+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Date post: 25-Feb-2016
Category:
Upload: sitara
View: 34 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point. Anchoring. Reading. Predictably Irrational Chapter 1 The Truth about Relativity Chapter 2 The Fallacy of Supply and Demand Nudge , “Rules of Thumb” in Chapter 1 - PowerPoint PPT Presentation
56
Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point Anchori ng
Transcript
Page 1: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Non-standard preferences:

How we choose by comparing with a nearby

reference point

Anchoring

Page 2: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Reading

• Predictably Irrational– Chapter 1 The Truth about Relativity – Chapter 2 The Fallacy of Supply and Demand

• Nudge, “Rules of Thumb” in Chapter 1• Thinking, Fast and Slow, Chapter 11

(“Anchors”)

Page 3: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Willingness to pay

• Standard economics assumes that a consumer knows what he/she would be willing to pay for any given commodity

• Behavioral economics shows that consumers generally have no clue what a given object is worth to them

• Consumers tend to estimate their willingness to pay for an object by using irrelevant information about other objects

Page 4: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Willingness to pay

• If there is a disconnect between what we are willing to pay for a commodity and some objective measure of the benefit obtained from that commodity, part of the case for the supremacy of free market-based economic systems loses validity

• A government, for instance, could impose price control, arguing that, as prices are arbitrary, price control could not have serious negative effects

Page 5: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Next, each bid the maximum amount they would be willing to pay for each item. Did the initial “anchor” amount influence each student’s ultimate bids?

In this experiment, business students were asked if they would pay the last 2 digits of their social security numbers for each of several items (e.g., 34 = $34)

Page 6: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

“Although students were reminded that the social security number is a random quantity conveying no information, those who happened to have high social security numbers were willing to pay much more for the products.”

Ariely, D. (MIT), Lowenstein, G. (Carnegie Mellon), & Prelec, D. (MIT), 2006, Tom Sawyer and the construction of value. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 1-10.

Page 7: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Anchoring experiment

Page 8: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Anchoring: another experiment

1. Subject witnesses the number that comes up when a wheel of fortune is spun

2. Is asked whether the number of African countries in the U.N. is greater than or less than the number on the wheel of fortune

3. Is asked to guess the number of African countries in the U.N.

Result: those who got higher numbers on the wheel of fortune guessed bigger numbers in Step 3

Page 9: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Anchoring and Adjustment

• When asked to estimate the population of Milwaukee, people in Chicago, IL consistently guess more than people in Green Bay, WI

• People begin the process of estimation with whatever information readily appears in their minds (anchoring)

• They then reassess their initial answers based on rough notions of what is a not-too-silly answer (adjustment)

Page 10: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Anchoring and Adjustment

• Statisticians have consistently measured the effect of the anchor value on the estimate that people make

• For different anchors, people make different estimates

• For any given change in the anchor, the estimate tends to change by 55% of the change in the anchor– See the top paragraph of page 124, Thinking, Fast and

Slow

Page 11: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Heuristics Lead to Biases

• Unfortunately, we tend to be too cautious in the adjustment phase

• As a result, the initial anchor tends to heavily influence our final estimates

• Our final estimates tend to get biased by our anchoring heuristics

Page 12: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

How happy are you?

• College students were asked the following questions in sequence:– How happy are you? – How often are you dating?

• The two answers showed a low correlation (0.11)

Page 13: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

How happy are you?

• Then the question sequence was reversed:– How often are you dating?– How happy are you?

• The two answers showed a high correlation (0.62)

• The answer to the dating question (objective and easily determined) acted as an anchor to the happiness question

Page 14: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Anchors and nudges

• It is possible to influence the figure you will choose in a particular situation by ever-so-subtly suggesting a starting point (anchor) for your anchoring-and-adjustment rule of thumb

Page 15: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Anchors and nudges

• People will give more to a charity – if the suggested options are $100, $250, $1,000,

and $5,000, – than if the options are $50, $75, $100, and $150

• Lawyers suing businesses in product liability cases, can get high jury awards if they succeed in getting jury members to anchor on multi-million dollar figures

Page 16: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Experiment:Business students were told their professor would be doing a 15-minute poetry reading. Half were asked if they would be willing to pay $2 to attend and half were asked if they would be willing to attend if they were paid $2. After answering, students were then told that the poetry reading would be free and were asked if they wanted to attend.

Question:Would the initial anchoring of the experience’s value affect who would attend for free?

Ariely, D. (MIT), Lowenstein, G. (Carnegie Mellon), & Prelec, D. (MIT), 2006, Tom Sawyer and the construction of value. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 1-10.

Page 17: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Initially asked if paid $2

Initially asked if cost $2

0%

5%

10%

15%

20%

25%

30%

35%

40%

8%

35%W

illin

g to

Att

end

for F

ree

Ariely, D. (MIT), Lowenstein, G. (Carnegie Mellon), & Prelec, D. (MIT), 2006, Tom Sawyer and the construction of value. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 1-10.

Page 18: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Perhaps students were just

using price as an

estimate of unknown quality?

Page 19: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Experiment #2:Now the professor first read poetry for 1 minute so that students actually experienced it. Then one group was asked if they would be willing to pay to attend, the other group if they would be willing to attend if paid.

Question:Would the anchoring effect go away when people were allowed to sample the experience first?

Ariely, D. (MIT), Lowenstein, G. (Carnegie Mellon), & Prelec, D. (MIT), 2006, Tom Sawyer and the construction of value. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 1-10.

Page 20: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

0%10%20%30%40%50%60%

9%

49%W

illin

g to

att

end

for f

ree

Ariely, D. (MIT), Lowenstein, G. (Carnegie Mellon), & Prelec, D. (MIT), 2006, Tom Sawyer and the construction of value. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 1-10.

Page 21: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Anchors can be sticky

• Subjects were made to listen to a slightly annoying sound

• Group 1 (2) was asked whether they’d listen to the sound again for 10 (90) cents

• Subjects were asked for what payment would they listen to the sound again

Result: Group 1 bid less than Group 2, indicating that anchoring had occurred

Page 22: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Anchors can be sticky

• The same subjects were made to listen to a slightly annoying sound

• Both groups were asked whether they’d listen to the sound again for 50 cents

• Subjects were asked for what payment would they listen to the sound again

Result: Group 1 again bid less than Group 2, indicating that the initial anchoring was still dominant

Page 23: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Anchors can be sticky

• The same subjects were made to listen to a slightly annoying sound

• Group 1 (2) was asked whether they’d listen to the sound again for 90 (10) cents

• Subjects were asked for what payment would they listen to the sound again

Result: Group 1 again bid less than Group 2, indicating that anchoring, once established, can be hard to shake

Page 24: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Starbucks and Dunkin Donuts

• Starbucks entered the coffee market after Dunkin Donuts was already established

• How were they able to get away with charging a lot more for coffee, given that coffee drinkers were anchored to Dunkin Donuts?

• By differentiating themselves from Dunkin Donuts in numerous (largely superficial) ways

Page 25: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Experiment with two types of subscription offers to The Economist magazine.

Which offer do you think was most popular?a) The firstb) The secondc) The thirdd) All were about

equale) The first and third

were about equal

Page 26: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

When these three choices were presented…

16%

0%

84%

Page 27: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Some were given only these two choices. Should the preferences be different for those without the second choice?

Page 28: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

When only two choices were presented…

16%

84%

68%

32%

0% X

Page 29: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Nearby comparison and choice [anchoring and adjustment]

The presence of the comparably worse nearby option, made the third option seem better.

16%

84%

Page 30: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Nearby comparison and choice

Without the comparably worse nearby option, the relative preference reversed.

16%

84%

68%

32%

Page 31: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Nearby comparison and choiceFirst group could have either $9 or a nice pen

Second group could have $9, a nice pen, or an uglier pen

Page 32: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Nearby comparison drives choice [anchoring and adjustment]

Group A Group B$9 64% 52%Cross pen 36% 46%Ugly pen 2%n 106 115

Simonson, I. (UC-Berkeley) & Tversky, A. (Stanford), 1992, Choice in context: Tradeoff contrast and extreme aversion. Journal of Marketing Research, 29, 281-295.

Page 33: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

“Williams-Sonoma, a mail-order and retail business located in San Francisco, used to offer one home bread maker priced at $275. Later, a second home bread maker was added, which had similar features except for its larger size. The new item was priced more than 50% higher than the original bread maker. Williams-Sonoma did not sell many units of the new (relatively overpriced) item, but the sales of the less expensive bread maker almost doubled.” Simonson, I. (Stanford), 1999, The effect of

product assortment on buyer preferences, Journal of Retailing, 75(3), 347-370.

When bread makers were new…

Page 34: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Is this grill expensive?

Beefeater Signature SL - 6 Burner BBQ

$5,984.05

from www.barbecue-grill-guide.com

Page 35: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

How about now?

Beefeater Signature SL - 6 Burner BBQ

$5,984.05$6,299.00

from www.barbecue-grill-guide.com

Page 36: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

And now?

Beefeater Signature SL - 6 Burner BBQ

$5,984.05$6,299.00

from www.barbecue-grill-guide.com

Page 37: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

How about now?

Beefeater Signature SL - 6 Burner BBQ

$5,984.05$6,299.00

from www.barbecue-grill-guide.com

$12,500.00Beefeater Signature SL - 6 Burner BBQ: Gold Plated Edition

Page 38: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

The Compromise Effect• [In an] experiment decades ago by Dr. [Itamar] Simonson,

then at Duke [but now at Stanford] … some subjects chose among three Minolta cameras: an inexpensive one, a midprice one and an expensive one.

• Another group was given a choice of just two of the Minoltas: the midprice one and the less expensive one.

• The researchers found that when study subjects had only two choices, most chose the less expensive camera with fewer features.

• But when given three choices, most chose the middle one.

Page 39: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

The Compromise Effect

• Dr. Simonson called it “the compromise effect” — the idea that consumers will gravitate to the middle of the options presented to them.

• The study showed how marketers could manipulate consumers.

• Just by presenting three differently priced options, they could get consumers to gravitate to a midprice one from a less expensive one.

Page 40: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

The Compromise Effect

• This finding further led Dr. Simonson and other scholars to describe widespread “irrational” behavior by consumers who made decisions not based on a product’s actual value but on how the item was presented relative to other products.

Page 41: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

The Compromise Effect

• In a more recent study, Dr. Simonson repeated his experiment but now giving his experimental subjects access to online amazon.com-style product reviews

• Now the compromise effect disappeared!• When people have the necessary information,

they no longer need to play it safe by picking the middle option

Page 42: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

From Compromise Effect to Absolute Value

• Absolute Value: What Really Influences Customers in the Age of (Nearly) Perfect Information– By Itamar Simonson and

Emanuel Rosen, HarperBusiness, 2014

Page 43: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Producers want to anchor to a higher priced alternative– Even if it means creating

an artificial alternative

Producers avoid anchoring to a lower priced alternative– Differentiation is key

If we anchored Starbucks coffee by Dunkin Donuts coffee, would

we buy Starbucks?http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=FaO3aGmuNFc

Page 44: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Designing a restaurant’s menu

• Expensive items on a restaurant menu can help even if no one orders them; they can steer customers to pricier (but not as expensive) items they were avoiding

Page 45: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Nearby comparisons in college quality

Question: Does having a top public university in your home county make you more likely to attend a higher quality college even if you do not attend college locally?

What do you think?a) Yes, but only for families with high wealth and educationb) Yes, but only for families with moderate or lower wealth

and educationc) Yes, for families of any wealth and educationd) No.

Do, C. (UC-Santa Barbara), 2004, The effects of local colleges on the quality of college attended. Economics of Education Review, 23, 249-257.

Page 46: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Question: Does having a top public university in your home county make you more likely to attend a higher quality college even if you do not attend college locally?a) Yes, but only for families with high wealth and

educationb) Yes, but only for families with moderate or lower

wealth and educationc) Yes, for families of any wealth and educationd) No.

Why is this “nearby” comparison more important for families with less education?

Do, C. (UC-Santa Barbara), 2004, The effects of local colleges on the quality of college attended. Economics of Education Review, 23, 249-257.

Page 47: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Anchoring in physical attraction?

http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=9X68dm92HVI 14:30-15:54

Page 48: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Anchoring shows

excessive influence of

nearby comparisons

Conclusion

Page 49: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

You can change your nearby comparisons by changing your environment or your focus within your environment.

Page 50: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Be intentional about choosing comparisons, instead of automatically using the easy anchor.

Page 51: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Mary is seriously overspending her income. Today, she buys these Escada shoes because they are marked down from $995 to $895. And also the matching $995 clutch purse, because it is 20% off if purchased as a set.

How might anchoring bias have affected her decision? How might she reframe her view of the price that would make the “good deal” easier to resist?

Page 52: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Relativity in earnings

• Our happiness tends to depend on relative salary– In 1993, federal securities regulators forced

companies to reveal the pay and perks of their top executives.

– This accelerated the demand for higher salaries• Perhaps companies should instead be required to

reveal the salaries of their rank-and-file workers!Average CEO pay in the US as a multiple of average worker pay1976 36

1993 131

2008 369

Page 53: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Relativity in earnings

• Standard economics claims that earnings are determined by productivity

• The evidence that we have just seen seems to suggest that there are other sociological forces at work that create a disconnect between earnings and productivity

Page 54: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Relativity in earnings

• Wealth — Any income that is at least $100 more a year than the income of one's wife's sister's husband.– H.L. Mencken, A Mencken Chrestomathy

(1949)

Page 55: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

We need to watch ourselves!

• Now that we know how easily we’re influenced by obviously irrelevant cues to which we get anchored, we need to develop a habit of constantly asking ourselves tough questions about our economic choices

Page 56: Non-standard preferences: How we choose by comparing with a nearby reference point

Video

• Anchoring, with Daniel Kahneman: http://youtu.be/HefjkqKCVpo


Recommended