+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Policy Brief to SPAD on Cost-Effective Bus Competition in Greater KL

Policy Brief to SPAD on Cost-Effective Bus Competition in Greater KL

Date post: 30-Oct-2014
Category:
Upload: the-association-for-the-improvement-of-mass-transit-malaysia
View: 53 times
Download: 4 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
This Policy Brief summarizes TRANSIT's recommendations for cost-effective bus transit competition in Greater KL.
3
TO: Tan Sri Syed Hamid Albar, Chairman, Land Public Transport Commission (LPTC) FROM: M Zulkarnain Hamzah, McGill University’s Department of Urban Planning DATE: 30 November 2012 SUBJECT: Cost-Effective Bus Transit Competition in Greater Kuala Lumpur (GKL) GKL’s Draft Land Public Transport Master Plan 1 acknowledges bus transit as one of the plan’s four building blocks towards LPTC’s mandate of sustainable and quality transit service, but the plan’s Bus Transformation section is silent on the present bus operations’ sustainability. The main bus operator, RapidKL (which monopolizes access to public-funded assets through its parent company, Prasarana) is under pressure to increase fares 2 , and the private operators (which cut corners to cope with fare price ceiling) are at risk of solvency 3 . RapidKL’s ambition to collude with private operators on resource sharing agreements 4 and private operators’ demands for new license freeze and mileage-based revenues 5 reveals the public and private operators’ desires for monopoly and oligopoly respectively. This brief seeks to evaluate the market structures’ effectiveness in achieving GKL bus operations’ value for money objective, drawing from the experiences of both the developed and the developing countries. North American transit agencies, which embody the classical monopolistic arrangement of publicly-owned bus asset-owner, regulator and operator, have relatively higher subsidy share as part of the operating cost among the developed nations 6 . Competitive tendering (CT) of services formerly served by mostly publicly- owned bus operators from 20 cities in 10 developed countries yielded unit operating cost reduction of mostly between 20 to 55 percent (30 to 46 percent in the United States) 7 . The savings derived from economies of scale of a monopolistic provider 8 can easily be cancelled by poorly incentivised operational management 9 . Many top- performing Canadian transit management boards (such as in Toronto which has the
Transcript

TO: Tan Sri Syed Hamid Albar, Chairman, Land Public Transport Commission (LPTC)

FROM: M Zulkarnain Hamzah, McGill University’s Department of Urban Planning

DATE: 30 November 2012

SUBJECT: Cost-Effective Bus Transit Competition in Greater Kuala Lumpur (GKL)

GKL’s Draft Land Public Transport Master Plan1 acknowledges bus transit as one

of the plan’s four building blocks towards LPTC’s mandate of sustainable and quality

transit service, but the plan’s Bus Transformation section is silent on the present bus

operations’ sustainability. The main bus operator, RapidKL (which monopolizes access

to public-funded assets through its parent company, Prasarana) is under pressure to

increase fares2, and the private operators (which cut corners to cope with fare price

ceiling) are at risk of solvency3. RapidKL’s ambition to collude with private operators on

resource sharing agreements4 and private operators’ demands for new license freeze

and mileage-based revenues5 reveals the public and private operators’ desires for

monopoly and oligopoly respectively. This brief seeks to evaluate the market structures’

effectiveness in achieving GKL bus operations’ value for money objective, drawing from

the experiences of both the developed and the developing countries.

North American transit agencies, which embody the classical monopolistic

arrangement of publicly-owned bus asset-owner, regulator and operator, have

relatively higher subsidy share as part of the operating cost among the developed

nations6. Competitive tendering (CT) of services formerly served by mostly publicly-

owned bus operators from 20 cities in 10 developed countries yielded unit operating

cost reduction of mostly between 20 to 55 percent (30 to 46 percent in the United

States)7. The savings derived from economies of scale of a monopolistic provider8 can

easily be cancelled by poorly incentivised operational management9. Many top-

performing Canadian transit management boards (such as in Toronto which has the

highest fare recovery ratio in the continent10) are scrutinized by elected city councillors

and citizen members11. In view of Malaysia’s absence of local council (LC) election, lack

of scrutiny over the solidification of policy and operational jurisdiction from LCs12 to

federal-level LPTC13 and RapidKL’s monopoly over bus assets and route planning, it is

recommended that LPTC opens up CT of transit assets to RapidKL’s competitors, and

that LPTC empowers LCs to plan and enforce routes and schedules of bus transit.

For CT to meet tendered bus operations’ value for money objective, the criteria14

of competency (sufficient market players and freedom of entry/exit barriers) and

transparency (symmetric knowledge among players), which do not exist in an oligopoly,

are required. Norwegian transit agencies, which adopted operating cost unit (e.g. per

km) payouts to ensure efficiency gains, resort to performance-based CT to avoid

collusion15, which limited the number of players in the long term as evidenced in Chile,

Italy and Norway16, 17. LPTC should replace the present entrepreneurial bus licensing

model with a more transparent performance-based CT. Prasarana, as the government’s

consolidated transit infrastructure and asset owner, can eliminate entry barriers

through bus lane and signal priority provisions (to counterbalance car-oriented road

subsidies). LCs’ ownership in transit planning and branding, together with operating

cost unit payouts will relieve bus operators from asymmetric knowledge on area-

specific ridership, marketing and profit risks. LPTC’s offering of a menu of periodical

contracts19 allow new and seasoned operators to tender for district-centric and

metropolitan-level contracts respectively, ensuring a sustainable pool of competitors.

Upon these international monopoly and oligopoly contexts, I recommend LPTC

to manage equitable role distributions among local councils, asset-owner and operators

and to work with LCs to enforce performance-based CT for the latter towards a more

sustainable and cost-effective bus transit in GKL.

APPENDIX

References

1. Land Public Transport Commission (LPTC). (2012). Draft Executive Summary of Land Public Transport Masterplan for

Greater Kuala Lumpur. Retrieved from http://www.spad.gov.my/news-events/announcements/2012/final-draft-national-land-

public-transport-master-plan

2. RapidKL Losses Due To Fares That Do Not Match Rising Operating Cost. (n.d.). Retrieved November 24, 2012, from

http://www.malaysiandigest.com/news/36-local2/146261-rapidkl-losses-due-to-fares-that-do-not-match-rising-operating-cost-

.html

3. No masterplan for public transport, only red tape. (n.d.). Retrieved November 24, 2012, from

http://archive.freemalaysiatoday.com/fmt-english/news/general/14797-no-masterplan-for-public-transport-only-red-tape

4. Prasarana Reiterate Need For Strategic Collaboration Among Bus Operators | Syarikat Prasarana Negara Berhad

(Prasarana). (n.d.). Retrieved November 24, 2012, from http://www.prasarana.com.my/news-events/media-

releases/2011/prasarana-reiterate-need-strategic-collaboration-among-bus-operators

5. (Reference No. 2)

6. Washington State Department of Transportation (2009). Transit Farebox Recovery and US and International Transit

Subsidization: Synthesis. Retrieved November 24, 2012, from http://www.wsdot.wa.gov/NR/rdonlyres/55CF12C9-9D4E-4762-

A27A-407A44546BE2/0/TrasitFareboxRecoveryandSubsidiesSynthesisKTaylorFINAL2.pdf

7. Hensher, D. A., & Wallis, I. P. (2005). Competitive Tendering as a Contracting Mechanism for Subsidising Transport: The

Bus Experience. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 39(3), 295–322.

8. Toronto transit for sale | NOW Magazine. (n.d.). Retrieved November 24, 2012, from

http://www.nowtoronto.com/news/story.cfm?content=188858

9. Department for International Development of the UK. (2000). Review of Urban Public Transport Competition Final Report,

Halcrow Fox Ltd. for Department for International Development of the UK. Retrieved November 24, 2012, from

http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTURBANTRANSPORT/Resources/uk_competition_bayliss.pdf

10. (Reference No. 8)

11. City Council Scorecard: Rob Ford loses control of the TTC « Ford For Toronto. (n.d.). Retrieved November 24, 2012, from

http://fordfortoronto.mattelliott.ca/2012/03/06/scorecard-ttc-board/

12. Government of Malaysia (2006). Laws of Malaysia (Act 171) - Local Government Act 1967. Retrieved from

http://www.agc.gov.my/Akta/Vol.%204/Act%20171.pdf

13. Government of Malaysia (2010). Laws of Malaysia (Act 715) – Land Public Transport Act 2010. Retrieved from

http://www.agc.gov.my/Akta/Vol.%204/Act%20171.pdf

14. Cambini, C., & Filippini, M. (2003). Competitive Tendering and Optimal Size in the Regional Bus Transportation Industry: An

Example from Italy. Annals of Public and Cooperative Economics, 74(1), 163–182. doi:10.1111/1467-8292.00220

15. Mathisen, T. A., & Solvoll, G. (2008). Competitive tendering and structural changes: An example from the bus industry.

Transport Policy, 15(1), 1–11. doi:10.1016/j.tranpol.2007.08.002

16. (References No. 15 and 16)

17. Estache, A., & GóMez‐Lobo, A. (2005). Limits to competition in urban bus services in developing countries. Transport

Reviews, 25(2), 139–158. doi:10.1080/0144164042000289654

18. (Reference No. 17)


Recommended