+ All Categories
Home > Documents > petroleum contracts

petroleum contracts

Date post: 17-Sep-2015
Category:
Upload: dineshhsenid
View: 66 times
Download: 3 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
petroleum contracts
Popular Tags:
27
i A BEAUTIFUL SHOE OF AGREEMENT: WHICH LEG BEST FITS INTO IT; PRODUCTION SHARING OR A SERVICE CONTRACT? Amos Sofedah 1 ABSTRACT: In recent years, a significant number of lower and middle-income countries have increasingly put much effort to attract foreign investors especially in natural resources projects. Now, many of the petroleum exporting countries have open up their upstream sector to investments by IOCs. The purpose of this paper is to evaluate the various types of petroleum agreement whether an appropriate model, either Service or Production Sharing Contract will be arrived at as best fit a model to consider by taking into account the cost of E&P by investors. In this paper, statistical data from experts in the oil and gas industry were collated and then grouped into three sections; low, medium and high E&P cost countries. The research found out that, a lot of factors come to play in adopting a petroleum agreement. It was found out that many of the IOCs are not concerned about the types of agreement to enter into with a host government but rather, the structure and the fiscal system of the agreement. However, the RSA system was found to be more profound in countries with low E&P cost. 1 The author is an MSc International Oil and Gas Management candidate at the CEPMLP with a BSc (Hons) in Mathematics from Kwame Nkrumah University of Science and Technology, Ghana. He is also affiliated with The Energy Institute, Society of Petroleum Engineers and Young Energy Professionals (YEP) under the Institute for Energy Law, USA. Email: [email protected]
Transcript
  • i

    A BEAUTIFUL SHOE OF

    AGREEMENT: WHICH LEG BEST

    FITS INTO IT; PRODUCTION

    SHARING OR A SERVICE

    CONTRACT?

    Amos Sofedah1

    ABSTRACT: In recent years, a significant number of lower and middle-income countries

    have increasingly put much effort to attract foreign investors especially in natural resources

    projects. Now, many of the petroleum exporting countries have open up their upstream sector

    to investments by IOCs. The purpose of this paper is to evaluate the various types of

    petroleum agreement whether an appropriate model, either Service or Production Sharing

    Contract will be arrived at as best fit a model to consider by taking into account the cost of

    E&P by investors. In this paper, statistical data from experts in the oil and gas industry were

    collated and then grouped into three sections; low, medium and high E&P cost countries.

    The research found out that, a lot of factors come to play in adopting a petroleum agreement.

    It was found out that many of the IOCs are not concerned about the types of agreement to

    enter into with a host government but rather, the structure and the fiscal system of the

    agreement. However, the RSA system was found to be more profound in countries with low

    E&P cost.

    1 The author is an MSc International Oil and Gas Management candidate at the CEPMLP with a BSc (Hons) in Mathematics from Kwame Nkrumah University of Science and Technology, Ghana. He is also affiliated with

    The Energy Institute, Society of Petroleum Engineers and Young Energy Professionals (YEP) under the Institute

    for Energy Law, USA. Email: [email protected]

  • ii

    Table of Contents

    List of abbreviations.. iii

    1. Introduction 1

    2. Energy Investment agreements 2

    2.1 Oil and gas exploration and production 2

    2.2 Production sharing contracts/agreement (PSA/PSC) 4

    2.3 Overview of fiscal system. 6

    2.4 The advantages of production sharing contract.. 8

    2.5 The disadvantages of production sharing contract 9

    3. An overview of service contract 9

    3.1 Overview of risk service contract. 10

    3.2 The advantages of RSA 11

    3.3 The disadvantages of RSA.... 11

    4. Evaluation of upstream petroleum agreements and the determination of an

    appropriate petroleum contract....11

    4.1The role of E&P cost on upstream petroleum agreement..11

    4.2An effect of the cost of E&P in countries with varied petroleum agreement.. 14

    5. Conclusion. 21

    Reference List

  • iii

    List of Abbreviations

    Abbreviation Meaning

    ADNOC Abu Dhabi National Oil Company

    BP British Petroleum

    E&P Exploration and Production

    EOR Enhanced Oil Recovery

    FTA First Tranche Petroleum Agreement

    HC Host Country

    IMF International Monetary Fund

    IOC International Oil Company

    IOR Improved Oil Recovery

    JV Joint Venture

    NIOC National Iranian Oil Company

    NOC National Oil company

    OPEC Organisation of Petroleum Exporting Countries

    OSA Operating Service Agreement

    PDO Petroleum Development of Oman

    PSA Production Sharing Agreement

    PSC Production Sharing Contract

    RSA Risk Service Agreement

    R/T Royalty Tax

    UAE United Arab Emirates

    UK United Kingdom

    UNCTAD United Nations Conference on Trade and Development

    US United States

  • iv

    List of Figures

    Figure 1- Oil Distribution under PSA

    Figure 2- Classification of Petroleum Fiscal System

    Figure 3- Iranian buy-back Model

    Figure 4- Strategic association agreement in Venezuela

    List of tables

    Table 1- Some Countries upstream cost

    Table 2- Profit Oil split under PSC 1993

    Table 3- Profit oil split under PSC 2005

  • 1

    1.0 Introduction

    In recent years, quite a number of lower and middle-income countries have massively put in

    much effort to attract foreign investors especially in natural resources projects like mining,

    petroleum and other commodities like rubber.2 Economic liberation and the rapid demand for

    energy have encouraged investment in the natural resource sector even parts of the world

    that were previously of less interest to international investors3.

    Foreign investment flow in Sub-Sahara Africa alone was about US$ 64 billion in 2008 with

    natural resources sector recording the highest share (UNCTAD, 2009)4. Investment flow in

    2005 was US$ 17 billion. It increased to about US $22billion in 2006 and sharply moved to

    the level of over US$ 30 billion in 2007.5 Mostly, increased investments, to some extent

    stimulates opportunities to promote development and improving living standards in recipient

    countries through economic growth and increased government revenues.6

    Many investments in the past with regards to natural resources contributed abysmally to

    sustainable development and created a situation captured as resource curse 7 . Those

    challenges emerged because, a lot of the investment plans then were improperly implemented

    and mismanagement of government revenues was the order of the day 8 . In order for

    government to achieve sustainable development especially in countries where their major

    source of export happened to be natural resources, one of the key areas to consider is their

    investment contracts. This is because investment contracts define the terms of an investment

    project and constitute a key instrument of governance9. In addition, the determination and

    distribution of risks, cost and benefits are all captured in investment contracts hence ought to

    be critically examined and be understood by both parties before commencement or

    implementation of any petroleum project10.

    2Cotula, L. (2010) Investment contracts and sustainable development: How to make contracts for fairer and

    more sustainable natural resource investments, Natural Resource Issues, No. 20. IIED, London. 3 ibid 4 UNCTAD (2009), Economic development in Africa report: Strengthening regional economic integration for

    Africa development 5ibid 6 supra note 1, at p. 1 7 supra note 1, at p. 1 8 supra note 1, at p. 1 9 supra note 1, at p. 3 10 supra note 1, at p. 3

  • 2

    Instances whereby investors felt the host government had breached its contractual obligation

    mostly results in disputes which sometimes are transferred to international arbitration for

    settlement11.

    However, many of the petroleum exporting countries have opened up their upstream sector to

    investment by International Oil Companies (IOCs) through petroleum contracts such as

    royalty tax system, production sharing and or service contracts12. Many of the challenges that

    have emerged from petroleum contracts have been as a result of inaccuracies or ambiguities

    in negotiation of the petroleum contracts and failure of one party for not fulfilling its

    contractual obligations.

    The purpose of this article is to evaluate the various types of petroleum agreements with the

    aim of finding appropriate petroleum agreement that in distinction best fits into a countys

    legal frame work (on petroleum) , taking into account the cost of E&P by investors.

    In this article, statistical data from experts in the oil industry were collated and then grouped

    into three sections; low E&P cost countries which were countries with E&P cost of $ 4.65/b

    or below, medium E&P cost countries, thus countries with E&P cost ranging between $

    4.65/b and $ 8.50/b and high E&P cost countries, i.e. cost exceeding $ 8.50/b.

    This paper is grouped into five respective sections. Section 2 highlights on the energy

    investments agreement; section 3 provides an overview of service contract; section 4

    evaluates the upstream petroleum investment to find out whether there will be a definite or

    appropriate petroleum contract for a country to adopt and section 5 presents the conclusion of

    the paper.

    2.0 Energy investment and agreements

    2.1 Oil and a Gas exploration and production

    The oil and gas industry is classified into upstream and downstream sectors. The upstream

    sector is into the exploration and production whereas downstream, deals with the refining and

    processing of the crude and gas products, their distribution and marketing13.

    11supra note1, at p. 3 12Al-Attar, A. and Alomair, O., Evaluationof upstream petroleum agreement and Exploration and production

    cost, OPEC Review, Vol. 29, Issue 4, Pages 243-266, 2005 13International and Petroleum and Policy lecture notes

  • 3

    The upstream sector of the industry heavily rely on the contractors or the investors who

    provide technical services ranging from geological and geophysical surveys, drilling, etc, in

    support of the operation.14

    Many of the oil or gas project undergoes several stages and the following however give an

    overview of the various stages;

    Licensing: Mostly, it is the initial stage of the project and here; the government grants

    a licence or enters into a contractual agreement with an oil company or joint

    companies without transferring the ownership of the mineral resources.15

    The exploration stage: The oil company or group of companies proceeds with the

    exploration of the hydrocarbons after they have been granted the licence to explore at

    this stage. The exploration involves geological and geophysical surveys such as

    seismic surveys and core borings. Here, the data obtained from the various surveys

    will determine whether the discovery is of commercial quantity or promising16.

    Appraisal: At this stage, more wildcats will be drilled if hydrocarbons are however

    discovered to establish the amount of recoverable oil, production mechanism and

    structure type. In addition, development planning and feasibility studies are carried

    out to be able to estimate the development cost of the project17.

    Development stage: Once the appraisal wells prove favourable, then the next stage

    of development planning begins using the geological and environmental data that had

    already been obtained.18

    Production: At this stage, extraction of hydrocarbons begins and then transported to

    the processing site19.

    14ibid 15Tordo, S., Fiscal systems for hydrocarbons, World Bank Working Paper, No. 123 16ibid 17ibid 18ibid 19ibid

  • 4

    Abandonment: At the end of successful oil and gas exploration, a decision is then

    made to abandon the oil field. Here, the equipments are either left for the host

    government or is totally removed by the contractor. Mostly, contractors or operators

    begin planning in about one or two years before the planned date of

    decommissioning20.

    There are three major kinds of petroleum agreements between foreign investors and/ or

    domestic investors and host states. They are production sharing, tax royalty (sometimes

    called modern concession or licence) and service contract (sometimes referred to as risk

    service contract).

    The individual type of agreement establishes quite a distinct regime of governance

    sanction by the host states.

    2.2 Production Sharing Contracts/ Agreements (PSA/PSC)

    In the late 1950s and 1960s, countries like Iran and Indonesia registered their displeasure

    against the use of traditional concession in favour of the production sharing agreement21.

    Indonesia was the first country to use PSA in the petroleum industry in the 1960s and is

    the standard of comparison for all PSAs22. The model agreement was signed between the

    IOC and Pertamina, the state oil company. Later, the agreement became popular in the

    developing countries and is now practiced in more than fifty-five countries worldwide23.

    The main driving force of the PSA was the rise of national hostility against the classic

    concession granted to the IOC in the petroleum industry24 . Production contracts are

    signed between host states which sometimes are represented by their NOCs and IOC for a

    specified period25.

    In addition, PSAs are largely practised in countries with high reserves and medium cost

    of exploration26.The contractual structure of production sharing agreement has evolved to

    20ibid 21Smith, E., From concession to service contract, 27 TulsaL.493, 1991-992

    22Onaiwu, E., How do fluctuating oil prices affect government take under Nigerias PSCs? Available at http://www.dundee.ac.uk/cepmlp/gateway/?news=30868 23 Cameron, P., International Energy Investment Law: The Pursuit of Stability, New York, Oxford University

    Press, 2010. 24See supra note 21 at p.4 25Ahmadov, I., Artemyev, A., Aslanly,K., Rzaev,I., Shaban, I. 2012. How to scrutinise a Production Sharing

    Agreement. IIED, London. 26 supra note 11at p.251

  • 5

    synchronise with the changing trend in the relationships between host states and the IOCs.

    The key features that have characterised PSA are as follows;

    1. The host state, mostly represented by NOC or the energy ministry, appoints the IOC as

    the main contractor to engage in the exploration and development in a certain area within

    a stipulated time period27.

    2. Under PSA the IOC bears the sole risks in the exploration and development of the

    petroleum resources but under the control of the host state28.

    3. The oil produced, thus, belongs to the HC with the exception of the cost oil and that of

    the profit oil29.

    4. The profit oil obtained, after the deduction of cost oil from the overall production is

    therefore shared between the IOC and the host state based on a predetermined percentage

    which mostly is in favour of the host state30.

    5. Also, under the PSA, the net income of the contractor which in this case, the IOC is

    taxable unless the provision in the agreement proves otherwise31.

    6. In addition, equipment for the exploration and production of the petroleum resource

    however becomes the host state property after the expiration of the agreement in

    accordance with the cost recovery schedules32.

    7. And once the PSA is negotiated or agreed upon and signed, often becomes part of the

    national legislation33. The diagram in the figure below shows the oil distribution under

    PSA.

    27 Duval, C., LeLeuch, H., Pertuzio, A., Weaver, J. International petroleum exploration and exploitation

    agreements: legal and economic policy aspects, 2nded, New York: Barrow, 2009 28ibid 29ibid 30ibid 31ibid 32ibid 33ibid

  • 6

    Figure1. Oil distribution under PSAs

    2.3 Overview of fiscal system

    Exploration for natural resources especially petroleum occurs based on concessions, leases,

    or contracts granted by governments34. Usually, the terms and conditions of the agreements

    are well define by law or negotiated for by cases. One of the pivotal aspects of the agreement

    is the fiscal terms which include royalties, bonuses, rentals, production sharing arrangement,

    carried interest provisions, corporate income taxes and special taxes. Payments made to

    government required under the agreement can however be termed as fiscal system35. The

    term fiscal system therefore highlights the dynamics of virtually all taxes, levies, legislative

    and that of contractual aspects of petroleum operations practiced within a sovereign state36. In

    other words, the fiscal system is the determinant of profit and revenue between the IOC and

    the host country in the event of commercial discovery of oil.

    34Khelil, C., Fiscal System for Oil. The government take and competition for exploration investment, The

    World Bank, No. 46, May, 1995 35ibid 36Johnston, D., International exploration and economics, risk, and contract analysis, Oklahoma (US), PennWell

    Publication Company, 2003.

  • 7

    A countrys fiscal system establishes a mechanism by which a sovereign state massages the

    economic rent to its advantage and also providing a potential return for the oil companies37.

    And for an effective fiscal system to be achieved, the political, geological risks and potential

    rewards ought to be taken into consideration38. There are two main classifications of fiscal

    systems and they are concessionary and the contractual system39. The distinction that exists

    between the categories is evident hugely in the ownership of the natural resources. Under the

    concessionary system, all rights and title to the international company are not denied but

    subject to all applicable taxes40.

    Figure 2. Classification of Petroleum Fiscal System41

    Under the contractual system the host government, retains title and the ownership of the

    natural resources and all production while the international company operates under the

    37ibid 38 ibid 39 Johnston, D., International Petroleum Fiscal Systems and Production Sharing Contracts, Oklahoma (US),

    PennWell Publishing Company, 1994. 40 ibid 41See Johnston 1994,ibid

    Petroleum Fiscal Agreements

    Concessionary System Contractual System

    Service Contract Production Sharing

    Contract

    Pure Service Contract Risk Service Contract

  • 8

    control of the government42. The contractual system can further be subdivided into service

    and production sharing contract. The establishment of a dichotomy between production

    sharing and risk service contract will profoundly be dependent on whether contractors

    compensations are either received in kind (crude) or in cash.43 But in both situations, bearing

    of risks are virtually inevitable whenever exploration is unsuccessful.

    2.4 The advantages of production sharing contract

    In the international petroleum industry, PSA has registered more prominence as far as

    petroleum agreement is concerned and as a result, its practiced in a lot of countries around

    the world44.

    In view of this, it is not insignificant to review the merits associated with the PSA. The

    petroleum agreement holds high advantages to both parties to the contract, thus the host

    government and the investor or the IOC in varied sense. And they are as follows;

    Under the PSA, all financial and operational risks are borne by the IOC leaving the

    host government virtually contributing nothing to the entire project45.

    The agreement also provides legal security for international oil companies if it is

    passed into law46.

    The PSA has for the several years proved to demonstrate flexibility in the event of

    volatile oil prices.47

    The PSA also grants title and that of ownership of the petroleum resources to the host

    government48.

    The PSA appears to be subjected to less public scrutiny than the remaining petroleum

    agreements49.

    Its for these significant reasons that many countries have opened up for this type of

    agreement.

    42ibid 43 supra note 26 at p.87 44 supra note 22 at p. 37 45Jenik, R., The ABCs of Petroleum contracts: License-Concession Agreement, Joint Ventures, and Production

    Sharing Agreement. In covering oil: A reports guide to Energy and Development, Open Society Institute, New York, 2005 46ibid 47ibid 48ibid 49ibid

  • 9

    2.5 Disadvantages of Production Sharing Contracts

    Mostly, the petroleum industries are characterised by knowledge intensive workers, hence

    discharge of professional duties are of high standard while on the other hand, in some cases,

    the host countries are inexperienced or lacked the skills and expertise in executing the oil and

    gas project under the PSA thereby thwarting the primary objectives of the exploration of the

    petroleum resources. Further, poorly supervised cost recovery provisions sometimes create an

    expensive challenge, thus resulting in gold plating50. And also, high cost fields are sometimes

    not properly accounted for by a well calibrated volumetric sliding scale51.

    The PSA is less suitable a model to be considered when engaging IOCs in areas with already

    high productivity and low risks. In addition, challenges have emerged under PSA with its

    capacity to provide for decommissioning52.

    3.0 Overview of Service Contract

    Service contract is another form of petroleum contract and under this contract, the IOC agrees

    for a fee or a share of production where it provides the host government and its state oil

    company with services and information to assist the country explore and to develop its own

    natural resources53. Under service contract, three basic types of arrangements have been

    designed to making an effective use of the IOCs technological and managerial expertise and

    that of their capital resources whereas ownership and control rest with the host government54.

    Under listed are the basic types of the arrangement;

    The pure service contract

    The technical assistance agreement and

    The risk service contract55.

    Concerning pure service contract, the host government or the state oil company enter into an

    agreement or contract with an IOC to undertake a specified service for an agreed fee56.

    50 See supra note 22 at p.39 51 See supra note 22 at p.39 52 See supra note 22 at p.39 53 See supra note 20, p. 519 54 Smith, E., Dzienkowski, J., Fifty-Year Perspective on World Petroleum Agreements, 24 Tex. Intl. J. 13, 1989 55ibid 56ibid

  • 10

    The next agreement under discussion is the technical assistance agreement which to some

    extent is seen as the complex version of the service contract57. Under this agreement, the

    contractor agrees to provide technical assistance in the exploration, development and at times

    in the refining of the oil. Here, the technical assistance provisions include equipment and

    training of employees to handle the petroleum facilities58. On the other hand, in fulfilling the

    other part of the agreement, reimbursement is therefore made by the host government to the

    company for cost incurred plus a fee which is based upon the production obtained59. Lets see

    an overview of Risk Service Contract is presented in the section that follows.

    3.1 Overview of Risk service Contract

    This is another form of agreement under service contract designed to guide the development

    of petroleum resources60. In this contract, the IOC gives an affirmative response to explore a

    specific area and to carefully assess its potential for discoveries. The contractor herein under

    this contract is however denied property rights in the reservoir but bears all financial risks

    and other expenses with no expectation for payment unless commercial production is

    attained.

    The major dissimilarity between the RSA and PSA is the modus operandi by which payment

    of contractual services and awarding of profit share is done61. In addition, with regards to

    booking of reserves, under RSA the IOCs are disallowed to book any reserves because

    reimbursements and the payment of service fees are made in cash only62. But in a situation

    where buy-back clause is applicable under RSA contract where payment of service fees are

    made in kind ( as in contractor receives oil as payment) the IOC is however granted economic

    interest which therefore entitles it to book portion of field production and the corresponding

    reserves63.

    The advantages and the disadvantages under this contract are heighted in the section that

    follows.

    57ibid 58ibid 59ibid 60 supra note 20, at p.519 61 supra note 26, at p.87 62 supra note 26, at p.87 63 supra note 26, at p.87

  • 11

    3.2 The advantages of RSA

    Risk Service, which is widely practiced in Latin America, has limited advantage compared to

    other forms of petroleum agreement64 . Herein, under this contract, the host government

    reimburse the contractor once commercial quantity of oil results plus a compensation for

    undertaking risks in the exploration and development of the petroleum resources65.

    3.3 Disadvantages of RSA

    One of the major challenges most IOCs face with regards to RSA is the mode of reward

    allocation. Mostly, the IOCs prefer reimbursement of cost in kind (thus, crude oil) to cash

    rewards by host states66. Secondly, countries whereby RSA is prominently practised are

    unable to render payment in American dollars, the globally recognised standard by which oil

    is sold67. This challenge is often experienced in situations where development cost and the

    exploration cost recovered are tied to the US prime rate68.

    4.0 Evaluation of upstream petroleum agreement and the determination of an

    appropriate petroleum contract

    4.1 The role of E&P cost of upstream petroleum agreement

    The exploration and production cost of oil significantly plays a key role in designing a fiscal

    system of an upstream petroleum agreement. In the case where E&P cost of oil is low, host

    states grant inflexible fiscal system whilst the opposite is experienced, thus an oilfield

    registering high E&P cost (i.e. flexible fiscal system).69 There are two reasons that account

    for high E&P cost. One is high demand of technology such as IOR in situations where

    production capacity is low owing to the maturing nature of major oilfields70. In circumstances

    like this, there are always huge capital outlay thereby shooting up the E&P cost of the

    oilfield. Secondly, the probability of finding huge oil reserves onshore mostly is low relative

    to deep water offshore.

    64 supra note 20, at p. 519 65 supra note 11, at p. 252 66 supra note 22, at p.42 67 supra note 20, at p. 520 68 supra note 20, at p. 520 69 supra note 11, at p. 248 70 supra note 11, at p. 248

  • 12

    And exploring and developing oil in deep water offshore come with a high E&P cost and

    risks which therefore requires huge investment to be able to develop, sustain or to increase oil

    production71.

    However, governments in considering the high risk nature of the venture refuse or are

    reluctant in undertaking any investment in that regard thereby opening up their upstream

    petroleum sector to IOC investment with the intension of obtaining capital or oil production

    and spreading of the technical risks. In iteration, E&P cost are highly considered as key

    element for host states in determining the fiscal system, legal frame work for upstream

    petroleum agreements and that of the type of agreement to enter with IOCs72. The Table

    below provides various countries with their E&P costs and the type of petroleum agreement

    they have with the IOCs.

    71 supra note 11, at p. 249 72 supra note 11, at p. 249

  • 13

    Table1. Some countries upstream costs73

    The table groups countries into three, in accordance with total cost of exploration and

    production. Thus, low, medium and high total costs, and these are based on a statistical

    approach. It is however observed from Table 1 that high E&P cost connotes a technical risk

    from the investors point of view and in addition establishes that, the stage of investment in

    73Cambridge Energy Research Associates (CERA) brief, upstream costs latest data show cost rising, November,

    2002.

  • 14

    the upstream sector to some extent correlates with the size of the risk borne by the IOC74. For

    instance, high risks are recorded during exploration phase and later starts to decline as it

    reaches the development level75.

    One other thing is that, some of the risks at the production phase tend to reduce and this

    compels some of the IOCs to select a discount rate, base on a certain assigned risk factor.

    Whenever discount rates are high, it reduces the uncertainties and risks involved in making

    poor investment.76 Further, it has however been noticed that in cases whereby E&P cost is

    low, host states seizes more control over operation and production and this development

    reflects in the type of agreement negotiated for.

    On the other hand, the RSA in theory grants more control to the host states over production,

    operation and also management followed by the PSA and R/T systems respectively. There are

    some countries, even with their low E&P cost; they have managed to enter into different

    types of agreement such as PSA or R/T system but mostly with NOC equity partnership. This

    equity partnership by NOCs results in host countries to having control over operation and

    production. Furthermore, equity participation by host states is dependent on the level of E&P

    costs and that of the countrys prospective petroleum area. This therefore means that a high

    E&P cost results low NOC equity participation and vice versa.

    In cases where medium costs are prominent, theres a high level of partnership and

    participation by the NOCs with the IOCs. This however is more profound in UAE and

    Nigeria (60%). Lets find out how the subsequent analysis will be unfolded in the section that

    follows.

    4.2 An effect of the E&P cost in countries with varied petroleum agreement

    From Table 1, the low E&P cost countries are Kuwait, Iran and Algeria. These are countries

    with exploration and production cost of $4.65/b or below. The dominant petroleum

    agreement found in these countries is RSA. The reason for the adoption of this type of

    agreement is to increase production from existing oilfield that calls for high technology but

    with low operating cost.

    74 supra note 11, at p. 249 75 supra note 11, at p. 251 76 supra note 11, at p. 249

  • 15

    However, the adoption of RSA poses some disadvantages for the host state, thus the host

    state bears all the risks in the event of price fluctuations since reimbursement are mostly

    made in cash77.

    For instance, if prices of oil drop, the host country has no other option than to sell more oil to

    compensate the IOCs for their cost. This is to state that oil price has huge impact on the

    countrys revenue as far as RSA is concerned. And from financial point of view, the

    practicing of RSA is accompanied by some complication than in PSA and R/T systems.

    From Table 1, Kuwait recorded the second lowest E&P cost of $3.55/b. On the other hand,

    Kuwait has a significant number of oilfields that have matured which however require huge

    capital outlay and technology such as IOR to maximise or sustain oil production. Considering

    the low cost of E&P, the kuwatians entered into an agreement with the IOC to develop the

    upstream sector for duration of 20 years under OSA, a type of RSA 78 . The Kuwatian

    government had a lot of control under this agreement.

    Irans exploration and development cost onshore was low but its continental shelf E&P costs

    were much higher owing to huge investment and high operational and maintenance costs. The

    Iranian constitution however prevents the awarding of petroleum rights on a concessionary

    basis or by direct equity79. But in 1987, the buy-back type of contract was adopted by the

    country whose features were of no difference from RSA80. The buy-back contract is usually

    between 5 years to 7 years with a fixed rate of return of 15 to 20 percent81. ConocoPhillips

    was the IOC to enter a buy-pack agreement with Iran but later withdrew. The figure below

    shows buy-pack agreement with National Iranian Oil Company (NIOC).

    77 supra note 11, at p. 252 78Supra note 11, at p. 252 79Supra note 11, at p. 254 80Supra note 11, at p. 254 81Supra note 11, at p. 254

  • 16

    Figure 3 Iranian buy-back model 82

    Venezuela, on the other hand, presently holds 24.8% of OPEC proven oil reserves as of 2011,

    thus making it the highest share holder in OPEC member countries83. The countrys upstream

    activity is both onshore and offshore and is one of the countries that enjoy low E&P cost.

    Venezuela, in 1990 introduced RSA in its petroleum upstream sector under different names

    such as OSA, risk/project sharing agreements and strategic association for extra- heavy crude.

    The extra-heavy crude recorded a low E&P cost compared to other countries. In 2005,

    Venezuela had four strategic association agreements for extra- heavy oilfields with the

    inclusion of exploration and development and with several IOCs participation along with the

    NOC as seen in figure (4).84 The strategic association agreement however had a royalty rate

    between zero and one percent.

    82Supra note 11, at p. 255 83www.opec.org/opec_web/en/data_graphs/330.htm (Last visited , 28th December, 2012) 84 See Supra note 11, at p. 255

  • 17

    Figure 4. Strategic association agreement in Venezuela85

    In addition, Venezuela had different RSA mechanisms for conventional oil exploration and

    production development and the countrys conventional oil recorded the lowest cost of

    $1.20/b.

    Algeria, similarly, from Table 1 had a low E&P cost and as result adopted several types of

    upstream petroleum agreements with the aim of increasing E&P by the IOCs. The action by

    Algeria led to an upward trend in the countrys production from 673,900 b/d in 1986 to 1.33

    million b/d in 2005.86 Although, Algerian Law No 86-14 and its amendments makes room for

    four types of upstream contracts, thus commercial company contracts, joint ventures, PSA,

    and RSA. However, the one commonly practised is the RSA87.

    Furthermore, the agreements adopted by the Algerians were signed between the NOC,

    Sonatrach and the IOC. And Sonatrach participation was no less than 51% at the point of

    discovery irrespective of the type agreement. It was a provision found in the Algerian

    petroleum legislation. But since 1989, NOC participation ranged between 25-35% under

    85United States Department of Energys Energy information Administration, Country analysis brief, Venezuela. 86 See supra note 11, at p. 256 87 See supra note 11, at p. 256

  • 18

    some PSAs88. Mostly, it is the Algerian model that determines the level of royalties and taxes

    in accordance with the area and stage of production.

    The countries under the medium E&P cost in Table 1 are United Emirates, Kazakhstan,

    Nigeria, Oman and Indonesia. United Arab Emirate practiced the R/T system and that of the

    JV agreement but has up to 60% participation of the Abu Dhabi National Oil Company

    (ADNOC) and 40% participation of international oil companies, thus, Exxon Mobil, BP shell,

    Total and Partex. Despite the countrys NOCs participation, royalties under R/T system are

    between 12.5% and 20% whereas taxes range between 55% and 85%.89

    Kazakhstan on the other hand adopted almost all the three types of petroleum agreement.

    Under Kazakhstans R/T system, participation of NOC was allowed up to 50%. Early in

    2004, there was amendment of law that made provisions for taxes to be increased whenever

    oil prices shot up. Also, government is entitled to 85% of profit oil in Kazakhstan. In the case

    of Nigeria, it however opted for the R/T system in the form of JV and that of the PSA. The

    country has two fiscal systems thus, one for onshore and the other for offshore. The flat rates

    under 2005 PSC mode are 20% and 10% for onshore and inland basins respectively90. See

    Table 2 and Table 3

    88 See supra note 11, at p. 256 89Supra note 11, at p. 258 90Supra note 21, at p. 259

  • 19

    Table 2. Profit Oil Split under the PSC199391

    Production

    Threshold

    (bbls)

    Profit Share %

    Government Contractor

    0-350 20 80

    351-700 35 65

    701-1000 45 65

    1001-1500 50 50

    1501-2000 60

    40

    Beyond 2000 Negotiable Negotiable

    Table 3. Profit Oil Split under the PSC 200592

    R Factor Contractor Share Government Share

    R

  • 20

    Oman PSA fiscal system however grants government take up to 80% and sliding scale for

    cost recovery between 40-50%. The royalty rate is completely absent under the PSA93.

    Further, Indonesia on the other hand adopted the PSA system and has four different

    modifications of the PSA, namely; First Tranche Petroleum agreement (FTA), Joint

    Operating Agreement (JOA), Technical Assistance Contracts and that of EOR contract. The

    fiscal system was designed such that there was not any inclusion of royalty for the FTA

    agreement but allows 100% cost recovery94.

    The last group is made up of countries with E&P cost exceeding $8.50/b and they are US

    Gulf of Mexico and the North Sea (UK and Norway). Under this group, the main upstream

    petroleum agreement that have been adopted is the R/T system. Under this agreement, all

    E&P cost and risks are borne by the IOC. The advantages, here are that, the IOC has the

    exclusive right to exploration and complete ownership of production.

    Norway, with adoption of R/T also had in addition NOC equity participation of up to 30% at

    the exploration phase. The equity participation together with R/T system grants the

    Norwegian government a share up to 78% of profit oil95.

    93supra note 11, at p. 261 94Supra note 11, at p. 262 95Noreng, . (2004), Norway economic diversification and the petroleum industry, MEES, Vol. 47:45, 8 November.

  • 21

    5.0 Conclusion

    It was observed that, regions where there was low recording of E&P costs, adoption of RSA

    was hugely profound and those countries were Iran, Kuwait, Venezuela and Algeria.

    Other countries like Kazakhstan, Oman and UAE opted for the R/T system in the form of

    NOC equity participation or that of JV agreement. However, Indonesia and Nigeria decided

    to settle for PSA. These countries were found to be in the medium E&P cost region. Norway

    adopted the R/T system and was also observed to record high E&P cost in the given table.

    The analysis in this article is that, many of the upstream petroleum agreements granted NOC

    equity precipitation or partnership with the aim of allowing NOC to play a part in controlling

    operations. In addition, different fiscal systems were designed to favour host governments in

    terms of capturing greater share of economic rent.

    It can therefore be said that, E&P cost in the petroleum industry has a significant role in

    determining an upstream petroleum agreement but that alone cannot provide sufficient

    grounds for International companies to appropriate a particular petroleum agreement or

    contract. Many of the IOCs are not much concerned about the type of petroleum contract to

    enter into but rather the structure of the agreement and the arrangement of the fiscal system

    within the agreement. Thus, whether fiscal system provides fare share of profit and risks.

    However, RSA will be an appropriate model to consider in regions where E&P cost is low

    and with high reserves.

    The study has its limitations. It was unable to examine recent data on exploration and

    production cost of some of the major oil producing countries owing to the obscured nature in

    accessing those information. This would surely have provided possible dimension in

    determining an appropriate petroleum model, as it would have accounted for some of the

    reasons that were left out in this report.

  • 22

    Reference List

    Secondary Source

    Books

    Cameron, P., International Energy Investment Law: The Pursuit of Stability, New York,

    Oxford University Press, 2010.

    Duval, C., LeLeuch, H., Pertuzio, A., Weaver, J., International petroleum exploration

    and exploitation agreements: legal and economic policy aspects, 2nded, New York: Barrow,

    c2009.

    Johnston, D., International exploration and economics, risk, and contract analysis, Oklahoma

    (US), PennWell Publication Company, 2003.

    Johnston, D., International Petroleum Fiscal Systems and Production Sharing Contracts,

    Oklahoma (US), PennWell Publishing Company, 1994.

    Jenik, R., The ABCs of Petroleum contracts: License-Concession Agreement, Joint

    Ventures, and Production Sharing Agreement. In covering oil: A reports guide to Energy

    and Development, Open Society Institute, New York, 2005.

    Articles

    Al-Attar, A. and Alomair, O., Evaluationof upstream petroleum agreement and Exploration

    and production cost, OPEC Review, Vol. 29, Issue 4, Pages 243-266, 2005

    Ahmadov, I., Artemyev, A., Aslanly,K., Rzaev,I., Shaban, I. 2012. How to scrutinise a

    Production Sharing Agreement. IIED, London

    Cotula, L. (2010) Investment contracts and sustainable development: How to make contracts

    for fairer and more sustainable natural resource investments, Natural Resource Issues, No.

    20. IIED, London

  • 23

    Smith, E., From concession to service contract, TulsaL Law Journal , Vol. 27, No. 4,

    Pp.493, Summer, 1992

    Smith, E., Dzienkowski, J., Fifty-Year Perspective on World Petroleum Agreements, 24 Tex.

    Intl. J. 13, 1989

    Tordo, S., Fiscal systems for hydrocarbons, World Bank Working Paper, No. 123

    Cambridge Energy Research Associates (CERA) brief, Upstream Costs Update Latest

    Data Show Cost Rising, November 2002

    Others

    Internet Source

    Chukwu, P.O., Joint Ventures & Production Sharing Contracts, at

    http://www.neiti.org.ng/publications/JV%20AND%20PSC%20ARRANGEMENTS%20PRE

    SENTATION%20TO%20NEITI.pps (last visited 28 December, 2012)

    Khelil, C., Fiscal System for Oil. The government take and competition for exploration

    investment, The World Bank, No. 46, May, 1995 at

    http://rru.worldbank.org/documents/publicpolicyjournal/046khelil.pdf

    (Last visited, 28 December, 2012)

    Onaiwu, E., How do fluctuating oil prices affect government take under Nigerias PSCs? At

    http://www.dundee.ac.uk/cepmlp/gateway/?news=30868

    (Last visited, 28 December, 2012)

    UNCTAD (2009), Economic development in Africa report: Strengthening regional economic

    integration for Africa development at

    httt://www.unctad.org/en/DOCs/oldcafrica 2009_en.pdf

    http://www.opec.org/opecweb/en/data_graphs/330.htm (Last visited, 28 December, 2012)


Recommended