+ All Categories
Home > Documents > O Sullivan parte 1.pdf

O Sullivan parte 1.pdf

Date post: 08-Jan-2016
Category:
Upload: juanu
View: 22 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 22

Transcript
  • \

    {

    Urban Economics FIFTH EDITION

    Arthur O'Sullivan Deparlmenl of Economics

    Lewis & Clark College

    LIBROS COMPAIA

    Cnllc 19 No. 3-16 Local 104 librosycomp@ho1ma i l.com Telcfox: 34 1 71 00 Bogo1. O.C. B McGraw-Hill t:M lrwin

    Boston Burr Ridge, IL Dubuque. IA Madison. WI New York San Francisco St. Louis Bangkok Bogot Caracas Kuala Lumpur Lisbon London Madrid Mexico City Milan Montreal New Delhi Santiago Seoul Singapore Sydney Taipei Toronto

  • CHAPTER 2

    Why Do Cities Exist?

    Man is the only animal that makes bargains; one dog does not change bones with another dog.

    -AOAM SMITH

    c ities exisl because it is efficient to produce sorne goods on a large scale. An activity is subject to economies of scale if the average cost of production decreases when we scale up the operation and produce more output. The way to exploit economies of scale is to concentrate production ata small number of sites. Because workers can economize on travel time, cities develop around these production sites. One of the folk theories of urban economics is that if there were no econornies of scale, there would be no cities. In this case, every household would be self-sufficient, producing its own goods and services in its own home. There would be no reason for cities because the cost of urban living (e.g., a high price of land) would not be offset by any benefits. As we'll see in this chapter, cities exist because the benefits associated with concentrated production more than offset the costs of living in a high population density.

    A REGION WITHOUT CITIES Under what conditions would a region have no cities? In other words, what set of assumptions guarantees a uniform distrbulion of population? In this section, we develop an economic model that generales a region without cities. This model provides a list of assumptions that together preclude the development of cities. Later in the chapter, we will relax these assumptions, and the new model will then predict that cities will develop.

    Consider a region that produces and consumes two goods: shirts and bread. People use land to grow raw materials (wool from sheep and wheat) and take time to transform the raw materials into shirts and bread. Travel within the region is by foot: Residents walk ata speed of eight miles per hour (four round-trip miles per hour). The following assumptions together preclude urban development.

    19

  • 20 Par! 1 Market Forces in the Developmen1 of Cilies

    1. Equal productivity. Ali residents are equally productive at producing bread and shirts. Similarly, ali land is equally productive in the production of raw materials.

    2. No scale economies in production. Production is subject to constant retums to scale; a worker produces one shirt per hour, regardless of how many shirts he or she makes. Similarly, the amount of bread produced per hour is independent of the volume produced.

    3. No scale economies in transportation. The transpo1t cost per unit shipped per rnile is independent of the volume shipped. These assumptions eliminate the possibility of trade. Every household in the

    region will produce its own bread and shirts. Because every household is equally productive in producing both goods, there are no advantages from specialization and trade. Although you could specialize in bread and exchange your surplus bread for shirts produced by someone else, you are justas efficient as everyone else in produc-ing shirts, so there is no advantage from specializing and trading. The disadvantage of trade is that it takes time away from production. Moreover, there are no economies of scale, so each person will produce one shirt or one loaf per hour, regardless of how much he or she produces. Therefore, it would not be sensible to bui ld a shirt factory ora bakery to produce on a large scale. Again, the disadvantage of central-ized production is that trade takes time away from production. To summarize, there are no advantages from trade or centralized production, so every household in the region will be self-sufficient.

    In this case, the population will be distributed uniformly throughout the region. To see the reason for the uniform concentration, consider what would happen if there were a concentration of population at sorne location in the region. The higher deni.and for land at that location would bid up the price of land, and households 1 iving in the concentration would be worse off than those living elsewhere. In response, the households in the concentration would move to places with lower land prices. In this equilibrium, there would be a uniform price for land and a uniform population density. There would be costs from concentrated production (higher land prices), but no benefits, so there would be no cities.

    TRADING CITIES

    Our model of the region without cities assumes that all households are equally productive in the production of shirts and bread. In this part of the chapter, we'll relax this assumption and show that comparative advantage may lead to the development of trading cities. Historically, trading cities developed to facilitate trade between people in different pa1ts of a region.

    Comparative Advantage Generates Trade In our model of the region without cities, we assume that all households are equally productive in the production of shirts and bread. If this assumption is relaxed, one

  • Chapter2 WhyDoCitiesExist? l.' i\JIVL 21 .._ .. Ut ' -' NI . . , .... ,, " ,-part of the region may have a comparative advantage irrsfrt production, and the other part may have a comparative advantage in bread production. It is possible-but not certain- that comparative advantage will cause specialization and trade.

    The notion of comparative advantage can be explained with a simple numerical example. Suppose that the northern half of the region is more productive than the southem half. In Table 2-1, the North has an absolute advantage in producing both bread and shirts; northem residents produce twice as much bread per hour and six times as many shirts per hour. The differences in productivity could be caused by differences in labor skills, weather, or natural resources.

    The notion of comparative advantage is based on the principie of opportunity cost. In a one-hour period, a northern worker can produce either six shirts or two loaves of bread. Therefore, the opportunity cost of a shirt is one-third loaf, and the opportunity cost of bread is three shirts. A southern worker can produce either one loaf or one shirt, so the opportunity cost of bread is one shirt, and vice versa. The North has a comparative advantage in the production of shirts beca use the opportunity cost of shirts is one-third loaf of bread, compared to one loaf in the South. Similarly, the South has a comparative advantage in bread because its opportunity cost of one loaf of bread is one shirt, compared to three shirts in the north.

    Comparative advantage may lead to trade between the North and South. To explain the possible advantages of trade, suppose that al! households in the region are initially self-sufficient. Suppose the exchange rate is two shirts per loaf of bread; that is, the price of bread is two shirts. If both regions move in the direction of specialization, both can get more goods to consume. As shown in the first row of Table 2-2, i fa northern household switches one hour of work from bread production to shirt production, it produces six additional shirts but two fewer loaves of bread. If a southern household switches three hours from shirt production to bread, it produces three more loaves but three fewer shirts. As shown in the second row of numbers, given the exchange rate of two shirts per loaf, the northern household can exchange

    TABLE 2-1 Comparative Advantage

    Bread Shirts

    Output per Hour South North

    2 6

    Opportunit)' Cost South North 1 shirt 1 loar

    3 shirts 1/3 loaf

    TABLE 2-2 SpeciaJization and the Gains from Trade

    Change in production Exchange 2 shirts per loaf Net effect of change in production and exchange

    Bread -2 loaves +3 loaves + l loaf

    North Shirts +6 shirts -6 shirts o

    Bread +3 - 3 loaves

    o

    South Shirts -3 shins +6 shirts +3 shirls

    ANGEL A JANNE DE LA O

  • 22 Part 1 Market Forces in the Developmcnt of Citics

    its six extra shirts for three loaves of bread from the southern household. On the ftip side, the southern household exchanges its three extra loaves for six shirts. As shown in the last row, the northem household has a gain of one loaf of bread, while the southem household has a gain of three shirts. In this case, each household benefits from a move toward specialization in the good for which it has a comparative advantage.

    What about transportation costs? Trade between the two households will be beneficia! if the transportation costs involved in trading aren't too large. Suppose that it takes an hour to execute a trade. For the northem household, the opportunity cost ofthe hour spent trading is the amount ofbread the household could produce for itself during this time. The opportunity cost is two loaves so it would not be sensible to trade. If, however, the travel time is less than a half hour, the household would have a net gain from trade. For example, it the trade takes only one-fifth of an hour, the opportunity cost is four-tenths of a loaf, leaving a net gain of six-tenths of a loaf. Similarly, the southern household would have a net gain. Therefore, households in the two regions will speciali ze and trade, exploiting their comparative advantages to increase consumption.

    Although there is now specialization and trade, there wi ll not be any cities. Given the fourth assumption (no scale economies in transportation), households in the two regions will engage in direct trade. Each northern household will link up with a southem household to exchange shirts and bread. There is no reason for an intermediary because individuals can transport goods as efficiently as someone who transports goods in bulk.

    Scale Econornies in Transportation and Trading Cities We can extend the model to incorporate scale economies in transportation. Suppose the transport cost per unit per mile decreases as the vol u me transported increases. In this case, it will be cheaper to transport shirts and bread in bulk, and it will be sensible for individual households to rely on intermediaries (middlemen or rniddlefolks) to collect, transport, and distribute shirts and bread. From the perspective of individual households, it will be sensible to pay middlefolks sorne amoum of bread to transport the goods, freeing up time to produce more outpul. For the northem household, paying the middlefolks one-tenth of a loaf would be better than spending one-fifth of an hour (at a cost of 0.4 loaves) transporting the bread and shirts. Similarly, the southern household would be better off paying something less than one-fifth of a shirt to have someone else take care of transportation.

    To fully exploit scale economies in transportation, a trading firm must collect and distribute a large volume of output. A trading firm will locate ata place convenient for the collection and distribution of goods, causing the development of marketplaces at crossroads, ports, river junctions, and other transshipment points.

    The location decisions of traders cause the development of market cities. People employed by the trading firms will live near the marketplace to economize on com-muting costs, and will bid up the price of land near the marketplace. As the price of land increases, residents will economize by occupying relatively small lots. In other

  • Chapter 2 Why Do Cities Exist? 23

    words, the population density around the marketplace will be higher than in the rest of the region. A city is defined as a place with a relatively high population density, so the combination of comparative advantage and scale economies in transportation causes the development of a market city.

    The market city develops because three conditions are satisfied. First, produc-tivity is high enough that people outside the city produce enough bread and shirts for themselves and the urban traders. The agricultura! surplus feeds and clothes the urban workers. Second, the differences in productivity that generate comparative ad-vantage are large enough to offset transportation costs, so trade occurs. Third, there are scale economies in transportation, meaning that intermed iaries (middlefolks) are more efficient at transporting and marketing goods, generating central marketplaces.

    Historical Insights: The English Woolen lndustry Before the Norman Conquest in 1066, the making of wool cloth in England was an entirely local affair. Individual households and villas raised their own sheep, spun the raw wool into yarn, and wove the yarn into cloth. In other words, households were self-sufficient in cloth production, and no cities were involved in the production or trade of wool cloth. A small number of towns and cities were involved in local trade.

    The Norman Conquest increased the interaction between England and the con-tinent, setting the stage for the development of the woolen cloth trade. The barriers to trade fell, and England was able to exploit its comparative advantage in the pro-duction of wool cloth. Exports to the continent rose, causing the development of small cities and towns based on the cloth trade.

    FACTORY CITIES

    T he third assurnption underlying the region without cities is the constant returns to scale in production. Specifically, each worker can produce either one shirt or one loaf of bread per hour, regardless of how much the worker produces. There are no advantages from centralized production in factories, so ali goods will be produced in homes. Jf we drop the assurnption of constant returns to scale and introduce scale economies in the production of shirts, factory production may replace home production, causing the development of factory cities.

    Scale Economies and the Shirt Factory Suppose that there are advantages from the large-scale production of shirts. In other words, as the volume of production increases, the labor required to produce one shirt decreases. Figure 2-1 shows the average labor times for different arnounts of factory shirts. The average labor time decreases frorn one hour for one shirt (the sarne time as home production) to one-fourth hour for an output of 400 shirts. T hese scale econornies arise for two reasons.

  • 24

    ? :e "' 8-::> o :, "' E ... o

    J:> '" ..J

    Part 1 Market Forces in the Development of Cities

    FIGURE 2-1 Scale Economies in Shirtmaking

    0.50

    0.25

    200 400 Number of shirts

    600

    If there are scale economies in shirtmaking. the average time required 10 make a shirt dccreases as thc volume produced increases.

    l. Factor specialization. A home worker performs ali the tasks associated with making a shirt: The raw wool is spun into yarn; the yarn is woven into cloth; the raw cloth is finished; the pieces of the finished cloth are sewn in to a shirt. A large operation allows labor specialization with each worker being assigned a single task; there could be spinner, a weaver, a finisher, anda sewer. The specialization of labor increases productivity because (a) a worker's productivity increases with repetition and (b) a worker spends less ti me switching from one production task to another.

    2. Indivisible inputs. An input to the production process is indivisible if the input has a mnimum efficient scale. If an indivisible input is cut in half, the total output of the two halves is less than the output of the whole. T he shirt factory uses equipment (spinning machines, power looms, and sewing machines) that cannot be efficiently scaled down for use by individual shirtmakers. As output increases, the factory uses more indivisible inputs, increasing productivity.

    If the shirt factory produces 400 shirts per day, it wi ll employ 100 workers, each of whom produces four shirts per hour.

    What about the wage of factory workers and the price of a shirt? The wagc must be high enough to make shirt workers indifferent between working in the factory and working at home. Recall that a home worker can produce one loaf of bread per hour. To make the shirt worker indifferent, the wage must be one loaf of bread per hour of factory work. To keep the example simple, suppose that there are no other costs of producing shirts. Because each worker produces four shirts per hour, and is paid one Ioaf, the firm 's production cost per shirt is 0.25 loafof bread.

  • Chap1er 2 Why Do Cities Exist? 25

    Under what circumstances will a household buy factory shirts instead of pro-ducing them at home? The net price of a factory shirt is the price paid to the firm (0.25 loaf) plus the consumer's opportunity cost of the time spent traveling to and from che factory. The opportunity cost is the loss of bread production resulting from traveling instead of producing bread. A household can produce one loaf pcr hour, so it will be sensible to buy a factory shirt if the trip takes less than 0.75 hour. For example, if the trip takes only 0.20 hour, the net price of a factory shirt is 0.45 loaf = 0.25 loaf paid to the factory plus 0.20 loaf sacrificed in travel time. The household will be indifferent if travel time is 0.75 hour; in this case, the net price is 1 loaf = 0.25 loaf paid to the factory +O. 75 loaf for travel.

    Figure 2-2 shows the market area of the shirt factory. The market area is defined as the area over which the factory underprices home production. The vertical axis

    FIGURE 2-2 Market Arca of Shirt Factory Cost of fac1ory shirt Cost of factory >hin

    1.00 t----_.....,,..----------------,f---- Cost of ,, 1 homemadc >hirt o 1

    0.75 : 1

    ...... 1 o 1 B 050 1 V 1 ;:; 1 z 0.25 ______ .._

    1

    Travcl cost

    1 Factory COSI L._ _ _._ _ _.1 _ _,___._ _ __. __ _._ _ _.. __ _._ _ __.. _ _ _,__ __ MiJc,

    4 3 2 O 2 3 4 from factory

    Market area of shirt factory

    The market area of the shirt factory is the area over which the nct cost of a factory shirt (production time plus travel time) is lcss than the production time of a homcmadc shirt ( 1 hour).

  • 26 Part 1 Market Forces in the Development of Cities

    measures the net price of shirts, the sum of the factory price (0.25 loaf) and travel time to the factory. The horizontal axis measures the distance to the factory in miles. If walking time is eight miles per hour (four round-trip miles per hour), the factory will underprice homemade shirts for residents within three miles of the factory (within 0.75 hour walking time). Therefore, the factory's market area is a circle with a radius of three miles.

    A Factory City A small urban area will develop around the shirt factory. The shirt workers will live near the factory to economize on commuting costs, and will bid up the price of land near the factory. As the price of land increases, workers will economize on land by occupying smaller lots. In other words, the popuiation density around the shirt factory will be higher than the population density in the rest of the region. A city is defined as a place with a relatively high population density, so the factory causes the development of a small factory city.

    The factory city develops because two conditions are satisfied. First, agricultural productivity is high enough that workers outside the city can generate enough food to feed themselves and have enough left over to feed the shirt workers in the city. Second, scaie economies are large relative to travel costs, so the shirt factory can underprice homemade shirts, at least for people living near the factory.

    Limits to City Size: Freight Cost and the Railroad The popuiation of the city is determined by the number of factory workers, which in turn depends on the total output of the factory. For a given level of economies of scale, the size of the city is limited by the cost of moving output from the factory to consumers in the region. In our model, the consumer incurs these freight costs by traveling between the home and the factory, but the same logic would be applicable if the firm were responsible for freight costs. The cost of transporting goods limits the ability of the factory to exploit economies of scale in production.

    To illustrate the notion that freight cost is a limit on city size, consider the effect of increasing the speed of travel within the region. Suppose the travel speed doubles to 16 miles per hour (eight round trip miles per hour). Recall that the factory can underprice home production if the travel time is less than 0.75 hour. Therefore, with a travel speed of 16 miles per hour, the factory can underprice home production over a six-mile radius. In other words, a doubling of travel speed would double the radius of the factory's market area. A doubling of the radius will increase the output of the factory, increasing the factory's workforce and the population of the factory city. In general, a decrease in freight cost allows the factory to more fully exploit economies of scale, increasing city size.

    During the industrial revolution, innovations in intercity transportation con-tributed to specialization, trade, and urbanization. The railroad decreased the cost of moving goods between regions, decreasing the delivered price of both agricultural and factory goods. Before the railroad linked eastern cities with the western parts

  • Chapter 2 Why Do Cities Exist? 27

    of the United States, a large fraction of the food consumed in New England was produced by the region's farmers . Similarly, a large fraction of the goods consumed in the West (e.g., shoes) was produced by local craftsmen. The railroad cut freight costs, so eastern factories could underprice western craftsmen and western farmers could underprice eastern farmers. As a result, both regions specialized to a greater extent and trade increased. The increase in the output of factories in New England increased the size of its factory cities.

    Limits to City Size: Scale Economies and the Sewing Machine The other limit to the size of the factory city is the extent of scale economies in production. As economies of scale become more powerful, the cost of factory pro-duction decreases relative to the cost of home production, and the market area of the factory increases, increasing the size of factory cities.

    The sewing machine, which was developed in the middle of the nineteenth century, increased scale economies in the making of clothing and contributed to the development of cities. Around the beginning of the nineteenth century, about four-fifths of the clothing worn in the United States was hand-sewn in the home for members of the household. The other fifth was hand-sewn by tailors. The sewing machine allowed factory producers to underprice home producers, and by 1890 nine-tenths of U.S. clothing was being made in factories. As clothing factories sprang up in the United States, new cities developed around the factories.

    The sewing machine also contributed to the development of U.S. cities around shoe factories . Before 1700, most shoes were produced in the home or the local village. The cost of transportation was so high that local production was efficient. Over time, transportation costs decreased, allowing the exploitation of compara-tive advantage in shoe production. The putting-out system was implemented in the l 700s: Shoe producers distributed raw materials to cottage workers, collected their output, and finished the shoes in a central shop. As new shoemaking machines were developed, the number of operations performed in the central shops increased. The McKay sewing machine mechanized the process of sewing the soles to the uppers, increasing scale economies in shoe production to the point that the central shops became genuine factories. Cities developed around the new shoe factories .

    LIMITS TO CITY SIZE: COMMUTING COSTS

    Up to this poi nt, we have implicitly assumed that the wage paid to factory workers is independent of city size. Each worker is paid one Ioaf of bread per hour of factory work, regardless of the size of the city. In fact, the wage paid to factory workers will increase as the city grows because bigger cities have longer commuting times. The factory must compensate workers for longer commutes, so the wage will increase as the city grows. As the wage increases, so does the cost of factory shirts relative to the cost of homemade shirts.

  • 28 Part 1 Markcl Forces in che Developmem ofCicics

    TABLE 2-3 Commuting Time, Wages, and Prices Number of Workers Commute Time Work Time

    100 20,000

    O hours 4 hours

    Wages Increase with City Size

    8 hours 4 hours

    Hourly Wage 1 loaf per hour 2 loaves per hour

    To illustrate the effects of commuting costs on wages and the price of factory shirts, considera factory city where each worker has eght hours per day to divide between commuting and factory work. Each hour spent commuting decreases work time by one hour. To be indifferent between producing bread at home and being employed in the factory (involving both commute and work times), the worker must be paid eight loaves of bread for each day of work and commuting.

    We can use the simple example shown in Table 2- 3 to show why wages increase with city size. Suppose that in a small city of 100 workers, commuting time is zero: every worker lives within a short walk ofthe shirt factory. Each worker spends eight hours in the factory and earns eight loaves per day, which translates into one loaf per hour of factory work. At the other extreme, suppose that in a city with 20,000 workers, cornmute time is four hours per day, leaving only four hours for factory work. To keep the worker indifferent between factory work and home production of bread, the firm must still pay the worker eight loaves for a day of working and commuting. On an hourly basis, the wage is now two loaves of bread per hour of factory work (eight loavcs divided by four hours). In other words, because the larger city has commuting cost, it has a higher hourly wage.

    Figure 2-3 shows the rclationship between city size and wages, using the two extremes shown in Table 2-3. The hourly wage rises from one loaf per hour in the small city to two loaves per hour in the city with 20,000 workers.

    What are the implications of higher wages for the shirt producer and the factory city? The higher the wage, the higher the production cost for factory shirts and thc higher the price of factory shirts. Recall that the market area ofthe factory is defined as the area over which the net price of factory shirts (the factory price plus travel costs incurred by the shirt buyer) is less than the cost of homemade shirts. As a city grows, rising wages will raise the factory price of shirts relative to the cost of homemade shirts. In other words, higher commuting costs will limit the market area of the factory and the s ize of the city.

    Decrease in Commuting Cost and the Boston Experience Because commuting costs limit city size, a decrease in the unit cost of commuting will cause a city to grow. Suppose the city's commuting speed were to double. In Table 2-3, the commute time associated wth a city of20,000 workers would be cut in half, reducing workers' commuting time, wages, the cost per shirt, and the price of factory shirts. As the factory price decreases relative to the cost of homemade shirts, the market area of the factory will increase, increasing the number of factory workers and the size of the city.

  • Chapter 2 Why Do Cities Exist? 29

    FIGURE 2-3 The Wage lncrcases with City Size

    Wage (loa ves per hour)

    2 'O fil .D ._ o

  • 30 Part 1 Market Forces in the Development of Cities

    The First Cities The first cities developed in the fertile river valleys in the Near East around 3000 B.C. The city-states that developed in the Mesopotamia Valley included Eiridu, Ur, Lagash, and Kish. Ur was the largest of these cities, with a land area of about 150 acres and a population of about 25,000. In 2000 B.C., the city of Babylon had a population of about 50,000. These cities developed shortly after a number of agri-cultura! breakthroughs generated a surplus of food, allowing sorne people to pursue nonagricultural activities in cities. Among the innovations were the domestication of grain, the development of irrigation systems, and the plow (replacing the hoe). According to Davis ( 1976), between 50 and 150 farmers were required to support a single city inhabitant.

    Why did the first cities develop? There is sorne uncertainty about the social and economic features of early societies, so historians can only speculate about the origins of cities. Most agree that the first cities served both religious and defensive purposes. Can the development of defensive and religious cities be explained by the same factors that explain the development of market-based cities?

    Consider first the defensive city. A farmer who generates an agricultura! surplus will eventually use the surplus, either consuming it himself or trading it for other goods. In either case, he must store the surplus food for sorne period of time. The stored food provides a lucrative target for thieves. If there are scale economies in food storage and protection, farmers may be better off storing their surpluses in a central storage facility rather than a set of facilities, one for each farmer. The people working in the fortified storage facility (managers and guards) will Iive near the facil-ity, generating a place with a relatively high population density, a small city. This is the theory of the defensive city: The first cities developed because of scale economies in the storage of the agricultura! surplus. Support for the theory comes from archae-ologists who uncovered the remains of fortified storage facilities in the first cities.

    Consider next the religious city. According to Mumford ( 1961), the development of the first cities coincided with the development of large-scale religion. Before the development of cities, most people worshipped in small groups, either in the home or in the local village. Around the time that the first cities developed, the local earth gods were replaced by celestial gods, who may have demanded worship on a grander scale. If adoration and supplication were considered more effective on a large scale, a doubling of the size of the shrine would more than double the religious output. The small shrines in homes and villages were replaced by large temples at central locations, which employed chieftains, priests, and religious workers, and caused the development of a place with relatively high population density, a city. This is the theory of the religious city: The earliest cities developed because of scale economies in the provision of religion. Support for the theory comes from archaeologists who uncovered the remains of large temples in the first cities.

    The most prominent feature of the early city was a large temple at the city center, a site for worship and the storage of the agricultura! surplus. Which carne first, the central storage faci li ty or centralized religion? Perhaps the central storage facility made worship in the central temple more convenient, causing the switch to

  • Chapter 2 Why Do Cities Exist? 31

    centralized re ligion. Alternatively, the development of a large temple could have provided a convenient and defensible storage facility for the agricultura! surplus. In other words, there were economies of scope in the provision of religion and defense: the t-wo services were provided more efficiently if they were provided together. A third possibility is that the local chieftains used centralized religion as a subterfuge to extract the agricultura! surplus from local farmers.

    The military played a major role in the early cities. The developmcnt of cities in-creased the frequency and severity ofhuman conftict for two reasons. First, the cities worshipped different gods and fought wars to settle religious disputes. Second. the urban societies accumulated wealth, providing lucrative targets that encouraged ma-terialistic wars. Although cities encouraged aggressive behavior, they also provided the most effective defense against aggression. Until the dcvelopment of gunpowder in the fourteenth century, the most effective defensive maneuver was a large but sim-ple wall. In addition, a city contained enough people to defend itself against attack from large forces. Once the simple wall was built, there was safety in numbers.

    Greek and Roman Cities The next stage of western urbanization occurred in Greece. In 500 B.C. there were hundreds of independent city-states, ranging in population from a few hundred to tens of thousands. Athens was the largest, with a population of about 150,000, and Sparta hada population of about 40,000. In contrast with earlier cities, which were controlled by chieftain-priests, most Greek cities were run by their citizens, using public assemblies to make policy.

    Athens was a market city, with trading activity centered in the Agora. Early in its history, the city established independent colonies and traded its household crafts and olive products for food and raw materials from the colonies. Trade was facilitated by the stamping of gold and si l ver coi ns in the seventh century B.C. In this early period, Athens fed itself through voluntary trade with other areas.

    The Athenian empire developed in the aftermath of the successful war against Persia in the fifth century B.C. After the Greek city-states repelled thc Pcrsian inva-sion, they formcd the Delian League to carry the war into Asia Minor. By the end of the successful campaign, Athens had assumed complete control ofthe league, dictat-ing policy to the other c ity-states. Athens took control of the treasury, transforming the voluntary contributions of member city-states into payments of tribute to Athens. The system of homage and crbute led ro the Peloponnesian War becween the Athenian Empire and Sparta (431 to 404 B.C.) . The war ended in 404 when Athens renounced control over its empire and demolished its defens ive walls. Athens ncvcr regained its former power. Evenrually, Philip of Macedonia was a ble to take advantage of the weakened city-states and expanded his kingdom to include most of Greece.

    The next stage of western urban development occurred under the Roman Empire. By the third century A.O., Ro me hada population exceeding one mili ion. The Romans set up colonies to the north and west, establishing colonial cities throughout Europe. Rome fed its large population with a combination of trade and tribute, with tribute playing a relatively large role.

  • 32 Part 1 Market Forces in the Development of Cities

    The Roman cities were eventually overrun by marauders from rural areas. Ac-cording to Hohenberg and Lees (1985), the Roman economy emphasized the col-lection of the agricultura! surplus and neglected production activity. lnstead of ex-changing urban goods for agricultura! products, Rome used conquest and tribute to feed its population. In the fourth and fifth centuries, German tribes invaded from the north, disrupting the Roman collection system. It appears that there was little interest outside of Rome in restoring the "trade" routes, so the losses from succes-sive invasions were cumulative. lf Rome had relied to a greater extent on voluntary exchange, the colonies might have been more interested in maintaining the ex-change network, and the Western empire might have recovered from the Germanic raid s.

    What are the lessons from the rise and fall of Athens and Rome? Early in its history, Athens engaged in voluntary trade with other areas, exchanging urban goods for food from the countryside. The city thrived under this system of voluntary exchange. The Athenians eventually switched to a system of conquest and tribute, resulting in war and the decline of the city. Mumford (1961) suggests that the city of Rome should have been called "Parasitopolis" to indicate the extent to which its population lived off the labors of outsiders. The decline of Rome was caused in part by the disruption of its collection system by the Germanic raids. Perhaps the lesson is that cities based on voluntary exchange are viable, but cities based on coercive transfer payments are not.

    Feudal Cities In the first few centuries following the fall of the Roman Empire, cities in the West declined. The Islamic conquest disrupted trading on the Mediterranean, causing the decline of many port cities. Waves of marauding barbarians continued to sweep across Europe, making travel and trade dangerous. People sought safety inside city walls, where, once again there was safety in numbers.

    The feudal economy of the eleventh through the fourteenth centuries was based on manorial estates and small walled cities. On the manor, the lord inherited his serfs, who worked the lord's land and served in the military in exchange for the use of a small plot of land. In the small towns, workers produced handicrafts (cloth, leather goods, metal goods), which they exchanged for the agricultura! surplus of the manor. Cities in the feudal era were small and numerous. In the eleventh century, London was the largest city in England, with a population of only 16,000. There were severa! other English cities with populations of around 5,000. The largest of the many German cities had a population of no more than 40,000.

    The largest cities served the Byzantine Empire and the Muslim areas of Spain. Venice was one of the few large cities beyond the Byzantine and Muslim areas, but it depended heavily on trade with the Eastern empire. During the eleventh and twelfth centuries, the Ttalian city-states forged agreements with the Byzantine and Islamic rulers for trade with North Africa and the East. The Europeans traded wood, iron, grain, wine, and wool cloth for medicines, dyes, linen, cotton, leather, and precious metals. The increased trade contributed to the growth of Ven ice, Genoa, and Pisa.

  • Chaptcr 2 Why Do Cities Exist? 33

    Between the eleventh and fourteenth centuries, the frequency of barbarian inva-sions decreased, and the small defensive cities gradually became market cities. The medieval cities specialized in commerce and handicrafts, and thus earned-rather than robbed- the agricultura! surplus of their hinterlands. A small merchant class developed, and marketplaces were established just outside the city walls. The mer-chants were protected from plunder by the establishment of weekly market days: Once a week, theft was outlawed in places marked by the market cross. The market peace was enforced by local chieftains, special courts with jurisdiction over traders, and thc church. The markets ftourished, and the cty walls were extended to include the marketplaces. The urban market was primarily a place for the exchange of local agriculture and handicrafts. The producers of handicrafts made up a large fraction of the city 's workforce.

    Hohenberg and Lees ( 1985) use Leicester, in the East Midlands of England, as an example of a medieval city in the fourteenth century. The city was surrounded by walls on three sides and a river on the fourth. The town ditch was just outside the wall. The city was a regional marketplace, serving as a commercial center for the surrounding county. The city produced staples such as beer and bread for lo-cal consumption and produced woolen cloth for export. Occupations in the city included butchers, shoemakers, tailors, mercers, weavers, and bakers. Over half of the city's workers were employed in manufacturing, with the other half employed as food makers (25 percent), traders and merchants ( 1 O percent), bui lders (5 percent), and other occupations. The merchant guild controlled most economic activity in the city.

    According to Davis ( 1976), the first market-based cities developed for two rea-sons. First, power in the feudal system was decentralized. Unlike the Greek and Roman cities, medieval cities could not simply domnate their hinterlands and de-mand tribute, but had to produce something in exchange for agricultura! goods. Second, agricultura! productivity was relatively low, so a city could not survive on the output of its immediate hinterland, but had to trade with a relatively large area. As a result, the city had to develop products that could compete with homemade products in its hinterland and products produced in other cities.

    Competition among the medieval cities caused innovations in production and commerce. Urban producers developed new production techniques, allowing them to underprice their competitors. Cities invested in secular education as a means of promoting literacy and developing commercial ski lis. These earl y efforts to improve the techniques of production and commerce set the stage for the industrial revolution of the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries.

    Mercantile Cities Starting in the fifteenth century, large mercantile cities developed in Europe. One factor in this development was the transfer of power from a large number of feudal lords to a relatively small number of princes, queens, and kings. The shift in power was caused in large part by military advances that rendered the traditional feudal defense maneuvers obsolete.

  • 34 Part 1 Market Forces in the Development of Cities

    Innovations in warmaking increased the seriousness and scale of conflict. The feudal lord used his serfs as part-time warriors. If these warriors could not defeat the attackers in the field, the feudal lord could always hunkerdown behind his castle walls to wait out a siege. The professional army of the fifteenth century combined infantry (armed with pikes, crossbows, and muskets) with siege cannons and cavalry. The professional soldiers, with their sophisticated weapons, usually defeated the feudal lord's part-timers in the field. When the lord retreated to his castle, the siege cannons blew holes in the castle walls. The professional armies defeated the feudal lords, centralizing power in the hands of princes, queens, and kings. In response, mercantile cities built intricate fortifications and also hired professional soldiers. The larger cities were able to exploit the increased scale economies in defense.

    The centralization of power caused the centralization of administrative and mil-itary functions in royal cities. After the sixteenth century, the most rapidly growing cities were the ones that harbored a royal court. In a short period of time, more than a dozen cities grew to a size attained by only a few medieval cities: London had 250,000 people, Naples 240,000, Milan 200,000, and Paris 180,000; cities with around 100,000 inhabitants included Rome, Lis bon, Palenno, Seville, Antwerp, and Amsterdam.

    A second factor in the growth of mercantile cities was long-distance trade. The consolidation of power eliminated local tariffs imposed by feudal lords and trade increased. The development of ocean travel led to exploration and the discovery of new markets. Cities developed along trade routes and at transshipment points. While cities with river and seaports ftourished (Naples, Palermo, Lisbon, and Liverpool), inland cities like Florence declined.

    Urbanization during the Industrial Revolution Despite the rapid spread of cities between 3000 B.C. and 1800 A.O., the world con-tinued to be predominantly rural. Urbanization was limited by the relatively low productivity of agriculture, the high costs of transporting goods (which limited the volume of trade), and the relatively small advantages of centralized production. Un-til the early part of the nineteenth century, the fraction of the world's population living in cities was only about 3 percent. Between 1800 and 1970, the percentage of the population in urban areas increased to 39 percent. In the United States, the percentage ofthe population in urban areas increased from 6 percent in 1800 to over 75 percent in 1990.

    The rapid urbanization of the last two centuries was caused by the industrial revolution, which started in the nineteenth century. The industrial revolution pro-duced innovations in manufacturing and transportation that shifted production from the home and the small shop to large factories in industrial cities. Between 1700 and 1900, .\1anchester, Birmingham, Glasgow, and Liverpool grew from tiny towns into giant industrial cities. The innovations of the industrial revolution can be divided into four areas: agriculture, manufacturing, transportation, and construction.

    The rapid urbanization of the industrial revolution was made possible by inno-vations that increased agricultura! productivity. Farmers substituted machinery for

  • Chap1er 2 Why Do Cities Exis1? 35

    muscle power and simple tools, increasing the output per farmer. For example, using a hor e-drawn reaper, two people could harvest the same amount of grain as eight people using tradtonal harvesting methods. In addition, the development of agri-cultura! science led to innovations in plantng, growing, harvestng, and processing. As produclivity increased, laborers were freed from food-raising responsibilties, al-lowing them to pursue other activities. In the United States, the share of employment in agriculture decreased from 69 percent in 1840 to 2.8 percent in 1988.

    Perhaps the most visible part of the industrial revolution involved innovations in manufacturing. Ncw machines, made of iron instead of wood; were developed for the production of most goods. Manual production by skilled artisans was replaced by mechanized production using interchangeable parts, specialized labor, and steam-powered machines. Output per worker rose, and scale economies in production increased. Mass production decreased the relative cost of factory goods, causing the centralization of production and employment in large industrial cities.

    Innovations in intercity transportation contributed to industrialization and urban-ization. The steamship and the railroad decreased the costs of moving goods between cities, decreasing the delivered price of factory goods. Production became more cen-tralized, and factory cities grew. The new transportation modes also decreased the costs of moving agricultura! goods, allowing greater regional specialization in agri-culture. Agricultura! regions were better able to exploit their comparative advantages, so agricultura! productivity increased. Trade increased because the railroad allowed both regions to exploit their comparative advantages.

    Innovations in construction methods also increased city sizes. The first sky-scraper, a 10-story building that housed the Home lnsurance Company, appeared in 1885 in Chicago. T he building was revolutionary because its frame was made of steel instead of bricks. Because the steel frame was relatively light, the building could be taller than the traditional brick building. The development of the elevator decreased intrabuilding travel costs in tall buildings, increasing the feasibility ofthe skyscraper. The skyscraper increased the intensity of land use, increasing the city's productive capacity and its feasible population.

    Urbanization in the United States Figure 2-4 shows the trend in U.S. urbanization from 1800 to 1990. In 1800, only about 6 percent of the population lived in cities. The share of population in cities increased to 15 percent by 1850, 40 percent by 1900, 64 percent by 1950, and 75 percent by 1990.

    The industrial revolution caused dramatic growth in U.S. cities. Between 1850 and 1890, the populations of New York and Boston more than tripled; the popula-tion of Baltimore more than doubled; and the population of Philadelphia increased more than eightfold. Further west, on average, the populations of Chicago, Detroit, Cleveland, Pittsburgh, and Los Angeles increased J 8-fold between 1850 and 1890. Lurking behind these changes were large increases in urban manufacturing activity. The share of employment in manufacruring more than doubled in most of these cities, from about 1 O percent of total employment to about 20 percent.

  • 36 Part 1 Market Forces in the Developrnent of Ci tes

    FIGURE 2-4 Percent of U.S. Population Living in Urban Areas, 1800-1990

    "' "' "' e "' -e ::> e

    80 75 70 65

    60 55

    50 45 40

    e

    ;: O)

    35 30 25 20 15 10 5

    1800 1820 1840 1860 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000 Y car

    SUMMARY

    l. Employment opportunities are concentrated in cities because sorne activities are subject to economies of scale.

    2. A trading city will develop if [a] the differences in productivity underlying comparative advantage are large relative to transportation costs and [b] there are scale economies in transportation.

    3. A factory city will develop if scale economies in production are Jarge relative to transportation costs.

    4. City size is limited by the cost of transporting goods (freight cost) and the cost of transporting workers within the city (commuting cost).

    S. The first cities developed for defensive and religious reasons. 6. T he centraJization of powerduring the mercantile period caused the development

    of administrative cities and reduced trade barriers. Combined with effi cient ocean traveJ, this resulted in the development of trading cities.

    7. The rapid urbanization in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries was caused by the industrial revolution and the associated innovations in agriculture, trans-portation, and manufacturing.

  • Chapter 2 Why Do Exist? 37

    EXERCISES ANO DISCUSSION QUESTIONS 1. The table below summarizes the productivity of workers in bread and shirt pro-

    duction in two parts of a region.

    Bread Shirts

    Output per Hour East Wesl

    1 3

    5 6

    Opportunity Cost East West

    a. Complete the table by providing the opportunity costs of producing bread and shirts in the East and the West. For which good does the East have a comparative advantage? What about the West?

    b. Assume that transport costs are zero and that the exchange rate is two shirts for one loaf. If a western household switches one hour from shirt production to bread production and exchanges all thc additional bread for shirts, will the household be better off'?

    c. Suppose that the time required to execute the trade in (b) is one hour. Is trade still beneficia!? At what transaction cost (time per trade) would the net gain from trade be zero?

    d. Under what cond itions will the differences in labor productivity cause the development of cities?

    2. Considera region that has a single trading city, a city that developed as a result of comparative advantage in the production of a homogeneous good (shirts) and scale economies in transportation. The shirts produced by different households are perfect substitutes, and communication between households is costless. Sup-pose that a matter transmitter is introduced into the region. The transmitter at no cost transpo1ts goods, but cannot be used to transport people. The transmitter is cbeap enough that every household can purchase one ata relatively low cost. a. Will the matter transmi11crcause the trading city to grow, shrink, ordisappear? b. How would your answcr to (a) changc if shirts are not homogcneous (i.e.,

    shirts from different households are not perfect substitutes)? 3. Consider a country with two regions that are separated by a mountain range.

    Initially, there are no cities in the country. Suppose that a tunnel is bored through the mountain, decreasing travel costs between the two regions. Under what conditions will the tunnel cause the development of trading cities?

    4. Considera region that has a single factory city, a city thatdeveloped as a rcsult of scale economies in production. lt is a walking region: People walk to work and to purchase consumer goods. Suppose pump sneakers are introduced (selling at the same price as traditional shoes), doubling walking speeds. Will pump sneakers cause the factory city to grow, shrink, or disappear?

    S. Region F has a single factory city (a city that devcloped as a rcsult of scale economies in production). Suppose that a matter transmitter is introduced into the region. The transmitter can costlessly transport goods, but cannot be used

  • 38 Part 1 Market Forces in the Development of Cities

    to transport people. The transmitter is cheap enough that every household can purchase one ata relatively low cost. Will the matter transmitter cause the factory city to grow, shrink, or disappear?

    6. Considera region that produces lemons and ice and consumes lemonade (lemons and ice together). Ali resources are distributed uniformly throughout the region, and ali people are equally productive in producing lemons and ice. There are scale economies in the production of ice, causing the development of an ice factory and a factory city. Suppose that a small refrigerator is introduced and imported into the region, providing an alternative to the ice purchased from ice factories. Explain the effects of the refrigerator on (a) the market area of the ice factory and (b) the size of the city surrounding the ice factory.

    7. Consider Retireland, a region where most residents are retired. Residents of the region consume a single good (food), which is imported from another region and sold in vending machines. Wi ll there be any cities in Retireland? If so, how will they differ from cities in regions where most people work?

    8. Using the example in Table 2-3 as a starting point, for each of the following events, depict graphically the effect of each event on the relationship between wages and city size (shown in Figure 2- 3). Then discuss the implications of the event for the size of the factory city. (a) The work


Recommended