail

petroleum industry has attracted the interest of many researchers because of the price cycles that

take place in petrol retailing. Over the last decade, there have been numerous studies by academics

(Atkinson 2009; Bloch 2010; Doyle 2008; Eckert 2002, 2003; Eckert & West 2004; Foros & Steen

2008; Lewis 2009; Lewis & Noel 2011; Noel 2007, 2011; Wang 2009a, 2009b) and government

authorities (ACCC 2000, 2001a, 2001b, 2004, 2005, 2006, 2007, 2010a, 2010b) analysing why retail

prices of petrol cycle. Interestingly, thus far, there has been no definite answer.

In theory, there are many reasons why retail prices may cycle in a market: competition, consumer

acquisition and price discrimination to list a few (Maskin & Tirole 1988; Doyle 1983; Conlisk et al.

1984). The conclusions of preceding papers, except for Foros and Steen (2008), are that retail prices

of petrol cycle because of competition that exists between service stations. They claim that the

cycles are explained by the Edgeworth cycles model in Maskin and Tirole (1988). For instance, Noel

(2007: 81-87) believes that it is the constant tug of war between small and large firms that generate

the cycling phenomenon. BP Australia (2006: 3) claims that “the price cycles reflect competition in

the market.” Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC 2007: 167) reports that “the

causes of the price cycles are not clear” and that “the existence of price cycles alone do not seem to

provide evidence of a lack of retail competition.”

In this dissertation, using (1) our experience as a service station operator and worker for more than

three years in five sites; (2) meetings with an owner of a company that manages more than thirty

service stations; (3) interviews from four service station operators; and (4) micro-level price and

quantity data1, we propose that retail prices of petrol do not cycle because of competition that exists

between service stations. We present the first piece of empirical evidence against the common

1 We acquire the data from the print-outs of the on-site computer systems of four service stations, which we

personally print out and enter into a spreadsheet. From the time we were given permission to retrieve the data to its current state which is ready for estimation, took approximately six months.

2

belief that the Edgeworth cycles model is consistent with the retail petrol industry. The similar price

elasticity estimates, recurring cycle lengths, price matching, and limited variation in the sales of

service stations that we establish from the data oppose the idea that competition is the cause of the

cycles. If competition is the cause of the cycles, then a new theory other than the Edgeworth cycles

model should be proposed.

In Chapter 2 of this dissertation, we explain how petrol, diesel and LPG are retailed in Australia. The

purpose is to shed light on to retail petroleum industry to assist with the analysis regarding the

cause of the cycles in Chapter 4. We provide information about each level of the petroleum industry,

discuss consumer and service station decision making, and examine when service stations change

their prices and how this affects their sales. We find cycles that do not vary in length, steady sales

levels at service stations, price matching rather than price cutting between service stations, the LPG

market displaying cycles and different pricing patterns in markets without cycles. There are several

details concerning the retail petroleum industry presented in this chapter that are not consistent

with the Edgeworth cycles model.

In Chapter 3 of this dissertation, we provide station level demand estimates for diesel and LPG in

four service stations that operate in metropolitan Melbourne. The purpose is to offer some insight

into how elastic or inelastic demand for diesel or LPG is in Australia. The estimates predict that the

short-run price elasticities of diesel are between to and of LPG between to

. To our knowledge, there is no previous Australian study that has estimated demand for

diesel or LPG. The estimates in this chapter not only serve as good comparisons to the petrol

estimates in Chapter 4 which will assist in determining the cause of the cycles, but also offer policy

makers in Australia a measure to judge if the ongoing tax raises on LPG will have significant effects

on the sales of service stations.

In Chapter 4 of this dissertation, we identify differences in the predictions of the Edgeworth cycles

model (Maskin & Tirole 1988) and the price discrimination model (Conlisk et al. 1984) that can be

3

empirically analysed. The purpose is to present the first piece of empirical evidence to reject the

prediction that there are price differences across service stations. The Edgeworth cycles model and

the current explanations for the cycles in petrol retailing predict price differences across service

stations. However, to date, there has been no empirical evidence in the literature to support this

prediction. By estimating station level demand for petrol in four service stations that operate in

Metropolitan Melbourne, we show that the similar price elasticities in local markets that have

different levels of competition indicate that service stations match each other’s prices and not

undercut. Therefore, (1) suggesting that the cycles are not in line with the Edgeworth cycles model

and (2) associating the cycles with other motives like price discrimination.

4

Bibliography

Atkinson, B. (2009) Retail Gasoline Price Cycles: Evidence from Guelph, Ontario Using Bi-Hourly,

Station Specific Retail Price Date. The Energy Journal. 30(1): 85-109.

Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) (2000) Report on the Movement in Fuel

Prices in the September Quarter 2000. Canberra: ACCC.

——(2001a) Reducing fuel price variability. Canberra: ACCC.

——(2001b) Reducing fuel price variability. Discussion Paper. Canberra: ACCC.

——(2004) Assessing shopper docket petrol discounts in the petrol and grocery sectors. Canberra:

ACCC.

——(2005) Understanding petrol pricing in Australia—answers to some frequently asked questions.

Canberra: ACCC.

——(2006) Senate Economics Legislation Committee inquiry into the price of petrol in Australia.

Canberra: ACCC.

——(2007) Petrol Prices and Australian Consumers: Report of the ACCC Inquiry into the Price of

Unleaded Petrol. Canberra: ACCC.

——(2010a) Monitoring of the Australian Petroleum Industry. Canberra: ACCC.

——(2010b) What are Petrol Price Cycles? Canberra: ACCC.

Bloch, H. (2010) Gasoline Price Cycle Drivers: An Australian Case Study. Working Paper. Curtin

Business School.

BP Australia Pty Ltd (2006) Submission by BP Australia Pty Ltd on the price of petrol in Australia to

Senate Economics Legislation Committee. Australia: BP.

Conlisk, J., Gerstner, E. and Sobel, J. (1984) Cyclic Pricing by a Durable Goods Monopolist. The

Quarter Journal of Economics. 99(3): 489-505.

Doyle, C. (1983) Dynamic Price Discrimination, Competitive Markets and the Matching Process.

Discussion Paper 229, University of Warwick.

5

Doyle, J., Muehlegger, E. and Samphantharak, K. (2008) Edgeworth Cycles Revisited. NBER Working

Paper 14162.

Eckert, A. (2002) Retail Price Cycles and Response Asymmetry. Canadian Journal of Economics. 35(1):

52-77.

Eckert, A. (2003) Retail Price Cycles and Presence of Small Firms. International Journal of Industrial

Organization. 21(2): 151-170.

Eckert, A. and West, D. (2004) Retail Gasoline Price Cycles across Spatially Dispersed Gasoline

Stations. Journal of Law and Economics. 22: 997-1015.

Foros, O. and Steen, F. (2008) Gasoline Prices Jump Up on Mondays: an Outcome of Aggressive

Competition? CEPR Working Paper DP6783.

Lewis, M. (2009) Temporary Wholesale Gasoline Price Spikes have Long Lasting Retail Effects: The

Aftermath of Hurricane Rita. Journal of Law and Economics. 52(3): 581-606.

Lewis, M. and Noel, M. (2011) The Speed of Gasoline Price Response in Markets with and without

Edgeworth Cycles. Review of Economics and Statistics. 93(2): 672-682.

Maskin, E. and Tirole, J. (1988) A Theory of Dynamic Oligopoly II: Price Competition, Kinked Demand

Curves and Edgeworth Cycles. Econometrica. 56(3): 571-599.

Noel, Michael D. (2007) Edgeworth Price Cycles: Evidence from the Toronto Retail Gasoline Market.

Journal of Industrial Economics. 55(1): 69-92.

——(2011) Edgeworth Price Cycles and Intertemporal Price Discrimination. Energy Economics.

Forthcoming.

Wang, Z. (2009a) Station Level Gasoline (Petrol) Demand in an Australian Market with Regular Price

Cycles. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics. 53(4): 467-483.

Wang, Z. (2009b) Mixed Strategies in Oligopoly Pricing: Evidence from Gasoline Price Cycles before

and under a Timing Regulation. Journal of Political Economy. 117(6): 987-1030.

6

2. Retailing of Petrol, Diesel and LPG in Australia

2.1 Introduction

In recent times, the retail petroleum industry has received the attention of academics (Atkinson

2009; Bloch 2010; Doyle 2008; Eckert 2002, 2003; Eckert & West 2004; Foros & Steen 2008; Lewis

2009; Lewis & Noel 2011; Noel 2007, 2011; Wang 2009a, 2009b) and regulatory authorities (ACCC

2000, 2001a, 2001b, 2004, 2005, 2006, 2007, 2010a, 2010b) because of the price cycles that occur in

petrol retailing. As petrol is a vital consumer good and forms a big portion of household expenditure,

this attention is quite understandable. Yet, the regular and predictable cycles are actually eye-

catching themselves. In Melbourne 20062, a typical cycle begins on a Wednesday afternoon with a

single large increase in price, approximately cents per litre on average. Thereafter, prices steadily

fall for six days, several small decreases of about cent per litre on average. This is until the

following Wednesday afternoon, whereupon the price is raised again and a new cycle begins.

Preceding academic and regulatory papers, even the ones explaining the retail petroleum industry of

other countries, are written from the perspective of an outsider looking into the industry. None of

the writers ever speak about working or operating a service station. Furthermore, nearly all

preceding academic papers either use macro-level data or micro-level data that only contains price

observations. The only paper that uses micro-level price and quantity data is Wang (2009a).

Unfortunately, however, the data in Wang (2009a) is collected at a time when the retail market in

Western Australia is under severe restrictions by the regulatory authorities and service stations are

not allowed to change their prices to match or beat their competitors' prices. As a result, the

descriptions in Wang (2009a) are less relevant outside Western Australia.

We believe having inside information and micro-level price and quantity data collected under regular

conditions where service stations are allowed to change their prices as many times as they desire is

2 During other periods or in other cities prices may cycle on a different day.

7

critical in being able to explain the retail petroleum industry. In this chapter, we explain how petrol,

diesel and LPG are retailed in Australia using (1) our experience as a service station operator and

worker for more than three years in five sites; (2) meetings with an owner of a company that

manages more than thirty service stations; (3) interviews from four service station operators; and (4)

micro-level price and quantity data. Moreover, we investigate when service stations change their

prices and how this affects their sales. The aim in undertaking this study is to improve the overall

understanding of the industry so that future research dealing with questions like ‘why does retail

prices of petrol cycle?’ can make the right decisions when choosing the assumptions of their models

and interpreting industry data.

This chapter is organised as follows. Section 2.2 outlines the data and provides details about the

service stations from where the data is acquired. Section 2.3 explains the Australian petroleum

industry. Section 2.4 provides information about consumer and service station decision making.

Sections 2.5, 2.6 and 2.7 examine the retail petrol, diesel and LPG markets to determine when

service stations change their prices and how this affects their sales. Section 2.8 concludes the

chapter.

2.2 Dataset and Service Stations

2.2.1 Dataset

The dataset we use is made up of intraday observations on retail prices and quantities sold of petrol,

diesel and LPG during the years of 2004, 2005 and 2006. We acquire the data from four service

stations located within the Melbourne metropolitan area and surrounding suburbs. Due to a

confidentiality agreement with the operators, we do not disclose their position and brand name. We

have labelled them (A), (B), (C) and (D) to allow fluency when writing. The letters chosen are random

8

and do not represent anything. All of the service stations are branded independents3 and they

compete in separate local markets.

We compile the observations directly from the on-site computer systems of the service stations,

which on a daily basis—24 hour period to 3pm—report the volume of sales in litres at the registered

prices of petrol, diesel and LPG. For instance, at 3pm on the 23rd of April 2006, the computer system

of one of the service stations reports the sale of litres of petrol at the price of dollars

per litre and litres of petrol at the price of dollars per litre. This sales report accounts

for all petrol sold from that particular service station between 3pm on the 22nd of April 2006 and

3pm on the 23rd of April 2006. The prices are reported in order of registration; however, the time of

registration is not made known. In other words, the computer system of that particular service

station reports that petrol is firstly sold for dollars per litre and later for dollars per litre.

It does not however report the exact time the price change occurs and as a result we do not know

the time-span of each registered price.

Petrol refers to unleaded fuel with a minimum Research Octane Number (RON) of 91. Octane

numbers indicate the quality of fuel; higher octane fuels undergo longer manufacturing processes at

the oil refinery. Higher octane fuels are required by high performance vehicles; hence,

predominantly used by them. We do not include unleaded fuel other than 91 octane in the dataset

for two reasons. Firstly, about of unleaded fuel sold in the service stations is 91 octane

unleaded. Secondly, the prices of other unleaded fuels move precisely in the same manner as 91

octane unleaded. In Australia, service stations retail higher octane fuels at a constant mark-up over

the prices of 91 octane unleaded. For instance, 95 octane unleaded always sells seven cents above

91 octane unleaded during the period of the data.

3 A branded independent service station is a service station operated independently of the oil majors, but is

branded with one of their names. For further details see section 2.3.3 on p.21.

9

The dataset also includes the average daily terminal gate price (TGP)4 of petrol and diesel for the

years of 2004, 2005 and 2006. We could not acquire any data on the TGP of LPG. We obtain the

average daily TGP of petrol and diesel from the Australian Institute of Petroleum (AIP) website

(www.aip.com.au). It is prepared by ORIMA Research Pty Ltd and runs from the 1st of January 2004

to the present day. ORIMA reports that the TGP is calculated from information provided on the

websites of the four oil majors. ExxonMobil, Royal Dutch Shell, BP and Chevron5 publish their TGP on

the internet on a daily basis. ORIMA every morning collates the average TGP of these companies for

the day and records it. Prices are inclusive of GST.

2.2.2 Pricing strategy of the owner of the service stations

The owner of the four service stations where we acquire the data from also manages more than

thirty other service stations in Melbourne. The owner entered into the retail petroleum industry

many years ago by purchasing a single service station and operating as an independent before

purchasing additional service stations. At present, his service stations are branded independents.

Naturally, as the owner purchased more and more service stations, he was compelled to manage

rather than operate. The owner currently employs individuals on monthly contracts to operate his

service stations while he manages. A standard contract includes the following terms:

1. The operator to agree to pay the owner a sum of money for having the right to operate a

service station for a given month.

2. To operate a service station, the operator to invest in stock made up of items that the oil

major they are branded with has approved of, varying from to dollars,

depending on the size of the service station.

3. The operator to use these items to stock up the service station he operates, as the owner is

only responsible in providing fuel.

4 The TGP broadly represents the price for bulk supply of petroleum excluding charges for additional services

such as freight to the retail outlet. For further details see section 2.3.1 on p.16. 5 In Australia, Chevron is represented by its subsidiary Caltex.

10

4. The operator to receive cent per litre from fuel sales at the service station he operates6.

5. The operator to receive the profits earned from the sale of non-fuel items excluding the car

wash (if applicable).

6. The owner to pay the water, gas and electricity bills.

The owner demands that his service station operators match the lowest price in the local markets

they operate in. He gives them strict orders. The owner truly believes that this strategy maximises

his profits and openly states that he has adopted other strategies beforehand, such as undercutting

the available market price, but these have lead to lower profits. There are three ways in which the

operators try to match the lowest price in the local markets they operate in. We will summarise each

in turn.

The first way in which the operators try to match the lowest price in the local markets they operate

in is by ordering employees to inspect the prices of competing service stations either visually if they

are in close vicinity or through shift changes if they are distant. If the prices of competing service

stations are lower, the operators authorise a price change immediately by ringing the owner. Once a

price change has been authorised, the new price is keyed into the register and changed on the price

board. There are commonly three or four shift changes during a 24 hour period, so if competing

service stations are distant, inspecting prices through shift changes is an effective way that operators

can match the lowest price in the local markets they operate in.

The second way in which the operators try to match the lowest price in the local markets they

operate in is by utilising the recommended price they receive on a daily basis from the oil major they

are branded with. This price generally serves as a good estimate for the lowest price in the local

markets they operate in. If their current price is significantly higher or lower than this recommended

6 The operators receive the cent per litre irrespective of the price or cost of fuel. Even if the owner sells

below cost, the operators still receive the cent per litre.

11

price, the operators immediately order employees to re-inspect the prices of competing service

stations.

The third way in which the operators try to match the lowest price in the local markets they operate

in is by communicating with the owner. The owner is in a position to continually update the

operators as he is aware of the prices of many service stations that are spread all over Melbourne.

Just like the daily recommended price, the operators make use of this information by comparing

their current price to the prices of other service stations. If something appears to be a little odd, the

operators immediately order employees to re-inspect the prices of competing service stations.

2.2.3 Service stations7

Figure 2.1.1 below displays the market structure of service station (A)8. Service station (A) competes

with three independent service stations9 denoted as (I), which lie 250m to the east. The three

independent service stations lie directly across each other; hence, are approximately equivalent in

distance from where service station (A) is located. The prices of the three independent service

stations are visible from where service station (A) is located. The operator or any employee can walk

to the entrance of the site and identify what prices the independent service stations have set. It can

be said with confidence that service station (A) is at all times matching the lowest price in its local

market.

7 Information about which service stations compete with service stations (A), (B), (C) and (D) are provided by

the operators. 8 The arrows in the figures report the distance between the service stations.

9 An independent service station is a service station operated independently of the oil majors. For further

details see section 2.3.3 on p.21.

12

Market Structure of Service Station (A)

Figure 2.1.1

Service station (A) and the top two independent service stations compete for market share when

motor vehicles are travelling east on a major road that runs from where service station (A) is

positioned. The top and bottom independent service stations furthest to the right compete for

market share when motor vehicles are travelling south on a different major road that runs from

where the top independent service station is positioned. There are traffic lights at the intersection of

these two major roads; thus, motor vehicles travelling one way can change direction if there are

price differences across the service stations.

Figure 2.1.2 below displays the market structure of service station (B). Service station (B) competes

with one supermarket operated service station10 denoted as (S) and three oil major11/branded

independent service stations denoted as (OM/BI). The three oil major/branded independent service

stations are labelled (OM/BI) because it is not definite if they are oil major franchisees or branded

independents. From the exterior they both look identical; without any details on how the service

stations are operated, their ownership is not identifiable. Service station (B) in contrast to service

station (A) is isolated from its competitors. The nearest service station lies 5.2km to the west. Service

station (B) monitors the prices of competing service stations through shift changes for the reason

10

A supermarket operated service station is a service station operated by one of the supermarket chains. For further details see section 2.3.3 on p.21. 11

An oil major service station is a service station operated by one of the oil majors. For further details see section 2.3.3 on p.21.

13

that it is so distant from where its competitors lie. The operator of service station (B) also receives

considerable help from the owner, who informs him of any updates received from the oil major or

other operators. The operator of service station (B) states that even if they are not able to match

their competitors’ prices instantly because of their location, they are quick to respond. He openly

claims that the loss of consumers from the delay is insignificant.

Market Structure of Service Station (B)

Figure 2.1.2

The top oil major/branded independent service station and the supermarket operated service

station compete for market share when motor vehicles are travelling east on a major road that runs

from where the top oil major/branded independent service station is positioned. The middle and

bottom oil major/branded independent service stations compete for market share when motor

vehicles are travelling west on the same major road. Service station (B), because of its position,

competes with all four service stations; motor vehicles travelling east or west are able to enter it

without changing direction. To access the bottom oil major/branded independent service station,

motor vehicles have to make a left turn when travelling west and drive a further 400m. There are

many traffic lights along this major road; therefore, motor vehicles travelling one way can change

direction if there are price differences across the service stations. Furthermore, this major road is

not a freeway and contains speed limits and traffic volumes comparable to the two major roads in

the local market of service station (A).

14

Figure 2.1.3 below displays the market structure of service station (C). Service station (C) competes

with one branded independent service station denoted as (BI) and one independent service station

denoted as (I). The branded independent service station lies 0.5km and the independent service

station lies 1.4km to the east of service station (C). Unlike the oil major/branded independent

service stations in area (B), the branded independent in area (C) has communicated to being a

branded independent. Service station (C) similar to service station (B) monitors the prices of its

competitors through shift changes. The operator of service station (C) also receives considerable

help from the owner, who informs him of any updates received from the oil major or other

operators. The operator of service station (C) in the same way as the operator of service station (B),

states that even if they are not able to match their competitors’ prices instantly because of their

location, they are quick to respond. He also claims that the loss of consumers from the delay is

insignificant.

Market Structure of Service Station (C)

Figure 2.1.3

Service station (C) and the two competing service stations lie on the same major road. Motor

vehicles travelling west prefer to drive into service station (C) and motor vehicles travelling east

prefer either to drive into the branded independent or the independent service station. There are

many traffic lights along this major road; consequently, motor vehicles travelling one way can

change direction if there are price differences across the service stations. This major road is also not

15

a freeway but contains lower speed limits and higher traffic volumes than the major roads in the

local markets of service stations (A) and (B).

Figure 2.1.4 below displays the market structure of service station (D). Service station (D) competes

with one independent service station denoted as (I), one branded independent service station

denoted as (BI), and one supermarket operated service station denoted as (S). The independent

service station lies directly across service station (D), practically facing one another. The branded

independent service station lies 600 metres to the east and the supermarket operated service

station lies 800 metres to the west of service station (D). Service station (D) monitors the prices of its

competitors in a unique way. Like service station (A), it can directly observe the price of the

independent service station. It is also aware of the price at the branded independent service station

because it is one of the other service stations the owner has purchased. Only the price of the

supermarket operated service station needs to be monitored and because service station (D) is a

large site, it has two employees working at all times making monitoring more frequent than in

service stations (B) or (C). For this reason, it can be said with confidence that just like service station

(A), service station (D) is at all times matching the lowest price in its local market.

Market Structure of Service Station (D)

Figure 2.1.4

Service station (D) and the three competing service stations lie on the same major road. Motor

vehicles travelling west prefer to drive into the branded independent service station and motor

vehicles travelling east prefer either to drive into the supermarket operated service station, the

16

independent service station or service station (D). There are many traffic lights along this major

road; consequently, motor vehicles travelling one way can change direction if there are price

differences across the service stations. This major road is also not a freeway and contains speed

limits and traffic volumes comparable to the major roads in the local markets of service stations (A)

and (B).

2.3 Australian Petroleum Industry

2.3.1 Refining

The Australian petroleum industry can be classified into three broad levels: refining, distributing and

retailing. Refining petroleum refers to the process of separating crude oil and natural gas into

different fractions by distillation (AIP Refining of Petroleum n.d.). Crude oil and natural gas are of

little use when extracted from the ground in their natural state. Refineries organise a series of

processes that remove and group elements from crude oil and natural gas to transform them into

products like petrol, diesel and LPG. There are seven refineries operating in Australia with one at

Port Stanvac in South Australia12 stopping production. They are all operated by the oil majors:

ExxonMobil, Royal Dutch Shell, BP and Chevron own two refineries each. The refineries are fairly

evenly spread across the main states of Australia. There are two refineries in Victoria, one in Altona

operated by ExxonMobil and one in Geelong operated by Royal Dutch Shell. New South Wales has

two refineries, one in Kurnell operated by Chevron and one in Clyde operated by Royal Dutch Shell.

Queensland has two refineries, one in Bulwer Island operated by BP and one in Lytton operated by

Chevron. Western Australia has one refinery in Kwinana operated by BP.

The annual capacity of the seven refineries was million litres in 2009-10 (ACCC 2010a).

However, there has been a decline in refining capacity since 2003 when the annual capacity was

million litres (ACCC 2006). This decline is mainly due to the fact that the Port Stanvac refinery

12

One of ExxonMobil’s refineries.

17

ceased to operate and the re-configuration of the other refineries to meet the new cleaner fuel

standards introduced in 2002. The higher average cost of refining in Port Stanvac because of its

relative size compared to the larger refineries in the Asia-Pacific region is the reason why it ceased to

operate. The introduction of the new cleaner fuel standards in 2002 is an initiative by the Australian

Government to reduce global warming and pollution in general (ACCC 2006). The standards simply

limit the use of certain chemicals in petroleum products. Other notable impacts of the introduction

of the new cleaner fuel standards are cents per litre increase in the retail prices of fuel and the

effect on independent importers who now find it more difficult to obtain fuel that meet the new

cleaner fuel standards (ACCC 2006).

It would be an understatement to say that the oil majors completely dominate the refinery level.

They own the refineries and the independent importers source most of their fuel from them. For

example, in 2009-10 the seven refineries collectively produced million litres of petrol (ACCC

2010a). Motorists consumed million litres in the same year and there were litres of

petrol imported. The discrepancy between production/imports and consumption is due to the

existence of stocks. Imports make up of total consumption of petrol, a fairly small share. More

importantly, however, most of the importing of petrol is carried out by the oil majors to meet

demand in areas that are distant from their refineries (ACCC 2010a). This is an example from the

petrol market but the diesel market is no different except for a higher percentage of imports (ACCC

2010a). The LPG market will be discussed in more detail in the retailing of LPG section but the oil

majors basically produce of the LPG that is consumed in Australia (LPG Autogas Australia n.d.).

Over of the crude oil used in the refineries is imported. The main sources are Vietnam,

Malaysia, Indonesia, Saudi Arabia, the United Arab Emirates, Papua New Guinea and Brunei (ACCC

2010a). Even though Australia is a net exporter of crude oil, Australian crude oil is lighter and more

expensive than most world crude oils, which are more appropriate for the refined petroleum

products in Australia. To avoid higher production costs the oil majors chose to import most of their

18

crude oil from overseas. The reference price for crude oil in Australia is the Malaysian Tapis crude oil

price (ACCC 2010a).

Petroleum products are supplied into the wholesale market from the terminals of the oil majors.

Competing oil majors that do not have a refinery in that location, commercial customers and

distributors purchase their fuel from the terminals. Prior to 2002, the oil majors had exchange

agreements with one another, which guaranteed supplies of petroleum products for exchange in

locations where they did not have refineries (ACCC 2004). The exchanges were organised in volumes.

However, since 2002, these agreements have been replaced by buy/sell arrangements (ACCC 2004).

Under buy/sell arrangements oil majors charge each other wholesale prices for supplies of

petroleum products in locations where they do not have refineries. In essence, the new

arrangements provide the oil majors with more flexibility to respond to competition.

Commercial customers and other distributors purchase their fuel at a wholesale price known as the

terminal gate price (TGP). The TGP broadly represents the price for bulk supply of petroleum

excluding charges for additional services such as freight to the retail outlet. The TGP of petrol is

believed to be determined by the following factors (ACCC 2010a): Singapore’s price of petrol;

insurance, wharfage and freight costs to the terminal; AU/US dollar exchange rate; terminalling costs

and margins; excise tax and goods and services tax (GST). The oil majors publish their TGP on the

internet on a daily basis. In Victoria and Western Australia they are required to do so, while in other

states they do it voluntarily.

There are over six hundred terminals in Australia13 and the TGP can differ for two reasons depending

on the terminal (ACCC 2010a). Firstly, the TGP differs because the oil majors use different methods

to calculate their TGP. Some use a five-day rolling average of the factors which determine the TGP

and others seven-day. The oil majors also demand different margins for their refined petroleum

13

The terminals are not all owned by the oil majors.

19

products. Secondly, the terminals vary in their distance from the refinery where they take deliveries.

Thus, wharfage and freight costs are different for each terminal, which is reflected in their TGP.

It is not definite how many sales actually take place at the published TGP. It is believed that oil

majors supply petroleum products to company owned and commission agency sites at lower prices

than the published TGP. Other oil major and supermarket operated sites should receive discounts off

the published TGP because of their business relationships. This also presumably applies to most

branded independent sites which have large supply contracts with the oil majors. Over of their

fuel is purchased from the oil major they are branded with. The oil major franchisees purchase

petroleum products at higher prices than the published TGP, as they subsequently receive price

support (ACCC 2001, 2006)14. What franchisees pay for petroleum products is not clear. Only the

independent operators should be subject to the published TGP and that is probably only when

making a spot purchase; purchases on contracts should involve some type of discounting off the

published TGP.

2.3.2 Distributing

Distributing petroleum refers to the act of delivering petroleum products from the terminals to

service stations. The deliveries of petrol/diesel and LPG arrive from two separate distribution chains.

Depending on the size of the service station and its sales volume, deliveries of petrol/diesel can vary

from a fortnightly to a per month basis. Given that the storage capacity for LPG is a lot smaller than

petrol/diesel15, LPG deliveries tend to occur every second day. Service stations have a lower

threshold on their fuel tanks and LPG cylinders for retail operators to inspect them. When levels

drop below the lower threshold, new supplies of petrol/diesel or LPG are ordered. The whole course

of action from detecting that the levels are low to ordering and receiving a new delivery is typically a

simple and straightforward procedure. There are currently around one hundred and thirty

14

Price support means franchisees get access to cheaper wholesale prices. 15

Petrol/Diesel is stored beneath service stations whereas LPG is stored in external cylinders.

20

petrol/diesel distributor companies working in Australia (ACCC 2006)16. Each retailer has some type

of connection or even a contract with one or more of these distributors who deliver fuel from the

terminals to service stations at their demand.

Distributors are generally prompt with their deliveries for two reasons. Firstly, the sales from service

stations are predictable17. Orders occur more or less around the same times every month for

petrol/diesel and around every second day for LPG. Arranging the deliveries of separate service

stations on different days of the month, distributors can become more prompt with their deliveries.

Secondly, the TGP does not vary often and it takes the TGP of petrol/diesel over a week for it to

respond to a change in Singapore’s price of petrol and diesel (ACCC 2010a). Contracts and franchisee

agreements between refiners and retailers also delay its variation. Consequently, there are not many

tactical orders that might group and slow deliveries. According to the operators of the service

stations from where the data is acquired, an order arriving after levels drop to zero rarely happens,

maybe once every few years18.

Distributors in return for their services receive a margin that is calculated on a price per litre basis.

The retailer who makes an order for deliveries of petrol/diesel or LPG is charged a fee that accounts

for the wholesale price of petrol/diesel or LPG, and a fee charged by the distributor for delivering its

petrol/diesel or LPG from the terminal. The charge by the distributor, just like the wholesale price of

petrol/diesel or LPG, is calculated on a per litre basis. For example, if the distributor delivers

litres of diesel and it charges cent per litre for its service, the distributor earns dollars for

delivering diesel from the terminal to the retail outlet.

There has been a significant decline in the number of petrol/diesel distributors operating in

Australia. In 1996 there were around four hundred petrol/diesel distributors operating compared to

one hundred and thirty in 2006, and this number has declined further (ACCC 2010a). The current

16

We could not obtain how many LPG distributor companies work in Australia. 17

See Tables 2.2.1 and 2.2.2 on p.29 and p.32 respectively. 18

Basically stating that the service stations do not run out of petrol, diesel or LPG.

21

trend is that the distributors the oil majors have equity in are competing strongly while others are

exiting. of the total industry volume is handled by these distributors (ACCC 2006, 2010a). The

reasons for the development of this trend are that (1) the distributors the oil majors have equity in

generally offer lower prices, (2) they reduce transport and handling costs by using high volume

trucks, (3) they deliver directly from the terminals without any need for storage, and (4) they cut

costs by improving logistics.

2.3.3 Retailing

Retailing petroleum refers to selling petroleum products directly to consumers at service stations.

Petroleum products are customarily retailed through pumps that are organised in rows for the

convenience of consumers. Consumers drive in and fill the desired quantity using the pumps, which

report the price per litre and the volume purchased. There are currently four different types of

service stations that retail petroleum in Australia: oil major, branded independent, supermarket and

independent (ACCC 2010a). They differ in ownership structure and operations.

The oil majors operate approximately of service stations in Australia (ACCC 2010a). They either

operate their service stations themselves ( ), they hire a commission agent to manage on their

behalf ( ) or they franchise ( ). The sites they choose to operate themselves are high volume

sites. They are generally located in the inner-metropolitan areas. The commission agency sites are

managed by selected individuals. These individuals are compensated based on the performances of

the sites they operate. The franchisee operated sites are owned by the oil majors but rented out

under a franchise agreement. Under this agreement a franchisee is required to pay an entry fee19,

pay monthly rent for the premises and purchase its fuel from the oil major. The agreement also

includes a section on the eligibility of receiving price support; that is, if a franchisee does adhere to

the recommended prices of the oil major20, it will be able to receive price support if earnings are not

19

This fee is known as a ‘goodwill’ payment. 20

Oil majors send daily recommended prices to its franchisees.

22

satisfactory (ACCC 2006). The oil majors determine the prices at their sites either directly, like they

do in company operated and commission agency sites, or indirectly through price support like in

franchisee operated sites.

The branded independents operate approximately of service stations in Australia (ACCC

2010a). Branded independents are like independent operators except that they are branded with

one of the oil majors’ names. In doing so, however, just like franchisee operated sites they source

majority of their fuel from the oil major they are branded with (ACCC 2006). There are also other

contractual obligations such as monthly fees and change in the appearance of sites. Branded

independents are free to determine their own prices. Distributor-owned service stations are

branded independent service stations, except that they are owned by companies that also distribute

petroleum products. They also predominantly operate in rural areas in comparison to branded

independents.

The supermarkets operate approximately of service stations in Australia (ACCC 2010a).

Supermarket operated sites have similar arrangements with the oil majors as branded independents.

Just like branded independents, they are expected to source their fuel from the oil majors but have

freedom to determine their own prices (ACCC 2006). However, the supermarket operated sites

choose not to compete by undercutting prices but through their ‘shopper docket’ schemes.

The independents operate approximately of service stations in Australia (ACCC 2010a).

Independent operators can be separated into two categories: the large independent chains that

include names like 7-Eleven and small independent operators that use their own brand names. The

large independent chains generally purchase fuel in bulk from the local oil major and sell it through

company owned sites (ACCC 2006). The small independent operators also purchase their fuel from

the local oil major but in smaller amounts and less frequently. Both the large independent chains

and small independent operators choose their own prices.

23

Since the 1970’s, there has been a continuing trend in the rationalisation of service stations. It is

reported that in 1970 there were around twenty thousand sites compared to six thousand five

hundred in 2009-2010 (ACCC 2010a). While there are many reasons for the rationalisation of service

stations, the most important are the change in the underlying supply and demand factors of the

petroleum industry. On the supply side, to lower the costs of service stations there has been a move

towards high volume sites with the availability of convenience goods. On the demand side, due to

higher traffic volumes and a growing desire of consumers for more convenient arrangements, small

service stations with one or two pumps have been replaced by modern service stations with multiple

pumps, fast food outlets and other facilities.

There are no statistics available to determine which service station type has been most affected by

the rationalisation of service stations. Nevertheless, it can be said from observation that the smaller

independents have suffered more. The latest market share estimates were reported in ACCC (2010a)

that held Coles/Royal Dutch Shell to have of the market, Woolworths/Chevron to have of

the market, Chevron by itself to have of the market, BP to have of the market and

ExxonMobil to have of the market. The remaining of the market is estimated to be other

brands These latest market share estimates reveal the influence the oil majors have on the retail

level of the petroleum industry.

2.4 Consumer and Service Station Decision Making

In the retail petroleum industry, the choices consumers make when purchasing their fuel and the

decisions service stations make when setting their prices are straightforward. Using our experience

as a service station operator and worker for more than three years in five sites, we can say that their

behaviour is actually very predictable. The two reasons for this straightforwardness and

predictability are (1) the physical characteristics of fuel and (2) the market structure of the retail

petroleum industry. These same two reasons are also why we see limited brand loyalty from

consumers and small local markets that do not compete with one another.

24

Beginning with the physical characteristics of fuel, the most notable one is homogeneity. As petrol,

diesel and LPG at service stations are commonly acquired from the same refinery of a given region

and serve the same purpose of releasing energy into consumers’ vehicles, fuel is unquestionably a

homogenous product. Taking into account that the supplies of fuel are always available, prices are

clearly displayed on large boards that can be seen by consumers before driving in, and consumers

are made aware of any discounts and the cheapest day to buy their fuel via the radio, television or

internet, this characteristic of fuel makes consumers choices straightforward. They drive into the

service station that is displaying the cheapest price of fuel using a discount if available or refilling on

the cheapest day possible. It also creates limited brand loyalty from consumers as they are happy to

switch service stations as long as they are offered cheaper prices.

Now coming to the market structure of the retail petroleum industry, fuel is commonly retailed

through service stations that are built in convenient places on major roads of suburbs and occupied

regions. They are organised in a way to help consumers conserve time when refilling their motor

vehicles. Furthermore, the locations of service stations are not random. Service stations locate

themselves in places that have more consumers. Depending on the number of consumers, certain

areas may have multiple service stations operating. The larger the consumer base, the more service

stations an area can accommodate. Service stations come to realise how many sites one particular

area can accommodate through entry and exit. This in turn creates a market structure that consists

of numerous service stations competing for the same consumers.

This type of market structure facilitates one of two pricing strategies: competitive or market leader

and follower. In our opinion the retail petroleum industry in Australia consists of leader and follower

service stations: sites operated by the oil majors on the one hand; oil major franchisees, branded

independents, non-branded independents, supermarkets and distributor-owned sites on the other

hand. The reasons for this belief are (1) our experience as a service station operator and worker

enable us to communicate with other franchisees that disclose that they are following the prices of

25

the oil majors, (2) meetings with an owner of the company that manages more than thirty service

stations that are matching the lowest price in the local markets they operate in; (3) interviews from

four service station operators that provide details on how they match the prices of other service

stations; and (4) recent research like Foros and Steen (2008) that show service stations increasing

their prices to the same level21. We will now explain how service stations make their decisions when

setting their prices from the market leader and follower perspective.

Firstly, follower service stations understand that price cuts do not increase market share. Therefore,

they do not try to cheat by lowering their prices; instead they match the prices of leader service

stations. Follower service stations might like to keep their prices high, but when leader service

stations lower their prices they have to match otherwise lose market share. This set of

circumstances make the follower service stations decisions when setting their prices

straightforward; especially in the case of diesel and LPG which are less complicated than petrol as

prices in these markets change less frequently. Even so, however, because the price cycles in the

petrol market occur in a predictable way, the decision making in that market should not be

considered too difficult either.

Leader service stations have a more complicated task as they are required to determine when prices

should change. Nonetheless, the following reasons lessen the complexity of the task that leader

service stations have to fulfil. First of all, leader service stations know exactly what the response of

follower service stations will be when they change their prices. There is no ambiguity in this regard,

which is helpful. If leader service stations decrease their prices, follower service stations will match

their prices or else lose market share. If leader service stations increase their prices, follower service

stations will again match their prices as this will increase profits by leading to higher margins on fuel

21

Also, see Chapter 4 for a structural model that indicates that service stations match each other’s prices.

26

sales22. So leader service stations know exactly what response they will receive when they change

their prices.

Secondly, leader service stations know that they will not increase their market share by lowering

prices. Given that their prices will be matched instantly, the gain from additional consumers will not

outweigh inframarginal losses. As a result, there is no incentive for them to try increase profits in

this way. All that leader service stations need to take into consideration when deciding on what

prices to set are (1) the wholesale price of fuel and (2) if there is an alternative pricing strategy other

than cost-based pricing that may increase profits. In Conlisk et al. (1984), it is shown that under

certain conditions cycling prices may lead to higher profits than cost-based pricing. This is one

possible reason why we observe cycles rather than cost-based pricing with the retailing of certain

petroleum products like petrol.

2.5 Retailing of Petrol

2.5.1 Price cycles

The most intriguing aspect of petrol retailing in Australia is the price cycles that typically occurs on a

weekly basis. In Melbourne, between the 27th of April 2005 and the 17th of June 2006, the cycles

begin on a Wednesday afternoon with a single large increase in price. The price increases are in the

region of cents per litre on average. Subsequently, prices fall for six days with small cent per litre

decreases on average. On the following Wednesday afternoon, seven days since the last price

increase, another price increase occurs and a new cycle begins.

Figure 2.2.1 below displays a sample of service station (A) from the dataset to demonstrate the

cycles in Melbourne. Note that the cycles begin with a single large increase in price on the 7th, 14th,

21st and 28th of December 2005, which are Wednesdays. Note also that the price increases are

22

See section 2.5.3 on p.29 for a discussion on this proposition.

27

around cents per litre on average. On the other days of the week, it can be seen that the prices

move down slowly with decreases of cent per litre on average.

Retail Prices of Petrol in December 2005

35302520151050

1.200

1.175

1.150

1.125

1.100

1.075

1.050

Date

Pric

e of

Pet

rol

December 2005

Figure 2.2.1

Figure 2.2.2 below displays the same sample of service station (A) for service stations (B) and (D). It

can be seen from Figure 2.2.2 how closely the prices of the three service stations move. The prices of

the three service stations move up or down around the same time. This is remarkable when we

consider that these three service stations are from separate local markets that have different market

structures and competing service stations. This finding is consistent with the prices of most service

stations in Melbourne moving up or down around the same time (ACCC 2010a).

Retail Prices of Petrol in December 2005 (Multiple)

35302520151050

1.200

1.175

1.150

1.125

1.100

1.075

1.050

Date

Pric

e of

Pet

rol

Service Station (A)

Service Station (B)

Service Station (D)

TGP

Variable

December 2005

Figure 2.2.2

28

2.5.2 Service stations that choose not to follow the price cycles

Figure 2.2.3 below displays the prices of service stations (B) and (D) in August 2005. Figure 2.2.3

provides a great example of when service stations occasionally choose not to follow the price cycles.

For whatever reason service stations choose not to follow the cycles, the service stations in the local

markets they operate in are also forced not to follow. Given that the prices of service stations are

completely visible to each consumer, service stations are required to match the lowest price in the

local markets they operate in or else lose market share.

Retail Prices of Petrol in August 2005

302520151050

1.30

1.25

1.20

1.15

1.10

Date

Pric

e of

Pet

rol

Service Station (B)

Service Station (D)

TGP

Variable

August 2005

Figure 2.2.3

Focus on the cycle that begins on the 17th of August 2005 and ends on the 24th of August 2005. It is

the third cycle appearing in Figure 2.2.3. Service station (D) or one of the service stations in its local

market for some reason decide not to follow the cycle that week. This is obvious from the figure and

the data. The price of service station (D) on the 17th of August 2005 increases from dollars per

litre to dollars per litre. From viewing service station (B), it is evident that this is the start of

the cycle for that week. Service station (D) thus initially chooses to follow the cycle. However, on the

18th of August 2005, service station (D) decreases its price to dollars per litre, opting out of the

cycle. The price of service station (D) for the rest of the week effectively stays the same ending at

dollars per litre with only three price changes for the week. This is in comparison to service

station (B) which started the cycle at the price of dollars per litre and finished at the price of

dollars per litre with eleven price changes for the week.

29

2.5.3 Decreases in profits

Table 2.2.1 below lists the sales of petrol between 3pm on Friday and 3pm on Monday for service

stations (B) and (D). The list, along with the previous and subsequent four cycles, includes the cycle

that begins on the 17th of August 2005 and ends on the 24th of August 2005. When service station (D)

decides or is forced not to follow the cycle during that week, between Friday and Monday is where

we should see increases in the sales of service station (D) if its decision to not follow the cycle is

profitable. This is the time when the prices of service station (D) are the furthest from the prices of

other local markets that are following the cycle.

Sales of Petrol between 3pm on Friday and 3pm on Monday

Date Service Station (D) Service Station (B)

22/07/05 – 25/07/05 litres litres

29/07/05 – 01/08/05 litres litres

05/08/05 – 08/08/05 litres litres

12/08/05 – 15/08/05 litres litres

19/08/05 – 22/08/05 * litres * litres

26/08/05 -29/08/05 litres litres

02/09/05 - 05/09/05 litres litres

09/09/05 - 12/09/05 litres litres

16/09/05 - 19/09/05 litres litres *Sales of petrol between 3pm on the 19

th of August 2005 and 3pm on the 22

nd of August 2005.

Table 2.2.1

In the long-run, the strategy to not follow the cycles is not optimal as service stations in other local

markets might also begin to do the same. Obviously, this is something undesirable by all service

stations, as it would cause lower prices at the pump. Yet, what is surprising from the data is that

even in the short-run there is no benefit for service stations to not follow the cycles. For instance,

the sales of service station (D) between 3pm on Friday and 3pm on Monday for the cycle that begins

on the 17th of August 2005 and ends on the 24th of August 2005 is litres. This quantity is

similar to the subsequent three cycles where the local market of service station (D) is following the

cycles. Nevertheless, let’s assume the increase in the sales of service station (D) to be from it not

following the cycle that week and compare its sales to the cycle between the 5th of August 2005 and

30

the 8th of August 2005 where the prices of service station (D) are identical with that of service station

(B). The sales of service station (D) between 3pm on Friday and 3pm on Monday for the cycle that

begins on the 5th of August 2005 and ends on the 12th of August 2005 is litres. This is a

decrease of litres. Even though from the table it seems that this decrease is a result of other

factors, let’s suppose it to be as a result of service station (D) choosing to follow the cycle.

The terminal gate price between the 19th of August 2005 and the 22nd of August 2005 is

dollars per litre. When we subtract the terminal gate price from the prices of service station (D)

between the 19th of August 2005 and the 22nd of August 2005 and multiply it by the quantity of

petrol sold at these prices, we can estimate that service station (D) made a profit of dollars

from the sale of petrol between the 19th of August 2005 and the 22nd of August 2005. The average

price of service station (B) between the 19th of August 2005 and the 22nd of August 2005 is

dollars per litre23. When we subtract the terminal gate price from the average price of service station

(B) and multiply it by the quantity of petrol sold by service station (D) between the 5th of August

2005 and the 8th of August 2005, we can estimate that service station (D) could have made a profit

of dollars from the sale of petrol between the 19th of August 2005 and the 22nd of August 2005

if it had followed the cycle.

This is the best possible scenario we can consider for service station (D) when it decides or is forced

by other service stations in its local market to not to follow the cycle. We ignore factors that may

influence the sales in service station (D) between the 19th of August 2005 and the 22nd of August

2005; we overlook the fact that the subsequent three cycles have similar quantities where service

station (D) is following the cycles; and we compare the sales between the 19th of August 2005 and

the 22nd of August 2005 to the lowest sales value that service station (D) registers during the two

month period. Even so, service station (D) losers more than of its profits for not following the

cycle.

23

We use the average price of service station (B) as a proxy for the cycle price between the 19th

of August 2005 and the 22

nd of August 2005 because service station (B) is following the cycle during this period.

31

2.5.4 Limited variation in the sales of service stations

We mentioned that the retail petrol industry is made up of small local markets that do not compete

with one another. Table 2.2.1 on p.29 supports this statement. From Table 2.2.1 we can see that

service station (B) is not affected by service station (D)’s decision to not follow the cycle. The sales of

service station (B) between 3pm on Friday and 3pm on Monday for the cycle that begins on the 17th

of August 2005 and ends on the 24th of August 2005 is litres. Eight out of the nine cycles in

Table 2.2.1 service station (B) registers similar numbers. The local market of service station (D) is the

nearest local market to service station (B)’s local market, and service station (D) having prices that

are cents per litre lower than service station (B)’s does not seem to affect the sales of service

station (B).

Table 2.2.1 also suggests that the price cycles occur all over Melbourne and that it is rare to observe

local markets that do not follow them. If local markets did not consistently follow the cycles,

consumers would hear about this news and search for lower prices driving to other local markets.

Accordingly, if consumers did search for lower prices driving to other local markets, we would

observe large variations in the sales of service stations. However, in Table 2.2.1 and the data in

general, we do not observe large variations. The sales of the four service stations are extremely

predictable; so predictable that any of the operators can estimate with high accuracy how much

petrol they will sell on a given day24.

For instance, take a look at Table 2.2.2 below. Table 2.2.2 contains the weekly sales of petrol

between the 30th of January 2005 and the 17th of June 2006 in service stations (A), (B) and (C). We

could use any part of the dataset to demonstrate that the variation in the sales of the service

stations is limited. Examining Table 2.2.2, we can see that service station (A) consistently registers

weekly sales in the region of litres, service station (B) in the region of litres, and

service station (C) in the region of litres. This is in spite of the fact that the data in Table 2.2.2

24

This information is provided by the operators.

32

is not adjusted for seasonal factors and overall prices. It is likely that some of the variances are

because of seasonal factors and overall prices. For instance, see the weekly sales of the service

stations between the 3rd and the 9th of April 2006, where there is a comparable increase across the

service stations.

Weekly Sales of Petrol between 30/01/2006 and 17/06/2006

Station A Station B Station C

Date Weekly

Sales Variance

of Average Weekly

Sales Variance

of Average Weekly

Sales Variance

of Average

30/01/06 - 05/02/06 06/02/06 - 12/02/06 13/02/06 - 19/02/06 20/02/06 - 26/02/06 * *

27/02/06 - 04/03/06 * *

05/03/06 - 11/03/06 12/03/06 - 18/03/06 19/03/06 - 25/03/06 * *

26/03/06 - 02/04/06 03/04/06 - 09/04/06 10/04/06 - 16/04/06 17/04/06 - 23/04/06 24/04/06 - 30/04/06 01/05/06 - 07/05/06 08/05/06 - 14/05/06 15/05/06 - 21/05/06 22/05/06 - 28/05/06 29/05/06 - 04/06/06 05/06/06 - 11/06/06

Average Weekly Sales Standard Deviation

The * symbol represents weekly sales that contain missing observations.

Table 2.2.2

2.5.5 Price increases

Price increases occur in a very unique way in petrol retailing. We have already mentioned that prices

always increase with a single large increase in price. In the whole dataset, which runs for almost

three years, there is not one instance when a price increase occurs by a small margin or one instance

when a price increase is followed by another price increase. Once the price is increased, prices never

33

increase again for at least seven days. Figure 2.2.4 below shows the coefficient of variation (COV) of

price increases that simultaneously occur in service stations (A), (B), (C) and (D)25. After analysing

Figure 2.2.4, we can see that the prices of the service stations always increase to the same level

given that the COV is nearly always equal to zero and never greater than cents26.

Coefficient of Variation of Price Increases

0.0040.0020.000-0.002-0.004-0.006

120

100

80

60

40

20

0

Price of Petrol

Freq

uenc

y

Coefficient of Variation

Figure 2.2.4

This is a well known fact by industry participants and probably many consumers; however, plenty of

preceding papers seem to ignore it (AIP 2006a; BP 2006; Noel 2007; Wang 2009a). If we refer to

Maskin and Tirole (1988), we can see that if competition is the cause of the price cycles, then prices

of service stations should never match under the Edgeworth cycles model. Rather the first service

station that relents in a local market should have the highest price and the second service station

that relents in the same local market should have a price just below that. Yet, in Figure 2.2.4, we

cannot observe anything that resembles this type of behaviour from the service stations.

2.5.6 Signalling

Price increases in petrol retailing also serve the purpose of signalling the start of the price cycles in

metropolitan areas. We can separate the dataset into two groups: the observations on retail prices

of petrol between the 9th of May 2004 and the 23rd of April 2005 and the observations on retail

25

How we calculate the COV is by taking the average of the price increases that occur on the same date in the four service stations and then subtracting each observation from its average. 26

The fact that service stations increase their prices to the same level is also documented in Foros and Steen (2008) and ACCC (2010a).

34

prices of petrol between the 27th of April 2005 and the 17th of June 2006. Between the 9th of May

2004 and the 23rd of April 2005 price increases always occur sometime between 3pm on Saturday

and 3pm on Sunday. Between the 27th of April 2005 and the 17th of June 2006 price increases always

occur sometime between 3pm on Wednesday and 3pm on Thursday. Regardless if the price

increases are to start a cycle or because the service stations wrongly anticipate a cycle to restart,

price increases always occur between these times27.

Figures 2.2.5 and 2.2.6 below contain the starting price of each cycle in the service stations. Between

the 9th of May 2004 and the 23rd of April 2005 we can see that the price increases occur sometime

between 3pm on Saturday and 3pm on Sunday. The ‘day’ frequencies make this clear as the

histogram is filled with the number , which indicates this period28. And, between the 27th of April

2005 and the 17th of June 2006 we can see that the price increases occur sometime between 3pm on

Wednesday and 3pm on Thursday. The day frequencies again make this clear as the histogram is

filled with the number , which indicates this period29.

Price Increases for Petrol between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005

7654321

40

30

20

10

0

Day

Freq

uenc

y

6 - Friday

7 - Saturday

Variable

Price Increases

Figure 2.2.5

27

It is also shown in Foros and Steen (2008) that service stations consistently increase their prices on the same day, which is a Monday in the Norwegian market. 28

The day frequencies in the figures represent the day codes used in the data. The numbers run from to . indicates a Sunday, indicates a Monday, etc. 29

ACCC (2009) reports on p.172 that of retail prices peaked on Wednesdays during 2006, 2007 and 2008 in Melbourne.

35

Price Increases for Petrol between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006

7654321

90

80

70

60

50

40

30

20

10

0

Day

Freq

uenc

y

4 - Wednesday

5 - Thursday

Variable

Price Increases

Figure 2.2.6

There are two inconsistencies in Figures 2.2.5 and 2.2.6, which we should clarify. There are four s

and fifteen s which appear in the histograms. The four s indicate four price increases that occur

sometime between 3pm on Friday and 3pm on Saturday and the fifteen s indicate fifteen price

increases that occur sometime between 3pm on Thursday and 3pm on Friday. At first this may seem

contrary to price increases always occurring sometime between 3pm on Saturday and 3pm on

Sunday and between 3pm on Wednesday and 3pm on Thursday. However, inspecting the data

together with the information provided by the operators, we can explain why the four s and the

fifteen s are not contrary to price increases always occurring sometime between 3pm on Saturday

and 3pm on Sunday and between 3pm on Wednesday and 3pm on Thursday.

The operators expressed that occasionally price increases occur just before 3pm or just after 3pm.

For example, the price increases that occur sometime between 3pm on Friday and 3pm on

Saturday30 which are supposed to occur sometime between 3pm on Saturday and 3pm on Sunday,

took place very close to 3pm on Saturday. For instance, 2pm on Saturday. Given that the data is

organised from 3pm to 3pm, the day codes make it seem as if the price increases took place a day

before, but that’s really not the case. We can also confirm this by analysing the data as the

quantities sold at these price increases are very low. This low quantity basically informs us that the

30

Price increases with the day code .

36

price increases took place a short time before 3pm. Price increases that occur at a much earlier

period would have larger quantities assigned to them.

2.5.7 Price increases that are not the start of a price cycle

We mentioned that the dataset contains price increases that are not the start of a price cycle. We do

not classify these price increases as genuine increases in the prices of petrol for two reasons

explained below31. How we identify if a price increase is genuine or not is by looking at the quantity

of petrol sold at that particular price. A price increase that is not genuine is associated with a very

low sales quantity. Another indication that a price increase is not genuine is when not long after the

increase, the price falls back to its previous level. For instance, the price rises from dollars per

litre to dollars per litre, and then falls back down to dollars per litre.

There are two reasons why price increases that are not the start of a price cycle occur. The first

reason is the large number of service stations that exist in the retail petrol industry. With multiple

service stations it is not always possible to coordinate price increases in one attempt. A service

station anticipates price increases to occur on a Wednesday afternoon and raises its price. If it

realises that nearby service stations, especially the oil major sites after a certain amount of time

have not increased their prices also, the service station decreases its price back down to the lowest

price in its local market to not lose market share.

The second reason why price increases that are not the start of a price cycle occur is because retail

prices of petrol are correlated with the wholesale price of petrol. When the wholesale price falls, it

does not translate into retail prices instantly. In the entire dataset, there is not one instance when a

change in the wholesale price results in a sudden change in retail prices or a discontinuation of the

cycle. What happens when there is a fall in the wholesale price is the cycle extends in length; the

cycle becomes fortnightly or three weekly or more depending on the size of the fall in the wholesale

31

A genuine price increase is when a service station increases its price and holds it there for a period of time long enough to give consumers an opportunity to make a purchase.

37

price. What happens when there is a rise in the wholesale price is the size of the price increases that

start the subsequent cycle increase. The subsequent price increases take into account the rise in the

wholesale price and restart the cycle at a higher price than it would have if the wholesale price had

not have changed.

Figures 2.2.7 and 2.2.8 below depict the August and November 2005 observations of service stations

(A), (B) and (D) from the dataset. Both figures have the TGP appearing in them to display how retail

prices adapt to changes in the wholesale price. The first thing to notice from Figure 2.2.7 is that the

wholesale price increases during August. Looking at how retail prices react to this change, we can

see that as the wholesale price begins to increase, retail prices continue to decrease in its usual

pattern. The initial reaction to the rise in the wholesale price happens seven days later when retail

prices take this into account by restarting the subsequent cycle at a higher price than the previous

cycle. We can also see that as the wholesale price continues to increase during August, the only

thing that changes is the size of the price increases that occur in the following cycles.

Retail Prices of Petrol in August 2005

302520151050

1.30

1.25

1.20

1.15

1.10

Date

Pric

e of

Pet

rol

Service Station (B)

Service Station (D)

TGP

Variable

August 2005

Figure 2.2.7

38

Retail Prices of Petrol in November 2005

302520151050

1.25

1.20

1.15

1.10

1.05

Date

Price

of P

etro

l

Service Station (A)

Service Station (B)

Service Station (D)

TGP

Variable

November 2005

Figure 2.2.8

From Figure 2.2.8 we can see that the wholesale price begins to decrease on the 14th November.

Looking at how retail prices react to this change, we can see that even before the wholesale price

starts to decrease officially in Melbourne, the oil majors are aware of the fall in the wholesale price

and extend the length of the cycle that starts on the 2nd of November. We can also see that the

operators of the four service stations are not aware of this change as service stations (A), (B) and (D)

raise their prices on the 9th of November anticipating a restart. Service stations (A), (B) and (D) not

long after increasing their prices however, understand that the oil majors have extended the cycle

and drop their prices back down to the original level. The price decreasing then continues until early

December where the wholesale price stabilises again. Once the wholesale price stabilises, the

weekly cycles recommence and the price decreasing goes back to its usual pattern.

2.5.8 Recurring cycle lengths

What is interesting about recurring cycle lengths is that it opposes the Edgeworth cycles model

(Maskin & Tirole 1988) but is consistent with the price discrimination model in Conlisk et al. (1984).

One of the structural predictions of the Edgeworth cycles model is that the lengths of the cycles are

random. Figure 2.2.9 below provides a histogram of the lengths of the cycles in service stations (A),

(B), (C) and (D). We can see from the figure that the data is not consistent with this prediction of the

39

Edgeworth cycles model. The lengths of the cycles are not random, rather equal to , , or

days32.

Lengths of the Price Cycles for Petrol

3521147

35

30

25

20

15

10

5

0

Number of Days

Freq

uenc

y

7 Days

14 Days

21 Days

35 Days

Variable

Length of the Price Cycles for Petrol

Figure 2.2.9

For instance, if retailers use the daily wholesale price at the terminals as a base for their costs, under

the Edgeworth cycles model, when the wholesale price falls, we would expect the undercutting

phase to increase in length. However, since the fall in the wholesale price is random, we would also

expect the increase in the length of the undercutting phase to be random. For example, the

wholesale price sometimes falls by cent per litre and sometimes cents per litre. Depending on

how far the wholesale price falls and at what stage of the cycle the fall occurs, we would expect the

undercutting phase to increase in length to that extent.

If retailers use the daily wholesale price at the terminals as a base for their costs, under the

Edgeworth cycles model, when the wholesale price rises, we would expect the undercutting phase

to decrease in length. However, since the rise in the wholesale price is random, we would also

expect the decrease in the length of the undercutting phase to be random. For example, the

wholesale price sometimes rises by cent per litre and sometimes cents per litre. Depending on

how far the wholesale price rises and at what stage of the cycle the rise occurs, we would expect the

undercutting phase to decrease in length to that extent. Even under certain circumstances, when the

32

See Foros and Steen (2008) for examples of 7 day cycle lengths from the Norwegian market.

40

wholesale price rises above the existing retail price, we would expect an instant discontinuation of

the undercutting phase.

The recurring cycle lengths in Figure 2.2.9 are not in agreement with this type of behaviour from

service stations. In Chapter 4, we show that if the price discrimination model in Conlisk et al. (1984)

is consistent with the retail petrol industry, we should observe cycle lengths that are matching.

These recurring cycle lengths in the table are more consistent with this structural prediction than

with the former. As a result, if competition is the cause of the price cycles, then a new model other

than the Edgeworth cycles model (Maskin & Tirole 1988) should be proposed where cycle lengths

are not random. Until a model with this feature is proposed, we should not consider competition to

be the cause of the cycles in petrol retailing.

2.5.9 Cycle amplitudes

Tables 2.2.3 and 2.2.4 below lists the cycle amplitudes in service stations (A), (B), (C) and (D). Table

2.2.3 is synchronised by date and Table 2.2.4 is synchronised by cycle lengths. The first row in Table

2.2.3 reports cycle amplitudes between the 7th of August 2004 and the 23rd of April 2005. This is the

period when price increases occur sometime between 3pm on Saturday and 3pm on Sunday. The

second and third rows reports cycle amplitudes between the 27th of April 2005 and the 29th of

December 2005 and the 11th of January 2006 and the 14th of June 2006. These are the periods when

price increases occur sometime between 3pm on Wednesday and 3pm on Thursday. We divide this

section of the dataset into two dates because service station (D) has missing observations for the

most part of 2006.

41

Average Cycle Amplitudes Arranged by Date

Date Service Station

(D) Service Station

(B) Service Station

(A) Service Station

(C)

07/08/04 - 23/04/05 cents cents

27/04/05 - 29/12/05 cents cents

11/01/06 - 14/06/06

cents cents cents

Table 2.2.3

Average Cycle Amplitudes Arranged by Cycle Lengths

Cycle Lengths Service Station

(D) Service Station

(B) Service Station

(A) Service Station

(C)

Weekly cents cents cents cents

Fortnightly cents cents cents cents

Three Weeks cents cents cents cents

Five Weeks cents cents cents NA

Table 2.2.4

There are two details about the retail petrol industry we would like to highlight from these two

tables. Table 2.2.3 shows that the average cycle amplitudes across the four service stations once

synchronised by date are nearly identical. If we concentrate on the third row of Table 2.2.3, which

runs for almost sixth months, there is only a mere cents per litre separating the three service

stations. In Table 2.2.3, the largest gap in cycle amplitudes are cent per litre that appears in the

first row. What this information suggests is that the prices at the four local markets more or less

always fluctuate around the same range. From this information it becomes apparent why consumers

do not search for cheaper prices by driving to other local markets.

Table 2.2.4 shows that when cycle lengths extend, they extend because there is a fall in the

wholesale price. This is an important detail as it eliminates any misconceptions about cycle lengths

extending because none of the service stations chose to relent at the bottom of the cycle due to the

randomisation in the Edgeworth cycles model (Maskin & Tirole 1988). If this claim is true, we would

expect to see similar cycle amplitudes for different cycle lengths. However, in Table 2.2.4, when the

lengths of the cycles increase so do the cycle amplitudes. This information is consistent with cycles

42

extending in length because there is a fall in the wholesale price and service stations are able to

decrease their prices further.

2.5.10 Price decreases

Price decreases also occur in a unique way in petrol retailing. We mentioned that prices always fall

with small increments of cent per litre on average. In the whole dataset, which runs for almost

three years, there are only a few occasions when prices fall by more than cents per litre. These

larger decreases are observed in service stations that are experiencing severe competition in their

local markets. These types of service stations tend to opt out of the price cycles during these

periods. The reason for them acting in this way is not known; although one thing for certain is that

they lower their own profits by behaving in this fashion as we have demonstrated.

Table 2.2.5 below contains the total number of price decreases that occur in service stations (A), (B),

(C) and (D). Due to the pattern of the cycles, the total number of price decreases is larger than the

total number of price increases. From the table, we can deduce that on most days of the week there

is a price decrease, and every so often there are days when two price decreases occur. We would

also like to declare from our experience that it’s not like a price decrease by one service station

triggers other service stations to start decreasing their prices in retaliation. It is more like a price

decrease occurs and service stations match each other’s prices. Then another price decrease occurs

and service stations match each other’s prices. This process is repeated until a price increase occurs

and the price decreasing restarts.

43

Number of Price Increases and Price Decreases for Petrol

Service Station Date Between Number of

Days Number of

Price Increases Number of

Price Decreases

A 2/11/2005-7/6/2006 B 5/9/2004-23/4/2005 B 27/04/2005-7/6/2006 C 11/1/2006-7/6/2006 D 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 D 27/4/2005-29/12/2005

Table 2.2.5

In the dataset, service station (A) on average has price decreases per day and on average

decreases its price by dollars per litre. Service station (B) on average has price decreases

per day and on average decreases its price by dollars per litre. Service station (C) on average

has price decreases per day and on average decreases its price by dollars per litre.

Service station (D) on average has price decreases per day and on average decreases its price

by dollars per litre. The slight differences in the average values are mainly generated from the

dates the observations of the service stations are obtained between.

2.5.11 Weekly Quantity Cycle

An interesting question is how the sales of petrol is affected by the price cycle. For instance, does

the sales of petrol significantly increase on the day before the cycle restarts? Or, is there a particular

day during the week where the sales of petrol is low? Figures 2.2.10 and 2.2.11 below present the

average daily sales of petrol in service stations (A), (B), (C) and (D) as a percentage of average weekly

sales. Figure 2.2.10 depicts the period when price increases occur sometime between 3pm on

Saturday and 3pm on Sunday and Figure 2.2.11 depicts the period when price increases occur

sometime between 3pm on Wednesday and 3pm on Thursday. Both figures reveal important

information about the weekly quantity cycle.

44

Weekly Quantity Cycle between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005

Service Station (B) Service Station (D)

Sat11.1%

Fri14.8%

Thu17.3% Wed

16.4%

Tue14.6%

Mon13.3%

Sun12.4%

Sat12.1%

Fri15.4%

Thu17.3% Wed

16.4%

Tue13.9%

Mon12.3%

Sun12.5%

Figure 2.2.10

Weekly Quantity Cycle between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006

Sat10.9%

Fri14.0%

Thu15.0%

Wed14.8%

Tue17.8%

Mon14.8%

Sun12.6%

Service Station (A)

Sat12.4%

Fri14.4%

Thu14.7%

Wed14.2%

Tue16.1%

Mon14.7%

Sun13.4%

Service Station (B)

Sat12.8%

Fri14.4%

Thu14.5%

Wed14.5%

Tue16.7%

Mon13.9%

Sun13.1%

Service Station (C)

Sat14.2%

Fri15.2%

Thu14.5%

Wed12.9%

Tue15.7%

Mon13.4%

Sun14.0%

Service Station (D)

Figure 2.2.11

45

It is evident from the figures that the sales of petrol increase prior to the cycle restart day. In Figure

2.2.10, sales hit their peak on the Thursday, which is two days ahead of the cycle restart day. There

is roughly a difference between the peak and the lowest sales day, which is a Saturday for both

service stations. In Figure 2.2.11, sales hit their peak on the Tuesday, which is one day ahead of the

cycle restart day. However, the difference between the peak and the lowest sales day is not as

definite. The lowest sales day is not consistent across the four service stations with Wednesday

being the lowest sales day for service station (D). Also, the difference varies from ,

suggesting that the difference may change depending on the location of the service station or its

type33. Service stations that operate in locations that are predominantly occupied by low income

earners or service stations with consumers that regularly search for discounts like shopper dockets

may experience larger differences between their peak and lowest sales day.

2.6 Retailing of Diesel

2.6.1 Prior information

Even though petrol and diesel are derivatives of crude oil, they are considered different products

and are sold in separate markets. There are linkages and transactions between the crude oil, petrol

and diesel markets but their prices reflect the supply and demand conditions in their respective

markets. The three markets are connected to the Asia-Pacific markets and follow the prices in those

markets closely. Singapore’s Gasoil 10ppm sulfur diesel is the benchmark price for diesel in Australia.

It is said that there is a lag of one to two weeks between changes in Singapore’s Gasoil 10ppm sulfur

diesel and changes in Australia’s TGP of diesel (AIP Facts on Diesel Prices and the Australian Fuel

Market n.d.).

Diesel is the most dominant fuel in the Asia-Pacific region. The prices of diesel have been affected

the most from the increase in demand for petroleum products from China and India. From 2004-

33

In ACCC (2010a), the difference between the peak and the lowest sales day in the five largest capital cities is reported to be .

46

2005 to 2009-2010, the average TGP of diesel was higher than the average TGP of petrol (ACCC

2010a). Also, the only times retail prices of diesel fell below retail prices of petrol was at the peak of

the cycles in the petrol market. AIP reports that another possible reason for this is the significant

growth in demand for diesel from the mining sector within Australia (AIP Facts on Diesel Prices and

the Australian Fuel Market n.d.). AIP also reports that to meet the increase in demand for diesel

within Australia, over of diesel consumption is imported (AIP Facts on Diesel Prices and the

Australian Fuel Market n.d.)34.

2.6.2 Profits from the diesel market

We would like to mention that AIP consistently attempts to portray the returns in the petroleum

industry as low (AIP Downstream Petroleum 2007 n.d.). There is no evidence or fact provided by AIP

that substantiates the low profits claim from the diesel market35. The increase in demand for diesel

internationally and the increase in demand for diesel from the mining sector of Australia suggest

that the returns are strong. Data sourced from the Australian Bureau of Agriculture and Resource

Economics (ABARE Mining Statistics 2000-2008 n.d.) and the Australian Competition and Consumer

Commission (ACCC 2010a) show that the annual sales and imports of diesel have increased.

We should not interpret an increase in imports as a rise in competition however, as it is more of a

cost cutting strategy. Most of the importing is done by the oil majors (ACCC 2010a). Figure 2.3.1

below demonstrates how diesel is sold well over cost at the retail level. The gap between price and

cost at the retail level is actually wider when considering that diesel is generally bought under the

publicised TGP. Also, as discussed in section 2.3.1 on p.16, the TGP includes the costs of getting

diesel from the terminal to the browser except for the distributor fee which is quite low. When

considering more than cents per litre in profits after paying the distributor fee of say cent per

litre, the retail diesel market looks profitable.

34

In 2009-2010 approximately of diesel consumption was imported (ACCC 2010a). 35

Diesel per litre net profit is higher than any other fuel type (ACCC 2010a).

47

Retail Prices of Diesel in January 2005

302520151050

1.03

1.02

1.01

1.00

0.99

0.98

0.97

0.96

0.95

Date

Pric

e of

Die

sel

Service Station (B)

Service Station (D)

TGP

Variable

January 2005

Figure 2.3.1

2.6.3 Price matching and the absence of price cycles

AIP reports that of diesel is sold to commercial/industrial customers like mining and transport

companies who do not purchase through retail outlets (AIP Facts on Diesel Prices and the Australian

Fuel Market n.d.). The other of diesel is sold to private/account customers who purchase from

service stations. AIP uses this information to justify why retail prices of diesel do not cycle like petrol.

AIP states that sales to private/account customers are so low that there is no point of service

stations competing by cutting each other’s prices (AIP Facts on Diesel Prices and the Australian Fuel

Market n.d.). Although, given that there are no costs for a retailer in changing the prices of diesel,

service stations not competing because sales are low does not appear to be consistent with what AIP

claims to happen in the petrol market. If service stations are fighting for market share by discounting

in the petrol market with low margins, why would they not want to increase their profits by cutting

the prices of diesel?

We are in agreement with AIP that most diesel buyers are commercial/industrial customers. Diesel

provides lower performance in vehicles but gives greater distance (kilometres) per litre compared to

petrol. Consequently, diesel is appealing to commercial/industrial customers. There is no material

available on the profit margins of diesel sales made from commercial/industrial customers.

Transactions of these sales do not occur at service stations. The profit margins from private/account

48

customers are healthy, so we really cannot see why the profit margins from commercial/industrial

customers would be any lower.

Another thing that is certain with diesel buyers is that their price elasticities are low compared to

petrol because there are no substitutes for vehicles and machinery that use diesel. Significant

amount of capital is invested into these vehicles and machinery but they cannot use any other fuel

except diesel. Obviously the vehicles and machinery can be sold off, but at a loss. In any case, what

this creates is a pool of consumers that are similar and have a high willingness to pay. We believe

that this is the likely reason why retail prices of diesel do not cycle. There is no benefit in cycling the

prices of diesel to discriminate between high and low valuation consumers when they all tend to be

high.

Private customers always search for cheaper prices and account customers are no different. The only

difference is that account customers have fleet, motorcharge and/or star cards that they use to pay

for their purchases. At the end of the month, the account customers pay for the outstanding amount

on their cards. However, account customers are still charged the same prices as private customers.

In the dataset, of automotive fuel sold is 91 octane petrol, is LPG, is diesel and

is 95 octane petrol. If the prices of 95 octane petrol cycle, why wouldn’t the prices of diesel cycle as

more of it is sold in terms of quantity? Why would service stations choose to match each other’s

prices? Figures 2.3.2 and 2.3.3 below visibly show that retail prices of diesel do not cycle and are

matching across the service stations. This is also partially true for retail prices of LPG, which is

discussed in more detail in section 2.7 on p.52.

49

Retail Prices of Diesel in September 2004

302520151050

1.08

1.07

1.06

1.05

1.04

1.03

1.02

1.01

1.00

0.99

Date

Pric

e of

Die

sel

Service Station (B)

Service Station (D)

TGP

Variable

September 2004

Figure 2.3.2

Retail Prices of Diesel in May 2005

302520151050

1.150

1.125

1.100

1.075

1.050

Date

Pric

e of

Die

sel

Service Station (B)

Service Station (D)

TGP

Variable

May 2005

Figure 2.3.3

For instance, look at Figure 2.3.2. For the whole month there are only price changes. The prices of

diesel increase times due to an increase in the cost of diesel, which can be seen from the rise in

the TGP. This is evidently a cost-based pricing strategy that the service stations are adopting.

Comparing Figure 2.3.2 to Figure 2.2.2 on p.27, we can see a considerable difference in the pricing

strategies of the service stations. Figure 2.3.1 on p.47 is even more interesting as there is not a single

change in the prices of diesel for the whole month. This is the total opposite of what happens in the

petrol market. Rarely a day goes by without the prices of petrol changing. Figure 2.3.3 is similar to

Figure 2.3.2 except that we have price decreases during the month. Once again, these price

decreases are a result of a decrease in the cost of diesel.

50

2.6.4 Price increases and price decreases

In the diesel dataset, we have price increases and price decreases in total across the four

service stations. Table 2.3.1 below contains a breakdown of the number of price increases and price

decreases for each service station. All of the price changes are influenced by a change in the

wholesale price of diesel. The price increases and price decreases ratio appears so much more

conventional than the petrol market. The diesel market never consistently registers large price

increases in the dataset that are typical of the price increases in the petrol market. Also, the diesel

market never registers constant price decreases with small increments of cent per litre. Price

increases and price decreases both have a random distribution such that a or cents per litre

increase or decrease has the same probability of occurring depending on what happens to the

wholesale price.

Number of Price Increases and Price Decreases for Diesel

Service Station Date Between Number of

Days Number of

Price Increases Number of

Price Decreases

A 2/11/2005-7/6/2006 B 5/9/2004-7/6/2006

C 11/1/2006-7/6/2006 D 9/5/2004-29/12/2005

Table 2.3.1

In the diesel dataset, service station (A) on average increases its price by dollars per litre and

decreases its price by dollars per litre. Service station (B) on average increases its price by

dollars per litre and decreases its price by dollars per litre. Service station (C) on

average increases its price by dollars per litre and decreases its price by dollars per litre.

Service station (D) on average increases its price by dollars per litre and decreases its price by

dollars per litre. The average value of price increases and price decreases for each service

station are summarised in Table 2.3.2 below. Comparing these numbers with the petrol market, we

can see that in the diesel market the average value of price increases are smaller and the average

51

value of price decreases are higher than on the petrol market. The low average values of price

increases clearly show the difference in the way petrol and diesel are retailed. They also show the

difference in the way service stations set their prices in markets without cycles.

Average Value of Price Increases and Price Decreases for Diesel

Service Station Date Between Price Increases Price Decreases

A 2/11/2005-7/6/2006 cents cents

B 5/9/2004-7/6/2006 cents cents

C 11/1/2006-7/6/2006 cents cents

D 9/5/2004-29/12/2005 cents cents

Table 2.3.2

2.6.5 Unpredictability of the day in which price increases occur

The days in which price increases occur in the diesel market are random. There is no way of

predicting which day prices of diesel will increase as we can with the petrol market. The intriguing

aspect is that when retail prices of diesel increase, the time it takes for competing service stations to

respond is exactly the same as the petrol market. By analysing Figure 2.3.2 on p.49, we can confirm

this as the price lines of the service stations lie on top of each other when price increases occur.

There is no lag that we can point out. This is valuable to know as it opposes the claim that service

stations require a prolonged period of time to restore prices because of the randomisation in the

Edgeworth cycles model (Maskin & Tirole 1988).

To demonstrate that the days in which price increases take place in the diesel market are random,

we will list some of the price increases that occur in the dataset. For example, on 3rd of August 2004,

the price of diesel increases by cents per litre in service station (D), which is a Tuesday. On the 8th

of April 2005, the price of diesel increases by cent per litre in service station (D), which is a Friday.

On the 13th of June 2005, the price of diesel increases by cent per litre in service station (D), which

is a Monday. On the 16th of June 2005, the price of diesel increases by cents per litre in service

station (D), which is a Thursday. On the 31st of December 2005, the price of diesel increases by

52

cents per litre in service station (D), which is a Saturday. Figure 2.3.4 below contains a histogram of

the days in which diesel prices increase in the dataset. The price increases are roughly uniformly

distributed between Tuesday and Saturday.

Price Increases for Diesel

7654321

30

25

20

15

10

5

0

Day

Freq

uenc

y

1 - Sunday

2 - Monday

3 - Tuesday

4 - Wednesday

5 - Thursday

6 - Friday

7 - Saturday

Variable

Price Increases

Figure 2.3.4

2.7 Retailing of LPG

2.7.1 Prior information

LPG is an abbreviation for liquefied petroleum gas and is the common name given to a mixture of

hydrocarbons that have an energy content similar to that of petrol. This mixture of hydrocarbons is

mainly made of propane and butane and is compressed to change from a gaseous state into a liquid

state. LPG is colourless and without odour; however a substance is added to the mixture to give it a

distinct smell because of the dangers that even a small leak may possess. The term LPG

encompasses gas used for cooking, heating and automobiles. LPG for automobiles is called ‘Autogas’

and has a specific blend that is controlled by the government. The wholesale price of Autogas is

more expensive than general LPG and treated separately in service stations.

LPG is produced through two processes. The first process involves extracting LPG directly from

natural gas or crude oil. of Australia’s LPG is produced through this process and is supplied

from places like Bass Strait (Vic), Cooper Basin (SA), Kwinana (WA), North West Shelf (WA) and Surat

Basin (QLD) (LPG Autogas Australia n.d.). The second process involves obtaining LPG as a by-product

53

of petroleum (LPG Autogas Australia n.d.). This makes up the other of Australia’s LPG and is

supplied from the seven petroleum refineries mentioned in section 2.3.1 on p.16. It should also be

stated that Australia is abundant with natural supplies of LPG and exports considerable amounts

each year.

2.7.2 Price cycles

Perhaps the most intriguing finding from the data is that retail prices of LPG cycle similar to that of

petrol for an extended period of time during 2004 and 2005. We must confess that we are staggered

by this finding and cannot believe that it slipped past us with our three years of experience as a

service station operator and worker. The two main reasons for our lack of knowledge of the LPG

price cycles prior to the collection of the data are (1) there was no prior information available on

how LPG is retailed and (2) we did not operate or work at a service station during this period when

prices of LPG cycled.

There are a couple of differences between the LPG and petrol cycles during the period of the data

that we should point out. Firstly, the cycles in the petrol market typically follow a weekly cycle

whereas the cycles in the LPG market follow a fortnightly or a three-weekly cycle. Secondly, price

increases in the LPG market are a little larger and the price decreases in the LPG market occur at a

slower rate than the petrol market. Other than these two differences however, the features of the

two cycles are exactly the same. For instance, both cycles begin with a single large increase in price

and both cycles exhibit small price decreases. Also, between the 9th of May 2004 and the 23rd of April

2005 both cycles begin with price increases that occur sometime between 3pm on Saturday and

3pm on Sunday.

Figures 2.4.1 and 2.4.2 below display the prices of LPG in service stations (B) and (D) during

November 2004 and February 2005. We could display any month between May 2004 and April 2005

from the dataset to prove that retail prices of LPG cycle, but we prefer November 2004 and February

54

2005 for two reasons. The first reason is that these two months produce one of the more

transparent graphs in terms of exhibiting the nature of the cycles. The second reason is that in

November 2004 there is a three-weekly cycle and in February 2005 there is a fortnightly cycle. This

option provides us with some diversity in demonstrating the LPG cycles. Looking at either one of the

figures, it can be seen that retail prices of LPG cycle. Both figures appear identical to some of the

petrol graphs except that they have price increases that are a little larger and price decreases that

occur at a slower rate.

Retail Prices of LPG in November 2004

302520151050

0.58

0.56

0.54

0.52

0.50

0.48

0.46

0.44

0.42

Date

Pric

e of

LPG

Service Station (B)

Service Station (D)

Variable

November 2004

Figure 2.4.1

Retail Prices of LPG in February 2005

302520151050

50.0

47.5

45.0

42.5

40.0

37.5

35.0

Date

Pric

e of

LPG

Service Station (B)

Service Station (D)

Variable

February 2005

Figure 2.4.2

Furthermore, to prove that between the 9th of May 2004 and the 23rd of April 2005 price increases in

the LPG market occur sometime between 3pm on Saturday and 3pm on Sunday, we will list some of

the price increases that occur in the dataset. For example, on the 5th of May 2004, the price of LPG

55

increases by cents per litre in service station (D), which is a Saturday. On the 10th of July 2004, the

price of LPG increases by cents per litre in service station (D), which is a Saturday. On the 6th of

November 2004, the price of LPG increases by cents per litre in service station (D), which is a

Saturday. On the 19th of March 2005, the price of LPG increases by cents per litre in service

station (D), which is a Saturday. All of the price increases in Figures 2.4.1 and 2.4.2 on p.54 occur on

a Saturday. Figure 2.4.3 below contains a histogram of the days in which LPG prices increase in the

dataset between the 9th of May 2004 and the 23rd of April 2005. Nearly all of the price increases

occur on a Saturday and the rest the day before because the data is organised from 3pm-3pm.

Price Increases for LPG during the Cycling Phase

7654321

25

20

15

10

5

0

Day

Freq

uenc

y

6 - Friday

7 - Saturday

Variable

Price Increases

Figure 2.4.3

2.7.3 Discontinuation of the price cycles

One bizarre detail about the LPG price cycles is that after April 2005 it discontinues. What is strange

about this event is that it occurs at the same time as retail prices of petrol change from cycling on a

Saturday to a Wednesday. For some reason on the 27th of April 2005 retail prices of LPG stop cycling

and retail prices of petrol start to cycle on a Wednesday instead of a Saturday36. This event is striking

because till that date retail prices of LPG were cycling exactly like that of petrol. The occurrence of

two major events from separate markets on the same date certainly cannot be a coincidence. This

36

See section 2.5.6 on p.33 for a discussion on this change.

56

change suggests that the cycles are something service stations can control. It places major doubts on

the claim that competition is the cause of the cycles.

Figure 2.4.4 below displays the retail prices of LPG in service stations (A), (B) and (D) during

December 2005. We can see from the figure that retail prices of LPG have stopped cycling. Service

station (A) changes its price once; service station (B) changes its price twice; and service station (D)

never changes its price for the whole month. There is not a single week in the petrol dataset with

less price changes than the month of December for LPG. The figure is the total opposite of the petrol

market and similar to the diesel market. Retail prices of LPG seem to now follow the wholesale price

with a certain margin.

Retail Prices of LPG in December 2005

302520151050

0.500

0.495

0.490

0.485

0.480

0.475

Date

Pric

e of

LPG

Service Station (A)

Service Station (B)

Service Station (D)

Variable

December 2005

Figure 2.4.4

Figure 2.4.5 below demonstrates how retail prices of LPG increase when retail prices do not cycle.

We do not want to claim that the prices are adjusting to changes in the wholesale price, as we do

not have any data on the wholesale price of LPG. We are almost certain however, that the increases

in price are a result of changes to the wholesale price. In any case, comparing Figure 2.4.5 to Figure

2.4.2 on p.54, we can see that in Figure 2.4.5 price increases are smaller in value and less frequent.

57

Retail Prices of LPG in November 2005

302520151050

50

48

46

44

42

40

Date

Pric

e of

LPG

Service Station (A)

Service Station (B)

Service Station (D)

Variable

November 2005

Figure 2.4.5

Tables 2.4.1 and 2.4.2 below contain the total number and the average value of price increases and

price decreases for LPG in each service station. Comparing the number of price increases and price

decreases between the 9th of May 2004 and the 23rd of April 2005 to the number of price increases

and price decreases between the 27th of April 2005 and the 17th of June 2006, we can see the

difference in the way service stations set their prices in markets without cycles. The number of days

between the 9th of May 2004 and the 23rd of April 2005 is lower than the number of days between

the 27th of April 2005 and the 17th of June 2006, whereas the number of price decreases between

the 9th of May 2004 and the 23rd of April 2005 is twice as large as the number of price decreases

between the 27th of April 2005 and the 17th of June 2006.

Number of Price Increases and Price Decreases for LPG

Service Station Date Between Number of

Days Number of

Price Increases Number of

Price Decreases

A 2/11/2005-7/6/2006 B 5/9/2004-23/4/2005 B 27/04/2005-7/6/2006 C 11/1/2006-7/6/2006 D 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 D 27/4/2005-29/12/2005

Table 2.4.1

58

Average Value of Price Increases and Price Decreases for LPG

Service Station Date Between Price Increases Price Decreases

A 2/11/2005-7/6/2006 cents cents

B 5/9/2004-23/4/2005 cents cents

B 27/04/2005-7/6/2006 cents cents

C 11/1/2006-7/6/2006 cents cents

D 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 cents cents

D 27/4/2005-29/12/2005 cents cents

Table 2.4.2

To demonstrate how prices started to increase on random days when retail prices of LPG stopped

cycling, we will list some of the price increases that occur in the dataset. For example, on 25th of

August 2005, the price of LPG increases by cents per litre in service station (B), which is a Thursday.

On the 10th of October 2005, the price of LPG increases by cents per litre in service station (B),

which is a Monday. On the 10th of February 2006, the price of LPG increases by cents per litre in

service station (B), which is a Friday. On the 9th of May 2006, the price of LPG increases by cents

per litre in service station (B), which is a Tuesday. Figure 2.4.6 below contains a histogram of the

days in which LPG prices increase in the dataset between the 27th of April 2005 and the 17th of June

2006. Instead of price increases being concentrated on one particular day, they are distributed

evenly throughout the week.

Price Increases for LPG with Cost Based Pricing

7654321

7

6

5

4

3

2

1

0

Day

Freq

uenc

y

2 - Monday

3 - Tuesday

4 - Wednesday

5 - Thursday

6 - Friday

7 - Saturday

Variable

Price Increases

Figure 2.4.6

59

2.7.4 Price increases and price decreases

In the LPG dataset, we have price increases and price decreases in total across the four

service stations. Table 2.4.1 on p.57 contains a breakdown of the price increases and price decreases

for each service station. The ratio is situated right in the middle of the petrol and diesel markets.

Seeing as retail prices of LPG cycle in the first half of the data and in the second half it does not, this

result is not surprising. There are less price increases than price decreases because retail prices of

LPG cycle in the first half of the data. The total number of price decreases is lower than the petrol

market because retail prices of LPG do not cycle in the second half of the data.

In the LPG dataset, during the cycling phase, Service station (B) on average increases its price by

dollars per litre and decreases its price by dollars per litre. Service station (D) on

average increases its price by dollars per litre and decreases its price by dollars per litre.

While adopting cost based pricing, service station (A) on average increases its price by dollars

per litre and decreases its price by dollars per litre. Service station (B) on average increases its

price by dollars per litre and decreases its price by dollars per litre. Service station (C)

on average increases its price by dollars per litre and decreases its price by dollars per

litre. Service station (D) on average increases its price by dollars per litre and decreases its

price by dollars per litre.

The average value of price increases and price decreases for each service station is summarised in

Table 2.4.2 on p.58. Comparing these numbers to the petrol and diesel markets, we can see that in

the LPG market the average value of price increases and price decreases are larger than in the other

two markets during the cycling phase because of the fortnightly or three-weekly cycles in contrast to

the weekly cycles or cost based pricing. Whereas when cost based pricing is adopted in the LPG

market, the average value of price increases and price decreases fall as we do not observe the large

price increases and the frequent price decrease that are common during the cycling phase.

60

2.8 Conclusion

This chapter explains how petrol, diesel and LPG are retailed in Australia. More specifically, it

provides details about when service stations change their prices and how this affects their sales.

Given that earlier studies are not carried out by a service station operator and worker, nor do any

have access to micro-level price and quantity data collected under regular conditions, the

descriptions of the retail petroleum industry and the illustrations of how service stations make their

decisions are unique. There are a several new details that are presented in this chapter that were

not previously available.

In the petrol market, price cycles are exceedingly predictable with corresponding lengths equal to 7,

14, 21 and 35 days. The daily and weekly sales of service stations are stable in the dataset, even

though there is an increase in sales prior to the cycle restart day. During the period of the data, there

are times when service stations choose or are forced not to follow the cycles. We are able use these

occasions to demonstrate that it is not profitable for service stations to not follow the cycles.

Furthermore, in the dataset, prices always increase with a single large increase in price. What is

striking about the price increases is that they occur on the same day and always increase to the

same level across the service stations.

In the diesel market, price cycles are absent. There are price increases and price decreases

in total across the service stations during the period of the data. Comparing this ratio to the petrol

market which has price increases and price decreases, we can identify a clear difference in

the way service stations set their prices in markets without cycles. Moreover, there is no indication

from the data that the profits are low in the diesel market. Prices follow the wholesale price with a

certain margin and are matching across the service stations. Accordingly, the days in which price

increases occur are unpredictable.

61

In the LPG market, retail prices of LPG cycle similar to that of petrol for an extended period of time

during 2004 and 2005. The details of the price cycles in the LPG market are similar to the petrol

market except that the LPG cycles are typically fortnightly or three-weekly. During the cycling phase,

price increases are predictable occurring sometime between 3pm on Saturday and 3pm on Sunday.

Also, the total number of price decreases is larger than the total number of price increases.

However, for some reason, halfway through the data, retail prices of LPG stop cycling. The

discontinuation of the LPG cycles occur on the same day as retail prices of petrol change from cycling

on a Saturday to a Wednesday. With cost based pricing, price increases become unpredictable and

occur on random days. Also, the price increases and price decreases ratio declines considerably.

62

Bibliography

Atkinson, B. (2009) Retail Gasoline Price Cycles: Evidence from Guelph, Ontario Using Bi-Hourly,

Station Specific Retail Price Date. The Energy Journal. 30(1): 85-109.

Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics (ABARE) Mining Statistics 2000-2008

(n.d.) [Online]. Available: http://www.abare.gov.au/publicationshtml/ams/ams_10/ams_10.html

[Accessed 01 January 2011]

Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) (2000) Report on the Movement in Fuel

Prices in the September Quarter 2000. Canberra: ACCC.

——(2001a) Reducing fuel price variability. Canberra: ACCC.

——(2001b) Reducing fuel price variability. Discussion Paper. Canberra: ACCC.

——(2004) Assessing shopper docket petrol discounts in the petrol and grocery sectors. Canberra:

ACCC.

——(2005) Understanding petrol pricing in Australia—answers to some frequently asked questions.

Canberra: ACCC.

——(2006) Senate Economics Legislation Committee inquiry into the price of petrol in Australia.

Canberra: ACCC.

——(2007) Petrol Prices and Australian Consumers: Report of the ACCC Inquiry into the Price of

Unleaded Petrol. Canberra: ACCC.

——(2010a) Monitoring of the Australian Petroleum Industry. Canberra: ACCC.

——(2010b) What are Petrol Price Cycles? Canberra: ACCC.

Australian Institute of Petroleum (AIP) Downstream Petroleum 2007 (n.d.) [Online]. Available:

http://www.aip.com.au/industry/facts.htm [Accessed 01 January 2011].

——(2006a) Submission to the Inquiry into the Price of Petrol in Australia [Online]. Available:

http://www.aip.com.au [Accessed 01 January 2011].

——(2006b) Submission to the Inquiry into Future Oil Supply and Alternative Transport Fuels

[Online]. Available: http://www.aip.com.au [Accessed 01 January 2011].

63

——Facts on Diesel Prices and the Australian Fuel Market (n.d.) [Online]. Available:

http://www.aip.com.au/pricing/pdf/Facts%20about%20Diesel%20Prices%20and%20the%20Australi

an%20Fuel%20Market.pdf [Accessed 01 January 2011].

——Refining of Petroleum (n.d.) [Online]. Available: http://www.aip.com.au/industry/fact_refine.ht

m [Accessed 01 January 2011].

Bloch, H. (2010) Gasoline Price Cycle Drivers: An Australian Case Study. Working Paper. Curtin

Business School.

BP Australia Pty Ltd (2006) Submission by BP Australia Pty Ltd on the price of petrol in Australia to

Senate Economics Legislation Committee. Australia: BP.

——(2008) Sustainability Report 2007-08 [Online]. Available: http://www.bp.com.au [Accessed 01

January 2011].

Conlisk, J., Gerstner, E. and Sobel, J. (1984) Cyclic Pricing by a Durable Goods Monopolist. The

Quarter Journal of Economics. 99(3): 489-505.

Doyle, J., Muehlegger, E. and Samphantharak, K. (2008) Edgeworth Cycles Revisited. NBER Working

Paper 14162.

Eckert, A. (2002) Retail Price Cycles and Response Asymmetry. Canadian Journal of Economics. 35(1):

52-77.

Eckert, A. (2003) Retail Price Cycles and Presence of Small Firms. International Journal of Industrial

Organization. 21(2): 151-170.

Eckert, A. and West, D. (2004) Retail Gasoline Price Cycles across Spatially Dispersed Gasoline

Stations. Journal of Law and Economics. 22: 997-1015.

Foros, O. and Steen, F. (2008) Gasoline Prices Jump Up on Mondays: an Outcome of Aggressive

Competition? CEPR Working Paper DP6783.

Lewis, M. (2009) Temporary Wholesale Gasoline Price Spikes have Long Lasting Retail Effects: The

Aftermath of Hurricane Rita. Journal of Law and Economics. 52(3): 581-606.

Lewis, M. and Noel, M. (2011) The Speed of Gasoline Price Response in Markets with and without

Edgeworth Cycles. Review of Economics and Statistics. 93(2): 672-682.

64

LPG Autogas Australia (n.d.) [Online]. Available: http://www.lpgautogas.com.au/index.cfm [Accessed

01 January 2011].

Maskin, E. and Tirole, J. (1988) A Theory of Dynamic Oligopoly II: Price Competition, Kinked Demand

Curves and Edgeworth Cycles. Econometrica. 56(3): 571-599.

Noel, Michael D. (2007) Edgeworth Price Cycles: Evidence from the Toronto Retail Gasoline Market.

Journal of Industrial Economics. 55(1): 69-92.

——(2011) Edgeworth Price Cycles and Intertemporal Price Discrimination. Energy Economics.

Forthcoming.

Wang, Z. (2009a) Station Level Gasoline (Petrol) Demand in an Australian Market with Regular Price

Cycles. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics. 53(4): 467-483.

Wang, Z. (2009b) Mixed Strategies in Oligopoly Pricing: Evidence from Gasoline Price Cycles before

and under a Timing Regulation. Journal of Political Economy. 117(6): 987-1030.

65

3. Station Level Demand for Diesel and LPG in Metropolitan Melbourne

3.1 Introduction

Fuel is a major portion of every household’s expenditure. Regardless if it is petrol, diesel or LPG, fuel

is a necessary good for most consumers. For this reason, information on consumer demand or

statistics like price elasticities of petrol, diesel and LPG are considered valuable information for

policy makers and academics. While there are several studies at the aggregate and station level for

petrol in Australia (Breunig & Gisz 2009; Wang; Chapter 4), to our knowledge, there is no study that

has estimated demand for diesel or LPG. There are no available estimates for price elasticities of

diesel or LPG. These are significant gaps in the current literature.

In this chapter, we provide station level demand estimates for diesel and LPG. The purpose is to

offer some insight into how elastic or inelastic demand for diesel or LPG is in Australia. The estimates

in this chapter serve as good comparisons to the recent petrol estimates (Breunig & Gisz 2009; Wang

2009; Chapter 4), especially to the estimates in Chapter 4, as they are for the same four service

stations. The difference between the LPG and petrol estimates will be of interest to policy makers in

Australia as it will suggest if the ongoing tax raises on LPG will have significant effects on the sales of

service stations.

The dataset we use consists of intraday observations on retail prices37 and quantities sold of diesel

and LPG during the years of 2004, 2005 and 2006. We obtain the data directly from the on-site

computer systems of the service stations, which on a daily basis—24 hour period to 3pm—report

the volume of sales in litres at the registered prices of diesel and LPG. For instance, at 3pm on the 5th

of November 2005, the computer system of one of the service stations reports the sale of

litres of diesel at the price of dollars per litre and litres of diesel at the price of

37

Prices are in nominal terms as (1) inflation during the period of the data is very low and (2) there are no daily indices available for inflation.

66

dollars per litre. This sales report accounts for all diesel sold from that particular service station

between 3pm on the 4th of November 2005 and 3pm on the 5th of November 2005.

The service stations that we estimate demand for are located in the metropolitan area of Melbourne

and compete in different local markets. Due to a confidentiality agreement with the operators, we

will not disclose their position and brand name. We have labelled them (A), (B), (C) and (D) to allow

fluency when writing. The service stations have freedom to set whatever price they desire. Also, the

local markets of the service stations contain different levels of competition. For instance, service

station (B) is isolated from its competitors with its nearest competitor 5.2km away. Whereas service

station (A) competes in a local market against three independent service stations that lie 250m to

the east of service station (A). Moreover, the local markets of the service stations contain different

combinations of service station types; for instance, some with oil major sites and others with

supermarket operated sites.

This chapter is organised as follows. In section 3.2 we describe the data and report the descriptive

statistics. In section 3.3 we provide details about the service stations. In section 3.4 we show the

demand functions that we use to estimate station level demand. In section 3.5 we apply some

diagnostic tests to the estimators and discuss why we omit certain explanatory variables. In section

3.6 we present the results. In section 3.7 we conclude the chapter.

3.2 Dataset

3.2.1 Dataset

There are observations in the diesel dataset. Out of the observations, are single

day observations where diesel is sold for a specific price for the entire day. Given that retail prices of

diesel do not cycle, we remove the intraday observations in order to increase the precision of

the estimates. The precision of the estimates increase when estimating with single day observations

because it eliminates any variation in demand while service stations adjust their prices. We use

67

intraday observations only when retail prices cycle38. Accordingly, the diesel dataset contains

single day observations, which includes single day observations from service station (A),

single day observations from service station (B), single day observations from service station (C),

and single day observations from service station (D).

There are observations in the LPG dataset. Unlike the diesel dataset, we do not remove all of

the intraday observations because retail prices of LPG cycle for an extended period of time during

2004 and 2005. Basically, between the 9th of May 2004 and the 23rd of April 2005, retail prices of LPG

cycle with price increases that occur sometime between 3pm on Saturday and 3pm on Sunday39.

Whereas, between the 27th of April 2005 and the 17th of June 2006, retail prices of LPG do not

cycle40. To take account of this change and also to measure the effects that price differences across

service stations have on the sales of LPG during the cycling phase, we separate the dataset into two

groups. The first group contains intraday observations, which includes intraday

observations from service station (B) and intraday observations from service station (D). The

second group contains single day observations, which includes single day observations

from service station (A), single day observations from service station (B), single day

observations from service station (C), and single day observations from service station (D).

When employing intraday observations to estimate demand for LPG, we calculate daily weighted

average prices to use them in conjunction with daily quantities. For example, at 3pm on the 5th of

April 2005 the computer system of service station (B) reports the sale of litres of LPG at the

price of dollars per litre and litres of LPG at the price of dollars per litre. By

dividing the sum of by we obtain the

38

The reason for this is that when retail prices do not cycle, price differences across service stations rarely exist. Consequently, there is no motive to measure the effects that price differences across service stations have on the sales of diesel. 39

See section 2.7.2 on p.53. 40

See section 2.7.3 on p.55.

68

weighted average price for service station (B). By summing we obtain the total

quantity sold for service station (B).

3.2.2 Dates and noteworthy shocks

The observations of service station (A) are from approximately an eight month period that begins on

the 25th of October 2005 and ends on the 17th of June 2006. Over this period, service station (A) is

not subject to any noteworthy shock such as a competing service station winding down.

The observations of service station (B) are from approximately a one year and ten month period that

begins on the 5th of August 2004 and ends on the 17th of June 2006. Over this period, service station

(B) is not subject to any noteworthy shocks.

The observations of service station (C) are from approximately a six month period that begins on the

1st of January 2006 and ends on the 17th of June 2006. Unlike service stations (A) and (B), the diesel

pumps in service station (C) are out of order many times during this period. These unfortunate

incidents negatively impact the sales of diesel. This valuable information is provided by the operator

of service station (C) and we will adjust for this when we estimate demand for diesel.

The observations of service station (D) are from approximately a one year and eleven month period

that begins on the 4th of May 2004 and ends on the 31st of March 2006. Over this period, service

station (D) is not subject to any noteworthy shocks.

3.2.3 Descriptive statistics

Table 3.1.1 below reports the descriptive statistics for diesel. The highest daily average for sales of

diesel, , is held by service station (D). Service station (A) is not far behind with a daily average

of . These two service stations receive regular visits from light-heavy rigid motor vehicles that

69

purchase large quantities of diesel41. Consequently, the quantities of diesel sold from service stations

(D) and (A) are noticeably larger than service stations (B) and (C).

Descriptive Statistics for Diesel

A B C D

Qty (L)

Price ($)

Qty (L)

Price ($)

Qty (L)

Price ($)

Qty (L)

Price ($)

Range Minimum Maximum Mean Median Standard Deviation Skewness Kurtosis

Table 3.1.1

The highest variation in the sales of diesel is also held by service stations (D) and (A). Service station

(D) has a standard deviation of and service station (A) has a standard deviation of .

The reason for this is that most light-heavy rigid motor vehicles do not operate on weekends, which

cause large gaps between weekday and weekend sales. One common thing among the service

stations is the non-normality of the distribution of diesel sales. The Jarque-Bera statistic is equal to

in service station (A), in service station (B), in service station (C) and in

service station (D) which are significantly larger than the critical value of at the level.

Therefore, we can conclude with confidence that the sales observations of diesel are non-

normal.

The lowest price of diesel in the dataset is dollars per litre. This price is registered in service

station (D). The highest price of diesel in the dataset is dollars per litre. This price is registered

in service stations (A), (B) and (C). The service stations exhibit great variation in price and the

observations are spread evenly across this range. The variation in the overall price of diesel is caused

41

Some of the light-heavy rigid motor vehicles hold accounts with service stations (D) and (A).

70

by large movements in the world price of diesel. These exogenous shocks allow more of the demand

curve to be traced out. One other thing to note is that service stations (A) and (C) do not have

observations during the years of 2004 and most of 2005. During this period the price of diesel is low

making the range of service stations (B) and (D) wider than that of service stations (A) and (C).

Table 3.1.2 below reports the descriptive statistics for LPG. The highest daily average for sales of

LPG, , is held by service station (D). Service station (C) is not far behind with a daily average of

. This is the first occasion that service station (C) is competitive against the other service

stations in terms of sales. Service station (C)’s large sales numbers are attributable to the regular

visits it receives from taxi motor vehicles. Taxis are known for using large amounts of LPG. Service

station (B) also sells significant amounts of LPG, . However, service stations (D) and (B) sell

LPG to regular consumers in contrast to service station (C).

Descriptive Statistics for LPG

A B C D

Qty (L)

Price ($)

Qty (L)

Price ($)

Qty (L)

Price ($)

Qty (L)

Price ($)

Range Minimum Maximum Mean Median Standard Deviation Skewness Kurtosis

Table 3.1.2

The highest variation in the sales of LPG is held by service station (D), which has a standard deviation

of . Service station (C) has the second lowest standard deviation with . This low

standard deviation illustrates the consistency at which taxis’ purchase LPG compared to regular

consumers. One common thing among the service stations is the non-normality of the distribution of

LPG sales. The Jarque-Bera statistic is equal to in service station (A), in service station

71

(B), in service station (C) and in service station (D) which are significantly larger than

the critical value of at the level. Therefore, we can conclude with 99% confidence that the

sales observations of LPG are non-normal.

The lowest price of LPG in the dataset is dollars per litre. This price is registered in service

station (D). The highest price of LPG in the dataset is dollars per litre. This price is registered in

service stations (A), (B) and (C). The service stations exhibit great variation in price and the

observations are spread evenly across this range. The variation in the overall price of LPG is caused

by large movements in the world price of LPG. These exogenous shocks allow more of the demand

curve to be traced out. One thing to note is that service stations (A) and (C) do not have observations

during the years of 2004 and most of 2005. During this period the price of LPG is low making the

range of service stations (B) and (D) wider than that of service stations (A) and (C).

3.3 Service Stations42

Figure 3.2.1 below displays the market structure of service station (A)43. Service station (A) competes

with three independent service stations denoted as (I), which lie 250m to the east. The three

independent service stations lie directly across each other; hence, are approximately equivalent in

distance from where service station (A) is located. The prices of the three independent service

stations are visible from where service station (A) is located. The operator or any employee can walk

to the entrance of the site and identify what prices the independent service stations have set. It can

be said with confidence that service station (A) is at all times matching the lowest price in its local

market.

42

Readers who have read section 2.2.3 on p.11 may skip this section without any loss of continuity. 43

The arrows in the figures report the distance between the service stations.

72

Market Structure of Service Station (A)

Figure 3.2.1

Service station (A) and the top two independent service stations compete for market share when

motor vehicles are travelling east on a major road that runs from where service station (A) is

positioned. The top and bottom independent service stations furthest to the right compete for

market share when motor vehicles are travelling south on a different major road that runs from

where the top independent service station is positioned. There are traffic lights at the intersection of

these two major roads; thus, motor vehicles travelling one way can change direction if there are

price differences across the service stations.

Figure 3.2.2 below displays the market structure of service station (B). Service station (B) competes

with one supermarket operated service station denoted as (S) and three oil major/branded

independent service stations denoted as (OM/BI). The three oil major/branded independent service

stations are labelled (OM/BI) because it is not definite if they are oil major franchisees or branded

independents. From the exterior they both look identical; without any details on how the service

stations are operated, their ownership is not identifiable. Service station (B) in contrast to service

station (A) is isolated from its competitors. The nearest service station lies 5.2km to the west. Service

station (B) monitors the prices of competing service stations through shift changes for the reason

that it is so distant from where its competitors lie. The operator of service station (B) also receives

73

considerable help from the owner44, who informs him of any updates received from the oil major or

other operators. The operator of service station (B) states that even if they are not able to match

their competitors’ prices instantly because of their location, they are quick to respond. He openly

claims that the loss of consumers from the delay is insignificant.

Market Structure of Service Station (B)

Figure 3.2.2

The top oil major/branded independent service station and the supermarket operated service

station compete for market share when motor vehicles are travelling east on a major road that runs

from where the top oil major/branded independent service station is positioned. The middle and

bottom oil major/branded independent service stations compete for market share when motor

vehicles are travelling west on the same major road. Service station (B), because of its position,

competes with all four service stations; motor vehicles travelling east or west are able to enter it

without changing direction. To access the bottom oil major/branded independent service station,

motor vehicles have to make a left turn when travelling west and drive a further 400m. There are

many traffic lights along this major road; therefore, motor vehicles travelling one way can change

direction if there are price differences across the service stations. Furthermore, this major road is

not a freeway and contains speed limits and traffic volumes comparable to the two major roads in

the local market of service station (A).

44

Service stations (A), (B), (C) and (D) are managed by the same owner. The owner also manages more than thirty other service stations in Melbourne.

74

Figure 3.2.3 below displays the market structure of service station (C). Service station (C) competes

with one branded independent service station denoted as (BI) and one independent service station

denoted as (I). The branded independent service station lies 0.5km and the independent service

station lies 1.4km to the east of service station (C). Unlike the oil major/branded independent

service stations in area (B), the branded independent in area (C) has communicated to being a

branded independent. Service station (C) similar to service station (B) monitors the prices of its

competitors through shift changes. The operator of service station (C) also receives considerable

help from the owner, who informs him of any updates received from the oil major or other

operators. The operator of service station (C) in the same way as the operator of service station (B),

states that even if they are not able to match their competitors’ prices instantly because of their

location, they are quick to respond. He also claims that the loss of consumers from the delay is

insignificant.

Market Structure of Service Station (C)

Figure 3.2.3

Service station (C) and the two competing service stations lie on the same major road. Motor

vehicles travelling west prefer to drive into service station (C) and motor vehicles travelling east

prefer either to drive into the branded independent or the independent service station. There are

many traffic lights along this major road; consequently, motor vehicles travelling one way can

change direction if there are price differences across the service stations. This major road is also not

75

a freeway but contains lower speed limits and higher traffic volumes than the major roads in the

local markets of service stations (A) and (B).

Figure 3.2.4 below displays the market structure of service station (D). Service station (D) competes

with one independent service station denoted as (I), one branded independent service station

denoted as (BI), and one supermarket operated service station denoted as (S). The independent

service station lies directly across service station (D), practically facing one another. The branded

independent service station lies 600 metres to the east and the supermarket operated service

station lies 800 metres to the west of service station (D). Service station (D) monitors the prices of its

competitors in a unique way. Like service station (A), it can directly observe the price of the

independent service station. It is also aware of the price at the branded independent service station

because it is one of the other service stations the owner has purchased. Only the price of the

supermarket operated service station needs to be monitored and because service station (D) is a

large site, it has two employees working at all times making monitoring more frequent than in

service stations (B) or (C). For this reason, it can be said with confidence that just like service station

(A), service station (D) is at all times matching the lowest price in its local market.

Market Structure of Service Station (D)

Figure 3.2.4

Service station (D) and the three competing service stations lie on the same major road. Motor

vehicles travelling west prefer to drive into the branded independent service station and motor

76

vehicles travelling east prefer either to drive into the supermarket operated service station, the

independent service station or service station (D). There are many traffic lights along this major

road; consequently, motor vehicles travelling one way can change direction if there are price

differences across the service stations. This major road is also not a freeway and contains speed

limits and traffic volumes comparable to the major roads in the local markets of service stations (A)

and (B).

3.4 Demand Functions

3.4.1 Demand functions

The average demand over a 24 hour period to 3pm in a sample service station is given by:

Function 3.4.1

That is, a service station’s sales in litres of diesel or LPG is assumed to be function of its own price in

Australian dollars , a lagged value of its own price , a lagged value of its own

quantity , school holidays , public holidays , a

vector of dummies for the days in a given week and a vector of dummies for the weeks in the

dataset. We also assume that there are no substitute goods, aggregate consumer income to be

unvarying, prices of diesel and LPG to be exogenous, and supply to be unlimited.

All of the dummy variables in the demand functions allow for variation in consumer behaviour.

Variations in consumer behaviour occur for two reasons: (1) preferences and (2) consumer

heterogeneity. An example of variation in consumer behaviour because of different preferences is

two homogenous consumers preferring to purchase fuel on different days of the week. An example

of variation in consumer behaviour because of consumer heterogeneity is two heterogeneous

77

consumers purchasing fuel one being a regular motor vehicle consumer and the other a taxi motor

vehicle consumer.

The purpose of inserting lagged values of own price and own quantity is to capture the dynamic

aspects of the consumer choice problem. Clearly, earlier quantities and prices have effects on the

choices being made today. For instance, we expect demand for diesel to be higher today when

prices decrease from to dollars per litre than when prices increase from to

dollars per litre. Or, we expect demand for diesel to be higher today when litres of diesel were

sold yesterday compared to litres of diesel. Note that we have used time series methods to

reveal how far backward looking consumers are and the autoregressive distributed lag model of

order one, i.e. ADL(1,1), proved to be the only statistically significant ADL model.

The purpose of inserting the school holiday dummy is to capture the effects of consumers using their

motor vehicles less during school holidays. Parents do not drive their children to school and tend to

go on family vacations through semester breaks. The purpose of inserting the public holiday dummy

is similar to that of the school holiday dummy. The purpose of inserting the day dummies in a given

week is to capture the effects of serving different consumers and the effects that stem from the

various stages of the weekly cycle. The purpose of inserting the week dummies in the dataset is to

capture the weekly shocks that may be present during the period of the data.

3.4.2 Specifications

Using the ADL model, F. (3.4.1), for diesel and LPG, we regress the natural log of sales in litres

against the natural log of its own price in Australian dollars, the natural log of the lagged value of its

own price, and the natural log of the lagged value of its own quantity.

Equation 3.4.1

78

Now we extend Eq. (3.4.1) using dummy variables to allow for variation in consumer behaviour on

school holidays, public holidays, different days of the week and different weeks in the dataset. The

dummy represents observations in the dataset that are obtained on school

holidays. The dummy represents observations in the dataset that are obtained on

public holidays. The dummy represents observations in the dataset that are obtained between

3pm on Saturday and 3pm on Sunday. Similarly, the dummy represents Sunday-Monday, the

dummy represents Monday-Tuesday, the dummy represents Tuesday-Wednesday, the

dummy represents Wednesday-Thursday and the dummy represents Thursday-Friday.

The dummies represent observations in the dataset that are obtained during

different weeks in the dataset.

Following this extension, to separate any station specific effects from combining the observations of

four different service stations, we insert three additional dummy variables and

representing the other three service stations in the dataset. Every one of the dummy

variables in the demand equations is introduced both as an intercept and as a slope dummy variable.

The slope dummies illustrate if and when consumers behave differently towards a change in price,

whereas the intercept dummies illustrate if and when a lump-sum amount is required to be added

or taken away from the quantity demand estimate. Eq. (3.4.2) below displays the final demand

equation that we will use to estimate demand for diesel and LPG.

Equation 3.4.2

79

3.4.3 Caveat

In general the ordinary least squares (OLS) procedure is not appropriate when estimating demand

equations. The reason for this is that one of the assumptions that make the OLS estimators the best

linear unbiased estimator (BLUE) is violated. Given that these models are typically determined jointly

with supply, prices are deemed to be endogenous. Therefore, it is more appropriate to use

simultaneous equations methods such as two-stage least squares to estimate the parameters. In the

context of Eq. (3.4.2) however, this does not apply as the four service stations where the

observations are acquired from match the lowest price in the local markets they operate in. At these

prices the service stations sell as much diesel and LPG as consumers demand regardless of cost.

Hence, their prices can be taken as exogenous.

In Chapter 2, there are sections that provide information on how service stations set their prices in

Australia. Information about how service stations match the lowest prices in the local markets they

operate in and how the loss of consumers are negligible while prices change can be obtained from

there. Additionally, in ACCC (2010), there are sections that explain how the petroleum markets in

Australia are all connected to the Asia-Pacific markets and follow the prices in those markets closely.

The reasons for this are that (1) Australia’s demand is too small to affect the Asia-Pacific markets and

(2) the surveillance by the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) do not allow

retail prices to vary from the prices in the Asia-Pacific markets. Consequently, we can consider the

overall prices of diesel and LPG to be exogenous also.

Furthermore, there is no omitted variable bias in Eq. (3.4.2) in terms of the missing price

observations of competing service stations. It is true that the service stations do compete with other

service stations that we do not have data for; however, because the service stations are at all times

matching the lowest price in the local markets they operate in, the effect of any other service station

pricing above this lowest price is considered negligible due to the characteristics of the retail diesel

and LPG industries.

80

Lastly, statistical models that estimate demand functions are generally taken to be linear in the

variables. Alternatively, the log-log form of the model is also frequently used when the relationship

between quantity and price appears non-linear. When deciding on the specification of F. (3.4.1), we

commenced by running the linear and the log-log form prior to trying any other specification within

the OLS estimators. As it turns out, the log-log form of F. (3.4.1) under the ADL model fits the data

the best for diesel and LPG according to the R-Sq value, the statistical significance of the explanatory

variables and the signs of the coefficient estimates.

In the appendix on pages 94-97, there are results for two other demand function specifications for

diesel and LPG. Tables 3.4.1 and 3.4.2 show the reciprocal and linear demand functions for diesel.

Tables 3.4.3 and 3.4.4 show the reciprocal and linear demand functions for LPG. By comparing the

different specifications, it can be seen that the log-log form fits best. We are aware that comparing

the R-Sq values of different specifications is not correct; however, using the statistical significance of

the explanatory variables it can be verified that the log-log form of diesel has less insignificant

estimates than the reciprocal and linear form45. As for LPG, the same applies as the log-log form has

less insignificant estimates than the reciprocal and linear form.

Some of the other specifications we try for F. (3.4.1) include non-linear models using polynomial and

interaction variables, the generalised least squares model, seemingly unrelated regressions model, a

dummy variable specification model with fixed and random effects, and the error components

model. Within all of these models where applicable we try different functional forms, multiple lags

and several interaction variables. None of the models produce better results than the log-log form of

F. (3.4.1). Some of them produce worse overall results (i.e. polynomial variables); some better R-Sq

values but the wrong signs on the coefficient or price elasticity estimates (i.e. linear-log

specification); and others require the elimination of many observations as the dates of observations

from the service stations do not always match (i.e. seemingly unrelated regressions model).

45

In the results tables, T-Stat₁ corrects for heteroskedasticity and T-Stat₂ corrects for autocorrelation.

81

3.5 Diagnostic Tests and Omitted Variables

3.5.1 Diagnostic tests

After undergoing many diagnostic tests, we realise that the results based on Eq. (3.4.2) suffer from

heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation. We carry out the Goldfeld-Quandt test and reject to

conclude that heteroskedasticity exists.

Diesel equation:

First LPG equation:

Second LPG equation:

Additionally, we carry out the Breusch-Godfrey test and reject to conclude that autocorrelation

exists (Obs*R-Sq , and ).

82

3.5.2 Omitted variables

After obtaining the initial estimates for diesel and LPG using Eq. (3.4.2), we decide to omit the

following explanatory variables due to their statistical insignificance.

Firstly, we decide to omit the dummy from the diesel and LPG equations as there is

no variation in the behaviour of consumers during school holidays. This includes no variation in

overall sales and no variation in the way consumers behave towards a change in price.

Secondly, we decide to omit the slope dummy from the diesel and LPG equations as

consumers do not change the way they behave towards a change in price on public holidays. This

result may be caused by the fact that prices do not change during public holidays.

Thirdly, we decide to omit the – slope dummies for the weeks in the dataset

from the diesel and LPG equations. Just like the dummy, the dummies for the

weeks in the dataset do affect overall sales but not the way consumers behave towards a change in

price.

Fourthly, we decide to omit the lagged value of price from the diesel and the second LPG equation.

As the overall price of diesel and the price of LPG between the 27th of April 2005 and the 17th of June

2006 do not cycle, the lagged price losses its explanatory power. This is due to the unpredictability of

the days in which prices of diesel and LPG increase.

Fifthly, we decide to omit the explanatory variables of service station (C) from the diesel equation.

The reason for this is that the diesel pumps in service station (C) are out of order many times during

the period of the data. We are not confident in using these observations to estimate demand for

diesel as the sales of diesel from service station (C) are adversely affected by these incidents as

reported by the operator.

83

3.6 Results

3.6.1 Demand estimates

Tables 3.3.1, 3.3.2 and 3.3.3 below contain the demand estimates for diesel and LPG. Clearly, Eq.

(3.4.2) fits the data well (R-Sq , and ). Most of the coefficient estimates are

significant at the level and more importantly consistent with theoretical expectations. There is

no evidence to suggest that the normal distribution assumption is unreasonable as we fail to reject

using the Jarque-Bera statistic for the estimates. Additionally, we have tackled the problem of

heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using White’s cross-section46 and White’s period47 estimators

(as calculated in EViews). The fact that the results using White’s cross-section and White’s period

standard errors are largely similar to those for the ordinary standard errors, indicate that

heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation do not seem to affect the results.

46

See the T-Stat₁ columns in the results tables. 47

See the T-Stat₂ columns in the results tables.

84

Results for Diesel (Log-Log)

Dependent Variable:

Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂ Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂

NR NR NR

T-Stat₁ is obtained with White’s cross-section estimators. T-Stat₂ is obtained with White’s period estimators. represents Sunday-Monday, represents Monday-

Tuesday, represents Tuesday-Wednesday, represents Wednesday-Thursday, represents Thursday-Friday and represents Friday-Saturday.

Table 3.3.1

85

Results for LPG between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 (Log-Log)

Dependent Variable: )

Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂ Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂

44.02

NR NR NR

T-Stat₁ is obtained with White’s cross-section estimators. T-Stat₂ is obtained with White’s period estimators. represents Sunday-Monday, represents Monday-

Tuesday, represents Tuesday-Wednesday, represents Wednesday-Thursday, represents Thursday-Friday and represents Friday-Saturday.

Table 3.3.2

86

Results for LPG between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006 (Log-Log)

Dependent Variable: )

Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂ Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂

NR NR NR

T-Stat₁ is obtained with White’s cross-section estimators. T-Stat₂ is obtained with White’s period estimators. represents Sunday-Monday, represents Monday-

Tuesday, represents Tuesday-Wednesday, represents Wednesday-Thursday, represents Thursday-Friday and represents Friday-Saturday.

Table 3.3.3

87

The coefficients in the tables are the estimates of the population parameters. For example, the value

in Table 3.3.1 is an estimate for in the diesel equation, an estimate that determines the

amount by which average demand for diesel in service station (D) on a Saturday-Sunday in week 110

decreases when the price of diesel increases. For example, if the price of diesel increases from

to dollars per litre—holding everything else constant—the average demand for diesel in

service station (D) on a Saturday-Sunday in week 110 decreases by multiplied by

. Similarly, the value in Table 3.3.1 is an estimate for in the diesel equation, an

estimate that determines the amount by which average demand for diesel in service station (D)

decreases if it is a public holiday. For example, if it is a public holiday—holding everything else

constant—the average demand for diesel in service station (D) decreases by

.

All of the other point estimates can also be interpreted in this manner. However, just a few notes of

caution. Firstly, the estimates are only good approximations for the regions where the data is

available. For instance, the value in Table 3.3.1 is an estimate for in the diesel equation, the

average demand for diesel when all explanatory variables are equal to zero. This should not be taken

literally since data is not available in this region. Secondly, since the estimates are nonlinear in the

variables, great care should be taken when interpreting them. They are no longer simply the slope

and intercept values as they are in the context of the demand functions presented in section 3.4.1

on p.76. For instance, the estimate for in the diesel equation, , is not the slope value; rather

is the slope value. Thirdly, the estimates are for one particular service station. In

other words, they are the estimates of a residual demand function. The values they take are larger

than the estimates of an aggregate demand function. The reason for this is that the estimates of a

residual demand function reflect the substitution consumers make between service stations.

88

3.6.2 Price elasticities

There are three recent demand estimates for petrol in Australia. One is by Breunig and Gisz (2009),

which use quarterly data from 1966-2006 to estimate aggregate demand. The other two are by

Wang (2009) and Chapter 4 of this dissertation, which use data from Western Australia and

Melbourne to estimate station level demand. Breunig and Gisz (2009) estimate that the aggregate

short-run price elasticity of petrol is around . Wang (2009) estimates that the station level

short-run price elasticities of petrol range from to , depending on the location of the

service stations. In Chapter 4, we estimate that the station level short-run price elasticities of petrol

range from to , depending on the demand during different days of the week. The

discrepancy between Wang’s (2009) estimates and the estimates in Chapter 4 are possibly due to

the 24-hour-rule that is in effect in Western Australia.

Tables 3.3.4, 3.3.5 and 3.3.6 below contain the price elasticity estimates for diesel and LPG. The

estimates show that the short-run price elasticities of diesel range from to and of LPG

from to . The diesel price elasticities are lower than the petrol estimates for Australia,

which is consistent with expectations48. What is striking about the LPG price elasticities is that they

are low in comparison to both petrol and diesel. Given that the price elasticities of LPG are nearly

half the value of petrol indicate that the aggregate short-run price elasticity of LPG is less

than . This is valuable information for policy makers in Australia as it suggests that the ongoing

tax raises on LPG will not have significant effects on the sales of service stations.

48

As most diesel is not purchased at service stations, these price elasticities reveal little about the aggregate price elasticity of diesel.

89

Price elasticities of Diesel

A B D

Days Of The Week Short-Run Elasticity

Short-Run Elasticity

Short-Run Elasticity

Saturday-Sunday Sunday-Monday Monday-Tuesday

Tuesday-Wednesday Wednesday-Thursday

Thursday-Friday Friday-Saturday Average Price

Average Quantity

Table 3.3.4

Price elasticities of LPG between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005

B D

Days Of The Week Short-Run Elasticity

Short-Run Elasticity

Saturday-Sunday Sunday-Monday Monday-Tuesday Tuesday-Wednesday Wednesday-Thursday Thursday-Friday Friday-Saturday Average Price

Table 3.3.5

Price elasticities of LPG between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006

A B C D

Days Of The Week Short-Run Elasticity

Short-Run Elasticity

Short-Run Elasticity

Short-Run Elasticity

Saturday-Sunday Sunday-Monday Monday-Tuesday Tuesday-Wednesday Wednesday-Thursday Thursday-Friday Friday-Saturday Average Price

Table 3.3.6

90

3.6.3 Summary

Both the demand and price elasticity estimates reveal important details about the diesel and LPG

markets. Firstly, the price elasticity estimates in Tables 3.3.5 and 3.3.6 on p.89 suggest that LPG

consumers are aware of the price cycles. Concentrating on Table 3.3.5, we can see that when retail

prices of LPG cycle with price increases that occur on a Saturday-Sunday, the price elasticities are

low during the middle of the week and high on a Saturday-Sunday. However, in Table 3.3.6, when

retail prices of LPG do not cycle, the price elasticities are low towards the end of the week and high

on a Wednesday-Thursday.

The second important detail the demand and price elasticity estimates reveal about the diesel and

LPG markets is the existence of intertemporal substitution. The statistical significance of lagged price

in Table 3.3.2 on p.85 suggests that earlier prices influence the choices consumers make today when

retail prices cycle. The fact that lagged price loses its explanatory power in Tables 3.3.1 and 3.3.3 on

p.84 and p.86, indicate that the cycles, meaning the predictability of the days in which price

increases occur, allow consumers to time their purchases. This finding strongly suggests that the LPG

consumers are aware of the cycles.

The third important detail the demand and price elasticity estimates reveal about the diesel and LPG

markets is the irrelevance of school holidays on the demand for diesel and LPG. As we mentioned in

section 3.5.2 on p.82, we remove the dummy from the demand equations of both

diesel and LPG because they have no identifiable effect on sales. None of the service stations in this

chapter display any correlation between their sales figures or the way their consumers behave

towards a change in price on school holidays.

The fourth important detail the demand and price elasticity estimates reveal about the diesel and

LPG markets is the difference in the behaviour of light-heavy rigid motor vehicle consumers and

regular motor vehicle consumers. The information about which type of consumer purchases diesel

91

from each service station is provided by the operators and the findings confirm its accuracy.

According to the operators, service stations (A) and (D) predominantly sell diesel to light-heavy rigid

motor vehicle consumers whereas service station (B) sells diesel to regular motor vehicle consumers.

From Table 3.3.4 on p.89, we can confirm that this information is correct as service stations (A)’s and

(D)’s price elasticities are lower on weekdays but higher on weekends and vice versa for service

station (B). The reason for this pattern is that most light-heavy rigid motor vehicle consumers

purchase diesel on weekdays (as they do not operate on weekends) whereas most regular motor

vehicle consumers purchase diesel on weekends.

The fifth important detail the demand and price elasticity estimates reveal about the diesel and LPG

markets is the difference in the behaviour of taxi motor vehicle consumers and regular motor vehicle

consumers. The information about which type of consumer purchases LPG from each service station

is provided by the operators and the results confirm its accuracy. According to the operators, service

station (C) predominantly sells LPG to taxi motor vehicle consumers whereas service stations (B) and

(D) sell LPG to regular motor vehicle consumers. From Table 3.3.6, we can confirm that this

information is correct as service station (C)’s price elasticities are lower than the price elasticities of

service stations (A) and (D). We expect taxi motor vehicle consumers to have lower price elasticities

than regular motor vehicle consumers because drivers generally take on the duty of filling LPG, not

the owners. What the drivers are concerned with is preventing time spent off the road as they are

compensated for what they pay for LPG by the owner.

3.7 Conclusion

This chapter provides station level demand estimates for diesel and LPG in four service stations that

operate in metropolitan Melbourne. The estimates predict that the short-run price elasticities of

diesel are between to and of LPG between to . The diesel estimates are

lower than the petrol estimates in Wang (2009) and Chapter 4, which is in harmony with the fact

that there are no substitutes for motor vehicles that use diesel. The LPG estimates are nearly half

92

the value of petrol and diesel, which suggests that the aggregate short-run price elasticity of LPG is

less than . This information is valuable for policy makers in Australia as it suggests that the

ongoing tax raises on LPG will not have significant effects on the sales of service stations.

The demand and price elasticity estimates reveal important details about the diesel and LPG

markets. Firstly, the change in the price elasticity estimates of LPG over the two periods reveals that

LPG consumers are aware of the price cycles. Secondly, the statistical significance of lagged price

during the cycling phase of LPG reveals that earlier prices influence the choices consumers make

today when retail prices cycle. Thirdly, the dummy having no identifiable effect on

the sales of diesel and LPG reveals that school holidays do not affect demand for diesel and LPG.

Fourthly, the difference between the price elasticity estimates for weekdays and weekends in the

diesel market reveals that light-heavy rigid motor vehicle consumers behave differently than regular

motor vehicle consumers. Fifthly, the difference between the price elasticity estimates for service

station (C) and service stations (B) and (D) in the LPG market reveals that taxi motor vehicle

consumers behave differently than regular motor vehicle consumers.

93

Bibliography

Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) (2006) Senate Economics Legislation

Committee inquiry into the price of petrol in Australia. Canberra: ACCC.

——(2010) Monitoring of the Australian Petroleum Industry. Canberra: ACCC.

Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics (ABARE) Mining Statistics 2000-2008

(n.d.) [Online]. Available: http://www.abare.gov.au/publicationshtml/ams/ams_10/ams_10.html

[Accessed 01 January 2011]

Australian Institute of Petroleum (AIP) Facts on Diesel Prices and the Australian Fuel Market (n.d.)

[Online]. Available:http://www.aip.com.au/pricing/pdf/Facts%20about%20Diesel%20Prices%20and

%20the%20Australian%20Fuel%20Market.pdf [Accessed 01 January 2011].

Breunig, R.V. and Gisz, C. (2009) An Exploration of Australian Petrol Demand: Unobservable Habits,

Irreversibility and Some Updated Estimates. The Economic Record. 85(268): 73-91.

LPG Autogas Australia (n.d.) [Online]. Available: http://www.lpgautogas.com.au/index.cfm [Accessed

01 January 2009].

Wang, Z. (2009) Station Level Gasoline (Petrol) Demand in an Australian Market with Regular Price

Cycles. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics. 53(4): 467-483.

94

Appendix: Different Specifications

Results for Diesel (Reciprocal)

Dependent Variable:

Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂ Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂

NR NR NR

T-Stat₁ is obtained with White’s cross-section estimators. T-Stat₂ is obtained with White’s period estimators. represents Sunday-Monday, represents Monday-

Tuesday, represents Tuesday-Wednesday, represents Wednesday-Thursday, represents Thursday-Friday and represents Friday-Saturday.

Table 3.4.1

95

Results for Diesel (Linear)

Dependent Variable:

Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂ Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂

NR NR NR

T-Stat₁ is obtained with White’s cross-section estimators. T-Stat₂ is obtained with White’s period estimators. represents Sunday-Monday, represents Monday-

Tuesday, represents Tuesday-Wednesday, represents Wednesday-Thursday, represents Thursday-Friday and represents Friday-Saturday.

Table 3.4.2

96

Results for LPG between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 (Reciprocal)

Dependent Variable:

Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂ Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂

NR NR NR

T-Stat₁ is obtained with White’s cross-section estimators. T-Stat₂ is obtained with White’s period estimators. represents Sunday-Monday, represents Monday-

Tuesday, represents Tuesday-Wednesday, represents Wednesday-Thursday, represents Thursday-Friday and represents Friday-Saturday. Table 3.4.3

97

Results for LPG between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 (Linear)

Dependent Variable:

Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂ Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂

NR NR NR

T-Stat₁ is obtained with White’s cross-section estimators. T-Stat₂ is obtained with White’s period estimators. represents Sunday-Monday, represents Monday-

Tuesday, represents Tuesday-Wednesday, represents Wednesday-Thursday, represents Thursday-Friday and represents Friday-Saturday.

Table 3.4.4

98

4. Competition or Price Discrimination? The Price Cycles in Petrol

Retailing

4.1 Introduction

The cause of the price cycles in petrol retailing is a lingering policy question for both academics and

government authorities. Over the last decade, there have been many papers written in Australia,

Canada and other parts of the world (ACCC 2006, 2007, 2010a, 2010b; Atkinson 2009; Bloch 2010;

Doyle 2008; Eckert 2002, 2003; Eckert & West 2004; Foros & Steen 2008; Lewis 2009; Lewis & Noel

2011; Noel 2007, 2011; Wang 2009a, 2009b) either dealing with the question directly or indirectly.

From the first publication released by the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC),

which was in year 2000, the question of why retail prices of petrol cycle still remains for the most

part unanswered.

There are two reasons why the results of previous papers have not been decisive. The first reason is

the lack of quantity data. It is extremely difficult to carry out a robust study without quantity data

from multiple service stations that come from a region that is free of pricing restrictions and with

existent cycles. The second reason is the difficulty of separating the predictions of the Edgeworth

cycles model (Maskin & Tirole 1988) from the price discrimination model (Conlisk et al. 1984). In

practice, due to the characteristics of the retail petrol industry and the surveillance by government

bodies for collusive behaviour, to differentiate between the two models is troublesome. There are

distinct differences, but to identify them empirically is a demanding task.

For example, in the Edgeworth cycles model, the cycles are shown to end when prices reach

marginal cost. While in the price discrimination model, the cycles are shown to end when prices

reach the reservation price of low willingness to pay consumers. This is a noticeable difference in the

predictions of the two models. However, in reality, when the reservation price of low willingness to

pay consumers is lower than marginal cost, both models converge and predict that the cycles should

99

end when prices reach marginal cost. Or, as another example, in the Edgeworth cycles model, the

cycles are shown to restart just above the monopoly price. While in the price discrimination model,

the cycles are shown to restart at the reservation price of high willingness to pay consumers. This

again is a noticeable difference in the predictions of the two models. However, in reality, when the

surveillance by government bodies places an upper limit on retail prices of petrol, to test the validity

of service stations restarting the cycles at the reservation price of high willingness to pay consumers

becomes impractical.

Furthermore, the Edgeworth cycles model and the current explanations for the cycles in petrol

retailing predict price differences across service stations. To date, there has been no empirical

evidence in any literature to support this prediction. Wang (2009a) claims to provide evidence and

validate this prediction by presenting high and varying price elasticities of petrol in eight service

stations that operate in Western Australia. However, the data in Wang (2009a) is collected at a time

when the retail market is under severe restrictions by regulatory authorities and the service stations

are not allowed to change their prices to match or beat their competitors’ prices. As a result, the

findings in Wang (2009a) are less relevant outside of Western Australia.

The first purpose of this chapter is to identify differences in the predictions of the Edgeworth cycles

model and the price discrimination model that can be empirically analysed. The objective of

performing this task is to allow future research with appropriate data to determine which model is

more consistent with retail petrol industry. Outside of the Edgeworth cycles model, the only other

model to have been mentioned in the petrol literature is the price discrimination model (Atkinson

2009; Noel 2011). There are other models that can explain why retail prices cycle (see Doyle 1983),

but there is no apparent relationship between them and the cycles in petrol retailing. At this present

time, the Edgeworth cycles model and the price discrimination model are the only two models that

can be considered relevant to the retail petrol industry.

100

Following this exercise, the focus of the chapter turns to providing station level demand estimates

for petrol in service stations that operate under regular conditions. What we mean by regular

conditions is that service stations are allowed to change their prices without any restraints and as

many times as they desire. The objective of obtaining station level demand estimates is to test the

prediction that there are price differences across service stations. For instance, if service stations are

undercutting each other’s price, the service stations in local markets with higher levels of

competition should produce larger price elasticities. However, if service stations are matching each

other’s price, then all service stations regardless of the level of competition should produce similar

price elasticities.

The dataset we use consists of intraday observations on retail prices49 and quantities sold of petrol

during the years of 2004, 2005 and 2006. We obtain the data directly from the on-site computer

systems of four service stations, which on a daily basis—24 hour period to 3pm—report the volume

of sales in litres at the registered prices of petrol. For instance, at 3pm on the 23rd of April 2006, the

computer system of one of the service stations reports the sale of litres of petrol at the

price of dollars per litre and litres of petrol at the price of dollars per litre. This

sales report accounts for all petrol sold from that particular service station between 3pm on the 22nd

of April 2006 and 3pm on the 23rd of April 2006.

The service stations that we estimate demand for are located in the metropolitan area of Melbourne

and compete in different local markets. Due to a confidentiality agreement with the operators, we

will not disclose their position and brand name. We have labelled them (A), (B), (C) and (D) to allow

fluency when writing. The service stations have freedom to set whatever price they desire. Also, the

local markets of the service stations contain different levels of competition. For instance, service

station (B) is isolated from its competitors with its nearest competitor 5.2km away. Whereas service

station (A) competes in a local market against three independent service stations that lie 250m to

49

Prices are in nominal terms as (1) inflation during the period of the data is very low and (2) there are no daily indices available for inflation.

101

the east of service station (A). Moreover, the local markets of the service stations contain different

combinations of service station types; for instance, some with oil major sites and others with

supermarket operated sites.

This chapter is organised as follows. In section 4.2 we summarise the Edgeworth cycles model and

state its predictions. In section 4.3 we specify the price discrimination model and state its

predictions. In section 4.4 we identify differences in the predictions of the Edgeworth cycles model

and the price discrimination model that can be empirically analysed. In section 4.5 we describe the

data and provide details about the service stations. In section 4.6 we measure the distance of service

stations operating in metropolitan Melbourne from their closest competitor. In section 4.7 we show

the demand function that we use to estimate station level demand. In section 4.8 we apply some

diagnostic tests to the estimators and discuss why we omit certain explanatory variables. In section

4.9 we present the results. In section 4.10 we conclude the chapter.

4.2 Edgeworth Cycles Model

The ‘Edgeworth cycles’ theory was first introduced by Edgeworth (1925) and later developed into a

model by Maskin and Tirole (1988). It is by far the main explanation given to the price cycles

observed in the retail petrol industry (ACCC 2010a; Doyle 2008; Eckert 2002, 2003; Eckert & West

2004; Lewis 2009; Lewis & Noel 2011; Noel 2007, 2011; Wang 2009a, 2009b). In this section, we

provide a summary of the Edgeworth cycles model—a version of the model that appears in Atkinson

(2009), Noel (2007), Lewis and Noel (2011) and Wang (2009a)—to outline its predictions.

Augmentations to the model can be found in Doyle (2008), Noel (2008) and Wang (2009b). We do

not include any of these modifications because they do not affect the basic predictions of the

Edgeworth cycles model. In Atkinson (2009), the predictions that we outline are presented in a table.

The only prediction that is missing is the prediction that price decreases occur more commonly on

high demand periods relative to price increases. This prediction is acquired from Wang (2009a). For a

mathematical presentation of the Edgeworth cycles model, Noel (2007) can be referred to.

102

4.2.1 Edgeworth cycles model

Assume a market for a homogeneous product. Time is discrete and agents are infinite lived. There

are two identical sellers that try to maximise their present discounted value by alternately setting

price. Marginal cost is assumed to be constant for both sellers and no fixed costs or capacity

constraints exist. If sellers charge the same price which induces consumers to buy, then each seller

attracts the same number of consumers; the total number of consumers is split evenly in half.

Otherwise the lowest priced seller serves the entire market. Pricing strategy of each seller is Markov;

in other words, the pricing strategy depends on the other seller’s price from the previous period and

constant marginal cost. Using this model it can be shown that many Markov perfect equilibria exist,

including Edgeworth cycles.

The Edgeworth cycles equilibrium can be described as follows. The equilibrium begins with one seller

undercutting the price of the other seller by one unit50. The seller whose price is undercut then

responds by undercutting also. Each seller decides to undercut price because their pricing strategy is

Markov. Sellers repeatedly undercut one another to steal market share until price reaches marginal

cost. Then a war of attrition begins with each seller waiting for the other with a positive probability

to restore price back up to its original level51. Sellers can be reluctant in restoring price back up

because it results in them undergoing two consecutive periods of zero profits. Sellers play standard

mixed strategies to decide which seller is to restore price back up. Ultimately the price is restored

back up by one seller and a cycle appears; hence, the Edgeworth cycles equilibrium.

The basic Edgeworth cycles model can be extended by allowing the two sellers to differ in size; in

this case sellers do not split the market evenly at equal prices (see Eckert 2003). In terms of the retail

petrol industry, this can be thought of as one seller operating more service stations than the other.

Using this modified model it can be shown that there are incentives for the larger seller to lead price

50

The undercutting phase. 51

The relenting phase.

103

increases and for the smaller seller to lead price decreases. The cost for the larger seller of waiting

for the price to be restored back up to its original level in the relenting phase is greater than for the

smaller seller and vice versa in the undercutting phase.

The assumption of sellers being dependent on price sensitive consumers can be used to predict that

price decreases will be more common on high demand periods relative to price increases. In Wang

(2009a), it is stated that if consumers are not price sensitive, Edgeworth cycles will not exist. In

terms of the retail petrol industry, high demand periods can be thought of as periods where

consumers are price sensitive while low demand periods can be thought of as periods where

consumers are not price sensitive. The relevance of high demand periods to price sensitive

consumers is the motive for sellers to undercut price expecting the gains from the additional

consumers to outweigh inframarginal losses. In view of this, we can expect price decreases to be

more common on high demand periods relative to low demand periods where idleness or price

increases will be more common.

4.2.2 Predictions

The predictions of both the basic Edgeworth Cycles model and the Eckert (2003) extension are

written in Table 4.1.1 below. There are seven predictions (ECN1-ECN7) that relate to the general

pricing dynamics of the retail petrol industry and one prediction (ECB1) that relates to pricing

patterns that may appear because of the ownership structure of service stations.

104

Predictions of the Edgeworth Cycles Model

(ECN1) Prices increase by large amounts in a single period, but decrease by small amounts over several periods.

(ECN2) Prices increase when they reach marginal cost.

(ECN3) When prices increase, they increase above the monopoly price so that the seller raising the price will be able to charge the monopoly price when its competitor undercuts its price in the following period.

(ECN4) Prices at the retail level cycle, even if wholesale prices are constant.

(ECN5) Price decreases are more common on high demand periods and price increases are more common on low demand periods.

(ECN6) Lengths of cycles are random.

(ECN7) Price differences across sellers.

(ECB1) Sellers that control relatively more sites tend to lead price increases and sellers that control relatively fewer sites tend to lead price decreases.

Table 4.1.1

4.3 Price Discrimination Model

A model that demonstrates how price cycles can be used to discriminate between high and low

valuation consumers appears in Conlisk et al. (1984). In this section, we specify a short version of this

model. It should be noted that an extension to this model is available; namely, Sobel (1984). The

relevant extensions are introduced in section 4.3.2 on p.106. The decision to specify the price

discrimination model rather than summarise is due to the price discrimination model not being

specified in any other petrol literature. Most of the assumptions, propositions and results are taken

from Conlisk et al. (1984) and Sobel (1984).

4.3.1 Price discrimination model

Assume a market for an infinitely durable product. Time is discrete and agents are fully informed,

rational and infinite lived.

105

The demand side includes consumers entering the market each period. All consumers are price

takers. There is minimum degree of consumer heterogeneity: who value the product at

dollars per period and – who value the product at dollars per period. and

. Consumers who value the product at dollars are referred to as ‘high’ consumers

and consumers who value the product at dollars are referred to as ‘low’ consumers. Consumers

discount the product at factor with . No consumer is allowed to buy more than one

unit of the product; and the consumers who decide not to buy stay in the market indefinitely.

Reselling the product is not permitted.

The supply side includes a monopolist setting price nonstochastically each period to maximise

present discounted value, calculated at discount factor with . Cost per unit is

assumed to be constant and equal to zero. Renting is disallowed; and any commitment about future

pricing is not binding.

In situations where agents are indifferent between acting immediately and acting later, it is assumed

that they choose to act immediately. More specifically, if a consumer is equal between purchasing

the product now and purchasing the product at a lower price later, the consumer is assumed to

purchase the product now. If the monopolist is equal between holding a sale now and holding a sale

later, the monopolist is assumed to hold a sale now. ‘Hold a sale’ refers to the situation where the

monopolist sets the price low enough to sell to low consumers.

Using this framework, it can be shown that the motivation for a single seller to hold periodic sales to

discriminate between high and low valuation consumers exists. The propositions in Table 4.1.2

below are used to arrive at this result. Refer to Appendix 4.1 on p.142 for a proof of each

proposition.

106

Propositions from Conlisk et al. (1984)

Proposition 1. The reservation price of a high consumer is

. The reservation

price of a low consumer is

.

Proposition 2. To maximise profits the monopolist follows a cyclic price path.

Proposition 3. The monopolist’s pricing strategy in equilibrium for a given must be

where , is the cycle length and are the prices in each period of the cycle.

Proposition 4. Prices follow an asymmetric pattern and display a constant range

equal to .

Proposition 5. The cycle length is unvarying and equal to

Table 4.1.2

4.3.2 Extension

The extension to the model in Conlisk et al. (1984) can be found in Sobel (1984). Sobel modifies the

model to determine if the motivation to hold periodic sales still remains if the single seller (the

monopolist) is replaced by multiple sellers. Relevant sections from this model are specified below.

Assume a market for an infinitely durable product. Time is discrete and agents are risk neutral, fully

informed, rational and infinite lived.

The demand side includes consumers entering the market each period. All consumers are price

takers. There is minimum degree of consumer heterogeneity: who value the product at

dollars per period and – who value the product at dollars per period. and

. Consumers who value the product at dollars are referred to as ‘high’ consumers

and consumers who value the product at dollars are referred to as ‘low’ consumers. Consumers

discount the product at factor with . No consumer is allowed to buy more than one

107

unit of the product; and the consumers who decide not to buy stay in the market indefinitely.

Reselling the product is not permitted.

The supply side includes a fixed number of identical sellers with . The th seller sets its

price taking the prices of other sellers as given to maximise its present discounted value

calculated at discount factor with 52. Cost per unit of each seller is assumed to be

constant and equal to zero. Renting for any seller is disallowed and any commitment made about

future pricing is not binding.

In situations where agents are indifferent between acting immediately and acting later, it is assumed

that they choose to act immediately. More specifically, if a consumer is equal between purchasing

the product now and purchasing the product at a lower price later, the consumer is assumed to

purchase the product now. If a seller is equal between holding a sale now and holding a sale later,

the seller is assumed to hold a sale now. ‘Hold a sale’ refers to the situation where a seller sets price

low enough to sell to low consumers.

It is assumed that all sellers have an ‘agreement’ to charge higher prices to high consumers. The

agreement involves certain sellers leading price changes while others follow53. It is assumed that the

loss in profits while prices are being adjusted is negligible. Any defects result in sellers returning to

‘simple strategies’; a pricing strategy that depends only on the number of high and low consumers in

the market and not on the behaviour of other sellers. If more than one seller charges the same price

which induces consumers to buy, then it is assumed that each seller attracts the same number of

consumers and the total number of consumers is split evenly between the sellers.

52

It is assumed that the discount factor is the same across all sellers. 53

The price leader and follower assumption does not appear in Sobel (1984), as the agreement between sellers to charge higher prices is left more general. However, we choose to use this assumption as it is the most plausible way in which sellers in the retail petrol industry could coordinate prices. The choice of using this assumption has no effect on the model or the results in Sobel (1984).

108

Using this framework, it can be shown that the motivation to hold periodic sales still remains even if

the single seller is replaced by multiple sellers. The propositions in Table 4.1.3 below are used to

arrive at this result. Refer to Appendix 4.1 on p.142 for a proof of each proposition.

Propositions from Sobel (1984)

Proposition 6. The level of total profit in any equilibrium can be attained in a symmetric equilibrium.

Proposition 7. If the gains from keeping to the agreement exceed that of defecting, a non-cooperative equilibrium with monopoly profits will result.

Table 4.1.3

4.3.3 Predictions

The predictions of the price discrimination model in Conlisk et al. (1984) together with the Sobel

(1984) extensions are written in Table 4.1.4 below. There are seven predictions (PDN1-PDN7) that

relate to the general pricing dynamics of the retail petrol industry.

Predictions of the Price Discrimination Model

(PDN1) Prices increase by large amounts in a single period, but decrease by small amounts over several periods.

(PDN2) Prices increase when they reach the reservation price of low willingness to pay consumers.

(PDN3) When prices increase, they increase to the reservation price of high willingness to pay consumers.

(PDN4) Prices at the retail level cycle, even if wholesale prices are constant.

(PDN5) Price decreases occur as a sale approaches nearer and price increases occur once low willingness to pay consumers have made their purchases.

(PDN6) Lengths of cycles are not random.

(PDN7) Price matching between sellers.

Table 4.1.4

109

4.4 Differences in the Two Models

4.4.1 Differences in the predictions

In this section, we identify differences in the predictions of the Edgeworth cycles model and the

price discrimination model that can be empirically analysed. There are some similarities in the

predictions of the two models such as prediction (ECN1) and (PDN1), where both maintain that

prices increase by large amounts in a single period but decrease by small amounts over several

periods. We do not discuss any similarities as such, since this information is easily accessible from

the above sections. We only discuss the differences, and differences that are identifiable in practice.

Table 4.1.5 below contains a summary of the differences including the types of data required to

identify them.

Differences in the Predictions

Predictions Edgeworth Cycles

Model Price Discrimination

Model Types of Data

Required

Cycle Lengths Random

Aggregate or Station Level Daily Price

Observations

Price Increases Low Demand Immediately after a

Sale Occurs

Station Level Intraday Price Observations

Including the Time of the Price Changes

Price Decreases High Demand Consistently as a Sale Approaches Nearer

Station Level Intraday Price Observations

Including the Time of the Price Changes

Response to Price Changes

Price Cutting Price Matching

Station Level Intraday Price Observations from Every Service

Station in a Particular Local Market

Table 4.1.5

110

There are three differences in the predictions of the two models. The first difference is between

(ECN6) and (PDN6). (ECN6) claims that the lengths of the cycles are random. In other words, the

number of days retail prices of petrol decrease is random. It can decrease for five days, eleven days

or any number of days. The probability of each day is exactly the same. Whereas (PDN6) claims that

the lengths of the cycles are not random. In other words, the number of days retail prices of petrol

decrease is not random. If there are no structural adjustments such as marginal cost changing, it will

always decrease for (

) number of days. ( )

can be any number of days depending on the parameters, but it is constant and not random.

We elected to discuss this particular difference first because it is the easiest to apply to the retail

petrol industry. It is clear from (ECN6) that if the Edgeworth cycles model is consistent with the retail

petrol industry, we should observe cycles that are random in length. However, if the price

discrimination model is consistent with the retail petrol industry, we should observe cycles that are

matching in length. If future research can obtain data on retail prices of petrol and marginal cost, it

can use this difference between (ECN6) and (PDN6) to determine which model is more consistent

with the retail petrol industry by analysing cycle lengths.

The second difference in the predictions of the two models is between (ECN5) and (PDN5). (ECN5)

claims that price decreases are more common on high demand periods and price increases are more

common on low demand periods. In other words, service stations will generally decrease their prices

when demand for petrol is high and increase their prices when demand for petrol is low. For

instance, let’s assume that demand for petrol in Melbourne peaks between 6am-10am and 3pm-

6pm. What this means in the context of the Edgeworth cycles model is that service stations will

mainly decrease their prices during these peak hours. Or said differently, service stations will rarely

decrease their prices at say 12am as it is not effective in stealing market share from its competitors.

As for (PDN5), it claims that price decreases occur as a sale approaches nearer and price increases

occur once low willingness to pay consumers have made their purchases. In other words, (1) that

111

service stations decrease their prices because they desire to sell to high willingness to pay

consumers and to do so they are required to keep discounting the price of petrol as a sale

approaches nearer and (2) that service stations increase their prices immediately after a sale occurs.

The reason for service stations increasing their prices immediately after a sale occurs is because the

accumulation of low willingness to pay consumers will clear; thus, making sales to high willingness to

pay consumers at a higher price more profitable. Similar to the first difference, if future research can

obtain data on when price changes occur they can use this difference between (ECN5) and (PDN5) to

determine which model is more consistent with the retail petrol industry.

The third difference in the predications of the two models is between (ECN7) and (PDN7). (ECN7)

claims that there are price differences across sellers. In other words, when service stations decrease

or increase their price, they always beat their competitors’ prices. Accordingly, we should never see

service stations with matching prices. Under the Edgeworth cycles model there is only one state

when service stations act contrary to (ECN7). This is when price reaches marginal cost and all service

stations wait for the cycle to be reset. At this stage all service stations have the same price.

Nevertheless, this state is negligible in the greater scheme of things.

As for (PDN7), it claims that there are price matching between sellers. In other words, there are

certain service stations that take the lead in making price changes, and other service stations that

follow their lead by matching their price. This type of behaviour might develop from an agreement

among service stations or from particular service stations recognising the opportunity to price

discriminate while others follow due to price matching being the best response. Either way, under

(PDN7) we should not observe price differences across service stations except for very short periods

when prices are being adjusted. Otherwise if there are losses in market share when prices are being

adjusted, service stations will decline to follow this strategy.

Both (ECN7) and (PDN7) place distinct restrictions on the way service stations carry themselves. In

short, if the Edgeworth cycles model is consistent with the retail petrol industry, we should never

112

observe service stations with the same price as its competitors. One should be higher or lower, not

equal. Also, in between price changes there should be a sufficient amount of time before

competitors can respond with their own price cuts. If this time in between price cuts is not long

enough, it wouldn’t be worthwhile for service stations to compete against each other because the

profits earned from the price cuts would not be justifiable. Accordingly, (ECN7) rules out suggestions

like ‘service stations move sequentially however price changes occur so rapidly that they appear to

move simultaneously’. This type of suggestion eliminates all incentives to decrease price in the first

place and hence is absurd. If the price discrimination model is consistent with the retail petrol

industry, we should observe the opposite of what we have just described.

4.4.2 Structural difference

In this section we point out a structural difference between the Edgeworth cycles model and the

price discrimination model that can be used to determine why retail prices of petrol cycle.

To begin with, we will highlight two assumptions that each model relies on starting with the

Edgeworth cycles model. The Edgeworth cycles model relies on two assumptions for it to be

consistent with the retail petrol industry. The first is price cutting between service stations. The

second is consumers that are price sensitive. If the price of service stations match or if consumers do

not respond to price decreases, the Edgeworth cycles model cannot be consistent with the retail

petrol industry.

The price discrimination model also relies on two assumptions for it to be consistent with the retail

petrol industry. The first is price matching between service stations. The second is consumers that

have heterogeneous valuations for petrol. If service stations undercut one another or if consumers

have homogenous valuations for petrol, the price discrimination model cannot be consistent with

the retail petrol industry. These two assumptions from each model will be the basis for the structural

difference we will point out.

113

We will now highlight certain details about the structure of the retail petrol industry. The retail

petrol industry is made up of service stations that sell petrol directly to consumers. There are

currently four different types of service stations that retail petrol in Melbourne; in other countries

there may be more. Moreover, the location of the service stations in a given area is not random.

Service stations locate themselves in places that have more consumers and that are easy to access

by motor vehicles. Depending on the number of consumers, certain areas may have up to five

service stations operating. Larger the consumer base, the more service stations an area can

accommodate. Service stations come to realise how many sites one particular area can

accommodate through entry and exit.

Furthermore, in the larger market for petrol, smaller local markets exist. For instance, it is reported

in Chapter 2 that service station operators admit to only following the prices of service stations that

operate in their local markets. There is also data provided in Chapter 2, which suggests that the

prices of neighbouring local markets do not affect one another. These details are also consistent

with the fact that it is not worth consumers to travel long distances to save a few cents on petrol as

the costs outweigh the savings. The reason for discussing the structure of the retail petrol industry is

that it makes the structural difference we will point out simpler to understand.

We will now present the structural difference between the two models. Firstly, it follows from the

structure of the retail petrol industry that there are some service stations that face limited

competition and other service stations that face intense competition. For instance, a suburb that has

a small population is only able to accommodate one service station. Whereas a suburb that has a

large population is be able to accommodate four or five service stations. For simplicity, if we assume

that service stations evenly share the total number of consumers in their local markets when their

prices are matching, which is what both models assume, we can confidently say that there will be

service stations that face different levels of competition in the retail petrol industry.

114

For instance, let’s take two local markets that are polar opposites. The first local market has one

service station and the second local market has four service stations. If the Edgeworth cycles model

is consistent with the retail petrol industry and if competition can be used to explain why retail

prices of petrol cycle, then the service stations operating in these two local markets should have

different price elasticities. Under the assumption that service stations will evenly split the total

number of consumers, the service stations in the second local market should have price elasticities

that are four times as large as the service station in the first local market.

Figure 4.1.1 below displays a sample demand equation for the service station in the first local

market. Figure 4.1.2 below displays a sample demand equation for one of the service stations in the

second local market. The demand equations in Figures 4.1.1 and 4.1.2 are drawn from a log-log

specification with price elasticities equal to and respectively. We use a log-log specification due

to the simple properties it entails. The demand curves basically inform us that when the price of

petrol decreases by , quantity will increase by at the service station in the first local market

and by at the service stations in the second local market.

Local Market with One Service Station

Price

Qu

anti

ty D

eman

d o

ver

a 24

Ho

ur

Peri

od

Residual Demand for PetrolLocal Market with One Service Station

Qd

Figure 4.1.1

115

Local Market with Multiple Service Stations

Price

Qu

anti

ty D

eman

d o

ver

a 24

Ho

ur

Peri

od

Residual Demand for PetrolLocal Market with Multiple Service Stations

Qd

Figure 4.1.2

It may be asked ‘why would the service station in the second local market have a price elasticity that

is four times as large as the service station in the first local market if the Edgeworth cycles model is

consistent with the retail petrol industry?’ As the demand curve in Figure 4.1.1 displays, the demand

for petrol at the service station in the first local market is quite flat. The reason for this is that when

the service station in the first local market decreases its price, it increases petrol sales by only

acquiring additional low willingness to pay consumers. It does not however increase petrol sales by

stealing market share from other service stations.

On the other hand, as the demand curve in Figure 4.1.2 displays, the demand for petrol at the

service station in the second local market is steep. The reason for this is that when the service

station in the second local market decreases its price, it increases petrol sales by not only acquiring

additional low willingness to pay consumers, but also stealing market share from the other three

service stations. Recall that under the Edgeworth cycles model, when service stations decrease their

price, they decrease it below their competitors. Consequently, the service station in the second local

market will have a price elasticity that is four times as large as the service station in the first local

market.

116

In short, if the Edgeworth cycles model is consistent with the retail petrol industry, we should

observe service stations that have different price elasticities. The price elasticities of each service

station will depend on how many service stations operate in its local market and its closeness to its

competitors. The closer service stations are to each other, the more consumers each service station

can steal from its competitors when it decreases its price because consumers do not have to travel

as far and can observe prices directly. The further away each station is from its competitors, the

more it costs consumers to observe prices; so less likely they will substitute across service stations

when prices are decreased.

Alternatively, if the price discrimination model is consistent with the retail petrol industry, we should

observe limited differences in the price elasticities of service stations. The price elasticities of each

service station will only reflect the acquisition of additional low willingness to pay consumers when

prices are decreased. Also, any differences in the price elasticities of service stations will be due to

the way consumers vary their behaviour towards a change in price at different local markets. Since

there is no transfer of market share from one service station to another, when prices are decreased

service stations should display similar price elasticities. Recall that in the price discrimination model

service stations match each other’s prices and not undercut, which is the driving force behind this

result.

4.6 Dataset and Service Stations

4.6.1 Dataset

There are intraday observations in the petrol dataset. Between the 9th of May 2004 and the

23rd of April 2005, retail prices of petrol cycle with price increases that occur sometime between

3pm on Saturday and 3pm on Sunday54. And, between the 27th of April 2005 and the 17th of June

2006, retail prices of petrol cycle with price increases that occur sometime between 3pm on

54

See section 2.5.6 on p.33.

117

Wednesday and 3pm on Thursday55. To take account of this change, we separate the dataset into

two groups. The first group contains intraday observations, which includes intraday

observations from service station (B) and intraday observations from service station (D). The

second group contains intraday observations, which includes intraday observations from

service station (A), intraday observations from service station (B), intraday observations

from service station (C), and intraday observations from service station (D).

When employing intraday observations to estimate demand for petrol, we calculate daily weighted

average prices to use them in conjunction with daily quantities. For example, at 3pm on the 27th of

October 2005 the computer system of service station (A) reports the sale of litres of petrol

at the price of dollars per litre and litres of petrol at the price of dollars per

litre. By dividing the sum of by we

obtain the weighted average price for service station (A). By summing we

obtain the total quantity sold for service station (A).

4.6.2 Dates and noteworthy shocks

The observations of service station (A) are from approximately an eight month period that begins on

the 25th of October 2005 and ends on 17th of June 2006. Over this period, service station (A) is not

subject to any noteworthy shock such as a competing service station winding down.

The observations of service station (B) are from approximately a one year and ten month period that

begins on the 5th of August 2004 and ends on 17th of June 2006. Over this period, service station (B)

is not subject to any noteworthy shock such as a competing service station winding down.

The observations of service station (C) are from approximately a six month period that begins on the

1st of January 2006 and ends on 17th of June 2006. Over this period, service station (C) is not subject

to any noteworthy shock such as a competing service station winding down.

55

See section 2.5.6 on p.33.

118

The observations of service station (D) are from approximately a one year and eleven month period

that begins on the 4th of May 2004 and ends on 31st of March 2006. Over this period, service station

(D) is not subject to any noteworthy shock such as a competing service station winding down.

4.6.3 Descriptive statistics

Table 4.2.1 below reports the descriptive statistics for petrol. The highest daily average for sales of

petrol, , is held by service station (B) who sells nearly twice as much as service station (C),

. Service stations (D) and (A) are not far behind service station (B) with daily averages of

and .

Descriptive Statistics for Petrol

Table 4.2.1

The highest variation in the sales of petrol is held by service station (D) which has a standard

deviation of . The other three service stations show similar standard deviations around the

mark. One common thing among the service stations is the non-normality of the distribution

of petrol sales. The Jarque-Bera statistic is equal to in service station (A), in service

station (B), in service station (C) and in service station (D) which are significantly

larger than the critical value of at the level. Therefore, we can conclude with

confidence that the sales observations of petrol are non-normal.

A B C D

Qty

(L)

Price

($)

Qty

(L)

Price

($)

Qty

(L)

Price

($)

Qty

(L)

Price

($)

Range Minimum Maximum Mean Median Standard Deviation Skewness Kurtosis

119

The lowest price of petrol during the dataset is dollars per litre. This price is registered both in

service stations (B) and (D). The highest price of petrol in the dataset is dollars per litre. This

price is registered in service station (A). The service stations exhibit great variation in price and the

observations are spread evenly across this range. The variation in the overall price of petrol is caused

by large movements in the world price of petrol. These exogenous shocks allow more of the demand

curve to be traced out. One thing to note is that service stations (A) and (C) do not have observations

during years of 2004 and most of 2005. During this period the price of petrol is low making the range

of service stations (B) and (D) wider than that of service stations (A) and (C).

4.6.4 Service stations56

Figure 4.2.1 below displays the market structure of service station (A)57. Service station (A) competes

with three independent service stations denoted as (I), which lie 250m to the east. The three

independent service stations lie directly across each other; hence, are approximately equivalent in

distance from where service station (A) is located. The prices of the three independent service

stations are visible from where service station (A) is located. The operator or any employee can walk

to the entrance of the site and identify what prices the independent service stations have set. It can

be said with confidence that service station (A) is at all times matching the lowest price in its local

market.

56

Readers who have read section 2.2.3 on p.11 may skip this section without any loss of continuity. 57

The arrows in the figures report the distance between the service stations.

120

Market Structure of Service Station (A)

Figure 4.2.1

Service station (A) and the top two independent service stations compete for market share when

motor vehicles are travelling east on a major road that runs from where service station (A) is

positioned. The top and bottom independent service stations furthest to the right compete for

market share when motor vehicles are travelling south on a different major road that runs from

where the top independent service station is positioned. There are traffic lights at the intersection of

these two major roads; thus, motor vehicles travelling one way can change direction if there are

price differences across the service stations.

Figure 4.2.2 below displays the market structure of service station (B). Service station (B) competes

with one supermarket operated service station denoted as (S) and three oil major/branded

independent service stations denoted as (OM/BI). The three oil major/branded independent service

stations are labelled (OM/BI) because it is not definite if they are oil major franchisees or branded

independents. From the exterior they both look identical; without any details on how the service

stations are operated, their ownership is not identifiable. Service station (B) in contrast to service

station (A) is isolated from its competitors. The nearest service station lies 5.2km to the west. Service

station (B) monitors the prices of competing service stations through shift changes for the reason

that it is so distant from where its competitors lie. The operator of service station (B) also receives

121

considerable help from the owner58, who informs him of any updates received from the oil major or

other operators. The operator of service station (B) states that even if they are not able to match

their competitors’ prices instantly because of their location, they are quick to respond. He openly

claims that the loss of consumers from the delay is insignificant.

Market Structure of Service Station (B)

Figure 4.2.2

The top oil major/branded independent service station and the supermarket operated service

station compete for market share when motor vehicles are travelling east on a major road that runs

from where the top oil major/branded independent service station is positioned. The middle and

bottom oil major/branded independent service stations compete for market share when motor

vehicles are travelling west on the same major road. Service station (B), because of its position,

competes with all four service stations; motor vehicles travelling east or west are able to enter it

without changing direction. To access the bottom oil major/branded independent service station,

motor vehicles have to make a left turn when travelling west and drive a further 400m. There are

many traffic lights along this major road; therefore, motor vehicles travelling one way can change

direction if there are price differences across the service stations. Furthermore, this major road is

not a freeway and contains speed limits and traffic volumes comparable to the two major roads in

the local market of service station (A).

58

Service stations (A), (B), (C) and (D) are managed by the same owner. The owner also manages more than thirty other service stations in Melbourne.

122

Figure 4.2.3 below displays the market structure of service station (C). Service station (C) competes

with one branded independent service station denoted as (BI) and one independent service station

denoted as (I). The branded independent service station lies 0.5km and the independent service

station lies 1.4km to the east of service station (C). Unlike the oil major/branded independent

service stations in area (B), the branded independent in area (C) has communicated to being a

branded independent. Service station (C) similar to service station (B) monitors the prices of its

competitors through shift changes. The operator of service station (C) also receives considerable

help from the owner, who informs him of any updates received from the oil major or other

operators. The operator of service station (C) in the same way as the operator of service station (B),

states that even if they are not able to match their competitors’ prices instantly because of their

location, they are quick to respond. He also claims that the loss of consumers from the delay is

insignificant.

Market Structure of Service Station (C)

Figure 4.2.3

Service station (C) and the two competing service stations lie on the same major road. Motor

vehicles travelling west prefer to drive into service station (C) and motor vehicles travelling east

prefer either to drive into the branded independent or the independent service station. There are

many traffic lights along this major road; consequently, motor vehicles travelling one way can

change direction if there are price differences across the service stations. This major road is also not

123

a freeway but contains lower speed limits and higher traffic volumes than the major roads in the

local markets of service stations (A) and (B).

Figure 4.2.4 below displays the market structure of service station (D). Service station (D) competes

with one independent service station denoted as (I), one branded independent service station

denoted as (BI), and one supermarket operated service station denoted as (S). The independent

service station lies directly across service station (D), practically facing one another. The branded

independent service station lies 600 metres to the east and the supermarket operated service

station lies 800 metres to the west of service station (D). Service station (D) monitors the prices of its

competitors in a unique way. Like service station (A), it can directly observe the price of the

independent service station. It is also aware of the price at the branded independent service station

because it is one of the other service stations the owner has purchased. Only the price of the

supermarket operated service station needs to be monitored and because service station (D) is a

large site, it has two employees working at all times making monitoring more frequent than in

service stations (B) or (C). For this reason, it can be said with confidence that just like service station

(A), service station (D) is at all times matching the lowest price in its local market.

Market Structure of Service Station (D)

Figure 4.2.4

Service station (D) and the three competing service stations lie on the same major road. Motor

vehicles travelling west prefer to drive into the branded independent service station and motor

124

vehicles travelling east prefer either to drive into the supermarket operated service station, the

independent service station or service station (D). There are many traffic lights along this major

road; consequently, motor vehicles travelling one way can change direction if there are price

differences across the service stations. This major road is also not a freeway and contains speed

limits and traffic volumes comparable to the major roads in the local markets of service stations (A)

and (B).

4.7 Distance from Closest Competitor

The distance of service stations from their closest competitor is a vital piece of information when

testing if different levels of competition in the local markets of service stations result in varying price

elasticities of petrol. Given that the way we identify different levels of competition may be

questioned, inferring for instance if there is a difference between the level of competition in service

station (B)’s and service station (A)’s local market, we must have a measure to distinguish between

different levels of competition.

Intuitively, a good measure could be the number of independent service stations that operate in a

local market. If there are any service stations that have incentives to undercut prices to increase

their market shares, it would be the independent service stations. Independent service stations have

smaller market shares than other service station types and have fewer obstructions to undercut

prices (ACCC 2010a). However, given that multiple studies (Atkinson 2009; Wang 2009a) have found

no correlation between independent service stations and competition, it would be inaccurate to use

the number of independent service stations to determine the level of competition in the local

markets of service stations.

The best measure we could develop that had some empirical value was the distance of service

stations from their closest competitor. We thought that this study would reveal the typical

positioning of service stations and help determine the level of competition in the local markets of

125

service stations. If there is persistent competition among service stations as previous literature

claim, the fact that a service station is close to its competitor would signify that its local market is

compact and that it competes for a larger cohort of consumers than a service station that is isolated.

The larger cohort of consumers in turn would make the local market of the service station close to

its competitor more competitive than the service station that is isolated.

Using the information provided by Australia Post (Australia Post n.d.) and a map of Melbourne we

make a list of all the suburbs in metropolitan Melbourne and order them by postcodes from smallest

to largest. The list begins with Melbourne that has a postcode of 3000 and finishes with Port

Melbourne that has a postcode of 3207. Trying to eliminate certain regional areas is difficult as some

are connected to metropolitan areas. Consequently, the final list of suburbs may include regional

areas. Then using a reliable online directory known as ‘Whereis’ (Whereis n.d.), we search each

suburb to locate every service station in metropolitan Melbourne and their closest competitor.

Between the 3000-3207 postcode range, there are three hundred and forty eight suburbs and five

hundred and forty eight service stations. Table 4.2.1 below contains a summary of the results and

reveals the typical positioning of service stations in metropolitan Melbourne. It’s quite striking that

more than of service stations are positioned between 0-500m from their closest competitor

and of service stations are positioned between 0-1500m. Also, another thing that is striking is

that only of service stations are positioned >3000m from their closest competitor. Out of the five

hundred and forty eight service stations on the list, only six were positioned >5000m.

Distance from Closest Competitor

Total Number of Service Stations

0-500m 500m-1500m 1500m-3000m 3000m-5000m >5000m

Table 4.2.2

126

The results from this study clearly show that if service stations are competing against each other, we

should expect the local market of service station (B) to be less competitive than the local markets of

the other three service stations, as it is positioned 5200m from its closest competitor. This makes

service station (B)’s positioning in the category and provides evidence that if competition does

exist, we should see major differences in service station (B)’s price elasticities. Additionally, given

that service stations (A), (C) and (D) are all positioned differently, we should observe some type of

difference in the price elasticities of these service stations; especially the price elasticities of service

station (C) as it cannot directly observe any of its competitors’ prices unlike service stations (A) and

(D).

4.8 Demand Function for Petrol59

4.8.1 Demand function

The average demand over a 24 hour period to 3pm in a sample service station is given by:

Function 4.8.1

A service station’s sales in litres of petrol is assumed to be a function of its own price in Australian

dollars , a lagged value of its own price , a lagged value of its own quantity

, school holidays , public holidays , a vector of

dummies for the days in a given week and a vector of dummies for the weeks in the dataset.

We also assume that there are no substitute goods, aggregate consumer income to be unvarying,

prices of petrol to be exogenous, and supply to be unlimited.

All the dummy variables in the demand function allow for variation in consumer behaviour.

Variations in consumer behaviour occur for two reasons: (1) preferences and (2) consumer

59

Readers who have read sections 3.4 and 3.5 on p.76 and p.81 can skip to section 4.10 on p.132 without any loss of continuity.

127

heterogeneity. An example of variation in consumer behaviour because of different preferences is

two homogenous consumers preferring to purchase fuel on different days of the week. An example

of variation in consumer behaviour because of consumer heterogeneity is two heterogeneous

consumers purchasing fuel one being a regular motor vehicle consumer and the other a taxi motor

vehicle consumer.

The purpose of inserting the lagged values of own price and own quantity is to capture the dynamic

aspects of the consumer choice problem. Clearly, earlier quantities and prices have effects on the

choices being made today. For instance, we expect demand for petrol to be higher today when

prices decrease from to dollars per litre than when prices increase from to

dollars per litre. Or, we expect demand for petrol to be higher today when litres of petrol were

sold yesterday compared to litres of petrol. Note that we have used time series methods to

reveal how far backward looking consumers are and the autoregressive distributed lag model of

order one, i.e. ADL(1,1), prove to be the only statistically significant ADL model.

The purpose of inserting the school holiday dummy is to capture the effects of consumers using their

motor vehicles less during school holidays. Parents do not drive their children to school and tend to

go on family vacations through semester breaks. The purpose of inserting the public holiday dummy

is similar to that of the school holiday dummy. The purpose of inserting the day dummies in a given

week is to capture the effects of serving different consumers and the effects that stem from the

various stages of the weekly cycle. The purpose of inserting the week dummies in the dataset is to

capture the weekly shocks that may be present during the period of the data.

4.8.2 Specification

Using the ADL model, F. (4.8.1), we regress the natural log of sales for petrol in litres against the

natural log of its own price in Australian dollars, the natural log of the lagged value of its own price,

and the natural log of the lagged value of its own quantity.

128

Equation 4.8.1

Now we extend Eq. (4.8.1) using dummy variables to allow for variation in consumer behaviour on

school holidays, public holidays, different days of the week and different weeks in the dataset. The

dummy represents observations in the dataset that are obtained on school

holidays. The dummy represents observations in the dataset that are obtained on

public holidays. The dummy represents observations in the dataset that are obtained between

3pm on Saturday and 3pm on Sunday. Similarly, the dummy represents Sunday-Monday, the

dummy represents Monday-Tuesday, the dummy represents Tuesday-Wednesday, the

dummy represents Wednesday-Thursday and the dummy represents Thursday-Friday.

The dummies represent observations in the dataset that are obtained during

different weeks in the dataset.

Following this extension, to separate any station specific effects from combining the observations of

four different service stations, we insert three additional dummy variables and

representing the other three service stations in the dataset. Every one of the dummy

variables in the demand equation is introduced both as an intercept and as a slope dummy variable.

The slope dummies will illustrate if and when consumers behave differently towards a change in

price, whereas the intercept dummies will illustrate if and when a lump-sum amount is required to

be added or taken away from the quantity demand estimate. Eq. (4.8.2) below displays the final

demand equation that we will use to estimate demand for petrol.

129

Equation 4.8.2

4.8.3 Caveat

In general the ordinary least squares (OLS) procedure is not appropriate when estimating demand

equations. The reason for this is that one of the assumptions that make the OLS estimators the best

linear unbiased estimator (BLUE) is violated. Given that these models are typically determined jointly

with supply, prices are deemed to be endogenous. Therefore, it is more appropriate to use

simultaneous equations methods such as two-stage least squares to estimate the parameters. In the

context of Eq. (4.8.2) however, this does not apply as the four service stations where the

observations are acquired from match the lowest price in the local markets they operate in. At these

prices the service stations sell as much petrol as consumers demand regardless of cost. Hence, their

prices can be taken as exogenous.

In Chapter 2, there are sections that provide information on how service stations set their prices in

Australia. Information about how service stations match the lowest price in the local markets they

operate in and how the loss of consumers is negligible while prices change can be obtained from

there. Additionally, in ACCC (2010a), there are sections that explain how the petroleum markets in

Australia are all connected to the Asia-Pacific markets and follow the prices in those markets closely.

The reasons for this is that (1) Australia’s demand is too small to affect the Asia-Pacific markets and

(2) the surveillance by the ACCC do not allow retail prices to vary from the prices in the Asia-Pacific

markets. Consequently, we can consider the overall prices of petrol to be exogenous also.

130

Furthermore, there is no omitted variable bias in Eq. (4.8.2) in terms of the missing price

observations of competing service stations. It is true that the service stations do compete with other

service stations that we do not have data for; however, because the service stations are at all times

matching the lowest price in the local markets they operate in, the effect of any other service station

pricing above this lowest price is negligible due to the characteristics of the retail petrol industry.

Lastly, statistical models that estimate demand functions are generally taken to be linear in the

variables. Alternatively, the log-log form of the model is also frequently used when the relationship

between quantity and price appears non-linear. When deciding on the specification of F. (4.8.1), we

commenced by running the linear and the log-log form prior to trying any other specification within

the OLS estimators. As it turns out, the log-log form of F. (4.8.1) under the ADL model fits the data

the best according to the R-Sq value, the statistical significance of the explanatory variables and the

signs of the coefficient estimates.

In Appendix 4.2 on pages 150-151, there are results for two other demand function specifications for

petrol. Tables 4.3.1 and 4.3.2 show the linear and reciprocal demand functions for petrol. By

comparing the different specifications, it can be seen that the log-log form performs best. We are

aware that comparing the R-Sq values of different specifications is not correct; however, using the

statistical significance of the explanatory variables it can be verified that the log-log form of petrol

has less insignificant estimates than the linear and reciprocal form60.

Some of the other specifications we try for F. (4.8.1) include non-linear models using polynomial and

interaction variables, the generalised least squares model, seemingly unrelated regressions model, a

dummy variable specification model with fixed and random effects, and the error components

model. Within all of these models where applicable we try different functional forms, multiple lags

and several interaction variables. None of the models produce better results than the log-log form of

F. (4.8.1). Some of them produce worse overall results (i.e. polynomial variables); some better R-Sq

60

In the results tables, T-Stat₁ corrects for heteroskedasticity and T-Stat₂ corrects for autocorrelation.

131

values but the wrong signs on the coefficients or price elasticity estimates (i.e. linear-log

specification); and others require the elimination of many observations as the dates of observations

from the service stations do not match (i.e. seemingly unrelated regressions model).

4.9 Diagnostic Tests and Omitted Variables

4.9.1 Diagnostic tests

After undergoing many diagnostic tests, we realise that the results based on Eq. (4.8.2) suffer from

heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation. We carry out the Goldfeld-Quandt test and reject to

conclude that heteroskedasticity exists.

First petrol equation:

Second petrol equation:

Additionally, we carry out the Breusch-Godfrey test and reject to conclude that autocorrelation

exists (Obs*R-Sq and ).

4.9.2 Omitted variables

After obtaining the initial estimates for petrol using Eq. (4.8.2), we decide to omit the following

explanatory variables due to their statistical insignificance.

132

Firstly, we decide to omit the dummy as there is no variation in the behaviour of

consumers during school holidays. This includes no variation in overall sales and no variation in the

way consumers behave towards a change in price.

Secondly, we decide to omit the slope dummy as consumers do not change the way

they behave towards a change in price on public holidays. This result may be caused by the fact that

prices do not generally change on public holidays.

Thirdly, we omit the – slope dummies for the weeks in the dataset. Just like

the dummy, the dummies for the weeks in the dataset do affect overall sales

but not the way consumers behave towards a change in price.

4.10 Results

4.10.1 Demand estimates

Tables 4.2.3 and 4.2.4 below present the results. The coefficient columns contain the estimates of

the population parameters. For instance, the value in Table 4.2.3 provides the average

demand for petrol in service station (D) when all explanatory variables are equal to zero. Or, the

value implies that when prices of petrol increase in service station (D) on a Saturday-

Sunday in week 50, average demand will decrease by

. Nearly all of the

explanatory variables are significant at the level. Using the Jarque-Bera statistic, the normal

distribution assumption is valid for the estimates. Moreover, we have addressed the issues relating

to heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using White’s cross-section61 and White’s period62

estimators (as calculated in EViews). The differences between the results using White’s cross-section

and White’s period standard errors and the ordinary standard errors are negligible, suggesting that

heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation do not affect the results.

61

See the T-Stat₁ columns in the results tables. 62

See the T-Stat₂ columns in the results tables.

133

Results for Petrol between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005 (Log-Log)

Dependent Variable: )

Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂ Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂

NR NR NR

T-Stat₁ is obtained with White’s cross-section estimators. T-Stat₂ is obtained with White’s period estimators. represents Sunday-Monday, represents Monday-

Tuesday, represents Tuesday-Wednesday, represents Wednesday-Thursday, represents Thursday-Friday and represents Friday-Saturday.

Table 4.2.3

134

Results for Petrol between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006 (Log-Log)

Dependent Variable: )

Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂ Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂

NR NR NR

T-Stat₁ is obtained with White’s cross-section estimators. T-Stat₂ is obtained with White’s period estimators. represents Sunday-Monday, represents Monday-

Tuesday, represents Tuesday-Wednesday, represents Wednesday-Thursday, represents Thursday-Friday and represents Friday-Saturday.

Table 4.2.4

135

Based on the demand estimates, we can conclude the following about the petrol market. Firstly, the

petrol consumers are aware of the price cycles. The significance of lagged price confirms that

yesterdays weighted average price influences the sales made today. When combining this

information with the fact that lagged price of LPG for the same service stations loses its explanatory

power when retail prices of LPG stop cycling (see section 3.6.1 on p.81), we can infer that consumers

do respond to the retail price cycles. The importance of knowing that the consumers are aware of

the cycles should not be undermined as it is a common question that appears in past papers (see

ACCC 2010a).

The second conclusion that we can make about the petrol market from the demand estimates is that

petrol consumers are heterogeneous. The fact that all of the slope variables are significant in the

results tables suggests that this assertion is true. Examining Table 4.2.4, we can see that there is a

different consumer cohort at each service station on every day of the week. Slope dummies such as

( ) make this clear. The reason why we consider this information important is

that it indicates why retail prices of petrol may cycle. In other words, if service stations are going to

price discriminate, the petrol market is a viable market to implement this pricing strategy.

4.10.2 Price elasticities

Tables 4.2.5 and 4.2.6 below contain the price elasticity estimates for petrol. Upon viewing them,

the first question that emerges is ‘why are they similar across the four service stations?’ As indicated

in section 4.6.1 on p.114, the data we use contains intraday observations. Additionally, in section 4.7

on p.122, we provide enough evidence to be able to claim that the service stations in this chapter

operate in local markets that have different levels of competition. Therefore, if the Edgeworth cycles

model is consistent with the retail petrol industry and if competition is the reason why retail prices

of petrol cycle, then there is no basis for the service stations to have similar price elasticities as in

Tables 4.2.5 and 4.2.6.

136

Price elasticities of Petrol between 9/5/2004-23/4/2005

B D

Days Of The Week Short-Run Elasticity

Short-Run Elasticity

Saturday-Sunday Sunday-Monday Monday-Tuesday Tuesday-Wednesday Wednesday-Thursday Thursday-Friday Friday-Saturday Average Price

Table 4.2.5

Price elasticities of Petrol between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006

A B C D

Days Of The Week Short-Run Elasticity

Short-Run Elasticity

Short-Run Elasticity

Short-Run Elasticity

Saturday-Sunday

Sunday-Monday Monday-Tuesday

Tuesday-Wednesday Wednesday-Thursday Thursday-Friday Friday-Saturday

Average Price

Table 4.2.6

The price elasticity estimates show that the short-run price elasticities of petrol range from to

. The intriguing aspect about the price elasticities is that the range is not caused by the

different levels of competition in the local markets of the service stations. It is rather caused by the

variation in demand during different days of the week. For instance, between the 27th of April 2005

and 17th of June 2006 the estimated price elasticity on a Tuesday-Wednesday for service station (A)

is , for service station (B) is , for service station (C) is and for service station (D) is

. Or, between the same period, the estimated price elasticity on a Thursday-Friday for service

station (A) is , for service station (B) is , for service station (C) is and for service

station (D) is .

137

As explained in section 4.4.2 on p.110, if there are different levels of competition in the local

markets of service stations, then the price elasticity estimates can determine if the Edgeworth cycles

model or the price discrimination model is more consistent with the retail petrol industry. The

theory behind the idea is that if service stations are undercutting each other’s price, the service

stations in local markets with higher levels of competition should produce larger price elasticities. On

the other hand, if service stations are matching each other’s price, then all service stations

regardless of the level of competition should produce similar price elasticities.

We should also clarify that these similar price elasticities do not suggest that consumers are not

sensitive to price differences. We believe that consumers are sensitive to price differences and there

is no evidence to suggest otherwise. What the similar price elasticities suggest is that there are no

price differences across service stations. They show that service stations match each other’s prices

and not undercut. Thus, suggesting that the cycles are more in line with the price discrimination

model in Conlisk et al. (1984) than the Edgeworth cycles model in Maskin and Tirole (1988).

4.10.3 Comparison with Wang’s (2009a) estimates

In Wang (2009a), there are price elasticity estimates for eight service stations operating in Western

Australia. The estimated short-run price elasticities range from to , depending on the

location of the service stations. As we have already mentioned, the data in Wang (2009a) is collected

at a time when the retail market is under severe restrictions by regulatory authorities and the

service stations are not allowed to change their prices to match or beat their competitors’ prices. As

a result, the findings in Wang (2009a) are less relevant outside of Western Australia.

Similar to the service stations in this chapter, the service stations in Wang (2009a) are from different

locations, each facing different levels of competition. For instance, in Wang (2009a) the estimated

short-run price elasticities are for a service station near the entrant of the Perth airport,

for a service station whose closest competitor is 4.2 kilometres away, and for a

138

service station that is located right next to its closest competitor. Wang (2009a) uses these estimates

to suggest that the different levels of competition result in varying price elasticities of petrol. He

does not however provide any explanation to as why that may be the case, just assumes it to be so.

We believe that the major cause for the discrepancy between Wang’s (2009a) estimates and the

estimates in this chapter is the 24-hour-rule put in place in Western Australia. Given that under

regular conditions, service stations are free to change their prices whenever they desire, whereas

under the 24-hour-rule, service stations must wait 24 hours before they can adjust their prices.

Obvious during this time, depending if their prices are higher or lower, service stations can lose or

gain many consumers from their competitors’. Consequently, the fact that Wang (2009a) finds

varying price elasticities across service stations does not come as a surprise; neither does the similar

price elasticities that we find in this chapter.

4.11 Conclusion

This chapter identifies differences in the predictions of the Edgeworth cycles model (Maskin & Tirole

1988) and the price discrimination model (Conlisk et al. 1984) that can be empirically analysed. The

three differences that we identify which can be used to determine which model is more consistent

with the retail petrol industry are: (1) predictions about the lengths of the price cycles, (2)

predictions about the timing of price increases and price decreases, and (3) predictions about the

reactions of service stations to price changes.

Furthermore, by using two assumptions from the Edgeworth cycles model and the price

discrimination model, we point out a structural difference that can be used to determine why retail

prices of petrol cycle. This structural difference entails comparing the price elasticities of service

stations from separate local markets that contain different levels of competition. If the price

elasticities of service stations vary, this suggests that competition is the cause of the price cycles. If

139

price elasticities of service stations are similar, this suggests that price discrimination is the cause of

the price cycles.

Finally, we provide station level demand estimates for petrol in four service stations that operate

under regular conditions. What we mean by regular conditions is that service stations are allowed to

change their prices without any restraints and as many times as they desire. The estimates predict

that the short-run price elasticities of petrol are between to . Strikingly, the

range is not caused by the different levels of competition in the local markets of the service stations;

rather, they are caused by the variation in demand during different days of the week. Therefore, (1)

indicating that service stations match each other’s prices and (2) suggesting that the cycles are not in

line with the Edgeworth cycles model.

140

Bibliography

Atkinson, B. (2009) Retail Gasoline Price Cycles: Evidence from Guelph, Ontario Using Bi-Hourly,

Station Specific Retail Price Date. The Energy Journal. 30(1): 85-109.

Australian Competition and Consumer Commission (ACCC) (2006) Senate Economics Legislation

Committee inquiry into the price of petrol in Australia. Canberra: ACCC.

——(2007) Petrol Prices and Australian Consumers: Report of the ACCC Inquiry into the Price of

Unleaded Petrol. Canberra: ACCC.

——(2010a) Monitoring of the Australian Petroleum Industry. Canberra: ACCC.

——(2010b) What are Petrol Price Cycles? Canberra: ACCC.

Australia Post (n.d.) [Online]. Available: http://www.auspost.com.au [Accessed 01 January 2011].

Bloch, H. (2010) Gasoline Price Cycle Drivers: An Australian Case Study. Working Paper. Curtin

Business School.

BP Australia Pty Ltd (2006) Submission by BP Australia Pty Ltd on the price of petrol in Australia to

Senate Economics Legislation Committee. Australia: BP.

Breunig, R.V. and Gisz, C. (2009) An Exploration of Australian Petrol Demand: Unobservable Habits,

Irreversibility and Some Updated Estimates. The Economic Record. 85(268): 73-91.

Conlisk, J., Gerstner, E. and Sobel, J. (1984) Cyclic Pricing by a Durable Goods Monopolist. The

Quarter Journal of Economics. 99(3): 489-505.

Doyle, C. (1983) Dynamic Price Discrimination, Competitive Markets and the Matching Process.

Discussion Paper 229, University of Warwick.

Doyle, J., Muehlegger, E. and Samphantharak, K. (2008) Edgeworth Cycles Revisited. NBER Working

Paper 14162.

Eckert, A. (2002) Retail Price Cycles and Response Asymmetry. Canadian Journal of Economics. 35(1):

52-77.

Eckert, A. (2003) Retail Price Cycles and Presence of Small Firms. International Journal of Industrial

Organization. 21(2): 151-170.

141

Eckert, A. and West, D. (2004) Retail Gasoline Price Cycles across Spatially Dispersed Gasoline

Stations. Journal of Law and Economics. 22: 997-1015.

Edgeworth, F.Y., (1925) The Pure Theory of Monopoly. Papers Relating to Political Economy. 1: 111-

142.

Foros, O. and Steen, F. (2008) Gasoline Prices Jump Up on Mondays: an Outcome of Aggressive

Competition? CEPR Working Paper DP6783.

Lewis, M. (2009) Temporary Wholesale Gasoline Price Spikes have Long Lasting Retail Effects: The

Aftermath of Hurricane Rita. Journal of Law and Economics. 52(3): 581-606.

Lewis, M. and Noel, M. (2011) The Speed of Gasoline Price Response in Markets with and without

Edgeworth Cycles. Review of Economics and Statistics. 93(2): 672-682.

Maskin, E. and Tirole, J. (1988) A Theory of Dynamic Oligopoly II: Price Competition, Kinked Demand

Curves and Edgeworth Cycles. Econometrica. 56(3): 571-599.

Noel, Michael D. (2007) Edgeworth Price Cycles: Evidence from the Toronto Retail Gasoline Market.

Journal of Industrial Economics. 55(1): 69-92.

——(2008) Edgeworth Price Cycles and Focal Prices: Computational Dynamic Markov Equilibria.

Journal of Economics and Management Strategy. 17:2: 345-377.

——(2011) Edgeworth Price Cycles and Intertemporal Price Discrimination. Energy Economics.

Forthcoming.

Sobel, J. (1984) The Timing of Sales. Review of Economic Studies. 51(3): 353-368.

Wang, Z. (2009a) Station Level Gasoline (Petrol) Demand in an Australian Market with Regular Price

Cycles. Australian Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics. 53(4): 467-483.

Wang, Z. (2009b) Mixed Strategies in Oligopoly Pricing: Evidence from Gasoline Price Cycles before

and under a Timing Regulation. Journal of Political Economy. 117(6): 987-1030.

Whereis (n.d.) [Online]. Available: http://www.whereis.com [Accessed 01 January 2011].

142

Appendix 4.1: Propositions and Proofs

Proposition 1. The reservation price of a high consumer is

. The reservation price of a low

consumer is

.

Proof 1. A high consumer values the product at dollars per period. The product is infinitely

durable and discounted at factor . Thus, the reservation price of a high consumer, call it ,

equals

In the same way, the reservation price of a low consumer, call it , equals

.

Proposition 2. To maximise profits the monopolist must follow a cyclic price path.

Proof 2. Consumers are aware of two facts: (1) eventually that the price will be lowered to and

(2) once lowered to that the price will never lessen further. Both facts are a requirement of

profit maximisation. If the monopolist does lower the price to , it will only sell to high consumers

at their reservation price . Yet, at some point in time, the number of low consumers waiting to

buy at will become so large that the monopolist’s discounted profits will be greater if it lowered

the price to , even if it had to leave it there forever. This result emerges from the continual influx

of new consumers. Additionally, since there are no consumers who value the product below ,

there is no benefit for the monopolist to lower its price below .

Therefore, using the argument provided in the last paragraph, it can be said that the monopolist will

eventually lower the price to and hold a sale. At each sale, both high and low consumers in the

market will buy the product, as they are aware that the price will never be any lower. The market

will clear and the monopolist will be left facing the same setting. Hence, the monopolist will act in

the same way and the price will cycle.

143

Proposition 3. The monopolist’s pricing strategy in equilibrium for a given must be

where , is the cycle length and are the prices in each period of the cycle.

Proof 3. Consider a high consumer entering at cycle period . He can delay his purchase from

to periods. His choice of when to purchase will depend on what is larger: his net benefit

from purchasing the product immediately or his discounted net benefit from waiting

periods for .

The monopolist wants to assure the high consumer purchases immediately for two reasons. First,

the monopolist prefers revenue now to revenue later. Second, the high consumer’s willingness to

pay decreases as he gets closer to the end of the cycle, the sale price . The question for

the monopolist is this: How high should the nonsale prices be so that each high

consumer upon entering the market purchases immediately? The answer is

for .

Setting and noting that , we can rearrange for the upper bound of

It is possible to set equal to this upper bound using the tie-breaking assumption

discussed above. Then turns out to be

144

For a given , is the highest nonsale prices that will induce high consumers to purchase

immediately.

Proposition 4. Prices follow an asymmetric pattern and display a constant range equal to .

Proof 4. Note that according to , prices fall steadily during a cycle ending

at the reservation price of the low consumer . However, according to the price rises

back up from to immediately, the following period. Hence, prices follow an

asymmetric pattern. Additionally, given that the prices in each period of the cycle do not

change in value from cycle to cycle, prices display a constant range equal to .

Proposition 5. The cycle length is unvarying and equal to

Proof 5. Let the be the present value of the monopolist’s total profits calculated from the th

period of a cycle, where cycles are periods long. Let be the present value of the

monopolist’s profits from the th to th period of a single cycle. We can then write as

The first term on the right of is the profit contribution from the th to th period of the

cycle, which the monopolist finds himself. The second term on the right of is the profit

contribution of the whole cycle repeat endlessly by the monopolist. Each whole cycle is worth

at its start. The value of them all at the start of the first whole cycle is

145

and this must be discounted by to bring

back to the th period. can be

expressed as

The first term on the right of is the profit contribution of low consumers. There are

[ low consumers that enter the market each period. There will be times [

ready to buy at the end of the cycle. Each low consumer pays and the resulting revenue is

discounted back to the calculation date, subperiod . The second term on the right of is the

profit contribution of high consumers. There are high consumers that enter the market each

period . Each high consumer pays the corresponding prices to the period they

enter. The appropriate discounting then gives the summation. Substituting for the prices in

using and substituting

and

for and , we

can get an expression for .

Arrange into an infinite dimensional payoff matrix .

The above diagonal elements of the payoff matrix are not defined since .

The first column of the matrix contains the payoffs for the monopolist in the first period of the cycle;

the second column of the matrix contains the payoffs for the monopolist in the second period of the

cycle; and so on. If the monopolist wanted to commit to a once-for-all cycle length, the monopolist

would chose the cycle length corresponding to the largest element in the first column. However, this

is ruled out by assumption; the monopolist will not stick to his promise of never holding a sale. To

solve the time consistency problem, we need to look further into the columns of . First note that

146

for large enough , the element is the largest in its column. is larger than

for all in that column. The intuition behind is that as the cycle length gets

larger, the number of low consumers willing to purchase will accumulate. Eventually getting to a

stage where holding a sale becomes irresistible to the monopolist. Consider profits from the th

period of a cycle for cycle length . There are amount of low consumers left

over from earlier periods that are ready to buy. Let’s call this the monopolist’s backlog. If the

monopolist holds a sale, profits from his backlog alone would be . Thus,

Now consider profits from the th period of a cycle for cycle length with . The present

value of the monopolist’s backlog is . As for current and future consumers,

the best the monopolist can do is charge them per period. Hence,

Then subtract from noting that

Then substitute

for and

for and simplify

Now if the cycle gets

periods long, the monopolist will definitely hold a sale.

147

Next work backwards from to , where is the equilibrium cycle length from the

view point of each period . To work back from to , use

Then compute to and set . The purpose behind this recursion is to ensure

is time consistent.

Proposition 6. The level of total profit in any equilibrium can be attained in a symmetric equilibrium.

Proof 6. Let sellers charge the minimum price offered in each period of any equilibrium. Given

that consumers buy from the seller that offers the lowest price, the symmetric equilibrium will

achieve the same level of profit of any equilibrium. To ensure that defections do not occur, assume

that sellers lower their price to zero forever if any seller decides to defect. Since this eliminates any

incentive to defect—if one seller is charging zero, then it is a best response for all other sellers to

also charge zero—the symmetric equilibrium does maintain an equilibrium.

Proposition 7. If the gains from keeping to the agreement exceed that of defecting, a non-

cooperative equilibrium with monopoly profits will result.

Proof 7. Consider a list of prices to be charged by the th seller in period . contains the

prices to be charged today and in the future including the time of sales and what prices to charge if

is not charged by some . Denote the discounted profits of seller calculated from the th

period of a cycle with no defection from any as . Denote the discounted profits of seller

with a defection in period by seller as . The market will be in equilibrium given that

for all and .

148

Let the be the discounted profits of seller calculated from the th period of a cycle with

no defection from any where cycles are periods long. Let be the discounted

profits of seller from the th to th period of a single cycle. We can then write as

The first term on the right of is the profit contribution from the th to th period of the

cycle seller finds itself. The second term on the right of is the profit contribution of the

whole cycle repeated endlessly. Each whole cycle is worth

at its start to seller . The value of them all at the start of the first whole cycle is

and this must be discounted by to bring

back to the th period. can be

expressed as

The first term on the right of is the profit contribution of low consumers to seller .

There are [ low consumers that enter the market each period. There will be times

[ ready to buy at the end of the cycle. Each low consumer pays and the resulting

revenue must be discounted back to the calculation date, subperiod and divided by the number

of sellers to deduce seller ’s portion. The second term on the right of is the profit

contribution of high consumers to seller . There are high consumers that enter the market

each period . Each high consumer pays the corresponding prices to the period

they enter. Appropriate discounting and division by the number of sellers then gives the

149

summation. Substituting for the prices in using and

substituting

and

for and , we get an expression for .

Let the be the discounted profits of seller with a defection in the th period of a cycle by

seller where cycles are periods long. Assuming that defections result in all sellers lowering

their price to zero forever, seller ’s gains from defecting can be summarised as follows:

if

if

Seller has two ways in which it can defect. First, to attract the high consumers, seller can

undercut on a non-sale . This type of defection will approximately yield seller a profit

of . Second, to attract the low consumers, seller can undercut . This type of defection

approximately yields seller a profit of on a sale or a profit of

on a non-sale . is equal or greater than

as ( and approaches one. As the number of sellers in the market falls, seller receives a

larger portion of the total profit. As seller ’s discount factor gets closer and closer to one,

goes to infinity whilst does not change as it does not depend on .

150

Appendix 4.2: Different Specifications

Results for Petrol between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006 (Linear)

Dependent Variable:

Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂ Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂

NR NR NR

T-Stat₁ is obtained with White’s cross-section estimators. T-Stat₂ is obtained with White’s period estimators. represents Sunday-Monday, represents Monday-

Tuesday, represents Tuesday-Wednesday, represents Wednesday-Thursday, represents Thursday-Friday and represents Friday-Saturday.

Table 4.3.1

151

Results for Petrol between 27/4/2005-17/6/2006 (Reciprocal)

Dependent Variable:

Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂ Explanatory Variables Coefficient T-Stat₁ T-Stat₂

NR NR NR

T-Stat₁ is obtained with White’s cross-section estimators. T-Stat₂ is obtained with White’s period estimators. represents Sunday-Monday, represents Monday-

Tuesday, represents Tuesday-Wednesday, represents Wednesday-Thursday, represents Thursday-Friday and represents Friday-Saturday.

Table 4.3.2

152

5. Conclusion

This dissertation analyses the retail petroleum industry. Chapter 2 explains how petrol, diesel and

LPG are retailed in Australia. It focuses on when service stations change their prices and how this

affects their sales. Chapter 3 provides station level demand estimates for diesel and LPG in four

service stations that operate in metropolitan Melbourne. Chapter 4 identifies differences in the

predictions of the Edgeworth cycles model (Maskin & Tirole 1988) and the price discrimination

model (Conlisk et al. 1984) that can be empirically analysed. It also presents the first piece of

empirical evidence against the common belief that the Edgeworth cycles model is consistent with

the retail petrol industry.

The main purpose of the dissertation is to illuminate parts of the retail petroleum industry that are

obscure in earlier literature. For instance, ‘what is the cause of the price cycles in petrol retailing?’

Or, ‘what are the short run price elasticities of diesel and LPG in Australia?’ Or, ‘how does the sales

of service stations vary?’ None of these questions were previously answered with certainty. We have

answered, if not made inroads into answering many of these questions. Future research can make

use of this dissertation by either applying the methods to a larger dataset to make the results more

robust or as guidance when interpreting industry data. Testing if the price elasticities of other service

stations from local markets that have different levels of competition are the same will further

substantiate that the Edgeworth cycles model is not consistent with retail petrol industry.

It may be asked why it is important to determine the cause of the price cycles in petrol retailing. The

answer to this question is that it entails policy implications. Knowing that competition is not the

cause of the price cycles will trigger major investigations into how service stations set their prices.

Another reason for why uncovering the cause of the price cycles is important is because it may be a

pricing scheme that the service stations are using to discriminate between heterogeneous

consumers. If this is true, it may become a blueprint for other suppliers in other industries to cycle

their prices. This in turn may give rise to thousands of dollars in profits.

153

In conclusion, the finding that four service stations from local markets that have different levels of

competition have similar price elasticities is a major result. It indicates that service stations in the

retail petrol industry match each other’s prices and not undercut. When this finding is

complemented with price elasticities of LPG that suggest that the ongoing tax raises on LPG will not

have significant effects on the sales of service stations, this dissertation appears valuable for policy

makers in Australia. The results may cause the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission

(ACCC) to collect quantity data to accompany the price data they accumulate when investigating

price fixing in the retail petrol industry, as this will provide them with an alternative way to inspect if

service stations are behaving anti-competitively.

The details concerning the retail petroleum industry in Chapter 2 not only corroborate the price

matching finding in Chapter 4, but also nullify any misconceptions about the retail petroleum

industry. It is now obvious from the data that in the petrol market (1) price cycles have

corresponding lengths, (2) sales of service stations are steady and (3) prices always increase with a

single large increase in price and to the same level across service stations. In the diesel market (1)

retail prices never cycle and (2) the days in which price increases occur are unpredictable. In the LPG

market (1) retail prices cycle similar to petrol during 2004 and 2005, (2) for some unknown reason

retail prices stop cycling on the same day as retail prices of petrol change from cycling on a Saturday

to a Wednesday, (3) during the cycling phase the days in which price increases occur are predictable

and (4) with cost based pricing the days in which price increases occur become unpredictable.

154

Bibliography

Conlisk, J., Gerstner, E. and Sobel, J. (1984) Cyclic Pricing by a Durable Goods Monopolist. The

Quarter Journal of Economics. 99(3): 489-505.

Maskin, E. and Tirole, J. (1988) A Theory of Dynamic Oligopoly II: Price Competition, Kinked Demand

Curves and Edgeworth Cycles. Econometrica. 56(3): 571-599.


Recommended