+ All Categories
Home > Documents > NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the...

NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the...

Date post: 25-Jul-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 2 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
36
Nominal GDP Targeting, Real Economic Activity and Inflation Stabilization in A New Keynesian Framework Huiying Chen Department of Economics, University of Central Oklahoma Abstract This paper examines the performance of a nominal GDP growth targeting (NGDP-GT) rule versus a Taylor rule in a New Keynesian model. Compared to the Taylor rule, the targeting of the growth rate of nominal GDP leads to the avoidance of nearly half of the fluctuations in output, consumption, and inflation when an economy is hit by a total factor productivity shock. The NGDP-GT regime produces one third less fluctuation in output and consumption when the economy is subject to a markup shock. Remarkably, NGDP-GT does not cause inflation instability; in fact, it generates only half of the volatility in inflation compared to the Taylor rule. Involving a more appealing combination of output and inflation to absorb shocks, the NGDP-GT is a demonstrable and system- atic improvement. NGDP-GT can better address the dual mandate of the Fed- eral Reserve. Another advantage of NGDP-GT is the increasing prominence of smoothing fluctuations of real economic aggregates as the target of GDP growth increases within a plausible range. Moreover, the NGDP-GT rule outperforms strict inflation targeting and a strong response to inflation rule in stabilizing la- bor (subject to a markup shock), output, consumption, real wage and the real marginal cost. Key words: Nominal GDP Targeting; Inflation Targeting; Taylor Rule; Stabi- lization; Fluctuations; Shocks. JEL Classification: E31; E52; E58; E50 1
Transcript
Page 1: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Nominal GDP Targeting, Real Economic Activity and Inflation

Stabilization in A New Keynesian Framework

Huiying Chen

Department of Economics, University of Central Oklahoma

Abstract

This paper examines the performance of a nominal GDP growth targeting(NGDP-GT) rule versus a Taylor rule in a New Keynesian model. Compared tothe Taylor rule, the targeting of the growth rate of nominal GDP leads to theavoidance of nearly half of the fluctuations in output, consumption, and inflationwhen an economy is hit by a total factor productivity shock. The NGDP-GTregime produces one third less fluctuation in output and consumption when theeconomy is subject to a markup shock. Remarkably, NGDP-GT does not causeinflation instability; in fact, it generates only half of the volatility in inflationcompared to the Taylor rule. Involving a more appealing combination of outputand inflation to absorb shocks, the NGDP-GT is a demonstrable and system-atic improvement. NGDP-GT can better address the dual mandate of the Fed-eral Reserve. Another advantage of NGDP-GT is the increasing prominence ofsmoothing fluctuations of real economic aggregates as the target of GDP growthincreases within a plausible range. Moreover, the NGDP-GT rule outperformsstrict inflation targeting and a strong response to inflation rule in stabilizing la-bor (subject to a markup shock), output, consumption, real wage and the realmarginal cost.

Key words: Nominal GDP Targeting; Inflation Targeting; Taylor Rule; Stabi-lization; Fluctuations; Shocks.JEL Classification: E31; E52; E58; E50

1

Page 2: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

1 Introduction

Prior to the frequent federal funds rate hikes in the recent two years, the economic

crisis of 2007 to 2009 and the nominal interest rate at the zero lower-bound (ZLB)

revived economists’ interest in the targeting of nominal GDP (or nominal income)

as an attractive monetary policy option. Before 2008, the Taylor rule had kept its

prevalence of nearly two decades by virtue of being both relatively simple to compute

and practically implementable by the Federal Reserve while having great effectiveness

in preventing the recurrence of high inflation. As pointed out by Sumner (2014), if the

Great Moderation had continued, there would be few reasons to abandon the Taylor

rule. The current study is motivated by the ineffectiveness of the Taylor rule due to

the ZLB in recent years and its congenital defects in requiring the measurement of

real economic activity and core inflation, and by the discussion about nominal GDP

targeting.

This paper evaluates a nominal GDP growth rate targeting (NGDP-GT) rule and

a Taylor rule within a calibrated New Keynesian framework. For empirically plausible

sizes of total factor productivity (TFP) shocks, the NGDP-GT regime can significantly

improve economic performance in comparison to the Taylor rule regime. Relative to

the Taylor rule, the NGDP-GT rule leads to a reduction of deviations by 40% or

more in output, inflation, consumption, real wage, real marginal cost and interest

rate when a negative TFP shock impacts the economy. When a negative markup

shock hits the economy, anywhere from a third to a half of all variation in output,

inflation, labor, consumption, real wage, real marginal cost and interest rate can be

avoided by targeting the NGDP growth rate. In addition, I found that the standard-

deviation-ratios of key variables between the Taylor rule and NGDP-GT rule increase

along with the NGDP growth rate, which reveals that when the NGDP growth rate

2

Page 3: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

increases within a plausible range the NGDP-GT rule further outperforms the Taylor

rule. Moreover, even though policy arrangements cannot be explicitly ranked when

nesting inflation targeting (IT) and strong response to inflation (IR)-type rules into

the pool, countries that implement strict IT and IR rules are expected to experience

smoother labor (in a markup shock case), output, consumption, real wage, and interest

rate paths. These countries are expected also to recover faster in recessions when they

instead pursue nominal GDP targeting.

The baseline setup of this paper is characterized by three sectors of the econ-

omy: households, monopolistically-competitive firms that face adjustment costs, and

a monetary authority. The private-sector equilibrium is constituted by optimal paths

of consumption, labor, real wage, real marginal cost, output, and inflation. For the

NGDP-GT rule, I keep the growth rate of nominal output between two consecutive

periods constant. In the benchmark model, the growth rate of NGDP is set to the U.S.

historical level. The paper then shows results that are robust to various nominal GDP

growth rates and to different magnitudes of shocks.

This paper contributes to the literature on NGDP targeting in the following as-

pects. First, the stability of an NGDP targeting rule is verified, and there is an

exploration of the mechanism that contributes to that stability. There is also a quan-

titative demonstration to what extent this rule can smooth out fluctuations of the

economy in comparison with the Taylor rule within a New Keynesian DSGE frame-

work. McCallum (1987), McCallum (1989), and Hall & Mankiw (1994) found that

this policy rule provides policy makers operability and robustness due to its favorable

performance across a range of models. In response to the ’Ball-Svensson’ instability

conclusion of Ball (1997) and Svensson (1997), McCallum (1997) utilizes a model in-

volving forward-looking rational expectations and alternative analysis of supply-side

specifications where he ultimately shows that the result of Ball (1997) and Svensson

3

Page 4: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

(1997) is fragile. To examine these two competing results, Dennis (2001) considers

the general case where inflation expectations are a mixture of backward-looking and

forward-looking terms, which nests those of Ball (1997) and McCallum (1997) as spe-

cial cases. This general case yielded the result that nominal GDP growth targeting did

not lead to instability. In a recent paper, Henderson & Kim (2005) designs a model

that features optimization and monopolistic competition in both product and labor

markets where one-period nominal contracts signed before shocks are known. Quali-

tatively, nominal-income-growth targeting turned out to dominate inflation targeting

for plausible parameter values In a more recent literature, Garín et al. (2016)finds that

nominal GDP targeting is associated with smaller welfare losses compared to a Taylor

rule regime.

A second finding of this article is that the NGDP growth rate matters to the

relative performance of NGDP-GT. Standard deviation ratios of key variables between

the Taylor rule and NGDP-GT regimes turn out to have a positive linear relationship

with the NGDP growth rate, implying that an increase in GDP growth rate within a

plausible range strengthens the comparative advantages of NGDP-GT rule.

Third, when the economy is mainly subject to shocks that do not necessarily involve

monetary policy trade-offs for society, NGDP-GT is also relatively more effective in

stabilizing output, consumption, labor, and wage, which differs from Jensen (2002).

Jensen (2002)evaluates NGDP-GT versus IT and concludes that when the economy

is mainly subject to shocks that do not involve monetary policy trade-offs for society,

nominal income growth targeting is not preferred.

Finally, a conclusion can be drawn that nominal output targeting minimizes vari-

ance of all key economic indicators, such as real output, consumption, inflation, labor

and real wage, thereby minimizing the variance of the combination of real output and

price level; this is in line with the conclusions of Meade (1978), Tobin (1980) and Bean

4

Page 5: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

(1983).

The rest of this paper is organized in the following structure: Section 3 outlines

the model and defines the private-sector equilibrium. Section 4 provides a description

of the policy rules. Section 5 presents the calibration of the model. Section 6 shows

the main results of this paper. Section 7 presents some robustness analysis. Section 8

concludes.

2 The Model

The economy is composed of three sectors: a continuum of infinitely-lived households

who derive utilities from consumption and leisure, monopolistically-competitive firms

that hire labor as the only input to produce differentiated products and face an ad-

justment cost for changing prices, and the monetary authority. The paper assumes an

efficient labor market.

2.1 Households

The representative household seeks to maximize the objective function:

E0

∞∑t=0

βtU(ct,lt)(1)

where β ∈ (0, 1) is the subjective discount factor, E0 is the mathematical expectation

operator conditional on information available in period 0. ct is the composite con-

sumption index, and lt is labor. The period utility function U(ct,lt) is assumed to be

continuous and twice differentiable, satisfying the usual properties: ∂U(·)∂c2 6 0, ∂U(·)

∂l< 0,

and ∂U(·)∂l2

6 0.

As standard in NK models, consumption ct is a Dixit-Stiglitz aggregator of differ-

5

Page 6: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

entiated products cj,t, supplied by monopolistically-competitive firms:

ct =(� 1

0c

εt−1εt

j,t dj,t

))εt

εt−1

(2)

where εt measures the elasticity of substitution between two varieties of final goods.

The elasticity of substitution is set to be time-varying to allow for exogenous cost-push

shocks. All else equal, an increase in εt leads to a fall in the desired markup, and hence

to less inflationary pressure in equilibrium. The paper allows for markup shocks (i.e.

variations in εt) to avoid the ’Divine Coincidence’ result. In what follows, the study

also considers a constant elasticity of substitution, which is the case with TFP shocks

only.

The solution to the household’s problem of maximizing the consumption bundle ct

for any given level of expenditures yields the set of demand equations:

cj,t =(Pj,tpt

)−εt

ct, (3)

where Pt =(� 1

0P1−εtj,t dj

) εtεt−1 is the Dixit-Stiglitz price index that results from cost

minimization.

Maximization is subject to the sequence of the budget constraints:

ct + Bt

Pt= Rt−1Bt−1

Pt+ Wtlt

Pt+ Trt

Pt+ Πt

Pt(4)

where Bt represents the quantity of one-period nominally riskless bond that is pur-

chased in period t and matures in period t+ 1. Each bond pays one unit of money at

maturity. Rt is the nominal gross policy (or market) interest rate. Wt denotes nominal

wage, and wt denotes the real wage expressed as Wt

Pt. Trt is the net nominal transfers,

and Πt stands for nominal profits from the ownership of firms. Household’s choices of

6

Page 7: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

ct, lt and Bt yield the following optimality conditions:

−Ul,tUc,t

= wt (5)

and

Uc,t = βRtEt

(Uc,t+1

πt+1

)(6)

where πt = Pt

Pt−1is the gross inflation rate, and Uc,t and Ul,t are respectively the marginal

utility of consumption and labor. Equation (1.5) describes the labor supply decisions,

and Equation (1.6) describes the optimal consumption decisions, which is the standard

Euler equation in consumption.

2.2 Firms

There is a continuum of identical monopolistically-competitive firms indexed by j ∈

[0, 1]. Each firm j hires labor as the only input and produces a differentiated product

yj,t using the identical technology:

yj,t = ztlj,t (7)

where zt represents the level of aggregate productivity, assumed to be common to all

firms, and to evolve exogenously over time. lj,t is the labor hired by firm j at time

t. First consider the cost minimization problem of firm j, min wtlj,t s.t. yj,t = ztlj,t,

where by symmetry, it implies

mct = wtzt

(8)

where mct is the Lagrange multiplier on the output constraint (7) and also the real

7

Page 8: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

marginal cost of production. Equation (1.8) is the labor demand function.

The pricing of a firm is subject to a quadratic adjustment cost as in Rotemberg

(1982),

φ

2

(Pj,tPj,t−1

− π)2

yt (9)

where φ > 0 determines the degree of price rigidity, and π is the gross steady-state

inflation rate.

The problem for firm j is then to choose its price to maximize the expected present

discounted stream of profits:

E0∑∞t=0

βtUc,t

Uc,0

{(Pj,t

Pt−mcj,t)yj,t − φ

2 ( Pj,t

Pj,t−1− π)2yt

}(10)

subject to the downward-sloping demand curve that firm j faces:

yj,t =(Pj,tPt

)yt (11)

where βtUc,t

Uc,0is the stochastic discount factor.

Firms can change their prices in each period, subject to the adjustment cost. There-

fore, all the firms face the same problem, and thus will choose the same price and

produce the same quantity. In other words, Pj,t = Pt and yj,t = yt for any j. Hence,

the first-order condition for a symmetric equilibrium

1− φ(πt − π)πt + βφEt

[Uc,t+1

Uc,t(πt+1 − π)πt+1

yt+1

yt

]= εt(1−mct) (12)

is the Rotemberg version of the non-linear Phillips curve showing that current inflation

is a function of future expected inflation, the real marginal cost, and the level of output.

At steady state, this equation collapses to the familiar condition, mc = ε−1ε

which is

8

Page 9: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

the inverse of the steady state gross price markup.

Since all firms will employ the same amount of labor, the aggregate production

function is simply given by:

yt = ztlt (13)

2.3 Market Clearing

In equilibrium, the aggregate resource constraint is given by:

yt = ct + φ

2 (πt − π)2yt (14)

2.4 The Private Sector Equilibrium

Given the exogenous process of zt and εt the private sector equilibrium is a state-

contingent sequence of allocations of {ct, lt, wt,mct, yt, πt}that satisfies the equilibrium

conditions of (5)-(6), (8) and (12)-(14) .

3 Policy Regimes

Given the model described above, I examine the performance of two simple policy rules

in the benchmark analysis. One rule targets the growth rate of nominal output and

the other resorts to the nominal interest rate as the instrument to respond to changes

of the economy (Taylor rule). Next, I discuss these two policy rules and analyze their

performances following a negative TFP shock and a negative markup shock with the

exogenous processes of zt and εt.

9

Page 10: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

3.1 Nominal GDP Growth Targeting Rule

McCallum (1998), Orphanides (1999), and Trehan (1999) suggest that monetary pol-

icy should focus on nominal output growth because such a strategy does not rely on

uncertain estimates of the level of the output gap. Rudebusch (2002)admits that it

automatically takes into account movements in both prices and real output and can

serve as a long-run nominal anchor for monetary policy. Such a target linked to a

weighted average of inflation and employment will better address the Fed’s dual man-

date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting

versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015) provides evidence that in the presence of

persistent supply and demand shocks, nominal GDP level targeting (NGDP-LT) is

not preferable. During ZLB episodes, NGDP-LT leads to larger fluctuations in eco-

nomic activity. Therefore, the paper mainly focuses on the growth-rate targeting. In

the NGDP-GT regime, policymakers observe and respond only to the variations of

nominal GDP growth rate.

Nominal GDP growth assumes that the monetary authority commits to a certain

growth rate of nominal GDP. Letting Yt being nominal output, this rule reads:

YtYt−1

= k (15)

where k is the growth rate of NGDP. Equation (1.15) can be rewritten as:

ytyt−1

πt = k (16)

The regime of NGDP-GT implies a positive steady state inflation (or zero inflation

when k is set to 1). In particular, π = k at steady state.

10

Page 11: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

3.2 The Taylor Rule

Following Faia (2008), a standard nonlinear version of the Taylor rule without labor

market inefficiency is an interest rate reaction function of this form:

log(Rt

R

)= ρrlog

(Rt−1

R

)+ (1− ρr)[ρπlog

(πtπ

)+ ρylog

(yty

)] (17)

where R and y represent the steady-state values of nominal gross interest rate and real

output, ρr denotes the smoothing coefficient of the interest rate, and ρπ and ρy are

respectively the coefficients of inflation and output. In line with the literature, the

interest rate responds to the deviations of inflation and output from their targets (or

steady-state values).

Different from most of the literature about the Taylor Rule, the paper does not

presume a zero (net) inflation steady state. For the purpose of consistency, the value

of π in the Taylor rule anchors at the value of π in the NGDP-GT rule, which also equals

to k. These identical steady-state inflation settings under the two policy frameworks

ensure that the steady-state values under both rules are the same. Any differences

between the rules will not result from the different steady states, which allows for

direct comparisons and contrasts between the policies to be made. For the benchmark

analyses, π in the benchmark analysis is set to 1.016 in the two regimes described

above. Other values are considered in the robustness tests.

4 Calibration

4.1 Functional Forms

Assume the following period utility function:

11

Page 12: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

U(ct, lt) = c1−σt

1− σ − χl1+θt

1 + θ(18)

where σ is the curvature parameter, which represents households’ risk aversion. χ is

the scaling parameter and θ is the inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution

(IES) for labor supply.

Total factor productivity and the elasticity of substitution are governed by the

following AR(1) process:

log(zt) = (1− ρz)log(µz) + ρzlog(zt−1) + vt (19)

log(εt) = (1− ρε)log(µε) + ρεlog(εt−1) + ut (20)

with ρz and ρε being the AR(1) coefficients of these processes, µz and µε, deterministic

steady state value of zt and εt respectively, being normalized to 1 and 6, the innovation

terms vt ∼ N(0, σ2z) and ut ∼ N(0, σ2

ε ). In the benchmark model, σz is set to 0.048 and

σε is set to 0.380 to generate a 0.015 standard deviation in output under the Taylor

rule.

4.2 Parameterization

Table 1 lists the baseline parameter values. These parameters are set to widely accepted

values based on US data. Assuming a time unit of one quarter, the discount factor β

is set to 0.99, implying a 4% annual interest rate. The risk aversion parameter sv is

set to 1.5. The scaling parameter χ is set to 12.792, so that the deterministic steady-

state value of l is 0.21, implying an average workweek of 35 hours in line with the

empirical average of weekly hours per worker over the period of 1964:Q1-2014:Q1, as

12

Page 13: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

in Abo-Zaid (2015). The underling theory introduced in Faia & Monacelli (2007) and

Abo-Zaid (2015) implies the adjustment cost parameter φ = λ(λ−1)(ε−1)λ−β(λ−1) , with λ being

the quarterly price duration. Following Christiano et al. (2005) and Abo-Zaid (2015),

I set the price duration to 2.5 quarters. The deterministic steady-state value of εt is

set to 6, so that the net steady-state markup is 20%, consistent with the literature.

In the benchmark calibration, I assume the monetary authority targets the nominal

GDP growth rate k at 1.016 based on the historical quarterly GDP growth rate over

the period of 1947:Q1-2015:Q1. Moreover, other values of k are used in Section 6. The

value of R can be easily obtained from the consumption Euler equation: R = π/β.

The steady-state output level y is determined by the aggregate production function.

Values of ρr, ρπ and ρy are set following Faia (2008).

5 Quantitative Results

This section presents the numerical results regarding the two policy rules when the

economy is hit by a TFP shock and a markup shock. A general approach to policy

evaluation is to check the ability of the policy to smooth output, consumption, infla-

tion, labor and other important aggregates paths around the potential levels. This

smoothing can be achieved by producing the least fluctuations in these important eco-

nomic indicators. Tables 2 and 3 and Figures 1 and 2 provide the dynamic results of

these two policy regimes with respect to a negative TFP shock and markup shock.

5.1 Moment Conditions

Tables 2 and 3 report the results of the first and second moments of the economic

indicators following shocks of the same magnitude. Compared to the Taylor rule, the

prevention of swings in NGDP growth vastly helps prevent deviations of economic

13

Page 14: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

aggregates from their trend path. The variables under the NGDP-GT render to be

substantially less volatile than under the Taylor rule. The standard deviations of

output, consumption, and inflation under the NGDP-GT are 60%, 60%, and 40%,

respectively, of the ones under the Taylor rule when the economy is hit by a negative

TFP shock. The Taylor rule also brings about at least 50% more fluctuations in real

wage and approximately 25%r more fluctuations in real marginal cost. Remarkably,

the interest rate appears to be sluggish under the NGDP-GT regime. Following an

exogenous markup shock, the Taylor rule still produces more than 40%, 40%, and

110% of fluctuations than the other regime, sequentially, on output, consumption, and

inflation, and about 42% more deviations on labor, real wage, and real marginal cost.

The interest rate also repeats its performance from the TFP shock scenario.

The effect of NGDP-GT on real economic activity and inflation stabilizing is sur-

prising to what economic intuition would suggest when the economy is subject to

supply shocks. The above numbers and the nature of the two policy rules reflect the

mechanism that makes the NGDP-GT rule a ’systematic improvement’. The Taylor

rule turns out to be rather aggressive in manipulating the interest rate to stabilize in-

flation; it places a larger weight on the deviation of inflation from its target. Through

the policy instrument of interest rates, the Taylor rule allows for variations in output

as well as other economic aggregates to absorb any shocks in order to keep inflation

under control. However, this forms an unstable environment for inflation and leads

to inflation’s “surprising” instability relative to the NGDP-GT rule: generating 60%

more fluctuations. In contrast, NGDP-GT does not cause inflation instability, but in

fact produces considerably low standard deviations. In fact, the NGDP-GT allows out-

put and inflation to share the shock burden, which results in mild variations in these

two variables. Furthermore, with the absence of an active interest rate as the transi-

tory channel, dramatic variations in other key economic aggregates are also effectively

14

Page 15: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

avoided.

An interesting point is labor’s performance following a productivity shock. The

negative correlation of labor with output shown in Table 2 and the behavior of labor

following TFP shocks in the impulse responses under the NGDP-GT rule in this paper

is consistent with the theoretical indication of Gali (1999) in his class of models with

imperfect competition, sticky prices, and variable effort. The combination of price

stickiness and demand constraints leads firms, in the short run, to contract labor in

the presence of a positive TFP shock and to expand labor in the face of a negative

TFP shock.

5.2 Impulse Responses

The impulse responses enable us to observe the short-run behavior of some key variables

following a negative TFP shock and a negative markup shock in order to gain some

insights about the mechanisms of the model. Since the paper considers each scenario

separately and there is no asymmetry in the model, the responses to positive shocks

are not shown, as they are just mirror images of the results to negative shocks. Figure

1 presents the response of the economy to a shock to productivity. Figure 2 displays

the behavior of the key variables following a negative markup shock.

In general, a negative TFP or markup shock decreases the aggregate supply as well

as output, leading to higher inflation that, in turn, drives up the nominal interest rate.

A negative TFP shock also reduces the demand for labor, causing a decline in the labor

and wages.

Figure 1 shows that under a Taylor rule, a negative TFP shock greatly undermines

output, consumption and the real wage, and produces more inflation, albeit associated

with a soaring nominal interest rate, which as a consequence, further discourages con-

sumption and output. When shocked with the same magnitudes under NGDP-GT,

15

Page 16: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

the above variables become inertial around the steady-state values with the assistance

of the systematic stability of NGDP-GT.

The responses to an exogenous markup shock essentially replicate the results of a

TFP shock with some differences in the behavior of labor. A markup shock directly

affects the marginal cost and inflation. The markup shock in Figure 2 causes a rise

in inflation, in line with the standard result in the NK model with ad-hoc cost push

shocks. This shock also leads to the drops in output, consumption, labor and wage as

in the case of the TFP shock. Figure 2 provides the solid evidence that even after the

introduction of an exogenous process to generate a trade-off between stabilizing output

and stabilizing inflation, the performances of the key economic indicators under the

NGDP-GT rule landslide those under the Taylor rule.

One side effect of policy rules, according to Hall & Mankiw (1994), is that it may

bring high volatility to other variables when keeping one variable under tight control.

The NGDP-GT rule, however, does not rely solely on the interest rate as an instrument.

With the economy anchored at a constant NGDP growth rate, the monetary authority

will respond accordingly once the actual growth rate deviates from the target. Target-

ing the growth rate assists in finding the point where the relative levels of output and

inflation lead to lower volatility of the economy. One of the advantages of NGDP-GT is

that maintaining output stability also serves as maintaining inflation stability1, which

does not compromise to the introduction of a trade-off between inflation stability and

output stability. These prove that NGDP-GT significantly outperforms the Taylor rule

in stabilizing the key economic aggregates, and could effectively prevent the economy

from stumbling into severe recessions when negative supply shocks hit the economy.1This could also be observed through log-linearization of the policy equation (1.16) in period t and

t+1: logyt+1− logyt+ logπt+1 = k, logyt− logyt−1 + logπt = k. By reorgamizing these two equations,we can derive log[ gyt+1

gyt] + log[πt+1

πt] = 0, where gyt+1 = log(yt+1/yt).

16

Page 17: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

6 Robustness Analysis

Sensitivity analysis takes the form of varying one parameter relative to the baseline.

This section shows the relative volatility changes under the two policy regimes with

deviations to the baselines of structural parameters.

6.1 Changing the Target Rate

Figure 3 shows the results when NGDP growth rate varies between 0% and 8% (net

annual rate) following the productivity shock. The ratios presented are between the

standard deviations under the Taylor rule and those under the NGDP-GT rule for

corresponding variables following a negative TFP shock.

The results for k < 1, which indicates a negative GDP growth rate, are not consid-

ered. From this robust test, two conclusions are drawn. First, the main claim of this

paper, that NGDP-GT outperforms the Taylor rule in stabilizing the economy, is ro-

bust to different targeting rates. Second, the volatility ratios, as shown in Figure 3, are

increasing for all variables in the value of k, a prominent advantage of the NGDP-GT

rule in better smoothing economic fluctuations with a higher k.

The test results have similarities when the economy is hit by a markup shock relative

to the results following a TFP shock, as shown in Figure 4, with a 0% to 8% net annual

GDP growth.

6.2 Elasticity between the Shock and Output Deviation

If the two types of shocks generate more volatility under the Taylor rule, then the

increased volatility can be taken as a strong indication that the Taylor rule regime is

more sensitive to shocks. Accordingly, this implies that in order to achieve a specific

level of output deviation, the Taylor rule regime would only require a smaller σz relative

17

Page 18: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

to the other rule. Consistent with the literature, I set a standard deviation of output

at 0.015.

As shown in Table 4, compared to the Taylor rule, it takes 1.65 times the size of

the TFP shock, and 1.4 times the magnitude of the markup shock for the NGDP rule

at any given k; to achieve the same output deviation (0.015), which again highlights

the advantage of NGDP growth targeting. Meanwhile, the advantage can be tested

by going one step further. By deriving the different values of σz for various k (or

π) to generate a 0.015 deviation of output under the Taylor rule, I list the standard

deviations of the six variables under two policy scenarios for each derived σz. Results

inform no significant difference from those of the benchmark model.

6.3 Changing Magnitudes of Shocks

In this experiment, I increase the shock size to observe the nature of the NGDP-GT

rule with respect to stability. Figures 5 and 6 show the results when the magnitude

of the shock is twice that of the benchmark value. I found no significant changes in

the relative performance between these two policy rules from the benchmark model.

Furthermore, the NGDP-GT regime becomes much more favorable as the magnitude

of the shocks (σz = 0.096 and σε = 0.761) are twice the value of the magnitudes of the

two shocks required separately to generate a 0.015 output deviation under the Taylor

rule in the benchmark model.

6.4 A Strict Inflation Targeting Rule and A Strong Inflation

Response Rule

Besides Taylor type rules and NGDP-GT rules, strict inflation targeting (IT) rules and

strong inflation response (IR) rules also receive much attention. There are about 28

18

Page 19: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

countries, including the United Kingdom, Canada, Australia, New Zealand, Sweden,

Brazil, Norway, and other countries, that are using inflation targeting through fixing

the consumer price index (CPI) as their monetary policy goal, as in Jahan (2012). In

this subsection, I add these two inflation-type-rules into the pool- a strict IT rule and

a strong IR rule to examine the relative performance of NGDP-GT rule among a wider

range of regimes.

As in Svensson (1999), the monetary authority is assumed to have perfect control

over the inflation rate. It sets the inflation rate in each period. For simplicity purposes,

I assume the inflation rate is set at its steady-state value π at any period t. Inflation

targeting can be written

πt = π (21)

Following Faia (2008), a strong IR rule can be expressed as Equation (1.17) by

setting ρπ = 5, and ρy = 0.

Since variables under the strong IR rule behave similar to their performance under

the IT rule, this paper mainly presents the impulse responses of the IT rule, the Taylor

rule, and the NGDP-GT rule. Tables 5 and 6, and Figures 7 and 8 show the dynamic

results of these three policy regimes following a negative TFP shock and a negative

markup shock.

In both scenarios, the NGDP-GT rule is still preferable in stabilizing output, con-

sumption, wage, interest rate and labor (only in the case of the markup shock). The

relative performance of the NGDP-GT rule is more favorable compared to the IT rule

in the case of a markup shock. In addition, it still holds for the above variables that

the volatility ratios of the economic aggregates are increasing in the value of k. The

economic intuition of the above results is quite straightforward. Following a supply

19

Page 20: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

shock, we either allow output or inflation or a combination of the two to absorb the

shock, which implies variations on output, inflation, or both. When keeping inflation

under control to allow output to fluctuate, which is the cases of IT rule and the Taylor

rule; it generates deviations in output and other important economic aggregates. When

keeping NGDP under control to allow output and inflation to share the shock burden,

it brings moderate variations in both variables and prevents other economic indica-

tors from fluctuating dramatically through the interest rate channel. However, due to

the nature of the IT rule, inflation keeps constant in both scenarios. Thus, policy ar-

rangements cannot be explicitly ranked according to the first order solution. Further,

welfare analysis will solve this question. Nevertheless, countries that implement strict

IT rules are expected to experience smoother paths of output, consumption, labor (only

in the case of the markup shock), and real wage, and recover faster in recessions when

switching to the nominal GDP targeting.

7 Conclusion

In this paper, I examine the performance of a nominal GDP targeting (NGDP-GT)

rule and a Taylor rule in a simple New Keynesian DSGE model. Results show that

the primary benefits of the NGDP-GT are lower volatilities in the output, inflation,

labor, and other important economic aggregates following a TFP shock. The NGDP-

GT framework reduces fluctuations in output and inflation by 40% or more in contrast

to the Taylor rule regime. Furthermore, implementing the NGDP-GT rule following a

markup shock reduces output volatility by one third and inflation by one half. More-

over, as the nominal output growth rate is set at a higher level within a plausible range,

the NGDP-GT regime further outperforms the Taylor rule. These results are robust

to introducing different magnitudes of shocks and various target rates.

20

Page 21: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

In a larger set of policy rules that includes strict inflation targeting and a strong

response to inflation rules, the NGDP-GT rule appears to have more advantages in sta-

bilizing output, consumption, wage and labor, but it is subject to further confirmation

whether this rule is the most efficacious.

This study stays within the domain of comparing alternative policy rules. This

paper did not discuss the conduction of the rule. As the implementation of the NGDP-

GT does not rely on the nominal interest rate as the sole instrument, alternative

monetary instruments that follow the NGDP-GT could replace the nominal interest

rate, a very meaningful and attractive difference during zero-lower-bound episodes.

21

Page 22: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Appendix

Table 1: Values of the Parameters

Parameter Description Value

β Households’ discount factor 0.990σ Risk aversion 1.500χ Scaling parameter 12.792θ Inverse of IES 0.250φ Price adjustment cost parameter 18.473µz Mean of productivity index 1.000µε Mean of elasticity of substitution between goods 6.000k Nominal GDP growth rate(gross) 1.016R Steady-state gross interest rate 1.026π Steady-state gross inflation 1.016y Steady-state output 0.210ρr Smoothing coefficient of the interest rate 0.900ρπ Coefficients of inflation in Taylor Rule 1.500ρy Coefficients of output in Inflation Targeting 0.125ρz AR(1) coefficient of TFP 0.950ρε AR(1) coefficient of MKP 0.900σz Standard deviation of the innovation term in TFP 0.048σε Standard deviation of the innovation term in MKP 0.380

22

Page 23: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Table 2: Moment Conditions under the two regimes following a TFP shock

Policies Moments y c π R l w mc

TR

x 0.2214 0.2214 1.0016 1.0133 0.2105 0.9020 0.8584

std(x) 0.0150 0.0150 0.0794 0.0170 0.0006 0.0898 0.0322

autocorr(x) 0.7482 0.7482 -0.0095 0.7469 0.7452 0.7509 0.7842

corr(x, y) 1.0000 1.0000 -0.5303 -1.0000 0.7468 1.0000 0.9978

NGDP-GT

x 0.2171 0.2171 1.0155 1.0254 0.2061 0.8717 0.8282

std(x) 0.0093 0.0093 0.0321 0.0010 0.0052 0.0502 0.0076

autocorr(x) 0.7457 0.7457 -0.0487 0.8340 0.7003 0.7500 0.5676

corr(x, y) 1.0000 1.0000 -0.3493 -0.8597 -0.9975 1.0000 -0.9708

Note: x represents the variable mean, std(x) is the standard deviation of a variable, autocorr(x)stands for autocorrelation, and corr(x, y) is the correlations between a variable and y.

23

Page 24: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Table 3: Moment Conditions under the two regimes following a markup shock

Policies Moments y c π R l w mc

TR

x 0.2162 0.2162 1.0081 1.0195 0.2162 0.8762 0.8762

std(x) 0.0150 0.0150 0.0798 0.0165 0.0150 0.1042 0.1042

autocorr(x) 0.7301 0.7301 -0.0229 0.7293 0.7301 0.7301 0.7301

corr(x, y) 1.0000 1.0000 -0.5390 -1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000

NGDP-GT

x 0.2144 0.2144 1.0155 1.0252 0.2144 0.8636 0.8636

std(x) 0.0106 0.0106 0.0378 0.0023 0.0106 0.0736 0.0736

autocorr(x) 0.7281 0.7281 -0.0605 0.8374 0.7281 0.7281 0.7281

corr(x, y) 1.0000 1.0000 -0.3639 -0.9676 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000

Table 4: Various values of σz, σε and the standard deviation of output.

kTFP Shock Markup Shock

TR NGDP TR NGDP

k=1.0000, net annual rate=0% 0.0489 0.0775 0.3825 0.5356

k=1.0025, net annual rate=1.00% 0.0488 0.0776 0.38221 0.5361

k=1.0050, net annual rate=2.00% 0.0487 0.0775 0.3819 0.5365

k=1.0074, net annual rate=3.00% 0.0486 0.0776 0.3816 0.5370

k=1.0099, net annual rate=4.00% 0.0485 0.0776 0.3813 0.5374

k=1.0161, net annual rate=6.58% 0.0482 0.0777 0.3805 0.5385

k=1.0194, net annual rate=8.00% 0.0481 0.0778 0.3825 0.5392

24

Page 25: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Table 5: Moment Conditions following a TFP shock

Policies Moments y c π R l w mc

TR x 0.2214 0.2214 1.0016 1.0133 0.2105 0.9020 0.8584

std(x) 0.0150 0.0150 0.0794 0.0170 0.0006 0.0898 0.0322

corr(x, y) 1.0000 1.0000 -0.5303 -1.0000 0.7468 1.0000 0.9978

NGDP-GT x 0.2171 0.2171 1.0155 1.0254 0.2061 0.8717 0.8282

std(x) 0.0093 0.0093 0.0321 0.0010 0.0052 0.0502 0.0076

corr(x, y) 1.0000 1.0000 -0.3493 -0.8597 -0.9975 1.0000 -0.9708

IT x 0.2178 0.2178 1.0160 1.0234 0.2069 0.8769 0.8333

std(x) 0.0104 0.0104 0.0000 0.0038 0.0042 0.0576 0.0000

corr(x, y) 1.0000 1.0000 0.0261 -1.0000 -1.0000 1.0000 0.0062

25

Page 26: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Table 6: Moment Conditions following a markup shock

Policies Moments y c π R l w mc

TR x 0.2162 0.2162 1.0081 1.0195 0.2162 0.8762 0.8762

std(x) 0.0150 0.0150 0.0798 0.0165 0.0150 0.1042 0.1042

corr(x, y) 1.0000 1.0000 -0.5390 -1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000

NGDP-GT x 0.2144 0.2144 1.0155 1.0252 0.2144 0.8636 0.8636

std(x) 0.0106 0.0106 0.0378 0.0023 0.0106 0.0736 0.0736

corr(x, y) 1.0000 1.0000 -0.3639 -0.9676 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000

IT x 0.2153 0.2153 1.0160 1.0224 0.2153 0.8699 0.8699

std(x) 0.0129 0.0129 0.0000 0.0095 0.0129 0.0898 0.0898

corr(x, y) 1.0000 1.0000 -0.0123 -1.0000 1.0000 1.0000 1.0000

26

Page 27: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Figure 1: Impulse Responses to a negative TFP shock

27

Page 28: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Figure 2: Impulse Responses to a markup shock

28

Page 29: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Figure 3: The relative volatilities of variables between the Taylor rule and the NGDP-GT rule for k ∈[1.0000,1.0194] following a TFP shock.

Figure 4: The relative volatilities of output, inflation and labor between the Taylorrule and the NGDP-GT rule for k ∈ [1.0000, 1.0194] following a markup shock.

29

Page 30: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Figure 5: Impulse Responses to σz = 0.096

30

Page 31: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Figure 6: Impulse Responses to σε = 0.761

31

Page 32: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Figure 7: Impulse Responses to a negative TFP shock

32

Page 33: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Figure 8: Impulse Responses to a negative markup shock

33

Page 34: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

References

Abo-Zaid, S. (2015), ‘Optimal long-run inflation with occasionally-binding financial

constraints.’, European Economic Review 75, 18–42.

Ball, L. (1997), ‘Efficient rules for monetary policy.’, National Bureau of Economic

Research Working Paper (5952).

Bean, C. (1983), ‘Targeting nominal income: An appraisal.’, The Economic Journal

93(372), 806–819.

Billi, R. (2015), ‘A note on nominal gdp targeting and the zero lower bound.’, Sveriges

Riksbank Working Paper (270).

Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M. & Evans, C. (2005), ‘Nominal rigidities and the dy-

namic effects of shock to monetary policy.’, Journal of Political Economy 113(1), 1–

45.

Dennis, R. (2001), ‘Inflation expectations and the stability properties of nominal gdp

targeting.’, The Economic Journal 111(468), 103–113.

Faia, E. (2008), ‘Optimal monetary policy rules with labor market frictions.’, Journal

of Economic Dynamics & Control 32(5), 1600–1621.

Faia, E. & Monacelli, T. (2007), ‘Optimal interest rate rules, asset prices, and credit

frictions.’, Journal of Economic Dynamics & Control 31, 3228–3254.

Gali, J. (1999), ‘Technology, employment, and the business cycle: Do technology shocks

explain aggregate fluctuations.’, American Economic review 89(1), 249–271.

Garín, J., Lester, R. & Sims, E. (2016), ‘On the desirability of nominal gdp targeting’,

Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 69, 21–44.

34

Page 35: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Hall, R. & Mankiw, G. (1994), Nominal income targeting., in ‘Monetary policy’, Uni-

versity of Chicago Press, pp. 71–93.

Henderson, D. & Kim, J. (2005), ‘Inflation targeting and nominal-income-growth tar-

geting: When and why are they suboptimal?’, Journal of Monetary Economics

52(8), 1463–1495.

Jahan, S. (2012), ‘Inflation targeting: holding the line.’, Finance & Development, www.

imf. org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/basics/target. htm .

Jensen, H. (2002), ‘Targeting nominal income growth or inflation?’, The American

Economic Review 92(4), 928–956.

McCallum, B. (1987), ‘The case for rules in the conduct of monetary policy: a concrete

example.’, Economic Review .

McCallum, B. (1989), Monetary Economics: Theory and Policy, New York: Macmillan.

McCallum, B. (1997), ‘The alleged instability of nominal income targeting.’, National

Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper (6291).

McCallum, B. (1998), Issues in the design of monetary policy rules., in ‘Handbook of

Macroeconomics’, New York: North-Holland.

Meade, J. (1978), ‘The meaning of internal balance.’, The Economic Journal 91, 423–

435.

Orphanides, A. (1999), The quest for prosperity without inflation., in ‘Manuscript’,

Federal Reserve Board.

Rotemberg, J. (1982), ‘Sticky prices in the united states.’, Journal of Political Economy

90(6), 1187–1211.

35

Page 36: NominalGDPTargeting,RealEconomicActivityandInflation ...date, according toSumner (2014). In the debate on nominal income level targeting versus growth rate targeting, Billi (2015)

Rudebusch, G. (2002), ‘Assessing nominal income rules for monetary policy with model

and data uncertainty.’, The Economic Journal 112, 402–432.

Sumner, S. (2014), ‘Nominal gdp targeting: A simple rule to improve fed performance.’,

Cato Journal 34(2).

Svensson, L. (1997), ‘Inflation targeting: some extensions’, National Bureau of Eco-

nomic Research Working Paper. (5962).

Svensson, L. (1999), ‘Price-level targeting versus inflation targeting: A free lunch?’,

Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 31(3), 277–295.

Tobin, J. (1980), ‘Stabilization policy ten years after.’, Brookings Papers on Economic

Activity (1), 19–72.

Trehan, B. (1999), ‘Supply shocks and the conduct of monetary policy.’, FRBSF Eco-

nomic Letter 21.

36


Recommended