+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford...

Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford...

Date post: 06-Jul-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
42
Optimal Fundamental Investing Matthew Lyle and Teri Lombardi Yohn * September 23, 2019 Abstract We show how fundamental analysis can be seamlessly integrated with mean-variance portfolio optimization to construct stock portfolios. We find that fundamental anal- ysis combined with mean-variance portfolio optimization yields substantial improve- ments in portfolio performance relative to portfolios constructed using alternative approaches examined in prior research. Both long-short and long-only optimal fun- damental portfolios produce large out-of-sample CAPM and factor alphas, with high Sharpe and Information ratios. The results are persistent through time and remain when small capitalization firms are eliminated from the investment set. We therefore demonstrate how to combine fundamental analysis and portfolio optimiza- tion to jointly exploit the benefits of each. JEL: G12, G14, G17 Keywords: Fundamental Analysis, Portfolio Optimization, Return Prediction * Lyle ([email protected]) is an Associate Professor at the Kellogg School of Man- agement, and Yohn ([email protected]) is Visiting Professor at the Kellogg School of Management and Professor of Accounting at the Kelley School of Business. We appreciate helpful sugges- tions and comments from Larry Brown, Charles Lee, Ron Dye, Ravi Jagannathan, Jeremiah Green, Bob Korajczyk, Bob McDonald, Steve Penman, Beverly Walther and workshop participants at the Kellogg School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable research assistance. We are grateful for the fund- ing of this research by the Kellogg School of Management, Lyle thanks The Accounting Research Center at Kellogg for funding provided through the E&Y Live and Revsine Research Fellowships.
Transcript
Page 1: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Optimal Fundamental Investing

Matthew Lyle and Teri Lombardi Yohn∗

September 23, 2019

Abstract

We show how fundamental analysis can be seamlessly integrated with mean-varianceportfolio optimization to construct stock portfolios. We find that fundamental anal-ysis combined with mean-variance portfolio optimization yields substantial improve-ments in portfolio performance relative to portfolios constructed using alternativeapproaches examined in prior research. Both long-short and long-only optimal fun-damental portfolios produce large out-of-sample CAPM and factor alphas, withhigh Sharpe and Information ratios. The results are persistent through time andremain when small capitalization firms are eliminated from the investment set. Wetherefore demonstrate how to combine fundamental analysis and portfolio optimiza-tion to jointly exploit the benefits of each.

JEL: G12, G14, G17

Keywords: Fundamental Analysis, Portfolio Optimization, Return Prediction

∗Lyle ([email protected]) is an Associate Professor at the Kellogg School of Man-agement, and Yohn ([email protected]) is Visiting Professor at the Kellogg School ofManagement and Professor of Accounting at the Kelley School of Business. We appreciate helpful sugges-tions and comments from Larry Brown, Charles Lee, Ron Dye, Ravi Jagannathan, Jeremiah Green, BobKorajczyk, Bob McDonald, Steve Penman, Beverly Walther and workshop participants at the KelloggSchool of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A specialthanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable research assistance. We are grateful for the fund-ing of this research by the Kellogg School of Management, Lyle thanks The Accounting Research Centerat Kellogg for funding provided through the E&Y Live and Revsine Research Fellowships.

Page 2: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

1. INTRODUCTION

Fundamental analysis uses accounting-based characteristics and ratios to estimate a

stock’s intrinsic value. The notion underlying fundamental analysis is that the difference

between a stock’s price and intrinsic value is predictive of the direction of the stock’s future

returns as the price converges to intrinsic value. Many valuation and accounting ratios,

such as book-to-market and profitability, have been shown to be useful for identifying

stocks whose future returns are likely to increase or decrease. Using fundamental analysis

for stock selection can be dated at least as far back as Benjamin and Dodd (1934),

and its ability to provide information about firm’s future stock returns has been shown

to be robust across time periods and countries. Despite the documented usefulness of

fundamental analysis for stock selection, it remains unclear how it can be employed to

construct stock portfolios.1

In his seminal paper, Markowitz (1952) argues that constructing a stock portfolio

consists of generating beliefs about the future performance of individual stocks and then

allocating wealth across the stocks to maximize the expected return of the portfolio sub-

ject to a given constraint (e.g., risk tolerance). While portfolio optimization has been

documented to improve portfolio performance (Engle et al., 2017; Jorion, 1985, 1986), its

usefulness has been limited due to poor quality estimates of expected returns (DeMiguel

et al., 2009; Jagannathan and Ma, 2003; Michaud, 1989). The research shows that com-

pletely disregarding expected return estimates and constructing minimum variance port-

folios (e.g., Jagannathan and Ma, 2003; Ledoit and Wolf, 2017) yields better performance

than optimized portfolios that incorporate expected returns. Thus, prior research sug-

gests that mean-variance portfolio optimization may be of use to investors only when

beliefs about expected returns are completely disregarded.

1The standard approach in the academic literature is to form either equal or value weighted portfoliosfrom groups of stocks ranked by the financial ratio of interest and to determine if there exists differencesin future stock returns across portfolios. Because the goal of these tests is to document systematic associ-ations between fundamental ratios and future returns, the literature provides insight into predictability,but not how an investor can or “should” form portfolios.

1

Page 3: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Because fundamental analysis provides information about expected returns and be-

cause portfolio optimization provides a solution for allocating wealth across stocks given

expected returns, it seems logical that linking the two streams of research would be ben-

eficial to both. However, fundamental analysis has not been used in a Markowitz mean-

variance portfolio optimization setting because the analysis has not generated expected

returns or stock return covariances of individual stocks. In this study, we analytically

demonstrate how fundamental analysis can be used to estimate expected returns and

covariances and seemlessly integrated with mean-variance portfolio optimization to con-

struct stock portfolios. We then empirically test whether optimal fundamental portfolios,

which combine fundamental analysis with mean-variance portfolio optimization, yield im-

provements in performance over portfolios formed using alternative approaches examined

in prior research.

Our model captures the key ideas underlying fundamental analysis, while remaining

tractable enough for straightforward estimation. The model is a new and practical ex-

tension of research that uses valuation models to either generate expected stock return

estimates (e.g., Gebhardt et al. 2001; Chattopadhyay et al. 2018; Lyle et al. 2013; Lyle

and Wang 2015) or to explain and predict index returns (e.g., Lee et al., 1999). We

assume, as is common in the literature (e.g., Frankel and Lee, 1998), that a fundamental

investor uses the residual income formula to estimate intrinsic value. We also assume

that a fundamental investor expects the difference between the stock’s intrinsic value

and share prices to follow a simple AR(1) process, with an unconditional mean of zero,

as in Johannesson and Ohlson (2019). These assumptions imply that stock returns are

a linear combination of firm size, book-to-market, expected earnings yield, and unpre-

dictable noise. This parsimonious linear structure allows us to uniquely incorporate both

cross-sectional and time-series information to estimate expected returns and a covari-

ance matrix within a single valuation setting, which allows us to integrate fundamental

analysis with mean-variance portfolio optimization.

We examine the performance of four portfolios that systematically incorporate dif-

2

Page 4: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

ferent information in expected returns and covariances for portfolio construction. The

first portfolios (EW portfolios) are “naive” equal weighted portfolios that ignore both

expected returns and covariances. The second portfolios (MV portfolios) are minimum

variance portfolios that disregard expected return estimates and rely exclusively on co-

variance estimates. The third portfolios (ER portfolios) disregard covariance estimates

and rely exclusively on expected return estimates. The fourth portfolios (MS portfolios)

maximize the Sharpe ratio using both expected returns and covariance matrices. For

each construction strategy, we examine expected returns and covariances based on the

fundamentals-based model. For comparison, and as in prior research, we also examine

portfolios that use historical average stock returns to estimate expected returns and co-

variances. We examine both “long-short” and “long-only” portfolios because taking short

positions is often not feasible and, even when feasible, implementation costs are often high

(Beneish et al., 2015).

Using fundamentals-based expected returns and covariances, we find, consistent with

prior research on portfolio optimization, that portfolios that incorporate information

about covariances (i.e., MV portfolios) outperform those that use a naive equal weighted

strategy (i.e., EW portfolios). However, unlike the prior research, we show that portfolios

that incorporate fundamentals-based estimates of expected returns (i.e., ER portfolios)

generally outperform the MV portfolios. Our key finding is that our optimal fundamental

portfolios (i.e., fundamentals-based MS portfolios) yield the highest out-of-sample Sharpe

and Information ratios as well as factor alphas of all the portfolios we examine. From 1981-

2017 (our full out-of-sample period), long-only optimal fundamental portfolios, which are

rebalanced monthly, have average future returns of 1.92%, a Sharpe ratio of 0.367, an

Information ratio of 0.395, and five factor (Fama and French, 2015) alphas of 0.888%.

Long-short optimal fundamental portfolios generate even higher performance metrics than

the long-only portfolios, with a monthly Sharpe ratio of 0.524 and an Information ratio

of 0.523, and outperform the alternative portfolios by an even greater margin. Consistent

with the findings of DeMiguel et al. (2009), we find that portfolios optimized incorporating

3

Page 5: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

historical-based stock returns tend to be the worst performing portfolios. These findings

suggest that integrating mean-variance optimization and fundamentals-based expected

returns and covariances delivers substantial improvements to portfolio performance.

The results hold over different time periods, even after well-known academic research

which highlights the predictive ability of financial ratios was published. The results

also hold when portfolios are limited to include only large stocks. This latter result is

important since Hou et al. (2018) find that most return-predictive signals documented in

prior studies do not significantly predict returns when small firms are removed from the

sample. The robustness of our findings to the exclusion of small stocks suggests that our

results are unlikely driven by small illiquid stocks or an unreplicable anomaly.

Several of the variables implied by our fundamentals-based return model (e.g., size

and book-to-market) are similar to those characteristics used by Fama and French (1993,

2015) to construct factor portfolios. Despite this, we find that our optimal fundamental

portfolios cannot be replicated by the Fama and French factor portfolios. This is not sur-

prising given that Fama and French portfolios are constructed by simultaneously longing

and shorting stocks that have high or low characteristics (e.g., book-to-market or size)

with portfolio weights being determined by market capitalization (i.e., value weighted).

In contrast, our optimal fundamental portfolio weights are optimized based on expected

returns and covariances.

Our study is also related to Brandt et al. (2009) who propose a novel methodology

that is meant to overcome some of the challenges of mean-variance optimization. Brandt

et al. (2009) combine a power utility function with firm characteristics and solve for

portfolio weights via non-linear estimation. Hand and Green (2011) extend Brandt et al.

(2009) by incorporating accounting-based characteristics and show that accounting-based

fundamental signals enhance portfolio performance over price-based signals. We employ

the Brandt et al. (2009) methodology using the same fundamental variables in our es-

timation for mean-variance optimization. We find that while the Brandt et al. (2009)

methodology does offer benefits to investors relative to naive portfolio construction, the

4

Page 6: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

performance does not match that of our optimal fundamental portfolios.

This study provides important contributions to both practice and research on funda-

mental analysis and portfolio optimization. Fundamental analysis is aimed at identifying

stocks that are likely to experience higher or lower future returns, but provides little

insight with respect to creating portfolios. Similarly, portfolio optimization provides the-

oretical arguments for optimizing portfolios, but poor quality expected return estimates

limit its usefulness in constructing portfolios in practice. We demonstrate how funda-

mental analysis can be combined with portfolio optimization and empirically document

the substantial gains to portfolio performance from doing so.

2. Fundamental Analysis, Stock Returns, and Portfolio Optimization

In this section we formally outline the investment problem from the point of view of a

fundamental investor who initially performs fundamental analysis to derive an “intrinsic

value” estimate of a stock, which we call Vt, that is currently trading at a price Pt. We

show how the fundamental investor can use differences between Vt and Pt to construct an

optimal portfolio. This setting can be considered a formal extension of Lee et al. (1999)

who argue that if Pt deviates from, but tends to converge to intrinsic value over time,

then high quality estimates of intrinsic value will have return prediction power. While

Lee et al. (1999) examine the ability of different valuation models to explain and predict

index returns, our study is focused on constructing portfolios from the cross-section of

stocks.

2.1. Fundamental Investing and Stock Returns

Fundamental investing requires the assertion that, at some point, the stock’s price

will converge to its intrinsic value. We operationalize this notion by assuming that the

difference between the market price and intrinsic value for firm i, Pi,t − Vi,t, follows an

AR(1) process, with an unconditional mean of zero, as in Johannesson and Ohlson (2019):

5

Page 7: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Pi,t+1 − Vi,t+1 = ωi(Pi,t − Vi,t) + εi,t+1, (1)

where ωi ∈ (0, 1) represents a persistence parameter and εi,t+1 is a mean-zero vari-

ance one noise term, which represents a shock to expected convergence. Assuming fun-

damental investors price an equity by discounting cash flows/dividends, then Vi,t =∑∞j=1 EFt [R−ji Di,t+j], where EFt [·] represents the time t expectation operator given fun-

damental investors’ beliefs and Di,t+j the dividends to be paid at time t+ j. Implicit in

this assumption is that EFt [Vi,t+1 + Di,t+1] = RiVi,t, where Ri > 1 is the gross discount

rate used in the valuation model. This in turn implies that fundamental investors believe

that future stock returns take the standard form of an expectation plus shocks:

Pi,t+1 +Di,t+1

Pi,t= Vi,tPi,t

Ri + ωi(1−Vi,tPi,t

)︸ ︷︷ ︸Expected Return

+ (Vi,t+1 +Di,t+1)−RiVi,tPi,t︸ ︷︷ ︸

Fundamentals Shock

+ εi,t+1

Pi,t︸ ︷︷ ︸Convergence Shock

. (2)

Fundamental investors’ beliefs about expected returns are, naturally, increasing in

the discount rate used in valuation, Ri, but this is modified by the value-to-price ratio,

Vi,t/Pi,t, which acts like a multiplier, where higher value-to-price ratios increase the ex-

pected returns. The persistence in the deviation between intrinsic value and price, ωi, has

an intuitive effect. For high value-to-price ratios, a high persistence parameter implies

a lower expected return because it is expected to take longer for the fundamental in-

vestor to capture gains from convergence between intrinsic value and price.2 Ultimately,

expected returns are maximized from a fundamental investor’s perspective if intrinsic

value-to-price ratios are high and expected to converge quickly.

There are two sources of risk to the fundamental investor: 1) an unpredictable shock

from fundamentals, (Vi,t+1 +Di,t+1)−RiVi,t = (Vi,t+1 +Di,t+1)− EFt [Vi,t+1 +Di,t+1], and

2) an unpredictable shock related to the convergence between price and intrinsic value,

2For low valuation ratios ωi has the same effect if the fundamental investor considers shorting.

6

Page 8: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

εi,t+1. These shocks may be correlated, but for our purposes, their correlation makes

no difference for the investment decision. Therefore, we can represent returns more

compactly as

Ri,t+1 ≡Pi,t+1 +Di,t+1

Pi,t= ωi + Vi,t

Pi,t(Ri − ωi) + Ωi,tξi,t+1, (3)

where Ωi,t represents fundamental investor’s beliefs about the volatility of stock re-

turns and ξi,t+1 is a mean zero, unit variance noise term.

To draw a direct connection to fundamentals, it is useful to recast the dividend

discount formula in terms of residual income, such that Vi,t = ∑∞j=1 EFt [R−ji Di,t+j] =

Bi,t(1 + ∑∞j=1R

−ji EFt [xai,t+j]/Bi,t), where Bi,t is book value, xai,t+1 = xi,t+1 − (Ri − 1)Bi,t

represents t+ 1 “residual income” and xi,t+1 is t+ 1 accounting earnings. As such, valu-

ations are a function of book values and projections of future profitability, which in turn

implies that fundamental investor’s beliefs about stock returns must also be a function

of these variables,

Ri,t+1 = ωi + (Ri − ωi)Bi,t

Pi,t(1 +

∑∞j=1R

−ji EFt [xai,t+j]Bi,t

) + Ωi,tξi,t+1. (4)

For (4) to be implementable, we must make an assumption about the dynamics for

residual income. We assume that residual income follows a simple stochastic process

xai,t+1 = hi,t + zi,t+1, where hi,t+1 = hi + κi(hi,t − hi) + wi,t+1. Here zi,t+1 and wi,t+1 are

noise terms, hi,t represents the conditional mean of abnormal earnings, which follows an

AR(1) process with persistence κi and an unconditional mean of hi.3 If follows that stock

returns have the following functional form:

Ri,t+1 = ωi + αi,01Pi,t

+ αi,1Bi,t

Pi,t+ αi,2

EFt [xi,t+1]Pi,t

+ Ωi,tξi,t+1, (5)

3The assumption of auto-regressive abnormal earnings is common, see for example Christensen andFeltham (2012) and the references within.

7

Page 9: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

αi,0 = hi(Ri − ωi)(1− κi)(Ri − 1)(Ri − κi)

> 0, (6)

αi,1 = (Ri − ωi)(1− κi)Ri − κi

> 0, (7)

αi,2 = Ri − ωiRi − κi

> 0. (8)

The stock return equation above is similar to the partial equilibrium returns model

derived by Lyle et al. (2013), and highlights that a fundamental investor can use a com-

bination of three key variables (i.e., market value, Pi,t, book value, Bi,t, and projections

of future earnings, EFt [xi,t+1]) to predict stock returns. When we estimate (5), we must

use a proxy for expected earnings, EFt [xi,t+1], since they are not observable. We do so

based on prior financial statement analysis research which shows that future profitability

is a function of not only current earnings, but also variables that measure growth. We

use the change in net operating assets, ∆NOAi,t, and change in financing, ∆FINi,t, as

our proxies for growth given prior fundamental analysis research of the relation between

growth and future profitability (Fairfield et al., 2003; Bradshaw et al., 2006; Cooper et al.,

2008). After substituting these variables in the equation, we obtain an estimable stock

return equation that is linear in firm characteristics

Ri,t+1 = Ai,0 + Ai,11Pi,t

+ Ai,2Bi,t

Pi,t+ Ai,3

xi,tPi,t

+ Ai,4∆NOAi,t

Pi,t+ Ai,5

∆FINi,t

Pi,t+ Ωi,tξi,t+1.

(9)

The parsimonious linear structure of (9) allows for straightforward estimation of both

the conditional mean and covariance in a single setting at the firm-level, which provides

a direct connection to mean-variance portfolio optimization as outlined next.

2.2. Optimal Portfolios

Here we outline our four main portfolio construction strategies. The fundamentals-

based return model, equation (9), implies that the expected return for the ith firm is given

by µi,t = Ai,0 +Ai,11Pi,t

+Ai,2Bi,tPi,t

+Ai,3xi,tPi,t

+Ai,4∆NOAi,t

Pi,t+Ai,5

∆FINi,tPi,t

and the covariance

8

Page 10: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

between the the ith and jth firm is given by cov(Ri,t+1 − µi,t, Rj,t+1 − µj,t). We first

show how portfolio weights are allocated across stocks assuming an investor uses mean-

variance optimization and accounts for cross-sectional differences in expected returns and

covariances. We call these MS portfolios because they correspond to maximum Sharpe

ratio portfolios. We then show that each of the other portfolio construction strategies

we study to construct minimum variance (MV), expected return only (ER), and equal

weighted (EW)) portfolios are all particular cases of MS portfolios. The portfolios allow

for short selling and impose no constraints on the weights allocated to each stock, except

that the weights must sum to one. In our empirical tests, when we impose constraints,

exact solutions are often not possible, so we use a quadratic program to solve for portfolio

weights numerically.4

2.2.1. Mean-Variance Portfolios

As is the standard formulation in mean-variance optimization, we assume that a

fundamental investor allocates wealth by solving the classic mean-variance optimization

program, where the investor minimizes portfolio variance for a given expected return, µP :

minωωTΣω, (10)

s.t. ωTµ = µp, (11)

ωT e = 1, (12)

where ω = (ω1, ω2, . . . , ωN)T is aN×1 vector of portfolio weights, µt = (µ1,t, µ2,t, . . . µN,t)T

is a N ×1 vector of expected returns, Σ is a N ×N covariance matrix, e is a N ×1 vector

of ones. Solving the program, and setting µp to the value that achieves the maximum

expected portfolio return per unit portfolio volatility yields

4For this study, we used the software package Matlab, and specifically it’s built-in function “quad-prog” to solve the optimization problem. However, several popular open source software packages,including R and Python, have similar capabilities.

9

Page 11: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

ω∗MS = Σ−1µ

eTΣ−1µ. (13)

Equation (13) represents portfolios constructed that take full advantage of both expected

returns and the covariance matrix. This corresponds to our MS portfolios.

2.2.2. Minimum Variance Portfolios

If investors disregard expected returns in constructing portfolios, then this is equiva-

lent to assuming that expected returns are cross-sectionally constant, i.e., µ = c × e for

some real constant c, and equation (13) becomes

ω∗MV = Σ−1e

eTΣ−1e. (14)

Equation (14) corresponds to our MV portfolios.

2.2.3. Expected Return Portfolios

If investors disregard cross-sectional differences in covariances in constructing portfo-

lios, then this is equivalent to assuming that covariances are cross-sectionally constant,

i.e., Σ = C× I where I is a N ×N identity matrix and C is a real constant, and equation

(13) becomes

ω∗ER = µ

eTµ. (15)

Equation (15) corresponds to our ER portfolios.

2.2.4. Equal Weighted Portfolios

If investors disregard cross-sectional differences in means and covariances in construct-

ing portfolios, then this is equivalent to assuming that both are cross-sectionally constant,

i.e., µ = c× e and Σ = C × I, and equation (13) becomes

10

Page 12: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

ω∗EW = 1N. (16)

Equation (16) corresponds to our EW portfolios.

3. Data and Estimation

3.1. Data

Our data are from standard sources: CRSP and Compustat. Our full sample time

period is from 1981-2017. We use the period 1976-1980 as an initial model estimation

period and 1981-2017 as the out-of-sample test period. Our initial estimation period

begins in 1976 because prior to this Compustat quarterly is not well populated. We also

examine more recent sub-periods to assess the gains that a fundamental investor could

have generated in periods that follow the publication of several academic papers that

document the predictability of stock returns based on the variables that we use in our

model (e.g., Bradshaw et al., 2006; Fama and French, 1992; Sloan, 1996; Fairfield et al.,

2003; Cooper et al., 2008).

At the end of each month, prior to portfolio construction, we remove penny stocks,

stocks with a negative book value, and stocks with less than five years of historical stock

return data. These criteria ensure we can reasonably estimate stock return volatility

and pairwise correlations (i.e., the covariance matrix). All expected return estimates are

winsorized at the 1 and 99% level. In addition to these filters, we also, as is common in

the literature, remove financial and regulated firms from the sample since the accounting

for these types of firms is systematically different from other firms. The risk-free rates

and factor portfolios used in our empirical tests are downloaded from Ken French’s data

library.5

5These data can be downloaded from http://mba.tuck.dartmouth.edu/pages/faculty/ken.french/data library.html

11

Page 13: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

3.2. Model Estimation for Mean-Variance Optimization

To generate expected returns, we must estimate equation (9). Prior research has

estimated models both cross-sectionally (e.g., Chattopadhyay et al., 2018; Lewellen, 2015;

Lyle et al., 2013) and by industry (e.g., Lyle and Wang, 2015). However, cross-sectional

estimation assumes that every firm in the sample has an identical slope coefficient on each

fundamental, whereas industry definitions tend to be exceptionally noisy and can lead

to worse estimates for prediction than simple cross-sectional estimation (e.g., Fairfield

et al., 2009). Given the lack of guidance on how to group firms for estimation, we use the

model directly to form groups. We do this by first estimating the model cross-sectionally

within our training period to obtain an initial estimate of expected returns. We then

form deciles by ranking these initial expected returns and re-estimate the model in our

training period within each of these deciles.

In our estimation, we update predictor variables, 1Pt

, BtPt

, xtPt

,∆NOAi,tPi,t

and ∆FINi,tPi,t

, quar-

terly at the end of the month in which they are reported according to Compustat to

ensure that the fundamentals have been publicly disclosed. If the reporting date is miss-

ing in Compustat, we assume that the information is public three months after the firm’s

fiscal quarter. 1Pt

is one over market value of equity from the CRSP; Bt, xt, ∆NOAt, and

∆FINt, are book value of equity, earnings before extraordinary items, the change in net

operating assets, and the change in financial assets, from the Compustat quarterly files,

respectively. To avoid potential issues with outliers, we cross-sectionally standardize each

of the predictor variables following Hand and Green (2011) by converting each predictor

variable into a percentile rank, dividing by 99, and subtracting 0.5. This ensures each

predictor is mean zero with a stable distribution over time.

To avoid any look-ahead bias, every month before we construct portfolios, we col-

lect five years of historical data to estimate the coefficients A0, A1, A2, A3, A4, A5 by

regressing one-month ahead stock returns on the fundamentals within each of the ten

groups. Because we update our predictor variables quarterly (approximately every three

12

Page 14: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

months) whereas returns are updated monthly, we include three lags in the model.6 We

use the estimated in-sample coefficients with the most recent fundamental variables to

generate expected returns and collect the in-sample residuals from these regressions and

estimate the covariance matrix using the non-linear shrinkage estimator of Ledoit and

Wolf (2017).7 We use these estimated expected returns and covariances to construct

portfolio weights at time t and examine out-of-sample portfolio returns from time t to

t+ 1.

While it is possible to expand the model to incorporate a larger set of variables

to potentially enhance out-of-sample predictability, maximizing predictability is not the

goal of our study. Nonetheless, if a fundamental-based strategy is to offer gains, it

should, at a minimum, be related to future stock returns. To test for predictability

of the model, we conduct (untabulated) out-of-sample predictability tests by regressing

future returns on current estimates of expected returns using the following specification:

Ri,t+1 = a + b × µi,t + εi,t+1. Our estimates of b using the Fama and MacBeth (1973)

approach is a highly significant 0.607 with a standard error of 0.0402, suggesting the

fundamentals model is a strong predictor of future stock returns.

3.3. Estimation of Performance Metrics

Our central research question is whether fundamental analysis when combined with

mean-variance portfolio optimization provides gains to investors. To answer this ques-

tion, we examine several different common measures used to evaluate the out-of-sample

performance of portfolios, such as average returns, return standard deviation, and Sharpe

6To see why we include lagged variables, suppose that a true model has the form yt+1 = xt + εt+1,but we only observe xt with delay (we wait for the accounting numbers to be reported in compustat)and update only every say three periods. In such a case if xt+1 = a + bxt + ξt+1, that is, the periodt + 1 predictor is related to the time t plus unpredictable noise, ξt+1. Thus for an arbitrary timet+ τ + 1 we have yt+τ+1 = a+ bxt+τ + εt+τ+1, but if we only have as a predictor xt, then yt+τ+1|xt =a b

τ−1b−1 + xtb

τ +∑τi=1 b

τ−iξt+1+i. The∑τi=1 b

τ−iξt+1+i term represents a moving average term, whichcan be interpreted as autocorrelation in stock returns, conditional on xt. Thus including lagged responsevariables when the predictor is updated slowly can help correct for this.

7We use the Ledoit and Wolf (2017) estimator because it represents the most recently developedcovariance estimator, dominates traditional estimators and was constructed for implementation in mean-variance portfolio optimization.

13

Page 15: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

and Information ratios. Because we assume that the representative fundamental investor

trades off expected return with expected risk (variance), our main measures used for

performance evaluation are Sharpe (SR) and Information (IR) ratios, where the Sharpe

and Information ratios for portfolio return, are respectively given by:

SR = RP,t+1 − RF√σ2P,t+1 − σ2

RF

, (17)

IR = RP,t+1 − β × Rm,t+1√σ2P,t+1 − β2σ2

m,t+1. (18)

RP,t+1 and σP,t+1 are the out-of-sample mean and standard deviation of the portfolio

return respectively, RF and σRF are the mean and standard deviation of the risk free

rate respectively. Rm,t+1 and σm,t+1 are the mean and standard deviation of the market

portfolio respectively; β is the portfolio’s beta. To test for differences in SR and IR

between two portfolios, we estimate two equations simultaneously, one for each portfolio,

of the form RP,t+1 − RF = aSR + σSRεt+1for SR and Rp,t+1 = aIR + βRm,t+1 + σIRεt+1

for IR, and conduct a nonlinear test of the model parameters. Specifically, to test for

differences in the Sharpe (Information) ratios between portfolio x and y we test the

hypotheses, a(x)SR

σ(x)SR

− a(y)SR

σ(y)SR

= 0 ( a(x)IR

σI(x)SR

− a(y)IR

σ(y)IR

= 0), using a Wald test.8

4. Empirical Results

Our empirical tests are meant to examine the benefits, if any, of combining funda-

mental analysis with portfolio optimization. To do this, we first report key portfolio

performance metrics and characteristics for each of the portfolios (i.e, EW, MV, ER, and

MS portfolios) as well as the differences in Sharpe and Information ratios across port-

folios. Upon presenting these results, we then report the performance of portfolios for

different samples and time periods.

8We also verify the results of the Wald tests using both the likelihood-ratio test and the Lagrangemultiplier test.

14

Page 16: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

4.1. Fundamental Portfolios Performance

Table 1 presents the key findings of our study as the table shows the portfolio perfor-

mance of the EW portfolios and the MV, ER, and MS portfolios using the fundamentals-

based model. For comparison to prior research, we also report the performance of portfo-

lios based on expected returns and covariances constructed from 60 months of historical

returns as opposed to a fundamentals-based model. The portfolios are constructed with

no constraints in terms of shorting stocks or portfolio allocation weights.

Table 1, Panel A reports the mean, volatility (Std.), Sharpe and Information ratios

for each portfolio using either the fundamentals model (FUND), calculated as in equa-

tion (9), or historical returns (HIST). We also report the portfolio weighted average of

characteristics of the variables used in the fundamentals model: firm size (Size), earnings-

to-price (EP), book-to-market (BM), change in net operating assets (∆NOA), and change

in financial assets (∆FIN). For example, for the MS portfolio, BM corresponds to the

time-series average of ∑Ni=1 ωi,t,MS

Bi,tPi,t

. Panels B and C report tests of differences in Sharpe

and Information ratios across portfolios for each model.

Column (1) of Table 1 Panel A reports the results for the EW portfolios, which

disregard cross-sectional differences in means and covariances and provide benchmark

summary statistics of cross-sectional average portfolios over our sample. Columns (2)

through (4) report results for the MV, ER, and MS portfolios based on the fundamentals

model, while columns (5) through (7) report results for the MV, ER, and MS portfolios

based on historical stock returns. Consistent with prior research (e.g., Engle et al.,

2017; Jagannathan and Ma, 2003; Jorion, 1985, 1986), we find that minimum variance

portfolios (MV) offer some performance improvements over naive EW portfolios. This

holds regardless of whether we use a covariance matrix constructed from the fundamentals

(column (2)) or historical returns (column (5)) model. Specifically, the MV portfolios

deliver the lowest volatility of all portfolios leading to higher Sharpe (SR) ratios and

significantly higher Information (IR) ratios.

15

Page 17: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Columns (3) and (6) of Table 1 Panel A show the impact on portfolio performance

of incorporating only information about expected returns (ER portfolios). The ER port-

folios based on the FUND model generate higher realized returns than either the EW

or MV portfolios; however, this comes at the cost of higher stock return volatility and

insignificantly lower Sharpe and Information ratios than the MV portfolios. The ER port-

folios based on historical returns perform very poorly, as they have lower stock returns

and higher volatility than either the EW or MV portfolios, leading to significantly lower

Sharpe and Information ratios. These results highlight that incorporating poor quality

expected returns in optimization can lead to portfolios that under-perform even naive

portfolios.

Columns (4) and (7) show the impact of simultaneously incorporating information

about expected returns and covariances (MS portfolios). The MS portfolios based on

the FUND model, which we refer to as optimal fundamental portfolios, fully exploit

information in expected returns and covariances, generating future stock returns of 3.85%,

the highest future stock returns of all the portfolios. This does come at a cost however,

as it has the highest volatility of 6.732 of all FUND portfolios. Nonetheless, this increase

in volatility does not overwhelm the increase in average returns, as the MS portfolios

generate the highest Sharpe ratio of 0.524 and Information ratio of 0.523. The differences

bertween MS portfolios and MV, ER, and EW portfolios are significant at the one percent

level. There is a general pattern with respect to characteristics of the portfolios such that

MV fundamental portfolios tend to put more weight on larger firms while MS fundamental

portfolios tend put more weight on firms with higher BM, EP and ∆FIN and lower ∆NOA.

The performance of MS portfolios based on historical returns highlights the fragility

of unconstrained mean-variance portfolio optimization when poor quality estimates of

expected returns are used - the portfolios have negative average returns and Sharpe and

Information ratios, and dramatically higher volatility than any other portfolios.

The results in Tables 1 are based on unconstrained optimization, which, by construc-

tion, allows for short positions in stocks. In practice short selling costs can be prohibitive

16

Page 18: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

and even infeasible (Beneish et al., 2015). Table 2 presents the results of portfolio per-

formance after imposing a long-only constraint on each portfolio. The constraint has

the most pronounced effect on the fundamentals-based MS portfolios, which experience a

decrease in average returns and volatility. However, the inferences do not change as every

panel in Table 2 suggests that the fundamentals-based MS portfolios yield the highest

portfolio performance. The MS portfolios earn 1.92% future returns, and yield a Sharpe

ratio of 0.367 and Information ratio of 0.395, significantly higher than the MV, ER, and

EW portfolios. The pattern that MV fundamental portfolios tend to put more weight on

larger firms while MS fundamental portfolios tend put more weight on firms with higher

BM, EP and ∆FIN and lower ∆NOA holds in the long-only portfolios. In addition, con-

sistent with DeMiguel et al. (2009), historical returns-based portfolios offer little to no

benefit to investors. Because portfolios relying only on historical returns are known to

perform poorly and because we also find this result for our sample, we do not report the

results for historical-based portfolios in our remaining tables.

The portfolios in Tables 1 and 2 were either unconstrained or constrained on the

long-side, allowing for potentially very large allocations to a few stocks. To determine

the sensitivity of our results to allocation constraints, Table 3 presents the results for the

fundamentals-based portfolios when the magnitude of weights are constrained to 2.5%.

Long-short portfolios are constrained to between -2.5% and 2.5%, and long-only portfolios

are constrained to between 0% and 2.5%. Each panel in Table 3 suggests that imposing

these constraints tends to improve upon the performance of unconstrained portfolios,

suggesting that our initial results are not driven by extreme allocations.9

4.2. Portfolios Grouped by Size

Hou et al. (2018) find that most return-predictive signals documented in prior stud-

ies do not significantly predict returns when small firms are removed from the sample,

suggesting that most predictive signals are concentrated among smaller potentially illiq-

9We replicate this table using 1%, 3% and 5% constraints and find similar results.

17

Page 19: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

uid firms. Given the importance of stock liquidity for portfolio construction, Table 4

presents the results for investment sets that progressively exclude a larger number of

smaller stocks, such that the portfolios are formed from the largest 1,000 stocks, 500

stocks, 200 stocks, and 100 stocks. While the portfolios in previous analyses exclude

penny stocks, excluding smaller stocks further removes stocks for which investors are

more likely to face liquidity issues and higher transactions costs. The table presents

the performance metrics for optimal fundamental portfolios which incorporate expected

returns from the fundamentals model with either ER, MV, or MS portfolio optimiza-

tion. Like Table 3, we report results here, and in remaining tables, based on portfolios

that are constrained to have weights with magnitude of no more than 2.5%. We present

the performance metrics for non-optimized (EW) fundamental portfolios as a benchmark

for comparison, and report the long-short portfolios as well as the long-only portfolios.

Consistent with the results in our prior tables, we find that the MS fundamental-based

portfolios yield the highest Sharpe ratios, Information ratios, and returns for each size.

Consistent with the “size effect,” returns, Sharpe ratios, and Information ratios decline

as the investment set is further constrained to fewer larger stocks. Nonetheless, the MS

portfolios dominate within each size group even within the most constrained set of 100

largest stocks.

4.3. Fundamental Portfolios Performance Grouped by Expected Returns

One of the most common academic tests of return predictability is to form groups

based on a characteristic of interest and then form portfolios based on these groups and

compare average returns across portfolios. Table 5 presents the performance of portfolios

after progressively shrinking the available set of stocks to the most extreme group of stocks

based on the expected returns from the fundamentals-based model. For the long-short

portfolios, we constrain firms in the top group to have non-negative weights that sum to

one and firms in the bottom groups to have non-positive weights that sum to negative one

such that the resulting long-short portfolio represents a “zero cost” portfolio. Long-only

18

Page 20: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

portfolios are portfolios constructed from those stocks with the highest expected returns.

Consistent with our prior results, Table 5 shows that the Sharpe and Information

ratios for the fundamental portfolios are higher with MS optimization relative to the

other fundamental portfolios within each expected return grouping. However, a curious

result that emerges in Table 5 is that the gains of MS over MV portfolios are smaller when

we exclude stocks based on expected returns. This might seem surprising, but as was

outlined in subsection 2.2.1, when cross-sectional differences in expected returns shrink,

the MS portfolios should come closer to the MV portfolios. Excluding stocks based on

expected returns essentially reduces cross-sectional differences in expected returns, and

the MS and MV portfolios should perform more similarly.

4.4. Fundamental Portfolios Performance Over Time

Our analysis thus far has focused on summary performance measures over the period

from 1981 to 2017. In Table 6, we report the portfolio performance metrics for non-

overlapping 10-year periods (except for the 8 year period 1981-1987) to provide insight

into the performance of portfolios over time. For each portfolio, there is a negative time

trend in average returns, Sharpe ratios, and Information ratios. However, within each

time period, optimized portfolios outperform the naive EW portfolios and MS portfo-

lios consistently outperform all other portfolios. Figures (1) and (2) provide graphical

analyses of differences in conditional Sharpe ratios over time.10 Both plots are broadly

consistent with Table 6 in that, outside of a few months, the Sharpe ratio of the MS port-

folios dominate alternative portfolios, suggesting the relative gains of the MS portfolios

are not driven by a particular time period.

10The conditional Sharpe Ratio of a portfolio at time t is calculated as the ratio of the conditional meanto the conditional standard deviation of the portfolio. The portfolio excess return (defined as portfolioraw return less the risk free rate) series is assumed to follow an AR (1) process with the variance ofthe error term following GARCH(1,1) process. The time series behavior of differences in conditionalInformation ratios are similar and available upon request.

19

Page 21: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

5. Factor Portfolios and Alternative Optimization

In this section, we first examine whether common factor portfolios can explain the

returns of fundamental portfolios. We then examine portfolios constructed using an

alternative optimization approach developed by Brandt et al. (2009).

5.1. Factor Alphas

The number of return predictors documented in the literature has grown to exceed 300

(see for example, Bartram and Grinblatt, 2018; Green et al., 2013, 2017; Harvey et al.,

2016) and, as the number of predictors have grown over time, so has the number of factors

used to explain returns: from one, the market factor, to at least five, the market factor

plus four factors related to firm characteristics (Fama and French, 2015). The Fama and

French (2015) factor models represent returns of portfolios which are constructed from

characteristics that are similar to some of the variables we use in our fundamentals-based

returns model and hence use to form portfolios. There are two natural concerns with this.

First, resultant portfolios from our model may simply mimic some combination of factors

used in the Fama and French models. Second, because more return predictors have been

found with the passage of time, it is possible that the fundamental portfolio returns we

document could be driven by large returns from one or several predictors prior to the

publication date of the predictor. We test this formally by running standard asset pricing

portfolio tests over different time periods following the publication date of fundamentals

and characteristics related to those in our model. Our empirical tests use the following

regression:

Rp,t+1 = α +m∑j=1

βjfj,t+1 + εt+1,

where α is the average return of portfolio that is not explained by the factor(s), fj,t+1,

i.e., the factor alpha. If the factors do not explain the average return of our portfolios,

we expect α to be non-zero.

20

Page 22: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

While factor models may have some conceptual similarities to the fundamentals model

we use, we do not anticipate that they will fully explain our portfolio returns. To see

why, ex ante, it is unclear whether the Fama and French factors can explain our portfolio

returns, recall that the vector of weights of our portfolios are of the form

ω∗ = Σ−1µ

eTΣ−1µ,

where the ith expected return is µi = Ai,0 + Ai,11Pi

+ Ai,2BiPi

+ Ai,3xiPi

+ Ai,4∆NOAi

Pi+

Ai,5∆FINiPi

. For a factor model to explain the average return of the optimized portfolios,

the weights of the factor portfolios would need to roughly align with our portfolio weights

with respect to the underlying fundamental characteristic. However, the Fama and French

factor models represent “zero cost” portfolios with respect to each characteristic. For

example, the book-to-market factor is long high book-to-market stocks and short low

book-to-market stocks and the weights of the book-to-market (or HML) factor portfolio

have a functional form similar to

ωi,hml =

ωi,H ,Bi,tMi,t≥ TH

−ωi,L, Bi,tMi,t≤ TL

0, TL <Bi,tMi,t

< TH

where ωi,H represents a market value weighting for stocks that have a book-to-market

ratio that is above the threshold TH and ωi,L represents a market value weighting for stocks

that have a book-to-market below the threshold TL. Because the Fama and French factor

portfolio weights have a different functional form than our portfolio weights, there is no

ex ante reason that our fundamental portfolios would be explained by standard factor

pricing models.

The results of this analysis is reported in Table 7 where we report α’s for each portfolio

for four different factor models: the CAPM, the Fama and French (1993, 2015) three,

21

Page 23: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

four, and five factor models. We report the α’s over four different time periods. The first

time period represents our full out-of-sample time period from 1981-2017. Our second

time period is 1993-2017, which follows the publication date of Fama and French (1992)

(related to size and book-to-market). Our third is 1996-2017 and represents a period

after publication of Sloan (1996) (related to accruals) and our final is 2003-2017 which is

after publication of Fairfield et al. (2003) (related to growth in operating assets).

As Table 7 shows, there is very little evidence to suggest that any of the portfolios we

test can be replicated by any of the factor models. In fact almost all optimized funda-

mental portfolios generate significant factor alphas, even over the most recent 2003-2017

time period. Moreover, similar to our prior tables, the MS portfolios which incorporate

information about expected returns and covariances have the highest factor alphas in

virtually every specification.

5.2. BSV Portfolios Performance

As an attempt to overcome the difficulty in estimating expected returns and other

return moments within mean-variance optimization, Brandt et al. (2009) propose the

combination of a power utility function with firm characteristics to solve for portfolio

weights via non-linear estimation. Specifically, Brandt et al. (2009) propose a method to

incorporate firm-level characteristics by utilizing the following estimation approach:

maxθ

1t

t−1∑j=0

Rp,j1−γ

1− γ , (19)

s.t. ωi,j = ωi,j + 1Nj

θci,j,

where ωi,j is the weight of a benchmark portfolio at time j, Nj is the number of firms in

the portfolio at time j, θ is a vector of parameters to be estimated, and ci,j a vector of firm

characteristics. Portfolio weights at time t are then given by ωi,t = ωi,t + 1Nθci,t, subject

to ∑Ni=1 ωi,t = 1. Consistent with our prior analyses, we use the equal weighted portfolio

22

Page 24: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

as the benchmark portfolio, and we use two different sets of characteristics in portfolio

construction. We first use our estimate of expected returns as a single characteristic, we

then include all of the characteristics 1Pi,t, Bi,tPi,t

, xi,tPi,t, goi,tPi,t

, gfi,tPi,t as individual variables in

the optimization program. Like Brandt et al. (2009) and Hand and Green (2011) we set

γ = 5 and estimate the parameter θ using equation (19) with an expanding window, with

a minimum of 10 years historical data. The minimum 10 year window changes our out-of-

sample time period to 1991-2017 in this analysis, so we report the portfolio performance

for the EW, MV, ER, MS portfolios as well as the Brandt et al. (2009) (BSV, henceforth)

portfolios for this time period. The results are reported in Table 8. For brevity, we report

the results of long-only portfolios because these portfolios are more representative of what

an investor could actually earn as opposed to long-short portfolios.

Consistent with Brandt et al. (2009) and Hand and Green (2011), the BSV ap-

proach offers benefits to an investor over naive portfolio construction. Using either the

fundamentals-based expected return (BSV1) or all six characteristics (BSV2) results in

portfolios that outperform EW and MV portfolios. However, the ER and MS portfolios

offer performance gains over the BSV approach and, consistent with our prior findings,

the MS portfolios dominate on virtually all dimensions of portfolio performance.

6. Conclusion

Constructing an investment portfolio generally consists of two activities: forming

beliefs about future stock returns and optimally allocating wealth in a portfolio based on

those beliefs. We formalize how fundamental analysis can be mapped directly into beliefs

through expected returns and covariances to construct optimal fundamental portfolios

and provide initial large sample evidence of gains to investors of combining fundamental

analysis and portfolio optimization.

Long-only optimizal fundamental portfolios, which incorporate fundamentals-based

expected returns and covariances and MS optimization, produce CAPM alphas of over

1% per month and 5-factor alphas of over 0.8% per month, with high Sharpe and In-

23

Page 25: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

formation ratios. Gains to investors over naive equal weighted strategies remain when

small capitalization firms are eliminated from the investment space. These gains are also

present in recent decades, well after well-known academic research was published which

highlighted the predictive content of financial ratios.

Our findings provides important contributions to both practice and research on funda-

mental analysis and portfolio optimization. Fundamental analysis is aimed at identifying

stocks that are likely to experience higher or lower future returns, but provides little

insight with respect to creating portfolios. Our study provides an implementable method

of developing portfolios that improve the performance of fundamental analysis. Similarly,

portfolio optimization provides theoretical arguments for optimizing portfolios, but there

is little empirical evidence to date suggesting that it results in portfolio performance pre-

dicted by theory. Our findings suggest that portfolio optimization, when combined with

fundamental analysis, can help investors realize substantial portfolio gains.

24

Page 26: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

References

Bartram, S. M. and M. Grinblatt (2018). Agnostic fundamental analysis works. Journal

of Financial Economics 128 (1), 125–147.

Beneish, M. D., C. M. Lee, and D. C. Nichols (2015). In short supply: Short-sellers and

stock returns. Journal of accounting and economics 60 (2-3), 33–57.

Benjamin, G. and D. L. Dodd (1934). Security analysis. Me Graw Hill Ine, New York.

Bradshaw, M. T., S. A. Richardson, and R. G. Sloan (2006). The relation between corpo-

rate financing activities, analysts’ forecasts and stock returns. Journal of Accounting

and Economics 42 (1-2), 53–85.

Brandt, M. W., P. Santa-clara, and R. Valkanov (2009). Parametric portfolio policies:

Exploiting characteristics. The Review of Financial Studies 22 (9), 3411–3447.

Chattopadhyay, A., M. R. Lyle, and C. C. Wang (2018). Accounting data, market values,

and the cross section of expected returns worldwide. Working Paper .

Christensen, P. O. and G. Feltham (2012). Economics of Accounting: Information in

markets, Volume 1. Springer.

Cooper, M. J., H. Gulen, and M. J. Schill (2008). Asset growth and the cross-section of

stock returns. The Journal of Finance 63 (4), 1609–1651.

DeMiguel, V., L. Garlappi, and R. Uppal (2009, May). Optimal Versus Naive Diver-

sification: How Inefficient is the 1/N Portfolio Strategy? The Review of Financial

Studies 22 (5), 1915–1953.

Engle, R. F., O. Ledoit, and M. Wolf (2017). Large dynamic covariance matrices. Journal

of Business & Economic Statistics, 1–13.

Fairfield, P. M., S. Ramnath, and T. L. Yohn (2009). Do industry-level analyses improve

forecasts of financial performance? Journal of Accounting Research 47 (1), 147–178.

25

Page 27: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Fairfield, P. M., J. S. Whisenant, and T. L. Yohn (2003). Accrued earnings and

growth: Implications for future profitability and market mispricing. The accounting

review 78 (1), 353–371.

Fama, E. F. and K. R. French (1992). The cross-section of expected stock returns. the

Journal of Finance 47 (2), 427–465.

Fama, E. F. and K. R. French (1993). Common risk factors in the returns on stocks and

bonds. Journal of financial economics 33 (1), 3–56.

Fama, E. F. and K. R. French (2015). A five-factor asset pricing model. Journal of

Financial Economics 116 (1), 1 – 22.

Fama, E. F. and J. D. MacBeth (1973). Risk, return, and equilibrium: Empirical tests.

Journal of political economy 81 (3), 607–636.

Frankel, R. and C. M. Lee (1998). Accounting valuation, market expectation, and cross-

sectional stock returns. Journal of Accounting and economics 25 (3), 283–319.

Gebhardt, W. R., C. M. Lee, and B. Swaminathan (2001). Toward an implied cost of

capital. Journal of accounting research 39 (1), 135–176.

Green, J., J. R. Hand, and X. F. Zhang (2013). The supraview of return predictive

signals. Review of Accounting Studies 18 (3), 692–730.

Green, J., J. R. Hand, and X. F. Zhang (2017). The characteristics that provide inde-

pendent information about average us monthly stock returns. The Review of Financial

Studies 30 (12), 4389–4436.

Hand, J. R. and J. Green (2011). The importance of accounting information in portfolio

optimization. Journal of Accounting, Auditing & Finance 26 (1), 1–34.

Harvey, C. R., Y. Liu, and H. Zhu (2016). ... and the cross-section of expected returns.

The Review of Financial Studies 29 (1), 5–68.

26

Page 28: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Hou, K., C. Xue, and L. Zhang (2018). Replicating Anomalies. The Review of Financial

Studies.

Jagannathan, R. and T. Ma (2003). Risk reduction in large portfolios: Why imposing

the wrong constraints helps. The Journal of Finance 58 (4), 1651–1683.

Johannesson, E. and J. A. Ohlson (2019). Explaining returns through valuation. Columbia

Business School Working Paper (17-38).

Jorion, P. (1985). International portfolio diversification with estimation risk. Journal of

Business, 259–278.

Jorion, P. (1986). Bayes-stein estimation for portfolio analysis. Journal of Financial and

Quantitative Analysis 21 (3), 279–292.

Ledoit, O. and M. Wolf (2017). Nonlinear shrinkage of the covariance matrix for portfolio

selection: Markowitz meets goldilocks. The Review of Financial Studies 30 (12), 4349–

4388.

Lee, C. M., J. Myers, and B. Swaminathan (1999). What is the intrinsic value of the

dow? The Journal of Finance 54 (5), 1693–1741.

Lewellen, J. (2015). The cross-section of expected stock returns. Critical Finance Re-

view 4 (1), 1–44.

Lyle, M. R., J. L. Callen, and R. J. Elliott (2013). Dynamic risk, accounting-based

valuation and firm fundamentals. Review of Accounting Studies 18 (4), 899–929.

Lyle, M. R. and C. C. Wang (2015). The cross section of expected holding period returns

and their dynamics: A present value approach. Journal of Financial Economics 116 (3),

505–525.

Markowitz, H. (1952). Portfolio selection. Journal of Finance 7 (1), pp. 77–91.

27

Page 29: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Michaud, R. O. (1989). The markowitz optimization enigma: Is ’optimized’ optimal?

Financial Analysts Journal 45 (1), 31–42.

Sloan, R. G. (1996). Do stock prices fully reflect information in accruals and cash flows

about future earnings? Accounting review, 289–315.

28

Page 30: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Figu

re1:

Shar

peR

atio

Gai

ns:

Long

-Sho

rtF

igur

e1

disp

lays

the

Shar

peR

atio

gain

sfo

rth

elo

ng-s

hort

MS

port

folio

sre

lati

veto

long

-sho

rtE

W,M

V,a

ndE

Rpo

rtfo

lios

for

the

tim

epe

riod

1981

-20

17.

Shar

peR

atio

gain

sar

ede

fined

asth

edi

ffere

nce

inth

eco

ndit

iona

lSha

rpe

rati

oof

the

two

port

folio

sw

here

the

cond

itio

nalS

harp

eR

atio

ofa

port

folio

atti

met

isca

lcul

ated

asth

era

tio

ofth

eco

ndit

iona

lm

ean

toth

eco

ndit

iona

lsta

ndar

dde

viat

ion

ofth

epo

rtfo

lio.

The

port

folio

exce

ssre

turn

(defi

ned

aspo

rtfo

liora

wre

turn

less

the

risk

free

rate

)se

ries

isas

sum

edto

follo

wan

AR

(1)

proc

ess

wit

hth

eva

rian

ceof

the

erro

rte

rmfo

llow

ing

aG

AR

CH

(1,1

)pr

oces

s.T

hetr

end

line

isca

lcul

ated

usin

ga

LOE

SSsm

ooth

er.

19

85

19

90

19

95

20

00

20

05

20

10

20

15

-0.6

-0.4

-0.20

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.81

1.2

MS

-EW

19

85

19

90

19

95

20

00

20

05

20

10

20

15

-0.6

-0.4

-0.20

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.81

1.2

MS

-MV

19

85

19

90

19

95

20

00

20

05

20

10

20

15

Date

-0.6

-0.4

-0.20

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.81

1.2

MS

-ER

Sh

arp

e R

atio G

ain

Tre

nd

29

Page 31: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Figu

re2:

Shar

peR

atio

Gai

ns:

Long

-Onl

yF

igur

e2

disp

lays

mon

thly

Shar

peR

atio

gain

sfo

rth

elo

ng-o

nly

MS

port

folio

sre

lati

veto

long

-onl

yE

W,M

V,a

ndE

Rpo

rtfo

lios

for

the

tim

epe

riod

1981

-201

7.Sh

arpe

Rat

ioga

ins

are

defin

edas

the

diffe

renc

ein

the

cond

itio

nalS

harp

era

tio

ofth

etw

opo

rtfo

lios

whe

reth

eco

ndit

iona

lSha

rpe

Rat

ioof

apo

rtfo

lioat

tim

et

isca

lcul

ated

asth

era

tio

ofth

eco

ndit

iona

lm

ean

toth

eco

ndit

iona

lsta

ndar

dde

viat

ion

ofth

epo

rtfo

lio.

The

port

folio

exce

ssre

turn

(defi

ned

aspo

rtfo

liora

wre

turn

less

the

risk

free

rate

)se

ries

isas

sum

edto

follo

wan

AR

(1)

proc

ess

wit

hth

eva

rian

ceof

the

erro

rte

rmfo

llow

ing

aG

AR

CH

(1,1

)pr

oces

s.T

hetr

end

line

isca

lcul

ated

usin

ga

LOE

SSsm

ooth

er.

19

85

19

90

19

95

20

00

20

05

20

10

20

15

-0.6

-0.4

-0.20

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

MS

-EW

19

85

19

90

19

95

20

00

20

05

20

10

20

15

-0.6

-0.4

-0.20

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

MS

-MV

19

85

19

90

19

95

20

00

20

05

20

10

20

15

Date

-0.6

-0.4

-0.20

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

MS

-ER

30

Page 32: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Tabl

e1:

Port

folio

Perfo

rman

ceTa

ble

1pr

esen

tsm

onth

lypo

rtfo

liope

rfor

man

cem

etri

csan

dfir

mch

arac

teri

stic

sfo

run

cons

trai

ned

EW

,M

V,

ER

,an

dM

Spo

rtfo

lios.

FU

ND

indi

cate

sth

atex

pect

edre

turn

san

dco

vari

ance

sar

ees

tim

ated

from

the

fund

amen

tals

-bas

edm

odel

(FU

ND

)es

tim

ated

follo

win

gSe

ctio

n3.

HIS

Tin

dica

tes

that

expe

cted

retu

rns

and

cova

rian

ces

are

esti

mat

edfr

omhi

stor

ical

stoc

kre

turn

data

(HIS

T).

Pan

elA

repo

rts

key

port

folio

perf

orm

ance

met

rics

and

port

folio

wei

ghte

dch

arac

teri

stic

s.M

ean,

Std.

,SR

,and

IRre

pres

ent

the

out-

of-s

ampl

em

onth

lym

ean,

stan

dard

devi

atio

n,Sh

arpe

Rat

io,

and

Info

rmat

ion

Rat

iore

spec

tive

ly.

The

Shar

peR

atio

isth

esa

mpl

em

ean

port

folio

retu

rnle

ssth

eri

skfr

eera

tedi

vide

dby

the

sam

ple

stan

dard

devi

atio

nof

the

port

folio

retu

rn.

The

Info

rmat

ion

Rat

iois

the

inte

rcep

toft

hem

arke

tmod

eldi

vide

dby

the

ofth

ere

sidu

alfr

omth

em

arke

tmod

el.

The

char

acte

rist

ics

C=S

ize,

EP,B

M,∆

NO

A,∆

FIN

are

give

nby

∑ iωi×Ci

whe

reωi

repr

esen

tpo

rtfo

liow

eigh

ts.

Size

ism

arke

tva

lue

ofeq

uity

,EP

isea

rnin

gs-t

o-pr

ice,

BM

isth

ebo

ok-t

o-m

arke

tra

tio,

∆N

OA

isth

ech

ange

inne

top

erat

ing

asse

ts,a

nd∆

FIN

isth

ech

ange

infin

anci

alas

sets

.P

anel

sB

and

Cre

port

sdi

ffere

nces

inSR

and

IRpo

rtfo

liope

rfor

man

cem

etri

csfr

omin

corp

orat

ing

info

rmat

ion

inco

vari

ance

s(d

enot

edΣ

)an

dm

eans

(den

oted

µ)

inpo

rtfo

lioco

nstr

ucti

on.I ∅

indi

cate

sno

info

rmat

ion

and

corr

espo

nds

toth

eE

Wpo

rtfo

lio.I Σ

(Iµ

)in

dica

tes

only

cova

rian

ce(m

ean)

info

rmat

ion

and

corr

espo

nds

toth

eM

V(E

R)

port

folio

.I µ,Σ

indi

cate

sth

atbo

thm

ean

and

cova

rian

cein

form

atio

nis

used

inpo

rtfo

lioco

nstr

ucti

onan

dco

rres

pond

sto

the

MS

port

folio

.Si

gnifi

canc

ele

vels

of1%

,5%

,and

10%

are

deno

ted

by,*

**,*

*,an

d*,

resp

ecti

vely

and

are

base

don

atw

o-ta

iled

Wal

dte

st.

(a)

Pane

lA:P

ortf

olio

Sum

mar

ySt

atist

ics

Mod

el:

NO

NE

FUN

DH

IST

Port

folio

:EW

MV

ERM

SM

VER

MS

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

Mea

n1.

275

1.14

81.

763

3.85

01.

156

0.93

8-1

.584

Std.

5.31

02.

984

5.60

56.

732

3.05

76.

133

22.3

14SR

0.17

60.

271

0.25

30.

524

0.26

70.

098

-0.0

86IR

0.07

50.

314

0.22

70.

523

0.30

8-0

.039

-0.0

85

Size

(/10

00)

2.60

55.

248

1.92

12.

835

5.19

32.

905

10.4

42EP

(x10

0)0.

156

1.24

80.

995

5.69

81.

238

1.64

819

.225

BM

0.73

10.

752

0.85

91.

134

0.74

40.

441

-2.6

41∆

NO

A(x

100)

0.41

20.

900

-1.9

15-1

0.98

70.

887

2.48

123

.602

∆FI

N(x

100)

0.40

40.

668

3.21

613

.504

0.66

81.

169

9.51

7

31

Page 33: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Tabl

e1:

Port

folio

Perfo

rman

ce,C

ontin

ued

(b)

Pane

lB:F

unda

men

tals-

Bas

edPo

rtfo

lioPe

rfor

man

ceD

iffer

ence

s

Mod

el:

FUN

D

Incr

emen

talI

nfor

mat

ion

Use

d:I Σ−I ∅

I µ−I ∅

I µ−I Σ

I µ,Σ−I Σ

I µ,Σ−I µ

I µ,Σ−I ∅

Port

folio

:M

V-E

WER

-EW

ER-M

VM

S-M

VM

S-ER

MS-

EW

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

SR0.

095

0.07

8-0

.018

0.25

4***

0.27

2***

0.34

9***

IR0.

239

***

0.15

2**

-0.0

870.

209*

**0.

296*

**0.

448*

**

(c)

Pane

lC:H

istor

ical

Ret

urns

-Bas

edPo

rtfo

lioPe

rfor

man

ceD

iffer

ence

s

Mod

el:

HIS

T

Incr

emen

talI

nfor

mat

ion

Use

d:I Σ−I ∅

I µ−I ∅

I µ−I Σ

I µ,Σ−I Σ

I µ,Σ−I µ

I µ,Σ−I ∅

Port

folio

:M

V-E

WER

-EW

ER-M

VM

S-M

VM

S-ER

MS-

EW

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

SR0.

091

-0.0

78-0

.169

**-0

.354

***

-0.1

84**

*-0

.262

***

IR0.

233*

**-0

.114

*-0

.347

***

-0.3

93**

*-0

.046

-0.1

60**

32

Page 34: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Tabl

e2:

Long

Onl

yPo

rtfo

lioPe

rform

ance

Tabl

e2

pres

ents

mon

thly

port

folio

perf

orm

ance

met

rics

and

firm

char

acte

rist

ics

for

EW

,M

V,

ER

,an

dM

Spo

rtfo

lios

cons

trai

ned

such

that

all

port

folio

wei

ghts

are

non-

nega

tive

.F

UN

Din

dica

tes

that

expe

cted

retu

rns

and

cova

rian

ces

are

esti

mat

edfr

omth

efu

ndam

enta

ls-b

ased

mod

el(F

UN

D)

esti

mat

edfo

llow

ing

Sect

ion

3.H

IST

indi

cate

sth

atex

pect

edre

turn

san

dco

vari

ance

sar

ees

tim

ated

from

hist

oric

alst

ock

retu

rnda

ta(H

IST

).P

anel

Are

port

ske

ypo

rtfo

liope

rfor

man

cem

etri

csan

dpo

rtfo

liow

eigh

ted

char

acte

rist

ics.

Mea

n,St

d.,

SR,a

ndIR

repr

esen

tth

eou

t-of

-sam

ple

mon

thly

mea

n,st

anda

rdde

viat

ion,

Shar

peR

atio

,and

Info

rmat

ion

Rat

iore

spec

tive

ly.

The

Shar

peR

atio

isth

esa

mpl

em

ean

port

folio

retu

rnle

ssth

eri

skfr

eera

tedi

vide

dby

the

sam

ple

stan

dard

devi

atio

nof

the

port

folio

retu

rn.

The

Info

rmat

ion

Rat

iois

the

inte

rcep

tof

the

mar

ket

mod

eldi

vide

dby

the

ofth

ere

sidu

alfr

omth

em

arke

tm

odel

.T

hech

arac

teri

stic

sC

=S

ize,

EP,B

M,∆

NO

A,∆

FIN

are

give

nby

∑ iωi×Ci

whe

reωi

repr

esen

tpo

rtfo

liow

eigh

ts.

Size

ism

arke

tva

lue

ofeq

uity

,EP

isea

rnin

gs-t

o-pr

ice,

BM

isth

ebo

ok-t

o-m

arke

tra

tio,

∆N

OA

isth

ech

ange

inne

top

erat

ing

asse

ts,a

nd∆

FIN

isth

ech

ange

infin

anci

alas

sets

.P

anel

sB

and

Cre

port

sdi

ffere

nces

inSR

and

IRpo

rtfo

liope

rfor

man

cem

etri

csfr

omin

corp

orat

ing

info

rmat

ion

inco

vari

ance

s(d

enot

edΣ

)an

dm

eans

(den

oted

µ)

inpo

rtfo

lioco

nstr

ucti

on.I ∅

indi

cate

sno

info

rmat

ion

and

corr

espo

nds

toth

eE

Wpo

rtfo

lio.I Σ

(Iµ

)in

dica

tes

only

cova

rian

ce(m

ean)

info

rmat

ion

and

corr

espo

nds

toth

eM

V(E

R)

port

folio

.I µ,Σ

indi

cate

sth

atbo

thm

ean

and

cova

rian

cein

form

atio

nis

used

inpo

rtfo

lioco

nstr

ucti

onan

dco

rres

pond

sto

the

MS

port

folio

.Si

gnifi

canc

ele

vels

of1%

,5%

,and

10%

are

deno

ted

by,*

**,*

*,an

d*,

resp

ecti

vely

and

are

base

don

atw

o-ta

iled

Wal

dte

st.

(a)

Pane

lA:P

ortf

olio

Sum

mar

ySt

atist

ics

Mod

el:

NO

NE

FUN

DH

IST

Port

folio

:EW

MV

ERM

SM

VER

MS

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

Mea

n1.

275

1.01

11.

745

1.92

01.

021

1.16

60.

953

Std.

5.31

03.

376

5.63

84.

307

3.49

05.

781

4.48

8SR

0.17

60.

198

0.24

90.

367

0.19

50.

143

0.13

6IR

0.07

50.

190

0.21

80.

395

0.17

9-0

.009

0.04

9

Size

(/10

00)

2.60

55.

126

2.04

22.

197

4.98

12.

674

3.56

1EP

(x10

0)0.

156

0.55

40.

475

1.38

70.

519

0.87

01.

119

BM

0.73

10.

769

0.82

31.

052

0.74

60.

540

0.45

2∆

NO

A(x

100)

0.41

20.

680

-1.2

36-3

.706

0.60

41.

502

1.66

9∆

FIN

(x10

0)0.

404

0.57

21.

947

5.10

20.

552

0.84

01.

113

33

Page 35: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Tabl

e2:

Long

Onl

yPo

rtfo

lioPe

rform

ance

,Con

tinue

d

(b)

Pane

lB:F

unda

men

tals-

Bas

edPo

rtfo

lioPe

rfor

man

ceD

iffer

ence

s

Mod

el:

FUN

D

Incr

emen

talI

nfor

mat

ion

Use

d:I Σ−I ∅

I µ−I ∅

I µ−I Σ

I µ,Σ−I Σ

I µ,Σ−I µ

I µ,Σ−I ∅

Port

folio

:M

V-E

WER

-EW

ER-M

VM

S-M

VM

S-ER

MS-

EW

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

SR0.

023

0.07

30.

051

0.16

8**

0.11

8*0.

191*

**IR

0.11

5*0.

143*

*0.

028

0.20

5***

0.17

7**

0.32

0***

(c)

Pane

lC:H

istor

ical

Ret

urns

-Bas

edPo

rtfo

lioPe

rfor

man

ceD

iffer

ence

s

Mod

el:

HIS

T

Incr

emen

talI

nfor

mat

ion

Use

d:I Σ−I ∅

I µ−I ∅

I µ−I Σ

I µ,Σ−I Σ

I µ,Σ−I µ

I µ,Σ−I ∅

Port

folio

:M

V-E

WER

-EW

ER-M

VM

S-M

VM

S-ER

MS-

EW

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

SR0.

019

-0.0

33-0

.052

-0.0

59-0

.006

-0.0

39IR

0.10

4-0

.084

-0.1

88**

*-0

.130

*0.

058

-0.0

26

34

Page 36: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Tabl

e3:

Con

stra

ined

Fund

amen

talP

ortfo

lioPe

rform

ance

Tabl

e3

pres

ents

mon

thly

fund

amen

talp

ortf

olio

perf

orm

ance

met

rics

and

firm

char

acte

rist

ics

for

EW

,MV

,ER

,and

MS

port

folio

sw

ith

wei

ghts

cons

trai

ned

tobe

twee

n-2

.5%

and

2.5%

(or

0%an

d2.

5%fo

rlo

ng-o

nly)

.E

xpec

ted

retu

rns

and

cova

rian

ces

are

esti

mat

edfr

omth

efu

ndam

enta

ls-b

ased

mod

el(F

UN

D)

esti

mat

edfo

llow

ing

Sect

ion

3.P

anel

Are

port

ske

ypo

rtfo

liope

rfor

man

cem

etri

csan

dpo

rtfo

liow

eigh

ted

char

acte

rist

ics.

Mea

n,St

d.,S

R,a

ndIR

repr

esen

tth

eou

t-of

-sam

ple

mon

thly

mea

n,st

anda

rdde

viat

ion,

Shar

peR

atio

,and

Info

rmat

ion

Rat

iore

spec

tive

ly.

The

Shar

peR

atio

isth

esa

mpl

em

ean

port

folio

retu

rnle

ssth

eri

skfr

eera

tedi

vide

dby

the

sam

ple

stan

dard

devi

atio

nof

the

port

folio

retu

rn.

The

Info

rmat

ion

Rat

iois

the

inte

rcep

tof

the

mar

ket

mod

eldi

vide

dby

the

ofth

ere

sidu

alfr

omth

em

arke

tm

odel

.T

hech

arac

teri

stic

sC

=S

ize,

EP,B

M,∆

NO

A,∆

FIN

are

give

nby

∑ iωi×Ci

whe

reωi

repr

esen

tpo

rtfo

liow

eigh

ts.

Size

ism

arke

tva

lue

ofeq

uity

,EP

isea

rnin

gs-t

o-pr

ice,

BM

isth

ebo

ok-t

o-m

arke

tra

tio,

∆N

OA

isth

ech

ange

inne

top

erat

ing

asse

ts,

and

∆F

INis

the

chan

gein

finan

cial

asse

ts.

Pan

els

Ban

dC

repo

rts

diffe

renc

esin

SRan

dIR

port

folio

perf

orm

ance

met

rics

from

inco

rpor

atin

gin

form

atio

nin

cova

rian

ces

(den

oted

Σ)

and

mea

ns(d

enot

edµ

)in

port

folio

cons

truc

tion

.I ∅

indi

cate

sno

info

rmat

ion

and

corr

espo

nds

toth

eE

Wpo

rtfo

lio.I Σ

(Iµ

)in

dica

tes

only

cova

rian

ce(m

ean)

info

rmat

ion

and

corr

espo

nds

toth

eM

V(E

R)

port

folio

.I µ,Σ

indi

cate

sth

atbo

thm

ean

and

cova

rian

cein

form

atio

nis

used

inpo

rtfo

lioco

nstr

ucti

onan

dco

rres

pond

sto

the

MS

port

folio

.Si

gnifi

canc

ele

vels

of1%

,5%

,and

10%

are

deno

ted

by,*

**,*

*,an

d*,

resp

ecti

vely

and

are

base

don

atw

o-ta

iled

Wal

dte

st.

(a)

Pane

lA:P

ortf

olio

Sum

mar

ySt

atist

ics

Mod

el:

NO

NE

Long

-Sho

rtLo

ng-O

nly

Port

folio

:EW

MV

ERM

SM

VER

MS

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

Mea

n1.

275

1.14

81.

773

3.68

11.

017

1.74

61.

876

Std.

5.31

02.

984

5.61

54.

951

3.37

35.

639

4.11

4SR

0.17

60.

271

0.25

50.

684

0.20

00.

249

0.37

3IR

0.07

50.

314

0.23

10.

717

0.19

30.

218

0.42

0

Size

(/10

00)

2.60

55.

249

2.01

32.

836

5.15

42.

042

2.47

7EP

(x10

0)0.

156

1.24

80.

710

6.05

00.

572

0.47

51.

242

BM

0.73

10.

752

0.83

21.

133

0.76

50.

823

1.01

1∆

NO

A(x

100)

0.41

20.

900

-1.5

28-1

1.14

90.

728

-1.2

36-3

.330

∆FI

N(x

100)

0.40

40.

669

2.46

914

.183

0.55

31.

947

4.36

0

35

Page 37: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Tabl

e3:

Con

stra

ined

Fund

amen

talP

ortfo

lioPe

rform

ance

,Con

tinue

d

(b)

Pane

lB:L

ong-

Shor

tPo

rtfo

lioPe

rfor

man

ceD

iffer

ence

s

Long

-Sho

rt

Incr

emen

talI

nfor

mat

ion

Use

d:I Σ−I ∅

I µ−I ∅

I µ−I Σ

I µ,Σ−I Σ

I µ,Σ−I µ

I µ,Σ−I ∅

Port

folio

:M

V-E

WER

-EW

ER-M

VM

S-M

VM

S-ER

MS-

EW

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

SR0.

023

0.07

30.

051

0.16

8**

0.11

8*0.

191*

**IR

0.11

5*0.

143*

*0.

028

0.20

5***

0.17

7**

0.32

0***

(c)

Pane

lC:L

ong-

Onl

yPo

rtfo

lioPe

rfor

man

ceD

iffer

ence

s

Long

-Onl

y

Incr

emen

talI

nfor

mat

ion

Use

d:I Σ−I ∅

I µ−I ∅

I µ−I Σ

I µ,Σ−I Σ

I µ,Σ−I µ

I µ,Σ−I ∅

Port

folio

:M

V-E

WER

-EW

ER-M

VM

S-M

VM

S-ER

MS-

EW

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

SR0.

025

0.07

40.

049

0.17

3**

0.12

4*0.

198*

**IR

0.11

8*0.

143*

*0.

025

0.22

8***

0.20

2***

0.34

6***

36

Page 38: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Tabl

e4:

Port

folio

Perfo

rman

ceC

ondi

tiona

lon

Size

Tabl

e4

pres

ents

mon

thly

port

folio

perf

orm

ance

met

rics

for

EW

,MV

,ER

,and

MS

port

folio

sw

ith

wei

ghts

cons

trai

ned

tobe

twee

n-2

.5%

and

2.5%

(or

0%an

d2.

5%fo

rlo

ng-o

nly)

.E

xpec

ted

retu

rns

and

cova

rian

ces

are

esti

mat

edfr

omth

efu

ndam

enta

ls-b

ased

mod

el(F

UN

D)

esti

mat

edfo

llow

ing

Sect

ion

3.M

ean,

Std.

,SR

,an

dIR

repr

esen

tth

eou

t-of

-sam

ple

mon

thly

mea

n,st

anda

rdde

viat

ion,

Shar

peR

atio

,an

dIn

form

atio

nR

atio

resp

ecti

vely

.T

heSh

arpe

Rat

iois

the

sam

ple

mea

npo

rtfo

liore

turn

less

the

risk

free

rate

divi

ded

byth

esa

mpl

est

anda

rdde

viat

ion

ofth

epo

rtfo

liore

turn

.T

heIn

form

atio

nR

atio

isth

ein

terc

ept

ofth

em

arke

tm

odel

divi

ded

byth

eof

the

resi

dual

from

the

mar

ket

mod

el.

Top

Nre

pres

ents

port

folio

sco

nstr

ucte

dfr

omth

eN

larg

est

firm

sin

the

econ

omy

atea

chpo

rtfo

liofo

rmat

ion

date

.

Long

-Sho

rtLo

ngO

nly

Port

folio

:EW

MV

ERM

SM

VER

MS

Size

Gro

up(1

)(2

)(3

)(4

)(5

)(6

)(7

)

Top

1,00

0

Mea

n1.

192

1.08

21.

415

2.90

11.

118

1.42

31.

586

Std.

5.14

83.

045

5.38

74.

399

3.30

25.

399

3.84

8SR

0.16

50.

245

0.20

00.

592

0.23

60.

201

0.32

5IR

0.04

20.

264

0.12

90.

407

0.26

40.

129

0.40

7

Top

500

Mea

n1.

137

1.10

01.

285

2.18

91.

140

1.29

01.

458

Std.

4.83

83.

194

5.02

93.

978

3.42

65.

029

3.79

1SR

0.16

50.

239

0.18

80.

471

0.23

40.

189

0.29

6IR

0.04

40.

256

0.11

20.

525

0.26

10.

117

0.38

4

Top

200

Mea

n1.

085

1.07

31.

184

1.57

61.

088

1.18

71.

269

Std.

4.54

23.

543

4.67

54.

059

3.55

14.

668

3.85

2SR

0.16

40.

208

0.18

00.

306

0.21

10.

181

0.24

1IR

0.05

80.

195

0.10

80.

316

0.21

30.

119

0.26

6

Top

100

Mea

n1.

068

1.03

11.

156

1.24

81.

078

1.15

61.

189

Std.

4.35

53.

652

4.41

53.

816

3.65

04.

423

3.84

1SR

0.16

70.

190

0.18

50.

238

0.20

30.

184

0.22

1IR

0.08

60.

162

0.14

30.

241

0.19

40.

148

0.23

6

37

Page 39: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Tabl

e5:

Port

folio

Perfo

rman

ceC

ondi

tiona

lon

Expe

cted

Ret

urns

Tabl

e5

pres

ents

mon

thly

fund

amen

tal

port

folio

perf

orm

ance

met

rics

for

EW

,M

V,

ER

,an

dM

Spo

rtfo

lios

wit

hw

eigh

tsco

nstr

aine

dto

betw

een

-2.5

%an

d2.

5%(o

r0%

and

2.5%

for

long

-onl

y).

Exp

ecte

dre

turn

san

dco

vari

ance

sar

ees

tim

ated

from

the

fund

amen

tals

-bas

edm

odel

(FU

ND

)es

tim

ated

follo

win

gSe

ctio

n3.

Mea

n,St

d.,

SR,

and

IRre

pres

ent

the

out-

of-s

ampl

em

onth

lym

ean,

stan

dard

devi

atio

n,Sh

arpe

Rat

io,

and

Info

rmat

ion

Rat

iore

spec

tive

ly.

The

Shar

peR

atio

isth

esa

mpl

em

ean

port

folio

retu

rnle

ssth

eri

skfr

eera

tedi

vide

dby

the

sam

ple

stan

dard

devi

atio

nof

the

port

folio

retu

rn.

The

Info

rmat

ion

Rat

iois

the

inte

rcep

tof

the

mar

ket

mod

eldi

vide

dby

the

ofth

ere

sidu

alfr

omth

em

arke

tm

odel

.To

p(B

otto

m)

Nre

pres

ents

port

folio

sco

nstr

ucte

dfr

omth

eN

firm

sin

the

econ

omy

wit

hth

ehi

ghes

t(l

owes

t)ex

pect

edre

turn

sat

each

port

folio

form

atio

nda

te.

Long

-Sho

rtLo

ng-O

nly

Sam

ple:

Top

Min

usB

otto

mTo

pO

nly

Port

folio

:EW

MV

ERM

SEW

MV

ERM

S

Expe

cted

Ret

urn

Gro

up(1

)(2

)(3

)(4

)(5

)(6

)(7

)(8

)

Top/

Bot

tom

500

Mea

n1.

455

1.27

11.

966

1.86

72.

047

1.72

62.

215

2.16

3St

d.2.

415

1.61

22.

941

2.08

96.

081

4.11

96.

225

4.49

0SR

0.46

30.

581

0.55

60.

740

0.28

00.

336

0.30

10.

406

IR0.

572

0.79

00.

638

0.89

00.

257

0.36

80.

287

0.44

8

Top/

Bot

tom

200

Mea

n2.

314

2.14

02.

554

2.47

52.

601

2.36

62.

695

2.61

5St

d.3.

447

2.75

03.

671

2.99

76.

676

4.88

26.

731

5.07

7SR

0.57

60.

661

0.60

80.

720

0.33

80.

415

0.35

00.

447

IR0.

642

0.76

40.

668

0.81

10.

333

0.44

80.

349

0.48

7

Top/

Bot

tom

100

Mea

n2.

876

2.71

73.

025

2.91

42.

986

2.80

43.

045

2.85

8St

d.4.

300

3.48

24.

415

3.70

66.

964

5.54

87.

002

5.64

9SR

0.59

40.

690

0.61

30.

703

0.38

00.

444

0.38

60.

445

IR0.

645

0.76

40.

662

0.77

00.

387

0.47

50.

396

0.47

6

Top/

Bot

tom

Dec

ile

Mea

n2.

360

2.17

02.

599

2.52

12.

619

2.35

22.

716

2.59

3St

d.3.

483

2.79

33.

706

3.05

06.

723

4.91

56.

774

5.09

7SR

0.58

50.

664

0.61

50.

725

0.33

90.

409

0.35

10.

441

IR0.

645

0.75

80.

672

0.80

70.

333

0.44

10.

350

0.48

1

38

Page 40: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Tabl

e6:

Port

folio

Perfo

rman

ceO

ver

Tim

eTa

ble

6pr

esen

tsm

onth

lyfu

ndam

enta

lpo

rtfo

liope

rfor

man

cem

etri

csfo

rE

W,

MV

,E

R,

and

MS

port

folio

sw

ith

wei

ghts

cons

trai

ned

tobe

twee

n-2

.5%

and

2.5%

(or

0%an

d2.

5%fo

rlo

ng-o

nly)

.E

xpec

ted

retu

rns

and

cova

rian

ces

are

esti

mat

edfr

omth

efu

ndam

enta

ls-b

ased

mod

el(F

UN

D)

esti

mat

edfo

llow

ing

Sect

ion

3.M

ean,

Std.

,SR

,an

dIR

repr

esen

tth

eou

t-of

-sam

ple

mon

thly

mea

n,st

anda

rdde

viat

ion,

Shar

peR

atio

,an

dIn

form

atio

nR

atio

resp

ecti

vely

.T

heSh

arpe

Rat

iois

the

sam

ple

mea

npo

rtfo

liore

turn

less

the

risk

free

rate

divi

ded

byth

esa

mpl

est

anda

rdde

viat

ion

ofth

epo

rtfo

liore

turn

.T

heIn

form

atio

nR

atio

isth

ein

terc

ept

ofth

em

arke

tm

odel

divi

ded

byth

eof

the

resi

dual

from

the

mar

ket

mod

el.

Long

-Sho

rtLo

ng-O

nly

Port

folio

:EW

MV

ERM

SEW

MV

ERM

S

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

1981

-198

7

Mea

n1.

478

1.93

02.

074

6.26

51.

478

1.58

92.

018

2.53

6St

d.5.

846

3.71

56.

089

6.29

45.

846

4.18

76.

065

4.89

1SR

0.13

00.

325

0.22

20.

879

0.13

00.

209

0.21

40.

371

IR0.

065

0.57

90.

337

1.00

80.

065

0.35

80.

312

0.60

7

1988

-199

7

Mea

n1.

388

1.23

12.

120

4.88

61.

388

0.97

72.

005

2.08

3St

d.3.

957

2.13

44.

171

3.66

43.

957

2.62

04.

132

2.98

0SR

0.23

80.

363

0.40

01.

217

0.23

80.

200

0.37

60.

542

IR0.

045

0.42

30.

310

1.27

70.

045

0.17

60.

273

0.57

5

1998

-200

7

Mea

n1.

207

0.88

81.

792

2.72

41.

207

0.85

61.

727

1.69

4St

d.5.

625

2.98

66.

187

4.08

45.

625

3.03

36.

170

3.70

1SR

0.16

30.

199

0.24

20.

591

0.16

30.

185

0.23

20.

377

IR0.

205

0.28

40.

324

0.70

30.

205

0.27

00.

308

0.49

1

2008

-201

7

Mea

n1.

089

0.77

91.

198

1.62

41.

089

0.81

61.

315

1.39

0St

d.5.

834

3.08

05.

968

4.72

85.

834

3.72

36.

127

4.82

2SR

0.18

20.

245

0.19

70.

338

0.18

20.

213

0.21

10.

283

IR-0

.015

0.14

90.

030

0.28

0-0

.015

0.08

00.

066

0.21

3

39

Page 41: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Tabl

e7:

Port

folio

Perfo

rman

ceC

ontr

ollin

gfo

rT

ime

and

Cha

ract

erist

ic-B

ased

Fact

ors

Tabl

e7

pres

ents

mon

thly

fund

amen

talp

ortf

olio

perf

orm

ance

met

rics

for

EW

,MV

,ER

,and

MS

port

folio

sw

ith

wei

ghts

cons

trai

ned

tobe

twee

n-2

.5%

and

2.5%

(or

0%an

d2.

5%fo

rlo

ng-o

nly)

.E

xpec

ted

retu

rns

and

cova

rian

ces

are

esti

mat

edfr

omth

efu

ndam

enta

ls-b

ased

mod

el(F

UN

D)

esti

mat

edfo

llow

ing

Sect

ion

3.αCAPM

repr

esen

tsth

eC

AP

Mal

pha,αFF

3,

αFF

4,a

ndαFF

5,r

espe

ctiv

ely

repr

esen

tth

eFa

ma

and

Fren

chth

ree,

four

,and

five

fact

oral

pha’

s.Si

gnifi

canc

ele

vels

of1%

,5%

,and

10%

are

deno

ted

by,*

**,*

*,an

d*,

resp

ecti

vely

and

are

base

don

robu

stst

anda

rder

rors

.

Long

-Sho

rtLo

ng-O

nly

Port

folio

:EW

MV

ERM

SM

VER

MS

Publ

icat

ion

Post

Publ

icat

ion

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

1981

-201

7

αCAPM

0.21

1*0.

480*

**0.

686*

**3.

006*

**0.

273*

*0.

654*

**1.

074*

**αFF

30.

145*

*0.

377*

**0.

629*

**2.

918*

**0.

174*

0.58

8***

0.96

2***

αFF

40.

276*

**0.

320*

**0.

749*

**2.

917*

**0.

165*

0.75

1***

1.02

6***

αFF

50.

129*

0.23

7**

0.64

2***

2.87

7***

0.05

90.

603*

**0.

888*

**

Size

/BM

1993

-201

7

αCAPM

0.25

2*0.

470*

**0.

637*

**1.

902*

**0.

391*

**0.

640*

**1.

081*

**αFF

30.

167*

0.40

0***

0.55

9***

1.83

2***

0.31

1***

0.55

5***

0.98

1***

αFF

40.

305*

**0.

356*

**0.

680*

**1.

855*

**0.

320*

**0.

724*

**1.

060*

**αFF

50.

158

0.25

0**

0.60

0***

1.82

0***

0.20

3*0.

591*

**0.

943*

**

Acc

rual

s19

96-2

017

αCAPM

0.28

2*0.

469*

**0.

637*

**1.

827*

**0.

368*

**0.

646*

**1.

031*

**αFF

30.

164*

0.39

8***

0.52

4***

1.74

7***

0.27

9**

0.52

5***

0.91

8***

αFF

40.

288*

**0.

357*

*0.

632*

**1.

769*

**0.

293*

*0.

678*

**0.

994*

**αFF

50.

154

0.22

0*0.

570*

**1.

734*

**0.

150

0.56

3***

0.86

5***

Net

Ass

etG

row

th20

03-2

017

αCAPM

0.08

00.

409*

**0.

273

1.45

1***

0.21

7*0.

322*

0.65

8***

αFF

30.

091

0.40

0***

0.28

6**

1.46

8***

0.21

6*0.

339*

**0.

669*

**αFF

40.

129

0.36

1**

0.30

2**

1.44

3***

0.20

6*0.

385*

**0.

690*

**αFF

50.

129

0.38

3***

0.38

5***

1.55

2***

0.22

0*0.

409*

**0.

696*

**

40

Page 42: Optimal Fundamental Investing · School of Management, Fox School of Business, and Stanford Graduate School of Business. A special thanks to Rishabh Aggarwal, who provided invaluable

Tabl

e8:

Alte

rnat

ive

Port

folio

Opt

imiz

atio

nTa

ble

8pr

esen

tsm

onth

lypo

rtfo

liope

rfor

man

cem

etri

csov

erth

eti

me

peri

od19

91-2

017.

EW

isan

equa

lwei

ghte

dpo

rtfo

lio.

BSV

1an

dB

SV2

corr

espo

nds

topo

rtfo

lios

cons

truc

ted

usin

gth

eB

rand

tet

al.(

2009

)met

hodo

logy

whe

reB

SV1

uses

expe

cted

retu

rns

from

the

fund

amen

tals

-bas

edm

odel

(FU

ND

)es

tim

ated

follo

win

gSe

ctio

n3

asth

ech

arac

teri

stic

and

BSV

2us

esal

lsi

xth

epr

edic

tors

inth

efu

ndam

enta

ls-b

ased

mod

el,

1 Pt,Bt

Pt

,xtPt,∆NOAi,t

Pi,t

and

∆FINi,t

Pi,t

,as

char

acte

rist

ics.

For

port

folio

s,M

V,

ER

,an

dM

Sex

pect

edre

turn

san

dco

vari

ance

sar

ees

tim

ated

from

the

fund

amen

tals

-bas

edm

odel

(FU

ND

)es

tim

ated

follo

win

gSe

ctio

n3.

Mea

n,St

d.,S

R,a

ndIR

repr

esen

tth

eou

t-of

-sam

ple

mon

thly

mea

n,st

anda

rdde

viat

ion,

Shar

peR

atio

,and

Info

rmat

ion

Rat

iore

spec

tive

ly.

The

Shar

peR

atio

isth

esa

mpl

em

ean

port

folio

retu

rnle

ssth

eri

skfr

eera

tedi

vide

dby

the

sam

ple

stan

dard

devi

atio

nof

the

port

folio

retu

rn.

The

Info

rmat

ion

Rat

iois

the

inte

rcep

tof

the

mar

ket

mod

eldi

vide

dby

the

ofth

ere

sidu

alfr

omth

em

arke

tm

odel

.αCAPM

repr

esen

tsth

eC

AP

Mal

pha,αFF

3,

αFF

4,a

ndαFF

5,r

espe

ctiv

ely

repr

esen

tth

eFa

ma

and

Fren

chth

ree,

four

,and

five

fact

oral

pha’

s.Si

gnifi

canc

ele

vels

of1%

,5%

,and

10%

are

deno

ted

by,*

**,*

*,an

d*,

resp

ecti

vely

and

are

base

don

robu

stst

anda

rder

rors

.

Port

folio

:EW

BSV

1B

SV2

MV

ERM

S

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

Mea

n1.

285

1.54

61.

586

0.99

91.

731

1.86

1St

d.5.

262

4.89

05.

442

3.20

85.

626

4.19

3SR

0.20

40.

273

0.25

20.

245

0.27

00.

393

IR0.

101

0.24

50.

192

0.21

70.

220

0.39

6

αCAPM

0.28

4*0.

599*

**0.

572*

**0.

373*

**0.

699*

**1.

163*

**αFF

30.

156*

0.44

8***

0.43

9***

0.26

0**

0.56

6***

1.01

9***

αFF

40.

301*

**0.

559*

**0.

585*

**0.

280*

**0.

744*

**1.

112*

**αFF

50.

156*

0.36

2***

0.46

8***

0.17

8*0.

610*

**1.

013*

**

41


Recommended