+ All Categories
Home > Documents > ON THE RAND: DETERMINANTS OF THE SOUTH ... THE RAND: DETERMINANTS OF THE SOUTH AFRICAN EXCHANGE RATE...

ON THE RAND: DETERMINANTS OF THE SOUTH ... THE RAND: DETERMINANTS OF THE SOUTH AFRICAN EXCHANGE RATE...

Date post: 18-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: vanbao
View: 218 times
Download: 1 times
Share this document with a friend
19
JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 1 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007 /v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130 ON THE RAND: DETERMINANTS OF THE SOUTH AFRICAN EXCHANGE RATE jeffrey frankel* Abstract This paper is an econometric investigation of the determinants of the real value of the South African rand over the period 1984-2007. The results show a relatively good fit. As always with exchange rate equations, there is substantial weight on the lagged exchange rate, which can be attributed to a momentum component. Nevertheless, economic fundamentals are significant and important. This is especially true of an index of the real prices of South African mineral commodities, which even drives out real income as a significant determinant. An implication is that the 2003-2006 real appreciation of the rand can be attributed to the Dutch Disease. In other respects, the rand behaves like currencies of industrialized countries with well-developed financial markets. In particular, high South African interest rates raise international demand for the rand and lead to real appreciation, controlling also for a forward-looking measure of expected inflation and a measure of default risk or country risk. JEL Classification: F31 Keywords: South Africa, rand, commodity currency, Dutch Disease, mineral prices, country risk The rand has undergone large movements in recent years. What explains these swings? Important questions include: • Is the rand a commodity currency, like the Australian and Canadian dollar are said to be (to pick two floaters)? That is, is it a currency that appreciates when prices of the mineral products that it produces are strong on world markets and depreciates when they are weak? • In other respects, does the rand behave like currencies of industrialized countries, in light of its developed financial markets? (South Africa borrows in rand, for example, unlike most developing countries.) This does not necessarily require that the exchange rate fit standard theories closely, as those theories don’t work well in practice for major industrialized currencies either. But such variables as GDP and rates of return should have an effect. * John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University. This work was done with the able research assistance of Melesse Tashu. It is a contribution within the Macroeconomics Group of the Harvard University Center for International Development’s Project on South Africa: Performance and Prospects. Relative to an earlier draft in mid-2006, the major innovations in this paper include: the addition of an absent theoretical model, the use of sovereign spread data to measure the risk premium and forward-looking inflation forecasts to measure real interest rates, allowing a break in 1995 for the end of apartheid and capital controls, and a dynamic simulation of the real value of the rand over 2003-2006. Thanks to Lesetja Kganyago, Ben Smit and other participants in the July 2006 meetings in Pretoria and to Brian Kahn, Stan du Plessis and other participants in the January 2007 meetings in Pretoria and Stellenbosch. None are implicated in the conclusions. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 2007 © 2007 The Author. Journal compilation © 2007 Economic Society of South Africa. Published by Blackwell Publishing, 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA. 1
Transcript

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 1 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

ON THE RAND: DETERMINANTS OF THE SOUTH AFRICAN

EXCHANGE RATE

jeffrey frankel*

AbstractThis paper is an econometric investigation of the determinants of the real value of the SouthAfrican rand over the period 1984-2007. The results show a relatively good fit. As always withexchange rate equations, there is substantial weight on the lagged exchange rate, which can beattributed to a momentum component. Nevertheless, economic fundamentals are significantand important. This is especially true of an index of the real prices of South African mineralcommodities, which even drives out real income as a significant determinant. An implication isthat the 2003-2006 real appreciation of the rand can be attributed to the Dutch Disease. In otherrespects, the rand behaves like currencies of industrialized countries with well-developed financialmarkets. In particular, high South African interest rates raise international demand for the randand lead to real appreciation, controlling also for a forward-looking measure of expected inflationand a measure of default risk or country risk.JEL Classification: F31Keywords: South Africa, rand, commodity currency, Dutch Disease, mineral prices, country risk

The rand has undergone large movements in recent years. What explains these swings?Important questions include:

• Is the rand a commodity currency, like the Australian and Canadian dollar are said tobe (to pick two floaters)? That is, is it a currency that appreciates when prices of themineral products that it produces are strong on world markets and depreciates when theyare weak?• In other respects, does the rand behave like currencies of industrialized countries, inlight of its developed financial markets? (South Africa borrows in rand, for example,unlike most developing countries.) This does not necessarily require that the exchangerate fit standard theories closely, as those theories don’t work well in practice for majorindustrialized currencies either. But such variables as GDP and rates of return should havean effect.

* John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University.This work was done with the able research assistance of Melesse Tashu. It is a contribution withinthe Macroeconomics Group of the Harvard University Center for International Development’sProject on South Africa: Performance and Prospects.Relative to an earlier draft in mid-2006, the major innovations in this paper include: the additionof an absent theoretical model, the use of sovereign spread data to measure the risk premium andforward-looking inflation forecasts to measure real interest rates, allowing a break in 1995 for theend of apartheid and capital controls, and a dynamic simulation of the real value of the rand over2003-2006. Thanks to Lesetja Kganyago, Ben Smit and other participants in the July 2006meetings in Pretoria and to Brian Kahn, Stan du Plessis and other participants in the January 2007meetings in Pretoria and Stellenbosch. None are implicated in the conclusions.

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

18

19

20

21

22

23

24

25

26

27

28

29

30

31

3233

34

35

36

37

38

39

40

41

42

43

South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 2007

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © 2007 Economic Society of South Africa. Published by Blackwell Publishing, 9600 GarsingtonRoad, Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden, MA 02148, USA.

1

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 2 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

• Did the removal of capital controls in 1995, or other elements of the transition todemocracy, cause a structural break in the determinants of the real exchange rate?• Has there been an element of momentum to some recent movements, or can they beexplained by fundamentals?

Fig. 1 suggests that there has been a relationship between the real mineral price and realexchange rate: the currency slumps when mineral exports are declining, as in the late1990s, but appreciates in natural resource booms as in 2002-2006 – the classic DutchDisease. But Fig. 2 shows that the real exchange rate has the same correlation with relativereal output, which could be explained either as a reflection of the Balassa-Samuelson effect(wherein productivity growth increases the price of nontraded goods relative to tradedgoods) or as a reflection of monetary theories of the nominal exchange rate (wherein

50.000

60.000

70.000

80.000

90.000

100.000

110.000

120.000

130.000

140.000

150.000

1996

Q4

1997

Q1

1997

Q2

1997

Q3

1997

Q4

1998

Q1

1998

Q2

1998

Q3

1998

Q4

1999

Q1

1999

Q2

1999

Q3

1999

Q4

2000

Q1

2000

Q2

2000

Q3

2000

Q4

2001

Q1

2001

Q2

2001

Q3

2001

Q4

2002

Q1

2002

Q2

2002

Q3

2002

Q4

2003

Q1

2003

Q2

2003

Q3

2003

Q4

2004

Q1

2004

Q2

2004

Q3

2004

Q4

2005

Q1

2005

Q2

2005

Q3

2005

Q4

2006

Q1

2006

Q2

Rea

l exc

hn

age

rate

ind

ex

0.600

0.800

1.000

1.200

1.400

1.600

1.800

2.000

Rea

l min

eral

ind

ex

RERIRWMPI

Figure 1. Real Exchange rate index(value of rand) and real mineral price index

50.000

60.000

70.000

80.000

90.000

100.000

110.000

120.000

130.000

140.000

150.000

Rea

l exc

han

ge

rate

ind

ex

9.10

9.30

9.50

9.70

9.90

10.10

10.30

rela

tive

rea

l GD

P o

f S

A t

o U

S (

%)

RERIRGDPRAT

1996

Q4

1997

Q1

1997

Q2

1997

Q3

1997

Q4

1998

Q1

1998

Q2

1998

Q3

1998

Q4

1999

Q1

1999

Q2

1999

Q3

1999

Q4

2000

Q1

2000

Q2

2000

Q3

2000

Q4

2001

Q1

2001

Q2

2001

Q3

2001

Q4

2002

Q1

2002

Q2

2002

Q3

2002

Q4

2003

Q1

2003

Q2

2003

Q3

2003

Q4

2004

Q1

2004

Q2

2004

Q3

2004

Q4

2005

Q1

2005

Q2

2005

Q3

2005

Q4

2006

Q1

2006

Q2

Figure 2. Real exchange rate (value of rand) and relative real GDP of SA to USA

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 20072

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 3 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

growth in real income raises the demand for money and appreciates the currencynominally). We may have some trouble distinguishing the effect of mineral prices fromthe effect of real output, because the two are themselves highly correlated, as Fig. 3 shows.

1. THEORETICAL BASIS OF MODEL

Here we focus on the determination of the real exchange rate, while recognizing thatmonetary factors are important.1 Our model of the real exchange rate divides itsdeterminants into two categories, determinants of the long-run equilibrium exchangerate, and deviations of the current real exchange rate from its long-run equilibrium.

The long run equilibrium real exchange rate is given by a version of PPP:

QSPP

q s p p≡ = + −*, * .or in log form: (1)

where s ≡ log of the nominal spot exchange rate, in rand per dollars.p ≡ log of the South African price level (probably a PPI or the GDP deflator)p* ≡ log of the foreign (here US) price level.

But we define the price indices at home and abroad as Cobb Douglas functions oftraded goods TG and non-traded goods NTG:

p p pNTGSA TGSA= + −( )α α1 , (2)

1 As Aron, Elbadawi and Kahn (2000). Chinn (1999) estimated a monetary model of the nominalrand exchange rate. Results for both the nominal and real rates were reported in Frankel (2006),an earlier version of the present paper.

0.800

1.000

1.200

1.400

1.600

1.800

2.000

Rea

l min

eral

pri

ce in

dex

9.20

9.30

9.40

9.50

9.60

9.70

9.80

9.90

10.00

10.10

10.20

Relative real GDP of SA to US (%)

RWMPI

RGDPRAT

1996

Q4

1997

Q1

1997

Q2

1997

Q3

1997

Q4

1998

Q1

1998

Q2

1998

Q3

1998

Q4

1999

Q1

1999

Q2

1999

Q3

1999

Q4

2000

Q1

2000

Q2

2000

Q3

2000

Q4

2001

Q1

2001

Q2

2001

Q3

2001

Q4

2002

Q1

2002

Q2

2002

Q3

2002

Q4

2003

Q1

2003

Q2

2003

Q3

2003

Q4

2004

Q1

2004

Q2

2004

Q3

2004

Q4

2005

Q1

2005

Q2

2005

Q3

2005

Q4

2006

Q1

2006

Q2

Figure 3. Real mineral price index (value of rand) and relative GDP1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

18

19

20

21

22

2324

25

26

3South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 2007

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 4 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

where a is the weight placed on NonTraded Goods in the basket.For simplicity we assume the same weights in the foreign country.

p* p pNTGSA TGSA= + −( )α α1 (3)

Combining (1), (2) and (3),

q s p p s a p a p a p a pNTGUS TGUS NTGSA TGSA= + − + + −( )[ ] − + −( )[ ]=

* = . 1 1

ss p p a p p p pTGUS TGSA NTGUS TGUS NTGSA TGSA+ −( ) + −( ) − −( )[ ]. (4)

The first term, (s + pTGUS - pTGSA), can be interpreted as the terms of trade, the relativeprice of the traded goods produced in the foreign basket in terms of traded goodsproduced at home. Our measure is the real price of the basket of six mineral commoditiesthat South Africa’s most important exports, r m p in log form. Among those who havefound mineral prices or the terms of trade to be an important determinant of the valueof the rand are Aron, Elbadawi, and Kahn (2000), MacDonald and Ricci (2004), Mtonga(2006), Ngandu (2005), Ricci (2005), and Stokke (2006).

The second term is the relative price of nontraded goods in terms of traded goods,abroad versus at home, with weight a.. Real appreciation occurs when the relative priceof nontraded goods rises more rapidly in the domestic country than in the formercountry. According to the well-known Balassa-Samuelson relationship, this in turnhappens when the rate of growth in productivity and income per capita is higher at homethan abroad (because the productivity growth tends to be concentrated in the tradedgoods sector, where prices are tied to world prices by arbitrage).

Thus p p income per cap and p p

inc

NTGUS TGUS US NTGSA TGSA−( ) = ( ) −( )=

ββ oome per cap

SA( ) .

Thus

qt = + ( ) − ( )[ ]μ αβrmp income per cap income per capt US SA t. (5)

We have included both variables, the real price of South African minerals and relativeincome per capita, in the regression equation.

We turn now to the substantial short-term deviations, (q - q̄)t, that real exchange ratesexperience relative to their long-run equilibrium value (q̄)t. The idea is that such deviationsarise routinely, but that they can be expected to correct themselves gradually over time, forexample as sticky goods prices adjust. Assume that speculators form expectations accordingto the regressive specification, with the addition of a possible bubble component:

E q q q q

E s q q E p E p q

t t t t

t t t t t t

Δ

Δ Δ Δ

= − −( ) +

= − −( ) + − +

θ δ

θ δ

1

1*

(6)

where EtDq is defined to be the expectation formed at time t of real depreciation over thecoming period, and analogously for nominal depreciation and inflation; q is the expectedspeed of regression toward the long run equilibrium, the speed with which deviations arethought to be corrected; and dqt is the possible bubble component.2 Assume also that

2 Regressive expectations is of course the formulation in the classic Dornbusch (1976)overshooting model, in which this functional form for expectations is shown to be rational for the

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

18

19

20

21

22

23

24

25

26

27

28

29

30

31

32

33

34

35

36

37

3839

40

South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 20074

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 5 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

uncovered interest parity holds, except for the country premium (default risk premium)that drives a wedge between South African interest rates and foreign interest rates, asreflected in the sovereign spread.

E s i i risk spreadt SAt SA t tΔ = −( ) − ( )∗ (7)

Now we combine equations (6) and (7)

− −( ) + − + = −( ) − ( )− ∗θ δq q E p E p q i i risk spreadt t t t t SAt SA t tΔ Δ * ,1

and solve for the current real exchange rate:

q q q i i E p E p risk spreat t t SAt US t t t= + − −( ) − −( )⎡⎣⎢

⎤⎦⎥

+− ∗δθ θ θ1

1 1Δ Δ * dd t( ) . (8)

Now bring this half of the model together with the other half, equation (5):

q q rmp income pc income pc r rt t t SA US t SA USt t= + − −[ ] − −( ) +−δθ

μ αβθ1

1 1

θθrisk spread t

( )(9)

where we have defined the domestic and foreign real interest rates:

r i E pSAt SAt t= − Δ and

r i E pUSt USt t= − Δ .

Equation (9) represents our model.

2. ESTIMATED EQUATION

As we turn to the empirical estimation, we begin to work in terms of the real value of therand, rather than its reciprocal the real exchange rate, in order to maximize the user-friendliness of the coefficient signs and graphs. Our general equation is:

Log Real Value of Rand Log Real Rand Value Log Real Worldt t 1= + +−α β β1 2

MMineral Price Log SA GDP per cap/foreign GDP per cap Reat t+ ( ) +β β3 4 ll

Interest Differential Country Risk Spread trend Cat t t+ + +β β β5 6 7 ppLib

CapLib*RID u

t

t t

+

+β β8 9 .

right value of q as a result of gradual adjustment of p. Frankel and Froot (1987) offered evidencefrom survey data that expectations at the one-year horizon do indeed encompass such regressivebehavior. Rationales for the addition of the term dqt go back to the bubble literature of the late1980s, e.g., the “dragging anchor” in Goodhart (1985) or the “overshooting of the overshootingequilibrium” in Frankel and Froot (1990). Some think that bandwagons or bubbles may haveaffected the rand at some points (e.g., the sharp fall in 2002). In any case, whatever the rationale,

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

18

19

20

21

22

2324

25

26

27

28

29

5South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 2007

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

m101
New Stamp1

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 6 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

• We have tried various versions of the equation: with the value of the rand definedbilateral against the dollar, or trade weighted.• Log Real Rand Valuet-1 is entered to capture the idea of a dragging anchor ormomentum elements. Hypothesis: 0 < b1 < 1.• Real World Mineral Pricet is computed as an appropriately weighted average of theprices of the specific mineral products that South Africa produces and exports. It isintended to capture the terms of trade, and so is expressed in real form by deflating by theforeign price level. Hypothesis: b2 > 0.• (SA GDP per cap/foreign GDP per cap) t often appears in nominal exchange rateequations as an important determinant of the demand for money (domestic relative toforeign). We are on firmer ground theoretically, when seeking to explain the real exchangerate, to invoke a Balassa-Samuelson effect, in which case real output per capita is the morerelevant variable. In any case, it is only possible to include the GDP variable when we areworking with quarterly data; we are forced to drop it when working with monthly data,unless we interpolate. Hypothesis: b3 > 0.• The remaining variables capture rates of return. It is not enough simply to add interestrates as a rate of return, and hope for a positive coefficient, because nominal high interestrates in developing countries usually reflect expected inflation, default risk, anddevaluation risk.

� The real interest differential (nominal interest rate on rand government bonds, minusexpected inflation, minus the same for abroad) should have a positive effect on theperceived rate of return to holding rand assets and therefore on the value of the rand.Initially we used the one-year lag in the inflation rate as a simple way of capturingexpected inflation. We now use better forward-looking measures of expected inflation,in the form of professional forecasts in South Africa and the US: We are now usingmeasures of ex ante expectations: the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Survey ofProfessional Forecasters in the case of US inflation3 and formal Bureau of EconomicResearch forecasts in the case of South Africa. Hypothesis: b4 > 0.

A country risk premium is included to control for risk of default, or risk of futureimposition of capital controls, when looking for a positive coefficient on the real interestdifferential. After all, a high interest differential does not attract investors to the extentthat it merely reflects a correspondingly high fear of default. The preferred measure of thecountry risk premium is the spread between the interest rate at which South Africaborrows when borrowing in dollars (not rand, because we want to separate out currencyrisk) and a foreign dollar interest rate of the same maturity. We have obtained data fromthe Treasury on the sovereign spread for borrowing by the South African government indollars.4 The series is illustrated in Fig. 4. One can see an impressive downward trend

many studies, of which Mark (1995) is perhaps the best-known, have found empirically that anequation that includes the lagged exchange rate together with current fundamentals performsbetter than either fundamentals alone or the lagged rate alone (random walk), especially at longerhorizons.3 Ang, Bekaert and Wei (2005) provide support for using such survey data.4 In earlier results we used a proxy: the spread between the corporate rand interest rate andthe government rand rate, under the theory that when default risk raises the South Africangovernment interest rates, it raises the corporate interest rate proportionately more. But thesovereign spread is a much better measure of country risk.

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

18

19

20

21

22

23

24

25

26

27

28

29

30

31

32

33

34

35

36

37

3839

40

41

42

43

44

45

46

47

South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 20076

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

m101
New Stamp2

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 7 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

in the perceived risk of South African debt since 2002, to well below 100 basis points inearly 2006, in tandem with some upgrades of South African debt by rating agencies.Sovereign spreads have come down across emerging markets, of course, but internationalinvestors appear to have far more confidence in South Africa than in others, as Fig. 5shows. Hypothesis: b5 < 0.

• One possible rationale for including the trend term is the growing role of AIDS.Kaufmann and Weerapana (2005) find statistical evidence that the rand reacts adverselyto news about AIDS in South Africa. They attribute the strength of the effect tounpredictability regarding long-term business prospects.5

Further details on data sources and how these variables were computed are given in theappendix.6

5 However, we have tried entering a measure of reported AIDS infections directly into theequation and we found no effect. This may be due to the inadequacy of the AIDS measure.6 MacDonald and Ricci (2004), and the updated version in Ricci (2005) have a rather similar list

-

100.00

200.00

300.00

400.00

500.00

600.00

700.00

10/1

5/1

996

2/1

5/1

997

6/1

5/1

997

10/1

5/1

997

2/1

5/1

998

6/1

5/1

998

10/1

5/1

998

2/1

5/1

999

6/1

5/1

999

10/1

5/1

999

2/1

5/2

000

6/1

5/2

000

10/1

5/2

000

2/1

5/2

001

6/1

5/2

001

10/1

5/2

001

2/1

5/2

002

6/1

5/2

002

10/1

5/2

002

2/1

5/2

003

6/1

5/2

003

10/1

5/2

003

2/1

5/2

004

6/1

5/2

004

10/1

5/2

004

2/1

5/2

005

6/1

5/2

005

10/1

5/2

005

2/1

5/2

006

6/1

5/2

006

Global 06 Global 09 Global 12

Global 14 Global 17

S&P Upgrade (BB+ to BBB-) S&P Upgrade (BBB- to BBB)

S&P Upgrade (BBB to BBB+)Moody's upgrade

(Baa3 to Baa2)

Moody's upgrade (Baa2 to Baa1)

Figure 4. Spreads on South African Dollar Debt

50

150

250

350

450

550

650

2-Jun-

03

30-Jul-03

26-Sep-

03

26-Nov-

03

28-Jan-04

26-Mar-

04

25-May-

04

23-Jul-04

21-Sep-

04

19-Nov-

04

20-Jan-05

21-Mar-

05

18-May-

05

18-Jul-05

14-Sep-

05

14-Nov-

05

13-Jan-

06

15-Mar-

06

12-May-

06

10-Jul-06

EM

BI+

EMBI+

RSA EMBI+

Figure 5. South African spread compared to aggregate of emerging market bonds.

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

1617

18

19

7South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 2007

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 8 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

3. RESULTS

The regression results for the nominal and real exchange rate are highly varied. But thereal commodity price index does appear generally to have the hypothesized positivesign. The lagged endogenous variable shows up highly significant, suggesting either amomentum/dragging anchor phenomenon, or else the omission of (serially correlated)determinants. The Breusch-Godfrey LM Test suggests that the use of the laggedendogenous variable does not leave in its wake much grounds for concern about serialcorrelation.7

Income per capita appears with the wrong sign when the regression is run using the realexchange rate for the entire sample period, and significantly so. ((These results arereported in Frankel, 2007.) The same is true when we include total income rather thanper capita, as in old models based on the demand for money. If we include income percapita (or income) without the real mineral price index, then it appears statisticallysignificant and of the expected sign. The explanation is the collinearity of real incomewith mineral prices. But mineral prices knock out real income when they competeside-by-side. Perhaps when we control for the exogenous supply-side influence of theworld mineral prices, the remaining variation in income captures endogenous response tofluctuations in demand, which have negative effects on the trade balance and through thisroute on the value of the currency. In any case, the results are a decisive rejection of theimportance of the Balassa-Samuelson effect in this context. If one is convinced that thisconclusion is right, then one should omit the per capita income differential from theequation, which also has the added advantage of allowing the use of monthly data ratherthan quarterly. This is what we do in the tables reported here.

The results for the rate of return variables are important. For many emerging markets,it is hard to find a positive effect of the interest differential on demand for the currency,presumably because nominal interest rates in practice signal rears of inflation,depreciation, and default, rather than high expected returns. The real interest differentialhas the hypothesized positive effect, as can be seen in the reported tables. Results that usethe dollar spread on South African borrowing to measure the risk premium show a highlysignificant negative effect on the value of the rand, as hypothesized. Unfortunately, thesovereign spread data are only available starting in 1996; these results are not reported inthe tables here.

The mid-1990s saw important structural changes in South Africa, with the transitionto democracy,8 the end of foreign sanctions, and the removal of most capital controls in

of variables in their equation. Perhaps our main improvements relative to their set are the expectedreturn variables.7 Other researchers have been concerned about the possibility of a unit root, even though this isnot as likely in the real exchange as in the nominal exchange rate. MacDonald and Ricci (2004)used the Johansen cointegration test. Du Plessis (2005) commented that the real exchange rate wasweakly exogenous in their results, and argued that they could not claim to have a model in whichthe real exchange rate adjusts toward a long-term equilibrium. Macdonald and Ricci (2005)responded that adding another six quarters of data solved the problem.8 Aron and Elbadawi (1999) describe a sequence of capital inflows into South Africa after itsdemocractic elections in 1994, followed by a speculative attack in 1996.

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

18

19

20

21

22

23

24

25

26

27

28

29

30

31

32

33

34

35

3637

38

39

40

41

42

43

44

45

46

South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 20078

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 9 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

March 1995. The capital account liberalization is probably the most relevant of thesechanges for the exchange rate equation. There had been a dual exchange rate system thathad separated the financial market for rand from the trade account, charging customersa higher rand price for foreign exchange if the purpose was to acquire assets abroad.9

These structural changes provide an argument for starting the sample in 1996. Anotherreason is that the sovereign spread data are only available since 1996 anyway. But we havealso continued to run regressions over the longer sample period (those reported here), inorder to maximize the number of observations. The capital liberalization evidently ventedpressure for capital outflow, because the coefficient on the dummy variable is negative,and usually significant statistically. On the theory that the degree of capital mobility mayhave increased in March 1995, we allowed for the possibility of a shift in the coefficienton the real interest differential;10 but the variable (the differential interacted with adummy that takes the value of 1 post-March 1995) was not statistically significant, oreven greater than zero. We also tried estimating the post-1995 sample by itself, but theresults were unsatisfactory, perhaps because of the smaller number of observations. Betterto go back to the 1980s, even though it means losing the country risk variable.

(i) Real Exchange Rate based on CPIDependent Variable: Log(Real RandCPI)Sample(adjusted): 1984:II-2007:IIncluded observations: 92 after adjusting endpoints

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

Log(Real RandCPI (-1)) 0.839 0.043 19.687 0.0000Log(Real World Mineral Price Index) 0.164 0.058 2.816 0.006Real Interest Differential 0.018 0.005 3.390 0.0011Cap Lib Dummy -0.050 0.023 -2.154 0.0341Cap Lib Dummy * RID -0.009 0.006 -1.468 0.1457C 0.738 0.202 3.652 0.0004R-squared 0.912 Mean dependent var 4.829Adjusted R-squared 0.907 S.D. dependent var 0.213S.E. of regression 0.065 F-statistic 178.628Sum squared resid 0.363 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000Log likelihood 124.047 Durbin-Watson stat 1.718

Breusch-Godfrey Serial Correlation LM Test:F-statistic 0.990 Probability 0.3759Obs*R-squared 1.212 Probability 0.3467

(ii) Real Exchange Rate based on PPIDependent Variable: Log(Real RandPPI)Sample(adjusted): 1984:II-2007:IIncluded observations: 92 after adjusting endpoints

9 See Farrell and Todani (2004) and Patrick Bond (1999).10 Chinn (1999) found more support for the overshooting version of the monetary model – whereinterest rates strengthen the currency – toward the end of his 1980-1997 sample period, consistentwith the 1995 unification of the financial and commercial exchange rates. Akinboade and Makina(2006) test for multiple structural breaks.

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

18

19

20

21

22232425262728293031323334353637

38

39

40

41

42

43

4445

46

47

48

49

9South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 2007

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 10 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

Log(Real RandPPI (-1)) 0.829 0.047 17.716 0.0000Log(Real World Mineral Price Index) 0.129 0.054 2.360 0.0206Real Interes Differential 0.016 0.005 3.098 0.0026Cap Lib Dummy -0.042 0.022 -1.936 0.0561Cap Lib Dummy * RID -0.010 0.006 -1.666 0.0994C 0.794 0.222 3.573 0.0006R-squared 0.892 Mean dependen var 4.812Adjusted R-squared 0.886 S.D. dependen var 0.182S.E. of regression 0.062 Sum squared resid 0.327Log likelihood 128.915 F-statistic 142.076Durbin-Watson stat 1.806 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000

Breusch-Godfrey Serial Correlation LM Test:F-statistic 0.597 Probability 0.5526Obs*R-squared 1.290 Probability 0.5247

(iii) Real Exchange Rate based on GDP DeflatorDependent Variable: Log(Real RandGDP deflator)Sample(adjusted): 1984:II 2007:IIncluded observations: 92 after adjusting endpoints

Variable Coefficient Std. Error t-Statistic Prob.

Log(Real RandCPI (-1)) 0.847 0.043 19.555 0.0000Log(Real World Mineral Price Index) 0.137 0.056 2.461 0.0158Real Interest Differential 0.020 0.005 3.629 0.0005Cap Lib Dummy -0.006 0.020 -0.301 0.7644Cap Lib Dummy * RID -0.016 0.006 -2.537 0.0130C 0.687 0.199 3.455 0.0009R-squared 0.890 Mean dependent var 4.731Adjusted R-squared 0.884 S.D. dependent var 0.185S.E. of regression 0.063 Sum squared resid 0.341Log likelihood 126.929 F-statistic 139.849Durbin-Watson stat 1.707 Prob(F-statistic) 0.000

Breusch-Godfrey Serial Correlation LM Test:F-statistic 1.082 Probability 0.3434Obs*R-squared 2.311 Probability 0.3148

4. COMPARING THE EQUATION PREDICTION AND ACTUAL EXCHANGE RATE

Fig. 6, 7, and 8 plot the actual real value of the rand (using different price indices) againstthe value predicted by the equation. In general the fit is remarkably close.

It is natural to suspect that this may be largely due to the lagged endogenous variable,in which case the equation would not be of much use in forecasting. Fig. 9 adds a“dynamic simulation,” that is, a projected path for the last three years of the sample basedonly on fundamentals. The value of QIV, 2003, is the last one to use the actual exchangerate for the lagged endogenous variable. From then on, the lagged prediction of theequation itself is used as the lagged endogenous variable, rather than the actual.Nevertheless, based on fundamentals such as a rising price of minerals, the projectionpredicts as strong a real appreciation of the rand through mid-2006 as did the fittedvalues of the regression.

Thus the equation does not supply evidence in favor of the proposition that the randwas overvalued (as of early 2007) when judged by its own past relationship to economic

123456789

10111213141516

17

18

19

20

21

22

23242526272829303132333435363738

39

40

41

42

43

44

45

46

47

48

49

50

51

52

53

South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 200710

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 11 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

3.80

4.00

4.20

4.40

4.60

4.80

5.00

5.20

5.40

Q2

1984

Q1

1985

Q4

1985

Q3

1986

Q2

1987

Q1

1988

Q4

1988

Q3

1989

Q2

1990

Q1

1991

Q4

1991

Q3

1992

Q2

1993

Q1

1994

Q4

1994

Q3

1995

Q2

1996

Q1

1997

Q4

1997

Q3

1998

Q2

1999

Q1

2000

Q4

2000

Q3

2001

Q2

2002

Q1

2003

Q4

2003

Q3

2004

Q2

2005

Q1

2006

Q4

2006

RERICPIactual RERICPIfitted

Figure 6. Actual vs Fitted Real Value of the Rand, based on the CPI (1984:II-2007:I)

3.80

4.00

4.20

4.40

4.60

4.80

5.00

5.20

Q2

1984

Q1

1985

Q4

1985

Q3

1986

Q2

1987

Q1

1988

Q4

1988

Q3

1989

Q2

1990

Q1

1991

Q4

1991

Q3

1992

Q2

1993

Q1

1994

Q4

1994

Q3

1995

Q2

1996

Q1

1997

Q4

1997

Q3

1998

Q2

1999

Q1

2000

Q4

2000

Q3

2001

Q2

2002

Q1

2003

Q4

2003

Q3

2004

Q2

2005

Q1

2006

Q4

2006

RERIPPIactual RERIPPIfitted

Figure 7. Actual vs Fitted Real Value of the Rand, based on PPI (1984:II-2007:I)

1

2

3

11South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 2007

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 12 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

3.80

4.00

4.20

4.40

4.60

4.80

5.00

5.20

Q2 198

4

Q1 19

85

Q4

1985

Q3 198

6

Q2

1987

Q1

1988

Q4 1

988

Q3

1989

Q2

1990

Q1 1

991

Q4

1991

Q3

1992

Q2 199

3

Q1

1994

Q4

1994

Q3 1

995

Q2

1996

Q1 1

997

Q4 1

997

Q3

1998

Q2 199

9

Q1 2

000

Q4

2000

Q3

2001

Q2 2

002

Q1

2003

Q4 2

003

Q3 20

04

Q2

2005

Q1 200

6

Q4 2

006

RERIGDPDEFactual RERIGDPDEFfitted

Figure 8. Actual vs Fitted Real Value of the Rand, based on GDP Deflator (1984:II-2007:I)

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

200

Q2

1984

Q1

1985

Q4

1985

Q3

1986

Q2

1987

Q1

1988

Q4

1988

Q3

1989

Q2

1990

Q1

1991

Q4

1991

Q3

1992

Q2

1993

Q1

1994

Q4

1994

Q3

1995

Q2

1996

Q1

1997

Q4

1997

Q3

1998

Q2

1999

Q1

2000

Q4

2000

Q3

2001

Q2

2002

Q1

2003

Q4

2003

Q3

2004

Q2

2005

Q1

2006

Q4

2006

RERICPIactual RERICPIfitted RERICPIprojected

Figure 9. Actual vs. Fitted vs. Projected Real Value of Rand, based on CPI (1984:II-2007:I)

1

2

3

South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 200712

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 13 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

fundamentals. But then efficiency in the financial market sense is not the same thing asefficiency in the sense of correct signals for the allocation of resources in the realeconomy.11 The speculative inflows during the recent boom in commodities andemerging markets may be “par for the course;” but this is not inconsistent with theproposition that Dutch Disease crowding out of non-commodity tradables could havenegative consequences, especially in the long run.

APPENDIX: DATA NOTES

Nominal Exchange Rate (NER): is the nominal foreign exchange value of South Africa’scurrency expressed in USD per South African Rand.

Real Bilateral Exchange Rate Index: is the nominal exchange rate multiplied by the ratioof South African price index to US price index, expressed in index form with base year2000. Three real exchange rate indices are constructed based on three different priceindices: Real Rand CPI is calculated using the CPI, Real Rand PPI is calculated using thePPI, and Real RandGDP deflator is calculated using the GDP deflator. The three series areplotted below for comparison.

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

84 86 88 90 92 94 96 98 00 02 04 06

RERICPI RERIPPI RERIGDPDEF

Real Mineral and Metal Price Index: The nominal weighted mineral and metal priceindex (World Mineral Price Index) is the weighted price index of South African majormineral and metal export commodities. Weights are derived from the commodity’s exportshare in the value of total exports of South Africa. While efforts are made to include allmajor commodities, some of them, such as diamond, are not included due to lack ofinternational price index. The commodities included and their weights are givenbelow:

11 Recent theoretical illustrations include Devereux and Engel (2006) and Caballero (2007).

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

18

19

20

21

22

23

24

25

26

27

2829

13South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 2007

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 14 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

Table. South African Major Export Commodities

Commodity Group Actual % share Adjusted % share

Gold and platinum 17.54 56.22Iron ores 2.78 8.90Coal 5.69 18.23Petroleum Oil 2.81 9.01Aluminum 2.38 7.64

Total 31.19 100.00

Source: Compiled from data from South African Trade and Industry Department

The real weighted mineral and metal price index (Real World Mineral Price Index) isthe World Mineral Price Index divided by the consumer price index of the US.

Expected Inflation Rates: The source of US’s expected inflation rate is the FederalReserve Bank of Philadelphia. The South Africa expected inflation rate is the inflationforecasts from the macro model of South Africa’s Bureau of Economic Research, providedby Professor Ben W Smit.

Real Interest Rate Differentials: The long term government bond yields of the US andSouth Africa are obtained from the IFS, IMF database. Then respective expectedinflations are subtracted from nominal long term bond yields to get the real interest rates.The real interest rate differential is then the difference between SA’s real governmentbond rate and US’s real government bond rate.

GDP RatiosReal and nominal GDPs are collected for South Africa and the US from IFS, IMF, andthe following ratio are calculated:

(i) Real GDP ratio between S. Africa and the US (RGDPrat)(ii) Nominal GDP ratio between S. Africa and the US (NGDPrat)(iii) Real per capita GDP ratio between S. Africa and the US (PERGDPrat)

Quarterly per capita GDPs are calculated using quarterly real GDPs and extrapolatedquarterly population. The annual mid-year population estimates, obtained from IFS,were decomposed to quarterly using the following formula:

Year t Q1 pop year t pop year t pop

Q2 pop year t po

= ∗ −( ) + ∗( )= ∗ −

3 8 1 5 8

1 8 1 pp year t pop

Q3 pop year t pop year t pop

Q4 pop

( ) + ∗( )= ∗( ) + ∗ +( )

7 8

7 8 1 8 1

== ∗( ) + ∗ +( )5 8 3 8 1year t pop year t pop

The following Fig. show how the generated quarterly per capita GDP series tracked theannual figures obtained from the World Development Indicators, World Bank.

1

23456789

10

11

12

13

14

15

16

17

18

19

20

21

22

23

24

25

26

27

28

29

30

31

32

33

South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 200714

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

33

44

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 15 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

9.8

9.9

9.9

10.0

10.0

10.1

10.1

10.2

1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005

9.70

9.75

9.80

9.85

9.90

9.95

10.00

10.05

10.10

10.15

Q1

1984

Q4

1984

Q3

1985

Q2

1986

Q1

1987

Q4

1987

Q3

1988

Q2

1989

Q1

1990

Q4

1990

Q3

1991

Q2

1992

Q1

1993

Q4

1993

Q3

1994

Q2

1995

Q1

1996

Q4

1996

Q3

1997

Q2

1998

Q1

1999

Q4

1999

Q3

2000

Q2

2001

Q1

2002

Q4

2002

Q3

2003

Q2

2004

Q1

2005

Q4

2005

Figure. Annual (top) and Quarterly (bottom) series of per capita GDP: USA1

15South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 2007

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

m101
New Stamp5

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 16 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

9.9

10.0

10.1

10.2

10.3

10.4

10.5

10.6

1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005

9.90

10.00

10.10

10.20

10.30

10.40

10.50

10.60

Q1

1984

Q4

1984

Q3

1985

Q2

1986

Q1

1987

Q4

1987

Q3

1988

Q2

1989

Q1

1990

Q4

1990

Q3

1991

Q2

1992

Q1

1993

Q4

1993

Q3

1994

Q2

1995

Q1

1996

Q4

1996

Q3

1997

Q2

1998

Q1

1999

Q4

1999

Q3

2000

Q2

2001

Q1

2002

Q4

2002

Q3

2003

Q2

2004

Q1

2005

Q4

2005

1

South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 200716

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 17 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

Dummy for Removal of Capital Controls (Cap Lib Dummy): A dummy for capitalmarket liberalization, which has a value of one since the second quarter of 1995, whenSouth African capital market was liberalized, and zero elsewhere.

Cap Lib Dummy * RID comes from Cap Lib Dummy interacted with the real interestrate differential.

REFERENCES

AKINBOADE, O. A. and MAKINA, D. (2006). Mean reversion and structural breaks in real exchange rates: south africanevidence, Applied Financial Economics vol. 16, no. 4/15, February (Routledge), 347-358.ANG, A., BEKAERT, G. and WEI, M. (2005). Do Macro Variables, Asset Markets or Surveys Forecast Inflation Better?NBER Working Paper No. 11538.ARON, J. and ELBADAWI, I. (1999). Reflections on the South African rand crisis of 1996 and policy consequences.Centre for the Study of African Economies Working Paper Series No. 97, Sept. 20.ARON, J., ELBADAWI, I. and KAHN, B. (2000). Real and monetary determinants of the real exchange rate in SouthAfrica, in Development Issues in South Africa, edited by Ibrahim Elbadawi and Trudi Hartzenberg (MacMillan: London).BOND, P. (1999) A case for capital controls, University of the Witwatersrand, Graduate School of Public andDevelopment Management, December.CABALLERO, R. (2007). Persistent appreciations and overshooting: a normative analysis. NBER Working Paper No.13077.CHINN, M. (1999). A monetary model of the South African Rand, UCSC WP 443. African Finance Journal 1, no. 1,Oct., 69-91.DEVEREUX, M. and ENGEL, C. (2006). Expectations and exchange rate policy, NBER Working Paper No. 12213, May.DORNBUSCH, R. (1976). Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics, Journal of Political Economy 84, no. 6, December.DU PLESSIS, S. (2005). Exogeneity in a recent exchange rate model: A response to Macdonald and Ricci. South AfricanJournal of Economics 73, no. 4, Dec., 741-753.FARRELL, G. N. and TODANI, K. R. (2004). Capital flows, exchange control regulations and exchange rate policy: TheSouth African experience. OECD Seminar, Bond Exchange of South Africa, March.FRANKEL, J. (2006). On the Rand: A note on the South African exchange rate, Harvard University., April. Athttp://ksghome.harvard.edu/~jfrankel/currentpubsspeeches.htm#For%20Other%20Emerging%20Market%20Countries.——— (2007). On the Rand: Update Note, Harvard University. At http://ksghome.harvard.edu/~jfrankel/currentpubsspeeches.htm#For%20Other%20Emerging%20Market%20Countries.——— and FROOT, K. (1987). Using survey data to test standard propositions regarding exchange rate expectations,American Economic Review 77, no. 1 (March): 133-53. Reprinted as Chapter 13 in Frankel, On Exchange Rates.——— and FROOT, K. (1990). Chartists, fundamentalists, and the demand for dollars, in Anthony Courakis and MarkTaylor, eds., Private Behavior and Government Policy in Interdependent Economies. Oxford: Clarendon Press.GOODHART, C. (1988). The foreign exchange market: a random walk with a dragging anchor. Economica 55, 437-60.KAUFMANN, K. and WEERAPANA, A. (2005). The impact of AIDS-related news on exchange rates in South Africa.Economics Department, Wellesley College, April.MACDONALD, R. and RICCI, L. (2004). Estimation of the equilibrium real exchange rate for South Africa. IMFWorking Paper /03/44. South African Journal of Economics, 2004 vol.72:2; p.282.——— and RICCI, L. (2005). Exogeneity in a recent exchange rate model: A reply. South African Journal Economics 73,no. 4 Dec., 747-753.MARK, N. (1994) Exchange rates and fundamentals: evidence on long-horizon predictability. American Economic Review85, No. 1 (Mar., 1995), 201-218.MTONGA, E. (2006). The real exchange rate of the Rand and competitiveness of South Africa’s trade. School ofEconomics, University of Cape Town, August 15. Munich Personal RePec Archive, Paper No. 1192, Dec.NGANDU, S. (2005). Mineral prices and the exchange rate: What does the literature say. Employment Growth andDevelopment Initiative, Human Sciences Research Council, South Africa, February.RICCI, L. A. (2005). South Africa’s real exchange rate performance, in Post-Apartheid South Africa: The First Ten Years,edited by Michael Nowak and Luca Antonio Ricci. Washington, DC: IMF.STOKKE, H. E. (2006). Resource boom, productivity growth and real exchange rate dynamics – A dynamic generalequilibrium analysis of South Africa. Department of Economics Working Paper Series No. 8/2006, Norwegian Universityof Science and Technology, Trondheim, Norway.

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

89

1011121314151617181920212223242526272829303132333435363738394041424344454647484950515253

17South African Journal of Economics Vol. 75:3 September 2007

© 2007 The Author.Journal compilation © Economic Society of South Africa 2007.

JOBNAME: No Job Name PAGE: 18 SESS: 100 OUTPUT: Wed Sep 19 18:13:17 2007/v2451/blackwell/journals/saje_v75_i3/saje_130

AUTHOR QUERY FORM

Dear Author,During the preparation of your manuscript for publication, the questions listed below have

arisen. Please attend to these matters and return this form with your proof.Many thanks for your assistance.

QueryReferences

Query Remark

1 Au: Should the Goodhart (1985) here be changedto Goodhart (1988) so as to match the referencelist?

2 Au: Should the Mark (1995) here be changed toMark (1994) so as to match the reference list?

3 Au: Please provide the id number for this table.

4 Au: Please provide the id number for this figure.

5 Au: Please provide the id number for this figure.

SNP Best-set Typesetter Ltd.Journal Code: SAJE Proofreader: EmilyArticle No: 130 Delivery date: 19 September 2007Page Extent: 17

MARKED PROOF

Please correct and return this set

Instruction to printer

Leave unchanged under matter to remain

through single character, rule or underline

New matter followed byor

or

or

or

or

or

or

or

or

and/or

and/or

e.g.

e.g.

under character

over character

new character new characters

through all characters to be deleted

through letter orthrough characters

under matter to be changedunder matter to be changedunder matter to be changedunder matter to be changedunder matter to be changed

Encircle matter to be changed

(As above)

(As above)

(As above)

(As above)

(As above)

(As above)

(As above)

(As above)

linking characters

through character orwhere required

between characters orwords affected

through character orwhere required

or

indicated in the marginDelete

Substitute character orsubstitute part of one ormore word(s)

Change to italicsChange to capitalsChange to small capitalsChange to bold typeChange to bold italicChange to lower case

Change italic to upright type

Change bold to non-bold type

Insert ‘superior’ character

Insert ‘inferior’ character

Insert full stop

Insert comma

Insert single quotation marks

Insert double quotation marks

Insert hyphenStart new paragraph

No new paragraph

Transpose

Close up

Insert or substitute spacebetween characters or words

Reduce space betweencharacters or words

Insert in text the matter

Textual mark Marginal mark

Please use the proof correction marks shown below for all alterations and corrections. If you

in dark ink and are made well within the page margins.wish to return your proof by fax you should ensure that all amendments are written clearly


Recommended