+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing,...

Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing,...

Date post: 01-Mar-2021
Category:
Upload: others
View: 3 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
21
Online Appendix 1 Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation 1 Mark A. Lemley 2 & Robin Feldman 3 Abstract Traditional justifications for patents are all based on direct or indirect contribution to the creation of new products. Patents serve the social interest if they provide not just invention, but innovation the world would not otherwise have. Non-practicing entities (NPEs) as well as product-producing companies can sometimes provide such innovation, either directly, through working the patent or transfer of technology to others who do, or indirectly, when others copy the patented innovation. The available evidence suggests, however, that patent licensing demands and lawsuits from NPEs are normally not cases that involve any of these activities. Some scholars have argued that patents can be valuable even without technology transfer because the ability to exclude others from the market may drive commercialization that would not otherwise occur. We demonstrate that even if various commercialization theories can sometimes justify patent protection, they cannot justify most NPE lawsuits or licensing demands. 1 © 2016 Robin Feldman & Mark A. Lemley. 2 William H. Neukom Professor, Stanford Law School; partner, Durie Tangri LLP. 3 Harry & Lillian Hastings Professor, University of California Hastings College of the Law. Thanks to Rose Hagan, Josh Lerner, Carl Shapiro, and participants at the American Economics Association annual meeting for comments on a prior draft.
Transcript
Page 1: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

1

PatentLicensing,TechnologyTransfer,&Innovation1

MarkA.Lemley2&RobinFeldman3

Abstract

Traditionaljustificationsforpatentsareallbasedondirectorindirectcontributiontothe

creationofnewproducts.Patentsservethesocialinterestiftheyprovidenotjustinvention,but

innovationtheworldwouldnototherwisehave.Non-practicingentities(NPEs)aswellas

product-producingcompaniescansometimesprovidesuchinnovation,eitherdirectly,through

workingthepatentortransferoftechnologytootherswhodo,orindirectly,whenotherscopy

thepatentedinnovation.Theavailableevidencesuggests,however,thatpatentlicensing

demandsandlawsuitsfromNPEsarenormallynotcasesthatinvolveanyoftheseactivities.

Somescholarshavearguedthatpatentscanbevaluableevenwithouttechnology

transferbecausetheabilitytoexcludeothersfromthemarketmaydrivecommercializationthat

wouldnototherwiseoccur.Wedemonstratethatevenifvariouscommercializationtheories

cansometimesjustifypatentprotection,theycannotjustifymostNPElawsuitsorlicensing

demands.

1©2016RobinFeldman&MarkA.Lemley.2WilliamH.NeukomProfessor,StanfordLawSchool;partner,DurieTangriLLP.3Harry&LillianHastingsProfessor,UniversityofCaliforniaHastingsCollegeoftheLaw.ThankstoRoseHagan,JoshLerner,CarlShapiro,andparticipantsattheAmericanEconomicsAssociationannualmeetingforcommentsonapriordraft.

Page 2: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

2

1. Innovation-RelatedJustificationsforNPEs

Thepatentsystemexiststoserveutilitariangoals,ratherthantoreflectsomenotionof

aninventor’smoralright.(Feldman2012,Lemley1997,Landes&Posner2003).Fromthemany

commercialactivitiesthatmightotherwisebeopentoanyone,weremovesomeforalimited

periodoftimeinthehopethatdedicatingthemtotheprovinceofafew,willredoundtothe

benefitofusall.(Feldman2013).

Thetraditionalutilitarianstorysupportingthepatentsystemisthatthelureofpatent

rightsencouragesinventionthatwouldnototherwiseoccur,orattheleastwouldoccurlater

butforthepatent.(Landes&Posner,2003;Duffy2004).Theinventionthesystemisdesigned

topromoteisnotwhatisknowninscienceas“basicresearch,”suchasanunderstandingof

hownatureworksorwhatforcespropeltheuniverse.Afterall,formorethanacentury,the

Courtshaveremindedusthatthepropersubjectmatterofapatentdoesnotincludelawsof

nature,naturalphenomenon,orabstractideas—nomatterhowvaluableandessentialtothe

progressofsciencethesemaybe.(AliceCorp.Pty.Ltd.v.CLSInt’l,134S.Ct.2347,2354(2014))

Rather,thepatentsystemisaimedatprotecting“applied”inventions,orinnovations,thatare

deployedintheworld.Onlywhenbroadandbasicprinciplesarereducedtoaparticular

practiceandappliedinaspecificendeavorwilltheybeeligibleforprotection.(Bilskiv.Kappos,

561U.S.593(2010)).

Thepatentsystem’sfocusisconsistentwitheconomicliterature,whichdistinguishes

invention—anidea—frominnovation—turningtheideaintoaviableproduct.Thepatent

Page 3: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

3

systemencouragesnotjustinventionintheabstract,butthecreationofnewproducts.Thisis

the“progress”ofthe“usefularts”mentionedinthepatentclauseoftheConstitution.

Thefocusoninnovation,notsimplyinvention,isparticularlyimportantwiththe

emergenceofthemodernnon-practicingentity(NPE)businessmodel.Colloquiallyknownas

patenttrolls,NPEsarethosewhosecoreactivityinvolveslicensingorlitigatingpatents,as

opposedtomakingproducts.Byallaccounts,themodernNPEbusinessmodelhasexpanded

rapidlysinceitsemergenceoverthelasttwodecades,anexpansionthatisparticularlyevident

inthecontextoflitigation.(Allisonetal.,2016).Differentscholarsslicethenumbers

differently,withsomeexcludingNPEsorganizedastrustsandindividualsandothersexcluding

“failedstartups”andoriginalinventors,forexample.Whenthebroaderdefinitionisapplied,

however,thedataareremarkablyconsistentacrossstudies,withallshowingthatNPEsnow

accountforthemajorityofpatentlawsuitsfiled.4

Consistentwiththegoalsofthepatentsystem,alloftheargumentssuggestingthe

benefitsofNPEsrestontheircontributions,eitherdirectlyorindirectly,tothecreationof

productssomewhereinthesystem.NPEs,unlikepracticingentities,donotdeploythe

technologyintheworldthemselves,butthatdoesnotanswerthequestionofwhetherthey

contributetoinnovationandthecreationofnewproducts.Topromoteinnovation,however,

theymustnotonlyinvent,butthatinventionmustleadtothecreationofproductsby

someone,somewhereinthesystem,atsomepoint.NPEsmaybeactingasmiddlemen4CompareFeldmanetal.,2013;Chien,2012(usingdatafromRPXCorporationandconcludingthatthepercentageoflitigationbynon-practicingentitiesin2012hasreached62%)withCotropiaetal.2014(usinganarrowerdefinitionofNPEsandfindingnorealincreaseinNPElitigationwhencomparingtheyears2010and2012,butalsonotingthat“whenwerepackageall[NPEs]intoasinglecategory,theyareresponsibleforamajorityof[patentlawsuits]in2012”);seealsoSag,2016(findingthatpatentlitigationvolumedoubledfrom2010to2013).

Page 4: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

4

transferringtechnologytothosewhowouldimplementit;ortheycouldbecollectingrevenue

fromthosewhocopiedtheirinventionandimplementedit.Neitherpossibility,however,

appearsbroadlysupportedbytheavailableevidence.

Thereisasubstantialliteraturethatcallsintoquestionwhetherthepatentsystemin

generalencouragesinnovationthatwouldnototherwisehappen.Thefactsthatmost

significantinnovationsaresimultaneouslycreatedbytwoormorepeople(Lemley,2012),and

thatinmostindustriesvirtuallyallpatentenforcementisdoneagainstindependentinventors

(Cotropia&Lemley,2009)castsignificantdoubtontheclaimthattheinnovationswouldnot

havehappenedbutforthelureofapatent.Theissueis,however,complicatedbythevery

differentcharacteristicsofdifferentindustries.Theremaybeindustriesinwhichinventionisso

complexanduncertainthatitwouldnotbeundertakenwithoutpatentprotection.(Burk&

Lemley,2009).Buttherealsoseemtobeindustries–perhapsmostofthem–inwhichthe

patentsystemdoesnotseemtobedrivingnewinvention,andmayevenberetardingit.

(Bessen&Meurer,2008).Thatmightleadonetoquestionthepatentsystemasawhole

(Boldrin&Levine,2007),oratleastthetraditionalinnovation-basedjustificationforit.

Inadditiontodoubtsabouthowwellpatentsingeneralactuallydriveinnovationsthat

wouldnototherwisehaveoccurred,theevidencecastssignificantdoubtontheefficacyofthe

patentdisclosureasawayofdisseminatingideasandleadingtothecreationofproducts.

Whilewritingdownandpublishingadescriptionoftheinventionhaslongbeenaquidproquo

forapatent,inthemodernworldthereisgoodreasontothinkthatengineersinmanyfields

rarelyreadpatentsinordertolearnaboutatechnology.(Lemley,2008;Lemley,2012;Harvard

Page 5: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

5

Note,2005).5Therearemanyreasonsforthis.Lawyersatmanycompaniesdiscouragetheir

engineersfromreadingpatentsforfearofincreasinglegalliability.(Lemley&Tangri,2003).

Thequalityofthedisclosureinthepatentmaybepoor,particularlyintheITindustries.(Burk&

Lemley,2002;Feldman;2012,othercites).Therearesimplytoomanypatentsinmanyfieldsto

possiblykeepupwith,and600,000moreapplicationsarefiledeveryyear.Andinafast-moving

industrylikeITadelayofseveralyearsbetweeninventionanddisclosuremaymakethe

technologydescribedobsoletebythetimeanyonecouldreadit.(Feldman&Lemley,2015).

Further,economicliteraturesuggeststhatinorderforeffectivetechnologytransfer—in

otherwords,transferthatcanleadtocommercialization—readingapatentaloneisnot

enough.Suchtransfergenerallymustincludenotonlytheinformationpubliclyavailableinthe

patent,butalsothetransferofknow-how,complementaryassetsandotherperipheral

disclosures.(Bessen,2015;Teece,1986;Rantanen,2012).Thus,ifpatentsactuallydrive

innovationbythirdpartieswewouldexpecttoseenotsimplypatentingbutbusiness

transactionsthatinvolvethetransferofothertypesofinformationassets.

Alternatively,NPEscoulddriveinnovationiftheyservedasefficientmiddlemen,

connectingthosewhoinventbutwhoseinventionshavenotbeendeployedwiththosewhocan

produceaproductfromthatinvention.SeveralpeoplehavearguedthatNPEsservethisrole.

(Khan2014;Spulber,2012;Crane,2009;)Here,too,aninnovationbenefitrequirestechnology

transfer.Thesocialbenefitofthemiddlemanstorydependsonthemiddlemanproviding

somethingofvaluetotheimplementer.

5Bycontrast,insomefieldspatentsmayprovidemoreusefulguidancetoengineers.(Ouellette,2012).

Page 6: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

6

Inshort,then,thetraditionaljustificationsforNPEscontributingtosocialwelfareall

involvesomeformoftechnologytransferorlearningdisseminationbywhichtheNPEorthe

patentitholdsteachestheimplementeratechnologyitdidnototherwisepossess.Practicing

entitiescanbenefitsocialwelfarewithouttechnologytransferbymakingandsellingthe

inventiondirectly;NPEscannot.

EarlyevidencetestingthepositiveimpactofNPEsoncommercializationgoalsisnot

encouraging.Theevidenceislargelyobservationalinnature,flowingfromsmallsamplestudies,

withalloftheattendantlimitations.Nevertheless,thedataprovideausefulwindowonthe

NPEbusinessmodelandsuggestapproachesforgeneralizableanalyses.

FeldmanandLemleyprovidesurveyevidenceofthedirectmeasureofthecreationof

newproductsasaresultofpatentassertionsbyNPEs.Wealsotestcommercializationeffects

bymeasuringothermarkersofpotentialinnovation,suchastechnologytransferbeyondthe

patent.(Feldman&Lemley,2015).Includingsuchmarkerscreatesamoredynamicpictureof

thepotentialforfuturecommercialization,evenifthatcommercializationhasyettooccur.

Weknowthatactualtechnologytransferhappenswithinthepatentsystemintheex

antecontext.(Arora,2001).BothpracticingentitiesandsomeNPEsengageinexante

technologytransfer.Inparticular,universitiesandinventorscreateallianceswithcompanies

thatcanmoreeasilydevelopandcommercializetheirinventionsthroughjointventuresand

othertypesoftechnologyandresearchsharingagreements.(Feldman&Lemley,2015).These

agreementsfrequentlyoccurbeforeapatentissuesorevenbeforeanyofthepartiesfilefora

patent.Notably,theseagreementsinvolvetechnologytransfer.Universitiesandother

inventorsinthesedealsprovidenewtechnologytothoseinapositiontoimplementit.And

Page 7: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

7

thattechnologyoftenincludestradesecretsandknow-howbeyondtheto-be-patented

technologyitself.

Patentlitigationandlicensingdemandsforexistingpatents,bycontrast,tendtooccur

afterthedefendanthasalreadydevelopedandimplementedthetechnology.Thisis

particularlytrueofNPEpatentassertionsandlicensingdemands,whichsomeevidence

suggeststendtohappeninthelastfewyearsofapatent’slife,althoughthepictureis

complicated.(Love,2013;Feldman,Ewing&Jeruss,2013).NPElicensingdemandsand

litigationagainstcompaniesthatareproducingproductsdonotseemtoinvolvetechnology

transferorotherindiciaofnewinnovation.

WhilesomehavearguedthatNPEsserveasefficientmiddlementhroughthisactivity,

transferringinventionsfromcreatorstocommercializers,FeldmanandLemleyfoundnosuch

evidence.Theauthorssurveyed181in-houselicensingattorneysatcompaniesthatproduce

products,onthetheorythatthesepartieshavedirectknowledgeofwhetherthecompany

implementednewtechnologyandbecausein-housecounselstendtonegotiatelicensesbothas

patentholdersandaspotentiallicensees.Thesurveyexaminedtheeffectsoflicensesthata

companytookafterreceivingapatentdemand,whichwasdefinedtoincludecallsorletters

suggestingareasofmutualinterestorjointventures,offeringtolicensepatents,threatening

litigation,givingnoticeofintenttofileaninfringementlawsuitoractuallyfilinginfringement

lawsuit.Respondentswereaskedwhetherthoselicensesledtoanymarkersofinnovation.

Directmarkersofinnovationincludedtheadditionofnewproductsorfeatures.Indirect

markersofinnovationincludedwhetherthepatentholdertransferredknow-howorother

technicalknowledgealongwiththepatent,whetherthepatentholdertransferredpersonnel

Page 8: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

8

(includingthroughaconsultingagreement),andwhetheranyjointventureswerecreated.

Again,thesurveyconsideredonlylicensestakeninresponsetounsolicitedlicensingrequests.It

didnotlookatthepractice,particularlyamonguniversityinventors,ofenteringintotechnology

transferagreementsbeforeembarkingondevelopmentofanewtechnology.

TheresponsessuggestthatlicensingrequestsfromNPEsrarelyleadtodirectorindirect

markersofinnovation.Ninety-twopercentofrespondentsreportingthattheyaddednew

productsorfeaturesfromzero-10%ofthetime,withNPElicensing.Theresultswereeven

strongerwhenrespondentswereaskedaboutindirectmarkersofinnovation,withrespondents

reportingwithcompleteunanimitythattheyrarereceivedtechnicalknowledge,transferof

personnelorjointventuresalongwithapatentlicense.Thus,theresultssuggestthatNPEsdo

notappeartobeplayingtheroleofefficientmiddlemen.Whileitiscertainlypossiblethata

middlemanrolecouldbereflectedinsomeothermarkersthantheonesweexamined,wedid

notfindsuchevidenceinourpreliminarywork.

Interestingly,theevidencewasalsodismalwhenexpostlicensingrequestscamefrom

thoseotherthantraditionalNPEs.Whenproductproducingcompaniesanduniversitiesmade

unsolicitedapproachesandthoseapproachesresultedinalicensingagreement,the

agreementswereunlikelytoleadtodirectorindirectmarkersofinnovation.Three-quartersof

respondentsreportednewproductsorfeaturesfromzeroto10percentofthetime;88%of

respondentsreportedtransfersofknowledgezeroto10percentofthetime;94%reported

transfersofpersonnel(includingthroughconsultingagreements)zeroto10percentofthe

time;and91%reportedjointventuresfromzeroto10%ofthetime.(Feldman&Lemley,

2015).Theseobservationalresultssuggestthatexpostpatentlicensingdemandsdonotappear

Page 9: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

9

toleadtotechnologytransferorothermarkersofinnovation,nomatterwhattypeofparty

initiatestheunsolicitedapproach.

Amiddlemanwhoisnotmakingaproductandnotactuallyprovidingthelicenseewith

newtechnologyisoperatingatmostasataxcollectorforinventorswhocouldnototherwisedo

battleagainstlargecompanieswhohaveimplementedtheirideas.(Feldman&Lemley,2015).

Buttransactionsarenotdesirablefortheirownsake.(Burstein,2015)Itissociallydesirableto

imposesuchataxoninnovatorsonlyiftheworldgainssomethingfromit.Thatmightbetrue

if,forinstance,theimplementerhadactuallycopiedtheideafromthepatentee.Ifwethink

copyingcouldreduceincentivestoinvent,wemightreasonablyprefertoforcecopiersinto

licensingarrangementsinstead,compensatingtheinventorwhoseworkiscopied.

Theavailableevidencesuggestsitisunlikelythatmostpatentenforcementtargetssuch

copying.Forexample,CotropiaandLemleydemonstratethatmostpatentlawsuitsarefiled

againstthosewhohavedevelopedaproductindependently,ratherthanthosewhohavetaken

theideafromapatentholder.(Cotropia&Lemley,2009).Andwhilesomehavespeculated

thatdefendantsmaycopyindirectly,learningabouttheinventionfromthepatentee’sproduct

orfromscientificdiscussionsoftheideawithouteverreadingthepatentitself(Merges,2014),

thatisfarmorelikelywhenthepatenteeactuallymakesaproductthanwhenitproduces

nothingotherthanthepatent.Further,thereisevidencethatNPEstendtoassertpatentsat

theendoftheirlives,whilepracticingentitiesassertpatentsearly,furtheringcastingdoubton

thecopyingstory.(Love,2013).6Andthereisverylittleevidencethatpatenteeshaveuseda

6We(andLove)acknowledgethattheinterpretationofhisdataiscomplicatedbythechangeinthenumberofNPEsuitsduringthetimeofhisstudy.(Feldman,Ewing&Jeruss2013).

Page 10: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

10

remedycreatedin1999toprotectagainstcopyingofpublishedpatentapplications.35U.S.C.

§154(d).

Somehavesuggestedadifferenttheoryoftaxcollection–thatNPEpatentsuitsprovide

analternativewayforventurecapitaliststorecoversomeinvestmentinafailedinvention.We

areskepticalthatventurecapitalistsaremuchmotivatedbytheprospectofasortof

consolationprize.Theytellusthattheyaren’t;insurveyresponsestheyindicatethatitisthe

prospectofabigwin,notthepossibilityofrecoveringsomemoneyfromafailedinvestment,

thatmotivatesthem.(Feldman,2014).Butevenifthereweresomemarginalincentiveto

additionalinvestmentfromNPEtaxation,thathastobeweighedagainstthecostimposedon

successful,product-implementingbusinesses,aswellasonstartupsthemselves.Inparticular,

venturecapitalistsnotethatifastartupcompanyhasapatentassertionagainstit,thatwould

beasignificantdeterrentforanyfundingrequest.(Feldman,2014).Finally,itisworthnoting

thatamajorityofNPEsuitstargetsmallcompaniessuchasventure-fundedstartups,notlarge

companies(Chien2014).Thus,atbest,manyoftheseNPEsuitswouldbetaxingsomeventure-

backedstartupsforthebenefitofsubsidizingothers.Thatseemsadubiouspolicyidea.

2. “Commercialization-Plus”Justifications

Respondingtosomeoftheconcernswithtraditionaljustificationsforpatentprotection

andlicensing,anumberofscholarshavearticulatedwhatwecall“commercialization-plus”

justificationsforpatentprotection.(Kitch,1977;Abramowicz,2007;Kieff,2001;Abramowicz&

Duffy,2008;Sichelman,2010).Thesejustificationsdifferfromthetraditionalinnovation-based

justificationsbecausetheyfocusontheallegedneedforearlyoradditionalprotectionsto

Page 11: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

11

encouragepost-inventioninvestmentincommercialization.Themostfamousofthese,known

as“prospecttheory,”recommendsgrantingstrongpatentsearlyinthelifecycleofanideaso

thatasinglepartycancontroldevelopmentoftheideamuchthewaythatamineralprospector

managesamineralclaimsite.(Kitch,1977).Otherscholarshavesuggestedthatweshouldgrant

patentstooldtechnologiesinareaslikepharmaceuticalsinordertoencouragethepatent

ownertobringtheproducttomarket.(Roin,2009).Stillothershavesuggestedgrantingnormal

patentsattheoutset,andthen,ifnoonecommercializesit,grantingextrarightstotheperson

whodoes.(Sichelman,2010).TheBayh-DoleAct,passedin1980,waspremisedontheworry

thatuniversityinventionswouldlanguishunlessonepartywasgiventherighttoturnthose

inventionsintocommercialproducts.(CouncilonGovernmentRelations,1999).

Commercialization-plustheoriesarecontroversial.Lemleyamongothershascriticized

Kitch’sprospecttheoryas“fundamentallyanti-market”becauseitpresumesthatcentral

controlissuperiortomarketallocationofexistingresources,andFeldmanhasarguedthat

patentsareentirelyunlikethemoreclearlydefinedrightsinKitch’smineralanalogy.(Lemley,

2004;Lemley,1997;Lemley,2012;Feldman2012).Othershavesuggestedthat

commercializationtheoryispoorlyfittedtoindustriesinwhichinventionproceedsbystages

andimprovementsratherthanbydiscreteadvances.(Merges&Nelson,1990).

Kitch’stheorymayjustifypatentprotectionincertainindustries.BurkandLemley

suggestthatthetheorymapsbesttothepharmaceuticalindustry,wheregovernment

regulatorybarrierssignificantlyraisethecostofentryandmayrequireexclusivity.(Burk&

Lemley,2009).AnditmayjustifypatentprotectionforNPEsinsomecases,aswithuniversity

technologytransferagreements.(Kieff,2001)

Page 12: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

12

Notably,though,anyformofcommercializationtheoryisself-limitingincertain

importantrespects.First,ifexclusivityisnecessarytoinduceafirmtocommercializea

technology,weshouldrarely,ifever,seemultiplecompaniesindependentlydevelopthesame

technology.Theveryconceptofcommercializationtheoryisthatnoonewouldinvestin

developingandcommercializingthetechnologyunlesstheywerefirstconfidenttheywould

haveexclusiverightsoverthattechnology.Theremaybeexceptionsinwhichcompanies

engageinpatentracing,eachhopingtobethefirsttoreachanimportantinvention.(Barzel,

1968;Tirole,1988;Dasgupta&Stiglitz,1980;Grady&Alexander,1992;Reinganum,1989).But

thehistoricalexamplesofpatentraceshavetendedtoberacestoinvent,notracesto

commercialize.(Lemley,2012).Ifcommercializationtheoryiscorrect,evenindependent

inventorswon’tcommercializethetechnologyunlessanduntiltheyareconfidenttheywill

haveexclusiverightsoverthattechnology.Andracingtocommercialize(ratherthantoinvent)

ispresumablysomethingmostlyengagedinbypracticingentities,notNPEs.Forthesame

reason,undercommercializationtheoryweshouldn’tseeopensourceorpublicdomain

companies.Ifwedo,thatisreasonableevidencethatexclusivityisnotnecessarytoinduce

commercializationinthatindustry.(Asay,2015).

Further,ifanyformofcommercializationtheoryiscorrect,andcertainlyifenhanced

commercializationtheoryis,infringementshouldberare.Independentlaterinventors

shouldn’tcommercialize,sincetheywon’thaveexclusiverightstotheinvention.Norshould

weseemuchcopyingofthepatentee’sinvention,sinceifcommercializationrequiresmarket

exclusivitythecopierwon’tgenerallybeanybetteroffthananindependentinventorwho

doesn’thaveexclusivity.Thatdoesn’tmeanwewouldneverseepatentlitigation.Butitdoes

Page 13: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

13

meanthatifcommercializationtheoryiscorrect,itshouldinvolveexceptionalcircumstances

suchasalowerregulatoryburdenonsecondentrants(trueofgenericpharmaceutical

companies)orsomereasontothinkthatsimplyknowingthatamarketexistssomehow

dramaticallyreducesthecostsofcommercialization.Theremaybesuchcases.Applev.

Samsungisarguablyone.Butthosecaseswouldinvolvecopyingofexistingmarket

participants.

Athirdimplicationofcommercialization-plustheoryisthatpatentownersshould

generallynotgrantnonexclusivelicenses.Ifthistypeoftheoryiscorrect,universitiesshouldbe

grantingexclusivelicensestopracticingentitiesinanygivenmarket,sincethelicenseeneeds

thatexclusivitytocommercializetheinvention.Nonexclusivelicensesshouldberareand

tightlycontrolled,sincethenonexclusivelicenseeswouldhavetocoordinatetheirproduction

andpricingdecisionsundercommercializationtheory.Andnonexclusivelicensestomultiple

partiesshouldbenonexistent,sinceallowingopenentryintoamarketisinimicaltothetheory

ofcommercialization.Infact,however,theevidencesuggestsnotonlythatnonexclusive

licensingbyuniversitiesiscommon,butthatthelackofexclusivityisanimportantdriverof

subsequentimprovementforcoreenablingtechnologies.(Lemley,2005).

Evenifcommercializationtheoryjustifiespatentprotectioninsomeindustries,itcannot

justifymostmodernpatentlitigation.NorcanitjustifyexpostlicensingdemandsbyNPEs.

Outsidethepharmaceuticalindustries,NPElicensingdoesnotlookmuchlikecommercialization

theorywouldpredict.ThereisevidencethatNPEpatentsareassertedlateinlife,(Love,2013),

andalmostalwaysagainstindependentinventors.(Cotropia&Lemley,2009).ExpostNPE

patentlicensesdon’ttransferthetechnologytoapartythatcanlatermakeuseofit.(Feldman

Page 14: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

14

&Lemley,2015).AndNPEpatentlicensingdemandsessentiallyalwaysseeknonexclusive

licensesfrommultipleparties,notanexclusivelicensefromasingleparty.Indeed,NPEs

commonlysuetwentyormoredefendantsinthesameindustryandthesametime,settling

witheachoftheminexchangeforanonexclusivelicense.(Allisonetal.,2009).

TheevidencealsosuggeststhatNPEsaretargetingsuccessfulcommercializers,not

facilitatingnewcommercialization.Feldman&Frondorfstudied50productcompaniesthat

hadinitialpublicofferingsbetween2007and2012.(Feldman&Frondorf,2016;Feldman,

2014;Chien,2014).Theauthorsfoundthatthat40%ofrespondentsreceivedpatentdemands

duringtheperiodsaroundthetimeoftheIPOs,withthosedemandscominglargelyfromNPEs.

Theeffectswereevenmorepronouncedforinformationtechnologycompanies,withalmost

60%ofrespondentsreportingpatentdemandsaroundthetimeoftheirIPOs.Similarly,Cohen,

Gurun,&Kominersfoundthatacompanywas50%morelikelytobesuedbyanNPEfollowinga

large,positivecashshocksuchasafundingeventoranIPO,andthatacashshockwasa

significantpredictorofthenumberoftimesacompanywassuedbyNPEs.(Cohenetal.,2015).

Theauthorsfoundfurtherthatnootherformoflitigationhasthesametypeofcashtargeting

behavior--nottorts,contracts,securities,environmental,orlaborlaw.Nothing,butpatent

law.TheresultssuggestthatNPEdemandbehaviormaybedrivenbythelureofdeeppockets

andtheleverageopportunitiesaffordedbyanIPOperiod,ratherthanthemeritorious

representationofclaimsthatawrongedinventorcouldnotbringonitsown.Suchstudiesalso

provideareminderthatanyvirtuousbenefitsofNPEactivityshouldbeevaluatedagainstany

coststoinnovationandsociety.(Bessen&Meurer,2014;Morton&Shapiro,2014).

Page 15: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

15

Allformsofcommercializationandproduct-basedtheorieshaveafinal,surprising

implicationforNPEsuits.Ifthereasonweneedapatentisnottoinduceinventionbutto

inducecommercializationofthatinvention,thelawshouldpreferthosewhoactually

commercializetheinventionoverthosewhomerelyinventitbutdonothingfurther.Thus,the

ownersofthosepatentshavefailedintheirpurposeiftheyhaveneithercommercializedthe

inventionthemselvesorexclusivelylicensedthepatenttosomeonewhodoes.Suchan

approach,therefore,mayjustifyaworkingrequirement,somethingthatisgenerallyconsidered

anathematopatentadvocates.(Sichelman,2010).Further,asbetweentheNPEinventorwho

doesnotengageintechnologytransferandtheindependentinventordefendant,

commercializationandproduct-basedtheoriesshouldpreferthedefendant,sinceitisthe

defendant,notthepatentee,whohasachievedthegoalofthepatentsystem.

3. IndependentInventionandPriorUserRights

MostotherIPregimes,includingcopyrightandtradesecrets,exemptindependent

developmentfromlegalliability.Patentlaw,bycontrast,punishesanyonewhopracticesthe

claimedinvention,evenindependentinventors.Anumberofscholarshavesuggestedthat

patentlawshouldadoptsomeformofindependentinventionorprioruserrightsdefense.

(Shapiro,2006;Vermont,2006).Othershaveworriedthatanindependentinventiondefense

mightinterferewithpatentracesorincentivestocommercialize.(Lemley,2007).

Ouranalysissuggeststhatthepatentsystemmightsensiblyrequirethatapatentee

showeitherthatitpracticesinthemarketorthatithasengagedintechnologytransfertothose

Page 16: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

16

whothenputthetechnologyintopractice.7Apatenteewhocannotshoweitherwouldstillbe

abletoenforceitspatent,butonlyagainstthoseitcouldshowcopiedtheinventionfromit,

directlyorindirectly.Thishybridapproachtracksthelegaljustificationsthathavebeenoffered

forpatents.Aninventorwhodevelopsanideaotherscopywouldbeabletoenforcethepatent

againstthosecopiers,sincecopyingisaformoftechnologytransfer(andoneweviewas

sociallyinferiortoalicenseagreement).Aninventorwhoendsupdisseminatingtechnologyto

theworld,eitherbypracticingtheinventionorbytransferringtechnologytootherswhodo,

wouldbeabletoenforcethepatentagainstbothcopiersandindependentinfringers.Anda

practicingentitywouldsimilarlybeabletoenforcepatentsagainstbothcopiersand

independentinfringersonacommercializationtheory.

Introducingevensuchalimitedindependentinventiondefensewouldrequirecourtsto

evaluatedisputedclaimsofcopyingonsomecases.Somehaveworriedthatmuch

independentinventionisreallycopyingindisguise(Merges,2014),thoughothersareskeptical.

(Lemley,2012).AsSamVermonthasobserved,though,courtsarequitegoodatresolving

factualdisputesofthissort.Independentdevelopmentwilltendtoleaveapapertrail.Andthe

partieswillhaveanincentivetocollectandpresentevidenceonthequestion.Further,we

thinkcourtscanproperlyincludeintheconceptofcopyingcasesofindirectcopyingfroman

ideaonceithasbeenpublicizedbythepatentee.(Merges,2014).

Arequirementthatpatenteeswhodonotengageinanyformofcommercializationor

technologytransferprovethatthedefendantcopiedfromthemshouldbepairedwithstricter7Whileinanidealworldacourtmightwanttodeterminewhethertherewastransferofnon-patentknow-howalongwiththepatent,anylegalrulerequiringsuchatransferwouldleadtoshamtransactionsinwhichNPEsattacheduseless“know-how”toanonexclusivepatentlicenseinordertoobtainmorefavorabletreatment.

Page 17: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

17

penaltiesagainstthosedeemedtohavecopiedtheinvention.Itwouldbereasonableto

require,notmerelypermit,trebledamageawardsandattorneys’feesagainstthosefoundto

copy.Increasingthepenaltiesforthosewhoopttotaketechnologyfromapatenteewithout

paying,whileeliminatingthepenaltyimposedoninnovatorswhodonotbenefitfrompatentee

technologytransfer,properlyalignsthepatentsystem’sincentiveswiththeevidenceandthe

arrayoftheoreticaljustificationsforpatents.

Page 18: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

18

References

Abramowicz,Michael.2007."TheDangerofUnderdevelopedPatentProspects"92CornellLaw Review.1065.Abramowicz,Michael&Duffy,F.John.2008."IntellectualPropertyforMarket Experimentation"83NewYorkUniversityLawReview.337.Allison,JohnR.,Lemley,A.Mark,&Schwartz,David.2016(forthcoming)."HowOftenDoPAEs WinPatentSuits?"(workingpaper).Allison,JohnR.,Lemley,A.Mark,&Walker,Josh.2009."ExtremeValueorTrollsonTop? EvidencefromtheMost-LitigatedPatents"158UniversityofPennsylvaniaLawReview.Arora,Ashish.2001.MarketsforTechnology,TheMassachusettsInstituteofTechnologyPress.Asay,D.Clark.2015."EnablingParentlessInnovation"74MarylandLawReview.431.Barzel,Yoram.1968."OptimalTimingofInnovations"50ReviewYoramBarzel,"OptimalTimingofInnovations"50TheReviewofEconomicsandStatistics.348,

352(note11).Bessen,James.2015.LearningbyDoing,YaleUniversityPress.Bessen,James&Meurer,J.Michael.2008.PatentFailure:HowJudges,Lawyers,and

BureaucratsPutInnovationatRisk,PrincetonUniversityPress.Bessen,James&Meurer,J.Michael.2014."TheDirectCostsfromNPEDisputes"99CornellLaw

Review.387,411.Boldrin,Michele&Levine,David.2007.AgainstIntellectualMonopoly,CambridgeUniversity

Press.Burk,L.Dan&Lemley,A.Mark.2009.ThePatentCrisisandHowtheCourtsCanSolveIt,

UniversityofChicagoPress.Burstein,Michael.2015."PatentMarkets:AFrameworkforEvaluation"47ArizonaStateLaw

Journal.Chien,V.Colleen.2012."PatentAssertionEntities"PresentationtotheDOJ/FTCHearingon

PAES"(December10),availableathttp://ssrn.com/abstract=2187314.

Chien,V.Colleen.2014."StartupsandPatentTrolls"17StanfordTechnologyLawReview.

Page 19: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

19

Cohen,Burun&Kominers.2015."PatentTrolls:EvidencefromTargetedFirms"Harvard

BusinessSchoolWorkingPaperNo.15-002.Cotropia,A.Christopher.2014."UnpackingPatentAssertionEntities"99MinnesotaLaw

Review.649,655.Cotropia,A.Christopher.2009."CopyinginPatentLaw"87NorthCarolinaLawReview.1421.Crane,A.Daniel.2009."IntellectualLiability"88TexasLawReview.253,286-287.CouncilonGovernmentRelations.1999."TheBayh-DoleAct:AGuidetotheLawand

ImplementingRegulations."Dasgupta,Partha&Stiglitz,Joseph.1980."Uncertainty,IndustrialStructure,andtheSpeedof

R&D"11BellJournalofEconomics.1.

Duffy,F.John.2004."TheMarginalCostControversyinIntellectualProperty"71UniversityofChicagoLawReview.37.

Feldman,Robin.2012.RethinkingPatentLaw,HarvardUniversityPress.Feldman,Robin.2013."IntellectualPropertyWrongs"18StanfordJournalofLaw,Businessand

Finance.252.Feldman,Robin,Ewing,Tome,&Jeruss,Sara.2013."TheAIA500Expanded:TheEffectsof

PatentMonetizationEntities"17UCLAJournalofLawandTechnology.1,42.Feldman,Robin&Frondorf,Evan.2016(forthcoming)."PatentDemandsandInitialPublic

Offerings"StanfordTechnologyLawReview.Feldman,Robin.2014."PatentDemands&StartupCompanies:TheViewformtheVenture

CapitalCommunity"16YaleJournalofLawandTechnology.236.Feldman,Robin&Lemley,A.Mark.2015."DoPatentLicensingDemandsMeanInnovation"101

IowaLawReview.137,139.Grady,F.Mark&Alexander,I.Jay.1992."PatentLawandRentDissipation"78VirginiaLaw

Review.305,306.Kahn,ZorinaB.2014."TrollsandOtherPatentInventions:EconomicHistoryandthePatent

ControversyintheTwenty-FirstCentury"21GeorgeMasonLawReview.825,832.Kieff,ScottF.2001."PropertyRightsandPropertyRulesforCommercializingInventions"85

Page 20: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

20

MinnesotaLawReview.697.Kitch,W.Edmund.1977."TheNatureandFunctionofthePatentSystem"20JournalofLawand

Economics.265,275-280.Landes,M.William&Posner,A.Richard.2003.TheEconomicStructureofIntellectualProperty

Law,HarvardUniversityPress.Lemley,A.Mark.1997."TheEconomicsofImprovementinIntellectualProperty"75TexasLaw

Review.989.Lemley,A.Mark.2012."TheMythoftheSoleInventor"110MichiganLawReview.709.Lemley,A.Mark.2005."PatentNanotechnology"58StanfordLawReview.601.Lemley,A.Mark.2004."ExAnteVersusExPostJustificationsforIntellectualProperty"71 UniversityofChicagoLawReview.129.Lemley,A.Mark.2007."ShouldPatentInfringementRequireProofofCopying?"105Michigan LawReview.1525.Lemley,A.Mark.2008."IgnoringPatents"2008MichiganStateLawReview.19.Lemley,A.Mark.2009."ACautiousDefenseofIntellectualOligopolywithFringeCompetition"5

ReviewofLawandEconomics.3.Lemley,A.Mark&Melamed,DouglasA.2013."MissingtheForestfortheTrolls"113Columbia

LawReview.2117.Lemley,A.Mark&Tangri,K.Ragesh.2003."EndingPatentlaw'sWillfulnessGame"18Berkeley

TechnologyLawJournal.1085.Love,Brian.2013."AnEmpiricalStudyofPatentLitigationTiming:CouldaPatentTerm

ReductionDecimateTrollsWithoutHarmingInnovators?"161UniversityofPennsylvaniaLawReview.1309.

Merges,P.Robert.2014."AFewKindWordsforAbsoluteInfringementLiabilityinPatentlaw,"

availableathttp://ssrn.com/abstract=2464756.Merges,P.Robert&Nelson,R.Richard.1990."OntheComplexEconomicsofPatentScope"90

ColumbiaLawReview.839.

Page 21: Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 · 2016. 6. 20. · Patent Licensing, Technology Transfer, & Innovation1 Mark A. Lemley2 & Robin Feldman3 Abstract Traditional

OnlineAppendix

21

Morton,M.ScottFiona&Shapiro,Carl.2014."StrategicPatentAcquisitions"79AntitrustLaw

Journal.463,482-483.Note.2005."TheDisclosureFunctionofthePatentSystem(orLackThereof)"118HarvardLaw

Review.2007,2025-2026.Ouellette,LarrimoreLisa.2012."DoPatentsDiscloseUsefulInformation?"25HarvardJournal

ofLaw7Technology.531.Rantanen,Jason.2012."PeripheralDisclosure"74UniversityofPittsburghLawReview.1.Reinganum,F.Jennifer.1989."TheTimingofInnovation:Research,Development,and

Diffusion"1HandbookofIndustrialOrganization,eds.RichardSchmalensee&RobertD.Willing.849.

Roin,N.Benjamin.2009."PatentableDrugsandtheStandardsofPatentability"87TexasLaw

Review.503,557-558.Sag,Matthew.2016."IPLitigationinUnitedStatesDistrictCourts:1994to2014"IowaLaw

Review(forthcoming).Manuscriptat17,availableathttp://ssrn.com/abstract=2570803.Shapiro,Carl.2006."PriorUserRights"96AmericanEconomicReview.Sichelman,Ted.2010."CommercializingPatents"62StanfordLawReview.341,345.Spulber,F.Daniel.2012."IntellectualPropertyandtheTheoryoftheFirm"Perspectiveson

CommercializingInnovation,eds.F.ScottKieff&TroyA.Peredes.9,31.Teece,J.David.1986."ProfitingfromTechnologicalInnovation:ImplicationsforIntegration,

Collaboration,LicensingandPublicPolicy"15ResearchPolicy.285,293.Tirole,Jean.1988.TheTheoryofIndustrialOrganization,TheMassachusettsInstituteof

TechnologyPress.394-399.Vermont,Samson.2006."IndependentInventionasaDefensetoPatentInfringement"105

MichiganLawReview.475.


Recommended