+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation...

Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation...

Date post: 15-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: phamthuy
View: 215 times
Download: 1 times
Share this document with a friend
24
Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien Foster
Transcript
Page 1: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

Policy Issues for theWater and Sanitation

Sectors

Vivien Foster

Page 2: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

Policy Issues for theWater and Sanitation

Sectors

Vivien Foster

Washington, D.C.August 1996— No. IFM96-101

Page 3: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

Vivien Foster is an Economic Consultant at Oxford Economic ResearchAssociates Ltd. (OXERA), in the United Kingdom. Ms. Foster specializes inthe economic and environmental regulation of privatized utilities, with specificreference to the water industry.

The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect theposition of the Inter-American Development Bank

Page 4: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

Contents

Executive Summary i

Introduction 1

The Infrastructure Problem 1

Separating Poachers and GamekeepersThe Depoliticization of Management

Characterization of the Latin American Water Sector 5

A Sectoral OverviewSpecial Features

Policy Responses 8

Optimal Sector StructureThe Scope for PrivatizationRedesigning Social Policy

Conclusion 16

References 19

Page 5: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

i

Executive Summary

In devising policy for Latin America’s environmental management, private sectorinfrastructure sector, it is important to participation, investment finance, regulatorydistinguish between the problems afflicting the control, and social policy.sector, and their fundamental causes. Thehypothesis put forward in this paper is that these Analysis of the role of competition for the marketfundamental causes can be characterized as the suggests that experiments to date have beenfailure to separate poachers from gamekeepers, largely confined to the metropolitan areas of theand the politicization of management. larger countries in the region, where economic

With the noteworthy exception of certain “flag- favorable. As privatization experiments areship” public sector providers of water services, extended to smaller countries and rural areas, itLatin America’s water and sanitation sector will be important to evaluate the extent to whichshows moderate but highly heterogeneous rates privatization can actually bring about sectoralof connection, and low levels of operational improvements, rather than simply necessitatingefficiency and cost recovery. them as a prerequisite for its successful

The key distinguishing characteristics of thewater and sanitation sector relative to other As far as social policy is concerned, the analysispublic utilities are identified as the low ratio of suggests that even those countries which are notvalue to transportation costs making for highly being compelled to reconsider their social policyfragmented distribution networks; the virtual as a result of some privatization initiative wouldabsence of any scope for direct competition in the nonetheless benefit from fundamental reforms.market; and the strong social character of the Such reforms should be based on the answers toservice as a result of positive social and negative three key questions regarding the objectives ofenvironmental externalities in consumption. social policy; the sources of funding and the

Building on the analysis of the sector’s empirical evidence to suggest that traditionaldistinguishing characteristics, the key economic social policy has focused excessively on the issueissues facing the industry in Latin America are: of affordability to existing users, at the expensethe degree of centralization of the operations; the of promoting access to those not yet connected toextent to which competition for the market can be the network.effectively used to improve sector conditions; andthe scope for reform of social policy toward the Finally, any country contemplating a reform ofconsumption of water and sanitation services. its water and sanitation sector should bear in

As far as the optimal horizontal structure of the advance of ownership issues; privatizationindustry is concerned, the analysis suggests that measures should be considered as lying on athis is a multidimensional question, which goes continuum as opposed to constituting an all-or-beyond the traditional considerations of nothing choice; and regulation is likely to play aoperational and managerial efficiency to role, even where privatization measures are notencompass the wider issues associated with considered feasible or desirable.

and sectoral conditions are comparatively

implementation.

instruments of implementation. There is some

mind that structural issues must be settled in

Page 6: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

1

Introduction

The decade of the 1990s is witnessing something discussion paper aims to identify those particularof a revolution in the modes of provision of features of the water and sanitation sector whichtraditionally state-owned infrastructure services distinguish it from other infrastructure servicesthroughout the developing world. The Latin and which will consequently merit specialAmerican and Caribbean region has been at the attention by countries engaging in such reforms.forefront of these developments, with a numberof countries initiating comprehensive, radical and The paper is structured along the following lines:often very innovative public service reformprograms. < The second section provides a generic

These experiments in restructuring, privatization facing state-owned providers of publicand regulation have often begun— and proceeded services.furthest— in the power and telecommunicationssectors. Owing to their technological and < The third section provides an overvieweconomic characteristics, these sectors present of the water and sanitation sector inthe greatest scope for the emergence of a Latin America and identifies the specialcompetitive market and are often the most characteristics which distinguish waterattractive to private sector capital. However, a and sanitation from other infrastructurenumber of countries have also been taking services.concrete steps to extending such reforms to thewater and sanitation sector, often regarded as the < The fourth section discusses policymost quintessentially public of the public responses to three key economic issues:services. optimal sector structure, the scope for

Given the importance of water and sanitation policy.loans in the Bank’s portfolio of infrastructureprojects and the significance of the measures that < The fifth section draws out the mainare underway throughout the region, this conclusions from the discussion.

overview of the institutional problems

privatization, and the redesign social

The Infrastructure Problem

Any policy package aimed at improving public increasing degree of consensus in recent yearsservices in Latin America and the Caribbean (Blanlot, 1995; Dussan, 1995)needs to be based on a sound theoreticalunderstanding of the problems which have One of the key features of Figure 1 is that ittraditionally afflicted the infrastructure sectors. attempts to distinguish between the causes of theFigure 1 is a graphical representation of one such problem and their ultimate consequences or, tohypothesis which has been attracting an use a medical analogy, between the underlying

Page 7: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

2

Figure 1: A Model of State-Owned Enterprise Failure

disease and its external symptoms. The symp- commercial criteria as a result oftoms exhibited by the infrastructure sector in the external influences from government. region are familiar enough. There areinsufficient investment, poor quality of service, The argument depicted in Figure 1 is that theselow tariff levels, low levels of efficiency, and two institutional defects— by preventing lack of accountability to customers. Historically, effective oversight, softening the budgetthere has been a tendency to direct efforts toward constraint of the enterprise, and dilutingattacking these superficial symptoms of the efficiency incentives— serve to bring about theproblem, often by relying on direct technical familiar range of problems affecting the publicassistance. However, more recently there has provision of infrastructure services.been a growing recognition that suchinterventions are likely to be ineffectual unless There is obviously room for discussion they are preceded by more fundamental reforms regarding the precise specification of the model,which attempt to rectify the problem at the level and indeed the diagrammatic representationof underlying causes. The two underlying causes presented above is intended to be suggestiveidentified here are: rather than definitive. However, what is clear is

< the poacher–gamekeeper problem: that guide reform measures in this area. Based on theis, the confusion or juxtaposition of two fundamental causes identified here, theregulatory and operational roles in state- following subsections examine the practicalowned enterprises; and strategies available to address the problems of

< the politicization of management: that is,the tendency to base decisions onpolitical rather than technical or

that some model of this nature is required to

separating roles and depoliticizing management.

Page 8: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

3

Distinct Roles Type of Provision Level of Provision

Sector Strategy Public Central

Social Policy Public Central

Regulation Public Central or Local

Investment Public or Private Central or Local

Operations Public or Private Central or Local

Table 1: The Separation of Roles

Separating Poachers and Gamekeepers

The process of the separation of roles entailsthree distinct stages, which are summarized inTable 1, as follows:

< the identification of the different rolesthat exist (see column one);

< the allocation of these roles between theprivate and public sectors (see columntwo); and

< the allocation of these roles betweendifferent tiers of government (see columnthree).

Since the second and third issues will receivemore extensive comment below, the discussionhere focuses on the question of identifying theseparate roles. This may not be straightforwardwhen they have been blurred for some timewithin a single institution. Table 1 attempts to becomprehensive in identifying five key roles,though some countries have taken the separationprocess further by distinguishing between theformulation of regulatory rules and their en-forcement. An example is the Colombian watersector, where the former function is undertakenby a sector-specific regulatory commission (Co-misión Reguladora de Agua), and the latter by a

cross-sectoral superintendency (Superintenden-cia de Servicios Públicos).

In addition to the need to separate the first threequintessentially public sector roles from the lasttwo roles which might potentially be dischargedby the private sector, a question arises as towhether each of the five functions should beallocated to a separate institution within thecorresponding sector. In practice, this is aquestion of whether operations should beseparated from investment within the sphere ofservice provision, and whether strategy,regulation and social policy should be separatedfrom each other and overseen by government.

In the case of the service provision function,there are examples both of:

< public sector operations complementedby private sector investment via build-operate-transfer (BOT) contracts; and

< private sector operations complementedby public sector investment finance,typically in the context of lease con-tracts.

Page 9: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

4

PoliticalIndependence

EfficiencyIncentives

Public Provision Low Absent

Corporatized State-Owned Enterprise

Medium Low Absent

Mixed Private/PublicEnterprise

Medium High PartiallyPresent

Cooperatives High Present

Private Provision High Present

Table 2: The Range of Available Institutions

While it may not always be feasible to discharge However, where the three roles identified areboth of these aspects of service provision within institutionally separated, it is important to ensurethe same institutional context, experience with an adequate degree of coordination between thelease contracts particularly suggests that it may relevant government entities.be highly desirable to do so. The examples ofwater lease contracts in Guinea and the IvoryCoast illustrate the serious coordination problems that may arise when investments areundertaken by a public sector investment financeagency and operations are in the hands of aprivate operator, potentially leading to aninefficient configuration of capital investments(OXERA/World Bank, 1995).

In the case where government is the overseer, tothe extent that the three facets of strategy,regulation and social policy entail mutuallyconflicting considerations, there may be somevirtue in allocating them to different arms ofgovernment. While it is not unusual for strategicissues to be retained by government andregulation to be delegated to an autonomousagency, it is less common for social policy to beexplicitly hived off from other aspects of watersector oversight. An interesting example of this isthe Chilean direct subsidy scheme which wasintroduced as part of that country’s nationalwater sector reform process.

The Depoliticization of Management

Table 2 illustrates the range of institutionaloptions for the provision of infrastructureservices that have been adopted throughout thecontinent.

Historically, in Latin America, water serviceshave often been provided directly by governmentagencies, though there has been a trend towardsthe creation of autonomous corporatized state-owned entities (Blanlot, 1995). In countries suchas Colombia, the hybrid approach of mixedprivate/public sector enterprises has also beenadopted. While elsewhere, such as in Bolivia,user-owned cooperatives have proved to be asuccessful vehicle for the provision of publicservices. More recently a number of countrieshave begun to experiment with private sectorinvolvement.

A key question is how far along the spectrumfrom private to public provision it is necessary

Page 10: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

5

to go before an effective depoliticization of Although the intermediate institutional modelsmanagement is achieved. The answer is likely to may be successful in achieving some measure ofdepend on the nature of the political system in depoliticization within the public sector, they doeach country. In some cases, it may be that the not of themselves ensure that efficiencyradical solution of private sector participation is incentives will be introduced. Only under thethe only way to break the political hold over cooperative framework (where there is a closewater and sanitation services. However, there is a identification between the interests ofdanger that a country may not be able to commit management and the interests of customers), orto a credible and autonomous regulatory under privatization (where there is a closeframework, thereby reintroducing political identification between the interests ofpressures under a different guise even where management and the interests of shareholders)private sector participation has been espoused. will a clear incentive for efficient managerial

behavior arise.

Characterization of theLatin American Water Sector

A Sectoral Overview

Turning now to the special features of the waterand sanitation sector, and the specificcircumstances of that sector in Latin Americaand the Caribbean, Table 3 provides a number ofoverview statistics. The table yields four keyinsights.

First, the average water and sewerage connectionrates for the region are moderately high, but mayoverstate the true position when one takes intoaccount the incidence of extreme quality ofservice deficiencies (with respect to potabilityand continuity); and the prevalence of relativelybasic versions of the two services (such as septictanks which make up 31% of urban sewerageprovision, or standpipes which constitute 11% ofurban water provision).

Second, the average connection rates hide aconsiderable degree of diversity in the levels ofaccess between: urban and rural sectors (with thelatter lagging 20 to 40 percentage points behind

the former); different countries (ranging fromuniversal coverage to minority coverage); anddiverse social strata (with differences inconnection rates sometimes in excess of 50percentage points between the highest and lowestincome quintiles within a particular country).

Third, only a small proportion (10%) of theregion’s wastewater undergoes treatment.

Fourth, The operational indicators illustrate thelow level of efficiency of water and sewerageprovision with unaccounted for water at up tothree times the rate prevalent in OECD countries;and labor-based efficiency indicators up to sixtimes the levels prevalent in OECD countries.

Fifth, the proportion of operating costs coveredby water tariffs for those countries for whichdata is available is as low as 27%, indicating themagnitude of the political problems which arelikely to arise when attempting to raise tariffs tocost recovery levels.

Page 11: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

6

Average Low High

Water Connection Rates 80% 8% 100%

Urban 89% -- --

Rural 57% -- --

Sewerage Connection Rates 67% 30% 100%

Urban 80% -- --

Rural 34% -- --

Proportion of Supplies from Groundwater 50% -- --

Proportion of Wastewater Treated 5%-10% -- --

Unaccounted for Water 40%-60% 34% --

Cost Recovery Rate 27%-43% -- --

Employees per 1000 Connections 10-20 5 --

Salaries as % of Total Cost >50% <40%

Sources: Blanlot, 1995; PAHO, 1994; Yepes, 1990.

Table 3: Overview Statistics

However, it would be wrong to suggest that the < adequate tariff levels based on thewater and sanitation sector in Latin America principle of cost recovery;presents a uniformly gloomy panorama. Therehave been some notable success stories for water < stability of tenure in managerial posts;utilities operating within the public sector, whichare worthy of study and emulation. Yepes (1990) < the existence of good cost accountingidentifies a sample of the leading water utilities in systems;Latin America whose performance on a varietyof efficiency indicators lies closer to the OECD < the use of private subcontractors; andaverage than to the average for the rest of theLatin American continent. They are: from < a strong customer focus.Colombia, ACUAVALLE (Cali) and EPM(Medellin); from Mexico, CAD (Monterrey);from Brazil, COPASA (Minas Gerais); and fromChile, EMOS (Santiago).

The study attempts to identify some of the sense of pride and ‘ownership’ within the localcommon features of these companies which community. It seems probable that it is suchexplain their superior performance, and stresses intangibles which lie at the root of the success in particular the importance of the following of these enterprises, and that the various featurescharacteristics: of the institutions outlined above are

However, many commentators, including Yepes, have emphasized the existence of a strong institutional culture, encompassing both a high degree of professionalism among staff and a

Page 12: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

7

Issue Economic Dimension Political Dimension

Horizontal Structure Fragmented Networks Municipal Control

Responsibility for Provision Limited Scope for Competition Desire to Retain Public SectorControl

Social Policy Health/Environmental Externalities Strong Ideological Character

Table 4: Special Features of the Water Sector

the outward manifestations rather than the mented municipal provision (as is often the caseunderlying causes of this success. This in Colombia). observation has important implications for thepossibility of replicating these experiences The possibility of adopting a highly elsewhere. decentralized model of provision is derived

Special Features

From this sectoral overview, it is possible toidentify three special features of the water andsanitation sector which set it apart from otherpublic service industries. These special featureshave both an economic and a political dimension,as highlighted in Table 4.

First, unlike other public services, the verticalstructure of the water and sanitation sector is arelatively uncontentious issue, with the majorityof countries adopting a vertically integratedapproach to the provision of clean and dirtywater services. This structure is quite readilyjustified both on the grounds of internalizing theenvironmental externalities associated with thedischarge of sewage, and of sanctioning thenonpayment of sewerage services which cannotbe disconnected (Blanlot, 1995).

However, the horizontal structure of theindustry exhibits an extremely wide degree ofvariation across countries, ranging from singlenationwide entities (for example, IDAAN inPanama), to large regional enterprises (such asthe regional water companies in Chile), to frag-

from the technological characteristics of waternetworks themselves. Specifically the relativelylow unit value of water relative to its costs oftransportation prevents the construction of alarge integrated national transmission grid as iscommonplace in the electricity industry, andtends to produce instead a set of highlyfragmented local distribution networks. Thesetechnological features are often reflectedpolitically in a history of municipal control of

the sector. For example, the new Colombianconstitution explicitly places the responsibilityfor these services in the hands of themunicipalities. Thus, the major structural issue inany reform of the water and sanitation sector isto identify the appropriate degree ofdecentralization in any particular case.

Second, the technological characteristics of thewater and sanitation sector which tend to produce the fragmentation of distributionnetworks tend also to preclude the developmentof competition in the market. The model ofelectricity generation plants competing toproduce electricity through a pool mechanism,cannot plausibly be applied to the case of watertreatment plants. An important reason for this isthat the fragmentation of distribution networks

Page 13: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

8

limits the number of economically efficient way of introducing private-sector participationtreatment plants that can be built to supply any into a sector which often presents a relativelyparticular conurbation. A further complication is unattractive commercial environment to thethat water, unlike electricity, is not an private investor. homogeneous product. Thus, anyimplementation of third party network accesswould require careful monitoring of the quality of the water that was being delivered into thedistribution system.

Consequently, discussions of the role forcompetition in the water sector have tended toconfine themselves to the mechanism ofcompetition for the market. Such an approach tothe development of competition has the furtheradvantage of retaining the ownership, or at leastthe ultimate ownership, of water and sanitationinfrastructure within the public sector. This canbe politically attractive, when the only otherprivatization alternative is the creation of aprivatized monopoly via a sale of assets (alongthe lines of that which has been undertaken inEngland and Wales). Moreover, in manydeveloping countries it may be the only feasible

Third, water and sanitation services are oftenidentified as having the strongest socialcharacteristics of any of the public utilityindustries. In economic terms, this is a result ofthe significant externalities associated with theuse of such services, which can be both positive(in terms of public health benefits) and negative(in terms of environmental degradation). Inaddition, the fundamental need for water as abasis for human survival, and the acutecompetition for the resource in arid countries,have combined to make access to water a highlypolitical issue. As a result, the disconnection ofthe water service is often considered sociallyunacceptable, and in some countries (forexample, Mexico) has been made illegal. Thisfeature of the sector can often come into conflictwith programs to increase the commercializationof service provision.

Policy Responses

Optimal Sector Structure

As noted above, the water and sanitation sectordisplays a wide degree of horizontal forms oforganization across countries. The considerationof the optimal horizontal structure of the industryhas traditionally only been considered in thenarrow economic context of economies of scaleas reflected in the technological cost structuresfacing the industry. Hence, the focus has been onoperational and managerial efficiency.

Even on these relatively narrow criteria there issome disagreement as to where the minimum

efficient scale lies, and much seems to depend on whether the question is posed at the plant level or at the level of the overall business unit.For Latin America, Yepes (1990) presentsevidence of continuously improving efficiencylevels over a range of population served from10,000 to 1,000,000.

However, it seems likely that many of theefficiency gains associated with serving largerunits come from the economies of density arising in large conurbations. Thus, one cannotnecessarily infer from such data that it would beoptimal for the provision of dispersed rural

Page 14: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

9

Consideration Criterion for Determining Optimal Scale

Operational Efficiency Volume Supplied>Minimum Efficient Scale

Managerial Efficiency Minimize Management Costs per Unit Volume

Environmental Preservation Scope of Hydrographic Basin

Private Participation Minimum Size of Commercially Viable Unit

Investment Finance Minimize Cost of Capital

Regulatory Control Feasibility of Overseeing Number of Enterprises

Social Solidarity Adequate Basis for Cross-Subsidy

Table 5: The Multiple Dimensions of Optimal Scale

communities to be agglomerated in the same both abstraction and discharge. This raises theway. need either to internalize these externalities by

The purpose of this section is to broaden the hydrographic boundaries, or at least to base thedebate on the optimal structure of the water and regulation of abstractions and discharges on asanitation sector by acknowledging the holistic view of the river basin. existence of a number of other importantconsiderations which should influence the The concept of integrated river basinchoice of sector structure. In practice, each of management was the guiding principle behind these different considerations may point to a the reorganization of the water sector in different degree of centralization or England and Wales in 1973, forming, from adecentralization. Thus, there may be no unique large number of dispersed municipal providers,answer to the question of optimal scale, ten water authorities based around the majornecessitating a prioritization between the river basins. Whether or not the hydrographicdifferent dimensions of the problem, or possibly unit should be the driving consideration inthe allocation of different aspects of sectoral determining the optimal sector structure in Latinactivity to different institutions each with its America will depend upon a number ofown optimal geographical scope of jurisdiction. considerations:These multiple dimensions of optimal scale aresummarized in Table 5. < population density, and the geographic

Perhaps the most obvious additional facet of the the major hydrographic features of theoptimal structure of the water and sanitation country, which will affect the degree ofsector is the issue of environmental environmental tension between watermanagement and protection. Unlike the other users;public utility services, the water and sanitationsector is essentially a man-made adjunct to the < the size and distribution of river basinsnatural water cycle whose geographical basis is relative to intranational and in-the hydrographic basin. Water users within a ternational political boundaries, and toparticular hydrographic basin will necessarilyimpose externalities upon each other in terms of

organizing the industry according to

dispersion of the population relative to

Page 15: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

10

the overall size of the country, which undertaken at different levels of geographicalmay affect the administrative feasibility scope: the capital city only, the majorof implementing this principle; and conurbations and the entire country. An

< the availability of resources for solving the period of the National Water Plan water use conflicts through regulatory (1974–87), which attempted to extend themechanisms; where there is limited experience of successful private sector waterregulatory capacity the resolution of provision in the metropolitan area to the ruralthese conflicts via the internalization of areas of the country, suggests that there may bethe externalities may be a relatively considerable problems associated with suchattractive approach. wide-scale privatization measures

A second consideration surrounds the issue ofprivate sector participation. Any policy towardprivatization of the water sector ought to takeplace in the context of a holistic view of theultimate scope for such measures at a nationallevel. In devising such a national policy towardprivate sector involvement, it is important to bearin mind the following two points:

< there will, in general, be a minimumviable size of contract for private sectorinvolvement, given the significant fixedcosts associated with bidding for afranchise award; and

< it is likely that many parts of the waterand sanitation sector will not presentsufficiently attractive business units forprivate investors, unless they areparceled together with morecommercially viable areas of service.

In combination, these two considerations pointtowards the danger of cherry-picking, that is,creating islands of private sector participation,and leaving a rump of commercially undesirableareas to be covered by a public sector provider.If such a situation is to be avoided, then thegeographical scope of the units of privatizationmust be carefully considered in advance, even ifspecific privatization measures are inevitablylikely to proceed on a sequential and piecemealbasis. The experience of water lease contractsand concessions in West Africa offers someexamples of water privatization measures

experiment undertaken in the Ivory Coast during

(OXERA/World Bank, 1995).

A third consideration concerns the cost ofinvestment finance. Where all investment isfunded from public or international funds atpreferential rates, the cost of capital may bear no relationship to the size of the operation. However, where there is an increasing movetoward private investment finance, whetherthrough concessions or BOT schemes the size ofthe business unit may have a significant impacton the cost of capital at which the privateinvestor is able to borrow. In a capital intensiveindustry requiring high levels of investment, thiseffect may have significant cost implications,linking back to the issue of commercial viabilitydiscussed above.

A fourth consideration is the interaction betweenindustry structure and the structure of economicregulation. This issue is certainly relevant whereprivatization measures have been adopted, butmay also be of interest in countries which aredeveloping arm’s length regulatory regimeswithin the context of continued public sectorprovision, for example, in Colombia. As withindustry structure there are two extreme modelsof regulatory structure:

< the French model, which has regulationby contract occurring at the level ofindividual municipalities; and

< the British model, which has regulationby licence implemented by a centralizedregulatory agency.

Page 16: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

11

Given the scarcity of regulatory resources, A final issue is the optimal structure from theparticularly at the municipal level, several point of view of achieving social objectives, incountries in Latin America and the Caribbean particular via the implementation of a cross-have pursued the British model creating a subsidy schemes. If social policy is to benumber of centralized regulatory agencies such implemented purely within the boundaries of aas: the Superintendencia de Servicios Sanitarios particular operational entity, then it becomes(SSS) in Chile; the Superintendencia Nacional important that the geographical scope of thatde Servicios Sanitarios (SNSS) in Peru; and the entity provides an adequate social base for cross-Comisón Reguladora de Agua (CRA) in subsidization, that is by encompassing both low-Colombia. The position in Argentina is somewhat and high-income areas. This becomes less of adifferent with the agency Ente Tripartito de constraint if it is possible for the government toObras y Servicios Sanitarios (ETOSS) having operate a system of grants between entities,jurisdiction over the water concession for Buenos whereby those operating in relatively high-Aires, and the provincial governments dealing income areas pay into a central fund which canwith regulation of provincial water concessions. then be redistributed to entities operating in

Where the centralized model is adopted, it isimportant to consider the optimum number ofentities for the process of regulation.

On the one hand, it is important that there be asufficient number of distinct providing entities toallow the regulator to undertake costcomparisons between them, thereby facilitatingyardstick regulation.

On the other hand, it is important that there notbe so many providing entities as to render theregulatory process of oversight virtuallyimpossible by increasing the volume ofinformation to be collected, and the number ofdeterminations to be made.

In view of these considerations, it mighttentatively be said that the optimum number ofproviding entities from a regulatory perspectivelies somewhere between 10 and 20, as is the casein Chile where the 1977 reform process produced13 regional entities to be regulated by the SSS.At the other extreme lies the case of Colombiawhere the CRA has jurisdiction over severalhundred municipalities. Where this sort ofstructural situation arises, the regulatory agencyis necessarily forced either to take a much morelight-handed approach to regulation, or perhapsto focus its efforts on the relatively small numberof larger service providers.

relatively low-income areas.

The Scope for Privatization

The discussion above indicated that competitionfor the market has been the preferred mode ofprivate sector involvement in the Latin Americanwater and sanitation sector. Table 6 summarizesthe range of privatization mechanisms which areavailable, and clarifies the allocation ofresponsibilities between the private and publicsector implied in each case.

The franchising mechanisms associated withcompetition for the market lie towards the moremodest end of the privatization spectrum,implying a limited and well-defined role for theprivate sector within a wider framework of publicservice provision. This preference for franchisingmeasures has also been reflected in developingcountry water privatization measures beyondLatin America. Examples are West Africa wherelease contracts and concessions have been widelyused, and in South East Asia where privatefinance measures such as the BOT method havebeen more prevalent. As illustrated in Table 7,the experience of water sector privatization inLatin America combines elements of both theWest African and South East Asian experience.

Page 17: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

12

Public Sector Responsibility Private Sector Responsibility

Country Geographical Scope Privatization Mechanism

Argentina Metropolitan Concession

Chile Provincial (various)Metropolitan

ConcessionService Contracts, BOTs

Mexico Provincial (various)Metropolitan

ConcessionService/Lease Contracts

Peru Metropolitan Concession

Venezuela MetropolitanProvincial (various)

Concession (failed)Concession, BOTs

Table 7: Privatization Overview

Although the earliest privatization measures took relying on private finance for the construction ofthe form of concessions and service contracts, water and waste water treatment plants under thethere has also been a move more recently towards BOT contractual form.

Table 6: Privatization Options

Ownership Investment Commercial Operation &Finance Risk Maintenance

Service/ManagementContracts

Lease Contracts

Concessions

BOTs

BOOs/PrivateSales/Flotations

Note: BOO: Build/Own/Operate; BOT: Build/Operate/Transfer.

This overview of water privatization measures in Colombia and Venezuela proceeding at a slowerLatin America serves to highlight a number of pace.important features of the experience.

Privatization activity has been concentrated in undertook a pilot lease contract in the provincialsome (although not all of) the larger countries of capital of Aguas Calientes, most countries havethe region, with countries such as Mexico, initiated their privatization measures in theArgentina and Chile at the vanguard of metropolitan areas. Only later, have there beenexperimentation, and countries such as Brazil, attempts to replicate measures in the provinces.

With the interesting exception of Mexico, which

Page 18: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

13

Figure 2: The Potential Vicious Circle of Privatization

With the exceptions of Mexico and Chile, which pattern of such activity is already informative.have preferred more limited vehicles of Thus far, privatization measures have tended toprivatization such as service and lease contracts, be concentrated in those regions of thosemost countries have opted for the concession as countries where sectoral and wider economicthe instrument of privatization. Such concessions conditions are already comparatively favorable.allocate investment responsibilities to the private Over the next five years it seems likely that thesector and involve the temporary transfer of asset experimentation will increasingly be extended toownership. rural areas, and smaller countries with less

Privatization measures have only been introducedin the last five years, making it too early to begin This second wave of experiments will be criticalto judge the success of the policy. However, the in determining to what extent privatization canfailure of the proposed concession for Caracas genuinely be a solution to the problems faced byprovides some evidence that privatizations are the Latin American water sector. For, thoughmost likely to succeed in situations where: cost privatization offers an attractively radicalrecovery rates are high; there is good information solution to the twin problems of confusion ofon the condition of the assets; and a clear roles and politicization of management, there isregulatory framework can be agreed in advance. also the danger that privatization may presentAnother lesson which has emerged from recent Latin American countries with something of aexperience is the potential for private contractors vicious circle, as illustrated in Figure 2. That isto bid up prices once the concession has been to say that, on the one hand, privatization is seenawarded, as occurred in Buenos Aires. as the means of bringing about the improvements

In spite of the absence of a long experience withwhich to evaluate private sector participation inthe Latin American water sector, the very

favorable sectoral conditions.

required in the sector, while, on the other hand,the sector cannot be made sufficiently attractiveto the private sector unless those sameimprovements are brought about beforehand.

Page 19: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

14

Redesigning Social Policy

However, in practice it may be possible to breakout of this cycle. The experience of the MexicoCity water privatization illustrates that theprivate sector itself can be used as the means ofbringing about the required sectoralimprovements, by utilizing an evolutionary multi-stage contractual arrangement whereby theprivate operator rectifies the fundamentalproblems in return for playing a graduallyincreasing role in the provision of the service. Afurther, and more pragmatic, consideration isthat, in some cases the goal of privatization mightbe the only politically effective catalyst formotivating a country to undertake the painfulsectoral reforms which may, in any case, berequired.

The increasing role of private investors in theprovision of water and sewage services has, insome countries, prompted a reconsideration ofthe form of social policy towards the sector. Ananalysis of the redistributive mechanisms oftenused in the context of water provision, suggeststhat most countries would be well-advised toundertake a similar exercise, whether or not theyare considering privatization as an eventualpolicy goal.

The most popular vehicle for acknowledging thesocial characteristics of water and sanitationservices has been through cross-subsidiesincorporated, more or less explicitly, into thetariff structure. These may take the form ofsocial levies on particular user groups, or of arising block tariff charging structure designed tofavor smaller consumers.

Such empirical evidence as exists suggests thatthese policy measures may not be particularlyhelpful in assisting the most needy strata ofsociety. Specifically, cross-subsidies tend to bequite regressive in nature. Studies of the ratio ofsubsidies to the richest versus poorest incomequintile produced results of 2.5:1 for theDominican Republic and 1.25:1 in Costa Rica

and Argentina. The reason for this is fairly clear:access to water networks is very regressivelydistributed in Latin American countries. (Forexample, in Peru over 90% of the top incomequintile have access to water supply, while lessthan 40% of the lowest income quintile haveaccess). Since cross-subsidies can only reachthose who are already connected to the network,they cannot be used to benefit the mostdisadvantaged groups in society which aretypically not connected to the network.

The regressivity of water access is compoundedby the high prices charged by water vendors,often the only source of water for urbanhouseholds which are not connected to the publicnetwork. Studies have found that the ratio of theunit price of water sold by vendors to the unitprice of the public water supply lies in the range10:1–50:1 for Tegucigalpa and 10:1–100:1 forPort au Prince (OXERA/World Bank, 1995).Even taking into account the price elasticity ofdemand, and the fact that public water supply istypically priced well below economic cost, thesefigures suggest that low-income households maybe spending more money on water than would bethe case if they were receiving a larger volume ofsupply from the public network (even if the latterwere priced at full economic cost). The inferenceis that low-income households do have arelatively high willingness to pay for waterservices, but may be prevented from accessingthe public network owing to credit constraints orsupply-side failures.

The reform of social policy toward the water andsanitation sector needs to be based around theanswers to three fundamental questions.

< What is the objective of social policytowards the water and sanitation sector?

< What source of funds will be used tofinance such social policy measures?

< What vehicle will be used to distributethese funds to the target population?

Page 20: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

15

Source of Finance Ultimate Impact Policy Instrument

General Taxation Access

Affordability

Connection SubsidiesConnection Credit SchemesUse of Service SubsidiesTariff Structure

Utility Customers Access

Affordability

Connection SubsidiesConnection Credit SchemesUse of Service SubsidiesTariff Structure

Table 8: Options for the Design of Social Policy

As far as the objective of social policy is The first consideration is the absolute availabilityconcerned, this could be targeted either toward of funds from the two sources. A country with apromoting access for those not currently large fiscal deficit may simply be precluded fromconnected, or improving affordability for those making further claims on the public purse. Acurrently connected. On the basis of the country with a low overall rate of waterdiscussion above, there may be quite a strong connections and/or a relatively high pricecase for shifting the focus of social policy from elasticity of demand for water, may be limited inaffordability to access in countries with relatively the extent to which it can raise water bills to fundlow or regressively distributed rates of social policy.connection.

Once the objective has been defined, it is of tax collection and tariff collection, which willimportant to estimate the cost of the policy which depend on the comparative extent of evasionwill depend, among other things, on the number between tax payers and water consumers.of households targeted by the policy, whetherurban, rural, or nationwide; and the level ofsupport provided, whether full or partial subsidy,or subsidized credit. There are essentially twosources of funds for a costed social policyscheme: either general taxation, or other utility

service users. In a first best world, economictheory suggests that social policy should befunded from general taxation to avoid introducinginefficient distortions into the pricing of publicservices. However, since first best conditions areunlikely to hold, three sets of considerations arelikely to be important in determining which ofthese two sources of finance should be used forthe purpose of funding social policy measures.

The second consideration is the relative efficiency

The third consideration is the relative fairness ofthe two modes of finance. If the tax system ishighly regressive, relying predominantly on salestaxes rather than income taxes, it may beinequitable to fund social policy from general

taxation. The converse argument would apply ifwater tariffs display characteristics of highregressivity.

When the objective has been fully costed and thesource of funding agreed, it remains to select theinstrument by which the funds are to bedistributed to the target population. A number ofdifferent policy instruments are identified inTable 8: connection subsidies, connection credit

Page 21: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

16

schemes; use of service subsidies; and tariff distributed as a direct subsidy scheme forstructures. An important feature of Table 8 is the connections, as was the case in the Ivory Coastfact that the source of finance is conceptually during the period of the National Water Planseparated from the ultimate policy instrument. 1974–87 (OXERA/World Bank, 1995).Thus, the fact that a social policy is fundedthrough taxation does not mean that the funds A three step procedure of the kind describedcannot ultimately be distributed through the tariff above should, where feasible, assist in ensuringstructure as a reduction in the bill of low-income that a country’s social policy toward theusers, as is the case in Chile. Similarly, the fact consumption of water and sanitation services isthat a social policy is funded through water bills both transparent and effective.does not mean that the funds cannot ultimately be

Conclusion

In summary, this paper has performed three First, in devising policy toward the infrastructurefunctions: sector in Latin America it is important to

< to provide— at the cross-sectorallevel— a tentative diagnosis of theproblems afflicting the public servicesector in Latin America and theCaribbean;

< to identify those features of the waterand sanitation sector which differentiateit from other public utility services, andwhich merit special attention in thecontext of a cross-sectoral policyinitiative; and

< to analyze each of the special features ofthe water and sanitation sector identified,with a view to characterizing the currentcircumstances in Latin America, andoutlining the special economic issueswhich arise and the options which mayexist for reform.

The principal conclusions which have emergedfrom the paper are as follows:

distinguish between the problems afflicting thesector, and the fundamental causes of thoseproblems. In this paper, it is hypothesized thatthe latter can be characterized as the failure toseparate poachers from gamekeepers, and thepoliticization of management.

Second, with the noteworthy exception of certain“flagship” public sector providers of waterservices, the Latin American water and sanitationsector presents a picture of moderate but highlyheterogeneous rates of connection and low levelsof operational efficiency and cost recovery.

Third, the key distinguishing characteristics ofthe water and sanitation sector relative to otherpublic utilities are identified as the low ratio ofvalue to transportation costs making for highlyfragmented distribution networks; the virtualabsence of any scope for direct competition in themarket; and the strong social character of theservice as a result of positive social and negativeenvironmental externalities in consumption.

Page 22: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

17

Fourth, building on the analysis of the even those countries which are not compelled todistinguishing characteristics of the water and reconsider their social policy as a result of somesanitation sector, the key economic issues facing privatization initiative would nonetheless benefitthe industry in Latin America are the degree to from fundamental reforms. Such reforms shouldwhich operations should be centralized or be based on the answers to three key questionsdecentralized; the extent to which competition for regarding the objectives of social policy; thethe market can be effectively used to bring about sources of funding, and the instruments ofsectoral improvements; and the scope for the implementation. There is some empiricalreform of social policy towards the consumption evidence to suggest that traditional social policyof water and sanitation services. has focused excessively on the issue of

Fifth, as far as the optimal horizontal structure ofthe industry is concerned, the analysis suggeststhat this is a multidimensional question whichgoes beyond the traditional considerations of Finally, the overall thrust of the paper is,operational and managerial efficiency to perhaps, best summarized diagrammatically inencompass the wider issues associated with Figure 3 which outlines the sequence of decisionsenvironmental management; private sector to be taken in any country contemplating reformparticipation; investment finance; regulatory of the water and sanitation sector. Figure 3control and social policy. stresses that:

Sixth, analysis of the role of competition for the < structural issues must be settled inmarket shows that experiments to date have been advance of ownership issues;largely confined to the metropolitan areas of thelarger countries in the region where economic andsectoral conditions are comparatively favorable.As these privatization experiments are extendedto smaller countries and rural areas, it will beimportant to evaluate the extent to whichprivatization can actually bring about sectoralimprovements, rather than necessitating them asa prerequisite for successful implementation.

Seventh, analysis of social policy suggests that

affordability to existing users, at the expense ofpromoting access to those not yet connected tothe network.

< privatization measures should beconsidered as lying on a continuum asopposed to constituting an all-or-nothingchoice; and

< regulation is likely to have a role to play,even where privatization measures arenot considered to be feasible or desirablein the short and medium term.

Page 23: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

18

Figure 3: A Possible Public Utility Reform Strategy

Page 24: Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectorsservices.iadb.org/wmsfiles/products/Publications/14814… ·  · 2013-10-05Policy Issues for the Water and Sanitation Sectors Vivien

19

References

Blanlot Soza, Vivianne (1995), Reflexiones Sobre la Reforma del Sector Sanitario, draft paper preparedfor the Inter-American Development Bank.

Dussan, Manuel Ignacio (1995), Domiciliary Public Services: Policy Discussion Paper, draft paperprepared for the Inter-American Development Bank.

OXERA/World Bank (1995), Competition and Regulation in Infrastructure: Concepts and Applications,course case study materials.

Pan-American Health Organization (1994), Health Conditions in the Americas, Volume 1.

Yepes, Guillermo (1990), Management and Operational Practices of Municipal and Regional Water andSewerage Companies in Latin America and the Caribbean, The World Bank, Infrastructure &Urban Development Department, Discussion Paper.


Recommended