+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Partial fiscal decentralization and demand responsiveness of the local public sector: Theory and...

Partial fiscal decentralization and demand responsiveness of the local public sector: Theory and...

Date post: 30-Dec-2016
Category:
Upload: jorn
View: 213 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
11
Partial fiscal decentralization and demand responsiveness of the local public sector: Theory and evidence from Norway Lars-Erik Borge a , Jan K. Brueckner b,, Jorn Rattsø a a Department of Economics, Norwegian University of Science and Technology, N-7491 Trondheim, Norway b Department of Economics, University of California, Irvine, CA 92697, USA article info Article history: Received 22 April 2013 Revised 24 December 2013 Available online 28 January 2014 Keywords: Fiscal decentralization Tiebout Norway abstract This paper provides an empirical test of a principal tenet of fiscal federalism: that spending discretion, when granted to localities, allows public-good levels to adjust to suit local demands. The test is based on a simple model of partial fiscal decentralization, under which earmarking of central transfers for par- ticular uses is eliminated, allowing funds to be spent according to local tastes. The greater role of local demand determinants following partial decentralization is confirmed by the paper’s empirical results, which show the effects of the 1986 Norwegian reform. Ó 2014 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction With fiscal decentralization, subnational governments gain autonomy in the provision and financing of public goods. Such autonomy has been a longtime feature of fiscal arrangements in the United States, Canada and a few other countries. A greater de- gree of central management of the public sector, however, is com- mon elsewhere, especially in developing countries. But partly in response to advice from the World Bank and other international agencies, many countries are embracing fiscal decentralization by attempting to devolve spending and taxing authority to subnation- al governments. This movement is motivated in part by the lessons of the Tiebout (1956) model, which show that local control of spending allows the public sector to better respond to heteroge- neous demands for public goods. Despite these developments, the fiscal decentralization pursued in other parts of the world often fails to match the North American pattern, being only partial in nature. Rather than gaining autonomy to set both spending and taxes, subnational governments often must rely on transfers from the central government to finance the provision of public goods. 1 With fixed transfers, subnational governments often have little latitude in choosing the levels of public goods, especially when transfers are accompanied by man- dates that specify how the money is to be allocated across spending categories. This reliance on transfers, and the lack of discretion it en- tails, is often a result of a lack of tax capacity at the subnational level. For either historical or constitutional reasons, subnational govern- ments may not have access to taxes capable of generating substan- tial revenue, in contrast to the situation in North America, where subnational income, sales and property taxes generate enormous revenue. Alternatively, productive subnational taxes may exist but their rates may be centrally controlled. 2 Despite its relevance in much of the world, partial fiscal decen- tralization has received only limited treatment in the public eco- nomics literature. One purpose of the present paper is to offer a simple new model that compares public-good provision under par- tial decentralization to the outcomes under centralized provision and, alternatively, ‘‘full’’ decentralization, where subnational gov- ernments gain complete fiscal autonomy. The model yields clear- cut predictions showing how a movement from centralization to partial decentralization affects public-good provision, and these predictions are then tested using data from Norway. A 1986 Nor- wegian reform gave local governments more control over spending decisions while maintaining their reliance on central transfers as a source of funds, and the empirical work investigates the effect of this reform. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2014.01.003 0094-1190/Ó 2014 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved. Corresponding author. E-mail address: [email protected] (J.K. Brueckner). 1 For example, figures presented by Shah and Shah (2006) show that, in a sample of ten lower-income countries, local governments relied on intergovernmental transfers for 51% of their revenue, in contrast to a smaller transfer share of 34% for OECD countries. In a larger sample of developing countries analyzed by Shah (2004), 42% of subnational revenue (local and provincial) came from transfers. 2 Although the Shah studies cited in footNote 1 do not present evidence on tax autonomy for the sample countries, a separate OECD study (1999) shows that, for one sample country (Mexico), subnational governments had effective control over only 14% of their tax revenue, with this limited control enjoyed only at the state rather than local level. Journal of Urban Economics 80 (2014) 153–163 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Urban Economics www.elsevier.com/locate/jue
Transcript

Journal of Urban Economics 80 (2014) 153–163

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Urban Economics

www.elsevier .com/locate / jue

Partial fiscal decentralization and demand responsiveness of the localpublic sector: Theory and evidence from Norway

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2014.01.0030094-1190/� 2014 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

⇑ Corresponding author.E-mail address: [email protected] (J.K. Brueckner).

1 For example, figures presented by Shah and Shah (2006) show that, in a sample often lower-income countries, local governments relied on intergovernmental transfersfor 51% of their revenue, in contrast to a smaller transfer share of 34% for OECDcountries. In a larger sample of developing countries analyzed by Shah (2004), 42% ofsubnational revenue (local and provincial) came from transfers.

2 Although the Shah studies cited in footNote 1 do not present evidencautonomy for the sample countries, a separate OECD study (1999) shows thasample country (Mexico), subnational governments had effective control o14% of their tax revenue, with this limited control enjoyed only at the stathan local level.

Lars-Erik Borge a, Jan K. Brueckner b,⇑, Jorn Rattsø a

a Department of Economics, Norwegian University of Science and Technology, N-7491 Trondheim, Norwayb Department of Economics, University of California, Irvine, CA 92697, USA

a r t i c l e i n f o

Article history:Received 22 April 2013Revised 24 December 2013Available online 28 January 2014

Keywords:Fiscal decentralizationTieboutNorway

a b s t r a c t

This paper provides an empirical test of a principal tenet of fiscal federalism: that spending discretion,when granted to localities, allows public-good levels to adjust to suit local demands. The test is basedon a simple model of partial fiscal decentralization, under which earmarking of central transfers for par-ticular uses is eliminated, allowing funds to be spent according to local tastes. The greater role of localdemand determinants following partial decentralization is confirmed by the paper’s empirical results,which show the effects of the 1986 Norwegian reform.

� 2014 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction

With fiscal decentralization, subnational governments gainautonomy in the provision and financing of public goods. Suchautonomy has been a longtime feature of fiscal arrangements inthe United States, Canada and a few other countries. A greater de-gree of central management of the public sector, however, is com-mon elsewhere, especially in developing countries. But partly inresponse to advice from the World Bank and other internationalagencies, many countries are embracing fiscal decentralization byattempting to devolve spending and taxing authority to subnation-al governments. This movement is motivated in part by the lessonsof the Tiebout (1956) model, which show that local control ofspending allows the public sector to better respond to heteroge-neous demands for public goods.

Despite these developments, the fiscal decentralization pursuedin other parts of the world often fails to match the North Americanpattern, being only partial in nature. Rather than gaining autonomyto set both spending and taxes, subnational governments oftenmust rely on transfers from the central government to financethe provision of public goods.1 With fixed transfers, subnationalgovernments often have little latitude in choosing the levels of

public goods, especially when transfers are accompanied by man-dates that specify how the money is to be allocated across spendingcategories. This reliance on transfers, and the lack of discretion it en-tails, is often a result of a lack of tax capacity at the subnational level.For either historical or constitutional reasons, subnational govern-ments may not have access to taxes capable of generating substan-tial revenue, in contrast to the situation in North America, wheresubnational income, sales and property taxes generate enormousrevenue. Alternatively, productive subnational taxes may exist buttheir rates may be centrally controlled.2

Despite its relevance in much of the world, partial fiscal decen-tralization has received only limited treatment in the public eco-nomics literature. One purpose of the present paper is to offer asimple new model that compares public-good provision under par-tial decentralization to the outcomes under centralized provisionand, alternatively, ‘‘full’’ decentralization, where subnational gov-ernments gain complete fiscal autonomy. The model yields clear-cut predictions showing how a movement from centralization topartial decentralization affects public-good provision, and thesepredictions are then tested using data from Norway. A 1986 Nor-wegian reform gave local governments more control over spendingdecisions while maintaining their reliance on central transfers as asource of funds, and the empirical work investigates the effect ofthis reform.

e on taxt, for onever onlyte rather

5 With full decentralization, jurisdictions in his model choose both the investmentlevel in individual public projects and the number of projects to implement, in asetting with interjurisdictional spillovers. The central government can improve theoutcome by specifying the level of project investment while still allowing localities tochoose the number of projects undertaken, a partial-decentralization outcome thatshares the spirit of the current approach.

6 It does so because spending is then fixed at the level of the central transferregardless of whether the uncertain unit cost of the public good turns out to be highor low (rather than adjusting to reflect this cost). As a result, rent-seeking politicianswho wish to masquerade as benevolent can more easily extract rents under partialdecentralization without revealing their type. While this conclusion affirms the

154 L.-E. Borge et al. / Journal of Urban Economics 80 (2014) 153–163

The model builds on the analysis of Brueckner (2009), whichalso compared outcomes under centralization, partial, and fulldecentralization. In a model like Brueckner’s that has only a singlepublic good (denoted z), a local government relying on a fixed cen-tral transfer under partial decentralization would ordinarily haveno discretion in its choices, with the z level automatically deter-mined by the transfer amount. However, public-good levels inBrueckner’s model are determined both by spending and by the‘‘effort’’ level of local governments, breaking the direct link be-tween the transfer and z.3 The present model differs fundamentallyby assuming provision of two distinct public goods (x and z) ratherthan one, with local-government effort dropped as an input. Localdiscretion under partial decentralization now exists despite the fixedtransfer because local governments are free to choose the mix of thetwo public goods, varying the levels of x and z to suit local prefer-ences while holding total spending constant at the amount of thetransfer. The simple prediction of the model is that, with per capitaspending held fixed, moving from centralization (where the centersets uniform levels of the two public goods) to partial decentraliza-tion leads to heterogeneity in the levels of the goods. Under partialdecentralization, the x and z levels in different localties diverge fromthe common level under centralization, reflecting local demand dif-ferences, even though total spending is held constant.

The model thus predicts that, following partial decentralization,local characteristics affecting the demand for public goods play agreater role in determining provision levels than before. Evidencefor this enhanced role comes from studying the effects of the1986 Norwegian reform, which relaxed the spending mandatesfor individual public goods that were part of the previous systemof intergovernmental grants. This change allowed new local discre-tion in the choice of the public-good mix while keeping the size ofgrants constant, representing the kind of partial decentralizationenvisioned in the model. In effect, the 1986 reform offers a naturalexperiment that allows a rare test of the effects of local discretion.Pre- and post-reform demand estimates show that local character-istics gained explanatory power following the reform, indicatingthat the reform allowed public-good provision to adjust in re-sponse to demand heterogeneity across jurisdictions. By allowinggreater local discretion, the reform may have also raised the incen-tives for the sorting of the population according to preferences forpublic goods. The paper offers evidence that intercity migration in-creased following the reform, which may reflect greater sortingincentives.

The paper’s demonstration of the enhanced role of local de-mand determinants following the reform offers support for a fun-damental tenet of fiscal federalism, namely, that local fiscaldiscretion enables the public sector to better respond to consumerpreferences for public goods. Despite this idea’s central importancein the vast literature on the Tiebout hypothesis, empirical work de-signed to explicitly test it is scarce. In one study, Ahlin and Mork(2008) exploit a similar natural experiment in Sweden that al-lowed greater local discretion in the determination of schoolspending, although they find mixed results that lend little supportfor the hypothesis. Earlier work by Borge and Rattsø (1993) also ex-plored the effects of the Norwegian reform, but their approach didnot deliver clearcut findings like those presented below. Incontrast, Faguet (2004) found that when a Bolivian reform raisedcentral-government transfers and gave localities more control over

3 This decoupling allows public-good provision to respond under partial decen-tralization to heterogeneity in the demands for z despite a common transfer level forall localities. The response is narrower, however, than under full decentralization.

4 Sigman (2007) offers a test for the effects of decentralization that does not rely ona natural experiment. Her empirical results show that variation in environmentalquality is higher within federalist countries than within non-federal states, evidentlyreflecting variation in the restrictiveness of local environmental policies within theformer set of countries.

investment projects, investment levels changed in ways that re-flected local characteristics.4 With only one prior empirical studyestablishing such a conclusion, more evidence is needed, and this pa-per provides it. Note also that the current evidence relates to public-service provision, not public investment.

Instead of addressing the role of local demand determinantsand exploiting such natural experiments, most previous work inthe Tiebout tradition has investigated the foundational aspects ofthe theory. Oates (1969) and the vast ensuing literature on capital-ization validates the premise that public goods matter to consum-ers and that interjurisdictional mobility registers thesepreferences, with house prices high in places with high public-good levels. Another foundational notion, that consumers votewith their feet in pursuing ideal levels of public spending, is testedin various studies. Some papers, including Pack and Pack (1978),Eberts and Gronberg (1981) and Rhode and Strumpf (2003), carryout tests for convergence toward a homogeneous communitystructure (an implication of voting with one’s feet), while Banzhafand Walsh (2008) look more explicitly for evidence of such behav-ior. A related literature explores intercommunity residence pat-terns using more-sophisticated econometric methods, with thegoal of inferring the existence of consumer sorting across jurisdic-tions (see, for example, Bayer and Timmins (2007)). The presentpaper complements all of this previous work by providing amore-direct test of a core idea of fiscal federalism.

The paper also adds to a recent resurgence of theoretical re-search on fiscal decentralization, which builds on the classic treat-ment of Oates (1972) (see also Wildasin (1986)). Recent papersinclude Lockwood (2002), Besley and Coate (2003), Brueckner(2004), Lorz and Willmann (2005), and Arzaghi and Henderson(2005), among others. The models of Besley and Coate and Lock-wood offer a contrast to the present approach by assuming that,when it exercises control, the central government can differentiatethe provision of public goods across local jurisdictions, blurring thedistinction between the centralized and decentralized cases.

In addition to Brueckner (2009), recent work that explicitly fo-cuses on partial fiscal decentralization includes an earlier paper bySchwager (1999), who analyzes what he calls ‘‘administrative fed-eralism’’.5 Peralta (2012) constructs a related model with imperfectinformation and rent-seeking politicians, where partial decentraliza-tion allows more scope for this activity than full decentralization.6

The analysis of Hatfield and Padró i Miguel (2012) reflects a differentview of partial decentralization. In their model, which has a contin-uum of public goods, partial decentralization emerges when a por-tion of the continuum is provided locally, with the remainderprovided by the central government.7 In addition to these papers

superiority of full decentralization, Brueckner (2009) (in a variant of his basic model)offers a different result by showing that partial decentralization instead limits theoptions of rent-seekers, making it potentially superior to full decentralization.

7 While local governments use nonredistributive and nondistortionary head taxesin a desire to avoid tax competition, a redistributive capital tax, which also distortsthe economy by depressing capital supply, funds central provision of public goods.Facing a tradeoff between efficiency and redistribution in the choice of local versuscentral provision, voters choose the optimal share of public goods to be providedlocally, thus determining the extent of partial fiscal decentralization. Panizza (1999)and Jametti and Joanis (2011) use similar models in empirically oriented papers.

L.-E. Borge et al. / Journal of Urban Economics 80 (2014) 153–163 155

and those cited above, many more recent studies bear some connec-tion to the present work.8

The plan of the paper is as follows. Section 2 presents the model,and Section 3 gives an overview of the Norwegian reform on whichthe empirical work is based. Section 4 discusses the data and pre-sents the regression results on the role of demand determinants.Section 5 presents the migration results, and conclusions are of-fered in Section 6.

2. The model

Consider an economy where individuals consume two publicgoods, x and z, along with a private good e. In order to avoid con-sideration of jurisdiction sizes, each public good is assumed to bea publicly produced private good with cost per capita equal to 1(the model’s main implications would hold more generally). Theeconomy has two consumer types denoted by i ¼ 1;2, who havedifferent Cobb-Douglas preferences given by

ui ¼ ailogðeÞ þ bilogðxÞ þ ð1� ai � biÞlogðzÞ; i ¼ 1;2; ð1Þ

and common incomes equal to I. The share of the type-1 consumersin the overall population equals d, with the type-2 population shareequal to 1� d. The economy contains a number of local jurisdictions(referred to subsequently as ‘‘cities’’), with decisions on their pub-lic-good levels made by majority voting in situations where localcontrol is allowed. In ‘‘type-1’’ cities, type-1 consumers are in themajority, with public-good levels chosen to reflect their prefer-ences, while type-2 cities have type-2 majorities. Although, in anextreme case, cities could be homogeneous, with the consumertypes segregated in separate jurisdictions, the analysis appliesregardless of the degree of intermixing of the types. But cities ofboth types are assumed to exist, so that one type of consumer isnot in the majority everywhere. This latter outcome would emerge,for example, if cities were identical, with their common composi-tion reflecting the overall population shares of the types. Once theanalysis is complete, an extension to an economy with more thantwo consumer types is discussed.

2.1. Public-good levels under different degrees of decentralization

The goal of the analysis is to compare the levels of the publicgoods under three regimes: centralization, partial decentralizationand full decentralization. The comparison between centralizationand partial decentralization is the relevant one for the empiricalwork, but the other comparisons yield some additional usefulconclusions.

In the case of full decentralization, public-good choices aremade locally, with spending financed by head taxes. The chosenlevels of the goods in the different city types are given by familiardemand functions associated with Cobb-Douglas preferences. In atype-i city, the z and x choices are

x�i ¼ biI; z�i ¼ ð1� ai � biÞI; i ¼ 1;2: ð2Þ

Total per capita spending on the goods (equal to the city head taxT�i ) is

x�i þ z�i ¼ T�i ¼ ð1� aiÞI; i ¼ 1;2: ð3Þ

8 For example, Rodden et al. (2003) offer a set of country studies addressing variousissues of fiscal discipline in centralized systems. In the Norwegian context, Borge andRattsø (2002) and Rattsø (2004) analyze fiscal adjustment within that country’scentralized fiscal structure. Barankay and Lockwood (2007) analyze the impact ofdecentralization on governmental productive efficiency, using data for Swiss cantonswith different degrees of decentralization. Zhuravskaya (2000) studies privatebusiness formation across Russian cities with different degrees of fiscal discretion.

Note from (3) that a type’s total spending on public goods varies in-versely with its strength of preference for the private good e, as rep-resented by ai.

Suppose, on the other hand, that public-good levels are dictatedby the central government, with the goods still provided locally butat levels that are uniform across cities despite differing majoritypreferences. The local expenditure is financed by uniform per capi-ta grants (supported by nationally uniform head taxes) sufficient tofund the specified public-good levels.

The mandated public-good levels set by the central governmentare assumed to equal weighted averages of the x and z levels thatwould be chosen under full decentralization, with the type-1weight equal to h. Thus,x� ¼ hx�1 þ ð1� hÞx�2; z� ¼ hz�1 þ ð1� hÞz�2: ð4Þ

This rule could reflect the choices of a benevolent central govern-ment that knows individual preferences and seeks to maximize to-tal utility in the economy. In this case, h would equal d, the type-1population share, as can be seen by computing this welfare-maxi-mizing solution. Alternatively, (5) could be the result of a politicalprocess in which h captures the extent of political influence of thetype-1 consumers in the centralized choice process (h > d wouldindicate outsize influence).

Given (4), total per capita spending T� on the public goods un-der centralization (equal to the uniform grant and head tax) is aweighted average of the T�i from (3). It equals

T� ¼ hT�1 þ ð1� hÞT�2 ¼ x� þ z�: ð5Þ

Suppose now that the central government switches to partialfiscal decentralization by providing the cities with equal per capitagrants of T� (again financed by uniform head taxes) without speci-fying the particular levels of public goods that must be provided. Inother words, the central government allows freedom of choice inselecting public-good levels, subject to the requirement that totalspending is the same as under centralization. Again, the goodsmust be entirely paid for with grant funds. Each city faces the fol-lowing constraints:

e ¼ y� T�; xþ z ¼ T�: ð6Þ

The chosen public-good levels for the two city types are now

zi ¼1� ai � bi

1� aiT� ¼ 1� bi

1� ai

� �T�; xi ¼

bi

1� aiT�; i ¼ 1;2: ð7Þ

Note that each public-good level equals T� times the relative prefer-ence weight for that good within the set of public goods. Thisweight equals the good’s preference coefficient in (1) divided thesum of x and z coefficients, a sum that equals1� ai � bi þ bi ¼ 1� ai.

2.2. Moving from centralization to partial decentralization

The following analysis carries out comparisons of public-goodlevels under the three regimes, moving from centralization to par-tial decentralization to full decentralization, and this section fo-cuses on the first of these movements. To compare x valuesbetween centralization and partial decentralization, (2) and (3)can be used to write x�i ¼ biT

�i =ð1� aiÞ. Substituting in (4) and

assumingb1

1� a1<

b2

1� a2ð8Þ

yields

x� ¼ b1

1� a1hT�1 þ

b2

1� a2ð1� hÞT�2

>b1

1� a1hT�1 þ

b1

1� a1ð1� hÞT�2 ¼

b1

1� a1hT� ¼ x1: ð9Þ

Fig. 1. Effects of decentralization.

156 L.-E. Borge et al. / Journal of Urban Economics 80 (2014) 153–163

If b2=ð1� a2Þ appears in place of b1=ð1� a1Þ in the last two expres-sions in (9), then the reverse inequality holds, so that x� < x2. Sincea parallel argument establishes the opposite relationship among thezi’s, it follows that

b1

1� a1<

b2

1� a2) x1 < x� < x2; z1 > z� > z2; ð10Þ

with the x and z inequalities reversed if b1=ð1� a1Þ > b2=ð1� a2Þ.Therefore, in moving from centralization to partial decentraliza-

tion, the public-good levels diverge from the common centralizedlevel, with x falling (rising) in the city type with the weaker (stron-ger) relative preference weight for x. The levels of z move in theopposite directions. Since total spending on public goods remainsfixed at the centralized level T� in moving to partial decentraliza-tion, private-good consumption remains at the centralized levele�, with adjustment occurring only in the mix of public goods in re-sponse to the relative preference weights for x and z in the twotypes of cities. In Fig. 1, the movement from the C to PD outcomesillustrates the pattern in (10). Note that x� > z� is assumed in thefigure in locating the starting point under centralization, and thatthe FD case is yet to be discussed.

Empirically, (10) and Fig. 1 predict that, when partial decentral-ization occurs, public-good levels diverge from the common cen-tralized levels in ways that reflect local preferences for the twogoods, leading to different mixes of x and z in across cities. Thisconclusion clearly generalizes to a situation with more than twopreference types,9 and it forms the basis for the ensuing empiricalwork.

2.3. Moving from partial to full decentralization

The movement from partial to full decentralization is more eas-ily analyzed, focusing first on the case where a1 > a2. First, notethat a1 > a2 implies T�1 < T�2 from (3), so that total spending onpublic goods under full decentralization is higher in type-2 cities.Since T� is a weighted average of the T�i from (5), it then followsthat T�1 < T� < T�2. Next, using (3) to replace I in (2) withT�i =ð1� aiÞ, it follows that x�i and z�i are proportional to T�i , withthe same proportionality factors that relate xi and zi to T� in (7).Since the movement from a common spending level of T� underpartial decentralization raises (lowers) total spending on publicgoods in type-2 (type-1) cities, and since x and z are given by con-stant proportions of total spending in both cases, this movementleads to an increase (decrease) in the levels of both public goodsin type-2 (type-1) cities. Thus,

a1 > a2 ) x�1 < x1; z�1 < z1; x�2 > x2; z�2 > z2; ð12Þ

with the inequalities reversed when a1 < a2.The conclusion in (12) follows because total spending on

public goods is lower in type-1 than in type-2 cities under fulldecentralization T�1 < T�2

� �as a result of their stronger preference

for the private good e, while the x=z mix remains under local con-trol. The conclusion is illustrated in Fig. 1 by the movements from

9 With more than two types, the number of possible city types would increase,given that each consumer type is potentially in the majority in some city. However,the divergence effect of partial decentralization continues to emerge. Letting hi denotethe population share of consumer type i, the analog to (10) is

xi < x�; zi > z� ifbi

1� ai<

Pj–ihjbjP

j–ihjð1� ajÞ;

with the first set of inequalities reversed if the third inequality is reversed. Therefore,depending on the relationships among the a’s and b’s for the consumer types, partialdecentralization will lead to increases in z and decreases in x in some cities andreverse changes in other cities, creating the kind of changes seen in the two-typecase. A further generalization that increases the number of public goods beyondtwo also leaves the main predictions of the theory unaffected.

PD to FD. The figure shows that the increase in x2 in moving from Cto PD is amplified by the further movement to FD, and that the de-cline in x1 is also amplified, widening the gap between the x’s. Butthe left side of the figure shows that the gap between z1 and z2

resulting from the C-to-PD movement is narrowed by the furthermovement from PD to FD, leaving the z comparison across the citytypes ambiguous without further information (the figure is drawnwith z�2 > z�1).

These conclusions can be seen directly from the solutions, giventhe assumptions reflected in the figure. With a1 > a2, satisfactionof b1=ð1� a1Þ < b2=ð1� a2Þ requires b1 < b2, so that x�1 < x�2 holdsfrom (2). But the first and third inequalities imply that the compar-ison between 1� a1 � b1 and 1� a2 � b2, and thus the comparisonbetween z�1 and z�2 from (2), is ambiguous. Therefore, comparison ofz�1 and z�2 requires an additional explicit assumption about the rel-ative magnitudes of 1� ai � bi; i ¼ 1;2. In general, these findingsimply that the high-a type will have the lower x level under FDif its public-good preferences favor z, with the z comparison beingambiguous without an additional assumption. If its preferences in-stead favor x, the high-a type will have the lower z level under FD,with the x comparison being ambiguous.

2.4. Empirical framework

The divergence in public-good levels that occurs in movingfrom centralization to partial decentralization, as seen in (10)and Fig. 1, motivates the ensuing empirical work. However, theempirical context differs from the stylized model in a number ofways, which must be taken into account. First, cities have differentincomes in addition to differences in preferences. In Norway, how-ever, the effect of income variation is muted by equalization grants,which partly offset income differences across localities. Second,public goods are financed partly by local tax revenue in additionto central transfers.

While more detail on these institutional factors is given in Sec-tion 3 below, it is useful generalize the previous model somewhatto incorporate them. Let preferences be written more generallythan in the previous framework, with utility given by Uðe; x; z; cÞ,where c is a vector of K taste parameters, ðc1; . . . ; cKÞ. Let a cityagain be identified according to the type of its majority voter, witha type-i city having c ¼ ci and, recognizing that incomes differ, anincome level of Ii. Ignoring for the moment the presence of local taxrevenue, the utility of the majority voter in a type-i city isU Ii � T�; xi; T� � xi; cið Þ. Under centralization, xi ¼ x� and zi ¼ z�,

L.-E. Borge et al. / Journal of Urban Economics 80 (2014) 153–163 157

and since these centrally chosen public-good levels do not varyacross cities,

@xi

@cik¼ 0; k ¼ 1; . . . ;K;

@xi

@Ii¼ 0; ð13Þ

with the same equalities holding for zi.While public-good levels are thus unresponsive to the city

characteristics (those of its majority voter) under centralization,they are chosen under partial decentralization to maximize theprevious utility expression in a type-i city, leading to xi ¼ xi.The first-order condition is Xi � Ui

x � Uiz ¼ 0 or Ui

x=Uiz ¼ 1, where

the subscripts denote partial derivatives and the i superscriptindicates that the marginal utilities are evaluated at type-ivalues.

The second-order condition is Xix < 0, and differentiating the

first-order condition, the effects of the preference parameters andincome on xi are given by

@xi

@cik¼ �

Xicik

Xix

’ Uizcik� Ui

xcik; k ¼ 1; . . . ;K ð14Þ

@xi

@Ii¼ �Xi

e

Xix

’ Uize � Ui

xe; ð15Þ

where ’ means ‘‘has same sign as.’’ Analogous equations give im-pacts on zi. Therefore, under partial decentralization, city character-istics affect public-good levels, as seen in the previous analysis. Eq.(14) shows that the impact of the taste parameter cik on xi dependson the difference between its effects on the marginal utilities of zand x, capturing the taste effects seen in the earlier analysis. Whileincome differences were previously suppressed, (15) shows that theeffect of a higher income on xi depends on the difference betweenthe effects of private consumption e on the marginal utilities of zand x. Note that, since total public spending is fixed at the cen-tral-transfer amount T�, the usual income effect that shifts this totalis absent.

Suppose now that cities raise local tax revenue in addition tospending transfer funds. Letting this revenue, which is raised as alocal head tax, be denoted Ri for city i, utility is now writtenUðIi � T� � Ri; xi; T� þ Ri � xi; ciÞ. With local taxes, xi under cen-tralization is composed of the fixed level x� mandated by the cen-tral government plus an incremental amount ~xi over which localdiscretion may be exercised, so that xi ¼ x� þ ~xi. If cities are com-pletely free to set Ri and ~xi, then the utility expression under cen-tralization is maximized by choice of these variables.10 Given thisfreedom of choice, xi (as well as zi) will vary with city characteristicsunder centralization, in contrast to case without local revenue,where the zero effects in (13) apply.

In moving to partial decentralization, T� remains fixed, but cit-ies now have full discretion in spending their combined local andtransfer revenue. As a result, compared to the centralization case,the effects of city characteristics on public-good levels will be morepronounced under partial decentralization given that the previouslymandated components are no longer fixed.

2.5. Intercity migration

The analysis of the simple model with two city types made noassumptions on the makeup of city populations aside fromassuming that cities of both types exist. The movement to partialdecentralization, however, would generate the usual kinds ofTiebout forces toward homogenization of the jurisdictionstructure, regardless of the number of consumer types. With

10 Note that zi ¼ T� þ Ri � xi ¼ T� þ Ri � x� � ~xi ¼ z� þ Ri � ~xi , with the z� componentfixed.

public goods no longer uniform across cities, minority residentsof a city, whose tastes are not represented in its choices, wouldhave an incentive to move to a city where their type is in themajority. So, in addition to generating divergence in public-goodlevels, partial decentralization would be expected to createmigration incentives, leading to more-extensive sorting of thepopulation. In Section 5, the paper offers evidence suggesting thatintercity migration may have indeed increased following thereform.

3. Norwegian institutional setting

The public sector in Norway is large and decentralized, with thesector’s local component accounting for about one-fifth of GDP.The major source of tax financing is the income tax paid by individ-uals. Income-tax revenue is shared between municipalities, coun-ties and the central government, with revenue shares determinedeach year by the Parliament. Since the 1992 tax reform, incomehas been taxed at an overall flat rate of 28%, which decomposesinto rates of about 13% for municipalities, 3% for counties and12% for the central government. Municipalities and counties are al-lowed to set their own tax rates within a narrow band, but they alluse the maximum rate.

While the income levels available for taxation are very differ-ent in urban and rural areas, a comprehensive tax equalizationsystem ensures that a locality is not penalized by a lowincome-tax base. This system lifts localities at the bottom to90% of the average tax base while reducing tax bases at the top.In addition, a comprehensive system of expenditure equalizationgrants is designed to neutralize the effect of variation in local costconditions, which arise partly due to differences in population agedistributions.

In addition to income taxation, which accounts for 45% of localrevenue, localities receive revenue from a voluntary property taxand user fees. The property tax is regulated and small for mostmunicipalities, but revenue can be large in cities with substantialhydroelectric energy production. While local discretion leads tosome variation across cities in the share of revenue from thesesources, the property tax and user fees generate about 15% of totallocal revenue, with most of this amount coming from user fees. Theremaining portion of local revenue consists of grants from the cen-tral government, about 40% of the total.

The current system is the legacy of public-sector decentraliza-tion during the 1980s, which occurred in Norway and severalother Nordic countries (see Lotz (1998) for an overview). Theanalysis concentrates on the major 1986 reform in the controland financing of the Norwegian local public sector. The historicalbackground was a centralized system of sectoral control wherenational ministries controlled local spending within their ownsector through mandating and the use of earmarked grants,usually arranged as matching grants. Ministries responsible foreducation and health care in particular exercised strong controlover local spending, attempting to equalize service levels acrossjurisdictions. The reform was designed by a government commis-sion with the broad goal of strengthening local democracy andimproving efficiency by giving local governments more discretionin the allocation of resources. The reform changed the expendi-ture equalization grants from earmarked transfers to general-purpose grants, with relatively few restrictions on the use offunds (the grants were still adjusted for the local age distributionand other cost-shifting municipal characteristics). About 50earmarked grants were replaced by general-purpose grants basedon objective criteria. The result was a simpler and more transpar-ent grant system.

The reform represented a shift in the design of fiscal federalismsimilar to the shift from centralization to partial decentralization in

158 L.-E. Borge et al. / Journal of Urban Economics 80 (2014) 153–163

the model of Section 2. The centralized regime before 1986 at-tempted to control local government spending with sectoral man-dating and earmarking. Although localities were required, underthe system’s matching arrangements, to supplement central trans-fers with their own funds, these required contributions (and thetaxes supporting them) were effectively determined by the center.As a result, the system was roughly equivalent to the full-central-ization regime in the model, where the center collects all taxes,dictates public-good levels, and fully funds the localities by trans-fers. However, it should be noted that, because of imperfect incomeand cost equalization, local property-tax revenues from hydroelec-tric plants, and the existence of some regionally targeted grants,the levels of provision of public goods and services were not uni-form prior to the reform, unlike in the model. Nevertheless, the re-form greatly relaxed the extent of central control, thus mirroringthe case of partial decentralization.

4. Demand regressions

4.1. Data

The dataset covers all 443 municipalities in Norway during theperiod 1980–1991. The analysis compares the 1980–1985 pre-re-form period to the 1986–1991 post-reform period using data forfive social-service sectors: child care, primary and secondary edu-cation, elderly care, cultural services, and parks. Selection of theseperiods was carried out recognizing that some effects of the reformmay not materialize quickly enough to be apparent in the first fiveyears following its implementation. However, choice of a longerpost-reform period would risk the inclusion of other secularchanges that might obscure the effects of interest. The relativeimportance of the chosen sectors is indicated by the average muni-cipal budget shares, which are approximately 4% for child care, 43%for education, 18% for health (which includes elderly care) and 6%for culture (which includes both cultural and park services). Theremaining categories are administration (12%) and infrastructure(17%, which includes fire protection). Police services are theresponsibility of the central government.

The provision of child care in a municipality is captured bythree different variables: child-care coverage (the share of childrenin child care), child-care employment per child in child care, andemployment per young child (1–6 years of age). Provision of pri-mary and lower (pre-high-school) secondary education is capturedby three interrelated variables: class size, teachers per class (a classmay have more than one teacher), and teachers per student.11 Theprovision of elderly care is the percentage of households with elderlyinhabitants 67 years or older that are covered by home-base nursingservices. Provision levels in the last two public-good categories, cul-tural services and parks, are measured by per capita spending levelsfor general cultural services and park services, both adjusted forinflation. Table 1 presents summary statistics.

4.2. The setup

In a previous analysis of the reform, Borge and Rattsø (1993)estimate a demand system based on budget shares in order toinvestigate parameter stability across the pre- and post-reformperiods. They find a shift in parameters from 1984–85 to 1986–87, indicating some change in behavior. But they do not find signif-icant changes in short-run and long-run expenditure elasticities orchanges in the effects of demographic variables that are consistent

11 Although class size is equal to teachers per class divided by teachers per studentat the level of individual observations, the same relationship does not hold for themean values shown in Table 1.

with the predicted effects of the reform. The present analysis, how-ever, relies on the measures of local service provision describedabove, which are more detailed than those in previous studiesand thus better able to capture the quantitative and qualitative as-pects of the services. Note that, because most of these variablesmeasure service levels rather than spending, estimation of a de-mand system becomes infeasible.

The estimated demand model follows the usual approaches inthe literature while also mirroring previous demand studies for lo-cal governments in Norway, including Borge and Rattsø (1993,1995). A key demand variable is per capita income for the munic-ipality, which is denoted PINC and measured on an after-tax basis.Since services are oriented toward specific age groups in the pop-ulation, demographic factors will also be important determinantsof demand. The demographic variables are the child share of thepopulation, measured by the fraction below 7 years of age (CH),the ‘youth’ share of the population, measured by the fraction be-tween 7 and 15 years of age (YO), and the elderly share of the pop-ulation, representing individuals aged 67 years and above (EL). Inaddition, population size (POP) is included to control for possiblescale effects in service production, which may reduce unit costsand thus raise provision levels. Summary statistics for these vari-ables are shown in Table 1.

The demand model is estimated to allow different coefficientsto emerge in the pre- and post-reform periods, 1980–85 and1986–1990. The main prediction is that local demand determi-nants should play a more important role in determining public-good levels after the reform than before it, a consequence of therelaxation of central controls over local resource allocation. Inother words, the estimated coefficients of the local characteristicsare expected to be higher in absolute value and more statisticallysignificant after the reform.

Another observation concerns the interpretation of the effectsof income on demand. Since the reform simply removed spendingmandates while holding grant amounts fixed, it should not haveled to a stronger association between a city’s income and its pub-lic-good levels through the usual purchasing-power channel, as ex-plained above. However, in addition to the income impact capturedin (15), the level of income may be a proxy for other unmeasuredhousehold characteristics that affect preferences (education, say),possibly strengthening the association between provision levelsand income.

Estimation of the pre- and post-reform demand coefficients iscarried out within a single regression model, where interactionterms allow different coefficients for the two periods while the er-ror structure is constrained to be the same across periods. Themodel, which facilitates inter-period hypothesis tests on the coef-ficients, is

Sit ¼ at þ Dpret gpre

i þ bpre1 logðPINCitÞ þ bpre

2 CHit þ bpre3 YOit

�þbpre

4 ELit þ bpre5 logðPOPitÞ

�þ 1� Dpre

t

� �gpost

i

�þbpost

1 logðPINCitÞ þ bpost2 CHit þ bpost

3 YOit þ bpost4 ELit

þbpost5 logðPOPitÞ

�þ �it ð16Þ

In (16), i denotes the municipality and t denotes the year, with thedummy variable Dpre

t taking the value one when t is a pre-reformyear and zero otherwise. Year fixed effects are denoted by at , whilegpre

i and gposti give municipality fixed effects that may vary between

the periods. The other demand coefficients are also allowed to differbetween the periods, and �it is the error term. In the estimation, thestandard errors are clustered by cities, given the possibility of with-in-city correlation in the error terms.

Note that the inclusion of pre- and post-reform city fixed effectsmeans that the impact of the demand determinants is identified

Table 1Summary statistics.

Variables Before thereform

After thereform

Allyears

Child careCoverage 0.261 0.408 0.328

(0.137) (0.153) (0.162)Child-care employment per child 0.206 0.230 0.214

(0.073) (0.067) (0.072)Employment per young child 0.051 0.095 0.071

(0.031) (0.048) (0.045)

EducationClass size 18.4 17.2 17.8

(3.47) (3.37) (3.47)Teachers per class 1.80 2.08 1.94

(0.21) (0.26) (0.28)Teachers per student 0.102 0.127 0.114

(0.025) (0.034) (0.032)

Elderly care, culture, and parksElderly-care coverage 0.089 0.108 0.097

(0.057) (0.058) (0.058)Cultural spending 390 505 436

(177) (261) (222)Parks spending 32 29 31

(59) (54) (57)

Explanatory variablesPrivate income net of taxes per

capita (PINC)21,006 23,313 22,054(2,472) (2,417) (2,703)

Share of children 0–6 years CH) 0.093 0.089 0.091(0.015) (0.014) (0.015)

Share of youths 7–15 years (YO) 0.148 0.130 0.140(0.018) (0.017) (0.020)

Share of elderly 67 years andabove (EL)

0.141 0.153 0.146(0.037) (0.039) (0.038)

Population size (POP) 8,025 8,196 8,102(14,678) (15,046) (14,845)

L.-E. Borge et al. / Journal of Urban Economics 80 (2014) 153–163 159

only through intraperiod, within-city variation in the levels of thedeterminants. Small intertemporal variation in these covariatesmight then militate against the emergence of significant demandeffects. In addition, since the grant share of local revenue is around40%, less than half of local public spending is affected by partial fis-cal decentralization, which may make post-reform demand effectsdifficult to isolate.

13 A significantly positive elderly-share effect, which is hard to interpret, exists in

4.3. Estimation results

The estimated demand models for the three child-care mea-sures are presented in Table 2. The results show that child-carecoverage was independent of income and the age composition ofthe population before the reform. For the post-reform period, how-ever, the estimates show that income became a significant deter-minant of coverage, with the share of children in the populationbecoming a marginally significant negative factor. This CH effectis consistent with recent evidence from Borge and Rattsø (2008),who conclude using data from Denmark that being part of a largecohort is a disadvantage in terms of child-care service levels.12 Theremaining columns of Table 2 show that the regressions for employ-ment per child in child care and employment per young child havemostly insignificant coefficients prior to the reform. But both vari-ables respond positively to income in the post-reform period,although one income coefficient is only marginally significant.

To better judge whether the reform strengthened the link be-tween service levels and the determinants of demand in an overall

12 Note that a larger population reduces child-care coverage both before and afterthe reform.

sense, Table 3 provides several F tests, with the first panel focusingon child care. The first column provides a test of the null hypothe-sis that the vector of pre-reform coefficients equals the vector ofpost-reform coefficients. None of the F statistics for the threechild-care regressions allows rejection of this hypothesis, althoughthe statistic for coverage is marginally significant. Rather than test-ing for coefficient equality, a different approach is to ask whetherthe coefficient vector is zero, both before and after the reform. Ascan be seen in the second and third columns, this hypothesis canbe rejected in both the pre- and post-reform cases for child-carecoverage and employment per young child.

These results, which give a somewhat mixed picture of the ef-fects of the reform, appear to be driven by the population coeffi-cients (meant to capture the effects of scale economies), whichare significant or nearly so in the pre-reform period. Since popula-tion can be viewed as a less-central determinant of demand thanthe remaining demographic variables in the regression, the lastthree columns of Table 3 carry out the previous F tests with thepopulation coefficient excluded. Now the picture provided by thetests is clearer. Coefficient equality across periods is rejected forchild-care coverage and nearly rejected for employment per youngchild. In addition, the hypothesis that the pre-reform coefficientvector is zero cannot be rejected for any of the child-care measures,while the post-reform vector is significantly different from zero forcoverage and employment per young child and marginally signifi-cant for the remaining measure. Thus, this second set of tests sug-gests that the reform strengthened the link between child-careservices and the determinants of demand.

Table 4 shows the regression results for the three educationmeasures. For the class-size measure, the YO coefficient gains sig-nificance in the post-reform period and has the expected positivesign (showing that more school-age children raise class sizes).For teachers per student, higher income has a positive effect inthe post-reform period but no pre-reform effect. A large youthshare reduces both teachers per class and per student in thepost-reform period, with the effect changing from insignificant tosignificant in the case of teachers per class. In addition, for bothservice measures, YO’s coefficient magnitude is much larger inthe post-reform period.13

Turning to the F tests in Table 3 and focusing on the tests thatexclude the population coefficient, pre- and post-reform coefficientequality is rejected for both teachers per class and per student. Inaddition, whereas the coefficient vectors for all three service mea-sures are significantly different from zero in the post-reform peri-od, two out of three are indistinguishable from zero in the pre-reform period. Thus, as in the case of child care, the F tests suggestthat the reform strengthened the link between education servicesand the determinants of demand.

The elderly-care, culture and parks regressions are shown in Ta-ble 5. Somewhat surprisingly, only one coefficient in the two el-derly care regressions is significant, that of population in the pre-reform period. In the case of cultural services, income becomes asignificant determinant of cultural spending in the post-reformperiod, with its effect much larger than the marginally significantpre-reform impact. In addition, an increase in the elderly share re-duces cultural spending in the post-reform period, whereas no pre-reform effect exists. This negative effect might seem counterintui-tive, but it likely reflects competition for funds between culturalservices and services for the elderly in the local budget. In thepark-spending regression, the only significant effect is POP’s nega-

the pre-reform period for teachers per student, but it disappears following the reform.Similarly, a significantly positive population effect exists prior to the reform forteachers per class, disappearing after it. These changes, which unfortunately runcounter to the predictions, contribute to the significance of the F statistics.

Table 2Child care regressions.

Coverage (share of children in child care) Child-care employment per child Employment per young child (1–6 years)

1980–1985 1986–1990 1980–1985 1986–1990 1980–1985 1986–1990

Log (PINC) 0.043 0.178 0.003 0.100 0.004 0.069(0.68) (3.02) (0.06) (1.77) (0.26) (2.43)

CH 0.855 �1.153 �0.299 �0.159 �0.042 �0.317(1.25) (�1.74) (�0.90) (�0.38) (�0.31) (�1.21)

YO 0.034 �0.645 0.232 0.427 �0.150 �0.065(0.08) (�1.09) (0.81) (1.14) (�1.22) (�0.27)

EL 0.286 �0.182 0.304 0.482 0.178 0.273(0.28) (�0.33) (0.87) (0.90) (0.80) (0.79)

Log (POP) �0.396 �0.288 0.004 0.081 �0.080 �0.074(�2.31) (�2.23) (0.07) (0.61) (�1.96) (�1.36)

N 443 443 412 412 443 443

Regressions include year and city fixed effects, and standard errors are clustered by cities; t-statistics are in parentheses.

Table 3F-tests.

All coefficients All coefficients except population size

Equality before andafter

Jointly zerobefore

Jointly zeroafter

Equality before andafter

Jointly zerobefore

Jointly zeroafter

Child careCoverage 1.90 3.14 5.59 2.23 0.053 3.39

(0.094) (0.009) (0.000) (0.065) (0.716) (0.001)Child-care employment per

child0.52 0.72 1.91 0.57 0.084 1.64

(0.759) (0.612) (0.092) (0.688) (0.498) (0.165)

Employment per young child 1.55 3.51 5.29 1.78 0.74 2.84(0.174) (0.004) (0.000) (0.131) (0.562) (0.024)

EducationClass size 1.07 4.36 3.05 0.19 2.19 3.52

(0.379) (0.001) (0.010) (0.944) (0.069) (0.008)Teachers per class 3.01 1.60 3.86 2.49 1.51 4.12

(0.011) (0.159) (0.011) (0.042) (0.199) (0.003)Teachers per student 7.41 4.85 15.45 8.73 2.81 14.99

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.025) (0.000)

Elderly Care, Culture, and ParksElderly-care coverage 0.97 1.54 0.87 1.19 1.51 0.69

(0.434) (0.175) (0.504) (0.313) (0.197) (0.599)Culture 0.85 3.94 9.69 1.04 1.41 7.29

(0.518) (0.002) (0.000) (0.388) (0.229) (0.000)Parks 1.92 0.69 3.54 0.40 0.76 1.59

(0.089) (0.628) (0.004) (0.812) (0.549) (0.176)

F statistics with p-values in parentheses.

Table 4Primary and lower secondary education regressions.

Class size Teachers per class Teachers per student

1980–1985 1986–1990 1981–1985 1986–1990 1981–1985 1986–1990

Log (PINC) �0.971 �0.945 �0.063 0.281 0.015 0.038(�0.84) (�0.99) (�0.24) (1.42) (1.15) (2.83)

CH 7.38 �2.51 0.394 �0.873 0.001 0.087(0.78) (�0.28) (0.14) (�0.47) (0.01) (0.87)

YO 19.6 20.2 �1.33 �5.31 �0.108 �0.556(1.76) (2.85) (�0.58) (�3.74) (�2.09) (�5.61)

EL 3.73 �2.13 2.26 �0.230 0.164 0.025(0.35) (�0.27) (1.43) (�0.14) (1.98) (0.23)

Log (POP) 4.85 0.137 0.650 �0.075 �0.017 �0.072(2.66) (0.08) (1.99) (�0.18) (�0.85) (�2.54)

N 443 443 443 443 443 443

Regressions include year and city fixed effects, and standard errors are clustered by cities; t-statistics are in parentheses.

160 L.-E. Borge et al. / Journal of Urban Economics 80 (2014) 153–163

Table 5Elderly-care, culture, and parks regressions.

Elderly-Care Coverage Cultural spending per capita Parks spending per capita

1980–1985 1986–1989 1980–1985 1986–1989 1980–1985 1986–1989

Log (PINC) �0.026 �0.015 199.7 363.1 �9.34 �4.21(�0.59) (�0.29) (1.70) (3.58) (�0.32) (�0.17)

CH �0.058 �0.261 �806.1 �1466.0 106.4 �67.3(�0.16) (�0.72) (�1.20) (�1.04) (0.47) (�0.32)

YO 0.571 �0.296 �374.8 420.6 445.3 411.4(1.48) (�0.99) (�0.55) (0.35) (1.91) (1.84)

EL �0.870 �0.471 �775.9 �3273.3 107.9 �282.6(�1.70) (�1.00) (�0.65) (�2.44) (0.37) (�1.46)

Log (POP) �0.173 �0.123 �575.8 �707.2 30.9 �116.4(�2.32) (�1.69) (�2.57) (�2.94) (0.72) (�2.62)

N 443 443 443 443 443 443

Regressions include year and city fixed effects, and standard errors are clustered by cities; t-statistics are in parentheses. Due to data limitations, the post-reform period forthese services does not include 1990.

L.-E. Borge et al. / Journal of Urban Economics 80 (2014) 153–163 161

tive post-reform impact. Although both effects are only marginallysignificant, a higher youth share raises park spending before andafter the reform, a natural outcome.

The F tests shown in the second half of the last panel of Table 3do not allow rejection of coefficient equality for any of the threeservices from Table 5. However, the post-reform coefficient vectorfor cultural spending is significantly different from zero while thepre-reform vector is not, suggesting that the reform strengthenedthe link between cultural spending and the determinants of de-mand (despite the failure to reject coefficient equality). Note thatneither coefficient vector is significantly different from zero inthe cases of elderly care and parks.

Overall, the results in Tables 2–5 offer support for the model’sprediction that local demographic characteristics should mattermore in the determination of public-service levels after the reformthan before it. In six out of the nine cases in Table 5, the demo-graphic variables show no combined effect on service levels priorto the reform while exhibiting a statistically significant impactafter the reform. In particular, the F tests for child-care coverageand employment per young child, class size, teachers per class,and cultural spending show a nonzero vector of demographicscoefficients in the post-reform period, while failing in each caseto reject the null hypothesis of no demographic effects in thepre-reform period. The income variable, which never has an effecton public-service provision prior to the reform, emerges after thereform as a determinant of child-care coverage and employmentper young child, teachers per student, and cultural spending. Inaddition, larger cohort sizes (for children, youth, and elderly) leadto reductions in post-reform levels for some services, when effectswere absent prior to the reform. This pattern is seen for CH inchild-care coverage (being marginally significant), YO in class sizeand teachers per class, and EL in cultural spending. The results thussuggest that local discretion granted under partial decentralizationallows public-service levels to respond to local demand.

5. The Reform’s effect on migration and heterogeneity

As noted above, the Tiebout model predicts that partial decen-tralization, and the resulting increase in demand responsivenessof the local public sector, is likely to heighten the incentives formigration and population sorting. To see whether the reform hadsuch an effect on intercity migration, yearly rates of in- and out-migration are computed for each city in the sample, with the rategiving the migration flow as a percentage of the existing popula-tion. Average migration rates range between 4 and 5 percent in

all years from 1980 to 1990, a conclusion that applies to the in-and out-migration rates separately and to the combined migrationrate (the average of the in and out rates).

The raw numbers do not indicate a major migration shift fol-lowing the reform, although migration was somewhat higher inthe post-reform period. The mean of the combined migration raterose from 0.043 to 0.045 between the periods, and the out-migra-tion rate showed a similar change in means. To provide a propertest, a panel regression is run over the 1980–1990 period for eachof the three migration measures, with the right-hand variablesconsisting of city fixed effects, a linear time trend, and a post-re-form dummy variable. The time trend takes the place of the yearfixed effects used in the demand regressions, which are perfectlycollinear with the reform variable and thus cannot be included.As seen in columns 1, 3 and 5 of Table 6, the post-reform coefficientis positive and strongly significant in all the regressions, while thetime trend coefficient is negative. Therefore, an existing downwardmigration trend experienced a discontinuous upward shift in its le-vel following the reform.

The previous demand variables are added in the regressions re-ported in columns 2, 4, and 6 of Table 6, with their presence allow-ing income, the age-group shares (children, youth and elderly), andpopulation size to affect migration rates. The regressions also in-clude the city unemployment rate, shown to be the major determi-nant of migration in Norway by Carlsen et al. (2013). In theseregressions, the post-reform coefficients decrease somewhat inmagnitude, but they are again all positive and statistically signifi-cant. Two of the trend coefficients are again negative and signifi-cant, although the out-migration coefficient becomesinsignificant. As for the other covariates, migration rates tend tofall with higher values of each of the age shares, indicating lowermigration in cities where population is concentrated at the ex-tremes of the age distribution. Higher unemployment reduces,and higher income increases, both the in- and combined-migrationrates, while larger cities have higher out- but lower in-migrationrates.

The results in Table 6 are thus consistent with a greater incen-tive for population sorting after the reform, as theory would pre-dict. However, the existence of some other intertemporal causeof higher post-reform migration cannot be ruled out.

To see whether increased migration creates greater heterogene-ity across cities, yearly dissimilarity indexes are computed usingthe population age shares. Greater segregation of the populationage groups (as captured by the index) could occur as some citiesshift resources toward education (attracting families with chil-

Table 6Migration regressions with linear trend.

In-migration Out-migration (In + Out)/2

REFORM 0.0068 0.0035 0.0044 0.0038 0.0056 0.0037(13.05) (5.78) (10.95) (6.49) (15.04) (8.18)

TREND �0.0011 �0.0013 �0.0002 0.0001 �0.0007 �0.0006(�13.68) (�6.32) (�2.89) (0.36) (�10.90) (�3.52)

Log (PINC) 0.0199 �0.0007 0.0096(3.42) (�0.14) (2.32)

CH �0.1403 0.017 �0.062(�3.45) (0.47) (�2.15)

YO �0.146 �0.052 �0.099(�4.64) (�1.81) (�4.00)

EL �0.079 �0.158 �0.118(�1.45) (�3.25) (�2.75)

Log (POP) �0.023 0.016 �0.004(�2.84) (2.06) (�0.53)

UNEMP �0.127 �0.039 �0.083(�5.25) (�1.68) (�4.31)

N 443 443 443 443 443 443Period 1980–1990 1980–1990 1980–1990 1980–1990 1980–1990 1980–1990

Regressions include city fixed effects, and standard errors are clustered by cities; t-statistics are in parentheses.

Table 7Heterogeneity.

CH YO EL OVERALL

Dissimilarity index1980–85 0.062 0.052 0.114 0.0761986–90 0.057 0.056 0.112 0.077

Regressions with linear trendREFORM �0.0037 0.0011 0.0065 0.0023

(�1.62) (0.63) (4.24) (2.28)TREND �0.0012 0.0016 �0.0022 0.0006

(�2.30) (3.22) (�4.01) (2.14)N 443 443 443 443Period 1980–1990 1980–1990 1980–1990 1980–1990

Regressions include city fixed effects and clustered standard errors; t-statistics arein parentheses. The dependent variable is calculated as jPaj � Paj=Pa for CH, YO andEL and

PajPaj � Paj=

PaPa for OVERALL.

14 Interestingly, the index values here are comparable to those calculated by Rhodeand Strumpf (2003) for US municipalities. They also find less heterogeneity for theyoung population than for the elderly.

162 L.-E. Borge et al. / Journal of Urban Economics 80 (2014) 153–163

dren) and others deemphasize education (becoming more attrac-tive to the elderly). The dissimilarity index uses the formula ofRhode and Strumpf (2003) and indicates the extent to which resi-dents would need to move between cities in order to equalize theage distributions. The index is given by

D ¼ð1=2Þ

Pa

PjNjjPaj � Paj

NP

aPað1� PaÞ; ð17Þ

where Nj is the population in city j; N is the total population of thecountry, Pja is the population share of age category a in city j, and Pa

is the overall share of age category a in the country’s population.The index takes the value 0 when each age category is equallyrepresented in all cities and 1 when the age groups are completelysegregated, so that a higher value of the index indicates greaterheterogeneity across cities. Mean index values for both thepre- and post-reform years are shown in the upper panel of Table 7,with four different versions of the index reported. The ‘‘overall’’ ver-sion makes use of the definition in (17), with a running across thethree age categories. The CH, YO and EL versions are based a mod-ified version of (17) that involves only a single age category, so thatthere is no summation across a. As can be seen in Table 7, theresults are mixed, with less post-reform heterogeneity for childrenand the elderly, but with more heterogeneity for youth. In addition,

the Table shows a slight increase in overall post-reformheterogeneity.14

Since there is only a single dissimilarity value for each year, useof the index in a regression framework like that of Table 6 is notworkable. A different approach, however, is to use jPaj � Paj=Pa,the (relative) absolute difference between a city’s population sharein a particular age group and the national-average share Pa, as adependent variable in a regression with city fixed effects, a post-re-form dummy, and a linear time trend, paralleling columns 1, 3 and5 of Table 6. This approach yields the results shown in the bottompanel of Table 7, where the ‘‘overall’’ regression uses a compositevariable (see the table note). The individual heterogeneity trendsare significantly negative for children and the elderly, while theyouth trend as well as the overall trend are significantly positive.While two of the individual post-reform coefficients are insignifi-cant, the elderly coefficient is positive, as is the overall post-reformcoefficient. This latter result is striking, showing that, as predicted,the reform increased the overall age-group heterogeneity of cities,an outcome that is consistent with greater age-based sorting of thepopulation related to the targeting of education services.

6. Conclusion

This paper provides an empirical test of a principal tenet of fis-cal federalism: that spending discretion, when granted to localities,allows public-good levels to adjust in response to local demands.The test is based on a simple model of partial fiscal decentraliza-tion, under which earmarking of central transfers for particularuses is eliminated, allowing funds to be spent according to localtastes. The model predicts that under partial decentralization, thedemographic characteristics of local jurisdictions should play abigger role in determining the levels of public goods after a decen-tralization reform than before. This prediction receives supportfrom the paper’s empirical results, which show that local demanddeterminants matter more after the 1986 Norwegian reform thanbefore it, and that the reform may have increased incentives for

L.-E. Borge et al. / Journal of Urban Economics 80 (2014) 153–163 163

population sorting. These findings are important because they rep-resent an affirmation of a central, but seldom-tested, principle ofpublic economics.

Acknowledgments

We thank Spencer Banzhaf, Jon Fiva, Arnt Ove Hopland, KangohLee, Albert Solé-Ollé, Will Strange, and several referees for helpfulcomments. We are also grateful to the following discussants forcomments: John Ashworth (‘‘End of Federalism’’ conference atWZB in Berlin, 2012), Norman Gemmell (LAV #11 conference inMarseille, 2012), Federico Revelli (‘‘Workshop on Fiscal Federal-ism’’ in Barcelona, 2013), and Enlinson Mattos (IIPF congress inTaormina, 2013). We also thank audiences at the 2013 EEA confer-ence in Gothenburg and the Einaudi Institute of Economics and Fi-nance for feedback.

References

Ahlin, A., Mork, E., 2008. Effects of decentralization on school resources. Economicsof Education Review 27, 276–284.

Arzaghi, M., Henderson, J.V., 2005. Why countries are fiscally decentralizing. Journalof Public Economics 89, 1157–1189.

Banzhaf, S., Walsh, R.P., 2008. Do people vote with their feet? An empirical test ofTiebout’s mechanism. American Economic Review 98, 843–863.

Barankay, I., Lockwood, B., 2007. Decentralization and the productive efficiency ofgovernment: evidence from Swiss cantons. Journal of Public Economics 91,1197–1218.

Bayer, P., Timmins, C., 2007. Estimating equilibrium models of sorting acrosslocations. Economic Journal 117, 353–374.

Besley, T., Coate, S., 2003. Centralized vs. decentralized provision of local publicgoods: a political economy analysis. Journal of Public Economics 87, 2611–2637.

Borge, L.-E., Rattsø, J., 1993. Dynamic responses to changing demand: a model of thereallocation process in small and large municipalities in Norway. AppliedEconomics 25, 589–598.

Borge, L.-E., Rattsø, J., 1995. Demographic shift, relative costs and the allocation oflocal public consumption in Norway. Regional Science and Urban Economics 25,705–726.

Borge, L.-E., Rattsø, J., 2002. Spending growth with vertical fiscal imbalance:decentralized government spending in Norway 1880–1990. Economics andPolitics 14, 351–373.

Borge, L.-E., Rattsø, J., 2008. Generational Conflict and the Disadvantage of BeingPart of a Large Cohort: Empirical Analysis of Demography and Welfare ServiceProduction in Denmark. CESifo Working Paper 2223.

Brueckner, J.K., 2004. Fiscal decentralization with distortionary taxation: Tiebout vs.tax competition. International Tax and Public Finance 11, 133–153.

Brueckner, J.K., 2009. Partial fiscal decentralization. Regional Science and UrbanEconomics 39, 23–32.

Carlsen, F., Johansen, K., Stambøl, L., 2013. Effects of regional labor markets onmigration flows, by education level. Labor 27, 80–92.

Eberts, R., Gronberg, T.J., 1981. Jurisdictional homogeneity and the Tiebouthypothesis. Journal of Urban Economics 10, 227–239.

Faguet, J.-P., 2004. Does decentralization increase government responsiveness tolocal needs? Evidence from Bolivia. Journal of Public Economics 88, 867–893.

Hatfield, J.W., Padró i Miguel, G., 2012. A political economy theory of partialdecentralization. Journal of the European Economic Association 10, 605–633.

Jametti, M., Joanis, M., 2011. Electoral Competition as a Determinant of FiscalDecentralization. Unpublished paper, University of Sherbrooke, Canada.

Lockwood, B., 2002. Distributive politics and the costs of centralization. Review ofEconomic Studies 69, 313–337.

Lorz, O., Willmann, G., 2005. On the endogenous allocation of decision powers infederal structures. Journal of Urban Economics 57, 242–257.

Lotz, J., 1998. Local government reforms in the Nordic countries, theory andpractice. In: Rattso, J. (Ed.), Fiscal Federalism and State-Local Finance: TheScandinavian Approach. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.

Oates, W.E., 1969. The effects of property taxes and local public spending onproperty values: an empirical study of tax capitalization and the Tiebouthypothesis. Journal of Political Economy 77, 957–971.

Oates, W.E., 1972. Fiscal Federalism. Harcourt Brace, New York.Pack, H., Pack, J., 1978. Metropolitan fragmentation and local public expenditure.

National Tax Journal 31, 349–362.Panizza, U., 1999. On the determinants of fiscal centralization: theory and evidence.

Journal of Public Economics 74, 97–139.Peralta, S., 2012. Partial fiscal decentralization, local elections, and accountability.

Unpublished paper, Nova School of Business and Economics, Lisbon.OECD, 1999. Taxing Powers of State and Local Governments. Organization for

Economic Cooperation and Development, Paris.Rattsø, J., 2004. Fiscal adjustment under centralized federalism: empirical

evaluation of the response to budgetary shocks. Finanzarchiv 60, 240–261.Rodden, J., Eskeland, G., Litvack, J., 2003. Fiscal Decentralization and the Challenge

of the Hard Budget Constraint. MIT Press, Cambridge, Mass.Rhode, P.W., Strumpf, K.S., 2003. Assessing the importance of Tiebout sorting: local

heterogeneity from 1850 to 1990. American Economic Review 93, 1648–1677.Schwager, R., 1999. Administrative federalism and a central government with

regionally based preferences. International Tax and Public Finance 6, 165–189.Shah, A., 2004. Fiscal Decentralization in Developing and Transition Economies,

Unpublished Paper, World Bank.Shah, A., Shah, S., 2006. The New Vision of Local Governance and the Evolving Roles

of Local Governments, Unpublished Paper, World Bank.Sigman, H., 2007. Decentralization and Environmental Quality: An International

Analysis of Water Pollution. National Bureau of Economic Research WorkingPaper #13098.

Tiebout, C.M., 1956. A pure theory of local expenditures. Journal of PoliticalEconomy 64, 416–424.

Wildasin, D.E., 1986. Urban Public Finance. Harwood Academic Publishers, Chur,Switzerland.

Zhuravskaya, E., 2000. Incentives to provide local public goods: fiscal federalism,Russian style. Journal of Public Economics 76, 337–368.


Recommended