+ All Categories
Home > Documents > New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

Date post: 04-Dec-2021
Category:
Upload: others
View: 3 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
251
1 New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output A thesis submitted in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy University of Western Sydney 2012 By Cung Cao
Transcript
Page 1: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

1

New Keynesian Theories of

Inflation and Output

A thesis submitted in fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy

University of Western Sydney

2012

By

Cung Cao

Page 2: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

2

Statement of Authentication

The work presented in this thesis is, to the best of my knowledge and belief, my own

and original except as acknowledged in the text. I hereby declare that I have not submitted

this material, either in full or in part, for a degree at this or any other institution.

Signature ...........................................................

Cung Cao

Page 3: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

3

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank my supervisors: Professor B. Bhaskara Rao, Professor Steve

Keen and Associate Professor Brian Pinkstone for their patience, guidance and wisdom.

I am very grateful to Professor John Lodewijks, in his capacity as the head of the

school of economics at the University of Western Sydney for his support and valuable

comments on this thesis. I would also like to acknowledge that I received very helpful

comments from two anonymous examiners.

I would like to thank the University of Western Sydney for supporting my research

with a scholarship (UWS Postgraduate Research Award).

Finally, I would like to thank my family and friends for their support.

Page 4: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

4

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Abstract

Introduction

7

8

Chapter 1

1.1

1.2

1.3

1.4

New Keynesian Economics: A Review of the Literature

Main Features of New Keynesian Economics

Microeconomic Foundations of Prices Rigidities

Real Rigidities in the Labour Market

Conclusion

12

12

14

19

22

Chapter 2

2.1

2.2

2.3

2.4

2.5

2.6

From Sticky-Prices to Sticky-Information to Sticky-Knowledge

Introduction

The Philips Curve and some Developments

The Sticky-Prices Approach

The Sticky-Information Approach

The Sticky-Knowledge Phillips Curve

Conclusion

23

23

24

28

33

42

51

Chapter 3

3.1

3.2

3.3

3.4

3.5

An Empirical Survey of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Introduction

Sticky-Price-Single-Equation Estimations of the NKPC

DSGE Model-Based Estimations of the NKPC

Estimations of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve (SIPC)

Conclusion

53

53

53

63

65

68

Chapter 4

4.1

4.2

4.3

Proxies for Real Marginal Cost

Introduction

Literature Review

Proxies for Real Marginal Cost

70

70

70

79

Page 5: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

5

4.4

4.5

4.6

4.7

4.8

4.9

4.10

Proxies for Inflation Expectations

Data and Estimation Strategy

Empirical Comparisons

Robustness Analysis

An Alternative Instrument Set

Endogeneity of Real Marginal Cost

Conclusion

83

84

85

88

92

94

97

Chapter 5

5.1

5.2

5.3

5.4

5.5

5.6

5.7

5.8

Estimations of the Phillips Curve Using Survey Measures of

Inflation Expectations

Introduction

Are Survey Measures of Inflation Expectations Rational?

Data and Estimation Strategy

Tests of Rationality of Survey Measures of Inflation Expectations

Empirical Comparisons Between Job Finding Probability, the

Output Gap and Labour’s Share of Income as Proxy for Real

Marginal Cost

Robustness Analysis

Conclusion

Appendix to Chapter 5

100

100

100

103

105

114

115

116

120

Chapter 6

6.1

6.2

6.3

6.4

6.5

The Flattening of the Phillips Curve

Introduction

The Flattening of the Phillips Curve

Tests for Structural Changes

Competing Explanations

The Labour Market and the Slope of the Phillips Curve

160

160

160

167

170

173

Page 6: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

6

6.6

6.7

Conclusion

Appendix to Chapter 6

183

185

Chapter 7

7.1

7.2

7.3

7.4

7.5

7.6

Non-Stationary Inflation and the Phillips Curve

Introduction

Time Series Properties of the Variables in the Phillips Curve

Tests for Cointegration

Does Non-Stationary Inflation Invalidate Previous Research

Findings?

Conclusion

Appendix to Chapter 7

193

193

193

195

196

201

203

Chapter 8

8.1

8.2

8.3

8.4

8.5

8.6

8.7

Estimations of the Phillips Curve for Australia with Different

Proxies for Real Marginal Cost

Introduction

The Australian Phillips Curve

The Data

Proxies for Real Marginal Cost

Empirical Comparisons Between Job Finding Probability, the

Output Gap and Labour’s Share of Income as Proxy for Real

Marginal Cost

Robustness Analysis

Conclusion

206

206

207

209

211

212

216

226

Chapter 9 Summary and Conclusions 228

References 234

Page 7: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

7

Abstract

This thesis examines two important issues in the empirical literature on the new

Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC). First, are inflation expectations consistent with rational

expectations? Many researchers find that the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive

expectations fits the data better new Keynesian Phillips curve with rational expectations.

Second, do real marginal costs drive inflation dynamics? Gali and Gertler (1999) argue that

the reason why the NKPC fits the data poorly is because traditional empirical work on the

Phillips curve uses some output gap measures as a proxy for real marginal cost rather than

labour’s share of income. Our results suggest that the pure rational expectations new

Keynesian Phillips curve might be misspecified and that the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips

curve fits the data best. The relative importance of backward-looking inflation expectations

and forward-looking inflation expectations changes over time. Backward-looking inflation

expectations dominate forward-looking inflation expectations independent of which measures

of real marginal cost are used. Furthermore, we have tested the rationality of various survey

measures of inflation expectations; our results indicate that these survey measures of inflation

expectations are biased and inefficient. We have also showed that there are Granger

causalities from the professional forecasters (as represented by the SPF forecasts and the

Greenbook forecasts) to households (as represented by the Michigan forecasts), but no

Granger causality in the opposite direction.

Our empirical results suggest that the probability of finding a job or job finding

probability (JFP) is a better proxy for real marginal cost than the output gap and labour’s

share of income, at the same time JFP provides a direct link between frictions in the labour

market and the Phillips curve relationship. The use of job finding probability as a proxy for

real marginal cost is a novel aspect of this thesis.

We have also examined the flattening of the slope of the reduced-form Phillips curve

for the United States over the last 20 years; this phenomenon is also observed in many other

industrialized countries. We proposed the flattening of the slope of the reduced-form Phillips

curve is caused by deindustrialization and the computer revolution have shifted employment

from the manufacturing sectors to the service sectors; these structural changes in the labour

market have changed jobs’ skill requirements, increasing heterogeneity (real rigidities)

between workers, producing more mismatches in the labour market.

Page 8: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

8

Introduction

Although the 1960s and 1970s macroeconomic models of IS-LM1 and the

Expectations-Augmented Phillips curve incorporated adaptive expectations into

macroeconomic analysis, the new classical models incorporated rational expectations.

Rational expectations modelling became a popular modelling technique. However, some

Keynesians, who developed explicit micro-foundations for macroeconomic theories, argued

that such micro-founded models are methodologically superior to ad hoc models based on

empirical considerations. Implicit in this view is that micro-founded models can explain

macro-phenomena better and yield improved and more accurate predictions. These

economists are known as the new Keynesians and can said to be the dominant group of

macroeconomists.

In a way the micro-founded new Keynesian models can also seen as a methodological

attempt to validate Keynesian models in theory also. Consequently, both the new classical

and new Keynesian models use similar optimization techniques and rational expectations.

They differ only in respects of their assumptions about adjustment lags, market imperfections

and imperfections in information. In the new classical models price-quantity adjustments are

fast, markets are perfectly competitive and information is perfect. Therefore, the economy

reaches equilibrium in a short period and fluctuations in output, prices and unemployment are

due to random shocks and short lived. In the Keynesian models price-quantity adjustments

take a long time and therefore the economy will depart from its long run equilibrium for a

number of periods.2 Fluctuations caused by shocks to the system persist and policy is

necessary to move the economy towards its long run equilibrium. These Keynesian objectives

are achieved by the new Keynesians in a number of ways. To limit the scope, this thesis will

examine only new Keynesian models with rational expectations based on sluggish price

adjustments and sluggish adjustment in expectations. It is our contention that that the sticky

information Phillips curve (Mankiw and Reis (2002) and Carroll (2003)), and the hybrid new

1 Rao (2006, p.2) points out that some post Keynesian economists do not consider Hick’s IS-LM model as

Keynesian, but as neoclassical instead. He suggests that “it is perhaps more appropriate to call the textbook

Keynesian models Hicksian rather than Keynesian”.

2 I thank Professor Steve Keen for clarifying that that term Keynesian economics in this thesis refers to the

neoclassical synthesis interpretation of Keynes’ work, this approach is based on the pioneering work of “Hicks

(1937), Modigliani (1944), Klein (1947), Samuelson (1948) and Hansen (1953). The IS-LM model formed the

backbone of theorizing within this approach…Following Modigliani’s contribution; Keynesian economics was

seen to be the economics of wage and price rigidities. The destabilizing impact of unstable expectations was

played down in this approach” (Snowdon and Vane, 2005, p.70-71).

Page 9: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

9

Keynesian Phillips curve (Furher (1995) and Gali and Gertler (1999)) can be interpreted as a

class of bounded rationality models of Simon. Simon (1957, 1959, 1979, 1991) believes that

human rationality is limited because agents don’t have all of the knowledge (for example,

about an uncertain future) and the mental capacity to process all relevant information, as a

result, people make choices that are satisfactory – good enough – rather than optimal.

Many new Keynesian economists use a micro-founded Phillips curve and at times a

monetary policy rule such as the Taylor Rule to explain the observed macroeconomic

fluctuations and dynamics. In this framework the key relationship is the Phillips curve. The

success or failure of the new Keynesian macro-model to explain macroeconomic fluctuations

depends mainly on the specification used for the Phillips curve. However, there are some

differences between the new Keynesians on the specification of this important relationship.

This is the subject matter of this thesis. We review the literature justifying different

specifications of the Phillips curve and estimate these specifications with alternative

econometric methods. After examining the pros and cons of these empirical estimates we

draw our conclusions about their relative merits. Our empirical results are based on the US

data. However, towards the end of this thesis we also estimate a Phillips curve with the

Australian data.

Organizational Structure

This thesis consists of nine chapters. Chapter 1 briefly surveys the main developments

in new Keynesian economics. New Keynesians attempt to develop business cycle theories,

which explain prices rigidities and market failures based on rational expectations with micro-

foundations. We will focus on potential causes of real and nominal rigidities and various

structural features of the labour market that could explain involuntary unemployment.

Chapter 2 briefly examines the main developments in the Phillips curve literature and

reviews the debate on its micro-foundations. The micro-foundations based Phillips curve is

known as the new Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC hereafter).The NKPC literature can be

divided into two categories: models based on sluggish adjustments in prices and sluggish

adjustments of inflation expectations. This has implications for the specification of the

Phillips curve and therefore for the inflation—output dynamics and the effectiveness of

discretionary policies. Proponents of models with sluggish expectations, such as Mankiw and

Reis (2001, 2002), argue that these models can explain stylized facts better than models with

sluggish price adjustments. We will attempt to argue that Mankiw and Reis and other new

Page 10: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

10

Keynesians have neglected an earlier rationalization for sluggish adjustments in expectations,

based on the bounded rationality approach of Herbert Simon.

Chapter 3 surveys selected empirical works on the new Keynesian Phillips curve

(NKPC) for the USA. We will focus on recent developments with regard to the abilities of

these models to fit the data, whether labour’s share of output or the output gap is the

appropriate measurement for real marginal cost, the relative importance of forward and

backward-looking expectations and whether these models assume that price adjustments are

sluggish or expectation adjustments are sluggish.

Chapter 4 examines two important issues raised by the work of Gali and

Gertler (1999) and Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2001, 2005). First, the new Keynesian

Phillips curve (NKPC) needs to take into account labour market frictions. Second, the output

gap (GAP) may not be an appropriate proxy for real economic activity because it assumes

that the labour market clears. In their influential paper, Gali and Gertler (1999) argue that the

reason why the NKPC fits the data poorly is because traditional empirical work on the

Phillips curve uses some output gap measures as a proxy for real marginal cost rather than

labour’s share of income. We will attempt to argue that the probability of finding a job or job

finding probability (JFP) is a better proxy for real marginal cost than GAP and labour’s share

of income, at the same time JFP provides a direct link between frictions in the labour market

and the Phillips curve relationship.

Chapter 5 examines the rationality of the Greenbook, the Survey of Professional

Forecasters (SPF) and the Michigan survey measures of inflation expectations. We will

estimates various specifications of the Phillips curve using survey measures of inflation

expectations as proxy for inflation expectations and examine whether job finding probability

(JFP), the output gap or labour’s share of income is a better proxy for real marginal cost.

Chapter 6 examines the flattening of the slope of the reduced-form Phillips curve for

the United States over the last 20 years; this phenomenon is also observed in many other

industrialized countries. The flattening of the Phillips curve raises two important questions:

What explains the flattening of the Phillips curve? And what are the implications of this

phenomenon for the proper conduct of monetary policy? We will attempt to argue that

increase in specialization of labour and lower and more-stable inflation that led to less-

frequent price adjustment are the causes of the flattening of the Phillips curve in the United

States and other industrialized countries.

Page 11: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

11

Chapter 7 argues that the finding that the United States inflation rates are non-

stationary does not necessarily invalidate previous body of empirical research that do not take

into account the non-stationary behaviour of inflation.

Chapter 8 estimates various specifications of the Phillips curve for Australia using

three proxies for real marginal cost: job finding probability (JFP), the output gap and labour’s

share of income as well as survey measures of inflation expectations and mathematical

expectations as proxy for inflation expectations. We will attempt to show that job finding

probability (JFP) is a better proxy for real marginal cost than the output gap or labour’s share

of income. Chapter 9 concludes.

Relationship to Previous Research by the Author

The idea of linking the definitions of information and knowledge, and drawing on the

sticky nature of knowledge to explain frictions in the economy as the result of human

bounded rationality, was previously considered in my Master’s thesis, completed at the

University of New South Wales in 2007 under the title “Asymmetric and Imperfect

Knowledge: A Proposal to Replace Unbounded Rationality with Bounded Rationality”. This

was subsequently published as a book with the same title in 2008 by VDM Verlag Dr.

Muller. In this thesis some of the themes from that earlier work, particularly two chapters

from my Master’s thesis: Asymmetric Knowledge and Unemployment (chapter 2, pp. 30-41)

and Imperfect Knowledge and Economic Fluctuations (chapter 3, pp. 42-68) are elaborated

on and developed in far more detail. Where I draw on that earlier work, the page references

are clearly indicated and those contributions acknowledged in full. The current work builds,

elaborates, extends and develops the earlier contributions. For example, in my Master’s thesis

I suggested that the Mankiw and Reis’ (2002) sticky information Phillips curve can be

considered as way of modelling bounded rationality. In this thesis I suggested that Fuhrer and

Moore (1995) and Gali and Gertler’s (1999) hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve can also be

considered as a way of modelling bounded rationality. Much of our empirical work in this

thesis is a direct response to Gali and Gertler’s (1999) empirical finding that the reason why

the new Keynesian Phillips curve fits the data poorly is because traditional empirical work on

the Phillips curve uses some output gap measures as a proxy for real marginal cost rather than

labour’s share of income. Another important issue that the work of Gali and Gertler (1999)

raised is the new Keynesian Phillips curve literature needs to take into account labour market

frictions. This motivated us to use job finding probability as a proxy for real marginal cost.

Page 12: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

12

CHAPTER 1 New Keynesian Economics: A Review of the Literature

“It is time to put Keynes to rest in the economists’ Hall of Fame, where he certainly

belongs, and to proceed with integrating the most relevant contributions by Keynes

and his early and late followers with other strands of macroeconomic theory”

(Lindbeck, 1998, p.178).

1.1Main Features of New Keynesian Economics

New Keynesian economics is a school of thought in modern macroeconomics that

evolved from the ideas of John Maynard Keynes. New Keynesian economics emerged as a

response to the theoretical challenge of rational expectations and new classical economics in

the 1970s.New Keynesian economics attempts to derive Keynesian propositions with rational

expectations and optimizing behaviours. New Keynesian economics can be considered as

attempts to provide plausible microfoundations to explain wages and prices rigidities in the

old Keynesian spirit.

Mankiw and Romer (1991) define new Keynesian economics with reference to the

following pair of questions (Snowdon and Vane, 2005, p.363, Romer, 1993, p. 20-21):

Question 1 Does the theory violate the classical dichotomy? That is, is money non-neutral?

Question 2 Does the theory assume that real market imperfections in the economy are crucial

for understanding economic fluctuations?

Of the mainstream macroeconomics research programmes only new Keynesians

answer both questions in the affirmative; real business cycle models gave a negative response

to both questions. The primary disagreement between new classical and new Keynesian

economists is over how quickly wages and prices adjust. New classical economics assume

that wages and prices are flexible, therefore markets clear quickly. New Keynesian

economists recognize that accepting that the labour market clears implies there are no

involuntary unemployment and accepting that there are no wages and price rigidities implies

the monetary policy is neutral. Hence, many new Keynesian models attempt to explain wages

and prices stickiness in order to justify the existence of involuntary unemployment and that

monetary disturbances have real effects.

The term new-Keynesian theory was first used by Parkin and Bade in 1982 in their

textbook on modern macroeconomics. However, this line of thought had been conceived in

Page 13: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

13

the 1970s during the first phase of the new classical revolution (Snowdon and Vane, 2005,

p.361).The word new rather than neo to describe the recent work in the classical tradition

distinguishes it from what Paul Samuelson in the early postwar period called the neoclassical

synthesis of old-Keynesian macroeconomics and classical microeconomics. In turn, the word

new rather than neo is used for the recent work in the Keynesian tradition, so that it can be

properly juxtaposed to the new-classical approach (Gordon, 1990.p. 1115).

New Keynesian economists are an extremely heterogeneous group partly because

there is no unifying new Keynesian model approximating the behaviour of the economy.

Some of the economists who have made significant contributions to the new Keynesian

literature are: Gregory Mankiw, Lawrence Summers, Olivier Blanchard, Stanley Fischer,

Bruce Greenwald, Edmund Phelps, Joseph Stiglitz, Ben Bernanke, Laurence Ball, George

Akerlof, Janet Yellen, David Romer, Christina Romer, Robert Hall and John Taylor, Dennis

Snower, Assar Lindbeck, Christopher Carroll, Ricardo Reis, Alan Blinder and Guillermo

Calvo. The proximity of US new Keynesians to the east and west coasts inspired Robert Hall

to classify these economists under the general heading of ‘Saltwater’ academic institutions:

Harvard, MIT, Columbia, Princeton, Stanford and Berkeley. By a strange coincidence new

classical economists tend to be associated with ‘Freshwater’ academic institutions: Chicago,

Rochester, Minnesota and Carnegie-Mellon (Snowdon and Vane, 2005, p.362).

Mankiw and Romer (1991) argue that much of new Keynesian economics could be

considered as ‘new monetarist economics’ because of the following two reasons: First, there

is no unified new Keynesian view of the role of fiscal policy although new Keynesians do

give much greater weight to the stabilizing role of monetary policy compared to the old

Keynesian view. Second, new Keynesians do not hold a unified view on the desirability and

feasibility of activist (discretionary) stabilization policy. While most new Keynesians accept

Friedman’s critique relating to the problems that arise from uncertainty, time lags and the

potential for political distortions of policy, they also reject the ‘hard core’ monetarist

argument relating to the need for a strict monetary growth rate rule (Snowdon and Vane,

2005, p.364).

From a modeling perspective, the main difference between new classical and new

Keynesian models is the price-setting behaviour. In contrast to the price takers who inhabit

new classical models, new Keynesian models assume price-making monopolistic, rather than

perfectly competitive, firms. Most new Keynesian models assume that expectations are

formed rationally. However, some prominent new Keynesians (Blinder, 1987; Phelps, 1992)

Page 14: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

14

remain critical of the theoretical foundations and question the empirical support for the

rational expectations hypothesis. New Keynesians regard both supply and demand shocks as

potential sources of instability, but, unlike real business cycle theorists when it comes to an

assessment of a market economy’s capacity to absorb such shocks so that equilibrium (full

employment) is maintained. Many new Keynesians (but not all) also share Keynes’s view

that involuntary unemployment is both possible and likely (Snowdon and Vane, 2005,

p.365).In short, new Keynesian economics is characterized by imperfect competition,

incomplete markets, heterogeneous labour, fairness concerns and asymmetric information. A

perceived weakness with new Keynesian school that is often pointed out by its critics is that

there are many different models addressing specific issues, rather than a universal model

approximating the behaviour of the economy, the new Keynesian models appear flexible and

ad hoc to some while realistic to others (Cao, 2008, p.46).

1.2 Microeconomic Foundations of Prices Rigidities

As mentioned previously, one of the inadequacies of the neoclassical synthesis was its

assumption that prices did not adjust immediately to equilibrate supply and demand, so that,

changes in demand have real effects. The natural response to the collapse of the synthesis was

thus to investigate whether imperfect price adjustment could be derived from realistic

assumptions about the microeconomic environment, rather than assumed (Romer, 1993, p.6-

7). New Keynesians attempt to develop business cycle theories, which explain prices

rigidities with rational expectations. Various phenomena were identified as potential causes

of prices rigidities. For convenience we will divide the explanations of rigidities between

those that focus on nominal rigidities and those that focus on real rigidities. A nominal

rigidity occurs if something prevents the nominal price level from adjusting. A real rigidity

occurs if some factor prevents real wages from adjusting or there is stickiness of one wage

relative to another (Snowdon and Vane, 2005, p.365).

Nominal Rigidities

Early new Keynesian models focus on providing possible theoretical explanations for

why nominal adjustment might be incomplete. These models (Fischer (1977) and Phelps and

Taylor (1980)) showed that nominal rigidities were capable of producing real effects in

models that incorporate rational expectations, providing the assumption of continuously

clearing markets was dropped, that is, perfect and instantaneous wage and price flexibility.

Page 15: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

15

Following these contributions it became clear to everyone that the rational expectations

hypothesis did not imply the end of Keynesian economics. The crucial feature of new

classical models was shown to be the assumption of continuous market clearing, that is,

perfect and instantaneous wage and price flexibility (Snowdon and Vane, 2005, p.367). There

are two types of nominal rigidities models: staggered wages and prices and menu costs.

Staggered Wages and Prices

The Fischer (1977) and Taylor (1980) models are examples of two early new

Keynesian models that attempt to provide theoretical justifications for nominal wage

rigidities. The Fischer (1977) and the Taylor (1980) models introduce nominal inertia in the

form of long-term wage contracts. That is, not everyone in the economy set new wages and

prices every period, but, adjustment is staggered. In developed economies wages are not

determined in spot markets but tend to be set for an agreed period in the form of an explicit

(or implicit) contract (Snowdon and Vane, 2005, p.367). The Fischer (1977) and the Taylor

(1980) models posit that wages and prices are set by multi-period contracts. In each period,

the contracts governing some predetermined fraction of wages and prices expire and are

renewed. Staggered wages and prices lead to gradual adjustment of the price level to nominal

disturbances. As a result, aggregate demand disturbances leads to monetary non-neutrality,

policy rules can be stabilizing even under rational expectations (Romer, 2001, p.280).

The Fischer (1977) and Taylor (1980) models differ in one important respect, the

Fischer (1977) model assumes prices are predetermined but not fixed (i.e. different prices can

be set in each period). The Taylor (1980) model assumes fixed prices throughout contract. In

the Fischer (1977) and Taylor (1980) models, the timing of price changes is determined

solely by the passage of time, this time dependent approach is an approximation introduced to

slow down the adjustment process. In most cases, firms are free to respond to economic

conditions and developments; therefore state dependent pricing needs to be considered. The

Caplin-Spulber (1987) model emphasizes the importance of endogenous state dependent

pricing. In the Caplin-Spulber (1987) model, price changes are determined endogenously so

that the fraction of prices that changes each period can vary.

Some critics pointed out that the existence of such contracts is not explained from

solid microeconomic principles. In most cases, workers and firms are free to respond to

economic developments. An immediate question that arises from the staggered wages and

prices approach is why are long-term wage agreements formed if they increase

Page 16: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

16

macroeconomic instability? Mankiw (1990) points out that staggered wages and prices

models implies that real wages are countercyclical, which is not consistent with empirical

evidence. A monetary expansion increases employment by lowering the real wages. Yet,

empirical evidence suggests that real wages appear to be weakly procyclical. Mankiw notes,

if this were the case then recessions would be “quite popular”. While many people will be

laid off, most people who remain employed will enjoy a higher real wage (Snowdon and

Vane, 2005, p.371). We will re-examine staggered wages and prices models in more details in

chapter 2.

Coordination Failure

Coordination failures can occur when firms strategically set prices based on other

firm’s actions (Cooper and John, 1988). Some new Keynesian economists suggest recessions

are the results of coordination failures. Coordination problems can arise in the setting of

wages and prices because those who set them must anticipate the actions of other wage and

price setters. Union leaders negotiating wages are concerned about the concessions other

unions will win. Firms setting prices are mindful of the prices other firms will charge.

Suppose the economy is made up of two firms. After a fall in the money supply, each

firm must decide whether to cut its price. Each firm wants to maximize its profit, but its profit

depends not only on its pricing decision but also on the decision made by the other firm. If

neither firm cuts its price, the amount of real money (the amount of money divided by the

price level) is low, a recession ensues, and each firm makes a profit of only, for example,

fifteen dollars. If both firms cut their price, real money balances are high, a recession is

avoided, and each firm makes a profit of thirty dollars. Although both firms prefer to avoid a

recession, neither can do so by its own actions. If one firm cuts its price while the other does

not, a recession follows. The firm making the price cut makes only five dollars, while the

other firm makes fifteen dollars. The main point of this example is that each firm’s decision

influences the set of outcomes available to the other firm. When one firm cuts its price, it

improves the opportunities available to the other firm, because the other firm can then avoids

the recession by cutting its price. The inferior outcome, in which each firm makes fifteen

dollars, is an example of a coordination failure. If the two firms could coordinate, they would

both cut their price and reach the preferred outcome. In the real world, unlike in this example,

coordination is often difficult because the number of firms setting prices is large. The moral

of the story is that even though sticky prices are in no one’s interest, prices can be sticky

simply because price setters expect them to be (Mankiw, 2000, p.518-519).

Page 17: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

17

Menu Costs

One reason why prices may not adjust immediately to clear when economic

conditions change is because adjusting prices is costly. To change prices firms need to send

out new catalogue, prices lists, or, in the case of a restaurant, print new menus, hence the term

‘menu costs’. These costs cause firms to adjust prices periodically rather than continuously.

In imperfect competition, a firm’s profits will vary differentially with changes in its

own price because its sales will not fall to zero if it marginally increases price. Price

reductions by such a firm will increase sales and raises real income. The stimulus from higher

income, in turn, raises the demand for the products of all firms. In such circumstances any

divergence of price from the optimum will only produce “second-order” reductions of profits.

Hence, the presence of even small costs to price adjustment can generate considerable

aggregate nominal price rigidity and aggregate demand externality. This observation is due to

Akerlof and Yellen (1985a), Mankiw (1985) and Parkin (1986) (Snowdon and Vane, 2005,

p.372).

Some economists are skeptical about whether menu costs can help explain short-run

economic fluctuations. They argue that these small costs are unlikely to help explain

recessions. James Tobin thinks that “Keynes would have laughed at the idea that menu costs

are a big enough resource-using problem to cause the Great Depression or any other

substantial losses of economic activity. It’s not credible” (Snowdon and Vane, 2005, p.156).

Any microeconomic basis for failure of the classical dichotomy (money is non-

neutral) requires some kind of nominal imperfection; otherwise, a purely nominal disturbance

leaves the real equilibrium (or the set of real equilibria) unchanged.' This immediately raises

a difficulty. Individuals are ultimately concerned with real prices and quantities: real wages,

hours of work, real consumption levels, and the like. Nominal magnitudes matter to them

only in ways that are minor and easily overcome. Prices and wages are quoted in nominal

terms, but it costs little to change (or index) them. Individuals are not fully informed about

the aggregate price level or the money supply, but they can obtain quite accurate information

at little cost. Thus, if failure of the classical dichotomy is important to fluctuations in

aggregate activity, it must be that nominal frictions that appear small at the level of individual

households and firms somehow have a large effect on the macro-economy (Romer, 1993, p.

8).

Page 18: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

18

Real Rigidities

Romer (1993, p. 10) points out that it is not plausible that adding imperfect

competition and small barriers to price adjustment is enough to provide a microeconomic

basis for the view that aggregate demand shocks are central to economic fluctuations because

of the nature of the labour market. If labor supply is relatively inelastic and if there are no

departures from Walrasian assumptions aside from the presence of small barriers to nominal

adjustment, then the decline in labour input associated with the decline in production leads to

a large fall in the real wage. In this case, marginal cost falls greatly in recessions. As a result,

unless the elasticity of demand also falls sharply, firms' incentives to reduce prices are large.

If labour supply is relatively inelastic, firms' incentives to change their prices in the face of

aggregate demand movements of a few percent swamp any plausible barriers to nominal

adjustment. A great deal of research in new Keynesian economics is concerned with specific

factors that can give rise to real rigidities. Below are four potential sources of real price

rigidity that the new Keynesian literature has identified, of the four, three are briefly

mentioned below and the fourth in more detail in section 1.3.

The first potential source of real price rigidity is external economies of scale arising

from "thick market externalities" (Diamond, 1982). Markets tend to function better during

periods of high economic activity when traders are more active than in times of low

economic activity. It is possible that people are much more willing to participate when

market are more active where a lot of trade is taking place and this leads to strategic

complementary; that is, “the optimal level of activity of one firm depends on the activity of

other firms. If these thick market externalities help to shift the marginal cost curve up in

recessions and down in booms, then this will contribute to real price rigidity” (Snowdon and

Vane, 2005, p.380).

The second line of work considers capital market imperfections (Bernanke and

Gertler, 1989) arising from asymmetric information between lenders and borrowers. That is,

borrowers are much better informed about their business than lenders. “It follows that in a

situation of asymmetric information, internal finance is less expensive than external finance.

Since firms have higher profits and hence more funds available for internal finance in booms

than in recessions, capital market imperfections tend to make the cost of capital

countercyclical; and since capital costs are an important component of overall costs, this acts

to make the cost curve move in a countercyclical direction” (Romer,1993, p. 11-12).

Page 19: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

19

The third area of research focuses on the cyclical behavior of demand elasticities in

goods markets. The elasticity of demand might vary in response to aggregate output

movements for a number of reasons. “For example, when aggregate output is high, "thick

market" effects may make it easier for firms to disseminate information and for consumers to

acquire it. This could act to make the elasticity of demand, and hence the marginal revenue

curve more procyclical, and would thus reduce firms' incentives to adjust their prices in

response to aggregate demand movements” (Romer, 1993, p. 12).

1.3 Real Rigidities in the Labour Market

The fourth and most important area of research is real rigidities in the labour market.

Due to its importance and the vast literature relating to this topic, we will consider this topic

under a different sub heading. Nominal rigidities allow fluctuations of aggregate demand to

have real effects and contribute to a non-market-clearing explanation of business cycles.

However, new Keynesian economists are also concerned with explaining the persistently high

levels of unemployment that have been a major feature of the labour markets of the major

industrial countries since the early 1970s. In new classical monetary and real business cycle

models all agents are price takers. Perfect and instantaneous price and wage flexibility

ensures that the labour market always clears at Walrasian market-clearing real wage. In a new

Keynesian world, where price makers predominate, an equilibrium real wage can emerge

which differs from the market-clearing real wage. Models involving real wage rigidity are

capable of generating involuntary unemployment in long-run equilibrium, in contrast to new

classical models where, with everyone on their labour supply function, unemployment in

equilibrium is a voluntary phenomenon (Snowdon and Vane, 2005, p.383).

An important empirical observation that new Keynesian theories of unemployment try

explain why shifts in labour demand appear to lead to large movements in employment and

only small movements in the real wage, that is, the real wage is weakly procyclical. If the

labor market were Walrasian and labour supply inelastic, real wages would be highly

procyclical. If this pattern held in practice, real rigidities elsewhere in the economy would

have to be extremely strong to overcome the large incentive for adjustment created by sharply

procyclical wages. However, although analysts dispute the precise cyclical behavior of real

wages, there is no evidence that they are strongly procyclical (Romer, 1993, p. 12). New

Keynesian explanations of real wage rigidity fall into four main groups: implicit contract

theories, efficiency wage theories, insider–outsider theories and search and matching

theories.

Page 20: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

20

Implicit Contracts

The main idea of implicit (unwritten) contract theory is to explain unemployment as a

result of implicit contract between an employer and an employee that specifies how much

labour is supplied and how much wage is paid. Implicit contract can lead to a firm choosing

wage and employment levels off the conventional labour demand curve, potentially helping

us to explain involuntary unemployment. Though originally intended to underpin the

Keynesian nominal wage rigidity assumption, it is now recognized that implicit contracts lead

to real rather than nominal wage rigidities. Important contributions to the implicit contracts

literature include Azariadis, (1975), Bailey (1974) and Gordon (1974) (Romer, 2001, p. 435).

Azariadis, (1975), Bailey (1974) and Gordon (1974) examine the consequences of

optimal labour contracts established between less risk-averse employers and risk-averse

workers. “Employers are less risk averse and have greater access to the capital market than

they do. As a result, employers provide some form of wage and employment insurance as

part of the employment package. To put it another way, a firm which offered such insurance

as part of its employment package would be able to attract workers at a lower (average)wage

than a firm which did not provide such insurance” (Stiglitz, 1984, p. 6).

A major problem with implicit contract models is they fail to explain involuntary

unemployment. “If all states of nature are observable (and verifiable), then the implicit

contract would specify the amount of labour and the wage to be paid in each state. In such

circumstances, though there may be relatively little fluctuations in wage (incomes), the

implicit contract would not give rise to unemployment: the marginal rate of substitution of

each individual between income and leisure would be equal to the marginal rate of

transformation, and there would be no lay-offs” (Stiglitz, 1984, p. 6).

Efficiency Wage Theories

The idea of efficiency wage theories is that the real wage is not only a cost for firms.

In the presence of perfect information and transaction costs, the wage is also an instrument to

recruit, retain and motivate workers. A firm which wants to recruit workers more quickly or

to reduce the number of quits can raise its wage above the wage set by others employers.

Similarly, a firm which cannot observe its employees’ effort may find worthwhile to increase

its wage in order to motivate them. In all of these cases, the wage is for something else that

the allocation of labour on the clearing of the labour market. Efficiency wage models can

Page 21: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

21

provide an explanation for involuntary unemployment as well as explaining why real wage is

weakly procyclical (Romer, 2001, p. 415 and Cao, 2008, p. 31).

Stiglitz (1984, pp. 43-49) points out that there are at least five different explanations

for the wage-productive relationship in the efficiency wage literature. The first theory is

based on the hypothesis that individual's productivity depended on their nutrition, which

depended in turn on their pay. This idea was first hypothesized by Leibenstein (1957) and

subsequently analyzed in greater detail by Mirrless (1975) and Stiglitz (1976). This version of

the theory is more relevant in developing countries where food is scarcer. However,

nutritional considerations are less important in more developed countries.

The second version of efficiency wage theory hypothesizes that some firms pay above

the market-clearing wage in order to reduce costly labour turnover. This approach is based on

the pioneering work of Phelps (1970) and Stiglitz (1974, 1982) in the development of

explanations of the natural rate of unemployment and search behaviour. Even in the presence

of unemployment firms are unlikely to lower its wages because unemployed workers might

continue to search for a still better job.

The third version of efficiency wage theory hypothesizes that firms have imperfect

information about the quality of job applicants; firms that pay higher wages in order to obtain

higher quality applicants and any applicant who offers to work for less than the efficiency

wage will be regarded as a potential “lemon” (adverse selection). This approach is based on

the pioneering work of Stiglitz (1976) and Weiss (1980).

The fourth version of efficiency wage theory is based on asymmetric information

concerning the efforts of workers; workers tend to know more about their effort levels than

their employers. This asymmetry creates a principal–agent problem. In order to induce

workers not to shirk, firms thus attempt to raise their wages relative to the market wage by

paying an efficiency wage as an incentive for workers not to shirk. This approach is based on

the work of Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984)

The fifth version of efficiency wage theory hypothesizes that the productivity of

workers depends on whether they believe they are being fairly treated. In a series of papers,

Akerlof (1982, 1984) and Akerlof and Yellen (1987, 1988, 1990) developed models where

fairness act as a deterrent to firms to offer too low wages in the labour market. “The ability of

workers to exercise control over their effort, and their willingness to do so in response to

grievances, underlies the fair wage–effort hypothesis” (Akerlof and Yellen, 1990, p. 262).

Page 22: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

22

“Though the five theories differ in a number of important respects, they have a

common mathematical structure”: the net productivity of a worker is a function of the wage

paid by the firm and the unemployment rate (Stiglitz, 1984, p. 48).

Search and Matching Theories

The search and matching theories provide a way of modeling frictional

unemployment in the labour market. This approach considers workers and jobs as highly

heterogeneous. Workers and firms meet in a one-on-one fashion and engage in a costly

process of trying to match up idiosyncratic preferences, skills and needs. Since this process is

not instantaneous, it results in some frictional unemployment.

1.4 Conclusion

The new Keynesian research programme has been driven by the view that the

orthodox Keynesian model lacked coherent microfoundations with respect to wage and price

rigidities. As a result the new Keynesian literature has been, until recently focused on

theoretical developments instead of empirical testing. The main problem with the new

Keynesian research programme is its incoherencies, since there are many alternative models

addressing a specific issue. New Keynesians recognize this problem, with Blanchard (1992)

reflecting that “we have constructed too many monsters with “few interesting results”. The

fascination with constructing a “bewildering array” of theories with their “quasi religious”

adherence to microfoundations has become a disease. Because there are too many reasons for

wage and price inertia, no agreement exists on which source of rigidity is the most important”

(Snowdon and Vane, 2005, p. 429).

Page 23: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

23

CHAPTER 2

From Sticky-Prices to Sticky-Information to Sticky-Knowledge

2.1 Introduction

The purpose of this chapter is to argue that inflation expectations are boundedly

rational and to provide the theoretical foundation for our empirical work in the later chapters.

Under rational expectations, the NKPC implies inflation is a purely forward variable;

inflation depends on expectations of future inflation and on current output. No lagged

variables-including lagged inflation-should have an impact on the current level of inflation.

However, contrary to the prediction of rational expectations, many empirical studies on the

new Keynesian Phillips curve find that the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive

expectations fits the data much better than the new Keynesian Phillips curve (Fuhrer and

Moore (1995), Fuhrer (1997), Mankiw (2001) and Rudd and Whelan (2006)).

In order to incorporate bounded rationality into the Phillips curve framework we

utilise two types of models that include lagged inflation as an explanatory variable in the

Phillips curve. The first type is Mankiw and Reis (2001, 2002) sticky-information Phillips

curve and the second type is Fuhrer and Moore (1995) and Gali and Gertler‘s (1999) hybrid

new Keynesian Phillips curve. Without considering bounded rationality, and the relationship

between economists and non-economists, these models cannot provide a plausible rationale

for the inclusion of lagged inflation as an explanatory variable in the Phillips curve. Fuhrer

and Moore (1995) assume that agents are concerned with relative real wages, Gali and

Gertler (1999) assume that only a fraction of agents use rational expectations, while the

remainder use last period’s inflation rate as a simple rule of thumb for forecasting inflation.

Mankiw and Reis (2001, 2002) sticky-information model use epidemiological analogy, and

use deviations of the actual inflation rates from the expected inflation rates to explain the

inflation-output dynamics.

We will attempt to argue that bounded rationality can explain the observation that

lagged inflation plays an important role in empirical inflation regressions as the dissemination

of economic information and knowledge between professional economists and non-

economists. Since economics agents take expectations subject to the information and

knowledge decision-making constraints that confront them, and if the required knowledge is

not common knowledge but professional knowledge, the best ways for non-professionals to

minimize their forecast errors is by employing the services of professionals forecasters or

Page 24: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

24

observe how professionals forecasters respond and replicate their actions, rather than making

forecasts without the required knowledge. Since the general public’s inflation expectations

respond to the professional economists’ expectations with time lag, lagged inflation rates are

correlated with the current inflation rate. In the later chapters, we use the NKPC as a

benchmark comparing the empirical results of the old Keynesian Phillips curve and the

hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve, which represents bounded rationality.

The structure of this chapter is as follows. Section 1 describes some of the early

developments of the Phillips curve and their implications. Section 2 examines sticky-prices

new Keynesian models of Taylor (1979, 1980) and Calvo (1983). While in these models the

price level is sticky, the inflation rate can change quickly because there is no sluggishness in

adjusting inflationary expectations. Although there are different ways of deriving the NKPC,

they all have a common formulation; inflation in the Taylor (1979, 1980) and the Calvo

(1983) models depends on expectations of future inflation and on current output (also see

Roberts (1995)). Section 3 examines sticky-information models of Carroll (2003) and

Mankiw and Reis (2001, 2002), it can be said that these models use expectations based on the

bounded rationality approach of Simon (1979, p. 507). The main difference between these

models and the earlier models of Taylor and Calvo is that while in these models sluggish

adjustments are in the formation of expectations, in the Taylor and Calvo models

sluggishness is due to inertia in price adjustments. Although this difference appears to be

minor, proponents of the sluggish expectations models claim that their models can explain

some observed facts better than the sluggish price adjustment models. Section 4 attempts to

redefine the microfoundations of Mankiw and Reis (2001, 2002) and Carroll’s (2001, 2003)

approach, based on the idea of that knowledge about monetary policy (inflation) is

professional knowledge, the best way for non-economists to minimize their forecast errors is

to listen to the advices of professional economists. Section 5 concludes.

2.2 The Philips Curve and some Developments

The Phillips curve is an empirical relationship first observed by A.W. Phillips in

1958. Phillips documented that there was a relatively stable relationship between wage

inflation and the rates of unemployment in the United Kingdom from 1861 to 1957. The

original Phillips curve was only an empirical phenomenon, lacking theoretical underpinning.

Lipsey (1960) provided the first major theoretical underpinning through the combination of

two postulated relationships: First, a positive linear relationship between the rate of increase

in money wage and excess demand for labour. Second, a negative non-linear relationship

Page 25: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

25

between excess demand for labour and unemployment rate. By combining these two

postulated relationships, Lipsey was able to provide the rationale that the rate of change of

money wages depends on the degree of excess demand (or supply) in the labour market as

proxy by the rate of unemployment (Snowdon and Vane, 2005, pp.137-139).

One of the main reasons why the Phillips curve was quickly adopted by the

Keynesians was it provided an explanation of price determination and inflation, which was

missing in the Keynesian macroeconomic literature based on the ISLM model at that time.

Keynesians thought that the price level was fixed and unresponsive to changes in aggregate

demand. Only when full employment is reached will changes in aggregate demand affect the

price level. The Phillips curve allowed the Keynesian theory of output and employment

determination to be linked to a theory of wage and price inflation (Snowdon and Vane, 2005,

p.142). Following Samuelson and Solow’s (1960) influential contribution, the Phillips curve

was interpreted by many Keynesians as the existence of a stable trade-off between inflation

and unemployment. In addition, this trade-off has generally been expressed in terms of price

inflation instead of wage inflation (Snowdon and Vane, 2005, p.144).

In the late 1960s and early 1970s many countries experienced high levels of

unemployment and inflation simultaneously, a phenomenon that theories based on the

Phillips curve could not explain. The idea of a stable relationship between inflation and

unemployment was challenged independently by Milton Friedman (1968) and Edmund

Phelps (1967, 1968) (Snowdon and Vane, 2005, p.144).Friedman’s (1968) and Phelps’ (1967,

1968) ‘natural rate hypothesis’ states that there is a natural rate of unemployment and that

monetary policy cannot keep unemployment below this level indefinitely. Friedman and

Phelps argued that the idea that nominal variables such as money supply or inflation could

permanently affect real variables such as output or unemployment was unreasonable; as in

the long-run, real variables are affected by real forces. Permanent expansionary monetary

policy would eventually change the way wages and prices are set. There is no reason for

workers and firms to settle on different levels of employment and real wage just because

inflation is higher (Romer, 2001, p.245-246).

Subsequently whether there is a permanent output-inflation trade-off became an

important debate in modern macroeconomics. These issues have important implications for

modelling the dynamics of inflation, unemployment and output and the scope for stabilisation

policy. In general, the monetarist and neoclassical models imply that stabilisation policies are

ineffective. On the other hand, the Keynesian and New Keynesian models imply that

Page 26: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

26

stabilisation policies are effective and should be implemented. An alternative way of stating

this difference is that while monetarists argue that changes to nominal demand have no real

effects, Keynesians argue that they have significant real effects.

There have been some crucial developments in this debate and one of the most

important developments was due to the Friedman-Phelps argument that the original Phillips

curve has ignored the role of inflation expectations in wage bargains and implies that workers

suffer with money illusion. This is not consistent with the axioms of economics that all agents

are rational.3 Therefore, these authors have developed the expectations augmented Phillips

curve and their theoretical arguments imply that there is no trade-off between inflation and

unemployment in the long run. This in turn validates the monetarist arguments that nominal

demand shocks have no real effects and stabilisation policies will be ineffective in the long

run.

There are two main theories regarding the formulations of expected inflation.

Expectations are adaptive if they are based on past behaviour of inflation; the main problem

with adaptive expectation is the failure of economic agents to use additional information

available to them other than past values of inflation, despite making repeated errors. In

contrast, expectations are rational if they are based on all information available at the time the

expectations are made and not just past information (Snowdon and Vane, 2005, p.227). The

problem with the adaptive expectations formulation employed in many Keynesians and

monetarists in the 1960’s and the 1970’s was that it implies systematic error in forecasting as

it does not take into account of other relevant information.

The Lucas Imperfect – Information Model

The Friedman (1968) and Phelps (1967, 1968) insight was given an explicit rational

expectations foundation by Robert Lucas. Lucas (1972, 1973) and Phelps (1970)

independently developed a monetary theory of the business cycle based on imperfect-

information to producers. The central idea of the Lucas-Phelps model is that when a producer

observes a change in the price of his product, he is not sure if it reflects a change in the

good’s relative price or a change in the aggregate price level, this is sometimes referred to as

3An alternative and simpler explanation is that it is the real wage rate—not the nominal wage rate as in the

original Phillips curve—that should change with the excess demand for labour. Therefore, the Phillips curve is

based on the assumption that workers suffer with money illusion and this is not consistent with rational

behaviour.

Page 27: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

27

a “signal extracting problem”. Suppose the price level of the firm’s product rises, the firm

will rationally attribute part of the change to an increase in the price level and part to an

increase in the relative price, and therefore to increase output somewhat. This implies that the

aggregate supply curve is upward sloping (Romer, 2001, p.266). The analysis of producer

behaviour under imperfect information led to what is referred to as the Lucas supply curve,

which is as follows.

* ( [ ])y y b p E p (2.1)

Equation (2.1) states that deviations of output ( )y from its natural level *( )y is an

increasing function of deviations of price ( )p from its expected level ( [ ]).E p The Lucas

supply curve is interpreted by many same as the expectations augmented Phillips curve.

However, while the Phillips curve is a price adjustment equation in a disequilibrium market,

the Lucas supply curve is a quantity response function of firms in the imperfect information

markets. Prices in these markets are determined by the equality of the demand and (Lucas)

supply functions. If we accept the common interpretation that the Lucas supply curve is an

inverted Phillips curve, it may be stated that both relationships imply that if we neglect

disturbances to supply, output is above its natural level only to the extent that inflation (and

hence the price level) is greater than expected (Romer, 2001, p.266-274). In this thesis,

however, we shall use this common interpretation of the Lucas supply curve, albeit with some

reservations.

The Lucas supply curve implies a positive statistical relationship between output and

inflation can arise even though prices adjust instantaneously and markets clear, but there is no

exploitable trade-off between output and inflation because changes in policy affect

expectations, which can change this trade off. In short, if policy makers attempt to take

advantage of this trade off, firms take into account the effects of changed policies on

expectations because these expectations are rational and the relationship breaks down. This

insight is known as the Lucas critique (Romer, 2001, p. 275)

The Lucas Imperfect Information model was very influential and provided important

insights into the effects of monetary policy under rational expectations. However, the model

implies that monetary disturbances should not have any transitory effects on real activity if

the public can observe changes in monetary policy. In real life the money supply is published

regularly and can be observed within a few weeks. Therefore the real effects of variations in

the money supply should last only a few weeks. Yet in empirical studies on the effects of

Page 28: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

28

monetary disturbances the real effects seem to persist for many quarters. According to

Woodford (2001, p.4) even after ten quarters from the initial shock, this real effect is still

more than one-third of the size of its peak effect.

2.3 The Sticky-Prices Approach

The First Taylor Model

One of the earliest formulations of the sticky price models is by Taylor (1979). His

staggered-contract model assumes that wage contracts last one year, with half of the contacts

are set in January and half in July. Let tx be the log of the contact wage for periods t and 1t , set at the start of period ,t then the contract wage determination is given by (Roberts, 1995,

pp. 978-979).

1 1 1ˆ ˆ ˆ( )t t t t t tx bx dx by dy (2.2)

where ty is a measure of excess demand in period t , t

is a random shock, and b , d and

are positive parameters. The “hat” over a variable represents its conditional expectation based

on period 1t information. Equation (2.2) states that contract wage in the current period

depends on the contract wage set in the previous period, the contract wage expected to be set

in the next period and a weighted average of excess demand expected during the next two

periods.

In order to derive the implied dynamics of equation (2.2) we need to specify an

aggregate demand equation and a policy rule. Assume that excess demand ( )ty is the

deviation of output from its trend and that the demand for money is given by t t t tm y w v ,

where the variable tm , t

w and tv are the logs of the money supply, the aggregate wage level,

and a shock, all measured as deviations from trend. Note that this money demand equation is

simply the quantity equation with the wage substituted for the price level.

If the policy rule for the money supply is given by t tm gw , then the aggregate demand

equation is given by

(1 )t t ty g w v w v (2.3)

where is a policy parameter indicating the degree of accommodation of aggregate demand

by the policy maker to wage changes. The average wage for two periods is given by

Page 29: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

29

10.5( )t t tw x x (2.4)

Workers are assumed to be concerned about real wages and unemployment, therefore the

labour supply curve, stated in terms of unemployment rate, given by (Roberts, 1995, p.979),

is as follows.

1 10

( ) ( )

2 2

t t t t t tt t

p E p RU E RUx c (2.5)

where p is the log of price, RU is the unemployment rate, is a white noise error term, and

0c and are constants. 0 , there is a negatively relationship between the unemployment

rate and real wage.

If firms set prices as a mark-up over costs, the price equation is:

(1 )t t

p w (2.6)

where is the mark-up ratio. For simplicity is assumed to be zero in the following price

equation.

t tp w (2.7)

Equations (2.4), (2.5) and (2.7) can be combined to give:

1 0 1 1 1

1

( )

2( )

t t t t t t t t t

t t t

p E p c RU RU E RU E RU

(2.8)

where t is an expectational error 1( )t t tE p p . Inflation depends on expected inflation and a

moving average of the unemployment rate (Roberts, 1995, p.979). This is the specification

implied for the NKPC and can be estimated with a suitable hypothesis for rational

expectations for inflation so that [ ] 0.E

The Second Taylor Model

In Taylor’s second model of 1980, the expected average real contract wage is

assumed to be increasing in the level of output ( ),ty which is simpler than his assumption in

his first model, and is as follows (Walsh, 2003, pp. 224-225).

Page 30: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

30

1

1( )

2t t t t t

x p E p ky (2.9)

If prices are set as a mark-up on the two periods average cost, with the mark-up assumed to

be zero for simplicity, we have the following price equation.

1

1( )

2t t t

p x x (2.10)

Substitution of (2.9) in (2.10) gives:

1 1 1 1

1 1 1

1 1 1( ) ( )

2 2 2

1 = (2 ) ( )

4 2

t t t t t t t t t

t t t t t t t

p p E p ky p E p ky

kp E p p y y

(2.11)

where 1t t t tE p p is an expectational error term. Rearranging (2.11) gives the following.

1 1 1

1 1 1( )

2 2 2t t t t t t t

p p E p k y y (2.12)

Thus in the second Taylor (1980) model inertia in the aggregate price level tp depends on

expectations of future prices and the price level in the previous period. If the inflation rate

1 t t tp p then (2.12) can be rearranged as:

1 12 ( )t t t t tE k y y (2.13)

Inflation depends on expectations of future inflation, current output and output in the

previous period. An important aspect of the Taylor (1979, 1980) models is that “while prices

display inertia, there is no inertia in the rate of inflation” (Walsh, 1998, p.217).

The Calvo Model

In the Calvo (1983) model each period a fraction ( ) of monopolistic competitive

firms update their information on the current state of the economy and compute optimal

prices based on that information. The rest of the firms (1 ) continue to set prices based on

past and outdated information. Calvo’s (1983) model is set in continuous time. We follow

Walsh (1998, pp. 218-220) and Rotemberg (1987) in our exposition of the Calvo model in

discrete time as it allows us to make comparisons easier.

Suppose the representative firm i sets its price using a quadratic loss function that

depends on the difference between its actual price ( )itp and its optimal price *( )tp . The firm

Page 31: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

31

sets its prices to minimize the squared deviations of its actual prices from its optimal prices

subject to when the firm will be next be able to adjust.

* 2

0

1( )

2

j

t it j t j

j

E p p (2.14)

Since 1 is the probability of not being able to adjust its price in the next period. The first

order condition for the optimal choice of itp requires that

*

0 0

1 1 0

jjj j

it t t j

j j

p E p

Let t denote the price set at t by all firms adjusting their price.

*

0

1 1 1j j

t t t j

j

E p

(2.15)

The price set by the firm at time t is a weighted average of current and expected future values

of the target*p . This can be rewritten as

*

11 1 1t t t tp E

Assume that the optimal price is given by *

t t tp p y w , the optimal price *p is

assumed to depend on the aggregate price level tp and output t

y as would be the case if

firm face a downward-sloping demand curve, where tw is a random disturbance. With a large

number of firms, a fraction will actually adjust their price each period, and the aggregate

price level can be expressed as 11

t t tp p .

The evolution of t and tp are given by

11 1 1t t t t t tp y w E (2.16)

11

t t tp p (2.17)

Update equation (2.17) by one period and take expectations

1 11

t t t t tE p E p

This can be rewritten as

Page 32: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

32

1 1t t t t tE E p

Eliminate 1t tE for equation (2.16), then eliminate t from equation (2.17).

1 1

1 1

1 1

t t t t

t t t t

p p y w

E p p

Rearranging

1

' '

1

1 1

1

t t t t t

t t t t

E y w

E y w

(2.18)

where

'

1 1

1

and

'

1 1

1

t

t

ww

Similar to the Taylor model, inflation in Calvo’s model depends on expectations of

future inflation and on current output. Another important similarity between the two models

is the Phillips curve only have forward-looking expectations, as a result, there is no inertia in

the rate of inflation.

Problems with the Sticky-Prices Approach

Much of the literature on the standard new Keynesian Phillips curve builds on the

pioneering work of Taylor (1979,1980), Rotemberg (1982) and Calvo (1983), and is based on

time-contingent price adjustment. Despite its popularity in the theoretical analysis of

monetary policy, the standard NKPC makes several predictions that are not supported by

empirical evidence. The two main problems with this standard NKPC are that inflation is not

very persistent and that the model predicts credible disinflations can cause booms. These

problems originate from the assumptions that prices are sluggish in the models, but, inflation

expectations can change quickly. Furthermore, empirical studies have shown inflation rates

are highly autocorrelated, this suggests that past inflation rates are important in the

determining the current rate of inflation. Below are various attempts to explain the

persistence of inflation.

Fuhrer and Moore (1995) attempt to explain the persistence of inflation by modelling

wage negotiations in terms of relative wage contracts (i.e. wage indexation) instead of

nominal wage contracts. Gali and Gertler (1999) modify Calvo’s (1983) model by

introducing lagged inflation into the Phillips curve. They also estimate the coefficient of

Page 33: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

33

lagged inflation of their hybrid Phillips curve and find that the coefficient of lagged inflation

is generally lower than that of other papers (i.e. Fuhrer, 1997), which suggest that inflation is

predominantly backward-looking. Gali and Gertler (1999) suggest that the output gap is a

poor proxy for real marginal cost. Rudd and Whelan (2006, p.319) find that adding lags to the

standard NKPC improve empirical fit, they suggest that inflation expectations are not fully

rational and that adding lagged inflation term is just addressing the cause of the problem,

which they believe to be deviations from rational expectations (bounded rationality).

In the next section we will examine another approach to explaining the persistence of

inflation by assuming inflation expectations are sluggish rather than assuming price

adjustments are sluggish.

2.4 The Sticky-Information Approach

Mankiw and Reis Model4

The motivation for Mankiw and Reis’ (2002, p. 1295) sticky-information Phillips

curve is to replace the earlier rationalisations of the NKPC based on sticky-prices and they

argue that:

“Compared to the commonly used sticky-price model, this sticky-information model

displays three related properties that are more consistent with accepted views about

the effects of monetary policy. First, disinflations are always contractionary (although

announced disinflations are less contractionary than surprise ones). Second, monetary

policy shocks have their maximum impact on inflation with a substantial delay. Third,

the change in inflation is positively correlated with the level of economic activity”.

Mankiw and Reis note that these problems appear to arise from the same source,

namely that although the price level is sticky in the model, the inflation rate can change

quickly because expectations adjust quickly. The central idea of Mankiw and Reis model is

that information about macroeconomic conditions diffuses slowly through the population.

They argue that this slow diffusion could arise because of either costs of acquiring

information or costs of reoptimizing. To formalize this idea, they assume that in each period a

fraction of the population updates itself on the current state of the economy and computes

optimal prices based on that information. The rest of the population continues to set prices

based on old plans and outdated information. Essentially, the model combines elements of

4 A less detailed version of this model was presented as part of my Master’s thesis (Cao, 2008, pp. 49-53).

Page 34: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

34

Calvo’s (1983) model of random adjustment with elements of the Lucas (1972) model of

imperfect information, set in monopolistic competition.

Expectations are formed similar to that of Fischer’s (1977) contracting model with the

current price level formed far in the past, because price setters are setting prices based on old

decisions and old information. This way of modelling expectations yields large differences in

the dynamic pattern of prices and output in response to monetary policy. This can be

modelled as follows. All variables are expressed in log. The optimal price *p of any firm in a

given period is given by:

*

t t tp p y (2.19)

wherety is the output gap and tp is the aggregate price level. The parameter captures the

sensitivity of the optimal relative price to the current output gap. If is small, then each firm

gives more weight to what other firms are charging than to the level of aggregate demand,

therefore a small value of α can be interpreted as a high degree of real rigidity (to use the

terminology of Ball and Romer (1990)) or high degree strategic complementarities (to use the

terminology of Cooper and John (1988)). In the sticky-information model, this real rigidity is

a source of inflation inertia.

In each period, a fraction of firms obtains new information about the state of the

economy and compute a new path of optimal prices. Other firms continue to set prices based

on old plans and outdated information. An assumption is made about information arrival that

is analogous to the adjustment in the Calvo model: Each firm has the same probability of

being one of the firms updating their pricing plans, regardless of how long it has been since

its last update.

A firm that last updated its plans j periods ago sets the price:

*j

t t j tE p (2.20)

The aggregate price level is the average of the prices of all firms in the economy:

0

1j j

t t

j

p

(2.21)

Putting these three equations together yield the following equation for the price level:

0

1

j

t t j t t

j

p E p y

(2.22)

Page 35: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

35

This is the short-run Phillips curve, where output is positively associated with surprise

movements in the price level. For convenience, we have included the algebra in the appendix

of Mankiw and Reis (2002, pp. 1320-1321) in the derivation of the sticky-information

Phillips curve.

By taking out the first term and redefining the summation index, this equation can be written

as:

1

1

0

1

j

t t t t j t t

j

p p y E p y

(2.23)

Analogous to equation (2.23), the previous period’s price level can be written as:

1 1 1 1

0

1

j

t t j t t

j

p E p y (2.24)

Subtracting (2.23) from (2.24) by breaking up the sum of tp and 1t

p and rearranging yields

the following equation for the inflation rate:

1

1

0

1

j

t t t t j t t

j

p p y E p y

2

1 21 1 ...t t t t t t t t tp p y E p y E p y

1 1 1 1

0

1

j

t t j t t

j

p E p y

1 1 1 1 2 1 11 ...

t t t t t t tp E p y E p y

1 1 1 1 1

2

2 2 1 1

1

1 1 ...

t t t t t t t t t t t

t t t t t t

p p p y E p y E p y

E p y E p y

Let 1t t tp p and 1t t t

y y y , after rearranging, we obtain

1 1 2

2 2

1 2

1

1 ...

t t t t t t t t t t t

t t t t t t

p p p y E y E y

E p y E p y

1

0

2

1

0

1

1

j

t t t t j t t

j

j

t j t t

j

p y E y

E p y

(2.25)

Page 36: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

36

Now equation (2.24) can be rearranged to show that:

1

0

11

j

t t t j t t

j

p y E p y

1

1

0

1

j

t t t t j t t

j

p p y E p y

1

1

0

1

j

t t t t j t t

j

p p y E p y

1

1

0

1

j

t t t t j t t

j

p p y E p y

1

0

1 1 1

j

t t t j t t

j

p y E p y

1

0

11

j

t t t j t t

j

p y E p y

(2.26)

We now use equation (2.27) to substitute for the last term in equation (2.26). After

rearranging, we obtain:

111

j

t t t t j t t t t

j o

p y E y p y

11

1

j

t t t t t t j t t

j o

p y p y E y

11 1j

t t t j t t

j o

y E y

(2.27)

where 1t t ty y y is the growth rate of output. This is the sticky-information Phillips

curve; inflation depends on output, expectations of inflation, and expectations of output

growth.

Page 37: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

37

Inflation and Output Dynamics

To complete the model, Mankiw and Reis add an aggregate demand equation

m p y (2.28)

where m is nominal GDP. This equation can be viewed as a quantity theory approach to

aggregate demand, where m can be interpreted as the money supply. Mankiw and Reis also

introduce a backward-looking model:

t t t 1 y (2.29)

This model can be viewed as the sticky-price model together with the assumption of adaptive

expectations:

t t 1 t 1E (2.30)

Three policy experiments were conducted:

E1 – An unexpected fall in the level of aggregate demand by 10% at date 0. Thus,

log(0.9)tm for 0t and 0tm for 0t

E2 – An unexpected drop in the rate of money growth m at date 0, from 2.5 percent per

period to 0 percent. Thus, 0.025(1 )tm t for 1t 0tm for 0t .

E3 – Same as E2 but announced at date 8t .

Results of Monetary Policy Experiments

Experiment 1: A 10% drop in the level of aggregate demand.

All three models predict sudden recessions.

All three models predict the fall in demand on output is close to zero after 16 quarters.

The backward-looking model generates an oscillatory pattern, whereas the other two

models yield monotonic paths.

In the sticky-price model, the greatest impact of the fall in demand on inflation occurs

immediately.

In the sticky-information model, the maximum impact of the fall in demand on

inflation occurs after seven quarters, implying more inflation inertia.

Page 38: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

38

Experiment 2: A sudden disinflation.

In the sticky-price model, prices are sticky but inflation exhibits no inertia, therefore

inflation responds instantly to the fall in money growth and output does not change.

Hence, the sticky-price model predicts disinflation is costless.

The sticky-information model predicts a gradual reduction in inflation because some

firms are setting prices based on old information. The economy experiences a

recession with the trough occurring about six quarters after the policy change.

Experiment 3: An anticipated disinflation

The predictions for the backward-looking model are the same as in Experiment 2

because the assumption of adaptive expectations prevents the announcement from

having any effect.

The sticky-price model predicts announced disinflation causes a boom. “When price

setters anticipate a slow-down in money growth, inflation, together with continued

increases in the money supply, leads to rising real money balances and higher output”.

The sticky-information model does not predict booms in response to anticipated

disinflations. In this model, there is no change in output on inflation until the

disinflationary policy of slower money growth begins. An announced disinflation

leads to a quicker inflation response and a smaller output loss than does a sudden

disinflation.

Mankiw and Reis then introduce a first-order autoregressive process for the money

supply t t tm pm and then examine the impulse responses of output and inflation to a

one-standard-deviation (-0.007) contractionary monetary policy shock.

In all three models, output exhibits a hump-shaped response. The backward-looking

model yields oscillatory dynamics, whereas the other two models yield a monotonic

recovery from the recession, with the sticky-price model taking longer to return to 0 .

The impulse responses for inflation to the monetary shock show important differences

between the sticky-price and sticky-information models. In the sticky-price model, the

greatest impart of monetary shock on inflation occurs immediately, whereas the

maximum impact of the monetary shock on inflation in the sticky-information model

occurs after seven quarters.

Page 39: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

39

The backward-looking model generates an oscillatory pattern.

Finally, Mankiw and Reis (2002, p.1297) examine whether their model can explain

the acceleration phenomenon documented by many empirical studies, that vigorous economic

activity causes inflation to rise. Their findings as summarized in the paper are:

“The standard sticky-price model is inconsistent with this finding and, in fact, yields a

correlation of the wrong sign. By contrast, the sticky-information model can explain

the widely noted correlation between economic activity and changes in inflation”.

In short, Mankiw and Reis sticky-information Phillips curve resolves three anomalies

in rational expectations staggered price models. Its empirical results matches empirical

evidence better and therefore are more consistent with accepted views of how monetary

policy works, which make it very appealing. However, the idea that information can be sticky

is not very plausible and faces the same criticisms as other imperfect information models.

Mankiw and Reis (2002, p.1317) believe that a better understanding of bounded rationality is

what is required.

“In the end, micro-foundations for the Phillips curve may require a better

understanding of bounded rationality. But until those foundations are established, the

sticky information model as describe here may offer a useful tool for the study of

inflation-output dynamics”.

Problems with the Sticky-Information Approach

The sticky-information Phillips curve successfully addressed three important

empirical anomalies with respect to the standard stick-price Phillips curve and has won the

support of some monetary policy researchers. However, its microfoundations are its major

weaknesses. The idea that inflational information diffuses slowly because of either costs of

acquiring information or costs of reoptimizing is not very satisfactory as the assumption of

imperfect information can be overcome easily. Quite accurate information about movements

in the price level is readily available, in most countries the current money supply is published

regularly and the cost of wage and price adjustment is relatively small. This raises the

question, why self-interested households and firms do not act in a way that brings about more

rapid adjustment?

In the model, the timing of price changes is determined solely by the passage of time,

this time contingent approach is an approximation introduced to slow down the adjustment

Page 40: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

40

process without any solid microeconomic foundations. In most cases, firms are free to

respond to economic conditions and developments; therefore state dependent pricing needs to

be considered. In short, Mankiw and Reis’ (2002) sticky-information Phillips curve lacks a

clear and plausible theory of information and knowledge processing by economic agents.

The Carroll Model

Suppose that an individual who is exposing to a disease in a given period has a fixed

probability p of catching the disease. Denote the set of newly infected individuals in period t

as tN and the set of susceptible individuals as ,ts t tN ps . The growth rate of the disease

depends on the fraction of the population already infected and the probability that someone

who is infected will recover. The dynamics of the disease are as follows, in the first period,

proportion p of the population catches the disease, leaving 1 p uninfected. In the second

period, proportion p of these people catch the disease and the new infection rate is 1p p ,

1p p p of the population is now infected. The total proportion infected at the end of t

period is given by

2

0

1 1 ... 1 1t

t s

s

Fraction ill p p p p p p p p p

(2.31)

whose limit as t is 1pp , implying that everyone will eventually become infected

(Carroll, 2001, p.4).

Now consider the dissemination of a piece of information about the latest forecast of

inflation by reading newspaper articles rather than the spread of a disease through a

population. Assume that every inflation article contains a complete forecast of the inflation

rate for all future quarters and readers can recall the entire forecast. Assume that in each

period a fraction of the population read newspaper articles on inflation. The rest of the

population 1 continues to set prices based on the last forecast that they read. Thus, this

framework is similar to the Calvo (1983) model mathematically (Carroll, 2003, p.272).

Let tM be the operator that yields the population-mean value of inflation expectations

at time t and denote the newspaper forecast printed in quarter t for inflation in quarter s tas t s

N .

Page 41: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

41

1 1 1 1 2 11 1 ...t t t t t t t tM N N N (2.32)

The derivation of this equation is as follows. In period t a fraction of the population will

have absorbed the current-period newspaper forecast for the next quarter, 1t tN . Fraction

1 of the population retains the views they held in period t−1 of period t+1’s inflation

rate. Those period-t−1 views in turn can be decomposed into a fraction λ of people who

encountered an article in period t – 1 and obtained the newspaper forecast of period t + 1’s

forecast, 1 1t tN , and a fraction 1 who retained their period-t − 2 views about the

inflation forecast in period t + 1. Recursion leads to the remainder of the equation. This

equation is similar to Mankiw and Reis’ equation for inflation expectations. In Mankiw and

Reis’ (2001, 2002) model economic agents compute their own forecasts rather than obtaining

inflation forecasts from reading newspaper.

Carroll then modify equation (2.33) in order to relate the population-mean value of

inflation expectations tM to the Michigan Survey mean value of inflation expectations

over the next year and for newspaper forecast of inflation t tN Carroll uses the mean value

from the survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) over the next year as a proxy (Carroll,

2003, p.278).

, 4 , 4 1 1, 31t t t t t t t t tM N M (2.33)

Thus, , 4t t tN and 1 1, 3t t tM denote inflation expectations of professional

forecasters and inflation expectations of the general public respectively, the dissemination of

inflational news can be thought of as a disease that spreads slowly across the population,

infecting a fixed proportion of the general public in each period.

Carroll (2003, p.283) estimate equation (2.34) using the Michigan household survey

measure of mean inflation expectation as proxy for 1 1, 3t t tM and the Survey of

Professional Forecaster over the next year as a proxy for, 4t t tN as represented by the

equation below

, 4 1 , 4 2 1 1, 3t t t t t t t t t tM N M (2.34)

Page 42: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

42

He estimates the above equation and obtains unrestricted estimates of 1 and 2 as:

1 0.33 and 2 0.66 . He also estimates the above equation and obtains restricted

1 21 estimates of 1 and 2 as 1 0.27 and 2 0.73 .

Carroll also observes that professional forecasters’ expectations and household

expectations are closer on average when there is more news coverage about inflation. This

observation suggests that the absorption rate is not constant over time.

Problems with the Epidemiological Approach

Carroll (2003) derives a model similar to Mankiw and Reis’ (2001) model, but his

model is based on an epidemiological model, where inflation expectations of professional

forecasters slowly spreads person–to–person, similar to the way a disease spreads in the

population. Carroll’s (2003) model is very useful for understanding differences in the lag

structures between sluggish price adjustments models from sluggish expectations models

because of its epidemiological analogy. However, it is also potentially problematic if we take

the epidemiological analogy seriously because of the human intentionality issue, unlike a

passive victim of a disease, people will actively devote more time and mental resources to

learning and thinking about economic matters so that they can respond to economic

developments quicker if they think the potential economic gains are greater than its costs.

This is a crucial factor necessary in order to understand the behaviour of people in economic

crises. Carroll (2003, p.296) also notes that his epidemiological approach lacks a general

explanation of how individuals process information and knowledge.

“Finally, it is clear that in order for this framework to be a complete and general

purpose tool, it will be necessary to develop a theory that explains the variations in the

absorption parameter λ overtime. For present purposes it was enough to show that λ is

related to the intensity of news coverage, but that only pushes the problem one step

back, to the need for a model of the extent of news coverage.”

2.5 The Sticky-Knowledge Phillips Curve

The purpose of the sticky-knowledge Phillips curve is to provide Mankiw and Reis’

(2001, 2002) sticky-information approach and Carroll’s (2003) epidemiological approach

more plausible micro-foundations, by endogenising the notion that inflational knowledge

cannot be obtained easily because of our bounded rationality. We borrowed the name from

Mankiw and Reis’ (2001, 2002) papers, but replace the word information with the word

Page 43: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

43

knowledge as our aim is to show that knowledge about inflation is professional knowledge

which cannot be obtained easily (Cao, 2008, p. 49).

�o��ded �atio�alit�

Much of the literature on bounded rationality is a reaction against the restrictive

assumptions of unbounded rationality in neoclassical economics. Economists have long

recognized the importance of bounded rationality as the concept seems so obvious in some

cases and also due to an increasing number of anomalies discovered with respect to the

predictions of rational choice theory in neoclassical economics.

More than fifty years ago Herbert Simon first expressed the idea that individuals are

constrained by limited information and knowledge, limited mental processing ability and

information and knowledge are costly to obtain and to store. As a result, much of economic

behaviour involves search, trial and error processes, with individuals being prepared to settle

for satisfactory outcomes (satisficing procedure) rather than optimal outcomes (Cao, 2008, p.

49).

The main problem with capturing bounded rationality in economic models is how to

formalize it, as much of Simon’s work was conceptual rather than formal (Foss, 2003). The

first problem with modeling bounded rationality is to define it. Simon (1957, p. XXIV)

defined bounded rationality as “intendedly rational, but only limitedly so”, this definition is

vague and therefore open to various interpretations. One common definition of bounded

rationality is all observed deviations from maximizing rationality. The problems with this

definition is that the sets of candidates for boundedly rational behaviour is without bounds

and could also include irrational behaviours, which implies that anything is possible. Perhaps

it is because of this negative perception and the difficulties with formalizing bounded

rationality that many economists do not use the term bounded rationality as a means of

explaining frictions in the economy, instead they attempt to identify various phenomena as

potential causes of frictions: staggered wages and prices, menu costs and transaction costs

(Cao, 2008, p. 80).

In order to operationalize bounded rationality it is necessary to redefine bounded

rationality. By redefining bounded rationality as people are rational, but are constrained by

asymmetric and imperfect knowledge, all irrational choices are excluded. This definition is

also more precise since it identifies the sources of bounded rationality as asymmetric and

imperfect knowledge, that is, bounded rationality is due to both not having the necessary

Page 44: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

44

knowledge (imperfect knowledge or uncertainty) and also due to not having the professional

knowledge to understand the new information and knowledge due to human cognitive

limitations (Cao, 2008, p. 82). Furthermore, the term knowledge incorporates the meaning of

the term information. Essentially, information and knowledge are made of the same building

blocks, called data, in the form of knowledge, some of the non-factual data and irrelevant

data have been filtered out, the remaining data are generalized into factual statements, and

these factual statements are then interconnected to form complex technical knowledge, to this

extent knowledge behaves more like a private good, the more complex nature of knowledge

relative to information means that it generates much greater persistence since the time

horizon of knowledge gaps are significantly longer (Cao, 2008, p. 6).

The interactions between economic agents are made necessary because of the

specialization of labour. The reason why the division of labour is necessary is because the

stock of knowledge is so vast that no one has sufficient time or ability to be an expert in

every field of knowledge. A natural way of overcoming human limited capacity to absorb the

vast stock of knowledge is by specialization of labour, because specialization of labour

allows economic agents to maximize their economic outcomes without having to obtain the

required knowledge by exchanging knowledge (Cao, 2008, p. 83).

Traditionally, expected inflation is modeled as the expectations of inflation

conditional upon the information available at time t ,

1 1 1

e

t t t t tE � E (2.35)

where t� represents the informational set at time t , but in many cases, having access to the

information is not enough, knowledge about the subject matter is also needed in order to

understand and to exploit the information for possible economic gains, and in this case the

constraints are about a lack of economic knowledge. Therefore expected inflation should be

modeled as the expectations of inflation conditional upon the information and knowledge

available at time t .

Thus expected inflation should be modeled as:

1 1 1

e

t t t t tE � E (2.36)

where t� represents the knowledge about inflation set at time t .

Whether constraints about the information and knowledge can be overcome easily or

not partly depends on the nature of the subject matter. Essentially it is a question about

Page 45: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

45

whether the nature of the subject matter is common knowledge or professional knowledge.

While it is reasonable to assume that the definition of inflation and the actions of the

monetary authorities are common knowledge, the causes, effects, costs and benefits of

inflation are not common knowledge. It takes intensive economic study in order to gain a

good understanding of inflation. The existence of educational institutions teaching economic

courses ranging from elementary level to advanced level suggests that we should think about

economic knowledge as a continuum ranging simple definitions to advanced economic

concepts, it also suggests that certain aspects of economic knowledge can only be obtained

through time consuming formal education and training (Cao, 2008, pp. 53-54).

Bounded rationality implies that the best way for non-economists to minimize their

forecast errors is to listen to the advices of professional economists. Furthermore, bounded

rationality opens up the possibility that when economists have the wrong model of economy,

which in turn causes non-economists to have the wrong model of the economy. This is

evident by the existence of many obsolete economic theories in the history of economic

thought and admissions of influential economists (such as Alan Greenspan recently) that they

had the wrong model of the economy. Thus, when an influential economist such as Alan

Greenspan makes predictions about the economy based on the wrong model of the economy,

he also causes many non-economists to make the wrong predictions about the economy.

Whether a non-economist decides to learn economics and become a professional

economist depends on the potential costs and benefits of his decision. For many non-

economists the costs of learning economics so that they can understand economics as well as

professional economists outweigh the benefits, this is reflect by the relatively small size of

economic profession to the general public as a whole. For these non-economists, the best way

to minimize their forecast errors is to listen to the advices of professional economists. This

implies that the most important cost of price adjustment is the mental cost of obtaining

information and knowledge about economic matters rather than the actual costs of changing

prices (menu costs).

Note that we are not proposing that all economic knowledge is professional

knowledge, but we are proposing that economic knowledge is a continuum ranging from

simple definitions (such as the definition of that inflation) that could be considered as

common knowledge to highly specialize economic concepts, such as financial derivatives,

economic growth and monetary economics. With respect to inflation expectations, it is

reasonable to assume that the definition of inflation and the actions of the monetary

Page 46: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

46

authorities are common information or knowledge, but having access to the information is not

enough, specialized knowledge about the subject matter is also needed in order to understand

and to exploit this information for possible economic gains, as a result the causes, effects,

costs and benefits of inflation are not common knowledge, but are professional knowledge,

rather than common knowledge. This is evident by the fact that the economic profession

exists, the reason why the economic professional exists is because economic knowledge is

not easily transferable, much of economic knowledge can only be obtained through time

consuming formal education and training and certain aspects of economic knowledge are

highly specialized as evident by the fact that the economic professional is further divided into

different fields of specialization, such as econometrics, finance, monetary economics...etc.

Thus, our approach to modeling bounded rationality could be considered as a direct

application of Adam Smith’s notion of the division of labour.

One of the main ideas in Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations is the division of labour

increases productivity, Smith (1776, pp. 4-5) demonstrates the power of the division of labour

by describing the work in a pin factory, Smith estimates that the division of labour in the pin

factory increases productivity between 240 and 4800 folds.

“I have seen a small manufactory of this kind where only ten men were employed,

and where some of them consequently performed two or three distinct operations. But

though they were very poor, and therefore but indifferently accommodated with the

necessary machinery, they could, when they exerted themselves, make among them

about twelve pounds of pins in a day. There are in a pound about four thousand pins

of a middling size. Those ten persons, therefore, could make among them upwards of

forty-eight thousand pins in a day. But if they had all wrought separately and

independently, and without any of them having been educated to this particular

business, they certainly could not each of them have made twenty, perhaps not one

pin a day; that is, certainly, not the two hundred fortieth, perhaps not the four

thousand eight hundredth part of what they are at present capable of performing, in

consequence of a proper division and combination of their different operations”.

The division of labor is such an important characteristic of a modern economy; the

production of complicated products (such as the computer, automobile, television, etc.)

would be unimaginable without the combine efforts of professionals. This is reflected by the

fact that every profession owes its function to the unequal distribution of knowledge between

the profession and its clients and that the more specialization of labour an economy

Page 47: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

47

experiences, the greater is the productivity in the economy. This readily observable

phenomenon is one of the most striking differences between a developed and a developing

country.

The reason why the division of labour is necessary is because the stock of knowledge

is so vast that no one has sufficient time or ability to be an expert in every field of knowledge.

A natural way of overcoming human limited capacity to absorb the vast stock of knowledge

is by specialization of labour, because specialization of labour allows economic agents to

maximize their economic outcomes without having to obtain the required knowledge by

exchanging knowledge. If people really have unbounded rationality, then it would be difficult

to explain why the division of labour is necessary (Cao, 2008, pp. 82-83).

The importance of economic knowledge is perhaps most elegantly expressed by

Keynes (1936, p.241).

“The ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and

when they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed the

world is ruled by little else. Practical men, who believe themselves to be quite exempt

from any intellectual influence, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist.

Madmen in authority, who hear voices in the air, are distilling their frenzy from some

academic scribbler of a few years back. I am sure that the power of vested interests is

vastly exaggerated compared with the gradual encroachment of ideas”.

There are at least two readily observable evidence of the importance of economics

generally and of the specialized nature of monetary economics more specifically. First, the

Federal Reserve is an extremely powerful institution and the Chairman of the Federal

Reserve is sometimes described as the second most powerful person in the world by the mass

media, after the president of the United States. If economic knowledge is common knowledge

and people really have unbounded rationality, then it would be difficult to explain why the

Federal Reserve and its chairman are so powerful. Second, the existence of organizations

such as the Council of Economic Advisers, it would be difficult to explain why the President

of the United States needs a Council of Economic Advisers to advise him about economic

matters, if economic knowledge is common knowledge and the President of the United States

has unbounded rationality.

The idea that economic knowledge is specialized knowledge and not common

knowledge in supported by Carroll’s (2001, 2003) (also see Mankiw and Reis (2001, p.28))

Page 48: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

48

empirical findings. Carroll compares the inflation expectations from surveys of two groups:

professional forecasters and the general public. He finds the professional forecasters are

better at forecasting inflation than the general public. In addition, he finds that the general

public’s expectations respond to the professionals’ expectations with a lag. Furthermore,

when there are more news stories about inflation; the public’s expectations adjust more

rapidly and are closer on average to the professionals’ expectations (Cao, 2008, p. 54).

The Mankiw and Reis (2001, 2002) model and the Carroll (2001, 2003) model are

similar to the Calvo (1983) model with respect to its assumption that in each period a fraction

of the population obtains new information about the economy regardless of how long it

has been since its last price adjustment, and the rest of the population 1 continues to set

price based on old information. The crucial difference between Calvo’s (1983) sticky-price

approach and Mankiw and Reis’ (2001, 2002) sticky-information approach is the timing of

expectations. In the Calvo (1983) model, current expectations of future economic conditions

play important an important role in determining the inflation rate. In the sticky-information

model the relevant expectations are past expectations of current economic conditions. This

difference yields large differences in the dynamic pattern of prices and output in response to

monetary policy (Mankiw and Reis 2002, p.1300).

Mankiw and Reis (2002, p.1302) find that 0.25 fits the data well (Carroll finds

that 0.27 fits the well), they claim that “[t]his value of means that firms on average

make adjustments once a year”. However, this creates a problem for explaining persistent

inflation because the probabilities of a firm not having the opportunity of adjusting its prices

after four quarters and eight quarters are given by (Cao, 2008, p. 55):

4

4( ) (0.75) 0.3164p E

8

8( ) (0.75) 0.1001p E

This implies that inflation persistence should not last for much more than eight

quarters. This is inconsistent with empirical evidence mentioned in the paper that the

maximum impact of a monetary shock on inflation occurs after 7 quarters and the full life

span of the shock lasts much longer, typically between 15-20 quarters.

In our model represents the flow of inflational knowledge from professional

economists to the general public. The value of is depended on factors such as: the

credibility of the monetary authority, the frequency and availability economic news,

Page 49: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

49

effectiveness of communication between economists and non-economists and the potential

economic gains or losses of responding quickly to economic developments.

“The general equation is given by:

2 2

t �t �t , provided that,1

�� (2.37)

where � is the number of periods in the lifespan of the monetary shock.

This general equation is based on the assumption that in each period, an additional

percentage of population acquire inflational knowledge � , therefore the proportion of

population that possesses inflational knowledge after t periods is given by �t , at the same

time the proportion of the population that have not acquired inflational knowledge is given by

1 �t . The flow of inflational knowledge in a particular period is given by the product of

the proportion of the population that have not acquired inflational knowledge 1 �t and the

proportion of the population that possesses inflational knowledge �t .

Thus the Sticky-Knowledge Phillips curve is given by:

1

0

1 1

t t t t t t t � t t

� E �

(2.38)

where 2 2

t �t �t , when 0.05, 20� � , the time path of t is given by” (Cao, 2008, pp.

55-56):

t 0 1 2 3 4 5 6

0 0.0475 0.0900 0.1275 0.1600 0.1875 0.2100

t 7 8 9 10 11 12 13

0.2275 0.2400 0.2475 0.25 0.2475 0.2400 0.2275

t 14 15 16 17 18 19 20

0.2100 0.1875 0.1600 0.1275 0.0900 0.0475 0

0.16625 4 17 0.20875

Page 50: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

50

Under the Carroll (2003) and the Mankiw and Reis (2001, 2002) framework, the

fraction of the population that have adjusted its prices is given by:

112 1

0

1 1 ... 1 1 1 1

ttt t

t

t

(2.39)

where t� is the fraction of the population that has adjusted prices, assuming that 0.25 , the

fraction of the population that have adjusted its prices for the first ten quarters are as follows:

1� 2� 3� 4� 5� 6� 7� 8� 9� 10�

0.250 0.4378 0.578 0.684 0.762 0.822 0.867 0.900 0.925 0.944

Under our framework, when 0.05, 20� � , the fraction of the population that have

adjusted its prices is given by t� �t , the fraction of the population that have adjusted its

prices for the first ten quarters are as follows:

1� 2� 3� 4� 5� 6� 7� 8� 9� 10�

0.050 0.100 0.150 0.200 0.250 0.300 0.350 0.400 0.450 0.500

The differences in the lag structures between the Carroll (2003) model, Mankiw and

Reis (2001, 2002) model and our model is clear, our approach yields much greater

persistence and hence it provides a better explanation for the empirical observation that the

maximum impact of a monetary shock on inflation occurs after seven quarters and the full

life span of the shock is much longer, typically between 15-20 quarters.

Mankiw and Reis (2002, p.1316) note that the sticky-information model cannot

explain Carroll’s (2001) empirical findings that “professional’s and public’s expectations are

closer on average when there are more news stories about inflation. In addition, when there is

more news stories about inflation, the public’s expectations adjust more rapidly to the

professional’s expectations… it suggests that the rate in information acquisition is not

constant overtime”.

Page 51: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

51

Under our formulation represents the flow of inflational knowledge from

professional economists to the general public, the rate of dissemination of inflational

knowledge depends on the credibility of the monetary authority, the frequency, availability

and effectiveness of communication between economists and non-economists. This also

implies that our approach is only an approximation, as there are many factors and shocks

affecting the real economy at the same time, people cannot identify individual shocks and

respond to them separately, it is also possible that they could make more than one price

adjustments in respond to a particular shock, over adjust and under adjust based on their

sources of information.

A simpler way of specifying that inflation expectations are boundedly rational is to

use a hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve

1 1t t b t � t tmc E . (2.40)

Inflation depends on real marginal cost, expected inflation and lagged inflation. This

specification is popular and a common interpretation of this specification is that only a

fraction � of agents use rational expectations, while the remainder use last period’s inflation

rate as a simple rule of thumb for forecasting inflation (Gali and Gertler, 1999 and Gali,

Gertler and Lopez-Salido, 2005). Fuhrer and Moore (1995) assume that agents are concerned

with relative real wages. Similarly, Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans (2005) and Smets and

Wouters (2003, 2004) attempt to explain inflation persistence (lagged inflation) by assuming

some form of indexation. However, Walsh (2010, p. 255) points out that are no empirical

evidence to support such indexation price setting behaviour.

Our rationale for the inclusion of lagged inflation in the hybrid new Keynesian

Phillips curve is bounded rationality. Bounded rationality implies that the best way for non-

economists to minimize their forecast errors is to listen to the advices of professional

economists as much of economic knowledge is professional knowledge. Since the general

public’s inflation expectations respond to the professional economists’ expectations with time

lag, lagged inflation rates are correlated with the current inflation rate.

2.6 Conclusion

Our main objective in this chapter was to show that bounded rationality can provide a

theory of information and knowledge processing by economic agents, which emphasizes that

when the nature of the required knowledge is professional economic knowledge, then the best

Page 52: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

52

way for non-economists to minimize their forecast errors is to listen to the advices of

economists, as the costs of acquiring this professional knowledge can be very high. Bounded

rationality explains why lagged inflation plays an important role in empirical inflation

regressions as the dissemination of economic information and knowledge between

professional economists and non-economists involves time lags, lagged inflation rates are

correlated with the current inflation rate.

Page 53: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

53

CHAPTER 3

An Empirical Survey of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve

3.1 Introduction

The purpose of this chapter is to survey selected empirical works on the new

Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) for the USA. We will focus on recent developments with

regard to the abilities of these models to fit the data, whether labour’s share of output or the

output gap is the appropriate measurement for real marginal cost (inflationary pressures), the

relative importance of forward and backward-looking expectations and whether these models

assume that price adjustments are sluggish or expectation adjustments are sluggish. This

chapter consists of four sections. The first section surveys sticky-price-single equation

estimations of the NKPC; the second section surveys dynamic stochastic general equilibrium

(DSGE) sticky-price-model-based estimations of the NKPC, the third section surveys

estimations of the sticky-information Phillips curve and the fourth section concludes.

3.2 Sticky-Price-Single-Equation Estimations of the NKPC

Single-equation estimations of the NKPC are appealing because they do not require us

to make any assumption about other sectors of the economy; hence their findings will still be

valid even if the other sectors of the economy are misspecified. The main disadvantage of

single-equation estimation is its incompleteness, since in the real world different sectors of

the economy are interconnected; taking into account what we know about other sectors of the

economy can help us to make more accurate estimations and gain greater insights (Nason and

Smith, 2008, p. 262).

Calvo’s (1983) formulation of the NKPC has become the workhorse for monetary

policy analysis. However, as mentioned previously, it does not fit the data well. Currently

there is a large body of research on the empirics of the NKPC. This literature originated from

the Gali and Gertler (1999) seminal paper, which focuses on measuring real marginal cost,

explaining the persistence in the rate of inflation and the relative importance of forward and

backward-looking expectations in determining the rates of inflation. We will first examine

the Gali and Gertler (1999) model and then discuss the empirical literature regarding the

issues mentioned above. We will examine the Gali and Gertler (1999) model in more detail

as, much of our empirical work is a direct response to Gali and Gertler’s (1999) empirical

findings.

Page 54: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

54

�he �ali a�d �ertler ������ �odel

A Baseline NKPC

Assume that each firm has a fixed probability 1 that it may adjust its price, this

probability is independent of its last adjustment. Hence, is the probability that it keeps its

price unchanged.

The aggregate price level tp is given by

*

1 (1 )t t tp p p (3.1)

where *

tp is the optimal price level and 1tp is the lag of price level tp .

Let �

tmc be the firm’s nominal marginal cost at t and let denote a subjective

discount factor, the optimal reset price is given by

*

0

(1 ) ( ) [ ]� �

t t �

p E mc

(3.2)

In setting its price at t , the firm takes into account the expected future path of

marginal cost, subject to the next time it can adjust its price.

Let 1t t tp p denote the inflation rate at t , and tmc the percent deviation of the

firm’s real marginal cost from its steady states value. The equation for inflation is derived by

combining equation (3.1) and equation (3.2).

1[ ]t t t tmc E (3.3)

where(1 )(1 ) depends on the frequency of price adjustment and the subjective

discount factor .Intuitively, because firm’s mark-up price over marginal cost, are forward

looking, and must lock into price for (possibly) multiple periods, they base their pricing

decision on the expected future behaviour of marginal costs.

Iterating equation (3.3) forward yields

0

[ ]�

t t t �

E mc

(3.4)

Page 55: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

55

The NKPC implies that inflation should equal a discounted stream of expected future

marginal cost.

Gali and Gertler (1999) argue that the reason why the NKPC fits the data poorly is

because traditional empirical work on the Phillips curve uses some output gap measures as

the relevant indicator of real economic activity. In other words, Gali and Gertler (1999)

attribute the poor empirical results of the NKPC to the output gap measure as a poor proxy

for real marginal cost.

To obtain an alterative measure for real marginal cost, Gali and Gertler (1999) note

that with a Cobb-Douglas production function the real marginal cost is given by the real wage

divided by the marginal product of labour (MPL), the marginal product of labour is

proportional to its average product. Thus, real marginal cost can be written as.

t t t t t tt t

t t t t

� P � P � ��� �

�P� � � P�

Hence, real marginal cost is proportional to labour’s share of total income. Expressed

in terms of percent deviations around the steady state, where t� is the labour income share

(equivalent to real unit labour costs). Let lower case letters denote percent deviations from

the steady state, we have t tmc s (also see Walsh, 2010, p.253).

The baseline NKPC with labour income share as a proxy for real marginal cost is given by:

1[ ]t t t ts E (3.5)

where (1 )(1 ) . Since under rational expectations the error in the forecast of 1t is

uncorrelated with information dated t and earlier, it follows from equation (3.5) that

10

t t t t tE s � (3.6)

where t� is a vector of variables dated t and earlier (and, thus, orthogonal to the inflation

surprise in period 1t ). The orthogonality condition given by equation (3.6) then forms the

basis for estimating the model via generalized method of moments (GMM).

Page 56: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

56

Gali and Gertler (1999) then estimate the reduced form equation (3.6) using real

marginal cost ts and detrended log GDP as a proxy for the output gap ( )t� . The following

results were obtained:

10.023 0.942 [ ]t t t ts E

(0.012) (0.045)

10.016 0.988 [ ]t t t t

� E

(0.005) (0.030)

The coefficient of the output gap ( )t� has the wrong sign, whereas the coefficient of

real marginal cost ( )t

s has the right sign. Hence, they conclude that real marginal cost is the

relevant real sector driving variable in the NKPC.

Gali and Gertler (1999) then estimate the following structural equations using GMM:

11 1 0t t t t tE s � (3.7)

1

11 1 0t t t t tE s � (3.8)

The structural parameters and were estimated using a nonlinear instrumental

variables estimator. Two alternatives to the benchmark case were considered. In the first

alternative the authors restrict the estimate of the discount factor to unity, and in the

second, nonfarm GDP deflator instead of the overall deflator. Finally, two different

normalizations were used, as given by equations (3.7) and (3.8).

The results are reported in Table 1. The first two columns give the estimates of and

. The third then gives the implied estimate of , the reduced form slope coefficient on real

marginal cost. In general, the structural estimates tell the same overall story as the reduced

form estimates. The implied estimate of is always positive and is highly significant in

every case but one (restricted , normalization (2)). The estimate of in the unrestricted

case is somewhat low, but not unreasonably so, given the sampling uncertainty.

Page 57: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

57

Table 3.1: Estimations of the Standard NKPC

GDP deflator (1)

(2)

0.829

(0.013)

0.884 (0.020)

0.926

(0.024)

0.941 (0.018)

0.047

(0.008)

0.021 (0.007)

Restricted

(1) (2)

0.829 (0.016)

0.915 (0.035)

1.000

1.000

0.035 (0.007)

0.007 (0.006)

NFB deflator

(1)

(2)

0.836 (0.015)

0.884 (0.023)

0.957 (0.018)

0.967 (0.016)

0.038 (0.008)

0.018 (0.008)

Notes: This table reports GMM estimates of the structural parameters of equation (3.5).

Rows (1) and (2) correspond to the two specifications of the orthogonal conditions found in equations (3.7) and (3.8) respectively. Estimates are based on quarterly data and cover the

sample period 1960:1-1997:4. Instruments used include four lags of inflation, labour income share, long-short interest rate spread, output gap, wage inflation, and commodity price

inflation. A 12-lag Newey-West estimate of the covariance matrix was used. Standard errors are shown in brackets.

Source: Gali and Gertler (1999, p. 208)

�he ��brid Philips ��r�e

The purpose of Gali and Gertler’s (1999) hybrid Phillips curve is to explain the

persistence nature of inflation. The authors modified the Calvo (1983) model by assuming the

existence of two types of firms. A fraction of firm (1 )w has forward-looking price setting

behaviour, while the remaining firms ( )w have backward-looking rule of thumb based price

setting behaviour, based on the recent history of aggregate price behaviour.

The aggregate price level is given by

*

1 (1 )t t tp p p (3.9)

Page 58: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

58

where*

tp is an index for the prices newly set in period t . Let �

tp denote the price set by a

forward-looking firm at t and b

tp the price set by a backward-looking firm. The index for

newly set prices is given by

*

(1 ) � b

t ttp w p wp (3.10)

forward-looking firms behave exactly as in the baseline Calvo (1983) model. Hence, �

tp is

given by

0

(1 ) ( ) [ ]� � �

t t t �

p E mc

(3.11)

The rule of thumb that backward-looking firms is assumed to follow has the following

features: First, no persistent deviations between the rule and optimal behaviour. Second, the

price in period t depends only information dated 1t or earlier. Third, Firms are unable to

tell whether their competitors are backward-looking or forward-looking price setters. These

considerations lead to the following rule of thumb:

*

11

b

t ttp p

Intuitively, a backward-looking firm at t sets its price equal to the average price set in

the most recent round of price adjustments, *

1tp , with a correction for inflation.

The hybrid Phillips curve is obtained by combining equations (3.9) – (3.11)

1 1[ ]t t � t t b tmc E (3.12)

where1(1 )(1 )(1 )w , 1

t and [1 (1 )]w

Inflation depends on real marginal cost, expected inflation and lagged inflation, where

is the degree of price stickiness, w is the degree of “backwardness” in price setting, and

is the discount factor. When 0w , all firms are forward looking, the hybrid Phillips curve

converges to the baseline NKPC. When 1 , then 1� b the model take the form of the

hybrid Phillips curve.

Gali and Gertler (1999) then estimate the hybrid Phillips curve using labour’s share of

output as a proxy for real marginal cost.

Page 59: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

59

1 1[ ]t t � t b ts E (3.13)

The authors consider three cases: the baseline model, the model with restricted to

unity and the non-farm deflator substituted for the overall GDP deflator. They also use two

alternative specifications of the orthogonal condition, one which does not normalize the

coefficient on inflation to be unity (method 1) and one which does (method 2).

11 1 1 0t t t t tE w s � (3.14)

1 1

11 1 1 0t t t t tE w s � (3.15)

Overall, the authors found the results are consistent with the underlying theory,

implying that expected future marginal costs drive inflation dynamics. With respect to the

relative importance of forward-looking expectations and backward-looking expectations,

their results indicates that forward-looking behaviour is more important that backward-

looking behaviour. Table 2 presents the estimates of equation (3.14).

Table 3.2: Estimations of the Hybrid Phillips Curve

w b �

GDP deflator (1) (2)

0.265

(0.031)

0.486 (0.040)

0.808

(0.015)

0.834 (0.020)

0.885

(0.030)

0.909 (0.031)

0.252

(0.023)

0.378 (0.020)

0.682

(0.020)

0.591 (0.016)

0.037

(0.007)

0.015 (0.004)

Restricted (1)

(2)

0.244

(0.030)

0.522 (0.043)

0.803

(0.017)

0.838 (0.027)

1.000

1.000

0.233

(0.023)

0.383 (0.020)

0.766

(0.015)

0.616 (0.016)

0.027

(0.005)

0.009 (0.003)

NFB deflator (1) (2)

0.077

(0.030)

0.239 (0.043)

0.830

(0.016)

0.866 (0.025)

0.949

(0.019)

0.957 (0.021)

0.085

(0.031)

0.218 (0.031)

0.871

(0.018)

0.755 (0.016)

0.036

(0.008)

0.015 (0.006)

Notes: This table reports GMM estimates of parameters of Eq. (3.14). Rows (1) and (2) correspond to the two

specifications of the orthogonality conditions found in equations (3.15) and (3.16) in the text, respectively.

Estimates are based on quarterly data and cover the sample period 1960:1}1997:4. Instruments used include

Page 60: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

60

four lags of inflation, labour income share, long-short interest rate spread, output gap, wage inflation, and

commodity price inflation. A 12-lag Newey-West estimate of the covariance matrix was used. Standard errors

are shown in brackets.

Source: Gali and Gertler (1999, p. 212)

Gali and Gertler (1999) also consider two robustness exercises. The first allows extra

lags of inflation to enter the right hand side of the equation for inflation. The second explores

sub-sample stability. Overall, the broad picture remains unchanged. Marginal costs have a

significant impact on short run inflation dynamics of roughly the same quantitative

magnitudes as suggested by the full sample estimates. Across all specifications forward-

looking behaviour remains dominant. In the estimated hybrid Phillips curve, the weight on

inflation lagged one quarter is generally small. Furthermore, additional lags of inflation

beyond one quarter do not appear to matter much at all. “Taken as a whole, accordingly, the

results suggest that it is worth searching for explanations of inflation inertia beyond the

traditional ones that rely heavily on arbitrary lags” (Gali and Gertler, 1999, p. 219).

Table 3.3: Robustness Analysis

w b �

GDP deflator

0.244

(0.062)

0.860

(0.025)

0.772

(0.054)

0.090

(0.040)

0.231

(0.050)

0.628

(0.033)

0.033

(0.007)

Restricted 0.291

(0.039)

0.787

(0.023)

1.000 -0.025

(0.014)

0.270

(0.028)

0.729

(0.021)

0.029

(0.006)

NFB deflator

0.018

(0.041) 0.922

(0.023) 0.779

(0.050) 0.208

(0.058) 0.019

(0.043) 0.767

(0.046) 0.022

(0.007)

Notes: This table reports GMM estimates of a version of equations (3.14) with three extra lags of inflation added. represents the sum of the coefficients of the extra lags. Using the specification of the orthogonality conditions

found in equation (3.15) in the text. Estimates are based on quarterly data and cover the sample period 1960:1}1997:4. Instruments used include four lags of inflation, labour income share, long-short interest rate spread, output gap, wage inflation, and commodity price inflation. A 12-lag Newey-West estimate of the covariance matrix was used. Standard errors are shown in brackets.

Source: Gali and Gertler (1999, p. 215)

Due to the large body of work on the empirics of the NKPC, it is not possible to list

all the results of this literature. Hence, we will only attempt to review some of the main

contributions and discuss their findings. Besides Gali and Gertler (1999), Gali Gertler and

Lopez-Salido (2001) and Sbordone (2002) have also argued that the standard NKPC is

Page 61: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

61

empirically valid, provided that real marginal cost rather than the output gap is used as the

variable driving inflation. Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2001) confirm Gali and Gertler

(1999) empirical findings for the Euro area and use their empirical result to compare with

those observed in the US. Some of their finding can be summarized as follows: “(a) the NPC

fits Euro area data very well, possibly better than U.S. data, (b) the degree of price stickiness

implied by the estimates is substantial, but in line with survey evidence and U.S. estimates,

(c) inflation dynamics in the Euro area appear to have a stronger forward-looking component

(i.e., less inertia) than in the U.S., (d) labour market frictions, as manifested in the behaviour

of the wage markup, appear to have played a key role in shaping the behaviour of marginal

costs and, consequently, inflation in Europe” (Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido, 2001, p.1237).

There are several issues regarding the estimation of the NKPC, below are some of the

discussions regarding these issues:

How do we interpret the empirical success of Gali and Gertler (1999) hybrid Phillips

curve? Do marginal costs drive inflation dynamics? The direct implication of Gali and

Gertler’s approach is the relationship between real marginal cost and the output gap is weak.

“According to New Keynesian models, a simple structural relationship between inflation and

the output gap does not hold in general—it holds only if the labour market is perfectly

competitive. If the labour market is not competitive, labour frictions become crucial, and one

needs to model the “wage markup” produced by monopoly power in labour supply, which

drives a wedge between real marginal cost and the output gap” (Neiss and Nelson, 2005,

p.1020, also see Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido 2001, p.1261-1262).Is the labour market

perfectly competitive? If not, what is the nature of the frictions in the labour market?

Gali and Gertler (1999, p. 204) state that “[A] more fundamental issue, we believe, is

that even if the output gap were observable the conditions under which it corresponds to

marginal cost may not be satisfied. Our analysis of the data suggests that movements in our

measure of real marginal cost (described below) tend to lag movements in output, in direct

contrast to the identifying assumptions that imply a co-incident movement. This discrepancy,

we will argue, is one important reason why structural estimations of Phillips curves based on

the output gap have met with limited success, at best.”

However, using labour’s share of output as a proxy for real marginal cost also has its

difficulties. The standard approximation of real marginal cost by real unit labour cost

(labour’s share of output) assumes a constant-returns-to scale production function. Under

Page 62: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

62

more realistic assumptions, real unit labour cost needs to be corrected for some factors, such

as: assumptions about technology, non-constant elasticity of factor substitution between

capital and labour, the presence of overhead costs and labour adjustment costs (Guay and

Pelgrim, 2004, p.5, Rotemberg and Woodford (1999)). The key issue is how to distinguish

when the increase in output is cause by technological progress, which does not cause

inflationary pressures and when the increase in output is not caused by technological

progress, which tends to raise nominal marginal costs or inflationary pressures, as workers

demand higher wages in order to supply more labour. The output gap cannot do this because

it assumes the labour market perfectly competitive. Similarly, labour’s share of output cannot

do this because it assumes constant returns to scale. Rudd and Whelan (2007, p. 160) plot the

output gap (based on HP filter) and labour income share (Nonfarm Business Sector) from

1960 to 2005, both measures of real marginal cost raised because it failed to recognise that

the increases in output from 1995 to 2000 were due to internet related technologies allowing

households and businesses to operate more efficiently, which does not cause inflationary

pressures, as reflected by the low rates of unemployment and inflation recorded during the

period.

Is the use of Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) appropriate for estimating the

NKPC? Linde (2005) argues that Full Information Maximum Likelihood (FIML) provide

more efficient parameters than GMM. Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2005, p. 1107) rebut

claims that their results are the product of specification bias by presenting a series of

robustness tests, including using FIML techniques. The authors point out that estimating the

NKPC using GMM may be sensitive to the choice of instruments. On the other hand,

maximum likelihood estimation may be sensitive to imposing false assumptions about either

the error term (normality of the error term is required) or the overall model structure (in the

case of FIML). They conclude that GMM estimations of the NKPC are informative and valid

(Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido 2005, p. 1116).

Are inflation expectations consistent with rational expectations? Most empirical

studies on the hybrid Phillips curve assume that inflation expectations are consistent with

rational expectations. Gali and Gertler’s (1999) hybrid Phillips curve cannot explain the

persistence nature of inflation without adding a lagged inflation term in an ad hoc manner.

Fuhrer and Moore (1995) attempt to explain the persistence of inflation by modelling wage

negotiations in terms of relative wage contracts (i.e. wage indexation) instead of nominal

wage contracts. Rudd and Whelan (2006, p.319) find that adding lags to the standard NKPC

Page 63: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

63

improve empirical fit, they suggest that inflation expectations are not fully rational and that

adding lagged inflation term is just addressing the cause of the problem, which they believe

to be deviations from rational expectations (bounded rationality).

3.3 DSGE Model-Based Estimations of the NKPC

More recently, empirical work on the NKPC has relied on dynamic stochastic general

equilibrium (DSGE) models to estimate the parameters of the NKPC. This approach

combines rational expectations with a microeconomic foundation in which a representative

household or firm is assumed to behave optimally, given their objectives and constraints.

This approach is becoming increasingly popular among central banks around the world for

policy analysis.

New Keynesian economists borrow this approach from new classical economists,

which is based on the pioneering work of Kydland and Prescott (1982), designed to study

how real (supply) shocks to the economy might cause business cycle fluctuations under the

assumptions of rational expectations, flexible prices and representative agents. In contrast,

new Keynesian DSGE models typically assume monopolistically competitive firms and

emphasise that prices and wages display rigidities and that this nominal stickiness accounts

for the real effects of monetary policy (Walsh, 2010, p.28).

Our approach to modelling bounded rationality in terms of asymmetric

(heterogeneous agents) and imperfect knowledge (uncertainty) implies that DSGE is not

appropriate for modelling and analysing models based on bounded rationality. Hence, we will

pay less attention to this literature.

Some examples of DSGE-base estimation of the NKPC are Christiano, Eichenbaum,

and Evans (2005), Smets and Wouters (2005), Cho and Moreno (2006), Linde (2005), Salemi

(2006) Andres, Lopez-Salido, and Nelson (2004). In this literature Bayesian and Maximum

Likelihood Estimation (MLE) techniques are often used to estimate the NKPC. Interested

readers can consult Tovar (2009) for more details on the use DSGE models by various central

banks.

A �imple ���E �odel

Our exposition of the structure of a DSGE model follows Cho and Moreno (2006,

p.1463 – 1465). A typical DSGE model consists of three structural equations: an aggregate

Page 64: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

64

supply (AS) equation, an aggregate demand (AD) equation and a monetary policy rule

equation. The model assumes that there is no informational difference between the private

sector (firms and households) and the central Bank. The aggregate supply equation is

represented by the NKPC, Cho and Moreno (2006) use a hybrid Phillips curve

1 1 ,(1 )t t t t t A� tE � (3.16)

where t is the inflation rate, t

� is the output gap and ,A� t is the aggregate supply structural

shock or error term.

The aggregate demand equation is represented by the new Keynesian IS equation

1 1 1 ,(1 ) ( )t t t t t t t ��t� E � � r E (3.17)

where t�is the output gap, t

is the inflation rate and ,�� t is the aggregate demand structural

shock or error term. In this specification, the habit formation in the utility function impacts

endogenous persistence to the output gap. The forward-looking parameter depends

inversely on the level of habit persistence. The monetary policy channel in the �� equation is

captured by the contemporaneous output gap dependence on the ex-ante real rate of interest.

To close the model, an interest rates rule that the central bank is assumed to follow in

setting the nominal interest rate

1 1 ,(1 )[ ]t �P t t t t �P tr pr p E � (3.18)

where tr is nominal interest rate, �P is a constant and �P is the monetary policy shock. The

policy rule exhibits interest rate smoothing, placing a weight of p on the past interest rate.

The Fed reacts to high-expected inflation and to deviations of output from its trend. The

parameter measures the long run response of the central bank to expected inflation and the

parameter describes it reaction to output gap fluctuations.

The three structural equations are expressed in matrix form and the rational

expectations equilibrium can be computed numerically using the generalized Schur matrix

decomposition method (QZ). When there are multiple equilibria, recursive method can be

used to solve the system. These structural equations can also be estimated separately using

Full Information Maximum Likelihood (FIML) or Bayesian methods.

Page 65: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

65

The main advantage of DSGE-based estimations of the NKPC is it allows us to take

into account what we know about other sectors of the economy, which can provide more

accurate estimations and greater insights. However, in practice this is very difficult to achieve

because DSGE models are difficult to build as we still do not know enough about some

sectors of the economy (i.e. finance) and strong assumptions have to be made, some of these

assumptions are: complete markets, no labour and financial market frictions. In many DSGE

models, Calvo pricing is used to model nominal rigidities, but it is assumed other markets

clear, which tend to lead to unrealistic and internally inconsistent implications. If prices are

sticky, it is unlikely that that the labour and the financial markets will clear.

Some economists have blamed DSGE models for the failure of modern

macroeconomics to anticipate and to make sense of the current financial crisis. Willem Buiter

(2009) has criticized DSGE models for its assumptions of complete and efficient markets.

Robert Solow (2010) was very critical of the DSGE models because of its unrealistic

assumptions and implications.

“[T]he basic story always treats the whole economy as if it were like a person... This

can not be an adequate description of a national economy…An obvious example is

that the DSGE story has no real room for unemployment of the kind we see most of

the time, and especially now…The only way that DSGE and related models can cope

with unemployment is to make it somehow voluntary, a choice of current leisure or a

desire to retain some kind of flexibility for the future or something like that…

DSGE model has nothing useful to say about anti-recession policy because it has built

into its essentially implausible assumptions the “conclusion” that there is nothing for

macroeconomic policy to do”.

3.4 Estimations of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve (SIPC)

Recall that the sticky-information Phillips Curve is given by:

1

0

(1 ) [ ]1

t t t � t t

� E �

(3.19)

where 1t t t� � � is the growth rate of the output gap. According to the SIPC, inflation

depends on the current output gap, past expectations of current inflation and the growth rate

of the output gap. The parameter represents the degree of information stickiness. A higher

Page 66: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

66

value of implied that more firms are updating their expectation about the state of the

economy. The parameter represents the sensitivity of the optimal relative price to the

output gap. It can be interpreted as the degree of real rigidity as discussed by Ball and Romer

(1990).

An important feature of the SIPC “is that current inflation depends not only on the

current output gap but also on the past expectations of both current inflation and the growth

rate of the current output gap. This feature also makes the empirical estimation of the SIPC

parameters difficult (Kahn and Zhu, 2006, p.196). Perhaps of the difficulties mentioned

above and the lack of interest in the SIPC in comparison to the standard NKPC and the

hybrid NKPC there has been relatively few attempts to estimate the SIPC (Dopke et al., 2008,

p.1514).The most important parameter in the SIPC is , as represents the degree of

information stickiness or the extent of deviations from unbounded rationality more generally.

In the literature on estimating the SIPC, the main objective is to estimate . Once is

estimated, the duration of information update in quarters is given by1

.

Currently there is no consensus with regard to what is the best method to estimate the

SIPC. Some of the methods commonly used to estimate the SIPC are: Full Information

Maximum Likelihood (FIML), Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE), Generalize Method

of Moments (GMM), Bayesian, Ordinary Least Square (OLS) and combining Vector

Autoregressive (VAR) and Ordinary Least Square (OLS). See table 4 for details of various

studies surveyed in this chapter. It should also be noted that most of the studies use VAR

models as proxies for inflation and output forecasts. Only two studies (Dopke et al., 2008 and

Coiboin, 2009) use survey-based data as proxy for inflation expectations.

Similarly, there is no consensus on the estimates of . In Mankiw and Reis’ (2002)

original paper, the authors obtain the value of 0.25 by calibration, each period in the

model represents a quarter, the average duration between information updates according to

Mankiw and Reis is given by 1

40.25

quarters. The durations of information updates of the

studies we surveyed in this chapter range from 4 months to 18 months (also see Knotek,

2006, p.40)

Since Mankiw and Reis (2002) proposed the SIPC as a possible replacement to

standard new Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC), many researchers have attempted to

Page 67: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

67

compare the empirical results of the SIPC with the NKPC and in the process these studies

also attempt to estimate the parameter of the SIPC. The general conclusion from this

literature (Arslan, 2010, Korenok 2008, Korenok and Swanson 2007, Dupor et. al. 2009, and

Coibion 2009) is that sticky price firms have a dominant role in comparison the sticky

information firms in explaining the relationship between inflation and the real side of the

economy. Furthermore, many of these studies also conclude sticky information firms should

also be taken into account in modelling firm’s price setting behaviour (Arslan, 2010, p.8).

Table 3.4 - Published SIPC Estimations of

Study Sample Period Average Duration

Between Information

Updates (Months)

Method

Single Equation Estimations

Kahn and Zhu

(2006)

1969.1 – 2000.4 8 VAR and OLS

Carroll (2003) 1981.3 – 2000.2 12 OLS

DSGE Model-Based Estimations

(with assumption of information stickiness only on the part of firms)

Andres et.al. (2005) 1979.3 – 2003.3 18 FIML

Dupor et.al. (2006) 1960.1 – 2005.2 8 VAR and OLS

Kiley (2007) 1965.1 – 2002.4 7 MLE

Kiley (2007) 1983.1 – 2002.4 5 MLE

Korenok (2007) 1983.1 – 2002.1 10 FIML

DSGE Model-Based Estimations

(with assumption of information stickiness imposed on workers and consumers also)

Mankiw and Reis 1954.3 – 2006.1 4 (firms) MLE

Page 68: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

68

(2007) 16 (consumers)

16 (workers)

and

Bayes

Mankiw and Reis

(2006)

1954.3 – 2005.3 6 (firms)

9 (consumers)

4 (workers)

Method

of Simulated

Moment

Arslan (2010, p.8) also points out that due to the poor performance of the sticky-

information model, Mankiw and Reis (2007) developed and analysed a general equilibrium

model with sticky information. Mankiw and Reis claim that the poor empirical performance

of the sticky information model arises from a partial equilibrium approach, which only

assumes information stickiness on the part of firms, they argue that information stickiness

should be pervasive across all markets.

3.5 Conclusion

In the empirical literature on the NKPC, two issues dominate this literature. First, are

inflation expectations consistent with rational expectations? Second, do real marginal costs

drive inflation dynamics?

In chapter 2 we attempted to argue that inflations expectations are boundedly rational

and that the persistence nature of inflation is cause by sticky nature of knowledge, which

disseminate slowly after monetary policy shocks. This approach is based on the work of

Mankiw and Reis (2002), Carroll (2003), Roberts (1995, 1997) and Furher and Moore

(1995).

The work of Gertler and Gali (1999) and Gertler, Gali and Lopez-Salido (2001) and

Sbordone (2002) have shown that the output gap is not a good proxy for real marginal cost

(inflationary pressures) because it is likely that the labour market is not competitive. If the

labour market is not competitive, labour frictions become critical, we need to model wage

markup produced by monopoly power in labour supply (Neiss and Nelson, 2005, p.1020).

This implies that we need to consider labour market frictions in modelling the NKPC.

However, using labour’s share of output as a proxy for real marginal cost is also potentially

problematic. The standard approximation of real marginal cost by real unit labour cost

Page 69: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

69

(labour’s share of output) assume a constant-returns-to scale production function. Under more

realistic, assumptions, real unit labour cost needs to be corrected for a number of factors, such

as: assumptions about technology, non-constant elasticity of factor substitution between

capital and labour, the presence of overhead costs and labour adjustment costs (Guay and

Pelgrim, 2004, p.5, Rotemberg and Woodford (1999)).

Page 70: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

70

CHAPTER 4

Proxies for Real Marginal Cost

4.1 Introduction

The work of Gali and Gertler (1999) and Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2001, 2005)

have raised two important issues. First, the new Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) needs to

take into account labour market frictions. Second, the output gap (GAP) may not be an

appropriate proxy for real economic activity because it assumes that the labour market clears.

Gali and Gertler (1999) argue that the reason why the NKPC fits the data poorly is because

traditional empirical work on the Phillips curve uses some output gap measures as a proxy for

real marginal cost rather than labour’s share of income. Moreover, there is not a single

method of measuring potential output and therefore the GAP. We will attempt to argue that

the probability of finding a job or job finding probability (JFP) is a better proxy for real

marginal cost than GAP and labour’s share of income, at the same time JFP provides a direct

link between frictions in the labour market and the Phillips curve relationship. This chapter is

structure as follows: Section 1 provides a brief literature review of recent debates. Section 2

examines the intuitions behind the use of the output gap, labour’s share of income and job

finding probability as proxies for real marginal cost. Section 3 compares their empirical

appropriateness as proxies for real marginal cost and section 4 concludes.

4.2 Literature Review

In recent years, there has been a trend in modelling inflation dynamics by using Calvo

(1983) pricing in order to motivate a forward-looking inflation equation known as the new

Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) of the form

1[ ]t t t tE mc (4.1)

The implication of this model is that inflation should be independent of its own lagged

values. As a result, this specification has often been criticized because it does not fit the data

well; empirical studies have shown that inflation can be predicted well from its own lagged

value. Simple regressions of inflation on its own lags have much higher 2� values than the

NKPC in equation (4.1).

In response to this critique, Gali and Gertler (1999, p.195) have suggested an

alternative to the pure forward-looking model that is intended to better capture observed

Page 71: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

71

inflation inertia. This "hybrid" specification modifies the new Keynesian Phillips curve so

that inflation depends on a weighted sum of its lag and its rationally expected future value.

1 1[ ]t b t � t t t tE mc (4.2)

Where the structural parameters of the reduced form coefficients are:

1

1

(1 )(1 )(1 )

[1 (1 )].

b

and t is the error term. The coefficients are explicit functions of three model parameters: ,

which measures the degree of price stickiness; , the degree of “backwardness” in price

setting, and the discount factor . Note that when goes to zero, the equation becomes the

pure forward-looking NKPC, with 0b and � .

Gali and Gertler (1999) attribute the poor empirical results of the NKPC to the output

gap measure as a poor proxy for real marginal cost. Gali and Gertler (1999 found “backward-

looking price setting, while statistically significant, is not quantitatively important and that

“the new Keynesian Phillips curve provides a good first approximation to the dynamics of

inflation”. Gali and Gertler’s (1999) work have generated much interest on the empirics of

the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve, their empirical findings are accepted by many as a

sensible compromise between the pure rational expectations new Keynesian Phillips curve

with micro-foundations, but does not fit the data well and the old Keynesian Phillips curve,

which lacks strong micro-foundations but fits the data better.

Rudd and Whelan (2005a, 2005b, 2006, 2007) are the leading critics of Gali and

Gertler’s approach, they based their criticisms on their empirical findings that labour share

does not drive inflation dynamics and also question the validity of the assumption of rational

expectations assumed in the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve. Furthermore, if

expectations are rational they should be model consistent, but the Gali and Gertler’s

expectations are not model consistent. Below are some of their critiques.

�he Persiste�ce Problem

Under rational model consistent expectations, the closed form of the pure forward-

looking NKPC can be written as (by applying repeated substitution):

Page 72: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

72

0

t t t �

E mc

(4.3)

Symbols used in (3) have the same meaning as in equation (4.2). The main difference

between the Gali and Gertler NKPC in (4.1) and the Rudd and Whelan NKPC in (4.3) is that

while inflationary expectations are model consistent in (4.3), they are not in (4.1). Both the

NKPCs imply inflation is a purely forward variable, current inflation is proportional to the

expected present discounted value of current and future real marginal cost. No lagged

variables-including lagged inflation-should have an impact on the current level of inflation.

The model predicts that current inflation should forecast future movement in real marginal

cost as, for example, a rise in future real marginal cost that can be forecast should

immediately raise current inflation. Rudd and Whelan (2005a) found that the empirical fit of

the NKPC is poor across a wide variety of VAR specifications. In addition, VAR

specifications that include lagged inflation reveal that there is a statistically significant and

economically large role for lagged inflation. This result is obtained whether one uses the

output gap or labour’s share of income as proxy for real marginal cost. The failure of the pure

forward-looking NKPC to account for the empirical importance of lagged inflation is known

as the persistence problem (also see Walsh, 2010, p. 253).

Rudd and Whelan (2005b) augment equation (4.3) with an additional one lag of

inflation in order to test whether the pure NKPC provides a good characterization of the

inflation process, if the pure forward-looking model were correct, coefficients on lagged

inflation should be relatively small. The equation they consider is given by.

1

0

t t t � t

E mc

(4.4)

Rudd and Whelan (2005b, p. 1167) constructed a proxy for the infinite discounted

sum of the expected future values of the driving variable then estimate equation (4.4) using

GMM. They concluded that “the new-Keynesian pricing model cannot explain the

importance of lagged inflation in standard inflation regressions, and find that forward-looking

terms play a very limited role in explaining inflation dynamics”. If estimates of the closed

form results are significantly different from those obtained from estimating the structural

form, then Gali and Gertler’s (1999) results are likely to be a product of mis-specification.

Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2005, p.1112) rebut Rudd and Whelan’s (2005b)

criticisms by arguing that the reason they got very different results is because they failed to

Page 73: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

73

exploit the connection between the key parameters of the structural form of the hybrid model

given by equation (4.2) and the reduced form parameters of the closed form they estimate. In

particular, the reduced form parameters of the closed form are explicit functions of the

parameters of structural form (4.2), including � and b , the parameters that identify the

relative importance of forward- looking versus backward-looking behaviour. They then

estimate the closed form equation in a way that incorporates the restrictions of the structural

form, the parameter estimates are virtually identical to those obtained in Gali and Gertler’s

(1999) and Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2001) by estimating the structural form directly.

More specifically, they argue that the parameter on lagged inflation is not the same as b ,

the coefficient on lagged inflation in the baseline hybrid specification (4.2). In other words, it

is not possible to assess the relative importance of forward-versus backward-looking

behaviour from the Rudd and Whelan (2005b) specification and that it is important to

identify the parameters � and b directly.

Rudd and Whelan (2007) summarise their previous empirical findings and also

respond to Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2005) defence of their previous critiques. Rudd

and Whelan (2007, p. 167) emphasise that the most important test of the NKPC “is whether

there is a statistically significant role for expected future labour shares”. They identify the

source of the disagreements between their empirical findings and that of Gali, Gertler and

Lopez-Salido (2005) is the very different metric for judging the importance of forward-

looking behaviour. Rather than focusing on the role played by expected future labour shares,

they focus on the values of � and b implied by the estimated roots of the closed form

representation. The relationship between the estimated roots of the closed form representation

and the implied values of � and b occurs through a second-order polynomial equation, and

cannot be related to values of � and b directly.

Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2005, p. 1117) recognise that the hybrid Phillips

curve lacks a “coherent rationale for the role of lagged inflation in the hybrid NKPC”. They

appeal to the work of Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans (2005) and Smets and Wouters

(2003, 2004) which attempt to explain inflation persistence by assume some form of

indexation. The Fuhrer and Moore (1995) model is perhaps the most well-known model to

explain inflation persistence by introducing indexation. Fuhrer and Moore (1995) assume that

wage negotiations are conducted in terms of the wage relative to an average of real contract

Page 74: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

74

wages in effect over the life of the contract. Fuhrer and Moore (1995, p. 130) specification

produce a hybrid Phillips curve of the form

1 1

2t t t t tE � (4.5)

where �̂ is a moving average of current and past output. Inflation depends on its past (and

thus on past output). This specification imparts significant inertia to the inflation rate (as well

as the price level) beyond the inertia in the driving term. One time shocks to output and

inflation will persist. The model also implies that disinflations lead to a decline in output,

which is more consistent with empirical evidence. Fuhrer and Moore (1995) then showed that

their model fits U.S. data better than Taylor’s (1980) model. It is important to point out that

the motivation for the Fuhrer and Moore (1995) model is to explain inflation persistence

which cannot be explained by the forward-looking Taylor staggered contract type models.

Fuhrer (1997, p. 349) tests the empirical significance of expected future prices in forward-

looking contract price specifications and finds that expectations of future prices are

empirically unimportant in explaining price and inflation behaviour.

Roberts (1997, p.174) shows that the Fuhrer and Moore (1995) model is

observationally equivalent to a model with sticky prices and expectations that are imperfectly

rational. That is, we could obtain equation (4.5) based on the assumption that expectations are

an average of rational expectations and a simple extrapolation of last period's inflation rate.

Using survey measures of inflation expectations, Roberts (1997, p. 173) concludes that

“inflation is not sticky and that inflation expectations are less than perfectly rational”. Below

are some selected reduced-form and closed-form GMM estimations of the Phillips curve for

the United States mentioned in the literature review.

Page 75: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

75

Table 4.1 Selected Reduced Form GMM Estimations of the Phillips Curve for the United States

General Equation 1 1t t b t � t tmc E

Authors Sample

Period

Proxy for RMC b � Instruments Notes

Gali and Gertler

(1999)

1960q1-

1997q4

Labour’s Share 0.23 - 0.942 Four lags of inflation, labour income share,

long-short interest rate spread, output gap,

wage inflation, and commodity price

inflation.

Coefficient of labour’s share of

income has the correct sign

Gali and Gertler

(1999)

1960q1-

1997q4

Output Gap -0.016 - 0.988 Four lags of inflation, labour income share,

long-short interest rate spread, output gap,

wage inflation, and commodity price

inflation.

Coefficient of the output gap

has the wrong sign

Gali and Gertler

(1999)

1960q1-

1997q4

Labour’s Share 0.037 0.252 0.682 Four lags of inflation, labour income share,

long-short interest rate spread, output gap,

wage inflation, and commodity price

inflation.

Forward expectations dominate

Gali and Gertler

(1999)

1960q1-

1997q4,

Labour’s Share 0.027 0.233 0.766 Four lags of inflation, labour income share,

long-short interest rate spread, output gap,

wage inflation, and commodity price

inflation.

1b �

Forward expectations dominate

Gali, Gertler and

Lopez-Salido

(2001)

1970q1-

1998q2

Labour’s Share 0.250 - 0.924 Four lags of inflation, and two lags of

labour’s share of income, the output gap,

and wage inflation.

Coefficient of labour’s share of

income has the correct sign

Gali, Gertler and

Lopez-Salido

(2001)

1970q1-

1998q2

Labour’s Share 0.291 0.347 0.584 Four lags of inflation, and two lags of

labour’s share of income, the output gap,

and wage inflation.

Forward expectations dominate

Page 76: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

76

Gali, Gertler and

Lopez-Salido

(2005)

1960q1–

1997q4

Labour’s Share 0.013 0.349 0.635 Two lags of detrended output, real

marginal costs and wage inflation and four

lags of price inflation.

1b �

Forward expectations dominate

Gali, Gertler and

Lopez-Salido

(2005)

1960q1–

1997q4

Output Gap -0.005 0.325 0.684 Two lags of detrended output, real

marginal costs and wage inflation and four

lags of price inflation.

1b �

Forward expectations dominate

Rudd and Whelan

(2005)

1960q1–

1997q4

Labour’s Share 0.011 0.221 0.764 Four lags of inflation, labour income share,

long-short interest rate spread, output gap,

wage inflation, and commodity price

inflation.

2SLS

Forward expectations dominate

Rudd and Whelan

(2005)

1960q1–

1997q4

Output Gap -0.010 0.188 0.817 Four lags of inflation, labour income share,

long-short interest rate spread, output gap,

wage inflation, and commodity price

inflation.

2SLS

Forward expectations dominate

Page 77: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

77

Table 4.2 Selected Closed Form GMM Estimations of the Phillips Curve for the United States

Authors Sample

Period

Proxy for RMC b � Instruments Notes

Gali, Gertler and

Lopez-Salido

(2005)

1960q1–

1997q4

Labour’s Share 0.013 0.374 0.618 Two lags of detrended output, real

marginal costs and wage inflation and four

lags of price inflation.

Forward expectations dominate

Gali, Gertler and

Lopez-Salido

(2005)

1960q1–

1997q4

Output Gap 0.016 0.882 -0.000 Two lags of detrended output, real

marginal costs and wage inflation and four

lags of price inflation.

Backward expectations

dominate

Gali, Gertler and

Lopez-Salido

(2005)

1960q1–

1997q4

Labour’s Share 0.010 0.373 0.627 Two lags of detrended output, real

marginal costs and wage inflation and four

lags of price inflation.

1b �

Forward expectations dominate

Gali, Gertler and

Lopez-Salido

(2005)

1960q1–

1997q4

Output Gap 0.002 0.540 0.460 Two lags of detrended output, real

marginal costs and wage inflation and four

lags of price inflation.

1b �

Backward expectations

dominate

Rudd and Whelan

(2007)

1960q1-

1997q4

Labour’s Share 0.042 0.486 0.473 Two lags of inflation, labour income share,

long-short interest rate spread, output gap,

wage inflation, and commodity price

Backward expectations weakly

dominate

Page 78: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

78

inflation.

Rudd and Whelan

(2007)

1960q1-

1997q4

Labour’s Share 0.032 0.440 0.535 Four lags of inflation, two lags each of

inflation, the output gap, the labour income

share, and wage inflation.

Forward expectations weakly

dominate

Rudd and Whelan

(2007)

1960q1-

1997q4

Labour’s Share 0.036 0.452 0.516 Two lags of inflation, and two lags each of

labour’s share of income, the output gap,

and wage inflation.

Forward expectations weakly

dominate

Page 79: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

79

4.3 Proxies for Real Marginal Cost

�he ��tp�t �ap

The output gap measures the gap between actual level of output and the potential level

of output that the economy could produce at full employment. The output gap allows us to

measure the size of the deviations of output from potential level of output or trend output

(Dornbush and Fischer, 1994, pp.14-15). The intuition of using the output gap as a measure

of real marginal cost is simple. If the actual level of output exceeds the potential level of

output, then there will be upward inflationary pressures because production costs and labour

costs are higher. Conversely, if the actual level of output is less than the potential level of

output, then there will be downward deflationary pressures because of underemployment of

human resources and machinery. This implies that the output gap and inflation are positively

correlated. As mentioned in chapter 3 the use of the output gap as a proxy for real marginal

cost is potentially problematic because it does not take into account labour market

imperfections and it cannot distinguish when an increase in output is caused by technological

progress, which is less inflationary and when an increase in output is induced say by

monetary policy.

�abo�r�s �hare o� ��come

The logic behind Gali and Gertler’s (1999) is based on the assumption of Cobb-

Douglas production function. Let tA denote technology, t

� capital and t� labour. Then

output t� is given by:

1

t t t t� A � � (4.6)

Real marginal cost is given by the ratio of the real wage rate to the marginal product

of labour (MPL); the marginal product of labour is proportional to its average product. Thus,

real marginal cost is proportional to labour’s share of total income (real unit labour cost). Let

lower case letters denote percent deviations from the steady state t tmc s , where s is the

measure of labour’s share (Walsh, 2010, p. 253). This is valid only when there are constant

returns.

/ /

/t t t t t

t t

t � t t

� P � P � ��� �

�P� � � P� (4.7)

Page 80: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

80

As mentioned previously, the approximation of real marginal cost by labour’s share of

income assumes a constant return to scale production function. Under more realistic

conditions, real unit labour cost needs to be corrected for assumptions about technology, non-

constant elasticity of factor substitution between capital and labour, the presence of overhead

costs and labour adjustment costs (Guay and Pelgrim, 2004, p.5).

�ob �i�di�g Probabilit�

The intuition behind the use of job finding probability as a proxy for real marginal

cost is that it directly measures how difficult it is for unemployed people to find jobs, in other

words, the tightness of the labour market. If the labour market is tight, then there will be

upward inflationary pressures because labours costs are higher as workers demand higher

wages in order to supply more labour. Conversely, if the labour market is slack, then there

will be downward deflationary pressures because of underemployment of human resources.

This implies that job finding probability and inflation are positively correlated.

Whether the output gap, labour’s share of output or job finding probability is a better

proxy for real marginal cost is an empirical question. However, theoretically job finding

probability is more appealing because of the following reasons: First, perhaps the most

important aspect about job finding probability is its ability to capture labour market frictions,

as mentioned in the previous chapter, because of our bounded rationality, a lack of

knowledge and skills and the difficulties in overcoming a lack of knowledge and skills are the

main sources of frictions in the labour market. Besides capturing labour market frictions due

to specialization of labour, job finding probability also captures other forms of heterogeneity

in the labour market such as: long-term unemployed, age, sex, race, marital status, levels of

education and geography (Shimer, 2007, p. 4). Second, we do not need to make assumptions

about the type of technology in the production process. In short, job finding probability

overcomes theoretical weaknesses of the output gap and labour’s share of income as proxies

for real marginal cost, at the same time it provides a direct link between labour market’s

frictions and the Phillips curve relationship.

The standard theory of job finding probability describes employers as recruiters of

workers. They expand their efforts until the cost of recruiting a worker exhausts the

employer’s share of the surplus of employing the worker. The employer-equilibrium curve

slopes upward because higher surplus gives employers more incentive to recruit more

Page 81: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

81

workers, creating a tighter labour market with a higher job finding probability. For job

seekers, a tighter labour market lowers the surplus. The surplus is the difference between the

present value of a worker’s product and the worker’s opportunity cost. The opportunity cost

in turn, depends on the ease of finding a job – in a tight labour market with a high job-finding

probability, the opportunity cost is higher and the surplus from a job is lower, the job-seeker

equilibrium curve is downward slopping. The equilibrium of the labour market occurs at the

intersection of the employer-equilibrium curve and the job seeker- equilibrium curve (Hall,

2005, p.23-24).

Source: Hall, 2005, p. 23.

The use of job finding probability as a proxy for real marginal cost is not without its

problems, as job finding probability is an unobservable variable, it has to be constructed from

other observable variables. This implies that job finding probability is sensitive to its own

definition as there are various ways of measuring job finding probability. There are at least

three types of job finding probabilities: First, some workers changed jobs without

experiencing unemployment. Second, some people are returning to the labour after being out

of the labour force for various reasons, such as health and child birth. Third, people who are

currently unemployed and wish to find employment (Hall, 2005, p.18).

Intuitively, the job finding probability is the ratio of the flow from other activities into

employment, divided by the number of people who are looking for work. Our objective is to

Employer Equilibrium

Job Seeker Equilibrium

Job Finding Probability

Surplus

Page 82: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

82

compute the probability of a job seeker in finding employment without having to be retrained

in order to find employment, it is reasonable that we exclude workers who are currently

employed, but, wish to find other jobs since these job seekers are only a small fraction of the

total number of job seekers, their exclusion should not affect the job finding probability.

Our formulation of job finding probability follows Robert Shimer’s (2005, p.30-31)

formulation, which infers the job finding probability from dynamic behaviour of the

unemployment level and the short-term unemployment level. Let �

t denote the number of

workers unemployed for less than 15 weeks, in month t . Then assuming all unemployed

workers find a job with probability t� in month t and no unemployed workers exit the labour

force, then the number of unemployed workers next month is equal to the number of

unemployed workers this month who failed to find a job, plus the number of newly

unemployed workers.

1 1(1 ) �

t t t t� (4.8)

The job finding probability is given by

1 11�

t tt

t

(4.9)

where t� is the job finding probability, t

is the number of unemployed workers, �

t is the

number of short term (less than 15 weeks) unemployed workers and 1t is the number of

unemployed workers next month. We have also considered job finding probability for the

number of workers unemployed for less than five weeks, the results are similar to the results

of job finding probability for the number of workers unemployed for less than 15 weeks. In

order to conserve space we will only report the results of job finding probability for the

number of workers unemployed for less than 15 weeks.

The use of job finding probability as a proxy for real marginal cost is a novel aspect

of this chapter. Previous works on job finding probability such as: Hall (2005), Shimer (2005,

2007), Elsby, Michaels and Solon (2007) and Fujita and Ramey (2007) do not take into

account the connection between specialization of labour as a source of labour market friction

and job finding probability. Cao (2008, pp. 30-41) presents a search and matching model due

to Romer (2001) which is re-interpreted with an emphasis on the role of asymmetric

Page 83: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

83

knowledge and the sticky nature of knowledge in the labour market so that the main matching

frictions in the labour market are due to heterogeneous knowledge between unemployed

workers and available jobs. The model proposes that job finding probability should captures

the extent of specialization of labour, informational imperfections about the timing of job

creation in different locations and the slow mobility of the production factors, which lead to

mismatch problems in the labour market, potentially helping us to explain involuntary

unemployment

4.4 Proxies for Inflation Expectations

An important issue in the empirical literature on the NKPC is what should be used as

proxy for inflation expectations because inflation expectations is an unobservable variable,

the choice of data as proxy for inflation expectations has important implications for various

methods of estimation and possibly the validity of the results.

A popular way of dealing with this problem is by using the actual value of inflation

expectations as a proxy for inflation expectations. However, the actual rate of inflation is

correlated with the error term; as a result, instrumental variables are use as proxy for actual

inflation. Suppose that the information used by price setters to forecast inflation 1 |t t t

E � .

As inflation expectations are unobservable, we need to generate econometric forecasts of

inflation expectations by using instrumental variables. Let 1 |t t tE � denote an econometric

forecast that uses some variables, t� to predict next period’s inflation rate 1t

, where t�a

subset of the information available to price setters. To generate our econometric forecast of

inflation expectations we regress actual inflation on our sets of instrumental variables t� .

1 1t t tb� (4.10)

Our forecast is simply the fitted values

1ˆ|t t t tE � b� (4.11)

By construction it is uncorrelated with the error term 1t̂ . According to the law of

iterated expectations, our econometric predictions of price-setters’ inflation expectations are

simply our forecasts.

Page 84: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

84

1 1| | |t t t t t t t

E E � � E � (4.12)

Generalized Method of Moments (GMM) is an instrumental variables technique,

which can be used to estimate the Phillips curve (Nason and Smith, 2008).

4.5 Data and Estimation Strategy

Table 4.3 presents the definitions and sources of the data used in this chapter; all

series are quarterly data for the United States and are expressed in log unless stated

otherwise. We use core CPI as our measure of inflation because it is less volatile than other

measures of inflation, since it excludes food and energy. The price of oil is an important

determinant of inflation since oil is needed in the production process as well as in delivering

goods and services, but the price of oil is often determined by external factors such as war. If

we were to use other measures of inflation5 such as the Consumer Price Index (CPI) we may

need to include the price of oil as an explanatory variable as Roberts (1995) did, which would

complicates our attempt to estimate the Phillips curve.

Table 4. 3 Definitions and Sources of Data

Variable Definition Source

t t is measured as4

ln t

t

p

p using core CPI. Core CPI - Consumer

Price Index (All Items Less Food and Energy), Index 1982-1984=100.

Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

dlw Wage Inflation, measured as the log- difference in nonfarm compensation per hour (Nonfarm Business Sector Real Hourly Compensation, Index 1992=100).

Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

j Job Finding Probability. Constructed from the number of unemployed workers, the number of short term (less than 15 weeks) unemployed workers and the number of unemployed workers next month.

Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

y Output Gap (Nonfarm Business Sector Output, Index 2005=100), using the Hodrick-Prescott filter with a smoothing parameter of 1600.

Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

s The Log of Labour’s Share of Income (Nonfarm Business Sector, Index 1992=100).

Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

5 In their influential paper, Gali and Gertler (1999) use the GDP deflator in their analysis.

Page 85: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

85

dlppi Commodity Price Inflation. Measured as4

ln t

t

ppi

ppi using

Producer Price Index: Finished goods, Index 1982=100.

research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/categories/31.

sp Long-Short Interest Rate Spread. The Difference Between 10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate and 3-Month Treasury Bill.

Federal Reserve Board (FRB).

Our estimation strategy is simple, we will estimate various specifications of the

Phillips curve and compare the empirical results using the output gap, labour’s share of

income and job finding probability as proxies for real marginal cost and also examine the

relative importance of forward-looking and backward inflation expectations. In particular, we

will estimate the reduced form of the hybrid Phillips curve and use the same instruments as

Gali and Gertler (1999) and Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2001, 2005), which will allows

us to directly compare our results with their results. We will use GMM to estimate the new

Keynesian Phillips curve and the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve.

4.6 Empirical Comparisons

First we estimate the old Keynesian Phillips curve using Ordinary Least Square

(OLS). We will use the results of the old Keynesian Phillips curve, with adaptive

expectations as our benchmark, since rational expectations predicts that modelling the

Phillips curve with rational expectations should fit the data better than modelling the Phillips

curve with adaptive expectations. Rational expectations implies that inflation expectations are

rational, in the sense that they efficiently incorporate all information available at time the

expectations are taken, and not just the past information as implied by adaptive expectations.

The empirical results in this chapter were estimated using Eviews; we used a HAC (Newey

West) weighting matrix, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information

criterion. The numbers of lags are presented in the proxy for real marginal cost column.

Page 86: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

86

Table 4.4 OLS Estimates of the Old Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t b tmc

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost Constant b

Job Finding Probability (1 lag)

-0.015781 0.003178

-4.965459 0.000000

0.024167 0.004485 5.387857

0.0000

0.960334 0.014313 67.09330

0.0000

Output Gap (1 lag)

0.000727 0.000666 1.092342

0.276000

0.001606 0.000309 5.204447

0.000000

0.983034 0.014106 69.68890

0.000000

Labour’s Share of Income ( 1 lag)

-0.148958 0.069784

-2.134567 0.034100

0.032696 0.015218 2.148541 0.032900

0.958852 0.016980 56.46937 0.000000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1961q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third

row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

The coefficients of the three proxies of real marginal cost are all statistically

significant at 5% level.

The following estimations below were estimated using Generalized Method of

Moments (GMM). The instrument set t�consists of four lags of inflation, labour income

share, long-short interest rate spread, output gap, wage inflation, and commodity price

inflation. This instrument set is the same as the instrument set used in Gali and Gertler

(1999).

Table 4.5 GMM Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real

Marginal Cost

Constant �

Job Finding Probability (2 lags)

0.015362 0.005583 2.751668 0.006500

-0.022438 0.007798

-2.877212 0.004500

1.021599 0.016934 60.32975 0.000000

Output Gap -1.35E-05 -0.000846 1.015788

Page 87: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

87

The coefficients of the three proxies for real marginal cost have the wrong signs. The

coefficients of the forward inflation expectations are all statistically significant at 1% level

for the three proxies of real marginal cost.

Table 4.6 GMM Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1 1t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

Job Finding Probability (4 lags)

0.000320 0.000887 0.360837

0.718600

-0.000814 0.001316

-0.618251

0.537200

0.505190 0.015124 33.40395

0.000000

0.502469 0.016508 30.43848

0.000000

Output Gap (4 lags)

-0.000307 7.70E-05

-3.992571 0.000100

-0.000230 0.000108

-2.123102 0.035100

0.463124 0.023645 19.58638 0.000000

0.546278 0.024747 22.07448 0.000000

Labour’s Share of Income (4 lags)

0.019587 0.007891 2.482128

0.013900

-0.004325 0.001728

-2.502913

0.013200

0.503032 0.011162 45.06467

0.000000

0.506640 0.011310 44.79621

0.000000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1961q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

The coefficients of the three proxies for real marginal cost have the wrong signs. The

results also indicate that the coefficients of forward-looking and backward-looking inflation

expectations are about the same in magnitude. The results of the new Keynesian Phillips

curve (Table 4.5) and the results of the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve above do not

(4 lags)

0.000458 -0.029455 0.976500

0.000398 -2.124386 0.034900

0.010177 99.81653 0.000000

Labour’s Share of Income ( 3 lags)

0.041830 0.042288 0.989172 0.323800

-0.009185 0.009252

-0.992736 0.322100

1.018013 0.013120 77.59343 0.000000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1961q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

Page 88: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

88

support the notion that labour’s share of income is a better proxy for real marginal cost than

the output gap.

4.7 Robustness Analysis

We consider two robustness exercises. The first robustness exercise examines sub-

sample stability, our sub-samples are the periods from 1961q1 to 1984q4 and the period from

1985q1 to 2010q1, we also wanted to examine the relative importance of forward-looking

and backward-looking inflation expectations during different sub-sample periods. The second

robustness exercise examines an alternative instrument set which includes four lags of

inflation, and two lags of the real marginal cost (labour’s share of income), the output gap,

and wage inflation. This instrument set is the same instrument set used by Gali, Gertler and

Lopez-Salido (2001, p.1250).

��b��ample �tabilit�

Table 4.7 OLS Estimations of the Old Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t b tmc

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost Constant b

Job Finding Probability (1 lag)

-0.032716 0.012124 2.698494 0.008300

0.045316 0.015504 2.922914 0.004400

0.977941 0.029517 33.13118 0.000000

Output Gap

(0 lag)

0.001470

0.001110 1.325080 0.188400

0.003650

0.000682 5.354550 0.000000

0.983038

0.027521 35.71904 0.000000

Labour’s Share of Income (1 lag)

-0.250777 0.452849

-0.553776 0.581100

0.054832 0.098119 0.558831 0.577600

0.952926 0.952926 26.53684 0.000000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1961q1 to 1984q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

Page 89: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

89

The coefficients of job finding probability and the output gap are statistically

significant at 1%. The coefficients of backward inflation expectations are all statistically

significant at 1% level for the three proxies of real marginal cost.

Table 4.8 OLS Estimations of the Old Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t b tmc

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

Job Finding Probability (0 lag)

-0.006209 0.001880

-3.302680

0.001300

0.011305 0.002955 3.825133

0.000200

0.936905 0.027062 34.62037

0.000000

Output Gap (0 lag)

0.000400 0.000726 0.550186 0.583400

0.000512 0.000155 3.296777 0.001400

0.975051 0.025195 38.70032 0.000000

Labour’s Share of Income (1 lag)

-0.067951 0.036291

-1.872382

0.064100

0.015004 0.008072 1.858807

0.066100

0.957827 0.037693 25.41106

0.000000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1985q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors

are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West

procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third

row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

The coefficients of job finding probability and the output gap are statistically

significant at 1%. The coefficients of backward inflation expectations are all statistically

significant at 1% level for the three proxies of real marginal cost.

Table 4.9 GMM Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost Constant �

Job Finding Probability

(0 lag)

0.046623

0.012950 3.600203 0.000500

-0.060680

0.016323 -3.717485 0.000400

0.986891

0.022455 43.95051 0.000000

Output Gap (0 lag)

-0.001518 0.000805

-0.003944 0.000524

1.021562 0.014999

Page 90: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

90

-1.885489 0.062600

-7.521233 0.000000

68.11082 0.000000

Labour’s Share of Income (2 lags)

-0.003542 0.123471

-0.028688 0.977200

0.000633 0.026788 0.023643 0.981200

0.996002 0.019147 52.01755 0.000000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1961q1 to 1984q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

The coefficients of forward inflation expectations are all statistically significant at 1%

level for the three proxies of real marginal cost. Compare to the results of the full sample

(Table 4.5), the sign of the coefficient of labour’s share of income is now positive, but not

statistically significant.

Table 4.10 GMM Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t � t t

mc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

Job Finding Probability (0 lag)

0.006231 0.001759 3.542796 0.000600

-0.009304 0.002946

-3.157926 0.002100

1.013673 0.025182 40.25423 0.000000

Output Gap

(0 lag)

-4.30E-05

0.000576 -0.074563 0.940700

-0.000685

0.000185 -3.707331 0.000300

1.009096

0.019547 51.62322 0.000000

Labour’s Share of Income (0 lag)

0.050213 0.031874 1.575334 0.118400

-0.010929 0.007040

-1.552461 0.123800

1.001967 0.025855 38.75351 0.000000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1985q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

The coefficients of forward inflation expectations are all statistically significant at 1%

level for the three proxies of real marginal cost. The coefficients of the three proxies for real

marginal cost have the wrong signs.

Page 91: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

91

Table 4.11 GMM Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1 1t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b �

Job Finding Probability (0 lag)

-0.004695 0.005252

-0.893996 0.373800

0.005376 0.006682 0.804606 0.423200

0.529394 0.035538 14.89660 0.000000

0.480562 0.035291 13.61731 0.000000

Output Gap (0 lag)

-0.000624 0.000459

-1.358735 0.177700

-0.000432 0.000506

-0.855054 0.394800

0.473848 0.054635

8.672891 0.000000

0.537466 0.058808

9.139401 0.000000

Labour’s Share of Income (0 lag)

-0.002027 0.069795

-0.029039 0.976900

0.000339 0.015115 0.022427 0.982200

0.509036 0.027071 18.80369 0.000000

0.498271 0.027353 18.21653 0.000000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1961q1 to 1984q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the

third row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

The coefficient of the output gap has the wrong sign. The coefficients of forward-

looking and backward-looking inflation expectations are about the same in magnitude and are

all statistically significant at 1% level for the three proxies of real marginal cost.

Table 4.12 GMM Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1 1t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b �

Job Finding Probability (0 lag)

-0.001327 0.001642

-0.808198 0.421000

0.002024 0.002768 0.731028 0.466500

0.617113 0.070008 8.814906 0.000000

0.377764 0.081663 4.625908 0.000000

Output Gap

(0 lag)

-0.000200

0.000266 -0.751322 0.454300

1.59E-05

0.000106 0.149999 0.881100

0.592147

0.073301 8.078313 0.000000

0.413408

0.078263 5.282319 0.000000

Labour’s Share of Income (0 lag)

0.000103 0.022207 0.004629

-3.31E-05 0.004884

-0.006772

0.584653 0.047893 12.20744

0.415958 0.053516 7.772617

Page 92: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

92

0.996300 0.994600

0.000000 0.000000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1985q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

The coefficient of labour’s share of income has the wrong sign. The coefficients of

backward-looking dominate forward-looking inflation expectations and these coefficients are

all statistically significant at 1% level for the three proxies of real marginal cost.

4.8 An Alternative Instrument Set

Next we consider an alternative instrument set, which includes four lags of inflation,

and two lags of labour’s share of income, the output gap, and wage inflation. This instrument

set is the same instrument set used by Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2001, p.1250).

Table 4.13GMM Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

Job Finding Probability (2 lags)

0.009993 0.006261 1.596089 0.112100

-0.014983 0.008902

-1.683073 0.094000

1.014705 0.020232 50.15369 0.000000

Output Gap (2 lags)

0.000307 0.000581 0.527287 0.598600

-0.001803 0.000585

-3.081177 0.002400

0.994676 0.013767 72.25140 0.000000

Labour’s Share of Income (4 lags)

0.033188 0.041725 0.795404 0.427400

-0.007336 0.009133

-0.803214 0.422900

1.023358 0.012638 80.97683 0.000000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1961q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

Page 93: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

93

The coefficients of forward inflation expectations are all statistically significant at 1%

level for the three proxies of real marginal cost. The coefficients of the three proxies for real

marginal cost have the wrong signs.

Table 4.14 GMM Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1 1t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b �

Job Finding Probability (4 lags)

0.000374 0.001030 0.363535 0.716600

-0.000916 0.001510

-0.606353 0.545000

0.500503 0.014664 34.13093 0.000000

0.507321 0.015891 31.92607 0.000000

Output Gap (4 lags)

-0.000387 0.000112

-3.467746 0.000700

-0.000507 0.000173

-2.933563 0.003800

0.425374 0.027847

15.27563 0.000000

0.587061 0.029472

19.91934 0.0000

Labour’s Share of Income (4 lags)

0.023085 0.012469 1.851375 0.065700

-0.005089 0.002728

-1.865774 0.063600

0.500347 0.012372 40.44285 0.000000

0.510151 0.012526 40.72825 0.000000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1961q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-

West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

The coefficients of the three proxies for real marginal cost have the wrong signs. The

results also indicate that the coefficients of forward-looking and backward-looking inflation

expectations are about the same in magnitude. The results of the new Keynesian Phillips

curve (Table 4.13) and the results of the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve above do not

support the notion that labour’s share of income is a better proxy for real marginal cost than

the output gap.

Page 94: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

94

4.9 Endogeneity of Real Marginal Cost

One possible explanation for the change in the sign of real marginal cost variable in

the new Keynesian Phillips curve – relative to the results for the old Keynesian Phillips curve

estimated by OLS – is that the real marginal cost variable is treated as endogenous and is

instrumented along with future inflation rather than the real marginal cost variable being

treated as an exogenous variable as in the old Keynesian Phillips curve6. We will now

examine whether treating the real marginal cost as an endogenous variable has a significant

impact on the results. We will estimate the new Keynesian Phillips curve and the hybrid new

Keynesian Phillips curve with and without the three proxies for real marginal cost in the

instrument set t� .

The following new Keynesian Phillips curves below were estimated using

Generalized Method of Moments (GMM). The instrument set t�consists of four lags of

inflation, labour income share, output gap, job finding probability, long-short interest rate

spread, wage inflation, and commodity price inflation.

6I thank an anonymous examiner for raising this issue.

Table 4.15 GMM Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t � t tmc E c

Proxy for Real

Marginal Cost

Constant �

Job Finding Probability (2 lags)

0.011702 0.003948 2.963950

0.0034

-0.017068 0.005546

-3.077624 0.0024

1.015422 0.016166 62.81202

0.0000

Output Gap (2 lags)

0.000473 0.000550 0.859928

0.3909

-0.002090 0.000577

-3.620822

0.0004

0.989877 0.012793 77.37471

0.0000

Labour’s Share of Income (2 lags)

0.055272 0.043535 1.269597

0.2058

-0.012052 0.009498

-1.268995 0.2060

1.005815 0.017031 59.05721

0.0000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1961q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the

third row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

Page 95: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

95

The following estimations below were estimated using Generalized Method of

Moments (GMM). The instrument set t�consists of four lags of inflation, long-short interest

rate spread, wage inflation, and commodity price inflation.

The coefficients of the three proxies for real marginal cost have the wrong signs for

estimations with and without labour income share, output gap and job finding probability in

the instrument set t�.

The following hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curves below were estimated using

Generalized Method of Moments (GMM). The instrument set t�consists of four lags of

inflation, labour income share, output gap, job finding probability, long-short interest rate

spread, wage inflation, and commodity price inflation.

Table 4.16 GMM Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t � t tmc E c

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

Job Finding Probability

(4 lags)

0.013171 0.005646

2.332921 0.0207

-0.020102 0.007869

-2.554633 0.0114

1.048545 0.015941

65.77513 0.0000

Output Gap (4 lags)

-0.000354 0.000610

-0.581278 0.5617

-0.002134 0.000789

-2.704799 0.0075

1.019004 0.009443 107.9084

0.0000

Labour’s Share of Income (5 lags)

0.245741 0.142306

1.726851 0.0858

-0.053713 0.031053

-1.729710 0.0853

1.047541 0.018617

56.26673 0.0000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1961q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

Page 96: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

96

Table 4.17 GMM Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1 1t t b t � t tmc E c

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b �

Job Finding Probability (4 lags)

0.001102 0.001160 0.949570

0.3435

-0.001933 0.001755

-1.101021 0.2723

0.476079 0.031553 15.08816

0.0000

0.530072 0.032423 16.34876

0.0000

Output Gap (0 lag)

-0.000223 0.000209

-1.064469 0.2885

-0.000128 0.000152

-0.837090 0.4036

0.477196 0.035147 13.57733

0.0000

0.527590 0.036255 14.55231

0.0000

Labour’s Share of Income (0 lag)

0.029483 0.018227 1.617574

0.1074

-0.006479 0.003992

-1.623002 0.1063

0.492714 0.026257 18.76486

0.0000

0.514641 0.025428 20.23899

0.0000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1961q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

The following estimations below were estimated using Generalized Method of

Moments (GMM). The instrument set t�consists of four lags of inflation, long-short interest

rate spread, wage inflation, and commodity price inflation.

Table 4.18 GMM Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1 1t t b t � t tmc E c

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

Job Finding Probability (4 lags)

0.002133 0.001753

1.216712 0.2252

-0.003478 0.002559

-1.359059 0.1758

0.477907 0.022807

20.95413 0.0000

0.533038 0.025483

20.91758 0.0000

Output Gap (4 lags)

-0.000379 0.000152

-2.495849 0.0134

-0.000410 0.000408

-1.003705 0.3168

0.441995 0.052554 8.410279

0.0000

0.568490 0.055870 10.17520

0.0000

Labour’s Share of Income (4 lags)

0.103708 0.048855

2.122751 0.0351

-0.022720 0.010665

-2.130326 0.0344

0.521114 0.022023

23.66211 0.0000

0.501351 0.024612

20.36992 0.0000

Note: The above equation was estimated over the 1961q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third row. Statistical probabilities are shown in the fourth row.

Page 97: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

97

Once again, the coefficients of the three proxies for real marginal cost have the wrong

signs for estimations with and without labour income share, output gap and job finding

probability in the instrument set t� . This brief section suggests that whether we include or

exclude labour income share, output gap and job finding probability from the instrument set

t� , the signs of the real marginal costs variable remain the same.

4.10 Conclusion

Our empirical results are not supportive of Gali and Gertler’s (1999) empirical

findings that labour’s share of income is a better proxy for real marginal cost than the output

gap. Also, our results are not supportive Gali and Gertler’s (1999, p.195) empirical findings

that “[b]ackward-looking price setting, while statistically significant, is not quantitatively

important”. In general, our results indicate that forward-looking and backward-looking

inflation expectations are about the same in magnitude.

Our first robustness exercise examines sub-sample stability of the periods from

1961q1 to 1984q4 and the period from 1985q1 to 2010q1. The results of first robustness

exercise suggest that the second sub-sample period fits the data slightly better overall, this is

as expected since the US economy experienced higher inflation and higher economic

volatility (due to the OPEC oil crisis of 1970’s) during the first sub-sample period, the lower

economic volatility of the second sub-sample period makes forecasting inflation easier

(despite the recent financial crisis), at the same time, it makes lagged inflation more reliable,

since the rates of inflation do not change much quarter to quarter (see table 4.7 and Table

4.8), this is also reflected by our empirical results showing that backward-looking dominate

forward-looking inflation expectations when the hybrid Phillips curve is estimated (see table

4.11and Table 4.12).Our first robustness exercise also indicate that the that the slope of the

reduced form Phillips curve for the United States has flattened over the last 25 years, this is

reflected by the lower values of the coefficients of real marginal cost of the second sub-

sample period relative to the first sub-sample period. We will examine this issue in more

details later. The results of our second robustness exercise are consistent with our initial

results.

Overall our results suggest the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive

expectations fits the data better than the new Keynesian Phillips curve with rational

Page 98: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

98

expectations, this result is consistent with some well-known previous work, such as Fuhrer

and Moore (1995) and Mankiw (2001). Rudd and Whelan (2006, p.319) conclude that

“lagged inflation plays an important role in empirical inflation regressions poses a major

challenge to the rational-expectations sticky-price models that underpin the new Keynesian

Phillips curve”. Similarly Mankiw (2001, p.59) made the following concluding remarks in his

survey article, which also reflect our sentiment regarding this matter.

“There is a simple way to reconcile the new Keynesian Phillips curve with the data:

adaptive expectations. In my analysis throughout this paper, I have used the now

standard assumption that expectations are formed rationally. If, instead, the inflation

rate expected in period t for period t + 1 always equals inflation experienced at time t

- 1, then the forward-looking model reduces to the backward-looking model, which

works just fine. Because of this, some people working in this area are now

questioning the assumption of rational expectations. (See, e.g., Roberts, 1997).

Assuming adaptive expectations, however, is far from a satisfying resolution to the

puzzle. The rational-expectations hypothesis has much appeal, for reasons that were

widely discussed in the 1970s. Moreover, the public is not ignorant about monetary

shocks. Central bank actions are widely reported in the news, and they are dissected

by commentators in agonising detail. In light of all this media coverage of monetary

policy, it is odd to assert that expectations about inflation are formed without

incorporating this news. Yet the assumption of adaptive expectations is, in essence,

what the data are crying out for”.

Rudd and Whelan (2007, p.163) note that the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve is

considered by many as a sensible compromise between the pure rational expectations new

Keynesian Phillips curve with micro-foundations, but does not fit the data well and the old

Keynesian Phillips curve, which lack strong micro-foundations but fits the data better. Even

if we accept the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve as having the right specifications for

the Phillips curve relationship we still need to consider two things: First, why are some price

setters backward-looking and why are some price setters forward looking? What determine

their price setting behaviours? Second, are the fraction of backward-looking firms and the

fraction forward-looking firms constant over time?

Page 99: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

99

We have introduced the concept of job finding probability which provides a direct

link between frictions in the labour market and the Phillips curve relationship and used job

finding probability as a proxy for real marginal cost to estimate of various specifications of

the Phillips curve. Our results suggest that job finding probability should be considered as an

alternative proxy for real marginal cost in empirical work on the Phillips curve.

Unfortunately, we have not been able to show conclusively that job finding probability is a

better proxy for real marginal cost than the output gap and labour’s share of income in this

chapter. We will re-examine this issue in the next in the next chapter using survey measures

of inflation expectations as proxy for inflation expectations.

Page 100: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

100

CHAPTER 5

Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using Survey Measures of Inflation

Expectations

5.1 Introduction

The purpose of this chapter is to estimate various specifications of the Phillips curve

using survey measures of inflation expectations as proxy for inflation expectations and to

examine whether job finding probability (JFP), the output gap or labour’s share of income is

a better proxy for real marginal cost. We found that the output gap and job finding probability

performed equally well when the old Keynesian Phillips curve is estimated. Labour’s share of

income is the best proxy for real marginal cost when the new Keynesian Phillips curve is

estimated. Job finding probability is marginally a better proxy for real marginal cost than the

output gap and labour’s share of income when the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve is

estimated. We also found that backward-looking dominate forward-looking inflation

expectations, independent of which measures of real marginal cost are used and that all of the

survey measures of inflation expectations are biased and inefficient. This chapter is structured

as follows: The first section examines the rationality various survey measures of inflation

expectations. The second section compares the empirical appropriateness of job finding

probability (JFP), the output gap and labour’s share of income as proxies for real marginal

cost. The third section considers two robustness exercises: The first robustness exercise

examines sub-sample stability. The second robustness exercise uses the implicit price deflator

(nonfarm business) instead of core inflation to examine if our initial results are robust. The

fourth section concludes.

5.2 Are Survey Measures of Inflation Expectations Rational?

Since the advent of rational expectations, researchers in monetary policy have

understood that the key to understanding how monetary policy works is to understand how

economic agents form inflation expectations. Furthermore, "[t]here is a growing consensus,

based on both historical analysis and econometric evidence, that monetary policy has strong

effects on real output. There is not, however any consensus about how to explain this fact"

(Ball and Croushore, 2003, p.473).

Page 101: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

101

A useful way of testing the rational expectations hypothesis is by directly testing

whether inflation forecasts are rational. Rational expectations predicts that inflation forecasts

should be unbiased, that is, the forecast errors should be zero over time (i.e. no systemic

errors) and inflation forecasts should be efficient, that is, forecasters should use all relevant

information at the time in forming their expectations. In his famous seminal paper on rational

expectations, Muth (1961, p. 316) notes two stylized facts about survey data on expectations.

“Averages of expectations in an industry are more accurate than naive [adaptive]

models and as accurate as elaborate equation system, although there are considerable

cross-sectional differences in opinion.

Reported expectations generally underestimated the extent of changes that actually

take place.”

Muth (1961, p.316) suggested that since expectations are informed predictions of

future events, they “are essentially the same as the predictions of the relevant economic

theory”. For Muth, the assumption that expectations were formed rationally was a natural

extension of the assumptions that firms rationally maximize profits and consumers rationally

maximize their utilities. Rational expectations implies that expectations are rational, in the

sense that they efficiently incorporate all information available at time the expectations are

taken, and not just the past information as implied by adaptive expectations, a popular way of

modelling expectations at the time. Furthermore, Muth thought that rational expectations was

more appealing than alternative theories of how economic agents form expectations was more

realistic, can be applied to all dynamics problems, can be tested and be compared to

alternative theories (Muth, 1961, p.330):

“From a purely theoretical standpoint, there are good reasons for assuming rationality.

First, it is a principle applicable to all dynamic problems (if true). Expectations in

different markets and systems would not have to be treated in completely different

ways. Second, if expectations were not moderately rational there would be

opportunities for economists to make profits in commodity speculation, running a

firm, or selling the information to present owners. Third, rationality is an assumption

that can be modified. Systematic biases, incomplete or incorrect information, poor

memory, etc., can be examined with analytical methods based on rationality. The only

Page 102: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

102

real test, however, is whether theories involving rationality explain observed

phenomena any better than alternative theories”.

Muth (1961, p.333) also noted that regression analysis can be used to test the

assumption of rational expectations. “The rational expectation hypothesis states that, in the

aggregate, the expected price is an unbiased predictor of the actual price”.

There is a relatively large literature on survey measures of inflation expectations; a

common conclusion from this literature is that survey measures of inflation expectations are

more accurate than adaptive expectations models, which confirms one of Muth’s (1961)

empirical findings mentioned above. However, most papers that have examined the

rationality of survey measures of inflation expectations have also concluded that inflation

expectations are not perfectly rational, in particular, they seems to indicate survey

participants do not use all relevant information available to them when forecasting inflation

(Roberts, 1997 p. 177). This suggests that we should consider bounded rational expectations

instead of adaptive expectations or pure rational expectations in modelling inflation

expectations.

The use of survey measures of inflation expectations provide data on an otherwise

unobservable variable and also to allow economic researchers to avoid making “strong”

assumptions about human rationality, by letting the data speak instead. The use of survey

measures of inflation expectations have their limitations, two of the main potential problems

are: survey participants may not be representative of the actual population and as there is no

monetary incentive for the survey participants to invest their time and efforts in formulating

their best expectations, the survey results may be poor proxies for the actual expectations of

the population (Roberts, 1995, p. 980). However, the problems with using econometric

forecasts of inflation as a proxy for inflation expectations is that we are implicitly assuming

inflation expectations are rational. If inflation expectations are not fully rational, then using

econometric forecasts of inflation as a proxy for inflation expectations may be less precise

than using survey measures of inflation expectations. Ang, Bekaert and Wei (2007, p. 1163)

examine the predictive power of four alternative methods of forecasting U.S. inflation out-of-

sample: time-series ARIMA models; regressions using real activity measures motivated from

the Phillips curve; term structure models that include linear, non-linear, and arbitrage-free

Page 103: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

103

specifications; and survey measures of inflation expectations. They found that survey

measures of inflation expectations are more accurate than other forecasting methods.

5.3 Data and Estimation Strategy

The definitions and sources of the data used in this chapter are presented in the data

appendix at the end of this chapter; all series are quarterly data for the United States. We use

core CPI as our measure of inflation because it is less volatile than other measures of

inflation, since it excludes food and energy. We will examine three well-known surveys of

inflation expectations: the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF), which collects inflation

expectations from economists who forecast for a living, the Michigan Survey, which collects

forecasts from consumers and the “Greenbook” forecasts, which are produced by the research

staff at the Board of Governors before each meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee

(FOMC).

�he ��r�e� o� Pro�essio�al �orecasters ��P��

The Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) came into existence in the fourth

quarter of 1968 under the management of the American Statistical Association and the

National Bureau of Economic Research, it was known as the ASA/NBER Economic Outlook

Survey. In the first survey participants were asked to forecast 10 variables for the next five

quarters. Among the variables to be forecast each quarter was the rate of change of the GNP

deflator for the current quarter and the next four quarters. Consumer Price Index inflation

forecast were not initiated until the third quarters of 1981. The forecasters in the survey come

predominantly from the business sector, where they make economic forecasts for a living. In

addition to submitting forecasts of inflation, the participants are also asked to assign

probabilities to various inflationary scenarios. This provides researchers an alternative

measure of inflation uncertainty other than the variance of inflation expectations. The

Philadelphia Federal Reserve is currently in charge of this survey, the data is publicly

available at the Philadelphia Federal Reserve’s website (www.phil.frb.org/research-and-

data/real-time-center/survey-of-professional-forecasters/). See Thomas (1999, p.129-130) and

Croushore (1997) for more details. The SPF data provide quarterly forecasts of inflation

expectations for the next four quarters, which we can use to test our model, we will use the

median values instead of the mean values because outliers can sometimes distort the mean

values for estimating various specifications of the Phillips curve. However, for testing the

Page 104: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

104

rationality of survey measures of inflation expectations we will use the mean values instead

of the median values because it allows us to make direct comparison with the mean values of

the Michigan survey.

�he ��stit�te o� �ocial �esearch ��ichiga�� ��r�e� o� �o�seholds

The Survey Research Center at the University of Michigan started collecting forecasts

of numerous macroeconomic variables, including the inflation rate over the next year in terms

of the “things you buy” via the telephone interview in 1948. The respondents are randomly

selected from a sample size of a minimum of 500 households. Prior to the second quarter of

1966, respondents were simply asked: “Do you think prices will go up in the next year, or go

down, or stay the same?” From the second quarter of 1966 through the third quarter of 1977,

respondents who indicated they expected prices to increase were asked to indicate a range in

which they expected prices to rise. After the third quarter of 1977, respondents were simply

asked to supply their expected rate of inflation. Another important change is the frequency of

the survey, before 1959, the Michigan Survey was conducted 2-3 times annually. From 1959

through the end of 1977, the survey was conducted quarterly. Since the beginning of 1978, it

has been conducted monthly. The historical series for the mean CPI inflation forecasts and its

variance are publicly available through the website of the Institute of Social Research’s

Survey of Consumer Attitudes at (www.sca.isr.umich.edu).

�he �ree�boo� �orecasts

The Federal Reserve forecasts are contained in the "Green Book" prepared by the staff

of the Board of Governors before each meeting of the Federal Open Market Committee

(FOMC).The data set includes the projections of real output growth and inflation. These

projections are made available to the public after a lag of five years. The historical series for

real output growth and inflation are publicly available through the website of the Philadelphia

Fed's (www.philadelphiafed.org/research-and-data/real-time-center/greenbook-data/) (See

Romer and Romer (2000, p. 431)).

Our estimation strategy is to estimate various specifications of the Phillips curve using survey

measures of inflation expectations as proxy for expected inflation and to compare the

empirical results of using the output gap, labour’s share of income and job finding probability

Page 105: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

105

as proxy for real marginal cost. We will also examine the relative importance of forward-

looking and backward-looking inflation expectations.

5.4 Tests of Rationality of Survey Measures of Inflation Expectations

For inflation expectations to be rational they should exhibit two main predictions of

rational expectations. First, they should be unbiased, that is survey participants should

forecast inflation correctly on average. Second, inflation expectations should be efficient, that

is survey participants should use all relevant information available to them when forecasting

inflation. We have also included an adaptive model as a simple test of the rationality various

surveys. The adaptive forecast is simply the most recent 12-month rate of core CPI inflation

known to the agent at the time the forecast is made. The adaptive forecast is purely

backward-looking. A failure of survey respondents to outperform the adaptive forecasts

would suggest that they fail to effectively take into account the past rate of actual inflation in

their forecast future inflation.

We first report various forecasting evaluation statistics and briefly compare the

performances of various survey measures of inflation expectations. The summary statistics

include the mean absolute error (MAE), the root mean squared error (RMSE) and Theil

Inequality Coefficient (U). The forecast error for any period is defined as the forecast

inflation rate minus the actual inflation rate. Thus, a positive mean error indicates that agents,

on average, overestimate inflation. A negative mean error indicates a propensity to

underestimate inflation. The mean absolute error (MAE) is a measure of accuracy of

forecasts. The root mean square error (RMSE) is an alternative measure of accuracy. The

RMSE has the effect of magnifying the effect of large forecast errors, as opposed to the MAE

(Thomas, 1999, p.132). Theil Inequality Coefficient (U) provides a measure of how well a

time series of estimated values compares to a corresponding time series of observed values.

The Theil inequality coefficient always lies between zero and one, where zero indicates a

perfect fit. The MAE, the RMSE and Theil Inequality Coefficient (U) are given by:

1

1 �

tt

�AE e�

(5.1)

Page 106: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

106

1/22

1

1 �

tt

���E e�

(5.2)

1

22

1/2 1/22 2

1 1

1

/ /

t t

� �

t tt t

� ��

� � � �

(5.3)

Table 5.1 Inflation Forecasts Evaluation Statistics for the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF),

Michigan, and the Greenbook Forecasts.

Survey Sample Period MAE RMSE U

Michigan 4t tE 1981Q3 2004Q4 0.005894 0.007655 0.097822

SPF 4t tE 1981Q3 2004Q4 0.004463 0.006044 0.086748

Greenbook 4t tE 1981Q3 2004Q4 0.004707 0.006571 0.083753

Adaptive 4t tE 1981Q3 2004Q4 0.007653 0.009892 0.128964

In terms of accuracy, if one uses the RMSE (or the MAE) as the criterion for evaluate

the surveys’ results, the rankings from best to worst are: SFP, Greenbook, Michigan and

Adaptive. If one uses Theil Inequality Coefficient (U), the rankings from best to worst are:

Greenbook, SFP, Michigan and Adaptive. All survey measures of inflation expectations are

more accurate than the adaptive expectations model, this result is consistent with Muth’s

(1961, p. 316) empirical finding and other previous research.

�ests �or the E�iste�ce o� As�mmetric ���ormatio�

Are economists better at forecasting inflation than the general public? To answer this

question, we run the following “horserace” regressions to test for the forecasting power of the

Michigan, the Survey of Professional Forecasters and the Greenbook forecasts using Romer

and Romer’s (2000) framework.

Page 107: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

107

Table 5.2: Tests for the Existence of Asymmetric Information Between the Michigan, SPF and The Greenbook

Forecasts

, 4 1 2 , 4 3 , 4 4 , 4General Equation :t t t t t t t t

�� �P� �ich

Equation

1

2

3

4

2�

1

0.007789 0.002722

2.861425 0.005300

0.005888 0.001296 4.544154 0.000000

0.002202 0.001618 1.360916 0.177100

-5.14E-05 0.001308 -0.039271 0.968800

0.768795

2

0.002693 0.002746 0.980552 0.329500

0.007492 0.001244 6.022518

0.000000

0.000622 0.001439 0.432032

0.666800

0.713280

3

0.007722 0.002125

3.634131 0.000500

0.005882 0.001280 4.595538

0.000000

0.002168 0.001355 1.600341 0.113100

0.768790

4

0.000340 0.002488 0.136613 0.891600

0.006761 0.001031 6.554926 0.000000

0.003228 0.001163 2.775185 0.006700

0.856206

Notes: t is the actual inflation rate at time t. , 4t t�ich is the period-t mean of the Michigan survey measure of

household expectations for inflation over the next year. , 4t t�P� is the period-t mean of the Survey of

Professional Forecasters’ forecasts of the inflation rate over the next year. , 4t t

�� is the Greenbook forecast of

the inflation rate over the next year. All equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1981q3 to 2004q4 period.

Our results show that the Greenbook forecasts of inflation has more predictive power

than the SPF forecasts and the Michigan forecasts; this is consistent with Romer and Romer

(2000) empirical finding. Both the Greenbook forecasts and the SPF forecasts have more

predictive power than the Michigan forecasts, providing support for the hypothesis that

economists are better at forecasting inflation than the general public. Note that the first

regression’s results indicate that the Michigan forecasts contain no information that is not

also included in the Greenbook forecasts and the SPF forecasts; this is consistent with

Carroll’s (2003) empirical finding. The results also implies that Michigan forecasts and the

SPF forecasts are prima facie irrational since the information that forecasters of the

Greenbook forecasts possessed that allowed them to make superior forecasts were in

principle also available to households and forecasters of the SPF. The findings that the

Page 108: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

108

Greenbook forecasts of inflation have more predictive power than the SPF forecasts and the

Michigan forecasts do not imply that the Greenbook forecasts are fully rational.

�ests �or ��biased�ess

The test for unbiasedness is usually conducted by running the following regression:

t t te (5.4)

where t is the actual inflation rate at time t, �

t is the inflation expectations from the survey

at time t and te is the error term. Inflation expectations are unbiased if =0 and = 1.Note

that inflation rates were converted to percentages.

Table 5.3 Tests for Unbiasedness of the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF), Michigan, and the Greenbook

forecasts.

Equation Estimated �

t t te

Survey Sample Period 2� 2

o�or�

SPF 1t tE 981Q3 2010Q1

-0.286400

0.146800 -1.950993 0.053600

1.103100

0.042800 25.793870 0.000000

0.855916 6.534639

(0.03810)

Greenbook 1t tE 1974Q2 2004Q4

0.435100 0.127700 3.406809 0.000900

1.055800 0.027000

39.129390 0.000000

0.926760

104.271400 ( 0.00000)

Michigan 4t tE 1981Q3 2010Q1

-0.886700

0.277200 -3.198671 0.001800

0.986400

0.061900 15.922160 0.000000

0.691691 125.953800

(0.00000)

SPF 4t tE 1981Q3 2010Q1

0.306300 0.164400 1.862752 0.065200

0.805300 0.044800

17.988780 0.000000

0.748033 65.224080 (0.00000)

Greenbook 4t tE 1974Q3 2004Q4

0.117100

0.205000 0.571358 0.568800

1.150800

0.046000 25.043340 0.000000

0.840519 64.676310

(0.00000)

Note: The above equations were estimated using Ordinary Least Square (OLS). Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row. Chi-squared statistics of null

hypothesis that 0 1a�d and its p-values (in parentheses) are shown in the last column.

Page 109: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

109

The results for each forecast are presented in the table above, along with the

coefficient of determination ( 2� ), and the chi-square statistics associated with the null

hypothesis of unbiasedness ( 0 1a�d ). The chi-square statistic indicates that

unbiasedness can be rejected at 5 % level for all of the forecasts.

�ests �or E��icie�c�

The tests for efficiency determine whether forecasters use all of the information

available to them when making inflation forecasts, the tests for efficiency are usually

conducted by regressing the forecast error ( te ) on the variables in the information set ( t�),

either individually or jointly.

t t te � � (5.5)

where te is the forecast error, t�is the information set and t�is the disturbance term. Inflation

expectations are said to be efficient if the forecast error is uncorrelated with the forecast error,

implying that the coefficient should equal zero.

A distinction is commonly made between weak-form and strong-form efficiency.

Weak-form efficiency implies that forecasters have adequately considered all the information

contained in past rates of inflation. Strong-form efficiency implies that forecasters use the

most up-to-date information when making inflation forecasts (Thomas, 1999, p.136). We will

conduct a series of weak-form efficiency tests; our information set consists of one lag of each

of the following variables: inflation ( 1t ), unemployment ( 1t� ), wage inflation ( 1t��� ),

the output gap ( 1t�AP ), monetary aggregate ( 12t� ), and the federal funds rate ( 1t�� ),

these variables were chosen because we thought that they would be useful in forecasting

inflation. Below are the results for the tests of efficiency for the Survey of Professional

Forecasters (SPF), Michigan, and the Greenbook forecasts.

Page 110: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

110

Table 5.4 Tests of Efficiency of the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) Forecasts 1t tE

Equation Estimated t t te � �

Independent

Variable t-statistic P-value

t-statistic

P-value 2�

1t -0.004085 -3.639949 0.0004 0.122446 4.040799 0.0001 0.127237

1t� -0.003507 -1.675827 0.0966 0.000572 1.728953 0.0866 0.025996

1t��� -0.001146 -1.891848 0.0611 0.104011 3.319114 0.0012 0.089553

1t�AP -4.04E-05 -0.077857 0.9381 -0.000527 -1.336743 0.1840 0.015704

12t� -0.001486 -0.981666 0.3284 0.000452 1.044991 0.2983 0.009656

1t�� -0.001505 -1.457455 0.1478 0.000270 1.681775 0.0954 0.024631

Note: The above equations were estimated using Ordinary Least Square (OLS) over the 1981q3- 2010q1 period.

Table 5.5 Tests of Efficiency of the Greenbook Forecasts 1t tE

Equation Estimated t t te � �

Independent

Variable t-statistic P-value

t-statistic

P-value 2�

1t -0.002953 -2.25761 0.0258 0.062332 2.593196 0.0107 0.052650

1t� 0.001024 0.338315 0.7357 -0.000161 -0.346670 0.7294 0.000992

1t��� -0.000104 -0.128460 0.8980 0.009746 0.224076 0.8231 0.000415

1t�AP 3.41E-05 0.051457 0.9590 0.000353 0.559947 0.5766 0.002585

22t� 0.000499 0.291010 0.7717 -0.000224 -0.486099 0.6281 0.002590

1t�� -0.001878 -1.320126 0.1893 0.000274 1.487138 0.1396 0.017949

Note: The above equations were estimated using Ordinary Least Square (OLS) over the 1974q2- 2004q4 period.

Page 111: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

111

Table 5.6 Tests of Efficiency of the Michigan Forecasts 4t tE

Equation Estimated t t te � �

Independent

Variable t-statistic P-value

t-statistic

P-value 2�

1t -0.008282 -4.939615 0.0000 0.244630 5.518118 0.0000 0.212267

1t� 0.001275 0.371605 0.7109 -0.000208 -0.383310 0.7022 0.001299

1t��� 0.000176 0.171661 0.8640 -0.016053 -0.302053 0.7632 0.000807

1t�AP 0.000145 0.179034 0.8582 0.001943 3.141920 0.0021 0.0021

22t� -0.010730 -5.001132 0.0000 0.003194 5.215018 0.0000 0.195382

1t�� -0.006621 -4.491612 0.0000 0.001167 5.231059 0.0000 0.194950

Note: The above equations were estimated using Ordinary Least Square (OLS) over the 1981q3- 2010q1 period.

Table 5.7 Tests of Efficiency of the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) Forecasts 4t tE

Equation Estimated t t te � �

Independent Variable

t-statistic P-value

t-statistic

P-value 2

1t -0.005419 -3.869040 0.0002 0.171365 4.146658 0.0001 0.136256

1t� 0.005859 2.747850 0.0070 -0.000964 -2.834523 0.0055 0.068651

1t��� 0.000335 0.507258 0.6130 -0.029821 -0.884268 0.3785 0.007123

1t�AP 0.000103 0.208985 0.8349 0.001789 4.774618 0.0000 0.172970

22t� -0.005153 -3.016292 0.0032 0.001619 3.165806 0.0020 0.084205

1t�� -0.002641 -2.355927 0.0203 0.000497 2.666986 0.0088 0.061258

Note: The above equations were estimated using Ordinary Least Square (OLS) over the 1981q3- 2010q1 period.

Page 112: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

112

The results of the weak-form tests for efficiency presented in the five tables above

indicate that some of the survey respondents of all of the forecasts failed to take into account

all of the information available to them when making inflation forecasts. All of the forecasts

have at least one of the variables in the informational set significantly (5% level) correlated

with the forecast errors.

Another useful way of testing whether past inflationary information are useful in

determining the current rate of inflation can be econometrically tested by implementing a

Granger causality test between the actual inflation rate t and the survey measures of inflation

expectations for over the next year, 4t t�ich . For example, the Michigan survey asks survey

respondents: “During the next 12 months, do you think that prices in general will go up, or go

down, or stay where they are now?” The pure rational expectations model predicts that the

Michigan survey measure of households’ expectations for inflation over the next year should

Granger-cause the actual inflation rate because future expectations matter. However, the pure

rational expectations model also predicts the past actual inflation rates should not Granger-

Table 5.8 Tests of Efficiency of the Greenbook Forecasts 4t tE

Equation Estimated t t te � �

Independent

Variable t-statistic P-value

t-statistic

P-value 2�

1t -0.005188 -2.746995 0.0069 0.110702 3.155469 0.0020 0.077212

1t� 0.012422 2.914982 0.0043 -0.001949 -2.987471 0.0034 0.069767

1t��� 0.001683 1.437479 0.1532 -0.152797 -2.430521 0.0166 0.047295

1t�AP 0.000220 0.232157 0.8168 0.002266 2.526663 0.0128 0.050916

22t

� 0.004850 2.201318 0.0302 -0.001992 -3.363245 0.0011 0.110559

1t�� -0.001572 -0.756678 0.4507 0.000231 0.854260 0.3947 0.006095

Note: The above equations were estimated using Ordinary Least Square (OLS) over the 1974q2- 2004q4 period.

Page 113: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

113

cause future inflation expectations because only significantly new information moves

markets, not something that people know already.

Table 5.9 Granger Causality Tests Between Actual Inflation Rates and the Michigan, Survey of

Professional Forecasters and Greenbook Forecasts

Null Hypothesis: F-value P-value

t does not Granger Cause, 4t t�ich 2.18718 0.0772

, 4t t�ich does not Granger Cause t

6.94944 7.E-05

t does not Granger Cause, 4t t�P� 3.77585 0.0072

, 4t t�P� does not Granger Cause t 11.4558 2.E-07

t does not Granger Cause, 4t t�� 5.96114 0.0003

, 4t t�� does not Granger Cause t 8.96415 4.E-06

Notes: t is the actual inflation rate at time t.

, 4t t�ich is the period-t mean of the Michigan survey

measure of household expectations for inflation over the next year. , 4t t�P� is the period-t mean of the

Survey of Professional Forecasters forecasts of the inflation rate over the next year. , 4t t�� is the

Greenbook forecasts of the inflation rate over the next year. All Granger causality tests were conducted over the 1981q3 to 2004q4 period with 4 lags.

The results of these Granger causality tests suggests that some of the survey

respondents in the Michigan survey, the Survey of Professional Forecasters and the

Greenbook forecasts formulate their inflation expectations by taking into account past actual

inflation rates. This also provides statistical evidence that survey measures of inflation

expectations are not perfectly rational.

Finally we test if households minimize their forecast errors by listening professional

forecasters’ forecasts of inflation; we have implemented Granger causality tests between the

Michigan forecasts, the SPF forecasts and the Greenbook forecasts. Rational expectations

predicts that economic agents form their own expectations. However, bounded rational

expectations predicts that the professional forecasts should Granger-cause the household

forecasts but there should be no Granger causality in the opposite direction, because

households minimize their forecast errors by listening professional forecasters’ forecasts of

inflation, The results of our Granger causality tests below confirm that there are Granger

causalities from the professional forecasts (as represented by the SPF forecasts)to household

Page 114: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

114

forecasts (as represented by the Michigan forecasts), but no Granger causality in the opposite

direction. This is consistent with Carroll’s (2003, p.282) empirical finding. Our results below

show that the Greenbook forecasts do not Granger-cause the Michigan forecasts, but the

Michigan forecasts Granger-cause the Greenbook forecasts, this could be because the

Greenbook forecasts are only made available to the public after a lag of five years.

Table 5.10 Granger Causality Tests Between the Michigan, Survey of Professional Forecasters and

Greenbook Forecasts

Null Hypothesis: F-value P-value

, 4t t�� does not Granger Cause

, 4t t�ich 1.28381 0.2644

, 4t t�ich does not Granger Cause

, 4t t�� 3.65798 0.0012

, 4t t�P� does not Granger Cause

, 4t t�ich 2.24814 0.0339

, 4t t�ich does not Granger Cause

, 4t t�P� 1.63175 0.1318

, 4t t�P� does not Granger Cause

, 4t t�� 4.32158 0.0003

, 4t t�� does not Granger Cause

, 4t t�P� 2.05337 0.0526

Notes:, 4t t

�ich is the period-t mean of the Michigan survey measure of household expectations for

inflation over the next year. , 4t t�P� is the period-t mean of the Survey of Professional Forecasters

forecasts of the inflation rate over the next year. , 4t t�� is the Greenbook forecasts of the inflation rate

over the next year. All Granger causality tests were conducted over the 1981q3 to 2004q4 period with 8

lags.

5.5 Empirical Comparisons Between Job Finding Probability, the Output Gap and

Labour’s Share of Income as Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

We estimated different Phillips Curve specifications (old Keynesian Phillips curve,

new Keynesian Phillips curve, and hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve ) with three different

proxies for real marginal cost (job finding probability, the output gap and labour’s share of

income). We used the results of the old Keynesian Phillips curve, with adaptive expectations

as our benchmark, since rational expectations predicts that modelling the Phillips curve with

rational expectations should fit the data better than modelling the Phillips curve with adaptive

expectations. Rational expectations implies that inflation expectations are rational, in the

sense that they efficiently incorporate all information available at time the expectations are

taken, and not just the past information as implied by adaptive expectations. The results of

these estimations are presented in the appendix of this chapter.

Page 115: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

115

We found that the output gap and job finding probability performed equally well

when the old Keynesian Phillips curve is estimated. Labour’s share of income is the best

proxy for real marginal cost when the new Keynesian Phillips curve is estimated. Job finding

probability is marginally a better proxy for real marginal cost than the output gap and

labour’s share of income when the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve is estimated. In

general, when the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve is estimated with job finding

probability as the proxy for real marginal cost, the 2

� values are marginally higher, the

coefficients of job finding probability tend to have the right sign and are statistically

significant.

5.6 Robustness Analysis

We consider two robustness exercises. The first robustness exercise examines sub-

sample stability, our first sub-sample is the period from 1974q1 to 1982q4; this period was

chosen because of the high level of inflation the US economy experienced. Our second sub-

sample is the period from 1987q1 to 2006q4, this sub-sample period is also referred to as the

Great Moderation; this period was chosen because of the lower level of inflation and lower

economic volatility the US economy experienced. Our objective is to examine if the results of

our estimations are robust during a period of higher inflation and higher economic volatility

and a period of lower inflation and lower economic volatility. Since the SPF forecasts are not

available before 1981q3, we will not examine the SPF forecasts in this robustness exercise.

Also, due to the Greenbook forecasts only available up to 2004q4 for the second sub-sample

period, we can only examine the Greenbook forecasts from 1987q1 2004q4.We will also

examine the relative importance of forward-looking and backward-looking inflation

expectations during the two sub-sample periods. The second robustness exercise examines an

alternative measurement of inflation; we will use the implicit price deflator (nonfarm

business) instead of core inflation to examine if our results are robust. The results of these

robustness exercises are presented in the appendix of this chapter.

We found that the job finding probability is clearly the best proxy for real marginal

cost in the first sub-sample period (1974q1 - 1982q4); which is characterized by higher level

of inflation and economic volatility, the reason why job finding probability is better than the

output gap and labour’s share of income as proxy for real marginal cost in the first sub-

sample period is not clear and warrants further investigation. The results of the second sub-

Page 116: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

116

sample period (1987q1 - 2006q4) are broadly consistent with the results of the full sample,

but, with higher 2

� values, indicating that these models fit the data better. This is as expected

since the lower economic volatility make forecasting inflation easier, at the same time, it

makes lagged inflation more reliable, since the rates of inflation do not change much quarter

to quarter. The results of our second robustness exercise are consistence with our initial

results.

With respect to the relative importance of forward-looking and backward-looking

inflation expectations, our results indicate that the backward-looking inflation expectations

dominate forward-looking inflation expectations. Note that weights of forward-looking and

backward-looking inflation expectations are similar independent of which measures of real

marginal cost are used. Our results indicate the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive

expectations fits the data better than the new Keynesian Phillips curve with rational

expectations and when the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curves are estimated, the

coefficients of backward-looking inflation expectations dominate the coefficients forward-

looking inflation expectations, these results are independent of which measures of real

marginal cost are used. Note that the SPF forecasts and the Greenbook forecasts are produced

by professional economists, they have been shown to be more accurate and more “rational”

than the Michigan forecasts, which is produced by non professional economists. The

coefficients of the backward-looking inflation expectations terms of the hybrid new

Keynesian Phillips curve when the Michigan forecasts are used as proxy for expected

inflation expectations, the coefficients of the backward-looking inflation expectations term

tend to be larger, suggesting that survey respondents in the Michigan forecasts are more

backward-looking (or less forward-looking).

5.7 Conclusion

We began this chapter by comparing the predictive power of the three survey

measures of inflation expectations, our results indicate that the Greenbook forecasts has more

predictive power than the SPF forecasts and the Michigan forecasts; this is consistent with

Romer and Romer (2000) empirical finding. We then test the rationality of these survey

measures of inflation expectations; our results indicate that all of the survey measures of

inflation expectations are biased and inefficient. We have also showed that there are Granger

causalities from the professional forecasters (as represented by the SPF forecasts) to

Page 117: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

117

households (as represented by the Michigan forecasts), but no Granger causality in the

opposite direction. Many empirical studies that have examined the rationality of survey

measures of inflation expectations have also concluded that inflation expectations are not

perfectly rational (Bryan and Gavin, 1986). Croushore (1998) shows that some of the

empirical work in the 1980’s that concluded that survey measures of inflation expectations

were not rational, were later found to be better when the sample periods were updated to

include more recent data . “However, there remain some problems in the forecasts. It appears

to be possible to improve inflation forecasts over some sample periods using bias regressions,

and the forecasts don’t pass all tests for optimality” Croushore (1998, p.2). Roberts (1997 p.

177) found that survey participants do not use all relevant information available to them when

forecasting inflation.

The main purpose of this chapter is to estimate various specifications of the Phillips

curve using survey measures of inflation expectations as proxy for inflation expectations and

to examine whether job finding probability (JFP), the output gap or labour’s share of income

is a better proxy for real marginal cost. In general, we found that the output gap and job

finding probability performed equally well when the old Keynesian Phillips curve is

estimated. Labour’s share of income is the best proxy for real marginal cost when the new

Keynesian Phillips curve is estimated. Job finding probability is marginally a better proxy for

real marginal cost than the output gap and labour’s share of income when the hybrid new

Keynesian Phillips curve is estimated. We also found that the old Keynesian Phillips curve

with adaptive expectations fits the data better than the new Keynesian Phillips curve with

rational expectations. Overall our results suggest the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve fits

the data best.

The finding that the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive expectations fits the

data much better than the new Keynesian Phillips curve when estimated with survey

measures of inflation expectations as proxy for inflation expectations suggests that lagged

inflation plays an important role in inflation dynamics beyond that could be explained by less

than fully rational survey measures of inflation expectations. This result is consistent with

Adam and Padula (2003, p.2) empirical finding that estimating the new Keynesian Phillips

curve with survey based data fit the data well but lagged inflation “enters the price equation

significantly suggesting that there is a role for lagged inflation beyond that of capturing non-

rationalities in expectations”. Rudd and Whelan (2006, p.318) argue that “the observation

Page 118: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

118

that lagged inflation plays an important role in empirical inflation regressions poses a major

challenge to the rational expectations sticky price models that underpin the new Keynesian

Phillips curve. Indeed, it has now become relatively well accepted that purely forward-

looking models of inflation cannot account for the degree of inflation inertia that we actually

observe in the data, and that this failure significantly reduces these models' usefulness in

assessing practical policy questions”.

Our results also suggest that the pure rational expectations new Keynesian Phillips

curve might be misspecified. Even if we accept the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve as

having the right specifications for the Phillips curve relationship, our results suggest that

backward inflation expectations strongly dominate forward-looking inflation expectations.

Furthermore, we need to be able to explain why are some price setters backward-looking and

why are some price setters forward-looking and also are the fractions of backward-looking

agents and the fractions forward-looking agents constant over time? Recall that bounded

rationality implies that the best way for non-economists to minimize their forecast errors is to

listen to the advices of professional economists as the costs of acquiring this professional

knowledge can be very high. This proposition is supported by Carroll’s (2003) empirical

findings that professional economists are better at forecasting inflation than the general

public. In addition, he finds that the general public’s inflation expectations respond to the

professional economists’ expectations with a lag. The way that professional economists help

the general public to overcome their lack of inflation knowledge is by giving their

professional advices via the mass media, economic education and private consulting. In real

life this is what financial and economic advisors do; they examine their clients’ economic

situations and give them the economic implications of the policy change regarding their

economic situations. Since the general public’s inflation expectations respond to the

professional economists’ expectations with time lag, lagged inflation rates are correlated with

the current inflation rates. In short, bounded rationality explains why lagged inflation plays

an important role in empirical inflation regressions as the dissemination of economic

information and knowledge between professional economists and non-economists involves

time lags, since the general public’s inflation expectations respond to the professional

economists’ expectations with time lags, lagged inflation rates are correlated with the current

inflation rate.

Page 119: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

119

With respect to whether the fractions of backward-looking agents and the fractions

forward-looking agents are constant over time, our results indicate that during a period of

lower inflation and lower economic volatility (The Great Moderation), backward-looking

inflation expectations are more significant, this implies that the fractions of backward-looking

agents and the fractions forward-looking agents are not constant over time.

Page 120: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

120

5.8 Appendix to Chapter 5 Empirical �es�lts o� �ompariso�s �etwee� �ob �i�di�g Probabilit�� the ��tp�t �ap a�d

�abo�r�s �hare o� ��come as Pro�� �or �eal �argi�al �ost

The tables 5.11 through to 5.22 below present the results of estimations of different

Phillips curve specifications with three different proxies for real marginal cost.

Table 5.11 Estimations (OLS) of the Old Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t b tmc

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

2

Job Finding Probability

-0.90021 0.3571 -2.521

0.013

1.6695 0.5982 2.791

0.006

0.90884 0.03133 29.010

0.000

0.9493

Output Gap

0.13540 0.7682E-01

1.763 0.081

0.10751 0.5042E-01

2.132 0.035

0.94287000 0.2487E-01

37.910 0.000

0.9516

Labour’s Share of Income

-2.4288 8.051

-0.3017 0.763

0.57051 1.762

0.3238 0.747

0.92336000 0.3419E-01

27.000 0.000

0.9441

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1981q3 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive expectations produces relatively high

2

� values for the three proxies of real marginal cost. The coefficients of job finding

probability and the output gap are statistically significant at 5%.

Page 121: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

121

Table 5.12Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the SPF Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation

Expectations

Equation estimated 1t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

-0.18072 0.6958

-0.2597 0.796

-0.50394 0.1109

-0.4542 0.651

1.1912 0.1356 8.788 0.000

0.8405

Output Gap

-0.53713 0.3300 -1.628 0.106

-0.16185 0.4468E-01

-3.623 0.000

1.1907 0.1066 11.17 0.000

0.8575

Labour’s Share of Income

-24.172 16.61

-1.455 0.148

5.2070 3.654 1.425 0.157

1.1046 0.1546 7.143 0.000

0.8450

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1981q3 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the SPF over the next quarter

forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produce lower 2

� values for the three proxies of

real marginal costs than the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive expectations; this is

contrary to the prediction of rational expectations. The coefficients of the job finding

probability and the output gap have the wrong signs.

Page 122: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

122

Table 5.13Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the SPF Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation

Expectations

Equation estimated 4t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

-1.3640 0.7104 -1.920 0.057

0.98699 1.088

0.9071 0.366

1.1695 0.1298 9.010 0.000

0.8656

Output Gap

-0.75166 0.3552 -2.116 0.037

-0.14329E-01 0.4579E-01

-0.3129 0.755

1.1875 0.1171 10.14 0.000

0.8640

Labour’s Share of Income

-8.2423 14.73

-0.5597 0.577

1.6482 3.266

0.5047 0.615

1.1637 0.1453 8.011 0.000

0.8643

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1981q3 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the SPF over the next year forecasts

as proxy for inflation expectations produce lower 2

� values for the three proxies of real

marginal costs than the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive expectations; this is

contrary to the prediction of rational expectations. The coefficient of the output gap has the

wrong sign.

Page 123: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

123

Table 5.14Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the SPF Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 1t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-0.67370 0.3829

-1.760 0.081

0.86478 0.5801

1.491 0.139

0.72404 0.5715E-01

12.67 0.000

0.29425 0.8741E-01

3.366 0.001

0.9588

Output Gap

-0.11756 0.1125 -1.045 0.298

0.51032E-01 0.4347E-01

1.174 0.243

0.75328 0.4549E-01

16.56 0.000

0.27584 0.7083E-01

3.894 0.000

0.9589

Labour’s Share of Income

4.3829 8.444

0.5190 0.605

-0.99645 1.873

-0.5321 0.596

0.71864 0.5205E-01

13.81 0.000

0.33511 0.9408E-01

3.562 0.001

0.9577

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1981q3 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the SPF over the next

quarter forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the old

Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs; all coefficients of

backward-looking and forward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically

significant at 1% level. The coefficient of labour’s share of income has the wrong sign.

Page 124: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

124

Table 5.15 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the SPF Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-0.97281 0.4157

-2.340 0.021

1.3213 0.6217

2.125 0.036

0.72687 0.4346E-01

16.73 0.000

0.27049 0.6044E-01

4.475 0.000

0.9557

Output Gap

-0.13674 0.1093 -1.251 0.213

0.86312E-01 0.4338E-01

1.990 0.049

0.76456 0.4074E-01

18.77 0.000

0.25507 0.5391E-01

4.732 0.000

0.9572

Labour’s Share of Income

5.3353 10.55

0.5057 0.614

-1.2089 2.329

-0.5191 0.605

0.72507 0.3820E-01

18.98 0.000

0.31613 0.7048E-01

4.485 0.000

0.9527

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1981q3 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the SPF over the next year

forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the old

Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs; all coefficients of

backward-looking and forward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically

significant at 1% level. The coefficient of labour’s share of income has the wrong sign. The

coefficients of the job finding probability and the output gap are statistically significant at 5%

level.

Page 125: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

125

Table 5.16 Estimations (OLS) of the Old Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t b tmc

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

2

Job Finding

Probability

-3.5216

1.241 -2.837 0.005

5.2585

1.833 2.869 0.005

0.95013

0.2729E-01 34.81 0.000

0.9616

Output Gap

0.70129E-01 0.9745E-01

0.7197 0.473

0.24143 0.6808E-01

3.546 0.001

0.98510 0.2365E-01

41.65 0.000

0.9593

Labour’s Share of Income

-36.390 48.09

-0.7566 0.451

7.9514 10.48

0.7584 0.450

0.93879 0.5224E-01

17.97 0.000

0.9519

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1974q2 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The old Keynesian Phillips curve estimated over the 1974q2 to 2004q4 period with

adaptive expectations produces relatively high 2

� values for the three proxies of real

marginal cost. The coefficients of job finding probability and the output gap are statistically

significant at 1%. Note that the coefficients of backward-looking inflation expectations for

the 1974q2 to 2004q4 sample period are higher than the coefficients of backward-looking

inflation expectations for the 1981q3 to 2010q1 sample period (Table 5.11).

Page 126: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

126

Table 5.17 Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Michigan Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 4t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

0.84573 2.577

0.3281 0.743

-2.1696 3.608

-0.6013 0.549

1.0569 0.9453E-01

11.18 0.000

0.7682

Output Gap

-0.90670 0.4560 -1.988 0.049

-0.49821 0.1717 -2.901 0.004

1.0884 0.8535E-01

12.75 0.000

0.8025

Labour’s Share of Income

-197.83 43.52

-4.545 0.000

43.033 9.528 4.516 0.000

0.81440 0.9169E-01

8.882 0.000

0.8238

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1974q2 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Michigan forecasts for over the

next year forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces lower 2

� values for the three

proxies of real marginal costs than the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive

expectations; this is contrary to the prediction of rational expectations. The coefficients of the

job finding probability and the output gap have the wrong signs.

Page 127: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

127

Table 5.18 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Michigan Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-2.3250 0.6693

-3.474 0.001

2.9067 0.9967

2.916 0.004

0.80304 0.3276E-01

24.52 0.000

0.22863 0.4083E-01

5.600 0.000

0.9716

Output Gap

-0.36784 0.1110 -3.315 0.001

0.82765E-01 0.5870E-01

1.410 0.161

0.80978 0.3122E-01

25.94 0.000

0.24478 0.4779E-01

5.122 0.000

0.9696

Labour’s Share of Income

-28.422 23.82

-1.193 0.235

6.1060 5.197

1.175 0.242

0.75575 0.2849E-01

26.53 0.000

0.27491 0.4626E-01

5.943 0.000

0.9697

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1974q2 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Michigan forecasts for

over the next year forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values

than the old Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs; all

coefficients of backward-looking and forward-looking inflation expectations terms are

statistically significant at 1% level. The coefficient of the job finding probability is

statistically significant at 1% level.

Page 128: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

128

Table 5.19 Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

1.1429 0.9266

1.233 0.220

-0.93049 1.364

-0.6824 0.496

1.0555 0.4546E-01

23.22 0.000

0.9069

Output Gap

0.45049 0.1684

2.674 0.009

-0.21414 0.9120E-01

-2.348 0.021

1.0580 0.4015E-01

26.35 0.000

0.9136

Labour’s Share of Income

-91.500 22.53

-4.061 0.000

20.053 4.910

4.084 0.000

0.94134 0.4507E-01

20.88 0.000

0.9172

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1974q2 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Greenbook forecasts for over

the next quarter forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces lower 2

� values for

the three proxies of real marginal costs than the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive

expectations; this is contrary to the prediction of rational expectations. The coefficients of the

job finding probability and the output gap have the wrong signs. The coefficient of the

labour’s share of income is statistically significant at 1% level.

Page 129: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

129

Table 5.20 Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 4t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

2.3297 1.458

1.598 0.113

-3.1288 2.181

-1.435 0.154

1.2009 0.8667E-01

13.86 0.000

0.8529

Output Gap

0.14698E-01 0.2752

0.5341E-01 0.957

-0.45746 0.1474 -3.103 0.002

1.2132 0.7958E-01

15.24 0.000

0.8801

Labour’s Share of Income

-142.34 35.08

-4.057 0.000

31.082 7.645

4.066 0.000

0.98505 0.7244E-01

13.60 0.000

0.8771

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1974q2 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Greenbook forecasts for over

the next year forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces lower 2

� values for the

three proxies of real marginal costs than the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive

expectations; this is contrary to the prediction of rational expectations. The coefficients of the

job finding probability and the output gap have the wrong signs. The coefficient of the

labour’s share of income is statistically significant at 1% level.

Page 130: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

130

Table 5.21 Estimations of the New Hybrid Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy

for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 1t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-1.9662 0.7249

-2.712 0.008

2.9786 1.005

2.965 0.004

0.69105 0.6066E-01

11.39 0.000

0.32199 0.6597E-01

4.881 0.000

0.9721

Output Gap

0.68736E-01 0.7220E-01

0.9520 0.343

0.99664E-01 0.5053E-01

1.972 0.051

0.69529 0.6364E-01

10.93 0.000

0.33932 0.7606E-01

4.461 0.000

0.9703

Labour’s Share of Income

-25.919 25.31

-1.024 0.308

5.6673 5.510

1.028 0.306

0.62632 0.5586E-01

11.21 0.000

0.38414 0.7380E-01

5.205 0.000

0.9698

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1974q2 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Greenbook forecasts for

over the next quarter as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the

old Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs; all coefficients of

backward-looking and forward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically

significant at 1% level. The coefficient of the job finding probability is statistically significant

at 1% level.

Page 131: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

131

Table 5.22 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy

for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-2.0383 0.9923

-2.054 0.042

2.8926 1.409

2.052 0.042

0.77132 0.3946E-01

19.55 0.000

0.27214 0.4988E-01

5.456 0.000

0.9692

Output Gap

-0.75618E-01 0.8197E-01

-0.9225 0.358

0.72941E-01 0.6174E-01

1.181 0.240

0.76903 0.4331E-01

17.76 0.000

0.30054 0.6930E-01

4.337 0.000

0.9671

Labour’s Share of Income

-30.370 29.28

-1.037 0.302

6.6019 6.379

1.035 0.303

0.70496 0.4054E-01

17.39 0.000

0.34148 0.5873E-01

5.815 0.000

0.9676

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1974q2 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Greenbook forecasts for

over the next year as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the old

Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs; all coefficients of

backward-looking and forward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically

significant at 1% level. The coefficient of the job finding probability is statistically significant

at 5% level.

Page 132: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

132

Empirical �es�lts o� �ob�st�ess A�al�sis

The tables 5.23 through to 5.36 below present the results of the first robustness exercise,

which examines sub-sample stability. The first sub-sample is the period from 1974q1 to

1982q4. The second sub-sample is the period from 1987q1 to 2006q4 (the Great Moderation).

��b��ample �tabilit�

Table 5.23OLS Estimations of the Old Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t b tmc

Proxy for Real

Marginal Cost

Constant b

2

Job Finding Probability

-9.1970 0.9116 -10.09 0.000

13.471 1.305 10.32 0.000

0.92133 0.3361E-01

27.41 0.000

0.8820

Output Gap

0.90798 0.5307

1.711 0.096

0.40839 0.7107E-01

5.746 0.000

0.90085 0.5267E-01

17.10 0.000

0.8183

Labour’s Share of Income

-69.141 91.92

-0.7522 0.457

15.244 19.97

0.7632 0.451

0.82988 0.6253E-01

13.27 0.000

0.7656

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1974q1 to 1982q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth

row.

The old Keynesian Phillips curve estimated over the 1974q1 to 1982q4 period yields

lower 2� values for the three proxies of real marginal cost than that of the full sample. The

coefficients of job finding probability and the output gap are statistically significant at 1%.

The coefficients of backward-looking inflation expectations are all statistically significant at

1% level for the three proxies of real marginal cost.

Page 133: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

133

Table 5.24 Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

7.1262 2.107

3.381 0.002

-10.181 3.188

-3.194 0.003

1.1697 0.8879E-01

13.17 0.000

0.6228

Output Gap

-0.60256 0.5922 -1.017

0.316-0

-0.53130 0.1873 -2.836

0.008

1.1942 0.6584E-01

18.14 0.000

0.6558

Labour’s Share of Income

-62.352 80.38

-0.7757 0.443

13.752 17.36

0.7924 0.434

0.94715 0.7250E-01

13.06 0.000

0.5772

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1974q1 to 1982q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated over the 1974q1 to 1982q4 period using

the Greenbook forecasts over the next quarter as proxy for inflation expectations yields lower

2

� values than the old Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal cost.

The coefficients of the job finding probability and the output gap have the wrong signs.

Page 134: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

134

Table 5.25 Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 4t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

4.3087 2.346 1.837 0.075

-1.2107 4.677

-0.2589 0.797

0.75397 0.1998 3.774 0.001

0.4005

Output Gap

2.4356 1.899

1.282 0.209

-0.44986 0.2065

-2.179 0.037

0.89546 0.2693

3.325 0.002

0.4626

Labour’s Share of Income

-217.81 53.65

-4.060 0.000

47.788 11.48 4.163 0.000

0.75740 0.1302 5.818 0.000

0.5457

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1974q1 to 1982q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated over the 1974q1 to 1982q4 period using

the Greenbook forecasts over the next year as proxy for inflation expectations yields lower2

values than the old Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal cost. The

coefficients of the job finding probability and the output gap have the wrong signs. The

coefficient of the labour’s share of income is statistically significant at 1% level.

Page 135: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

135

Table 5.26Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Michigan Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 4t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

13.545 5.123 2.644 0.012

-15.926 9.576

-1.663 0.106

0.78237 0.3016 2.594 0.014

0.2354

Output Gap

2.1274 1.687 1.261

0.216

-0.65700 0.2389 -2.750

0.010

0.73806 0.2200 3.355

0.002

0.2536

Labour’s Share of Income

-138.25 104.6

-1.321 0.196

30.960 22.46 1.378 0.177

0.39170 0.2017 1.942 0.061

0.2196

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1974q1 to 1982q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation

using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated over the 1974q1 to 1982q4 period using

the Michigan forecasts over the next year as proxy for inflation expectations yields lower2

values for the three proxies of real marginal costs than the old Keynesian Phillips curve with

adaptive expectations. The coefficients of the job finding probability and the output gap have

the wrong signs.

Page 136: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

136

Table 5.27 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy

for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 1t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-7.0671 2.344

-3.015 0.005

9.7277 3.675

2.647 0.013

0.81508 0.1228

6.639 0.000

0.20246 0.1768

1.145 0.261

0.8858

Output Gap

-0.56200 0.4040 -1.391 0.174

0.80401E-01 0.1083 0.7427 0.463

0.66879 0.7127E-01

9.384 0.000

0.45279 0.1006

4.502 0.000

0.8577

Labour’s Share of Income

-29.640 41.36

-0.7167 0.479

6.2846 9.012

0.6974 0.491

0.63082 0.6130E-01

10.29 0.000

0.49169 0.1023

4.807 0.000

0.8587

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1974q1 to 1982q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the Greenbook over the next

quarter forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the old

Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs. All of the coefficients of

backward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically significant at 1% level. The

coefficients of forward-looking inflation expectations term of job finding probability is not

statistically significant. The coefficient of the job finding probability is statistically

significant at 5% level.

Page 137: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

137

Table 5.28 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy

for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-8.4009 1.223

-6.872 0.000

12.132 1.734 6.997 0.000

0.87378 0.5749E-01

15.20 0.000

0.89843E-01 0.4874E-01

1.843 0.075

0.8819

Output Gap

0.60303 0.6683 0.9024

0.374

0.28534 0.1019

2.801 0.009

0.82106 0.8315E-01

9.874 0.000

0.14666 0.8270E-01

1.773 0.086

0.8198

Labour’s Share of

Income

-106.62

54.52 -1.956 0.059

23.169

11.92 1.944 0.061

0.64856

0.6993E-01 9.274 0.000

0.35628

0.1046 3.406 0.002

0.8332

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1974q1 to 1982q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the Greenbook over the next

year forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the old

Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs. All of the coefficients of

backward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically significant at 1% level. All of

the coefficients of forward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically significant at

10% level. The coefficients of the three proxies of real marginal costs are statistically

significant at 10% level.

Page 138: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

138

Table 5.29 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using Michigan Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-9.1338 2.838

-3.219 0.003

13.358 4.745

2.815 0.008

0.92017 0.6077E-01

15.14 0.000

0.35093E-02 0.1239

0.2832E-01 0.978

0.8783

Output Gap

-0.55418 0.3025 -1.832 0.076

0.10583 0.1411 0.7502

0.459

0.82396 0.4474E-01

18.42 0.000

0.25061 0.6758E-01

3.708 0.001

0.8420

Labour’s Share of Income

-30.865 49.93

-0.6181 0.541

6.5323 10.91

0.5985 0.554

0.79301 0.3006E-01

26.38 0.000

0.28856 0.7147E-01

4.037 0.000

0.8425

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1974q1 to 1982q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Michigan forecasts for

over the next year forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values

than the old Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs. All of the

coefficients of backward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically significant at

1% level. The coefficients of forward-looking inflation expectations term of job finding

probability is not statistically significant. The coefficient of the job finding probability is

statistically significant at 1% level.

Page 139: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

139

�he �reat �oderatio�

Table 5.30 Estimations (OLS) of the Old Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t b tmc

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

2

Job Finding Probability

-0.89751 0.3207 -2.798 0.006

1.5098E-01 0.5216 2.895 0.005

0.94147 0.3078E-01

30.59 0.000

0.9697

Output Gap

0.44668E-01 0.6058E-01

0.7374 0.463

0.81754E-01

0.1819E-01 4.496 0.000

0.97971

0.2063E-01 47.49 0.000

0.9707

Labour’s Share of Income

-1.6295 8.498

-0.1917 0.848

0.36689 1.854

0.1979 0.844

0.97609 0.3000E-01

32.53 0.000

0.9646

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1987q1 to 2006q4 period using quarterly data.

Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The old Keynesian Phillips curve estimated over the 1987q1 to 2006q4 period yields

higher 2

� values for the three proxies of real marginal cost than that of the full sample. The

coefficients of job finding probability and the output gap are statistically significant at 1%.

The coefficients of backward-looking inflation expectations are all statistically significant at

1% level for the three proxies of real marginal cost.

Page 140: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

140

Table 5.31 Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

-0.25644 0.8122

-0.3157 0.753

1.6247 1.318 1.233 0.222

0.86613 0.7102E-01

12.20 0.000

0.7965

Output Gap

0.74171 0.8656E-01

8.568 0.000

-0.57198E-01 0.6223E-01

-0.9192 0.361

0.92263 0.5341E-01

17.27 0.000

0.7933

Labour’s Share of Income

-70.407 26.41

-2.666 0.010

15.523 5.766 2.692 0.009

0.81769 0.6203E-01

13.18 0.000

0.8333

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1987q1 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the Greenbook over the next quarter

forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces lower2

� values than the old Keynesian

Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs. All coefficients of forward-looking

inflation expectations terms are statistically significant at 1% level. The coefficient of the

output gap has the wrong sign. The coefficient of the labour’s share of income is statistically

significant at 1% level.

Page 141: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

141

Table 5.32 Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 4t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

1.0455 1.246

0.8389 0.404

-0.44519 1.876

-0.2373 0.813

0.94312 .1099 8.584 0.000

0.7485

Output Gap

0.64884 0.2094

3.099 0.003

-0.14482 0.1216 -1.191 0.238

0.97200 0.1019

9.543 0.000

0.7641

Labour’s Share of Income

-69.048 32.03

-2.156 0.035

15.229 6.995 2.177 0.033

0.82802 0.9198E-01

9.002 0.000

0.7884

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1987q1 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the Greenbook over the next year

forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces lower 2

� values than the old

Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs. All coefficients of

forward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically significant at 1% level. The

coefficients of job finding probability and the output gap have the wrong signs.

Page 142: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

142

Table 5.33 Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Michigan Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 4t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

-3.8983 1.776

-2.195 0.031

5.5517 3.020 1.838 0.070

0.77766 0.1651 4.710 0.000

0.5655

Output Gap

-0.91889 0.6308 -1.457 0.149

-0.19608 0.1245 -1.575 0.119

1.0159 0.1884 5.393 0.000

0.5209

Labour’s Share of Income

-114.54 28.83

-3.973 0.000

24.863 6.282 3.958 0.000

0.83989 0.8889E-01

9.448 0.000

0.6934

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1987q1 to 2006q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Michigan forecasts for over the

next year forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces lower 2

� values for the three

proxies of real marginal costs than the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive

expectations. The coefficient of the output gap has the wrong signs. The coefficient of the

labours share of income is statistically significant at 1% level.

Page 143: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

143

Table 5.34 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy

for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 1t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-0.89015 0.2870

-3.101 0.003

1.4532 0.4456

3.262 0.002

0.92071 0.4056E-01

22.70 0.000

0.34947E-01 0.3136E-01

1.114 0.269

0.9725

Output Gap

0.45681E-01 0.6947E-01

0.6576 0.513

0.82916E-01 0.2223E-01

3.731 0.000

0.96972 0.3619E-01

26.80 0.000

0.12435E-01 0.3196E-01

0.3891 0.698

0.9729

Labour’s Share of Income

-13.750 8.865

-1.551 0.126

3.0116 1.931 1.560 0.123

0.88753 0.5109E-01

17.37 0.000

0.86709E-01 0.3967E-01

2.186 0.032

0.9691

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1987q1 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the Greenbook over the next

quarter forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the old

Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs; all coefficients of

backward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically significant at 1% level. The

coefficients of job finding probability and the output gap are statistically significant at 1%.

Page 144: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

144

Table 5.35 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy

for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-0.58137 0.2394

-2.429 0.018

0.94430 0.3191

2.959 0.004

0.87069 0.4028E-01

21.61 0.000

0.11820 0.4137E-01

2.857 0.006

0.9753

Output Gap

0.30306E-01 0.5850E-01

0.5181 0.606

0.55550E-01 0.1496E-01

3.714 0.000

0.89258 0.3705E-01

24.09 0.000

0.11439 0.4028E-01

2.840 0.006

0.9757

Labour’s Share of Income

-12.549 8.072

-1.555 0.125

2.7442 1.756 1.562 0.123

0.83808 0.2711E-01

30.92 0.000

0.16204 0.3944E-01

4.108 0.000

0.9748

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1987q1 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the Greenbook over the next

year forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the old

Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs; all coefficients of

backward-looking and forward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically

significant at 1% level. The coefficients of the job finding probability and the output gap are

statistically significant at 1% level.

Page 145: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

145

Table 5.36 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using Michigan Survey Data

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-1.0802 0.1862 -5.802 0.000

1.3105 0.2718

4.822 0.000

0.88114 0.2793E-01

31.54 0.000

0.13101 0.3668E-01

3.572 0.001

0.9750

Output Gap

-0.19964 0.1094 -1.824

0.072

0.53172E-01 0.1282E-01

4.149

0.000

0.92766 0.2969E-01

31.25

0.000

0.10435 0.4686E-01

2.227

0.029

0.9733

Labour’s Share of Income

-11.706 5.357

-2.185 0.032

2.4879E-01 1.168E-01

2.130 0.036

0.87171 0.3146E-01

27.71 0.000

0.16642 0.4432E-01

3.75 0.000

0.9725

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1987q1 to 2006q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Michigan forecasts for

over the next year forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values

than the old Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs; all

coefficients of backward-looking and forward-looking inflation expectations terms are

statistically significant at 5% level. The coefficients of the three proxies of real marginal

costs are statistically significant at 5% level.

Page 146: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

146

Empirical �es�lts o� Estimatio�s �si�g a� Alter�ati�e �eas�reme�t o� ���latio�

The tables 5.37 through to 5.48 present the results of estimations using the implicit

price deflator (nonfarm business) instead of core inflation to examine if our initial results are

robust.

Table 5.37 Estimations (OLS) of the Old Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t b tmc

Proxy for Real

Marginal Cost

Constant b

2

Job Finding Probability

-0.79996 0.3320 -2.410 0.018

1.4562 0.5016 2.903 0.004

0.89091 0.2472E-01

36.05 0.000

0.9355

Output Gap

0.15697 0.6290E-01

2.496

0.014

0.76709E-01 0.4196E-01

1.828

0.070

0.90923 0.2224E-01

40.89

0.000

0.9351

Labour’s Share of Income

-4.4032E-01 10.05

-0.4381 0.662

0.99905 2.192

0.4558 0.649

0.89443 0.2750E-01

32.53 0.000

0.9306

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1981q3 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth

row.

The old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive expectations produces relatively high

2

� values for the three proxies of real marginal cost. The coefficients of job finding

probability and the output gap are statistically significant at 10% level.

Page 147: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

147

Table 5.38 Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the SPF Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation

Expectations

Equation estimated 1t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

0.72396 0.8639 0.8380

0.404

-2.2285 1.469

-1.517 0.132

0.99381 0.1958 5.075 0.000

0.6637

Output Gap

-0.66386 0.6564 -1.011 0.314

-0.99283E-01 0.9992E-01

-0.9936 0.323

0.94899 0.1893 5.014 0.000

0.6613

Labour’s Share of Income

32.448 27.11 1.197 0.234

-7.2730 5.917

-1.229 0.222

1.0468 0.1943 5.389 0.000

0.6650

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1981q3 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the SPF over the next quarter

forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produce lower 2

� values for the three proxies of

real marginal costs than the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive expectations; this is

contrary to the prediction of rational expectations. The coefficients of the three proxies of real

marginal costs have the wrong signs.

Page 148: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

148

Table 5.39 Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the SPF Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation

Expectations

Equation estimated 4t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

-0.30281 0.9855

-0.3073 0.759

-0.57171 1.447

-0.3951 0.693

0.90486 0.2271 3.985 0.000

0.5945

Output Gap

-0.65848 0.7706

-0.8545 0.395

0.15174E-01 0.9576E-01

0.1585 0.874

0.89490 0.2186 4.094 0.000

0.5939

Labour’s Share of Income

35.253 34.46 1.023 0.308

-7.9034E-01 7.533E-01

-1.049 0.296

1.0126 0.2244 4.512 0.000

0.6066

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1981q3 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the SPF over the next year forecasts

as proxy for inflation expectations produce lower 2

� values for the three proxies of real

marginal costs than the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive expectations; this is

contrary to the prediction of rational expectations. The coefficients job finding probability

and labour’s share of income have the wrong signs.

Page 149: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

149

Table 5.40 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the SPF Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 1t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-0.61389 0.3104

-1.978 0.050

0.87521 0.4656

1.880 0.063

0.81854 0.4894E-01

16.73 0.000

0.12114 0.7519E-01

1.611 0.110

0.9383

Output Gap

-0.60344E-01 0.1575

-0.3832 0.702

0.57245E-01 0.3763E-01

1.521 0.131

0.82285 0.4330E-01

19.01 0.000

0.13327 0.6712E-01

1.985 0.050

0.9393

Labour’s Share of Income

10.007 12.32

0.8124 0.418

-2.2213 2.700

-0.8228 0.412

0.79558 0.4913E-01

16.19 0.000

0.19588 0.7990E-01

2.451 0.016

0.9379

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1981q3 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the SPF over the next

quarter forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the old

Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs. The coefficient of

labour’s share of income has the wrong sign.

Page 150: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

150

Table 5.41 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the SPF Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-0.77548 0.3286

-2.360 0.020

1.2947 0.4476

2.893 0.005

0.86440 0.4247E-01

20.36 0.000

0.44284E-01 0.6102E-01

0.7257 0.470

0.9355

Output Gap

0.11407E-01 0.1555

0.7336E-01 0.942

0.75185E-01 0.3751E-01

2.004 0.047

0.86021 0.3735E-01

23.03 0.000

0.77942E-01 0.5875E-01

1.327 0.187

0.9364

Labour’s Share of Income

3.6779 12.86

0.2860 0.775

-0.80677 2.821

-0.2860 0.775

0.84806 0.4707E-01

18.02 0.000

0.96774E-01 0.7715E-01

1.254 0.212

0.9319

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1981q3 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the SPF over the next year

forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the old

Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs. The coefficient of

labour’s share of income has the wrong sign. The coefficients of the job finding probability

and the output gap are statistically significant at 5% level.

Page 151: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

151

Table 5.42 Estimations (OLS) of the Old Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1t t b tmc

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

2

Job Finding

Probability

-3.0893

1.489 -2.075 0.040

4.5594

2.121 2.150 0.034

0.95337

0.2374E-01 40.16 0.000

0.9644

Output Gap

0.59032E-01 0.8672E-01

0.6807 0.497

0.22085 0.6437E-01

3.431 0.001

0.98255 0.2425E-01

40.51 0.000

0.9634

Labour’s Share of Income

-22.588 47.48

-0.4758 0.635

4.9322 10.34

0.4772 0.634

0.95295 0.4716E-01

20.21 0.000

0.9576

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1974q2 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The old Keynesian Phillips curve estimated over the 1974q2 to 2004q4 period with

adaptive expectations produces relatively high 2

� values for the three proxies of real

marginal cost. The coefficients of job finding probability and the output gap are statistically

significant at 5% level. All of the coefficients of backward-looking inflation expectations are

statistically significant at 1% level. Note that the coefficients of backward-looking inflation

expectations for the 1974q2 to 2004q4 sample period are higher than the coefficients of

backward-looking inflation expectations for the 1981q3 to 2010q1 sample period (Table

5.37).

Page 152: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

152

Table 5.43 Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Michigan Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 4t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

1.2358 2.214

0.5581 0.578

-4.7410 2.952

-1.606 0.111

1.1525 0.1142

10.09 0.000

0.7541

Output Gap

-2.3248 0.4281 -5.430 0.000

-0.68779 0.2795 -2.461 0.015

1.1768 0.9162E-01

12.84 0.000

0.8063

Labour’s Share of Income

-158.70 55.13

-2.879 0.005

34.216 12.06

2.838 0.005

0.92667 0.1182

7.842 0.000

0.7785

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1974q2 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Michigan over the next year

forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces lower 2

� values for the three proxies

of real marginal costs than the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive expectations. The

coefficients of the job finding probability and the output gap have the wrong signs. The

coefficient of labour’s share of income is statistically significant at 1% level.

Page 153: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

153

Table 5.44 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Michigan Forecasts as Proxy

for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

--1.9186 1.133

-1.693 0.093

1.9550 1.577 1.239 0.218

0.81612 0.3619E-01

22.55 0.000

0.23437 0.3450E-01

6.794 0.000

0.9736

Output Gap

0.61739 0.1549 -3.986 0.000

0.37931E-01 0.5797E-01

0.6544 0.514

0.81448 0.2812E-01

28.96 0.000

0.25327 0.3721E-01

6.807 0.000

0.9726

Labour’s Share of Income

-3.3333E-01 28.75

-0.1159 0.908

0.58242 6.251

0.9317E-01 0.926

0.80061 0.2867E-01

27.92 0.000

0.26887 0.3507E-01

7.667 0.000

0.9725

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1974q2 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Michigan over the next

year forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the old

Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs; all coefficients of

backward-looking and forward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically

significant at 1% level.

Page 154: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

154

Table 5.45 Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

1.1924 1.755

0.6794 0.498

-2.6219 2.447

-1.072 0.286

1.1067 0.1047

10.57 0.000

0.8348

Output Gap

-0.68728 0.3417 -2.012 0.046

-0.36900 0.2099 -1.758 0.081

1.1018 0.9363E-01

11.77 0.000

0.8503

Labour’s Share of Income

-61.120 46.75

-1.307 0.194

13.195 10.15

1.300 0.196

1.0136 0.9089E-01

11.15 0.000

0.8365

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1974q2 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Greenbook over the next

quarter forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces lower 2

� values for the three

proxies of real marginal costs than the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive

expectations. The coefficients of the job finding probability and the output gap have the

wrong signs.

Page 155: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

155

Table 5.46 Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy for

Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 4t t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

2.1790 2.104

1.036 0.302

-4.3958 3.058

-1.438 0.153

1.2280 0.1134

10.83 0.000

0.7496

Output Gap

-1.0583 0.3933 -2.691 0.008

-0.61298 0.2730 -2.246 0.027

1.2421 0.1118 11.11 0.000

0.7911

Labour’s Share of Income

-132.63 64.14

-2.068 0.041

28.748 13.95

2.061 0.041

1.0109 0.8547E-01

11.83 0.000

0.7641

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1974q2 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Greenbook over the next year

forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces lower 2

� values for the three proxies

of real marginal costs than the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive expectations. The

coefficients of the job finding probability and the output gap have the wrong signs. The

coefficient of the labour’s share of income is statistically significant at 5% level.

Page 156: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

156

Table 5.47 Estimations of the New Hybrid Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy

for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 1t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-2.4188 1.362

-1.775 0.078

3.3510 1.885

1.778 0.078

0.84936 0.4674E-01

18.17 0.000

0.14525 0.4793E-01

3.030 0.003

0.9666

Output Gap

-0.10554 0.1387

-0.7611 0.448

0.14756 0.5718E-01

2.58 0.011

0.86942 0.4782E-01

18.18 0.000

0.14636 0.5922E-01

2.471 0.015

0.9655

Labour’s Share of Income

-3.2015 39.27

-0.8152E-01 0.935

0.65865 8.541

0.7712E-01 0.939

0.81077 0.4904E-01

16.53 0.000

0.21300 0.5032E-01

4.233 0.000

0.9633

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1974q2 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Greenbook over the

next quarter forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the

old Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs; all coefficients of

backward-looking and forward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically

significant at 5% level. The coefficients of the job finding probability and the output gap are

statistically significant at 10% level.

Page 157: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

157

Table 5.48 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy

for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant b

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-2.4961 1.585

-1.575 0.118

3.4635 2.285

1.516 0.132

0.88991 0.5133E-01

17.34 0.000

0.11103 0.6232E-01

1.782 0.077

0.9656

Output Gap

-0.98867E-01 0.1109

-0.8917 0.374

0.15332 0.6377E-01

2.404 0.018

0.91363 0.5238E-01

17.44 0.000

0.10763 0.5469E-01

1.968 0.051

0.9644

Labour’s Share of Income

-7.4557 42.01

-0.1775 0.859

1.5786 9.146

0.1726 0.863

0.85486 0.4410E-01

19.38 0.000

0.18252 0.5828E-01

3.132 0.002

0.9624

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1974q2 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure with 12 lags. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using the Greenbook forecasts for

over the next year as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the old

Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs. All coefficients of

backward-looking and forward-looking inflation expectation terms are statistically significant

at 10% level. The coefficient of the output gap is statistically significant at 5% level.

Page 158: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

158

Table 5.49 Definitions and Sources of Data

Variable Definition Source

dlp t is measured as 100

4ln t

t

p

p using core CPI.

Consumer Price Index (All Items Less Food and Energy), Index 1982-1984=100. Source:

Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

u Unemployment Rate (in %). Bureau of Labor Statistics

(BLS).

jfp Job Finding Probability. Constructed from the number of unemployed workers, the number of short term (15 weeks) unemployed workers and the

number of unemployed workers next month.

Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

gap Output Gap (Nonfarm Business Sector Output, Index 2005=100), using the Hodrick-Prescott filter

with a smoothing parameter of 1600.

Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

s Labour’s Share of Income (Nonfarm Business Sector, Index 1992=100).

Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

p Implicit Price Deflator of Nonfarm Business Sector Output, Index 1992=100.

Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

S1 Represents the median forecasts of the SPF for the first quarter after the current quarter.

www.philadelphiafed.org/.../survey-of-professional-

forecasters/

S4 Represents the median forecasts of the SPF for the

fourth quarter after the current quarter.

www.philadelphiafed.org/..

./survey-of-professional-forecasters/

MI Represents the mean forecasts of the Michigan Survey for the fourth quarter after the current quarter.

www.src.isr.umich.edu/

DLW Wage Inflation, measured as the log- difference in nonfarm compensation per hour (Nonfarm Business Sector Real Hourly Compensation, Index 1992=100).

Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

FF Federal Funds Rates (in %). Federal Reserve Board (FRB).

DLPPI Measured as4

ln t

t

ppi

ppi using Producer Price Index:

Finished goods (Index 1982 = 100).

http://research.stlouisfed.or

g/fred2/categories/

Page 159: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

159

SP Long-Short Interest Rate Spread. The difference

between 10-Year Treasury Constant Maturity Rate and 3-Month Treasury Bill.

Federal Reserve Board

(FRB).

G1 Greenbook forecasts for the GNP/GDP price level

for the first quarter after the current quarter.

http://www.philadelphiafed

.org/research-and-data/real-time-center/greenbook-

data/

G4 Greenbook forecasts for the GNP/GDP price level for the fourth quarter after the current quarter.

http://www.philadelphiafed.org/research-and-data/real-time-center/greenbook-data/

M1 Represents the mean forecasts of the SPF for the first quarter after the current quarter.

www.philadelphiafed.org/.../survey-of-professional-forecasters/

M4 Represents the mean forecasts of the SPF for the

fourth quarter after the current quarter.

www.philadelphiafed.org/..

./survey-of-professional-forecasters/

M2 M2 consists of M1 plus: (1) savings deposits

(which include money market deposit accounts, or MMDAs); (2) small-denomination time deposits

(time deposits in amounts of less than $100,000); and (3) balances in retail money market mutual funds(MMMFs). Seasonally adjusted M2 is computed by summing savings deposits, small-denomination time deposits, and retail MMMFs, each seasonally adjusted separately, and adding this result to seasonally adjusted M1.

http://research.stlouisfed.or

g/fred2/series/M2SL?cid=29

Page 160: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

160

CHAPTER 6

The Flattening of the Phillips Curve

6.1 Introduction

In recent years, a number of empirical studies such as: Roberts (2006), Ihrig et al

(2007), Mishkin (2007), Kuttner and Robinson (2006), Binyamini and Razin (2007) and

Beaudry and Doyle (2000) report that the slope of the reduced form Phillips curve for the

United States has become much smaller over the last 20 years, this phenomenon is also

observed in many other industrialized countries. The flattening of the Phillips curve raises

two important questions: What explains the flattening of the Phillips curve? And what are the

implications of this phenomenon for the proper conduct of monetary policy? We will attempt

to argue that increase in specialization of labour is also a possible cause of the flattening of

the Phillips curve. This chapter is structured as follows: The first section presents empirical

evidence of the flattening of the Phillips curve and tests for structural changes. The second

section examines competing explanations for the flattening of the Phillips curve. The third

section proposes that increase in specialization of labour is a possible cause of the flattening

of the Phillips curve. The fourth concludes.

6.2 The Flattening of the Phillips Curve

As a starting point, we estimate the hybrid new Keynesian of the Phillips curve using

the Michigan forecasts, the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF) forecasts and the

Greenbook forecasts as proxies for inflation expectations. We also consider job finding

probability, the output gap and labour’s share of income as proxy for real marginal cost.

Table 6.1, 6.2 and 6.6 present the results of estimations of the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips

curve using the Michigan forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations. Table 6.4, 6.5 and 6.6

present the results of estimations of the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve using the SPF

forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations. Table 6.7, 6.8 and 6.9 present the results of

estimations of the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve using the Greenbook forecasts as

proxy for inflation expectations and are presented in the appendix of this chapter. The results

from the nine tables mentioned above show that the slopes of the reduced form new

Keynesian of the Phillips curve are much smaller over the past 20 years. Besides the

flattening of the Phillips curve over the past 20 years, we have also noted the following

interesting empirical findings:

Page 161: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

161

1. The relative importance of backward-looking inflation expectations and forward-

looking inflation expectations changes over time. Backward-looking inflation

expectations dominate forward-looking inflation expectations independent of which

measures of real marginal cost and survey measures of inflation expectations are used.

This is consistent with our previous empirical finding in chapter 5.

2. The signs and magnitudes of the slope of the reduced form Phillips curve depend on

which measure of inflation expectations are used and which measures of real marginal

cost are used.

3. The recent financial crisis does not seem to have affected the slopes of the reduced

form hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve. We have estimated the hybrid new

Keynesian Phillips curve for the sub-sample periods from 2000q1 to 2006q4 and for

Phillips curve from 2007q1 to 2010q1; it appears that the slopes and the R square

values have not changed much. Note that the second sub-sample period is relatively

short, we need to be careful about drawing any conclusion from this sub-sample

period.

4. The R square values of the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated for the

sub-sample period from 2000q1 to 2010q1 are lower than that of the previous two

decades, this suggests the inflation process has become more difficult to forecast; this

is consistent with Stock and Watson’s (2007) empirical finding. Our results also

indicate that backward-looking inflation expectations have become less significant

(less persistent), but forward-looking inflation expectations have not become more

significant. This is an empirical result that needs further investigation and is beyond

the scope of this chapter.

5. Job finding probability is marginally a better proxy for real marginal cost than the

output gap and labour’s share of income when the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips

curve is estimated.

Page 162: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

162

Table 6.1 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Michigan Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation Expectations and with Job Finding Probability as Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Sample Period Constant b

2�

1961q1 to 1969q4 0.7324 1.0898

0.672072 0.5065

-1.7030 1.6959

-1.004176 0.3231

0.875677 0.056137 15.59903

0.0000

0.3201 0.0953

3.358082 0.0021

0.975927

1970q1 to 1979q4 -5.4480 01.7670

-3.083139 0.0039

6.1728 2.2321

2.765412 0.0089

0.963073 0.059258 16.25229

0.0000

0.1552 0.0513

3.028107 0.0045

0.939176

1980q1 to 1989q4 -2.1894 1.3108

-1.670199 0.1036

2.3562 1.8619

1.265521 0.2138

0.679871 0.067757 10.03389

0.0000

0.4042 0.0919

4.398224 0.0001

0.962117

1990q1 to 1999q4 -1.6932 0.4029

-4.203029 0.0002

1.8194 0.5452

3.337395 0.0020

0.888320 0.034310 25.89078

0.0000

0.1857 0.0481

3.860308 0.0005

0.976544

2000q1 to 2010q1 -0.56.79 0.23.50

-2.416087 0.0207

1.40.14 0.39.20

3.574975 0.0010

0.726571 0.084294 8.619477

0.0000

0.0660 0.0355

1.859752 0.0709

0.831325

2000q1 to 2006q4 -1.0343 0.4113

-2.515061 0.0190

1.7780 0.7686

2.313405 0.0296

0.791480 0.094251 8.397576

0.0000

0.0887 0.0527

1.682290 0.1055

0.872219

2007q1 to 2010q1 0.0547 0.3114

0.175809 0.8643

2.8782 0.9946

2.893945 0.0178

0.028622 0.286442 0.099922

0.9226

0.0678 0.0548

1.238698 0.2468

0.851044

1961q1 to 2010q1 -1.5105

0.2702 -5.591050

0.0000

1.7251

0.3894 4.430226

0.0000

0.825487

0.019734 41.83093

0.0000

0.2076

0.0239 8.677273

0.0000

0.972790

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

Page 163: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

163

Table 6.2 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Michigan Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation Expectations and the Output Gap as Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Sample Period Constant b

� 2�

1961q1 to 1969q4 -0.3028 0.1560

-1.940742 0.0614

0.1081 0.1414

0.764274 0.4505

0.867623 0.055281 15.69486

0.0000

0.2311 0.0743

3.110024 0.0040

0.975603

1970q1 to 1979q4 -0.6466 0.3619

-1.786353 0.0825

-2.24E-03 0.1416

-0.015813 0.9875

0.865678 0.073526 11.77383

0.0000

0.2289 0.0711

3.220710 0.0027

0.926255

1980q1 to 1989q4 -0.5066 0.2586

-1.958888 0.0579

0.1437 0.1017

1.412175 0.1665

0.717845 0.078596 9.133376

0.0000

0.3656 0.1022

3.578252 0.0010

0.962509

1990q1 to 1999q4 -0.4421 0.1545

-2.860961 0.0070

0.0859 0.0404

2.126728 0.0404

0.936668 0.041097 22.79184

0.0000

0.1548 0.0534

2.897211 0.0064

0.972714

2000q1 to 2010q1 0.2949 0.2639

1.117640 0.2709

0.0510 0.0230

2.212613 0.0332

0.826179 0.082434 10.02235

0.0000

0.0173 0.0481

0.359302 0.7214

0.799580

2000q1 to 2006q4 0.1463 0.3145

0.465322 0.6459

0.0723 0.0348

2.074563 0.0489

0.878681 0.079012 11.12087

0.0000

0.0395 0.0669

0.589926 0.5608

0.867488

2007q1 to 2010q1 0.4750 0.5964

0.796543 0.4462

0.0382 0.0371

1.031261 0.3293

0.604170 0.235073 2.570141

0.0302

0.0702 0.0819

0.857030 0.4137

0.742824

1961q1 to 2010q1 -0.3230 0.0790

-4.086299 0.0001

0.0502 0.0310

1.620371 0.1068

0.838952 0.022926 36.59331

0.0000

0.2078 0.0278

7.482747 0.0000

0.970413

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

Page 164: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

164

Table 6.3 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Michigan Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation Expectations and Labour’s Share of Income as Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Sample Period Constant b

� 2�

1961q1 to 1969q4 -25.7121 16.2363

-1.583614 0.1234

5.4684 3.5010

1.561944 0.1285

0.813181 0.061512 13.21982

0.00

0.3180 0.0785

4.051476 0.0003

0.976957

1970q1 to 1979q4 -95.3349 30.3329

-3.142954 0.0033

20.4567 6.5528

3.121829 0.0035

0.917265 0.049508 18.52743

0.0000

0.1873 0.0449

4.172137 0.0002

0.941966

1980q1 to 1989q4 17.0309 42.2774

0.402837 0.6895

-3.8240 9.1890

-0.416154 0.6798

0.677648 0.087130 7.777452

0.0000

0.4319 0.0924

4.674714 0.0000

0.960621

1990q1 to 1999q4 -31.5177 15.8656

-1.986546 0.0546

6.7774 3.4594

1.959120 0.0579

0.822137 0.053711 15.30683

0.0000

0.2263 0.0570

3.969309 0.0003

0.972245

2000q1 to 2010q1 -10.9254 5.0170

-2.177669 0.0359

2.3859 1.1017

2.165686 0.0369

0.817009 0.084407

9.679430 0.0000

0.1088 0.0405

2.688118 0.0107

0.798592

2000q1 to 2006q4 -3.7563 8.0900

-0.464321 0.6466

0.7592 1.7570

0.432083 0.6695

0.913242 0.086649 10.53956

0.0000

0.1412 0.0598

2.362489 0.0266

0.844931

2007q1 to 2010q1 -54.2659 20.4386

-2.655071 0.0263

12.3023 4.6306

2.656745 0.0262

-0.025774 0.325685

-0.079138 0.9387

0.1213 0.0542

2.235827 0.0522

0.838831

1961q1 to 2010q1 -17.8503 5.7445

-3.107405 0.0022

3.8133 1.2522

3.045337 0.0027

0.799602 0.021580 37.05279

0.0000

0.2326 0.0240

9.675960 0.0000

0.971390

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

Page 165: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

165

Table 6.4 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the SPF Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation Expectations and with Job Finding Probability as Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Sample Period Constant b

� 2�

1981q3 to 1989q4 -3.0028 1.4088

-2.131445 0.0414

2.7582 1.8217

1.514075 0.1405

0.652109 0.098482 6.621616

0.0000

0.5434 0.1890

2.874334 0.0074

0.914300

1990q1 to 1999q4 -1.9944 0.4292

-4.646381 0.0000

2.1641 0.5509

3.928378 0.0004

0.814391 0.048324 16.85286

0.0000

0.3115 0.0791

3.939720 0.0004

0.976826

2000q1 to 2010q1 -0.7216 0.3412

-2.114571 0.0413

1.0758 0.5179

2.077150 0.0448

0.664258 0.100573 6.604770

0.0000

0.3140 0.2504

1.253853 0.2178

0.823075

2000q1 to 2006q4 -1.2325 0.4536

-2.717258 0.0120

1.3680 0.9230

1.482069 0.1513

0.675889 0.104628 6.459951

0.0000

0.4305 0.2851

1.510211 0.1440

0.869548

2007q1 to 2010q1 -0.2957 0.7022

-0.421083

0.6836

3.2137 0.9993

3.215809 0.0106

-0.164088 0.391832

-0.418770

0.6852

0.3756 0.5380

0.698182 0.5027

0.834607

1981q3 to 2010q1 -0.5904 0.1933

-3.054384 0.0029

0.7757 0.3171

2.446020 0.0161

0.775954 0.042863 18.10310

0.0000

0.2237 0.0461

4.854514 0.0000

0.963904

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

Page 166: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

166

Table 6.5 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the SPF Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation Expectations and the Output Gap as Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Sample Period Constant b

� 2�

1981q3 to 1989q4 -0.9182 0.5280

-1.739173 0.0923

0.2758 0.0999

2.762122 0.0097

0.799240 0.110072 7.261072

0.0000

0.3712 0.1894

1.960555 0.0593

0.926455

1990q1 to 1999q4 -0.4214 0.1713

-2.459413 0.0189

0.0919 0.0416

2.208255 0.0337

0.903203 0.057779 15.63208

0.0000

0.2107 0.0895

2.354100 0.0241

0.970841

2000q1 to 2010q1 -0.4110 0.3972

-1.034748 0.3075

0.0380 0.0192

1.976669 0.0556

0.681112 0.101147 6.733852

0.0000

0.4628 0.2147

2.155235 0.0377

0.821313

2000q1 to 2006q4 -0.4471 0.4653

-0.960826 0.3462

0.0613 0.0288

2.130960 0.0435

0.744609 0.102484 7.265629

0.0000

0.4266 0.2486

1.716395 0.0990

0.880264

2007q1 to 2010q1 0.8138 1.1800

0.689636

0.5078

0.0566 0.0358

1.582904

0.1479

0.627154 0.394539 1.589590

0.1464

-0.0505 0.7729

-0.065371 0.9493

0.721967

1981q3 to 2010q1 -0.1211 0.0703

-1.722091 0.0881

0.0403 0.0164

2.452957 0.0158

0.805069 0.042399 18.98776

0.0000

0.2151 0.0465

4.622393 0.0000

0.963915

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

Page 167: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

167

Table 6.6 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the SPF Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation Expectations and Labour’s Share of Income as Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t tmc E

Sample Period Constant b

� 2�

1981q3 to 1989q4 56.7864 45.4168

1.250338 0.2208

-12.5568 9.8595

-1.273570 0.2126

0.728683 0.128769 5.658845

0.0000

0.4989 0.1997

2.497595 0.0182

0.912483

1990q1 to 1999q4 -32.9549 17.0106

-1.937311 0.0606

7.0883 3.7057

1.912805 0.0638

0.751092 0.075714 9.920127

0.0000

0.3411 0.0993

3.434469 0.0015

0.969946

2000q1 to 2010q1 -0.4755 5.1272

-0.092751 0.9266

-0.0782 1.1696

-0.066877 0.9470

0.670644 0.106370 6.304825

0.0000

0.6534 0.2297

2.844938 0.0072

0.802468

2000q1 to 2006q4 7.1594 6.8504

1.045113 0.3064

-1.8025 1.5176

-1.187757 0.2466

0.708663 0.106361 6.662810

0.0000

0.7390 0.2324

3.179431 0.0040

0.865514

2007q1 to 2010q1 -63.2481 23.8872

-2.647780

0.0266

14.1322 5.3664

2.633443

0.0272

-0.446487 0.528591

-0.844674

0.4202

0.9198 0.6147

1.496290 0.1688

0.799252

1981q3 to 2010q1 -4.8228 4.5227

-1.066361 0.2888

1.0292 0.9958

1.033516 0.3038

0.785246 0.044091 17.80958

0.0000

0.2269 0.0475

4.780299 0.0000

0.962199

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

6.3 Tests for Structural Changes

��a�dt�A�drews �rea�poi�t �est �or ����ow� �tr�ct�ral �rea�poi�ts

We will now formally test for structural changes. Our first objective is to determine

when the structural changes took place and attempt to explain the breakpoints. We use the

Quandt-Andrews breakpoint test for one or more unknown structural breakpoints (trimming

15 percent of the data). The Quandt-Andrews test performed a Chow breakpoint test at every

observation between two dates. The point in the series with the highest Likelihood Ratio F-

statistic and the Wald F-statistic determines the breakpoint.

Page 168: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

168

Table 6.7 Quandt-Andrews Unknown Breakpoint Tests

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost Maximum LR F-statistic (1975Q3) Maximum Wald F-statistic (1975Q3)

Output Gap 1.320277 0.0443

9.108471 0.0011

Job Finding Probability 4.707637

0.0184

18.83055

0.0184

Labour’s Share of Income 5.195267 0.0084

20.78107 0.0084

Note: The above Quandt-Andrews unknown breakpoint tests were conducted over the 1961q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly data. The maximum LR F-statistics and maximum Wald F-statistics are associated with the null hypothesis of no breakpoints within 15% trimmed data. P-values are shown in the second row.

The Quandt-Andrews breakpoint tests indicate that a structural break occurred in

1975q3. It is interesting that three proxies for real marginal cost suggest the same break point

date. Fig. 6.3 plots the unemployment rates (percentages) and the average duration of

unemployment (weeks) over the 1948M02 to 2010M08 period. Note that the average

duration of unemployment series is trending upward while the unemployment rate series is

relatively flat and this phenomenon started at about 1975q3. It is also interesting that the

Quandt-Andrews breakpoint tests did not detect the 1973 oil crisis and the 1979 change in

policy at the Federal Reserve, which helped to end the stagflation crisis of the 1970s.

�how �est �or �tr�ct�ral �rea�s

We will now use the Chow tests for structural breaks to confirm the results from the

Quandt-Andrews tests. The results of the Chow breakpoint tests below (Table 6.8) support

the Quandt-Andrews tests that a structural break occurred in 1975q3.

Table 6.8 Chow Breakpoint Tests:1975Q3

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost F-Statistic Log Likelihood Ratio Wald Statistic

Output Gap 6.895918 0.0000

26.83380 0.0000

27.58367 0.0000

Job Finding Probability 4.707637 0.0012

18.70974 0.0009

18.83055 0.0008

Labour’s Share of Income 5.195267 0.0005

20.54947 0.0004

20.78107 0.0003

Note: The above Chow Breakpoint Tests were conducted over the 1961q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly

data. The F-statistics, Log likelihood ratio and Wald statistics are associated with the null hypothesis of no break at specified breakpoint (1975Q3). P-values are shown in the second row.

Page 169: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

169

�ests �or �tr�ct�ral �ha�ges i� the ��brid �ew �e��esia� Phillips ��r�e �si�g ��mm�

�ariable

The Quandt-Andrews and Chow tests suggest that there was a structural change in

1975q3. However, these tests do not tell us whether the difference in the two regressions was

because of differences in the intercept terms or the slope coefficients or both. An alternative

to the Chow test is to use dummy variable. The source of difference, if any, can be identified

by pooling all the observations and running the regression below. Note that is the

differential intercept, it enables us to distinguish between the intercepts of the two periods. is the differential slope coefficient, it enables us to differentiate between slope coefficients of

the two periods (Gujarati, 2003, pp.307-310).

1 4t t t b t � t t t tc � mc E �mc (6.1)

where:

t Core Inflation

tmc Real Marginal Cost

4t tE Expected Inflation (proxies by the Michigan survey of inflation expectations)

D = 1 for observations from 1975q4-2010q1

D = 0 for observations from 1961q1–1975q3

Table 6.9 Tests for Structural Changes in the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using Dummy Variable

Equation estimated 1 4t t b t � t t tc � mc E �mc

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

� b �

2

Job Finding Probability

-0.667989 0.453953

-1.471494 0.1428

-0.353221 0.513545

-0.687809 0.4924

1.021034 0.941100

1.084937 0.2793

0.825411 0.020627

40.01557 0.0000

0.213947 0.024863

8.605054 0.0000

0.709169 1.114729

0.636181 0.5254

0.972412

Output Gap

-0.221846 0.087909

-2.523578 0.0124

-0.178901 0.066875

-2.675144 0.0081

-0.067068 0.087806

-0.763819 0.4459

0.825851 0.024831 33.25921

0.0000

0.224169 0.029025 7.723267

0.0000

0.125140 0.087694 1.427014

0.1552

0.971839

Labour’s Share of Income

-36.75893 16.79266

27.47709 17.79136

7.907594 3.633986

0.814302 0.022694

0.225078 0.024436

-5.967277 3.849310

0.971994

Page 170: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

170

-2.188988 0.0298

1.544406 0.1242

2.176011 0.0308

35.88178 0.0000

9.211059 0.0000

-1.550220 0.1228

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1961q2 2010q1period using quarterly data. Standard

errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The Michigan survey of inflation expectations was used as proxy for expected inflation.

The differential intercept coefficient is statistically insignificant for job finding

probability and labour’s share of income but is significant for the output gap; we can accept

the hypothesis that the two regressions have the same intercept for job finding probability and

labour’s share of income but not for the output gap before and after the break date (1975q3).

The differential slope coefficient b is statistically insignificant for all three proxies for real

marginal cost; we can accept the hypothesis that the two regressions have the same slope

before and after the break date (1975q3).

We have also tested for structural changes in the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve

using dummy variables7 that correspond to each decade from 1961q1 to 2010q1. In general,

when labour’s share of income is used as proxy for real marginal cost, the intercepts and the

slopes of the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve are different for the 1970s and 1980s.

When the output gap is used as proxy for real marginal cost, the intercept of the hybrid new

Keynesian Phillips curve is different for the 1970s, the slope of the hybrid new Keynesian

Phillips curve is different for the 1980s. When job finding probability is used as proxy for

real marginal cost, the differential intercept coefficient and differential slope coefficient are

statistically insignificant in all five decades. The results of this exercise are presented in the

appendix of this chapter.

6.4 Competing Explanations

In recent years, a number of empirical studies such as: Roberts (2006), Williams

(2006), Ihrig, Kamin, Linder and Marquez (2007), Mishkin (2007), Kuttner and Robinson

(2006), Binyamini and Razin (2007) and Beaudry and Doyle (2000) report that the slope of

the reduced form Phillips curve for the United States has flattened over the last 20 years, this

phenomenon is also observed in many other industrialized countries. However, there is no

consensus regarding what explains this phenomenon, many of the proposed explanations can

be broadly categorized as: globalization and improvements in the conduct of monetary

policy.

7I thank an anonymous examiner for suggesting the use of dummy variables to test for structural changes.

Page 171: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

171

�lobalisatio� a�d ���latio�

The dramatic decline in the slope of the reduced form Phillips curve for the United

States (and in other industrialized countries) over the last 20 years is one of the most

remarkable developments in the nature of the inflation process. To what extent has

globalisation affected the nature of the inflation process? There is a rapidly growing body of

empirical literature examining this question.

Globalisation is generally referred to the integration of national economies into the

international economy through the increase in openness to trade, immigration and the spread

of scientific ideas and technology. Below are some of the channels that globalisation may

have affected the nature of the inflation process, providing potential explanations for the

flattening of the short-run trade-off between inflation and the domestic output gap (real

marginal cost). First, the increased trade associated with globalisation reduces importance of

domestic gaps and increased the importance of the rest of the world demand and supply

(global gaps) in explaining inflation dynamics of individual countries because import prices

become more important in domestic inflation. Borio and Filardo (2006) find empirical

evidence for this proposition across a range of countries. However, Ihrig et al (2007) and Ball

(2006) find only weak evidence that import prices affect domestic inflation.

Second, increase in competition among workers in the labour market due to

migration and out sourcing to China and India implies that wages are likely to be less

sensitive to the state of the business cycle. Workers are less likely to demand higher wages

when unemployment falls, reducing the effect of higher economic activity on the marginal

cost of labour. Third, increase in competition between domestic firms and a foreign firm in

the product market make domestic firms less able to raise their prices when domestic demand

increases, if foreign firms do not. This implies that the domestic output gap becomes less

important in determining domestic inflation. Iakova (2006) of the IMF and Borio and Filardo

(2006) argues that globalisation, in the form of increased openness to trade is the cause of

flattening of the Phillips curve, but other authors such as Ihrig et al (2007), Kohn (2006) and

Ball (2006) find little evidence of the increase in importance of the foreign or global output

gap relative to the domestic output gap. Rogoff (2003, 2006) argues that globalization should

make the Phillips curve steeper, rather than flatter. This is because increase in competition

makes wages and prices more flexible, it also encourages businesses to revise their prices

more frequently, which tend make the Phillips curve steeper. Contrary to Rogoff’s argument,

Page 172: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

172

Iakova (2006) of the IMF argues that that globalization flattens the Phillips curve because

increases in competition make it hard for firms to raise prices.

Since Borio and Filardo (2006) find strong empirical evidence supporting the

argument that globalisation reduces importance of domestic gaps and increased the

importance of the rest of the world demand and supply (global output gaps) in explaining

inflation dynamics and the paper has received widespread attention, we will briefly review

this paper.

Borio and Filardo (2006) augment a mainstream model of inflation to include the

foreign or global output gaps

1 1

� � �

t t t t tc �ap �ap (6.2)

where t is the inflation rate, � is the underlying inflation rate trend (used largely as a proxy

for slowly changing inflation expectations),��ap is the domestic output gap and is a

random error. ��ap is the global output gap or a global measure of economic slack.

Borio and Filardo (2006, p.32) examines 17 industrialized countries for the period

1985-2005, their results show in 16 out of 17 countries examined, the global gaps have larger

effects on inflation than the domestic gaps. With respect to the United States, the domestic

output gap is negative and statistically insignificant.

Ball (2006, p.6) questions the logic of this argument. “In mainstream theories, output

affects inflation because it affects firms’ marginal costs. Rises in marginal cost are passed

through into higher prices. Marginal costs for a country’s firms depend on their own output

levels, not foreign output... Higher domestic output still raises marginal cost and hence prices.

For globalization to dampen this effect, it would have to somehow cause countercyclical

movements in mark-ups. I don’t see a reason to expect this outcome”.

Ihrig et al (2006) argue that Borio and Filardo (2006) results are not robust. Ihrig et al

(2006, p.13) change the country weights used by Borio and Filardo (2006) to construct the

global output gaps, their results show that global gaps do not have larger effects on inflation

than the domestic gaps.

“We find the coefficient on the foreign output gap to be positive and significant in

only five of the 14 industrial economies considered. This discrepancy reflects the fact

that our estimates of the foreign output gap for each individual country differ from the

Borio-Filardo estimates”.

Page 173: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

173

�mpro�eme�ts i� the �o�d�ct o� �o�etar� Polic�

A complementary explanation for the flattening of the reduced form Phillips curve is

improvements in the conduct of monetary policy. Roberts (2006, p. 195) argues that changes

in monetary policy can provide an explanation for the reduction in the slope of the reduced-

form Phillips curve and for a large portion of the reduction in the volatility of output gap.

Since the early 1980s the monetary authorities in the U.S. have been more aggressive against

increases in inflation, generating greater monetary policy credibility, which help to anchor

inflation expectations. Ball, Mankiw, and Romer (1988) argue that more-stable inflation may

lead less-frequent wage and price adjustments, which also reduce in the slope of the reduced-

form hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve.

While it is possible that more-stable inflation may lead less-frequent wage and price

adjustments, which flattens the Phillips curve. It is unlikely that this is sufficient to explain

the flattening of the Phillips curve; this is because higher domestic output raises marginal cost

and hence prices, when a firm decides to keep prices unchanged, it would be very costly for

the firm that is making this decision.

6.5 The Labour Market and the Slope of the Phillips Curve

In this section we will attempt to argue that part of the reason why the slope of the

reduced form Phillips curve for the United States has flattened over the last 20 years is

because of increase in specialization of labour. As the rationale behind each of these

arguments are very different, we can not think of a direct way of testing which argument is

correct, it is very plausible that all of the three arguments mentioned above are partly

responsible for causing of the flattening of the Phillips curve. In addition, our task is further

complicated by the fact the signs and magnitudes of the slope of the reduced form Phillips

curve depend on which measure of inflation expectations are used and which measures of real

marginal cost are used.

Our argument that the increase in specialization of labour as a possible cause for the

flattening of the reduced form Phillips curve is based on the observations that the average

duration of unemployment has been increasing since 1970 and the probability of finding a job

after 15 weeks of unemployment has been decreasing since 1970, this about the same time

that deindustrialization started in the United States.

Page 174: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

174

Fig. 6.1Average duration of unemployment, monthly data from 1948M01 to 2010M08.

Fig. 6.2 The probability of finding a job after 15 weeks of unemployment, quarterly data from 1961q1 to 2010q1.

Deindustrialization refers to the decrease in the output of manufactured goods and

employment in the manufacturing sectors and the increase in the output of services and

employment in the service sectors. There is a large body of literature on the costs and benefits

of deindustrialization and its implications for international trade which we will not discuss

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

194

8 -

M01

195

0 -

M07

195

3 -

M01

195

5 -

M07

195

8 -

M01

196

0 -

M07

196

3 -

M01

196

5 -

M07

196

8 -

M01

197

0 -

M07

197

3 -

M01

197

5 -

M07

197

8 -

M01

198

0 -

M07

198

3 -

M01

198

5 -

M07

198

8 -

M01

199

0 -

M07

199

3 -

M01

199

5 -

M07

199

8 -

M01

200

0 -

M07

200

3 -

M01

200

5 -

M07

200

8 -

M01

201

0 -

M07

Average Weeks Unemployed

.3

.4

.5

.6

.7

.8

.9

1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Job Finding Probability (JFP)

Page 175: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

175

here, as it is beyond the scope of this chapter. Our main interest in the process of

deindustrialization is the changes in the skills and knowledge of workers that are required

when employment shift from the manufacturing sectors to the service sectors that

deindustrialization embodied. According to the Bureau of Labour Statistics (BLS)

(http://www.bls.gov/spotlight/2008/around_the_world/). “In the United States, the share of

employment in services increased from about 60 percent in 1965 to 79 percent in 2005. In

contrast, the share of U.S. employment in manufacturing decreased from 27 percent to about

12 percent. This employment shift from manufacturing to services seen in the United States is

also seen in countries around the world”.

Our hypothesis is the shift in employment from the manufacturing sectors to the

service sectors and the changes in skills and knowledge that is associated with this change

increase the number of mismatches between unemployed workers and vacancies, increasing

the level of real rigidities in the labour market, reducing the inflation-output tradeoffs and

reducing the slope of the Phillips curve, in other words inflation is less responsive to changes

in real marginal cost.

Cao (2008, pp. 30-41) presents a search and matching model due to Romer (2001)

which is re-interpreted with an emphasis on the role of asymmetric knowledge and the sticky

nature of knowledge as the main source of frictions in the labour market. In this model i

k

represents the probability of an unemployed worker finding another job without having to be

retrained because of heterogeneity between workers and jobs’ skill requirements. As an

aggregate variable, K captures the extent of specialization of labour, which leads to

mismatch problems in the labour market, potentially helping us to explaining involuntary

unemployment. In addition some frictions are also generated by informational imperfections

about the timing of job creation in different locations and by the slow mobility of the

production factors. Empirical studies have shown that jobs destruction appears to be much

more variable than job creation. That is, the fall in employment in recessions stem mainly

from increases in the loss of existing jobs and only to a small extent from decreases in the

creation of new jobs, ((Blanchard and Diamond, 1990; Davis and Haltiwager,

1990,1992,1999)). The dynamics of the economy is such that there is a high turnover of jobs.

In US manufacturing, at least 10% of existing jobs disappearing each year (Davis and

Haltiwager, 1990, 1992, quoted in Romer (2001, p.452)). The high turnover of jobs and the

cyclical variations in turnover implies some unemployed workers will not be able to find

employment in the same profession. These unemployed workers will have to be retrained in

Page 176: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

176

order to find employment in another profession and since much of professional knowledge

cannot be transferred easily, the process of education and training can be very lengthy,

typically, from one to three years as indicated by the durations of vocational and university

courses. Unemployed workers that have difficulties in changing to another profession will

suffer long-term unemployment; in addition their existing skills and knowledge may decay or

become obsolete. Furthermore, unemployment is complicated by the effects of aging on

learning, as people become older, their ability to absorb new knowledge decreases and also

differences in natural abilities, which make acquiring certain skills and knowledge difficult

(Cao, 2008, pp. 33-34).

One of the most significant changes in the labour market in the last forty years that

could provide further support for the notion that increases in specialization of labour is the

use of computer technology in the workplace and in the production process; computer

technology has created entirely new products and services, altering the way firms producing

existing products, the way that it communicates with its staff and customers. These changes

require workers to upgrade their skills and knowledge and to acquire new skills and

knowledge. As a consequence of these changes, the skills and knowledge of workers are

much more diverse than before the computer revolution. The increase in heterogeneity

between workers will inevitably leads to more mismatches in the labour market, this change

is capture by Job Finding Probability (JFP), the plot of JFP over time shows that the

probability of an unemployed worker finding another job after fifteen weeks of

unemployment has decrease over the past forty years, suggest the real rigidities in the labour

market has increased in the past forty years.

Since our results from Table 1-Table 6 and Table 9-Table11 indicate that job finding

probability is marginally a better proxy for real marginal cost than the output gap and

labour’s share of income when the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve is estimated, this

result is robust independent of which survey measures of inflation expectations are used. We

will briefly return to this issue by examining the correlations of the three proxies for real

marginal cost with inflation and unemployment. The results shown in the table below indicate

potential problems with using the output gap and labour’s share of income as proxy for real

marginal cost. Note that the correlation between core CPI and the output gap (-0.007891) has

the wrong sign and the correlation between unemployment and labour’s share of income

(-0.012243) has the correct sign but it is very weak. In contrast, job finding probability’s

correlations with the output gap and labour’s share of income are relative strong.

Page 177: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

177

Table 6.10 Correlation Matrix of Three Proxies for Real Marginal Cost with Inflation and Unemployment

Core CPI

Job Finding

Probability Output Gap

Labour’s Share of

Income Unemployment

Core CPI 1.000000 0.282482 -0.007891 0.483455 0.333555

Job Finding Probability 0.282482 1.000000 0.489600 0.626852 -0.644585

Output Gap -0.007891 0.489600 1.000000 0.002727 -0.583569

Labour’s Share of Income 0.483455 0.626852 0.002727 1.000000 -0.012243

Unemployment 0.333555 -0.644585 -0.583569 -0.012243 1.000000

Note: The correlation matrix was computed using quarterly data from 1961q1 to 2010q1.

A useful way to picture the changes in the labour market in the past forty years is to

plot the unemployment rates and the average duration of unemployment over time. Both the

unemployment rates and the average duration of unemployment are counter cyclical and

should rise and fall over the business cycle together. Fig. 6.1 plots the unemployment rates

(percentages) and the average duration of unemployment (weeks) over the 1948M02 to

2010M08 period. As expected both the unemployment rates and the average duration of

unemployment are counter cyclical, they rise and fall over the business cycle together.

Page 178: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

178

Fig. 6.3 Changes in the unemployment rates and average duration of unemployment over time, monthly data from1948M01 to 2010M08.

Fig. 7.4 The difference between the average duration of unemployment series and the unemployment rate series, monthly data from1948M01 to 2010M08.

In principle, when the unemployment rates are high, it is more difficult for

unemployed workers to find jobs; as a result the corresponding average durations of

unemployment are higher. This pattern can be observed in Fig. 6.3, it also appears the

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

28

32

36

50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 00 05 10

Unemployment RateAverage Weeks Unemployed

0

4

8

12

16

20

24

28

50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 00 05 10

Average Weeks Unemployed - Unemployment Rate

Page 179: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

179

unemployment rate series leads the average duration of unemployment series by about a year.

The most puzzling aspect about Fig. 6.3 is that the average duration of unemployment series

is that it is trending upward while the unemployment rate series is relatively flat.

Alternatively, if the unemployment rates are not increasing over time, then why is it taking

longer for unemployed workers to find jobs? Fig. 6.4 is the difference between the average

duration of unemployment series and the unemployment rate series. There is no structural

relationship between the two series as the average duration of unemployment series is

measured in weeks and the unemployment rate series is measured in percentages. Our

objective is to examine the increases in the average duration of unemployment over time

taking on to account changes in the rates of unemployment over time. Fig. 6.4 shows the

differences between the series have increased over time; note the every consecutive peak is

higher than the previous peaks since 1970. It is also interesting to note that the plot of the

probability of an unemployed worker finding another job after fifteen weeks of

unemployment (Fig. 6.5) has decrease over the past forty years.

Fig. 6.5 The probability of finding a job after 15 weeks of unemployment (JFP), monthly data from 1948M01 to 2010M08.

Table 6.8 below presents the correlations between the unemployment rates (U), job

finding probability (JFP) and the average duration of unemployment (ADU) over time, our

objective is to examine changes in the labour market from 1948M02 to 2010M08. Note that

.1

.2

.3

.4

.5

.6

.7

50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 00 05 10

Job Finding Probability (JFP)

Page 180: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

180

job finding probability is highly correlated with the unemployment rates, in all of the sub-

sample periods except for the 1990M01-1999M12 sub-sample period the, job finding

probability and the unemployment rates are strongly (negatively) correlated, the correlation

between job finding probability and the unemployment rates for the full sample period is (-

0.725110) considerably smaller than that of the five sub-sample periods presented below, the

reason why the full sample period is considerably smaller is because of the 1990M01-

1999M12 sub-sample period (-0.551872) is not as strongly correlated .

Table 6.11 Correlations between the Unemployment Rates (U), Job Finding Probability (JFP) and the Average Duration of Unemployment (ADU) Over Time.

1948m02-1959m12 U JFP ADU

U 1.000000 -0.904210 0.655632

JFP -0.904210 1.000000 -0.719688

ADU 0.655632 -0.719688 1.000000

1960m01-1969m12 U JFP ADU

U 1.000000 -0.950548 0.913184

JFP -0.950548 1.000000 -0.914924

ADU 0.913184 -0.914924 1.000000

1970m01-1979m12 U JFP ADU

U 1.000000 -0.939867 0.827902

JFP -0.939867 1.000000 -0.818318

ADU 0.827902 -0.818318 1.000000

1980m01-1989m12 U JFP ADU

U 1.000000 -0.945308 0.658850

JFP -0.945308 1.000000 -0.692156

ADU 0.658850 -0.692156 1.000000

1990m01-1999m12 U JFP ADU

U 1.000000 -0.551872 0.456313

JFP -0.551872 1.000000 -0.831802

ADU 0.456313 -0.831802 1.000000

2000m01-2010m08 U JFP ADU

U 1.000000 -0.933880 0.889543

JFP -0.933880 1.000000 -0.877470

Page 181: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

181

ADU 0.889543 -0.877470 1.000000

1948M02-2010M08 U JFP ADU

U 1.000000 -0.725110 0.639816

JFP -0.725110 1.000000 -0.874810

ADU 0.639816 -0.874810 1.000000

Note: Monthly Data from 1948M01 to 2010M08.

�������������������������������k�������������i��i��������������i����i��i�������������

The Phillips curve relationship predicts that inflation rises when the labour market

tightens, this relationship appears to have broken down in the 1990s (Brayton, Roberts, and

Williams, 1999) due to the information technology revolution, which allows goods and

services to be produced more cheaply, dramatically increasing economic productivity,

producing a deflationary environment. The three graphs below show what happened to the

labour market and the Phillips curve relationship during the economic expansion of the1990s.

Fig. 6.6 shows that the unemployment rate fell while core inflation (Fig. 6.7) and labour’s

share of income (Fig. 6.8) fell in the 1990s. These empirical data are at odds with the Phillips

curve relationship. Our results also show (Table 6.8) that in the last decade (2000M01-

2010M08) the Phillips curve relationship appears to resume its normal pattern.

Fig. 7.6 Unemployment rate, quarterly data from 1961q1 to 2010q1.

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Unemployment

Page 182: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

182

Fig. 6.7 Core CPI, quarterly data from 1961q1 to 2010q1.

Fig. 6.8 Labour’s share of income, quarterly data from 1961q1 to 2010q1.

.00

.02

.04

.06

.08

.10

.12

.14

1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Core CPI

4.48

4.52

4.56

4.60

4.64

4.68

1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010

Labour's Share of Income

Page 183: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

183

6.6 Conclusion

We have presented evidence of the flattening of the Phillips curve using job finding

probability, the output gap and labour’s share of income as proxies for real marginal cost.

Our results confirmed previous of empirical studies that the slope Phillips curve for the

United States has become much smaller over the past 20 years.

We have also examined some of the competing explanations given for why this has

occurred. Currently, there is no consensus regarding what explains this phenomenon, many of

the proposed explanations can be broadly categorized as: globalization and improvements in

the conduct of monetary policy. We believe that structural changes in the labour market in the

past forty years can partly account for this phenomenon. Our view is that deindustrialization

and the computer revolution have shifted employment from the manufacturing sectors to the

service sectors; these structural changes in the labour market have changed jobs’ skill

requirements, increasing heterogeneity (real rigidities) between workers, producing more

mismatches in the labour market. Increase in the division of labour implies that it would take

longer for unemployed workers to be retrained in order to find employment in another

profession and since much of professional knowledge cannot be transferred easily, the

process of education and training can be very lengthy, this is reflected by the fact that the

average duration of unemployment has been increasing since 1970 and the probability of

finding a job after 15 weeks of unemployment has been decreasing since 1970, this about the

same time that deindustrialization started in the United States. In other words, inflation is less

responsive to changes in real marginal cost, because of increase in the level of real rigidities

in the labour market, reducing the inflation-output tradeoffs and reducing the slope of the

reduced form Phillips curve.

The findings that inflation has become less responsive to real marginal cost is

generally interpreted as a positive output / unemployment gap would be less inflationary, but,

the cost of reducing inflation would be greater (Mishkin 2007. p.5).

“The finding that inflation is less responsive to the unemployment gap, suggests that

fluctuations in resource utilization will have smaller implications for inflation than

used to be the case. From the point of view of policymakers, this development is a

two-edged sword: On the plus side, it implies that an overheating economy will tend

to generate a smaller increase in inflation. On the negative side, however, a flatter

Phillips curve also implies that a given increase in inflation will be more costly to

wring out of the system”.

Page 184: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

184

The stylized fact that inflation has become less responsive to the output /

unemployment gap can lead to inappropriate policy recommendations. For example, the

above interpretations suggest that policymakers could respond less to shocks as inflation is

likely to remain at a low level. Similarly, policymakers may think that reducing inflation is

very costly because it causes extended periods of high unemployment. However, if the

monetary authorities were to become complacent about high inflation then inflation

expectations would raise as the monetary authorities’ credibility erode. This is because the

actual causes of the flattening of the Phillips curve are structural changes in the labour market

have changed jobs’ skill requirements, increasing heterogeneity between workers, producing

more mismatches in the labour market. The policy recommendations of our approach are

monetary authorities should continue to be aggressive against high inflation and try to reduce

unemployment by focusing on providing more flexible education and retraining to

unemployed workers in order to reduce the number of mismatches in the labour market.

Page 185: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

185

6.7 Appendix to Chapter 6

Table 6.12 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation Expectations and with Job Finding Probability as Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Equation estimated 1 4� � � � � � ��� �

Sample Period Constant �

� 2�

1974q2 to 1979q4 -0.3478 2.1697

-4.769196 0.0001

16.2519 3.4424

4.721147 0.0001

0.964604 0.081229 11.87507

0.0000

-0.1885 0.1585

-1.189475 0.2489

0.902782

1980q1 to 1989q4 -2.5445 1.2766

-1.993109 0.0539

2.8166 1.8007

1.564171 0.1265

0.688868 0.063846 10.78946

0.0000

0.4637 0.1015

4.569802 0.0001

0.963142

1990q1 to 1999q4 -0.9249

0.4397 -2.103604

0.0425

1.1904

0.6466 1.840892

0.0739

0.900403

0.042131 21.37166

0.0000

0.1440

0.0594 2.424464

0.0205

0.971489

2000q1 to 2004q4 -0.7239 0.4996

-1.449069 0.1666

1.4699 1.1635

1.263371 0.2246

0.715507 0.095620 7.482806

0.0000

0.2156 0.2362

0.912973 0.3748

0.912290

1974q2 to 2004q4 -2.0383

0.6129 -3.325868

0.0012

2.8926

0.9034 3.201940

0.0018

0.771316

0.036179 21.31939

0.0000

0.2721

0.0490 5.556442

0.0000

0.969977

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

Page 186: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

186

Table 6.13 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation Expectations and the Output Gap as Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Equation estimated 1 4� � � � � � ��� �

Sample Period Constant �

� 2�

1974q2 to 1979q4 -0.8595 1.3413

-0.640745 0.5293

-0.0255 0.2563

-0.099624 0.9217

0.792699 0.139144 5.696983

0.0000

0.4065 0.2578

1.576962 0.1313

0.788844

1980q1 to 1989q4 -0.5286 0.2683

-1.970005 0.0566

0.1063 0.1104

0.962960 0.3420

0.715227 0.082524 8.666881

0.0000

0.4327 0.1266

3.417682 0.0016

0.961625

1990q1 to 1999q4 -0.1764 0.1052

-1.677867 0.1020

0.0785 0.0424

1.851448 0.0723

0.926440 0.047156 19.64633

0.0000

0.1491 0.0584

2.555005 0.0150

0.971517

2000q1 to 2004q4 0.0653 0.2098

0.311427 0.7595

0.0645 0.0349

1.849142 0.0830

0.804781 0.096216 8.364295

0.0000

0.2432 0.1775

1.369877 0.1896

0.920525

1974q2 to 2004q4 -0.0756 0.0936

-0.807661 0.4209

0.0729 0.0525

1.389478 0.1673

0.769025 0.043109 17.83888

0.0000

0.3005 0.0554

5.426263 0.0000

0.967911

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

Page 187: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

187

Table 6.14 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation Expectations and Labour’s Share of Income as Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Equation estimated 1 4� � � � � � ��� �

Sample Period Constant �

2�

1974q2 to 1979q4 -196.1680 41.8839

-4.683617 0.0002

42.5845 9.1274

4.665557 0.0002

0.785903 0.074050 10.61317

0.0000

0.1821 0.1112

1.637214 0.1180

0.901538

1980q1 to 1989q4 -33.4202 46.2144

-0.723156 0.4743

7.1305 10.0367

0.710441 0.4820

0.611338 0.097587 6.264552

0.0000

0.5489 0.1152

4.763130 0.0000

0.961181

1990q1 to 1999q4 -28.3498 15.9048

-1.782465 0.0831

6.1664 3.4763

1.773820 0.0846

0.812334 0.057643 14.09257

0.0000

0.2237 0.0596

3.751342 0.0006

0.971313

2000q1 to 2004q4 13.9816 14.2646

0.980160 0.3416

-3.1186 3.1502

-0.989981 0.3369

0.780649 0.104514

7.469341 0.0000

0.5417 0.1719

3.151705 0.0062

0.909108

1974q2 to 2004q4 -30.3699 15.3652

-1.976539 0.0504

6.6019 3.3508

1.970267 0.0511

0.704955 0.038422 18.34751

0.0000

0.3415 0.0444

7.697371 0.0000

0.968420

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

Page 188: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

188

Table 6.15 Tests for Structural Changes in the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using Dummy Variable

Equation estimated 1 1 4 1� � � � � � � �� � �� � ���

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

� � �

2�

Job Finding Probability

-0.956100 0.203693

-4.693825 0.0000

0.241879 0.599811 0.403258

0.6872

1.508475 0.553349 2.726084

0.0070

0.829779 0.020103 41.27724

0.0000

0.214447 0.025289 8.479782

0.0000

-0.370907 1.223745

-0.303092 0.7622

0.972400

Output Gap

-0.423949 0.086889

-4.879195 0.0000

0.222078 0.085807 2.588108

0.0104

0.041591 0.030803 1.350214

0.1786

0.841395 0.022626 37.18675

0.0000

0.218488 0.027642 7.904101

0.0000

0.123182 0.201625 0.610949

0.5420

0.971607

Labour’s Share of Income

-12.71181 6.540321

-1.943606 0.0534

-6.548806 23.64840

-0.276924 0.7821

2.677197 1.429767 1.872471

0.0627

0.809474 0.022222 36.42745

0.0000

0.238260 0.024299 9.805554

0.0000

1.453413 5.121363 0.283794

0.7769

0.971861

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1961q1 2010q1period using quarterly data. Standard

errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The Michigan survey of inflation expectations was used as proxy for expected inflation. 1

1� for

observations from 1961q1-1969q4. 1

0� for observations from 1970q1-2010q1.

Page 189: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

189

Table 6.16 Tests for Structural Changes in the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using Dummy Variable

Equation estimated 2 1 4 2� � � � � � � �� � �� � � ��

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

� � �

2�

Job Finding Probability

-1.029293 0.187037

-5.503145 0.0000

-0.097921 0.748133

-0.130887 0.8960

1.707787 0.430574 3.966306

0.0001

0.829194 0.022707 36.51741

0.0000

0.219421 0.028016 7.831925

0.0000

-0.005353 1.661376

-0.003222 0.9974

0.972517

Output Gap

-0.359523 0.087330

-4.116822 0.0001

-0.040215 0.091712

-0.438493 0.6615

0.056735 0.031936 1.776528

0.0772

0.826212 0.025676 32.17855

0.0000

0.228649 0.033625 6.799955

0.0000

-0.085229 0.078177

-1.090214 0.2770

0.970616

Labour’s Share of Income

-13.38052 6.219169

-2.151496 0.0327

-63.08480 23.28421

-2.709339 0.0074

2.838875 1.353643 2.097211

0.0373

0.820246 0.022817 35.94898

0.0000

0.222489 0.026595 8.365964

0.0000

13.61638 5.034599 2.704560

0.0075

0.972664

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1961q1 2010q1period using quarterly data. Standard

errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The Michigan survey of inflation expectations was used as proxy for expected inflation. 2

1� for

observations from 1970q1-1979q4. 2

0� for observations from 1961q1-1969q4, 1980q1-2010q1.

Page 190: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

190

Table 6.17 Tests for Structural Changes in the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using Dummy Variable

Equation estimated 3 1 4 3� � � � � � � �� � �� � ���

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

� � �

2�

Job Finding Probability

-0.908526 0.175804

-5.167825 0.0000

-1.041934 0.683685

-1.523997 0.1292

1.464979 0.422976 3.463500

0.0007

0.836745 0.021996 38.04109

0.0000

0.205395 0.024559 8.363477

0.0000

2.446806 1.610797 1.519003

0.1304

0.972668

Output Gap

-0.334938 0.077657

-4.313035 0.0000

-0.048341 0.083994

-0.575524 0.5656

0.012863 0.032817 0.391972

0.6955

0.848895 0.024459 34.70676

0.0000

0.204064 0.027805 7.339038

0.0000

0.229085 0.069776 3.283130

0.0012

0.972033

Labour’s Share of Income

-19.44300 5.718131

-3.400236 0.0008

54.55742 21.73017 2.510676

0.0129

4.152396 1.246158 3.332158

0.0010

0.822545 0.023981 34.30004

0.0000

0.222929 0.024313 9.169288

0.0000

-11.82353 4.706097

-2.512385 0.0128

0.972338

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1961q1 2010q1period using quarterly data. Standard

errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The Michigan survey of inflation expectations was used as proxy for expected inflation. 3 1� for

observations from 1980q1-1989q4. 3 0� for observations from 1961q1-1979q4, 1990q1-2010q1.

Page 191: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

191

Table 6.18 Tests for Structural Changes in the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using Dummy Variable

Equation estimated 4 1 4 4� � � � � � � �� � �� � � ��

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

� � �

2�

Job Finding Probability

-0.978865 0.182752

-5.356244 0.0000

-0.138367 0.713775

-0.193853 0.8465

1.629931 0.426163 3.824664

0.0002

0.828715 0.020061 41.31037

0.0000

0.210848 0.024309 8.673796

0.0000

0.399928 1.813380 0.220543

0.8257

0.972349

Output Gap

-0.314476 0.084674

-3.713978 0.0003

-0.023036 0.079905

-0.288295 0.7734

0.050917 0.032560 1.563818

0.1195

0.838875 0.023075 36.35360

0.0000

0.207027 0.028088 7.370592

0.0000

-0.010487 0.098100

-0.106902 0.9150

0.970426

Labour’s Share of Income

-17.29987 5.893691

-2.935321 0.0037

-19.93698 27.63748

-0.721375 0.4716

3.693002 1.283754 2.876722

0.0045

0.798081 0.021769 36.66195

0.0000

0.234441 0.024379 9.616683

0.0000

4.338571 6.012074 0.721643

0.4714

0.971470

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1961q1 2010q1period using quarterly data. Standard

errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The Michigan survey of inflation expectations was used as proxy for expected inflation. 4 1� for

observations from 1990q1-1999q4. 4 0� for observations from 1961q1-1989q4, 2000q1-2010q1.

Page 192: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

192

Table 6.19 Tests for Structural Changes in the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using Dummy Variable

Equation estimated 5 1 4 5� � � � � � � �� � �� � � ��

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

� � �

2�

Job Finding Probability

-1.113176 0.256053

-4.347440 0.0000

0.258833 0.422148 0.613134

0.5405

1.926565 0.571570 3.370655

0.0009

0.835026 0.022030 37.90374

0.0000

0.205547 0.025007 8.219701

0.0000

-0.569215 1.116865

-0.509654 0.6109

0.972410

Output Gap

-0.252029 0.085363

-2.952446 0.0036

-0.117601 0.082191

-1.430833 0.1541

0.117646 0.047118 2.496855

0.0134

0.846135 0.025423 33.28247

0.0000

0.191797 0.029344 6.536083

0.0000

-0.115548 0.057688

-2.002967 0.0466

0.971401

Labour’s Share of Income

-19.13433 9.518616

-2.010201 0.0458

3.758474 13.54201 0.277542

0.7817

4.093617 2.069095 1.978457

0.0493

0.798684 0.021914 36.44677

0.0000

0.231792 0.024417 9.493055

0.0000

-0.821853 2.949270

-0.278663 0.7808

0.971406

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the1961q1 2010q1period using quarterly data. Standard

errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The Michigan survey of inflation expectations was used as proxy for expected inflation. 5 1� for

observations from2000q1-2010q1. 5 0� for observations from 1961q1-1999q4.

Page 193: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

193

CHAPTER 7

Non-Stationary Inflation and the Phillips Curve

7.1 Introduction

This chapter argues that the finding that the United States inflation rates are non-

stationary8 does not necessarily invalidate a previous body of empirical research that did not

take into account the non-stationary behaviour of inflation. This chapter is structured as

follows: The first section examines if inflation and various proxies for real marginal cost and

various survey measures of inflation expectations are non-stationary. The second section

examines if inflation is cointergrated with these variables. The third section examines if

cointergration between inflation and various proxies for real marginal cost and inflation and

various survey measures of inflation expectations lead to spurious regression problems. The

fourth section concludes.

7.2 Time Series Properties of the Variables in the Phillips Curve

The standard new Keynesian Phillips curve builds on the pioneering work of Taylor

(1979, 1980), Rotemberg (1982) and Calvo (1983) has the form:

1[ ]� � � �� �� (7.1)

Inflation depends on expectations of future inflation and on real marginal cost. The

implication of this model is that inflation should be independent of its own lagged values.

This specification has often been criticized because it does not fit the data well; empirical

studies have shown that inflation can be predicted well from its own lagged value. Simple

regressions of inflation on its own lags have much higher 2� values than the NKPC in

equation (7.1). Furthermore, the coefficient of real marginal cost traditionally represented by

the output gap often has the wrong sign or is not statistically significant.

Before we formally test to see if various variables in the Phillips curve are non-

stationary we should anticipate what we expect to find. Economic theory suggests that

expected inflations should be able to track actual inflation “fairly closely” and the two

variables should have similar statistical properties, that is, if inflation is non-stationary then

we should expect survey measures of inflation expectations to be non-stationary. If actual

inflation and expected inflations are non-stationary, then we should expect that that the two

variables are cointergrated because there should be a long-run relationship between the two

variables. These predictions are made based on the assumption that survey measures of

8I thank an anonymous examiner for raising this point.

Page 194: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

194

inflation expectations are “reasonably” accurate. In chapter 5 (section 5.2) of this thesis we

examined if survey measures of inflation expectations are consistent with predictions of

rational expectations. In general we found that all of the survey measures of inflation are not

perfectly rational.

Empirical evidence suggests that there is a relationship between inflation and real

marginal cost in the short-run but not in the long-run. Empirical studies show that vigorous

economic activities tend to cause inflation to rise; this is known as the acceleration

phenomenon. However, there is no relationship between inflation and real marginal cost in

the long-run. That is, there in no positive relationship between inflation and economic growth

in the long-run. Thus, if inflation and real marginal cost are non-stationary, the two variables

should not be cointergrated, as cointergration implies that there is a long-run relationship

between the two variables.

We use core CPI as our measure of inflation. We considered three proxies for real

marginal cost: output gap (GAP), labour’s share of income (LS) and job finding probability

(JFP) (see section 5.3 of this thesis). We have also used three survey measures of inflation

expectations so proxies for expected inflation: the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF),

which collects inflation expectations from economists who forecast for a living, the Michigan

Survey, which collects forecasts from consumers and the “Greenbook” forecasts, which are

produced by the research staff at the Board of Governors before each meeting of the Federal

Open Market Committee (FOMC). For more details about the three survey measures of

inflation expectations above, please refer to section 5.3 of this thesis and the data appendix at

the end of this chapter.

First we examine if inflation and various proxies for real marginal cost and survey

measures of inflation expectations are non-stationary. The results of the Augmented Dickey-

Fuller (ADF), Phillips-Perron (PP) and Kwiatkowski-Phillips-Schmidt-Shin (KPSS) unit root

tests are reported in Table 7.1 below. All of the variables tested are first-order integrated I

(1), except for the output gap, which is stationary9.

9Culver and Papell (1997) using panel data unit root tests find that inflation is stationary.

Page 195: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

195

Table 7.1 Unit Root Tests

Variable Sample Period ADF PP KPSS

� 1961Q1 - 2010Q1 -1.217887 -2.199186 0.478868**

� 1961Q1 - 2010Q1 -6.579304*** -8.207592*** 0.135901

��� 1961Q1 - 2010Q1 -6.282778*** -4.462408*** 0.019618

��� 1961Q1 - 2010Q1 -10.19951*** -10.28453*** 0.023994

��� 1961Q1 - 2010Q1 -1.333538 -1.181570 1.066906***

��� 1961Q1 - 2010Q1 -7.209865*** -12.97946*** 0.200256

�� 1961Q1 - 2010Q1 -0.690982 -0.632463 1.271203

�� 1961Q1 - 2010Q1 -15.30225*** -15.28659*** 0.161550

��������K 1983Q3 - 2004Q4 -1.605328 -1.290914 1.188939***

��������K 1983Q3 - 2004Q4 -11.10034*** -11.81995*** 0.187039

��� 1983Q3 - 2004Q4 -1.305676 -1.127290 1.101983***

��� 1983Q3 - 2004Q4 -11.47386*** -11.59578*** 0.047702

�������� 1983Q3 - 2004Q4 -2.951347** -2.729120* 0.964585***

�������� 1983Q3 - 2004Q4 -12.24768*** -12.79873*** 0.050326

Notes: *** Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; * Significant at 10%. The lags in ADF are selected with

Schwartz Information Criterion. The PP and the KPSS test statistics were computed using Newey-West

automatic bandwidth selection. The null hypothesis in the ADF and the PP tests are that the variables are non-

stationary and are reversed in the KPSS tests.

7.3 Tests for Cointegration

Table 7.2 presents the results of the Engle-Granger two step tests for cointegration.

The first step of this test involves running a regression of inflation on each variable, saving

the residuals. The second step tests the residuals to determine if it is stationary. The two

series are said to be cointegrated if the residual is itself stationary. The results of the

Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF), Phillips-Perron (PP) and Kwiatkowski-Phillips-Schmidt-

Shin (KPSS) unit root tests of various residual series are reported below. Inflation is

cointegrated with LS, GREENBOOK, SPF and MICHIGAN but not with JFP.

Page 196: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

196

Table 7.2 Engle-Granger (EG) tests for Cointegration

���i����� Sample Period ��� PP K���

and �

��� 1961Q1 - 2010Q1 -2.506601 -2.372774 0.350030***

and LS� 1961Q1 - 2010Q1 -2.813170*** -3.024395** 0.249968

and GREENBOOK�

1983Q3 - 2004Q4 -4.148931*** -4.168483*** 0.249539

and SPF� 1983Q3 - 2004Q4 -3.186576** -4.133009*** 0.110301

and MICHIGAN�

1983Q3 - 2004Q4 -3.684830*** -3.714469*** 0.609870**

Notes: *** Significant at 1%; **Significant at 5%; * Significant at 10%. The lags in ADF are selected with

Schwartz Information Criterion. The PP and the KPSS test statistics were computed using Newey-West

automatic bandwidth selection. The null hypothesis in the ADF and the PP tests are that the variables are non-

stationary and are reversed in the KPSS tests.

As expected we found that actual inflation and the three survey measures of inflation

expectations are cointergrated, implying that there is a long-run relationship between actual

inflation and expected inflation. Our results also show that labour’s share of income and job

finding probability are first-order integrated I (1) and actual inflation is cointergrated with

labour’s share of income but not job finding probability. This implies that there is a long-run

relationship between actual inflation and job labour’s share of income, but there is no long-

run relationship between actual inflation and job finding probability. The finding that actual

inflation is cointergrated with labour’s share of income is not consistent with economic

theory and empirical evidence on monetary policy which suggest that there in no positive

relationship between inflation and economic growth in the long-run. This leads us to question

whether labour’s share of income is an appropriate proxy for real marginal cost.

7.4 Does Non-Stationary Inflation Invalidate Previous Research Findings?

Many empirical studies on the NKPC simply assume that inflation is stationary. Does

the finding that inflation is non-stationary invalidate previous research findings? The answer

to this question essentially depends on whether the cointergration between actual inflation

and expected inflation leads to spurious regression problem. A spurious regression refer to a

regression that seem to give a good fit and statistically significant relationship between

variables, but this relationship does not really exist. This problem was first recognized by

Yule in 1926. Hendry (1980) provides an example of spurious regression involving inflation;

Page 197: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

197

he shows that cumulative rainfall in the UK provided an excellent statistical explanation of

inflation.

Granger and Newbold (1974, p.111) began their paper by observing that many

econometric studies tend to have very high 2� and very low Durbin-Watson (DW) statistics

(residuals are autocorrelated). They wanted to determine what could be inferred from these

regression results.

“It is very common to see reported in applied econometric literature time series

regression equations with an apparently high degree of fit, as measured by the

coefficient of multiple correlation 2� or the corrected coefficient

2� , but with an

extremely low value for the Durbin-Watson statistic. We find it very curious that

whereas virtually every textbook on econometric methodology contains explicit

warnings of the dangers of autocorrelated errors, this phenomenon crops up so

frequently in well-respected applied work. Numerous examples could be cited, but

doubtless the reader has met sufficient cases to accept our point. It would, for

example, be easy to quote published equations for which 2� = 0.997 and the Durbin-

Watson statistic (d) is 0.53. The most extreme example we have met is an equation for

which 2� = 0.99 and d = 0.093”.

Granger and Newbold (1974) then showed that the regression of two generated

random walks series can generate spurious regression results with very high 2� and very low

Durbin-Watson (DW) statistics. Granger and Newbold (1974, p.117) suggested that the DW

statistics could be used to identify spurious regressions, they argued that a low DW statistic is

a strong indication that the model is misspecified.

“It has been well known for some time now that if one performs a regression and

finds the residual series is strongly autocorrelated, then there are serious problems in

interpreting the coefficients of the equation. Despite this, many papers still appear

with equations having such symptoms and these equations are presented as though

they have some worth. It is possible that earlier warnings have been stated

insufficiently strongly. From our own studies we would conclude that if a regression

equation relating economic variables is found to have strongly autocorrelated

residuals, equivalent to a low Durbin-Watson value, the only conclusion that can be

reached is that the equation is mis-specified, whatever the value of 2� observed”.

Page 198: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

198

Much of the empirical studies on the NKPC that do not take into account the time

series properties of inflation. However, the mains problems that applied macroeconomists

face regarding the NKPC are the opposite to the problems of spurious regressions (the model

fits the data but the theory doesn’t make sense). To many applied macroeconomists the

NKPC makes sense (has strong microfoundations and is consistent with the assumption of

rational expectations) but it does not fit the data well enough; the real marginal cost variable

often has the wrong sign or is not statistically significant (note that the coefficient of the

output gap has the wrong sign (-0.017298) below. Backward-looking inflation expectations

tend to dominate forward-looking inflation expectations. Furthermore, tests the rationality of

various survey measures of inflation expectations often indicates that survey measures of

inflation expectations are biased and inefficient (see chapter 5). Table 7.3 below presents the

results of the regressions of core inflation and various proxies for real marginal cost; note that

the 2� values are very low; there are no indications of spurious regression between core

inflation and various proxies for real marginal cost.

Table 7.3 Estimations of Core Inflation and Various Proxies for Real Marginal Cost

Equation Estimated � ��� �

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

c 2�

Output Gap

4.001954 0.178681

22.39724 0.0000

-0.017298 0.156975

-0.110196 0.9124

0.000062

Job Finding Probability

1.185544 0.981961 1.207322

0.2288

6.766642 2.321302 2.915020

0.0040

0.041757

Labour’s Share of Income

-194.1364 25.69185

-7.556341 0.0000

43.00261 5.575876 7.712261

0.0000

0.233728

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1961q1 to 2010q1 period using quarterly

data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

Table 7.4 below presents the results of the regressions of core inflation and various

proxies for expected inflation. This table is the same as table 6.3, the results of our test for

unbiasedness in chapter 5. Note that the 2� values are reasonably high, but not as high as

(i.e. 0.99) some of the examples given by Granger and Newbold (1974, p.111) mentioned

Page 199: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

199

above. The chi-square statistics are associated with the test for unbiasedness ( 0 1��� ).

Our results show that unbiasedness is rejected for all survey measures of inflation

expectations.

Table 7.4 Estimations of Core Inflation and Various Proxies for Expected Inflation

Equation Estimated �

� � ��

Survey Sample Period 2� 2

�����

SPF 1� �� 981Q3 2010Q1

-0.286400 0.146800

-1.950993 0.053600

1.103100 0.042800

25.793870 0.000000

0.855916 6.534639 (0.03810)

Greenbook 1� �� 1974Q2 2004Q4

0.435100 0.127700 3.406809 0.000900

1.055800 0.027000

39.129390 0.000000

0.926760

104.271400 ( 0.00000)

Michigan 4� �� 1981Q3 2010Q1

-0.886700 0.277200

-3.198671 0.001800

0.986400 0.061900

15.922160 0.000000

0.691691 125.953800 (0.00000)

SPF 4� �� 1981Q3 2010Q1

0.306300 0.164400 1.862752 0.065200

0.805300 0.044800

17.988780 0.000000

0.748033 65.224080 (0.00000)

Greenbook 4� �� 1974Q3 2004Q4

0.117100 0.205000 0.571358 0.568800

1.150800 0.046000

25.043340 0.000000

0.840519 64.676310 (0.00000)

Note: The above equations were estimated using Ordinary Least Square (OLS). Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row. Chi-squared statistics of null

hypothesis that 0 1��� and its p-values (in parentheses) are shown in the last column.

Table 7.5 below presents the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated using

the Greenbook forecasts for over the next year as proxy for inflation expectations produces

relatively high 2� values; all coefficients of backward-looking and forward-looking inflation

expectations terms are statistically significant at 1% level. Durbin-Watson (DW) test

statistics in the second last column indicate that the residuals are not autocorrelated.

However, it is well known that if there are lagged dependent variables DW test statistics are

biased and therefore not valid. A more general test is the Breusch-Godfrey LM test which can

be used if there are lagged dependent variables. Note that the DW test and the LM test do not

Page 200: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

200

directly test for spurious regressions; they test for autocorrelated in the residuals which

indicate if the equation is mis-specified. The LM tests indicate that the hybrid new Keynesian

Phillips curve is correctly specified, which implies that it is unlikely that there is spurious

regression problems in the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve.

Table 7.5 Estimations of the New Hybrid Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Greenbook Forecasts as Proxy

for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 1� � � � � � ��� �

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

� 2� DW LM

Job Finding Probability

-0.176181 0.192467

-0.915379 0.3627

0.696364 0.537414 1.295767

0.1987

0.818194 0.035900 22.79122

0.0000

0.175051 0.036245 4.829656

0.0000

0.966453 1.732890 1.525448 (0.4664)

Output Gap

0.073622

0.070396 1.045828

0.2987

0.042883

0.026428 1.622649

0.1085

0.832989

0.036606 22.75522

0.0000

0.167755

0.036815 4.556729

0.0000

0.966831 1.765637 1.148143

(0.5632)

Labour’s Share of Income

-15.76281 8.293264

-1.900677 0.0609

3.455126 1.811325 1.907514

0.0600

0.792443 0.038237 20.72435

0.0000

0.192746 0.034035 5.663135

0.0000

0.967221 1.765039 1.260767 (0.5324)

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1983q3 to 2004q4 period using quarterly data.

Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row. Durbin-Watson (DW) test statistics are presented in the second last column. The Breusch-Godfrey LM test statistics associated with null hypothesis that there is no serial correlation and its p-values (in parentheses) are shown in the last column.

If there is spurious regression problem in the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve,

then the source of the problem is most likely to be due to the expected inflation variable,

because actual inflation and expected inflation are cointergrated. If that is the case, then

estimations of the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve should show very high 2� values, the

residuals are autocorrelated and the expected inflation variable should be highly statistical

significant. Our results shows that the 2� values are relatively high, but this is because

lagged inflation is highly correlated with actual inflation, note that backward-looking

inflation expectations dominate forward-looking inflation expectations independent of which

measures of real marginal cost are used. Furthermore, The LM test statistics in the last

Page 201: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

201

column indicate that the residuals are not autocorrelated. In short, these results suggest that

spurious regression is not a problem in the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve.

In a paper on spurious regression called “Econometrics – Alchemy or Science?”

David Hendry (1980, p.390) warns of the flaws of regression analysis.

“Econometricians have their Philosophers’ Stone; it is called regression analysis and

is used for transforming data into “significant” results! Deception is easily practised

from false recipes intended to simulate useful findings and these are derogatively

referred to by the profession as “nonsense regressions”.

We have considered David Hendry’s (1980, p.390) warning of the flaws of regression

analysis. We are confident that the variables in the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve are

not “nonsense variables”. As mentioned in chapter 1, the main objectives of new Keynesian

economics are to derive Keynesian propositions with rational expectations and optimizing

behaviours, not just producing models that fit the data. The problem is the new Keynesian

Phillips curve is it does not includes lagged inflation as an explanatory variable; the NKPC

implies inflation is a purely forward variable; current inflation is proportional to real marginal

cost and expected inflation. It has been well known for some time now that lagged inflation

plays an important role in empirical inflation regressions; simple regressions of inflation on

its own lags have much higher 2� values than the NKPC. This has led some economists to

question the validity of the assumption of rational expectations and to provide a plausible

rationale for the inclusion of lagged inflation as an explanatory variable in the Phillips curve.

7.5 Conclusion

We have examined time series properties for the main variables (real marginal cost

and expected inflation) of the new Keynesian Phillips curve and its relationships with

inflation. We found that all of the variables tested are first-order integrated I (1), except for

the output gap, which is stationary. Our cointegration tests show that actual inflation and the

three survey measures of inflation expectations are cointergrated and inflation is

cointergrated with labour’s share of income. We follow Granger and Newbold’s (1974,

p.117) suggestion and tested the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips for autocorrelation in the

residuals as a mean for identifying spurious regression problems. Our tests (LM) for

autocorrelation in the residuals suggest that the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve is

Page 202: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

202

correctly specified, implying that it is unlikely that there is spurious regression problems in

the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve.

The finding that the inflation rates are non-stationary does not invalidate previous

body of empirical research, but instead it complements previous studies. It has been well

known for sometime now that inflation is persistence (see chapter 2). The persistence of

inflation is a central concern to macroeconomists and central bankers and it has implications

for the specifications of the Phillips curve and the conduct of monetary policy. If there a unit

root in inflation, then it is implies that the pure forward-looking New Keynesian Phillips

curve is likely to be mispecified. Indeed, much of the New Keynesian Phillips curve literature

in recent years is about the inability of the pure forward-looking New Keynesian Phillips

curve to generate sufficient persistence in inflation. This has motivated some economists to

incorporate backward-looking inflation expectations term in the New Keynesian Phillips (see

chapter 2). From a central banker’s perspective the persistence of inflation implies that

disinflation is contractionary. Furthermore, the finding that actual inflation and the three

survey measures of inflation expectations are cointergrated implies that there is a long-run

relationship between actual inflation and expected inflation, which is consistent with the

notion that people’s future expectations matter. This implies that the old Keynesian Phillips

curve is likely to be mispecified as it does not include expected inflation as an explanatory

variable.

Page 203: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

203

7.6 Appendix to Chapter 7 Table 7.5 Definitions and Sources of Data

Variable Definition Source

� Inflation is measured as 1004

ln �

� using core

CPI. Consumer Price Index (All Items Less Food and Energy), Index 1982-1984=100. Source:

Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

JFP Job Finding Probability. Constructed from the number of unemployed workers, the number of short term (5 weeks) unemployed workers and the number of unemployed workers next month using Shimer’s (2005) formulation.

Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

GAP Output Gap (Nonfarm Business Sector Output, Index

2005=100), using the Hodrick-Prescott filter with a smoothing parameter of 1600.

Bureau of Labor Statistics

(BLS).

LS Labour’s Share of Income (Nonfarm Business Sector, Index 1992=100).

Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).

MICHIGAN Represents the mean forecasts of the Michigan Survey for the fourth quarter after the current quarter.

www.src.isr.umich.edu/

G1 Greenbook forecasts for the GNP/GDP price level for the first quarter after the current quarter.

http://www.philadelphiafed.org/research-and-data/real-time-center/greenbook-data/

GREENBOOK Greenbook forecasts for the GNP/GDP price level for the fourth quarter after the current quarter.

http://www.philadelphiafed.org/research-and-data/real-time-center/greenbook-data/

M1 Represents the mean forecasts of the SPF for the first quarter after the current quarter.

www.philadelphiafed.org/.../survey-of-professional-forecasters/

SFP Represents the mean forecasts of the SPF for the fourth quarter after the current quarter.

www.philadelphiafed.org/.../survey-of-professional-forecasters/

S1 Represents the median forecasts of the SPF for the first quarter after the current quarter.

www.philadelphiafed.org/.../survey-of-professional-forecasters/

S4 Represents the median forecasts of the SPF for the fourth quarter after the current quarter.

www.philadelphiafed.org/.../survey-of-professional-forecasters/

� �

Page 204: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

204

�����������i����������i��������i����������������i���������

Fig. 7.1 core CPI, output gap (GAP), labour’s share of income (LS) and job finding

probability (JFP), quarterly data from 1961q1 to 2010q1.

-4

-2

0

2

4

65 70 75 80 85 90 95 00 05 10

GAP

.1

.2

.3

.4

.5

.6

65 70 75 80 85 90 95 00 05 10

JFP

4.48

4.52

4.56

4.60

4.64

4.68

65 70 75 80 85 90 95 00 05 10

LS

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

65 70 75 80 85 90 95 00 05 10

CORE CPI

Page 205: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

205

�����������i����������i��������i����������������������i���

Fig. 7.2 core CPI, the “Greenbook” forecasts, the Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF)

and the “Michigan” Survey, quarterly data from 1983q3 to 2004q4.

1

2

3

4

5

6

84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04

CORE CPI

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04

GREENBOOK

1

2

3

4

5

6

84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04

SPF

1

2

3

4

5

6

84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04

MICHIGAN

Page 206: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

206

CHAPTER 8

Estimations of the Phillips Curve for Australia with Different Proxies for Real Marginal

Cost

8.1 Introduction

In their influential paper, Gali and Gertler (1999) argue that the reason why the new

Keynesian Phillips curve (NKPC) fits the data poorly is because traditional empirical work

on the Phillips curve uses some output gap measures as a proxy for real marginal cost rather

than labour’s share of income. Gali and Gertler (1999) also raise two related issues: First, the

NKPC needs to take into account labour market frictions. Second, the output gap may not be

an appropriate proxy for real economic activity because it assumes that the labour market

clears. The main purpose of this chapter is to address the two issues raised by Gali and

Gertler (1999) mentioned above by using job finding probability (JFP) as proxy for real

marginal cost. We re-examined Gali and Gertler (1999) empirical results by estimating

various specifications of the Phillips curve for Australia using three proxies for real marginal

cost: job finding probability (JFP), the output gap and labour’s share of income. We found

that the three as proxies for real marginal cost performed equally well when the old

Keynesian Phillips curve is estimated. Labour’s share of income is the best proxy for real

marginal cost when the new Keynesian Phillips curve is estimated. Job finding probability is

marginally a better proxy for real marginal cost than the output gap and labour’s share of

income when the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve is estimated. We also found that

backward inflation expectations looking dominate forward-looking inflation expectations

independent of which measures of real marginal cost are used.

This chapter is structured as follows: The first section briefly review the Australian

new Keynesian Phillips curve literature. The second section compares the empirical

appropriateness of job finding probability (JFP), the output gap and labour’s share of income

as proxies for real marginal cost. The third section considers three robustness exercises: The

first robustness exercise examines sub-sample stability. The second robustness exercise uses

the Consumer Price Index instead of the Reserve Bank of Australia’s analytical measures of

consumer price inflation to examine if our initial results are robust. The third robustness

exercise estimates the new Keynesian Phillips curve and the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips

curve using GMM. The fourth section concludes.

Page 207: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

207

8.2 The Australian Phillips Curve

The first Australian Phillips Curve was estimated by A.W. Phillips in 1959, during

Phillips’ sabbatical year in Australia at the University of Melbourne. The equation Phillips

estimated related wage inflation to unemployment; this specification influenced many early

studies of the Australian Phillips curve. Gruen, Pagan and Thompson (1999, pp.9-10) provide

a summary of these works. The emergence of the new Keynesian economics, which

emphasises the importance of microeconomic foundations to the Phillips curve, incorporated

rational expectations to the Phillips curve theoretic (Fischer (1977), Taylor (1979, 1980) and

Calvo (1983)). More recent studies of the Australian Phillips Curve tend to relate price

inflation to the output gap and inflation expectations. In addition, empirical studies on the

Australian Phillips curve tend to focus on backward-looking inflation expectations, as it fits

the data better than the pure forward-looking new Keynesian Phillips curve. Gali and

Gertler’s (1999) hybrid specification is also popular. In an open economy setting, price

inflation is determined by a weighted average of domestic and imported inflation, with the

latter equal to the change in real import prices and the former determined as per the standard

closed economy NKPC (Norman and Richards, 2010, p.4). Since Australia is a small open

economy, import prices could be an important determinant of domestic consumer price level,

as a result some empirical studies on the Australian Phillips curve include import prices as an

explanatory variable (See Gruen, Pagan and Thompson, 1999).

Some researchers (Debelle and Vickery 1998, p.386) have attempted to allow for

shifts in the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU) over time. Gregory

(1986) and Simes and Richardson (1987) allow for a time trend in their specification,

although it is not apparent whether this is necessarily capturing the shifts in the NAIRU. The

Treasury model (TRYM) allows for a once-off level shift in the NAIRU in 1974

(Commonwealth Treasury 1996). Debelle and Vickery (1998, p.384) compare the actual rates

of unemployment in Australia and the United States and argue that the assumption of a

constant NAIRU over the sample period may be appropriate in the United States, but not for

Australia. Gruen, Pagan and Thompson (1999, pp.236-237) discuss various ways to allow the

NAIRU to shift over time, a once-off level shift in the NAIRU is absorbed into the intercept,

“presenting the possibility of using statistical procedures to determine the number and

location of breaks in that coefficient. Once located, any shifts in the NAIRU could be

captured by a series of dummy variables”. Traditionally Australian studies have “not treated

Page 208: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

208

breaks in the NAIRU in such a formal manner. Instead, breaks in the NAIRU have been

imposed after an inspection of the history of the unemployment rate; the logic being that,

within a few years of a shock to the NAIRU, the unemployment rate adjusts to this new

equilibrium level in most macroeconomic models in use in Australia”. More recently some

researchers treat the NAIRU as a unit-root process. For example Debelle and Vickery (1998)

used a Phillips curve framework to estimate the NAIRU as a unit-root process using the

Kalman filter. Gruen, Pagan and Thompson (1999, p.236) plotted the unemployment rate

over the sample period (1965-1997) and examine the peaks and troughs, the plot reveals quite

clearly the shift in the NAIRU, although estimates of it tend to have been fairly stable since

the early 1980s. Such an outcome is consistent with estimates of the Phillips curve made in

previous research in Australia, which had the NAIRU creeping up as data from the early

1970s was included. Moreover, the unemployment rate rose sharply in the mid 1970s and has

never returned to its pre-1973 level.

Another feature of the Australian Phillips curve literature is the inclusion of the speed

limit effects; this refers to the view that rapid reductions in the unemployment rate are

associated with increased inflationary pressure. Debelle and Vickery (1998, p.393) attempt to

capture the speed limit effects by introducing an unemployment change variable in their non-

linear and linear Phillips curve specifications. They also tested for speed-limit effects, but

generally found them to be of the wrong sign (also see Gruen, Pagan and Thompson, 1999,

p.237).

Some studies on the Australian Phillips curve use mark-up pricing, that is, firms raise

their mark-up over marginal cost when demand for their products is high. In these models,

“inflation is determined by current and lagged growth in unit labour costs and import prices,

based on the theory that firms set their prices as a mark-up on costs, as in the NKPC.

However, there has previously been little explicit allowance for forward-looking behaviour

by firms in such models, and the presence of nominal rigidities has only been included

implicitly by allowing for lags of input costs’ (Norman and Richards, 2010, pp.5-6).More

recently, some researchers such as Jaaskela and Nimark (2008) and Buncic and Melecky

(2007) have also started to estimate the new Keynesian Phillips curve using dynamic

stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) framework.

Page 209: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

209

Two different measures of inflation expectation are used in the Australian Phillips

curve literature: an estimate derived from bond-market yields, and the Melbourne Institute10

measure of consumer inflation expectations. Debelle and Vickery (1998, p.389) derived a

measure of inflation expectations from bond yield data, this measure of inflation expectations

is computed from bond-market yields by subtracting a measure of the equilibrium world real

interest rate from the 10-year bond yield. The series for the world real interest rate is based on

empirical work that relates the equilibrium world real interest rate to movements in the stock

of world government debt. The Melbourne Institute measure of consumer inflation

expectations started in 1973; the Melbourne Institute of Applied Economic and Social

Research conduct telephone interviews of a minimum of 1200 Australian households on a

regular basis about the outlook for consumer price index (CPI) inflation, among other

variables. The design of this survey of similar to that of the Michigan survey (Thomas and

Grant, 2008, p.239). The Melbourne survey was initially conducted quarterly, since January

1987 it has been conducted on a monthly basis.

8.3 The Data

Table 8.1 presents the definitions and sources of the data used in this chapter; all

series are quarterly data for Australia and are expressed in log unless stated otherwise. We

use Reserve Bank of Australia’s (RBA) analytical measures of consumer price inflation as

our measure of inflation; this series is constructed by the RBA and are provided as a

convenience for researchers. The series excludes interest charges and the tax changes of

1999/2000 and the effect of major health policy changes and some other policy changes.

10 I am grateful to Guy Debelle for providing data on the Melbourne Institute measure of consumer inflation expectations.

Page 210: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

210

Table 8.1 Definitions and Sources of Data

Variable Definition Source

� Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) Analytical Measures of

Consumer Price Inflation. The interest charges and tax

adjustments made for this series are the same as those made in

Heath, Roberts and Bulman (2004). Further adjustments are made

for the impact of major health policy changes, such as the

introduction of Medibank and Medicare and changes to health

insurance rebates; in these quarters CPI inflation rates excluding

hospital and medical services have been used. This series is also

adjusted for the inclusion of the child care tax rebate in the

September 2007 quarter.

Reserve Bank of Australia

�� �� is measured as

4100 ln �

� using the Consumer Price Index. Reserve Bank of

Australia

J13 Job Finding Probability. Constructed from the number of

unemployed workers, the number of short term (less than 13

weeks) unemployed workers and the number of unemployed

workers next month using Shimer’s (2005) formulation.

Reserve Bank of Australia

J26 Job Finding Probability. Constructed from the number of

unemployed workers, the number of short term (less than 26

weeks) unemployed workers and the number of unemployed

workers next month using Shimer’s (2005) formulation.

Reserve Bank of Australia

G Output Gap. Chain volume measures are referenced to 2008/2009

values. Constructed using the Hodrick-Prescott filter with a

smoothing parameter of 1600.

Australian Bureau

of Statistic, ABS

Cat No 5206.0.

S The log non-farm of Real Unit Labour Cost. Datastream, Series

ID:AUULCNF.G.

MEL Consumers’ inflation expectations are measured by the

Melbourne Institute median expected inflation rate for the year

ahead.

Melbourne Institute Survey of Consumer Inflation

Page 211: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

211

U The Unemployment rate is defined as unemployed persons as a

percentage of the labour force.

Australian Bureau

of Statistic, ABS

Cat No 6202.0.

WI Wage Inflation, measured as the log-difference in nonfarm

average weekly earning per wage and salary earner.

Australian Bureau

of Statistic, ABS

Cat No 5206.0.

8.4 Proxies for Real Marginal Cost

We will briefly examine the correlations of the three proxies for real marginal cost

with inflation and unemployment. The results shown in the table below indicate potential

problems with using the output gap and labour’s share of income as proxy for real marginal

cost. Note that the correlation between inflation and the output gap (0.049270) has the correct

sign but it is very weak and the correlation between unemployment and labour’s share of

income (0.379737) has the wrong sign. In contrast, job finding probability’s correlations with

inflation and unemployment have the correct signs and are relative strong.

Table 8.2 Correlation Matrix of Three Proxies for Real Marginal Cost with Inflation and Unemployment

U � S J26 J13 G

U 1.000000 0.044325 0.379737 -0.816829 -0.880445 -0.464241

� 0.044325 1.000000 0.784966 0.233397 0.133099 0.049270

S 0.379737 0.784966 1.000000 -0.125095 -0.238924 -0.056420

J26 -0.816829 0.233397 -0.125095 1.000000 0.887402 0.202941

J13 -0.880445 0.133099 -0.238924 0.887402 1.000000 0.312910

G -0.464241 0.049270 -0.056420 0.202941 0.312910 1.000000

Note: The correlation matrix was computed using quarterly data from 1978q2 to 2011q1

The intuition behind the use of job finding probability as a proxy for real marginal

cost is that it directly measures how difficult it is for unemployed people to find jobs, in other

words, the tightness of the labour market. Our formulation of job finding probability follows

Robert Shimer’s (2005, pp.30-31) formulation, which infers the job finding probability from

dynamic behaviour of the unemployment level and the short-term unemployment level. Let

� denote the number of workers unemployed for less than 13 weeks, in month �. Then

Page 212: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

212

assuming all unemployed workers find a job with probability �� in month � and no

unemployed workers exit the labour force, then the number of unemployed workers next

month is equal to the number of unemployed workers this month who failed to find a job,

plus the number of newly unemployed workers.

1 1(1 ) �

� � � �� (8.1)

The job finding probability is given by

1 11�

� ��

(8.2)

where �� is the job finding probability, �

is the number of unemployed workers, �

� is the

number of short term (less than 13 weeks) unemployed workers and 1� is the number of

unemployed workers next month. We have also considered job finding probability for the

number of workers unemployed for less than 26 weeks, the results are similar to the results of

job finding probability for the number of workers unemployed for less than 13 weeks. In

order to conserve space we will only report the results of job finding probability for the

number of workers unemployed for less than 13 weeks.

8.5 Empirical Comparisons Between Job Finding Probability, the Output Gap and

Labour’s Share of Income as Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

First we estimate the old Keynesian Phillips curve using ordinary least square (OLS).

We use the results of the old Keynesian Phillips curve, with adaptive expectations as our

benchmark, since rational expectations predicts that modelling the Phillips curve with rational

expectations should fit the data better than modelling the Phillips curve with adaptive

expectations. Rational expectations implies that inflation expectations are rational, in the

sense that they efficiently incorporate all information available at time the expectations are

taken, and not just the past information as implied by adaptive expectations.

Page 213: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

213

Table 8.3 Estimations (OLS) of the Old Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1� � � �� ��

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding

Probability

-0.459447

0.357055 -1.286766

0.2005

1.304261

0.793413 1.643861

0.1026

0.969168

0.019067 50.83011

0.0000

0.952564

Output Gap

0.099302 0.109038 0.910708

0.3641

9.002609 4.441238 2.027050

0.0447

0.972016 0.018863 51.53002

0.0000

0.953065

Labour’s Share of Income

-15.45751 7.548277

-2.047820 0.0426

3.368309 1.634172 2.061171

0.0413

0.924114 0.030086 30.71535

0.0000

0.953115

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1978q2 to 2011q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive expectations produces relatively high

2

� values for the three proxies of real marginal cost. The coefficients of labour’s share of

income and the output gap are statistically significant at 5%.

Page 214: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

214

Table 8.4Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Melbourne Institute Forecasts as Proxy

for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 4� � � � �� �� �

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

-0.679956 0.593096

-1.146452 0.2537

1.732442 1.312538 1.319917

0.1892

0.850109 0.028972 29.34243

0.0000

0.870018

Output Gap

-0.001852 0.185389

-0.009990 0.9920

-21.10123 7.289028

-2.894931 0.0045

0.865981 0.028436 30.45381

0.0000

0.876299

Labour’s Share of Income

-48.86822 11.17061

-4.374714 0.0000

10.59658 2.418849 4.380835

0.0000

0.719571 0.040904 17.59157

0.0000

0.885323

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1978q2 to 2011q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the Melbourne Institute over the

next year forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produce lower 2

� values for the three

proxies of real marginal costs than the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive

expectations; this is contrary to the prediction of rational expectations. The coefficient of the

output gap has the wrong signs. The coefficient of labour’s share of income is statistically

significant at 1%.

Page 215: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

215

Table 8.5 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Melbourne Institute Forecasts as

Proxy for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 4� � � � � � �� �� �

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-0.579453 0.337386

-1.717477 0.0883

1.292267 0.747001

1.729939 0.0861

0.784305 0.047663

16.45524 0.0000

0.183181 0.043752

4.186854 0.0001

0.957952

Output Gap

-0.018446 0.109167

-0.168965 0.8661

2.964018 4.560054 0.649996

0.5169

0.798480 0.051111 15.62240

0.0000

0.172213 0.047460 3.628579

0.0004

0.957111

Labour’s Share of Income

-12.30245 7.194522

-1.709975 0.0897

2.659315 1.558321 1.706526

0.0903

0.757799 0.050678 14.95337

0.0000

0.174853 0.044055 3.968972

0.0001

0.957926

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1978q2 to 2011q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the Melbourne Institute over

the next year forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the

old Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs; all coefficients of

backward-looking and forward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically

significant at 1% level. The coefficients of labour’s share of income and job finding

probability are statistically significant at 10% level.

Page 216: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

216

Table 8.6Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Melbourne Institute Forecasts as

Proxy for Inflation Expectations and Import Prices

Equation estimated 1 4� � � � � � � i �� �� � �

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

� i 2

Job Finding Probability

0.829303 2.530761

0.327689 0.7437

1.110991 0.780807

1.422876 0.1575

0.763984 0.051751

14.76277 0.0000

0.177919 0.046014

3.866587 0.0002

-0.264498 0.524798

-0.503999 0.6152

0.951016

Output Gap

0.810587 2.561734 0.316421

0.7523

4.007614 4.861084 0.824428

0.4114

0.785385 0.056483 13.90490

0.0000

0.163872 0.051591 3.176382

0.0019

-0.161265 0.520222

-0.309993 0.7571

0.950442

Labour’s Share of Income

-14.17423 11.62571

-1.219215 0.2253

2.639065 2.039681 1.293862

0.1983

0.756847 0.052395 14.44495

0.0000

0.186989 0.046061 4.059615

0.0001

0.405037 0.644841 0.628119

0.5312

0.950868

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1978q2 to 2011q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth.

Some empirical studies on the Australian Phillips curve include import prices as an

explanatory variable because Australia is a small open economy. Our results show that the

coefficients of import prices for the three proxies of real marginal cost are not statistically

significant at 10% level.

8.6 Robustness Analysis

We consider three robustness exercises. The first robustness exercise examines sub-

sample stability. Our sub-samples are the periods from 1978q2 to 1989q4, 1990q1 to 1999q4,

2000q1 to 2011q1, 2000q1 to 2006q4, and the full sample period from 2007q1 to 2011q1, we

also wanted to examine the relative importance of forward-looking and backward-looking

inflation expectations during different sub-sample periods. The second robustness exercise

examines an alternative measurement of inflation; we use the Consumer Price Index without

various adjustments instead of the Reserve Bank of Australia’s analytical measures of

consumer price inflation to examine if our initial results are robust. The third robustness

exercise examines the new Keynesian Phillips curve and the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips

curve using generalized method of moments (GMM).

Page 217: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

217

���������������i�i���

Table 8.7 Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Melbourne Institute Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation Expectations and with Job Finding Probability as Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Equation estimated 1 4� � � � � � �� �� �

Sample Period

Constant �

� 2�

1978q2 1989q4

-4.708178 2.853552

-1.649936 0.1062

2.691179 1.998028 1.346918

0.1851

0.806498 0.081540 9.890783

0.0000

0.526017 0.341630 1.539728

0.1310

0.804760

1990q1 1999q4

-0.677981 0.710182

-0.954658 0.3461

3.063017 2.203650 1.389975

0.1731

0.698001 0.104732 6.664659

0.0000

0.098734 0.079702 1.238797

0.2234

0.865889

2000q1 2011q1

-0.466626 0.683634

-0.682568 0.4987

-0.125831 1.461144

-0.086118 0.9318

0.625670 0.089823 6.965551

0.0000

0.487346 0.096679 5.040873

0.0000

0.697525

2000q1 2006q4

-0.242455 0.870985

-0.278369 0.7831

1.011801 1.604427 0.630631

0.5342

0.559283 0.138210 4.046608

0.0005

0.320595 0.121242 2.644249

0.0142

0.539944

2007q1 2011q1

-1.130187

1.758870 -0.642564

0.5317

0.012232

3.775292 0.003240

0.9975

0.641273

0.146816 4.367878

0.0008

0.618311

0.165920 3.726574

0.0025

0.782993

1978q2 2011q1

-0.579453 0.337386

-1.717477 0.0883

1.292267 0.747001 1.729939

0.0861

0.784305 0.047663 16.45524

0.0000

0.183181 0.043752 4.186854

0.0001

0.958915

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second

row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

Page 218: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

218

Table 8.8Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Melbourne Institute Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation Expectations and with the Output Gap as Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Equation estimated 1 4� � � � � � �� �� �

Sample Period Constant �

� 2�

1978q2 1989q4

-5.273633 3.023747

-1.744072 0.0883

-3.633520 8.026664

-0.452681 0.6531

0.773890 0.102137

7.576944 0.0000

0.735091 0.358841

2.048513 0.0466

0.797488

1990q1 1999q4

0.317591 0.195020 1.628506

0.1121

16.00744 7.645109 2.093815

0.0434

0.742614 0.094246 7.879504

0.0000

0.110505 0.076995 1.435216

0.1599

0.874032

2000q1 2011q1

-0.742800 0.387006

-1.919347 0.0619

-13.26340 8.866891

-1.495834 0.1424

0.620650 0.084710 7.326737

0.0000

0.554550 0.101872 5.443593

0.0000

0.713126

2000q1 2006q4

0.115124 0.465561 0.247280

0.8068

-22.50437 9.665426

-2.328337 0.0286

0.502162 0.128433 3.909901

0.0007

0.396273 0.113274 3.498351

0.0018

0.618496

2007q1 2011q1

-1.287856 0.714850

-1.801575 0.0948

-8.349816 17.29328

-0.482836 0.6372

0.644525 0.130391 4.943007

0.0003

0.667930 0.188156 3.549878

0.0036

0.786816

1978q2 2011q1

-0.018446 0.109167

-0.168965 0.8661

2.964018 4.560054 0.649996

0.5169

0.798480 0.051111 15.62240

0.0000

0.172213 0.047460 3.628579

0.0004

0.958093

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

Page 219: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

219

Table 8.9Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Melbourne Institute Forecasts as Proxy for Inflation Expectations and with Labour’s Share of Income as Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Equation estimated 1 4� � � � � � �� �� �

Sample Period Constant �

� 2�

1978q2 1989q4

-40.12865 13.98731

-2.868934 0.0064

7.588507 2.955107

2.567929 0.0138

0.689750 0.088684

7.777569 0.0000

0.688373 0.308184

2.233643 0.0308

0.823578

1990q1 1999q4

101.1636 47.61433 2.124646

0.0406

-21.56458 10.17674

-2.119008 0.0411

0.743480 0.094101 7.900883

0.0000

0.157967 0.080445 1.963671

0.0573

0.874362

2000q1 2011q1

-3.010206 13.73513

-0.219161 0.8276

0.535932 2.950664 0.181631

0.8568

0.626498 0.088255 7.098706

0.0000

0.486031 0.093222 5.213690

0.0000

0.697714

2000q1 2006q4

1.434286 19.97793 0.071794

0.9434

-0.263992 4.281935

-0.061653 0.9514

0.561872 0.140619 3.995716

0.0005

0.329237 0.121644 2.706564

0.0123

0.532395

2007q1 2011q1

58.61725 38.64506

1.516811 0.1532

-12.97918 8.394807

-1.546096 0.1461

0.585384 0.126100

4.642213 0.0005

0.702859 0.156188

4.500073 0.0006

0.816698

1978q2 2011q1

-12.30245 7.194522

-1.709975 0.0897

2.659315 1.558321 1.706526

0.0903

0.757799 0.050678 14.95337

0.0000

0.174853 0.044055 3.968972

0.0001

0.958890

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The results of the first robustness exercise presented above show that the slopes of the

reduced form hybrid new Keynesian of the Phillips curve are much smaller over the past 10

years when Job finding probability and labour’s share of income are used as proxies for real

marginal cost. The relative importance of backward-looking inflation expectations and

forward-looking inflation expectations changes over time. Backward-looking inflation

expectations dominate forward-looking inflation expectations independent of which measures

of real marginal cost are used. The signs and magnitudes of the slope of the reduced form

Phillips curve depend on which sample periods and which measures of real marginal cost are

Page 220: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

220

used. We have also estimated the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve for the sub-sample

periods from 2000q1 to 2006q4 and for Phillips curve from 2007q1 to 2011q1; it appears that

the R square values have increase after the recent financial crisis, this is an unexpected

finding as one would expect the R square values to be lower because of greater uncertainty

making modelling inflation more difficult. Note that the second sub-sample period is

relatively short, we need to be careful about drawing any conclusion from this sub-sample

period. Based on the signs and magnitudes of the slope of the reduced form hybrid new

Keynesian Phillips curve and the R square values, job finding probability is marginally a

better proxy for real marginal cost than the output gap and labour’s share of income.

�����������i������������������������i���

Our alternative measurement of inflation is defined as 4

100 ln �

� using the

Consumer Price Index.

Table 8.10 Estimations (OLS) of the Old Keynesian Phillips Curve

Equation estimated 1� � � �� � �� �

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

-0.429111 0.461204

-0.930416 0.3539

1.414127 1.051544 1.344810

0.1810

0.951376 0.024576 38.71185

0.0000

0.923402

Output Gap

0.172161 0.131469 1.309515

0.1927

18.31982 5.653663 3.240345

0.0015

0.955182 0.023353 40.90206

0.0000

0.928175

Labour’s Share of Income

-12.34342 8.663796

-1.424712

0.1567

2.700852 1.870684 1.443778

0.1512

0.924219 0.033495 27.59309

0.0000

0.923564

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1978q2 to 2011q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive expectations produces relatively high

2

� values for the three proxies of real marginal cost. The coefficient the output gap is

statistically significant at 5% level.

Page 221: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

221

Table 8.11Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Melbourne Institute Forecasts as Proxy

for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 4� � � � �� � �� � �

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

2

Job Finding Probability

-2.462800 0.792281

-3.108493 0.0023

5.759913 1.753339 3.285110

0.0013

0.811392 0.038702 20.96517

0.0000

0.780717

Output Gap

-0.009672

0.264052 -0.036627

0.9708

-4.738918

10.38184 -0.456462

0.6488

0.826613

0.040502 20.40943

0.0000

0.762755

Labour’s Share of Income

-21.83081 16.42578

-1.329058 0.1862

4.728792 3.556787 1.329512

0.1860

0.763962 0.060148 12.70146

0.0000

0.765584

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1978q2 to 2011q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the Melbourne Institute over the

next year forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produce lower 2

� values for the three

proxies of real marginal costs than the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive

expectations. The coefficient of the output gap has the wrong signs. The coefficient of job

finding probability is statistically significant at 1%.

Page 222: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

222

Table 8.12Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Melbourne Institute Forecasts as

Proxy for Inflation Expectations

Equation estimated 1 4� � � � � � �� � �� � � �

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

� 2

Job Finding Probability

-0.859847 0.459842

-1.869876 0.0638

1.949057 1.021128 1.908730

0.0585

0.803893 0.048672 16.51647

0.0000

0.156935 0.045301 3.464245

0.0007

0.929421

Output Gap

0.018597 0.142337 0.130657

0.8963

14.86716 5.703635 2.606612

0.0102

0.848956 0.047757 17.77647

0.0000

0.115480 0.045573 2.533948

0.0125

0.931071

Labour’s Share of

Income

-1.976673

9.213157 -0.214549

0.8305

0.422531

1.995041 0.211791

0.8326

0.823580

0.048468 16.99239

0.0000

0.139579

0.049699 2.808460

0.0058

0.927438

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1978q2 to 2011q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth

row.

The hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve estimated with the Melbourne Institute over

the next year forecasts as proxy for inflation expectations produces higher2

� values than the

old Keynesian Phillips curve for the three proxies of real marginal costs; all coefficients of

backward-looking and forward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically

significant at 5% level. The coefficients of job finding probability and the output gap are

statistically significant at 10% level.

Page 223: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

223

Table 8.13Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using the Melbourne Institute Forecasts as

Proxy for Inflation Expectations and Import Prices

Equation estimated 1 4� � � � � � � i �� � �� � � � �

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost

Constant �

� i 2

Job Finding Probability

-2.353473 3.435977

-0.684950 0.4948

1.768276 1.127836 1.567849

0.1197

0.802454 0.051679 15.52778

0.0000

0.168657 0.058474 2.884326

0.0047

0.323399 0.713645 0.453166

0.6513

0.914070

Output Gap

-0.556915 3.484136

-0.159843 0.8733

16.00409 6.378317 2.509140

0.0135

0.851438 0.051237 16.61778

0.0000

0.113686 0.061167 1.858605

0.0657

0.120946 0.708082 0.170808

0.8647

0.916811

Labour’s Share of

Income

-12.49728

16.65533 -0.750347

0.4546

1.730821

2.899248 0.596990

0.5517

0.815350

0.051488 15.83568

0.0000

0.167681

0.059053 2.839506

0.0054

0.916059

0.916825 0.999165

0.3198

0.912491

Note: The above equations were estimated (OLS) over the 1978q2 to 2011q1 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth.

The coefficients of import prices for the three proxies of real marginal cost are not

statistically significant at 10% level. Overall, the results of the second robustness exercise are

consistence with our initial results.

�������i���i����

The third robustness exercise examines the new Keynesian Phillips curve and the

hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve using generalized method of moments (GMM). Our

instrument set includes four lags of inflation, and two lags of labour’s share of income, the

output gap, and wage inflation. This instrument set is similar to the instrument set used by

Gali, Gertler and Lopez-Salido (2001, pp.1250).

Page 224: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

224

Table 8.14Estimations of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using GMM

Equation estimated 1� � � � �� �� �

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost Constant �

Job Finding Probability

(0 lag)

0.258398 0.813895

0.317483 0.7514

-0.918891 1.961624

-0.468434 0.6403

1.029047 0.024012

42.85530 0.0000

Output Gap

(0 lag)

-0.145283 0.090825

-1.599603 0.1122

-8.740759 3.609836

-2.421373 0.0169

1.033213 0.021201 48.73337

0.0000

Labour’s Share of Income

(0 lag)

3.379606 18.84963 0.179293

0.8580

-0.760041 4.076105

-0.186463 0.8524

1.037690 0.059096 17.55944

0.0000

Note: The above equations were estimated (GMM) over the 1978q2 to 2010q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The coefficients of the three proxies of real marginal costs have the wrong signs.

Page 225: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

225

Table 8.15Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve Using GMM

Equation estimated 1 1� � � � � � �� �� �

Proxy for Real Marginal Cost Constant �

Job Finding Probability

(0 lag)

-1.316378 0.751750

-1.751085 0.0823

3.230459 1.811231

1.783571 0.0769

0.822034 0.145614

5.645282 0.0000

0.143031 0.160206

0.892794 0.3737

Output Gap

(0 lag)

0.050436 0.080780 0.624362

0.5335

4.338309 5.650586 0.767763

0.4441

0.835471 0.178450 4.681819

0.0000

0.147834 0.192835 0.766635

0.4447

Labour’s Share of Income

(0 lag)

29.78048 11.80209 2.523323

0.0129

-6.441849 2.554895

-2.521375 0.0129

0.772400 0.105537 7.318748

0.0000

0.309637 0.111652 2.773241

0.0064

Note: The above equations were estimated (GMM) over the 1978q2 to 2010q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

All coefficients of backward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically

significant at 1% level. The coefficient of job finding probability and labour’s share of

income are statistically significant at 10% level, but, the coefficient of labour’s share of

income has the wrong sign.

Page 226: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

226

Table 8.16Estimations of the Hybrid New Keynesian Phillips Curve with Import Prices Using GMM

Equation estimated 1 4� � � � � � � i� �� � �

Proxy for Real Marginal

Cost

Constant �

� i

Job Finding Probability

(0 lag)

-7.390669 3.210472

-2.302050 0.0232

1.159493 2.394049 0.484323

0.6291

0.665970 0.154447 4.311970

0.0000

0.397966 0.193388 2.057859

0.0419

1.407405 0.782713 1.798111

0.0748

Output Gap

(0 lag)

-7.485784

2.138261 -3.500875

0.0007

2.563460

5.670240 0.452090

0.6521

0.680922

0.144977 4.696769

0.0000

0.389738

0.161011 2.420578

0.0171

1.530445

0.436871 3.503196

0.0007

Labour’s Share of Income

(0 lag)

-28.14116 32.69093

-0.860825 0.3912

3.704099 5.887508

0.629146 0.5305

0.589698 0.085813

6.871904 0.0000

0.484261 0.088335

5.482083 0.0000

2.243139 1.185721

1.891794 0.0611

Note: The above equations were estimated (GMM) over the 1978q2 to 2010q4 period using quarterly data. Standard errors are shown in the second row; errors are corrected for heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation using Newey-West procedure, with automatic lags selection based on Schwarz information criterion. t-ratios are shown in the third row. P-values are shown in the fourth row.

The coefficients of import prices for the three proxies of real marginal cost are

statistically significant at 10% level. The coefficients of the three proxies for real marginal

costs are not statistically significant at 10% level. All coefficients of backward-looking and

forward-looking inflation expectations terms are statistically significant at 5% level.

8.7 Conclusion

We have introduced and applied job finding probability to estimate the Australian

Phillips curve, which provides a direct link between frictions in the labour market and the

Phillips curve relationship. Our results suggest that job finding probability should be

considered as an alternative proxy for real marginal cost in empirical work on the Phillips

curve, particularly when the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve is estimated.

In general, our empirical results are not supportive of Gali and Gertler’s (1999)

empirical findings that labour’s share of income is a better proxy for real marginal cost than

the output gap. Also, our results are not supportive of Gali and Gertler’s (1999, p.195)

empirical findings that “[b]ackward-looking price setting, while statistically significant, is not

Page 227: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

227

quantitatively important”. Our results suggest the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive

expectations fits the data better than the new Keynesian Phillips curve with rational

expectations; this result is consistent with many previous studies on the Australian Phillips

curve, as well as some well known studies on the American Phillips curve, such as Fuhrer

and Moore (1995) and Mankiw (2001). Bounded rationality can explain the observation that

lagged inflation plays an important role in empirical inflation regressions as the dissemination

of economic information and knowledge between professional economists and non-

economists involves time lags, since the general public’s inflation expectations respond to the

professional economists’ expectations with time lags, lagged inflation rates are correlated

with the current inflation rate. Overall, our results using Australian data are broadly

consistent with our results using American data from previous chapters.

The results of the first robustness exercise indicate that the relative importance of

backward-looking inflation expectations and forward-looking inflation expectations changes

over time. Backward-looking inflation expectations dominate forward-looking inflation

expectations independent of which measures of real marginal cost are used. The signs and

magnitudes of the slope of the reduced form Phillips curve depend on which sample periods

and which measures of real marginal cost are used.

The second robustness exercise examines an alternative measurement of inflation; we

use the Consumer Price Index without various adjustments instead of the Reserve Bank of

Australia’s analytical measures of consumer price inflation series to examine if our initial

results are robust. The results of the second robustness exercise are broadly consistent with

our initial results.

The third robustness exercise examines the new Keynesian Phillips curve and the

hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve using generalized method of moments (GMM).The

coefficients of the three proxies of real marginal costs output gap have the wrong signs. The

coefficients of import prices for the three proxies of real marginal cost are not statistically

significant when the Melbourne Institute forecasts are used as proxy for inflation

expectations. However, when mathematical expectations (GMM) are used as proxy for

inflation expectations import prices are statistically significant for the three proxies of real

marginal cost.

Page 228: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

228

CHAPTER 9

Summary and Conclusions

We have examined two important issues in the empirical literature on the NKPC.

First, are inflation expectations consistent with rational expectations? Many researchers find

that the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive expectations fits the data better new

Keynesian Phillips curve with rational expectations. Rudd and Whelan (2006, p.319)

conclude that “lagged inflation plays an important role in empirical inflation regressions

poses a major challenge to the rational-expectations sticky-price models that underpin the

new Keynesian Phillips curve”. In general, our empirical results using American data and

Australian data are not supportive of Gali and Gertler’s (1999) empirical findings that

labour’s share of income is a better proxy for real marginal cost than the output gap. Also,

our results are not supportive Gali and Gertler’s (1999, p.195) empirical findings that

“[b]ackward-looking price setting, while statistically significant, is not quantitatively

important”. Our results suggest the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive expectations

fits the data better than the new Keynesian Phillips curve with rational expectations and that

the relative importance of backward-looking inflation expectations and forward-looking

inflation expectations changes over time. Backward-looking inflation expectations dominate

forward-looking inflation expectations independent of which measures of real marginal cost

are used. Furthermore, we have tested the rationality of survey measures of inflation

expectations in chapter 5; our results indicate that all of the survey measures of inflation

expectations are biased and inefficient. We have also showed that there are Granger

causalities from the professional forecasters (as represented by the SPF forecasts) to

households (as represented by the Michigan forecasts), but no Granger causality in the

opposite direction. Second, do real marginal costs drive inflation dynamics? Gali and Gertler

(1999) argue that the reason why the NKPC fits the data poorly is because traditional

empirical work on the Phillips curve uses some output gap measures as a proxy for real

marginal cost rather than labour’s share of income. In general, our results suggest that job

finding probability (JFP) is marginally a better proxy for real marginal cost than the output

gap and labour’s share of income when the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve is estimated.

Our results from chapters 4 and chapter 5 suggest that the pure rational expectations

new Keynesian Phillips curve might be misspecified and that the hybrid new Keynesian

Phillips curve fits the data best. If we accept the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve as

Page 229: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

229

having the right specifications for the Phillips curve relationship, we need to be able to

explain why are some price setters backward-looking and why are some price setters

forward-looking and also are the fractions of backward-looking agents and the fractions

forward-looking agents constant over time? Bounded rationality implies that the best way for

non-economists to minimize their forecast errors is to listen to the advices of professional

economists as much of economic knowledge is professional knowledge. The way that

professional economists help the general public to overcome their lack of inflational

knowledge is by giving their professional advices via the mass media, economic education

and private consulting. Since the general public’s inflation expectations respond to the

professional economists’ expectations with time lag, lagged inflation rates are correlated with

the current inflation rate. In short, bounded rationality explains why lagged inflation plays an

important role in empirical inflation regressions as the dissemination of economic

information and knowledge between professional economists and non-economists involves

time lags, since the general public’s inflation expectations respond to the professional

economists’ expectations with time lags, lagged inflation rates are correlated with the current

inflation rate.

In chapter 6 we presented evidence of the flattening of the Phillips curve and

examined some of the competing explanations given for why this has occurred. We proposed

that structural changes in the labour market in the past forty years can partly account for this

phenomenon. Our view is that deindustrialization and the computer revolution have shifted

employment from the manufacturing sectors to the service sectors; these structural changes in

the labour market have changed jobs’ skill requirements, increasing heterogeneity (real

rigidities) between workers, producing more mismatches in the labour market, this is

reflected by the fact that the average duration of unemployment has been increasing since

1970 and the probability of finding a job after 15 weeks of unemployment has been

decreasing since 1970, this about the same time that deindustrialization started in the United

States. In other words, inflation is less responsive to changes in real marginal cost, because of

increase in the level of real rigidities in the labour market, reducing the inflation-output

tradeoffs and reducing the slope of the reduced form Phillips curve.

In Chapter 7 we argued that the finding that the United States inflation rates are non-

stationary does not necessarily invalidate a previous body of empirical research that did not

Page 230: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

230

take into account the non-stationary behaviour of inflation, but instead it complements

previous studies.

In Chapter 8 we estimated various specifications of the Phillips curve for Australia

using job finding probability (JFP), the output gap and labour’s share of income as well as

survey measures of inflation expectations and mathematical expectations as proxy for

inflation expectations. In general, our results suggest that job finding probability should be

considered as an alternative proxy for real marginal cost in empirical work on the Phillips

curve, particularly when the hybrid new Keynesian Phillips curve is estimated. Also, our

results are not supportive Gali and Gertler’s (1999, p.195) empirical findings that

“[b]ackward-looking price setting, while statistically significant, is not quantitatively

important”. Our results suggest the old Keynesian Phillips curve with adaptive expectations

fits the data better than the new Keynesian Phillips curve with rational expectations; this

result is consistent with many previous studies on the Australian Phillips curve. Overall, our

results using Australian data are broadly consistent with our results using American data.

An important implication of our approach is that economists’ inflation expectations

are more important than households’ inflation expectations for macroeconomic outcomes;

this may sound obvious since it is a direct application of Adam Smith’s notion of the division

of labour. However, it also implies that when there are serious problems with the economy,

economists and their theories are likely to play some role in this process. Bounded rationality

opens up the possibility that when economists have the wrong model of economy, it causes

non-economists to have the wrong model of the economy. This is evident by the existence of

many obsolete economic theories in the history of economic thought and admissions of

influential economists (such as Alan Greenspan recently) that they had the wrong model of

the economy.

When people do not have sufficient knowledge about the nature of the problem, they

often seek the advices of those that they believe know more than them. This behaviour is

highly rational and is an important feature of the economy, in an uncertain environment,

when an “expert” claims or gives the impression that he knows what will happen in the

future, then it is rational for those whose don’t know what will happen due to their lack of

understanding about a particular subject (asymmetric knowledge) to base their opinions and

expectations on the opinions and expectations of the experts in that particular field of

knowledge, such as those of professional economists or rating agencies (Note that, the

Page 231: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

231

recently appointed prime ministers of Italy (Mario Monti) and Greece (Lucas Papademos) are

economic professors).

By redefining bounded rationality in terms of asymmetric and imperfect knowledge it

implies that knowledge about the subject matter is also needed in order to understand and to

exploit the information for possible economic gains and by drawing on the sticky nature of

knowledge, it is possible to explain short-run monetary non-neutrality and other real rigidities

in the economy as a result of knowledge lags rather than informational lags, which makes it

much more plausible. From a business cycle perspective bounded rationality opens up the

possibility that when economists have the wrong model of economy, it causes non-

economists to have the wrong model of the economy, which may exacerbate economic crisis.

In Mankiw and Reis (2002) and in Carroll’s (2003) models, the authors assumed that

professional economists do not suffer from sticky information. Similarly, in our model, we

also assumed that professional economists do not suffer from sticky knowledge. However, by

redefining bounded rationality in terms of asymmetric and imperfect knowledge we have

explicitly acknowledged that economists do not have perfect foresight. Under bounded

rational expectations economists are the first to adjust their inflation expectations because

they know more about the economy than non-economists; this action does not imply that

economists have perfect foresights.

In the real world, the interactions between economists and non-economists go

something like this. Both non-economists and economists know that economists do not have

perfect foresight. This is reflected by the large number of jokes about economic predictions.

Part of the reasons why economists make forecast errors is simple, economists are asked to

make predictions about the future, both economists and non-economists know that the future

cannot be predicted with certainty. Despite the fact that non-economists know that

economists often make forecast errors, economists are better at making economic forecasts

than non-economists because they know more about economics. This is reflected by the fact

the economics as a profession exist, the reason why the economics profession exist (or any

other profession) is because of the unequal distribution of knowledge between the profession

and its clients. This is further complicated by the fact that economics is characterized by

many competing of schools of thought and that predictions of economists cannot be verified

accurately because other factors may influence the outcome that economists could justify that

they have no way of knowing, as economists often qualify their predictions with the clause

Page 232: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

232

"ceteris paribus" . Some non-economists may choose to learn economics so that they don’t

have to rely on economists’ forecasts, learning economics will allow non-economists to

respond to economic news quicker, it does not allow non-economists to make predictions as

accurately as economists until they have invested as much time and efforts as a professional

economist in studying about economics.

Whether a non-economist decides to learn economics and become a professional

economist depends on the potential costs and benefits of his decision. For many non-

economists the costs of learning economics so that they could make economic forecasts as

accurately as profession economists outweigh the benefits, this is reflect by the relatively

small size of economic profession to the general public as a whole. For these non-economists,

the best way to minimize their forecast errors is by employing the services of professional

economists or observe how professional economists respond and replicate their actions, rather

than making economic forecast themselves without the requires economic knowledge. Given

that economics is characterized by many competing of schools of thought and that predictions

of economists cannot be verified accurately, it is likely that non-economists take into account

the uncertain nature of economic forecasts mentioned previously, that is, they take

economists’ advices but, with a grain of salt. As a result they take a wait and see approach to

updating their expectations of inflation, in other words, they make many incremental

adjustments in respond to economic developments as reported by the media during the life

span of a monetary policy shock. Furthermore, how quickly people respond to economic

developments also depends on the potential economic gains or losses of responding quickly.

When the monetary policy shock occurs and the government has good credibility the

potential economic gains or losses are small, as the general public believes that the

government’s policy will have a positive outcome. However, when the government is

perceived as incompetent, and its policy is viewed as not credible, this is likely to have a

negative outcome. The economic gains or losses of responding to economic development

quickly are very high as an economic recession happens much quicker than an economic

expansion. People will devote more time and mental resources to learning and thinking about

economic matters so that they can respond to economic developments quicker.

Page 233: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

233

REFERENCES

Adam, K. and M. Padula (2003), “Inflation Dynamics and Subjective Expectations in the

United States”, ��������������������k����ki������������i��, No. 222.

Akelof, G.A. and J.E. Stiglitz (1969), “Capital, Wages and Structural Unemployment”,

������i���������, 79: 269-81.

Akerlof, G. A. and J. L. Yellen (1985), “A Near-Rational Model of the Business Cycle with

Wage and Price Inertia”, ���������������������������i��, 100: 823-838

Akerlof, G. A. and J. L. Yellen (1985), “Can Small Deviations from Rationality Make

Significant Differences to Economic Equilibria?”,�����i����������i�����i��, 75(4): 708-721.

Akerlof, G. and H. Miyazaki. (1980), “The Implicit Contract Theory of Unemployment Meets

the Wage Bill Argument”, ���i������������i������i��, 47: 321-338.

Akerlof, G.A. (1984), “Gift Exchange and Efficiency Wage Theory: Four Views”, ����i����

������i�����i��, 74: 79-83

Akerlof, G.A. and J. L. Yellen (1987), “Rational Models of Irrational Behavior”, ����i����

������i�����i��, 77: 137-142.

Akerlof, G.A. and J. L. Yellen (1988), “Fairness and Unemployment”, ����i����������i��

���i��, 78: 44-49.

Akerlof, G.A. and J. L. Yellen (1990), “The Fair Wage-Effort Hypothesis and Unemployment”,

���������������������������i��, 105: 255-283.

Akerlof, G.A. and J. L. Yellen, (eds) (1986), ���i�i����������������������������������k��,

Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

Akerlof, G.A., W.T. Dickens, and G.L. Perry, (1996), “The Macroeconomics of Low Inflation”,

����ki��������������������i�����i�i��, 1: 1-76.

Akerlof, George (1970), “The Market for Lemons: Quality Uncertainty and The Market

Mechanism”, ���������������������������i��, 98: 488-500.

Akerlof, George and Janet, Yellen (1983), “The Macroeconomic Consequences of Near

Rational Rule of Thumb Behavior”, �i���, U.C. Berkeley.

Andres, J., J. D. Lopez-Salido, and E. Nelson (2005), “Sticky Price Models and the Natural

Page 234: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

234

Rate Hypothesis”, ��������������������������i��, 52(5): 1025-1053.

Andrews, D. (1993), “Tests for Parameter Instability and Structural Change with Unknown

Change Point: A Corrigendum”, ���������i��, 71 (1): 395-397.

Ang Andrew, Geert Bekaert, and Min Wei, (2005), “Do Macro Variables, Asset Markets, or

Surveys Forecast Inflation Better?”, ��������ki������������i����No. 11538.

Arnold, Lutz (2002), ���i�����������������, New York, Oxford University Press.

Arslan, M.M. (2008), “Dynamics of the Sticky Information and Sticky Price Models in a New

Keynesian DSGE Framework”, ������i��������i��, 25: 1276-1294.

Azariadis, C. (1975), “Implicit Contracts and Underemployment Equilibria”, �����������

���i�i�����������, 83: 1183-1202.

Bailey, M.N. (1974), “Wages and Unemployment under Uncertain Demand”, ���i������

������i������i��, 41: 37-50.

Ball, L., (1994), “Credible Disinflations with Staggered Price Setting”, ����i����������i��

���i��� 84: 282-289.

Ball, L., N.G. Mankiw, R. Reis (2004), “Monetary Policy for Inattentive Economies”, ��������

������������������i��� 52: 703-725.

Ball, Laurence (1994), “Credible Disinflation with Staggered Price-Setting”, ����i����

������i�����i��� 84(1): 282-289.

Ball, Laurence and David Romer (1990), “Real Rigidities and the Non-Neutrality of Money”,

���i������������i������i��, 57: 183-203.

Ball, Laurence, and Mankiw, N. Gregory (1994), "A Sticky-Price Manifesto", ������i��

����������������������������i�����i��, 41: 127- 151.

Ball, Laurence, N. Gregory Mankiw, and David Romer (1988), "The New Keynesian

Economics and the Output-Inflation Trade-off", ����ki��������������������i�����i�i��, 1: 1-

65.

Barro, R.J. (1974), “Are Government Bonds Net Wealth?”, ��������������i�i�����������,

82(6): 1095-1117.�

Page 235: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

235

Barro, R.J. (1977), “Unanticipated Money Growth and Unemployment in the United States”,

����i����������i�����i��, 67 (2): 101-115.

Bils, M., Klenow, P.J. (2004), “Some Evidence on the Importance of Sticky Prices”, �����������

���i�i�����������, 112: 947-985.

Blanchard, O.J. (1992), “For a Return to Pragmatism”, in M. Belongia and M. Garfinkel (eds),

�������i�����������������i���������i�����, London, Kluwer Academic Publishers.

Blanchard, O.J. (1997a), �����������i��, New Jersey, Prentice-Hall.

Blanchard, O.J. (1997b), “Is There a Core of Usable Macroeconomics?”, ����i����������i��

���i��, 2: 244-246.

Blanchard, O.J. and Fischer, S. (1989), �����������������������i��, Cambridge, MA: MIT

Press.

Blanchard, O.J. and Kiyotaki, N. (1987), “Monopolistic Competition and the Effects of

Aggregate Demand”, ����i����������i�����i��, 77: 647-666.

Blanchard, Olivier and Peter Diamond (1990), “The Cyclical Behavior of The Gross Flows of

U.S. Workers”, ����ki�������������������i�����i�i��, 2: 85-155.

Blanchard, Olivier and Peter Diamond (1992), “The Flow Approach to Labour Markets”, ����

����i����������i�����i��, 82: 354-359.

Blinder, A.S. (1997a), “Is There a Core of Practical Macroeconomics That We Should All

Believe?”, ����i����������i�����i��, 87(2): 240 - 243.

Blinder, A.S. (1997b), “What Central Bankers Can Learn from Academics and Vice Versa”,

�����������������i����������i���, 11(2): 3-19.

Blinder, A.S. (1998), �����������ki���i������������������i��, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Blinder, Alan (1988), “The Challenge of High Unemployment”, ��������i����������i��

���i��, 78(2): 1-15.

Borland, Jeff (1996), “Job Creation and Job Destruction in Manufacturing Industry in

Australia”, ����������i��������, 72: 46-62.

Bowlus, Audra (1995), “Matching Workers and Jobs: Cyclical Fluctuations in Match Quality”,

�����������������������i��, 13(2): 335-350.

Page 236: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

236

Brayton, Flint, John M. Roberts, and John C. Williams, “What's Happened to the Phillips

Curve?” (1999), ����� ���ki��� ������ ���� �����. Available at SSRN:

http://ssrn.com/abstract=190852 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.190852.

Brissimis, Sophocles N., and Nicholas S. Magginas, (2008), “Inflation Forecasts and the New

Keynesian Phillips Curve”, ��������i���������������������������ki��, 4 (June): 1-22.

Buiter, Willem (2009), "The Unfortunate Uselessness of Most ‘State of the Art’ Academic

Monetary Economics", ft.com/maverecon, Financial Times,

http://blogs.ft.com/maverecon/2009/03/the-unfortunate-uselessness-of-most-state-of-the-art-

academic-monetary-economics/

Buncic, D. and M. Melecky (2008), “An Estimated New Keynesian Policy Model for

Australia”, ����������i��������, 84: 1-16.

Calvo, G. (1983), “Staggered Prices in a Utility-Maximizing Framework”, ��������������������

������i����12: 383-398.

Cao, Cung (2008), ��������i����������������K������������������������������������������

���i����i����i��������������i����i��, Germany, VDM Verlag Dr. Muller.

Caplin, Andrew S., and Daniel F. Spulber (1987). "Menu Costs and the Neutrality of Money”,

���������������������������i��, 102(4): 703-726.

Carroll, Christopher (2001), “The Epidemiology of Macroeconomic Expectations”, �����

���ki������������i��, No. 8695.

Carroll, Christopher (2003), “Macroeconomic Expectations of Household and Professional

Forecasters”, �������������������������������i��, 118 (1): 269-298

Challen, D., W., and A. J. Hagger (1975), “Another Look at Australia’s Inflation-

Unemployment Trade-offs”, �������i���������i��������, 14: 137-153.

Chen-Yu Leu, S., and J. Sheen (2006), “Asymmetric Monetary Policy in Australia”, ����

������i��������, 82: 85-96.

Cho, Seonghoon, and Antonio Moreno (2006), “A Small-Sample Study of the New Keynesian

Macro Model”, ����������������������i���������ki��, 39: 471-507.

Christiano, L.J., M. Eichenbaum, C.L. Evans (2005), “Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic

Page 237: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

237

Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy”, ��������������i�i�����������, 113(1): 1-45.

Christiano, Lawrence, Martin Eichenbaum, and Charles Evans, (1999), “Monetary Policy

Shocks: What Have We Learned And To What End?”, �������k���������������i��, J.B.

Taylor and Michael Woodford, eds. (Amsterdam, The Netherlands), 65-148.

Clarida, Richard, Mark Gertler, and Jordi Gali, (1999), "The Science of Monetary Policy: A

New Keynesian Perspective”, �����������������i���i��������, 37: 1661-1707.

Coibion, O. (2010), “Testing the Sticky Information Phillips Curve”, �������i������������i���

��������i��i����92: 87-101.

Commonwealth Treasury (1996), “User’s Guide to the TRYM Model of the Australian

Economy”, CPN Printing, Canberra.

Conlisk, John (1996), “Why Bounded Rationality?”, �����������������i���i��������, 34: 669-

700.

Croushore, Dean (1998), “Evaluating Inflation Forecasts”, �������������������k����

��i�������i�����ki������������������.

Croushore, Dean and Tom, Stark (2001), "A Real-Time Data Set for Macroeconomists",

��������������������i��� 105: 111-130.

Culver, S.E and D.H. Papell (1997), “Is There a Unit Root in the Inflation Rate?”, J����������

����i������������i��, 12: 435-444.

Darby, Michael, John Haltiwanger, and Mark Plant (1985), “Unemployment Rate Dynamics

and Persistent Unemployment Under Rational Expectations”, ����i����������i�����i��,

75(4): 614-637.

Darby, Michael, John Haltiwanger, and Mark Plant (1986), “The Ins and Outs of employment:

The Ins Win”, ��������ki������������i����No. 1997�

Davis, S.J., R.J. Faberman and J. Haltiwanger (2006), “The Flow Approach to Labor Markets:

New Data Sources and Micro-Macro Links”, ��������ki������������i��, No. 12167.

Davis, Steven and John, Haltiwanger (1999), “On the Driving Forces Behind Cyclical

Movements in Employment and Job Reallocation”, ����i����������i�����i��� 89: 1234-

1258.

Page 238: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

238

Davis, Steven, and John Haltiwanger (1990), “Gross Job Creation and Destruction:

Microeconomic Evidence and Macroeconomic Implications”, ����������������i���������,

ed. by Olivier Blanchard, and Stanley Fischer, MIT Press.

Davis, Steven, and John Haltiwanger (1992), “Gross Job Creation, Gross Job Destruction, and

Employment Reallocation”, ���������������������������i��, 107(3): 818-863.

Davis, Steven, Jason Faberman and John Haltiwanger (2005), “The Flow Approach to Labor

Markets: New Data Sources, Micro-Macro Links and the Recent Downturn”, �����i�����i���

������ No. 1639.

de Brouwer G., and N. Ericsson (1995), “Modeling Inflation in Australia”, �������������

�i�����i��������, No. 9510.

Debelle, G., J. Vickery (1998), “Is the Phillips Curve a Curve? Some Evidence and Implications

for Australia”, ������i��������, 74 (227): 384-398.

Diamond, Peter A. (1982), “Aggregate Demand Management in Search Equilibrium”, ��������

������i�i�����������, ���(5): 881-894.

Dixon, Huw and Neil, Rankin (1994), "Imperfect Competition and Macroeconomics: A

Survey", �������������i��������, 46: 171-199.

Dixon, Huw and Neil, Rankin (1995), �������������������i�����������������k��������

���i���������i������, New York, Cambridge University Press.

Dopke, J., J. Dovern, U. Fritsche, and J. Slacalek (2005), “European Inflation Expectations

Dynamics", ������������������k��i�����i������������i����, Economics Studies No. 37.

Dornbusch, Rudiger and Stanley, Fischer (1994), �����������i����Sixth Edition, New York,

McGraw- Hill.

Dufour, Jean-Marie, Lynda Khalaf, Maral Kichian (2006), “Inflation Dynamics and the New

Keynesian Phillips Curve: An Identification-Robust Econometric Analysis”, �����������

������i�������i��������������, 30: 1707-1727.

Dupor, B., T. Kitamura, T. Tsuruga (2010), “Integrating Sticky Prices and Sticky Information”,

�������i������������i�����������i��i��� 92: 657-669.

Dupor, Bill and Takayuki, Tsuruga, (2005), “Sticky Information: The Impact of Different

Information Updating Assumptions”, ����������������������i����������ki��� 37(6): 1143-

Page 239: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

239

1152.

Dwyer J., and K., Leong (2001), “Changes in the Determinants of Inflation in Australia”, ����

����������i�����i��������, No. 02.

Elsby, Michael W., Ryan Michaels, and Gary Solon (2007), “The Ins and Outs of Cyclical

Unemployment”, ��������ki������������i����No. 12853.

Engle, R. and C.W.J. Granger, (1987), “Co-integration and Error Correction: Representation,

Estimation and Testing”, ���������i��, 55 (2): 251-276.

Fischer, Stanley (1977), “Long-Term Contracts, Rational Expectations, and the Optimal Money

Supply Rule”, ��������������i�i�����������, 85: 191- 205.

Foote, Christopher (1998), “Trend Employment Growth and the Bunching of Job Creation and

Destruction”, �������������������������������i��, 113(3): 809-834.

Foss, Nicolai (2003), “Bounded Rationality in Economics of Organization: Much Cited and

Little Used”, �����������������i������������, 24: 245-264.

Foster, Lucia, John Haltiwanger and Namsuk Kim (2006), “Gross Job Flows for the U.S.

Manufacturing Sector: Measurement from the Longitudinal Research Database”,

http://econweb.umd.edu/~haltiwan/download/gflows_112906.pdf.

Frank, Robert (1997), �i���������i������������i��, Third Edition, New York, McGraw Hill.

Friedman, M. (1957), ������������������������i��������i����Princeton, Princeton University

Press.

Friedman, Milton (1968), "The Role of Monetary Policy”, ����i����������i�����i��, 58(1):

1-17.

Fuhrer, J.C., G. Moore (1995), “Inflation Persistence”, �������������������������������i��,

110: 127-159.

Fuhrer, Jeffrey C. (1997), “The (Un)Importance of Forward-Looking Behavior in Price

Specifications”, ����������������������i���������ki��� 29: 338-350.

Gali, J. and M. Gertler (1999), “Inflation Dynamics: A Structural Econometric Analysis”,

��������������������������i��, 44: 195-222.

Galı, J., M. Gertler, D. Lopez-Salido (2001), “European Inflation Dynamics”, ���������

Page 240: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

240

������i�����i��, 45 (7): 1237-1270.

Galı, J., M. Gertler, D. Lopez-Salido (2003), “Erratum to European Inflation Dynamics”,

���������������i�����i��, 47 (4): 759-760.

Galı, J., M. Gertler, D. Lopez-Salido (2005), “Robustness of the Estimates of the Hybrid new

Keynesian Phillips Curve”, ��������������������������i��, 52: 1107-1118.

Golosov, M., R.E. Lucas Jr. (2007), “Menu Costs and Phillips Curves”, ��������������i�i����

�������� 115 (2): 171-199.

Gordon, D.F. (1974), “A Neoclassical Theory of Keynesian Unemployment”, ������i��

����i��, 12: 431-459

Granger, C. W. J. and P. Newbold (1974), "Spurious Regressions in Econometrics", �����������

������������������i��, 2: 111-120.

Gregory, R.G. (1986), “Wages Policy and Unemployment in Australia”, ������i��, 53 (210)

Supplement: S53-S74.

Gruen D., A., Pagan and C., Thompson (1999), “The Phillips Curve in Australia”, �����������

���������������i��, 44(2): 223-258.

Gujarati, D. (2003),” ���i�����������i��”, 4th edition, New York: McGraw-Hill.

Hagger. A.J. (1978), “Inflation”, in F.,H., Gruen (ed.), ������������������i���������i����

Sydney, Allen & Unwin, 133-186.

Haley, J. (1990), “Theoretical Foundations of Sticky Wages”, �����������������i���������, 4:

115-155.

Hall, R. (2005), “Employment Fluctuations with Equilibrium Wage Stickiness”, ����i����

������i�����i��, 95: 50-65.�

Hall, Robert (1972), “Turnover in the Labor Force”, ����ki��������������������i�����i�i��, 3:

709-756.

Hall, Robert (1988), “Fluctuation in Equilibrium Unemployment”, ��������i����������i��

���i��, 78(2): 269-275.

Hall, Robert (1999), “The Concentration of Job Destruction”, ��������ki������������i��, No.

7025.

Page 241: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

241

Hall, Robert E (2005), “Job Loss, Job Finding, and Unemployment in the U.S. Economy over

the Past Fifty Years”, ����������������i���������, 20: 101-137.

Hashimoto, H. (1981), “Firm-Specific Human Capital as a Shared Investment”, ����i����

������i�����i��, 71: 475-482.

Hausman, Daniel (1994), ������i�����������������i����������������, Second Edition, New

York, Cambridge University Press.

Heertje, Arnold (1995), ������k��������������������i��, �olume Two, �rookfield, US,

Edward Elgar.

Hendry, D.F., (1980), “Econometrics: Alchemy or Science�”, ������i��, 47: 387-406.

Hornstein, Andreas (2007), “Evolving Inflation Dynamics and the New Keynesian Phillips

Curve”, �������������������k�����i�������������i������������ 93: 317-39.

Ireland, P.N. (2001) “Sticky Price Models of the �usiness Cycle: Specification and Stability”,

��������������������������i��� 47(1): 3-18.

J��skel� J., and K., Nimark (2008), “A Medium-Scale �pen Economy Model of Australia”,

��������������i�����i��������, No. 07.

Jondeau, E., H. Le �ihan (2005), “Testing for the New Keynesian Phillips Curve, Additional

International Evidence”, ������i��������i��, 22: 521-550.

Jonson, P., K. Mahar, G. Thompson (1973), “Earnings and Award Wages in Australia”, ��������

���k�����������i������������i�����i����������� (revised).

Jonson, P., Mahar, K., Thompson, G., (1974), “Earnings and Award Wages in Australia”,

�������i���������i��������� 13 (22): 80-98.

Kahneman, Daniel and �ernon Smith (2002), “Foundation of �ehavioral and E�perimental

Economics”, http:��www.nobelprize.org�nobel�prizes�economics�laureates�2002�advanced-

economicsciences2002.pdf

Kahneman, Daniel, and Amos, Tversky (1979), “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision

Under Risk”, ���������i��, 47: 263-292.

Katz, L.F. (1986), “Efficiency Wage Theories: A Partial Evaluation”, ����������������i���

������, 1: 235-276.

Page 242: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

242

Katz, L.F. (1988), “Some Recent Developments in Labour Economics and Their Implications

for Macroeconomics”, ����������������������i����������ki��, 20(3):507-522.

Khan, H., �. �hu (2006), “Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve for the United

States”, ����������������������i���������ki��, 38: 195-207.

Khan, Hashmat and �henhua, �hu (2002), “Estimates of the Sticky-Information Phillips Curve

for the United States, Canada, and the United Kingdom”, ���k��������������ki��������� No.

19.

Kiley, M. (2007), “A �uantitative Comparison of Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models

of Price Setting”, ����������������������i����������ki��, 39: 102-125.

Klenow, P. J. and J. L. Willis, (2007), “Sticky Information and Sticky Prices”, �����������

���������������i��, 54(S1): 79-99.

Knotek, E. (2006), “A Tale of Two Rigidities Sticky Prices in a Sticky Information

Environment”,��������������������k����K�������i��, Research Working Paper No. 15.

Korenok, �. (2008), “Empirical Comparison of Sticky Price and Sticky Information Models”,

����������������������i�, 30: 906-927.

Korenok, �., N. Swanson (2007), “How Sticky is Sticky Enough� A Distributional and Impulse

Response Analysis of new Keynesian DSGE Models”, ����������������������i���������ki��,

39: 1481-1508.

Kuhn, Thomas (1970), �������������������i���i�i���������i��, Chicago, University of Chicago

Press.

Kurmann, Andre (2005), “�uantifying the Uncertainty about a Forward-Looking, New

Keynesian Pricing Model”, ��������������������������i��, 52: 1119-1134.

Kuttner, K. and T. Robinson (2010), “Understanding the Flattening Phillips Curve”, ����������

����i���������������������i��������i�����, 21(2): 110-125.

Kydland, F.E. and E.C. Prescott (1977), “Rules Rather Than Discretion: The Inconsistency of

�ptimal Plans”, ��������������i�i�����������, 85(3): 473-492.

Kydland, F.E. and E.C. Prescott (1982), “Time to �uild and Aggregate Fluctuations”,

���������i��, 50(6): 1345-1370.

Page 243: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

243

Lacker Jeffrey M., and John A. Weinberg (200), “Inflation and Unemployment: A Layperson�s

Guide to the Phillips Curve”, �������������������k�����i�������������i�����������, 93: 201-

227.

Leeper E., C. Sims, and T. �ha (1996), “What Does Monetary Policy Do�”, ����ki�����������

���������i�����i�i��, 2: 1-78.

Lelbensteir, J. (1957), ������i�����k�������������������i��������, New York, Wiley.

Lindbeck, A. and D.J. Snower (1985), “E�planations of Unemployment”, ����������i������

������i�����i��, 28(2): 34-59.

Lindbeck, A. and D.J. Snower (1986), “Wage Setting, Unemployment, and Insider-�utsider

Relations”, ����i����������i�����i��, 76(2): 235-239.

Lindbeck, A. and D.J. Snower (1988a), “Cooperation, Harassment and Involuntary

Unemployment: An Insider-�utsider Approach”, ����i����������i�����i��, 78(1): 167-188.

Lindbeck, A. and D.J. Snower (1988b), �������i��������i�����������������������������

������������, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Lind�, Jesper (2005), “Estimating the New-Keynesian Phillips Curves: A Full Information

Ma�imum Likelihood Approach”, ��������������������������i��, 52(6): 1135-1149.

Lipsey, R.G. (1960), “The Relationship �etween Unemployment and the Rate of Change of

Money Wage Rates in the U.K. 1862-1957: A Further Analysis”, ������i��, 17: 1-31.

Lucas, Robert (1972), “E�pectations and Neutrality of Money”, �����������������i��������, 4:

103-124.

Lucas, Robert (1973), “Some International Evidence on �utput-Inflation Trade-offs”, ����i����

������i�����i��, 63: 326-334.

Lucas, Robert E. (1976), “Econometric Policy Evaluation: A Critique”, ������i������������

��������������i����������i�����i��� 1: 19-46.

Mankiw, Gregory (1985), “Small Menu Costs and Large �usiness Cycles: A Macroeconomic

Model of Monopoly”, ���������������������������i��, 100: 529-539.

Mankiw, Gregory (1988), “Recent Developments in Macroeconomics: A �ery �uick Refresher

Course”, ����������������������i���������ki��, 20: 436-458.

Page 244: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

244

Mankiw, Gregory and Ricardo Reis (2001), “Sticky Information �ersus Sticky Prices. A

Proposal to Replace the New Keynesian Phillips Curve”, ��������ki������������i��, No.

8290.

Mankiw, Gregory and Ricardo Reis (2002), “Sticky Information �ersus Sticky Prices: A

Proposal to Replace The New Keynesian Philips Curve”, �������������������������������i��,

117(4): 1295-1328.

Mankiw, N. Gregory (2006), "The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer", ���������������

������i����������i���, 20(4): 29-46.

Mankiw, N. Gregory, and Ricardo Reis (2006), “Pervasive Stickiness”, ����i����������i��

���i��, 96(2): 164-169.

Mankiw, N. Gregory, Ricardo Reis, and Justin Wolfers (2003), “Disagreement About Inflation

E�pectations”, ��������ki������������i����No. 9796.

Mankiw, N.G. (1992), “The Reincarnation of Keynesian Economics”, ���������������i��

���i��, 36(2-3): 559-565.�

Mankiw, N.G. (2001), “The Ine�orable and Mysterious Trade-off �etween Inflation and

Unemployment”,�����������i���������, 111: 45-61.

Mankiw, N.G. and D. Romer (eds) (1991), ����K�����i���������i��, Cambridge, MA: MIT

Press.

Mankiw N.G., R. Reis (2007), “Sticky Information in General Equilibrium”, ���������������

���������������i�������i��i��, 5: 603-613.

Mavroeidis, S. (2005), “Identification Issues in Forward-Looking Models Estimated by GMM,

with an Application to the Phillips Curve”, ����������������������i����������ki��� 37(3): 421-

448.

McDonald, J. (1975), “Wages and prices in Australia: �n the Short and Long-Run Trade-offs

�etween Inflation and Unemployment”, �������i���������i��������� 14 (25): 154-170.

Mirrlees, J. (1975), “A Pure Theory of Underdeveloped Economies”, ���i��������i��

��������������������ed. L.A. Reynolds, New Haven, Yale University Press.

Mortensen, Dale and Christopher A. Pissarides (1994), “Job Creation and Job Destruction in the

Page 245: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

245

Theory of Unemployment”, ���i������������i������i��, 61(3): 397-415.

Nason, James, and Gregor Smith (2008), “The New Keynesian Phillips Curve: Lessons From

Single-Equation Econometric Estimation”, ������i������������ �olume 94, No. 4, �on-line�

�September 5, 2009� available from:

http:��www.richmondfed.org�publications�research�economic�quarterly�2008�fall�pdf�nason�sm

ith.pdf

Nason, James, and Gregor Smith (2008), “Identifying the New Keynesian Phillips Curve”,

���������������i������������i����23: 525-551.

Neiss, Katharine S., and Edward Nelson (2005), “Inflation Dynamics, Marginal Cost, and the

�utput Gap: Evidence from Three Countries”, ����������������������i���������ki��, 37

(December): 1019-1045.

Nelson, C.R. and C.I. Plosser (1982), “Trends and Random Walks in Macroeconomic Time

Series: Some Evidence and Implications”, ��������������������������i��, 10: 139-162.

Nevile, J. (1977), “Domestic and �verseas Influences on Inflation in Australia”, �������i���

������i����������16(28): 121-129.

Nevile, J. (1975), “A Comment on Short-Run and Long-Run Trade-offs �etween Inflation and

Unemployment In Australia”, �������i���������i��������� 14 (24): 132-136.

Norman, R., and A. Richards (2010), “Modelling Inflation in Australia”, �������������

�i�����i��������� No. 03.

�rmerod, Paul (1994), �������������������i��, London, Faber and Faber.

Parkin, M. (1973), “The Short-Run and Long-Run Trade-offs between Inflation and

Unemployment in Australia”, �������i���������i����������12 (21): 127-144.

Parkin, M. (1986), “The �utput-Inflation Trade-off When Prices Are Costly to Change”,

��������������i�i�����������, 94: 200-224.

Parkin, M. and R. �ade (1982), ������������������i��, ��ford, Philip Allan.

Pennant-Rea, Rupert and Clive Crook (1986), ����������i����������i��, New York, Pelican

�ooks.

Page 246: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

246

Perry, L., (1980), “A Note on Phillips and Phillips Curve Economics”, ������i��������, 56

(152): 87-90.

Phelps, E.S. (1967), “Philips Curves, E�pectations of Inflation and �ptimal Unemployment

�ver Time”, ������i��, 34: 254-281.

Phelps, E.S. (1970), �i����������i���������i����������������������������i���������, New

York, Norton.�

Phelps, E.S. (1990), ����������������������������i���������, ��ford, ��ford University

Press.

Phelps, E.S. (1992), “E�pectations in Macroeconomics and the Rational E�pectations Debate”,

in A. �ercelli and N. Dimitri (eds), �����������i��������������������������������i��, ��ford,

��ford University Press.

Phelps, Edmund (1967), “Phillips Curves, E�pectations of Inflation and �ptimal

Unemployment �ver Time”, ������i��, 2(3): 22-44.

Phelps, Edmund (1968), "Money-Wage Dynamics and Labor Market Equilibrium”, �����������

���i�i�����������, 76 (4): 678-711.

Phelps, Edmund (1970), “Introduction”, In Edmund Phelps et al., �i���������i���������i����

������������������������i���������, New York, Norton.

Pissarides, Christopher (1985), “Short-Run Dynamics of Unemployment, �acancies and Real

Wages”, ����i����������i������i��, 75: 676-690.

Polanyi, Michael (1958), ���������K��������, Chicago, Chicago University Press.

Porter, Michael (1990), ����������i�i�������������������i���, New York, Macmillan.

�uandt, R. (1960), “Tests of the Hypothesis That a Linear Regression System �beys Two

Separate Regimes”, �������������������i��������i��i���������i��i��, 55 (290): 324-330.

Rabanal, Pau and Juan F. Rubio-Ramırez (2005), “Comparing New Keynesian Models of the

�usiness Cycle: A �ayesian Approach”, ��������������������������i����52: 1151-1166.

Rao, �. �haskara (1977), “An Analysis of the Short and Long-Run Trade-offs between

Unemployment and Inflation and Estimates of the Equilibrium Steady State Unemployment

Rate in Australia”, �������i���������i��������, 16: 273-284.

Page 247: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

247

Rao, �. �haskara (1992), “A Model of Income, Unemployment and Inflation for the USA”,

����i���������i��, 24(6): 597-605.

Rao, �. �haskara and Tamazian, Artur (2008), “A Model �f Growth and Finance: FIML

Estimates for India”, http:��mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de�8763�

Reis, Ricardo (2005), “Inattentive Producers”, ���i������������i������i��� 73: 793-821.

Richard, Curtin (1996), “Procedure to Estimate Price E�pectations”, mimeo, University of

Michigan Survey Research Center.

Roberts, J.M. (1998), “Inflation E�pectations and the Transmission of Monetary Policy”,

���ki��������, Federal Reserve �oard.

Roberts, J.M. (1995), “New Keynesian Economics and the Phillips Curve”, ������������������

����i����������ki��, 27(4): 975-984.

Roberts, J.M. (2001), “How Well Does the New Keynesian Sticky-Price Model Fit the Data�”

�i����������������i����i�����i������i����No. 13, Federal Reserve �oard.

Romer, Christina and David Romer (2000), “Federal Reserve Information and the �ehavior of

Interest Rates”, ��������i����������i�����i��, 90(3): 429-457.

Romer, David (2001), ��������������������i��, New York, McGraw Hill.

Rotemberg, J.J., M. Woodford (1997), “An �ptimization-�ased Econometric Framework for

the Evaluation of Monetary Policy”, In: �ernanke, �.S., Rotemberg, J.J. (Eds.), �����

�����������i���������, Cambridge, MIT Press.

Rotemberg, Julio (1982), “Sticky Prices in the United States", ��������������i�i�����������,

90(6): 1187-1211.

Rotemberg, Julio (1987), “The New Keynesian Microfoundations", ������i���������������

������i����������������������i���������, edited by Stanley Fischer, 69-104.

Rudd, Jeremy, and Karl Whelan (2005a), “Does Labor�s Share Drive Inflation�”, �����������

�����������i���������ki��, 37: 297-312.

Rudd, Jeremy, and Karl Whelan (2005b), “New Tests of the New Keynesian Phillips Curve”,

��������������������������i��� 52 (September): 1167-1181.

Page 248: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

248

Rudd, Jeremy, and Karl Whelan (2006), “Can Rational E�pectations Sticky-Price Models

E�plain Inflation Dynamics�”, ����i����������i����i��,96 (March): 303-320.

Rudd, Jeremy, and Karl Whelan (2007), “Modelling Inflation Dynamics: A Critical Review of

Recent Research”, ����������������������i����������ki��, 39: 155-170.

Russell, �. and A. �anerjee (2006), “The Long-run Phillips Curve and Non-stationary

Inflation”, �����������i����i�������i����, Working Papers EC� 2006�16.

Salemi, Michael K. (2006), “Econometric Policy Evaluation and Inverse Control”, �����������

�����������i����������ki����38: 1737-1764.

Salop, S.C. (1973), “Wage Differentials in a Dynamic Theory of the Firm”, �����������

������i��������, 6:321-344.

Salop, Steven (1979), “A Model of the Natural Rate of Unemployment”, ����i����������i��

���i��, 69: 117-125.

Samuelson, P.A. and R.M. Solow (1960), “Analytical Aspects of Anti-Inflationary Policy”,

����i����������i�����i��, 49: 177-194.

Sargent, T.J. and N. Wallace (1975), “Rational E�pectations, the �ptimal Monetary Instrument

and the �ptimal Money Supply Rule”, ��������������i�i�����������, 83: 241-254.

Sargent, T.J. and N. Wallace (1976), “Rational E�pectations and the Theory of Economic

Policy”, ��������������������������i��, 2: 169-183.

Sbordone, A. (2002), “Prices and Unit Labor Costs: a New Test of Price Stickiness”, �����������

���������������i��� 49 (2): 235-456.

Sbordone, Argia M (2005), “Do E�pected Marginal Costs Drive Inflation Dynamics�”, ��������

������������������i��, 52: 1183-1197.

Shimer, R. (2005), “The Cyclical �ehaviour of Equilibrium Unemployment and �acancies”,

����i����������i�����i��, 95(1): 25-49.

Shimer, Robert (1998), “Why is the U.S. Unemployment Rate So Much Lower�”,

http:��www.princeton.edu��shimer

Shimer, Robert (2007), “Mismatch”, ��������i����������i�����i��, 97(4): 1074-1101.

Shimer, Robert (2007), “Reassessing the Ins and �uts of Unemployment”,

Page 249: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

249

http:��robert.shimer.googlepages.com�reassess-print.pdf

Shimer, Robert and Ivan Werning (2007), “Reservation Wages and Unemployment Insurance”,

�������������������������������i��, 122(3): 1145-1185.

Simes, R. and C. Richardson (1987), “Wage Determination in Australia”, ������i��������, 63(181): 144-155.

Simon, Herbert (1957), ������������������i����������i����, New York, John Wiley and Sons.

Simon, Herbert (1959), “Theories of Decision Making in Economics and �ehavioral Science”,

����i����������i�����i��, 49: 253-283.

Simon, Herbert (1979), “Rationality Decision Making in �usiness �rganizations”, ����i����

������i�����i��, 69: 493-513.

Simon, Herbert (1991), “�rganizations and Markets”, �����������������i����������i���, 5: 25-

44.

Sims, C. (2003), “Implications of Rational Inattention”, ��������������������������i��, 50:

665-690.

Smets, F., R. Wouters (2003), “An Estimated Stochastic General Equilibrium Model of the

Euro Area”, ������������������������������i�������i��i��� 1(5): 1123-1175.

Snowdon, �rian and Howard, �ane, ������������������i�� (2005), MA (USA), Edward

Elgar.

Solow, R.M. (1979), “Another Possible Source of Wage Stickiness”, �������� ���

�����������i��, 1:79-82.

Solow, R.M. (1990), ��������������k�����������i�������i���i��, ��ford, �asil �lackwell.

Solow, R.M. (1997), “Is There a Core of Usable Macroeconomics That We Should All �elieve

In�”, ����i����������i�����i��, 87(2): 230-232.

Solow, Robert (1981), “�n Theories of Unemployment”, ����i����������i�����i��, 91: 848-

866

Solow, Robert (2010), “�uilding a Science of Economics for the Real World”, Prepared

Statement of Robert Solow, Professor Emeritus, MIT, to the House Committee on Science and

Technology, Subcommittee on Investigations and �versight.

Page 250: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

250

Stiglitz, J.E. (1976), “The Efficiency Wage Hypothesis, Surplus Labor and The Distribution of

Income in L.D.C.�s”, �������������i��������, 28: 185-207.

Stiglitz, J.E. (1982), “The Wage-Productivity Hypothesis: Its Economic Consequences and

Policy Implications”, Paper presented at the New York Meetings of the American Economic

Association. Also in M.J. �oskin, ed., ��������������������i������i���i�����, ��ford, �asil

�lackwell, 1987, pp. 130-165.

Stiglitz, J.E. (1984), “Theories of Wage Rigidity” ��������ki������������i��, No. 1142.

Stiglitz, J.E. (1997), “Reflections on the Natural Rate Hypothesis”, �����������������i��

��������i���, 11(1): 3-10.

Stiglitz, J.E. (1976), “Prices and �ueues as Screening Devices in Competitive Markets”, �����

�����i������������������, Stanford University.

Stiglitz, Joseph (2000), “The Contributions of the Economic of Information to Twentieth

Century Economics”, ���������������������������i��, 115: 1441-1478.

Stiglitz. J.E. and A. Weiss (1983), “Incentive Effects of Terminations: Applications to the

Credit and Labor Markets”, ����i����������i�����i��, 73: 912-927.

Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson (2007), “Why Has U.S. Inflation �ecome Harder to

Forecast�”, ����������������������i���������ki��� 39: 3-34.

Stone, A., T. Wheatley and L. Wilkinson (2005), “A Small Model of the Australian

Macroeconomy”, �����������k�����������i���i�����i��������, No. 11.

Summers, Lawrence (1986), “Why Is the Unemployment Rate So �ery High Near Full

Employment�”, ����ki��������������������i�����i�i��, 2: 339-383.

Summers, Lawrence, Charles Holt, Robert Hall, Martin �ailey, and Kim Clark (1979), “Labor

Market Dynamics and Unemployment: A Reconsideration”, ����ki��������������������i��

���i�i��, 1: 13-72.

Svensson, Lars (1997), “Inflation Forecast Targeting: Implementing and Monitoring Inflation

Targets”, ���������������i�����i��, 410: 1111-1146.

Taylor, John (1979), “Staggered Wage Setting in a Macro Model”, ����i����������i�����i��,

69(2): 108-113.

Page 251: New Keynesian Theories of Inflation and Output

251

Taylor, John (1980), "Aggregate Dynamics and Staggered Contracts", ��������������i�i����

�������, 88(1): 1-23.

Thurow, L.C. (1983), ���������������������������������������i��, New York, Random

House.

Tisdell, Clem (1996), �����������i����i�������������i��������i��, MA (USA), Edward

Elgar.

Tovar, Camilo (2008), “DSGE Models and Central �anks”, ���k�������������i�����������������

���ki������������.

Trabandt, M. (2006), “Sticky Information vs. Sticky Prices: A Horse Race in a DSGE

Framework”, ���ki��������, Humboldt University.

Weiss, A. (1991), ���i�i������������������������������������������������������i�����i��,

��ford, Clarendon Press.�

Weiss, Andrew (1980), “Job �ueues and Layoffs in Labor Markets with Fle�ible Wages”

��������������i�i������������ 88: 526-538.

Woodford, M. (2003), ���������������i������������i�������������������������������i��,

Princeton, Princeton University Press.

Woodford, Michael (2001), “Imperfect Common Knowledge and the Effects of Monetary

Policy”, ��������ki������������i��, No. 8673.

Woodford, Michael (2008), "Convergence in Macroeconomics: Elements of a New Synthesis",

Annual Meeting of the American Economics Association,

http:��www.columbia.edu��mw2230�Convergence�AEJ.pdf

Yellen, J. (1984), “Efficiency Wage Models of Unemployment”, ����i����������i�����i��,

74: 200-205

Yule, G.U. (1926), "Why Do We Sometimes Get Nonsense Correlations between Time Series�

A Study in Sampling and the Nature of Time Series", �������������������������i��i�������i���

89: 1-64.

�hang, Chengsi, Denise �sborn, and Dong Heon Kim (2008), “The New Keynesian Phillips

Curve: From Sticky Inflation to Sticky Prices”, ����������������������i���������ki��, 40: 667-

699.


Recommended