+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

Date post: 01-Oct-2021
Category:
Upload: others
View: 2 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
35
HAL Id: hal-00916513 https://hal-unilim.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-00916513 Preprint submitted on 10 Dec 2013 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- entific research documents, whether they are pub- lished or not. The documents may come from teaching and research institutions in France or abroad, or from public or private research centers. L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires publics ou privés. Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit Insurance: Evidence from an Emerging Economy Emmanuelle Nys, Amine Tarazi, Irwan Trinugroho To cite this version: Emmanuelle Nys, Amine Tarazi, Irwan Trinugroho. Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit Insurance: Evidence from an Emerging Economy. 2013. hal-00916513
Transcript
Page 1: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

HAL Id: hal-00916513https://hal-unilim.archives-ouvertes.fr/hal-00916513

Preprint submitted on 10 Dec 2013

HAL is a multi-disciplinary open accessarchive for the deposit and dissemination of sci-entific research documents, whether they are pub-lished or not. The documents may come fromteaching and research institutions in France orabroad, or from public or private research centers.

L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, estdestinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documentsscientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non,émanant des établissements d’enseignement et derecherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoirespublics ou privés.

Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and FormalDeposit Insurance: Evidence from an Emerging

EconomyEmmanuelle Nys, Amine Tarazi, Irwan Trinugroho

To cite this version:Emmanuelle Nys, Amine Tarazi, Irwan Trinugroho. Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and FormalDeposit Insurance: Evidence from an Emerging Economy. 2013. �hal-00916513�

Page 2: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

1

Political connections, bank deposits, and formal deposit insurance:

Evidence from an emerging economy

Emmanuelle Nysa*, Amine Tarazia, Irwan Trinugrohoa

a Université de Limoges, LAPE, 5 rue Félix Eboué, 87031 Limoges Cedex, France

This version: June 18, 2013

Abstract This paper investigates the impact of banks' political connections on their ability to collect

deposits under two different deposit insurance regimes (blanket guarantee and limited

guarantee). We estimate a simultaneous equations model of supply and demand for funds

using quarterly data for Indonesian banks from 2002 to 2008. We find that, regardless of their

type (state-owned or private entities), politically connected banks are able to attract deposits

more easily than their non-connected counterparts. We also show that this effect is more

pronounced after the implementation of formal deposit insurance with limited coverage. Our

findings have various policy implications. Formal deposit insurance might have improved

market discipline, as highlighted by earlier studies, but it has also exacerbated the issue of

political connections in the banking sector.

JEL Classification: G28, D72

Keywords: Banking; Political connections; Bank Deposits; Funds; Deposit insurance system;

Indonesia

* Corresponding author (email: [email protected], tel.: +33 555 14 92 13)

Page 3: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

2

Political connections, bank deposits, and formal deposit insurance:

Evidence from an emerging economy

Abstract This paper investigates the impact of banks' political connections on their ability to collect

deposits under two different deposit insurance regimes (blanket guarantee and limited

guarantee). We estimate a simultaneous equations model of supply and demand for funds

using quarterly data for Indonesian banks from 2002 to 2008. We find that, regardless of their

type (state-owned or private entities), politically connected banks are able to attract deposits

more easily than their non-connected counterparts. We also show that this effect is more

pronounced after the implementation of formal deposit insurance with limited coverage. Our

findings have various policy implications. Formal deposit insurance might have improved

market discipline, as highlighted by earlier studies, but it has also exacerbated the issue of

political connections in the banking sector.

JEL Classification: G28, D72

Keywords: Banking; Political connections; Bank Deposits; Funds; Deposit insurance system;

Indonesia

Page 4: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

3

1. Introduction

Worldwide, politics remarkably influences business, particularly in countries with

high level of corruption, weak legal systems and poor governance (Faccio, 2006). Three main

channels of political influence on business have been outlined in the literature. Firstly, the

grabbing hand theory (Shleifer and Vishny, 1994, 1998) states that public firms are exploited

to fulfill the interests of politicians and bureaucrats under their control. Secondly, the rent

seeking theory posits that bureaucrats rent their position by providing privileges to

businessmen and they take advantage of their position by receiving bribes (Krueger, 1974).

Finally, the last channel concerns politically connected firms, those with political figures on

their board or those which have close relationships with whom possesses political power.

Studies on politically connected firms show that political linkages are likely to affect

firms either positively or negatively. On the one hand, some empirical studies find that the

benefits of political connections are i) an easier access to financial resources such as bank

loans or others funds at more convenient conditions (Charumilind et al., 2006; Claessens et

al., 2008; Fraser et al., 2006; Khwaja and Mian, 2005; Li et al., 2008); ii) a build up

confidence in the legal system (Li et al., 2008); iii) an improved performance (Johnson and

Mitton, 2003); iv) a higher probability of being bailed out (Faccio et al., 2006); v) an increase

in firm value by, for example, increasing its stock value (Goldman et al., 2009), and vi) a

lower cost of equity capital (Boubakri et al., 2012). On the other hand, some studies find

negative impacts of being politically connected firms such as i) lower quality of accounting

information (e.g. reported earnings (Chaney et al., 2011)); ii) lower qualifications of the

appointed managers and directors (Boubakri et al., 2012; Leuz and Oberholzer-Gee, 2006);

iii) a decrease in long term performance because of lower managerial incentives and/or

inefficiency (Claessens et al., 2008; Fan et al., 2007); and iv) a higher cost of debt (Bliss and

Gul, 2012).

If the literature on political connections of non-financial firms is well documented, the

impact of being a politically connected bank is less studied. Most papers on the role of

politics in the banking industry study profitability, lending behavior and risk-taking of state-

owned (government) banks compared to private banks. Molyneux and Thornton (1992) find

that government ownership has a positive impact on bank profitability. Sapienza (2004)

documents that state-owned banks charge lower interest rates than private banks to similar or

identical firms. Moreover, the lending behavior of state-owned banks is influenced by the

electoral performance of the party affiliated with the bank. Dinc (2005) concludes that

Page 5: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

4

government banks increase their lending in election years relatively to private banks

particularly in developing countries.

In this paper, we study the role played by banks’ political connections in attracting

deposits and whether this might be influenced by the type of deposit insurance system in

place. Specifically, we question whether formal insurance with limited coverage – which is

expected to credibly exclude some creditors – outweighs, to some extent, the benefits of

being politically connected or if it provides more value to political connections. We start by

investigating whether bank political connections effectively impact the supply of funds, i.e.

facilitates the access to deposit funding. It is generally considered that banks invest in such

connections because they expect that the benefit they would receive is higher than the cost

that they would bear. Particularly in an unsophisticated and turbulent banking environment,

being politically connected could be a valuable resource for banks, enabling them to more

easily obtain resources under the form of deposits1. Depositors might perceive these banks as

less risky because banks’ political connections are expected to implicitly guarantee that the

government would rescue them2 in case of distress and thus depositors could recover their

funds more easily.

We then introduce a change in the regulatory environment and more specifically in

the deposit insurance system. We question whether this potential added value of being

politically connected is identical under a blanket guarantee regime and a limited guarantee

system. Looking at both environments will reveal insights on the effectiveness or not of the

implementation of deposit insurance with limited coverage. By credibly excluding some

creditors, formal deposit insurance is expected to increase the monitoring efforts of bank

creditors and market participants. Several studies examine depositors’ behavior when a

blanket guarantee system is replaced with a limited guarantee system. For instance, Imai

(2006) finds that the deposit insurance reform in Japan, from a blanket guarantee system to a

limited guarantee system, has enhanced market discipline by increasing the sensitivity of

deposit interest rates and by increasing the sensitivity of deposit quantity to default risk.

However, this paper also concludes that the reform led to more frequent and more generous

too big to fail policies. Hadad et al. (2011) obtain mixed results with regard to market

discipline while considering regulatory changes in Indonesia after the 1997/1998 financial 1 Collecting deposits is an important activity for banks. Banks have specific characteristics in how they fund their assets by collecting deposits from the public, then use these deposits to finance their loans to generate income. Therefore, they need to attract more deposits to support their increased lending activities as deposits are considered as cheaper and more stable funds than other sources of funding. 2 Faccio et al. (2006) show that politically connected firms are more likely to be bailed out.

Page 6: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

5

crisis. Concerning the adoption of a blanket guarantee system and later on by the limited

guarantee system, they show that the need for market discipline in the banking industry has

been lessened. In the present paper we address the issue of the credibility of the explicit

deposit insurance and therefore of the effectiveness of market discipline – i.e. depositors

believe that banks might fail – by studying whether the added value of being politically

connected is different during the blanket guarantee scheme and the limited guarantee system.

If explicit deposit insurance credibly excludes some creditors and insolvent banks do actually

fail (no bail-out policy) political connections will have less value. If however, insolvent

banks can still, to some extent, benefit from some sort of support, political connections will

have more value.

We study the case of Indonesian banks, which have undergone two regulatory

changes regarding deposit insurance during the time period we cover. We take advantage of

the introduction of a limited guarantee (LG) system in Indonesian banking that has replaced a

blanket guarantee scheme (BGS). When the 1997/1998 financial crisis was at its height, the

Indonesian government closed 16 small banks, which led to bank runs in almost all banks. To

prevent the collapse of the overall banking system, the government consequently had to inject

a very large amount of last resort loans (Kane and McLeod, 2002; Djiwandono, 2004). Thus,

to restore depositors’ confidence, a blanket guarantee of all deposits and other liabilities

(except equity and subordinated debt) was introduced in January 1998 (Kane and McLeod,

2002; McLeod, 2005; Hadad et al., 2011). The BGS applied to all commercial banks in

Indonesia, except for the branch offices of foreign banks. In other words there was an explicit

insurance that all banks would be bailed out, except the foreign ones3. Then, after several

improvements in the banking system such as the increase in minimum capital requirements4,

the implementations of related lending limitations5, Central Bank independency6, and good

3 Banks that participate in the BGS have to pay a fixed-rate premium of 0.25% of deposits per year. The Indonesian Bank Restructuring Agency (IBRA) was assigned to manage the BGS (Hadad et al., 2011). 4 The regulation with regard to capital requirement has changed twice since the 1997/1998 financial crisis. In November 1998, the minimum CAR was temporarily reduced from 8% to 4% of the risk weighted assets, it then returned to 8% in December 2001 (Hadad et al., 2011) 5 In January 2005, the Central Bank enforced a strict regulation on bank’s lending limitation to its related parties. The maximum related lending is 10% of bank capital. A related party is defined as any natural person or company/entity exercising control over the bank, whether directly or indirectly, through ownership, management, and/or financial links (Hamada and Konishi, 2010). 6 The Central Bank independency was enacted on May 17, 1999 based on Act (UU) No. 23/1999 on Bank Indonesia, and has been amended with Act (UU) No.3/2004 on January 15, 2004. The Act states the status and position of Bank Indonesia as an independent state institution and freedom from interference by the Government or any other external parties.

Page 7: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

6

governance rules, the limited guarantee scheme was implemented in September 20057 to

replace the blanket guarantee scheme. We look in this paper at the impact of banks' political

connections within these two different regulatory environments.

In our study, we use detailed information on banks’ political connections. Since the

1997/1998 crisis, banks’ political connections consist of recruiting former bureaucrats and

politicians for banks’ board of commissioners and board of directors. There are two kinds of

politically connected banks. First, we consider state-owned banks as politically connected

banks. Second, we incorporate politically connected private banks, which we define as those

banks with at least one politically connected commissioner, or politically connected director,

or politically connected controlling shareholder. We use more detailed information than in

previous literature on banks’ political connections. While most papers on the role of politics

in the banking industry focus on banks' ownership, in the present paper we provide a deeper

investigation by looking not only at political connections of state-owned banks but also at

those of private banks, which have such connections through their board members or

shareholders. Our paper is hence related to Carreta et al. (2012) who consider the role of

politicians on the board of banks by studying Italian cooperative banks. They find that banks

with politically connected directors have higher net interest revenues, lower loan portfolio

quality and lower efficiency than banks without such connections.

We use a simultaneous equations panel data model of supply and demand for funds.

We base our investigation on quarterly data from 2002 to 2008 by separating the two deposit

insurance environments under which Indonesian banks have operated: the pre-deposit

insurance state with blanket guarantee until the third quarter of 2005 and the post-deposit

insurance state thereafter. We do find that politically connected banks collect deposits at

better conditions. But after the replacement of the blanket guarantee with limited guarantee,

political connections play an even stronger role. This result indicates that the explicit deposit

insurance system with limited guarantee in Indonesia is credible but only to some extent.

Depositors do seem to believe that banks may fail but they prefer to deposit their funds in

politically connected banks because they still believe that they are less likely to fail.

7 The existence of explicit deposit insurance with limited guarantee was constituted by the Act (UU) No. 24/2004 concerning the Deposit Insurance Institution (LPS), an institution which is assigned to conduct banking deposit guarantee (McLeod, 2005).

Page 8: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

7

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the hypotheses

we test. Section 3 presents the data and the econometric simultaneous equations model.

Section 4 reports the empirical results and robustness checks. Section 5 concludes the paper.

2. Hypotheses Development

The focus of the present study is to investigate whether banks' political connections

affect depositors' choice (supply function), under different deposit insurance systems.

On the one hand, the literature on market discipline imposed by depositors argues that

depositors are sensitive to the riskiness of banks8. On the other hand, the literature on

political connections supports that stronger connections will increase the probability of being

bailed out. Such banks are more likely to be rescued by the government through, for instance,

capital injection, in line with the findings of Faccio et al. (2006). We therefore make the

hypothesis that political connections enables banks to collect deposits easier because

connections might implicitly guarantee that these banks would not fail.

H1: Supply of funds is higher for politically connected banks than for those which are non-

politically connected

Moreover, we question whether a change in the deposit insurance system impacts the

role played by political connections regarding the supply of funds. We take advantage of the

implementation of a limited guarantee system in Indonesia to replace the blanket guarantee

scheme to analyze the potential effect of political connections on the supply of funds under

two such systems. The value of banks’ political connections is supposedly higher after the

implementation of the limited guarantee because not all deposits are insured. Thus, if political

connections have more value under the limited guarantee system, we conjecture that such a

system (with limited guarantee) is credible but only to some extent, in that although

depositors actually believe that banks might fail, they also expect highly connected banks to

still benefit from public support. We therefore expect that the effect of banks’ political

connections on the supply of funds will be stronger during the limited guarantee period than

during the blanket guarantee period.

8Market discipline in banking is defined as a condition in which stockholders, depositors, or creditors face costs that increase as banks undertake higher risk strategies, and that they take action on the basis of these costs (Berger, 1991). Martinez-Peria and Schmukler (2001) show that uninsured depositors may take action by requiring higher interest rates or by withdrawing their deposits.

Page 9: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

8

H1': Banks’ political connections have a stronger impact under a limited guarantee system

than a blanket guarantee system because although depositors are convinced that banks

can actually fail they still expect connected banks to benefit from public support.

3. Data, Methodology, and Variables

3.1. Data

Indonesian banks consist of conventional and Islamic commercial banks (which can

be regional development banks, state-owned banks, foreign-owned banks, joint-venture banks

and domestic-private banks) as well as rural banks. However, in this study, we exclude from

our sample Islamic banks and rural banks and only keep the conventional commercial banks9.

Our sample consists of 109 commercial banks. Information comes from the Indonesian

Central Bank (Bank Indonesia) which provided us with banks’ quarterly financial statements

over the 2002 – 2008 period (Q1:2002 – Q2:2008). Macroeconomic data come from Bank

Indonesia, and Indonesia Statistics Bureau (BPS).

Several steps are taken to classify politically connected private banks. First, we gather

information on the name of commissioners and directors as well as owners of banks from

banks’ quarterly financial statements. Second, we collect their biography to identify whether

they have a political background from several sources: banks’ annual reports, OneSource

database, and the directory data of Indonesian Banks Association. Finally, we manually

retrieve data from various websites to check the information obtained in the second step and

to complete information not found in the previous steps (detailed data sources are provided in

table A1, column 3, appendix 1).

3.2. Methodology

To investigate the effect of political connections on the supply of funds we consider a

structural model of deposit demand and supply, where the supply and demand functions for

funds are as follows:

9 We exclude Islamic banks and rural banks because of their specificities. In 2008, the asset share of rural banks was only 1.39% of the banking industry, and the asset share of Islamic banks was 2.11% of the assets of the banking industry (Indonesian banking statistics, 2012)

Page 10: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

9

(Supply of funds)i,t = f (Interesti,t, Political Connectionsi,t, Bank Fundamentalsi,t-1, Deposit

Insurancet, Political Connectionsi,t * Deposit Insurancet, Foreign Own

Banki,t, Macroeconomicst) …………………………………………. (1)

(Demand of funds)i,t = f (Interesti,t, Bank Fundamentalsi,t-1, Loan Growthi,t, Listedi,t,

Macroeconomicst, Market Structuret) ……………………..……… (2)

where Interesti,t is the interest rate on deposits of bank i at quarter t, Political Connectionsi,t is

the political status of bank i at quarter t, Bank Fundamentalsi,t-1 represents a vector of bank

specific variables of bank i included with a quarter lag to avoid endogeneity issues. The

literature underlines four major variables as bank fundamentals: bank profitability, bank risk,

bank liquidity and bank size. Deposit Insurancet is the deposit insurance system in place at

time t. Political Connectionsi,t*Deposit Insurancet is an interaction term to test hypothesis 1'.

Foreign Own Banki,t is a dummy variable that takes the value of 0 if the bank is domestic and

1 if it is foreign. Loan Growthi,t is the rate of loan growth of bank i at quarter t. Listedi,t is a

dummy variable, which identifies listed banks on the Indonesian market. Macroeconomicst

and Market Structuret are exogenous control variables, which change over time but not across

individuals.

In this paper, we simultaneously estimate the demand and supply of funds on our

panel dataset, using a TSLS procedure. We focus on the simultaneous equation results as it

allows to address simultaneity and endogeneity issues. We follow the Plumper and Troeger

(2007) methodology to estimate simultaneous equations on panel data with individual-

invariant and dummy variables (which rarely vary in the time dimension). The procedure is

detailed in appendix 2.

The supply of funds (equation 1) and the demand for funds (equation 2) can be

rewritten as follows:

(Deposits)i,t = f (Interesti,t, Political Connectionsi,t, Bank Fundamentalsi,t-1,

Macroeconomicst, Deposit Insurancet, Political Connectionst*Deposit

Insurancet) …………………………………………………………..(3)

(Interest)i,t = f (Depositsi,t, Bank Fundamentalsi,t-1, Loan Growthi,t, Macroeconomicst,

Market Structuret) …………………………………………………. (4)

where equation 4 is the inverse function of deposit demand (as presented in equation 2).

Page 11: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

10

3.3 Variables

Our dependent variables are bank deposits for the supply function and the interest rate

on deposits for the demand function. We use the natural log of deposits (LNDEP) as a proxy

of the quantity of bank deposits in line with Imai (2006). To measure the interest rate on

deposits, we use the implicit deposit interest rate (INTDEP) measured as the ratio of interest

expenses to total deposits following Martinez-Peria and Schmukler (2001) and Hadad et al.

(2011).

As we estimate a simultaneous equations model, the amount of deposits (LNDEP)

appears as an explanatory variable in the demand function, and the interest rate on deposits

(INTDEP) as an explanatory variable in the supply function.

The literature on the deposit market emphasizes the role of bank characteristics (bank

fundamentals) to explain the supply and demand for funds: these variables are bank risk,

bank liquidity, bank profitability and bank size. One can expect that depositors would leave a

bank for a safer one or require higher interest rates from riskier banks, less liquid banks,

unprofitable banks and smaller banks. To measure bank risk, we use the ratio of non-

performing loans to total loans (NPL). The supply of funds is inversely related to banks'

riskiness (Martinez-Peria and Schmukler, 2001; Fueda and Konishi, 2007). When bank risk

increases its default probability is higher leading to larger potential losses for depositors. On

the demand side, riskier banks have to increase the deposit rate they offer to attract deposits

(Martinez-Peria and Schmukler, 2001). The ratio of liquid assets to total assets (LATA) is

used in this study as a measure of liquidity risk. Banks with a large volume of liquid assets

are perceived to be safer, because these assets would allow them to meet unexpected

withdrawals (Martinez-Peria and Schmukler, 2001; Finger and Hesse, 2009). Therefore, the

supply of funds should be higher for liquid banks and less liquid banks should pay a higher

interest rate to attract deposits (Martinez-Peria and Schmukler, 2001; Hadad et al., 2011).

Bank profitability is measured by the ratio of return on assets (ROA). Higher bank profits are

expected to signal better bank soundness making things easier to attract funds/deposits

(Martinez-Peria and Schmukler, 2001; Hori et al., 2009; Finger and Hesse, 2009). On the

demand side, we might expect higher profitability to enable banks to offer lower rates

(Martinez-Peria and Schmukler, 2001, Hori et al., 2009). In the present study, we use, as a

proxy of bank size, a dummy variable that identifies the ten largest banks in Indonesia (TEN).

Large banks are perceived as systemically important banks that would most likely be bailed

out by the government if they collapse (Imai, 2006; Onder and Ozyildirim, 2008). Therefore

we expect a higher supply of funds for these too-big-to-fail banks, and a lower interest rate

Page 12: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

11

paid on deposits (Mondscean and Opiela, 1999; Opiela, 2004; Onder and Ozyildirim, 2008;

Hadad et al., 2011).

Bank control variables are also introduced. We take into account the bank’s rate of

loan growth (Loan Growth), as fast growing banks should demand more deposits. We also

control for listed banks (LISTED). Publicly traded banks may have an easier access to market

financing, which thus reduces their dependency on deposits; their demand of funds should be

lower. In the supply function, we consider whether banks are domestic or foreign (FOB).

Indeed, foreign banks did not benefit from the blanket guarantee scheme in Indonesia, but

they benefit from the limited guarantee system introduced thereafter (Hadad et al., 2011).

Therefore, one can expect the supply of funds to be lower for foreign banks than for domestic

banks, especially before the limited guarantee system. Foreign banks consist of branches of

foreign banks, subsidiaries of foreign banks, and joint venture banks.

Macroeconomic factors may also impact the deposit market. The macroeconomic

controls for the supply function are inflation, business cycle, and the Treasury Bill interest

rate. The supply of funds is expected to increase during booms and/or higher inflation

periods. But an increase in inflation could also induce a shift to other types of assets (real

estate...). The business cycle variable (CYCLE) has been defined applying the Hodrick-

Prescott method10 to the Indonesian real GDP per capita. When the Treasury bill interest rate

(TBILL) increases, the opportunity cost of holding funds increases. One can therefore expect

a decrease in the supply of funds. On the demand side, we expect that when the interest rate

on treasury bills (TBILL) increases, the interest rate on deposits will increase as well. We

also take into account the effect of market structure on bank deposits using a Herfindahl-

Hirschman Index (HHI). When banking market concentration increases, we expect the

deposit interest rate to diminish.

Corporate political connections are well documented in the corporate finance

literature. Previous studies have used several proxies to classify politically connected firms

such as i) firms, which have government bureaucrats as board members (Fan et al., 2007;

Francis, et al., 2009), ii) closeness to the country’s president or top politicians (Fisman, 2001;

Mobarak and Purbasari, 2005; Leuz and Oberholzer-Gee, 2006; Adhikari et al., 2006), iii)

firms’ owners that are members of a political party (Li et al., 2008), and iv) firms which

provide contributions during general elections (Hilman et al., 1999; Claessens et al., 2008).

10The Hodric-Prescott filter decomposes a time series into orthogonal components that can be regarded as ‘‘trend’’ and ‘‘cycle’’ (Mise et al., 2005).

Page 13: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

12

In our work, we follow the most commonly used measure of corporate political

connections, which is government bureaucrats and politicians on the board. Indonesia has a

dual board system whereby each bank has a board of commissioners and a board of directors.

The board of commissioners performs the supervisory and advisory roles, while the board of

directors performs the executive roles (Nam and Nam, 2004). We consider two kinds of

politically connected banks: the first ones are state-owned banks11, and the second ones are

private banks which have at least one of their owners, commissioners, or directors who is a

political party member12, a parliament member13, a government official (including military

and central bank officer), a former of parliament member and/ or a former of government

official.

Hence, our sample identifies two types of banks:

- the politically connected banks (POL);

- the non politically connected banks (NON POL).

We then distinguish between the politically connected banks depending on their

ownership. We have:

- state-owned banks (SBPOL);

- politically connected private banks (PBPOL).

Finally, for private banks, we take the type of political connection into consideration.

We divide PBPOL into three different categories based on who is politically connected and

on the nature of the political links:

11 We classify state-owned banks as politically connected banks because they are directly connected to the government under the form of ownership. In addition, on the board of commissioners of state-owned banks, at least one of the commissioners is a government representative as a majority shareholder. We here follow Francis et al. (2009). 12 We include membership in political parties because as party members, they can interact with government officials and managers of state-owned enterprises and can build up connections with key political and economic figures (Li et al., 2008). 13 We account for parliament members as the parliament has the possibility to present laws, and has authority to select the officers of state institutions (for example: governor and deputy governor of the Central Bank).

Page 14: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

13

- private banks for which at least one of their controlling shareholders or commissioners is

politically connected as a government official (including military and central banks

officer) or a former government official (GOVOFF);

- private banks for which at least one of their controlling shareholders or commissioners is

politically connected as a political party member, a parliament member or a former

parliament member (PAR);

- private banks for which at least one of their directors is politically connected (DIR).

To investigate the implications of the move from one deposit insurance system to the

other in Indonesia, we use a dummy variable (LG), which represents the period covering the

explicit deposit insurance system with limited guarantee. However, because we assume that

depositors anticipate the reform, the dummy variable starts taking the value of 1 two quarters

before the limited guarantee scheme is enacted. To measure the effect of political connections

on the demand for deposits during the formal deposit insurance period, we interact political

connections variables with the dummy variable standing for limited guarantee (POL*LG,

SBPOL*LG, PBPOL*LG, GOVOFF*LG, PAR*LG, and DIR*LG).

Detailed data on the number of banks based on their political connections each year

are presented in table A2, appendix 3. The descriptive statistics of all our variables are in

table A3, appendix 3. The correlation matrix is reported in table A4, appendix 4.

Equations 5 and 6 are derived from the empirical model presented in equations 3 and

4. In this first set, we have one proxy for politically connected banks (POL) in the supply of

funds equation.

LNDEPdi,t = α0 + α1INTDEPi,t + α2POLi,t + α4LGt + α5POL*LGi,t + α6NPLi,t-1 + α7LATAi,t-1 +

α8ROAi,t-1 + α9TENi,t + α10FOBi + α11INFLATIONt + α12CYCLEt + α13TBILLt +

εi,t …………………………………………………………………………… (5)

INTDEPsi,t = α0 + α1LNDEPi,t + α2NPLi,t-1 + α3LATAi,t-1 + α4ROAi,t-1 + α5TENi,t +

α6LOANGROWTHi,t + α7LISTEDi + α8CYCLEt + α9T-BILLt + α10HHIt +

εi,t…….……………………………………………………………………… (6)

In equations 7 and 8, we then consider two proxies for political connections in the

supply function: state owned banks (SBPOL) and private banks (PBPOL).

Page 15: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

14

LNDEPdi,t = α0 + α1INTDEPi,t + α2SBPOLi,t + α3PBPOLi,t + α4LGt + α5SBPOL*LGi,t +

α6PBPOL*LGi,t + α7NPLi,t-1 + α8LATAi,t-1 + α9ROAi,t-1 + α10TENi,t + α11FOBi +

α12INFLATIONt + α13CYCLEt + α14TBILLt + εi,t …………………………… (7)

INTDEPsi,t = α0 + α1LNDEPi,t + α2NPLi,t-1 + α3LATAi,t-1 + α4ROAi,t-1 + α5TENi,t +

α6LOANGROWTHi,t + α7LISTEDi + α8CYCLEt + α9T-BILLt + α10HHIt +

εi,t…………………………………………………………………………… (8)

In equations 9 and 10, we include detailed proxies for politically connected private

banks, which depend on the nature of the political links: GOVOFF, PAR, and DIR.

LNDEPdi,t = α0 + α1INTDEPi,t + α2SBPOLi,t + α3GOVOFFi,t + α4PARi,t + α5DIRi,+ α6LGt +

α7 SBPOL*LGi,t + α8 GOVOFF*LGi,t + α9 PAR*LGi,t + α10 DIR*LGi,t +

α11NPLi,t-1 + α12LATAi,t-1 + α13ROAi,t-1 + α14TENi,t + α15FOBi + α16INFLATIONt

+ α17CYCLEt + α18TBILLt + εi,t …..………………………………………… (9)

INTDEPsi,t = α0 + α1LNDEPi,t + α2NPLi,t-1 + α3LATAi,t-1 + α4ROAi,t-1 + α5TENi,t +

α6LOANGROWTHi,t + α7LISTEDi + α8CYCLEt + α9T-BILLt + α10HHIt +

εi,t…………………………………………………………………………… (10)

4. Results and Robustness checks

4.1. Results

We examine the impact of banks’ political connections on the supply of funds by

estimating the supply and demand functions of deposits using simultaneous equations panel

data techniques. One of the focuses of this study is whether or not politically connected banks

face a higher supply of funds. We also investigate whether there is a difference on the effect

of banks’ political connections under two different deposit insurance systems.

Results for equations (5) and (6), for equations (7) and (8), and for equations (9) and

(10) are respectively presented in tables 1, 2, and 3.

----------------------------- Insert Table 1 here

----------------------------- -----------------------------

Insert Table 2 here ----------------------------- -----------------------------

Insert Table 3 here -----------------------------

Page 16: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

15

Table 1 presents the results for the structural model where all the politically connected

banks (either private or state-owned) are distinguished from the non-connected institutions

(POL). The last two columns of the table show the results when the limited guarantee dummy

variable and the associated interaction terms are introduced in the supply function. Table 2

shows the results with a more detailed breakdown for political connections: state-owned

banks (SBPOL) and politically connected private banks (PBPOL). Finally, estimation results

for the set of state-owned banks and the three different proxies of politically connected

private banks (GOVOFF, PAR, and DIR) are reported in table 3.

Overall, our results support the conjecture that the supply of funds is higher for

politically connected banks. In table 114, the POL variable, which identifies politically

connected banks, has a positive and significant coefficient. This result is consistent with our

hypothesis that politically connected banks benefit from a higher supply of funds than their

non-politically connected counterparts. In table 2, our two measures of banks’ political

connections, the one for state-owned banks (SBPOL) and the one for politically connected

private banks (PBPOL), also have a positive and significant impact on the supply of deposits.

Furthermore, when we consider the detailed information on the nature of the political

connections of private banks (GOVOFF, PAR and DIR) in table 3, we find that having

former/current bureaucrats (GOVOFF), politicians – parliament or political party members –

on the board of commissioners or as banks’ owners (PAR), and/or politically connected

directors (DIR) makes it easier for banks to collect deposits. Therefore the results confirm our

hypothesis that being politically connected can help banks attract deposits. Such politically

connected banks are presumably perceived as less risky by depositors because their political

connections might prevent them from failure. Another possible explanation is that the

political figures on the board of these banks could take advantage of their political power to

encourage government or state-owned enterprises to place their assets in the banks where

they are commissioners.

We then examine the impact of a change in the deposit insurance system. We argue

that the effect of political connections on the supply of funds might be stronger after the

introduction of the limited guarantee (LG) system because in theory only a fraction of the

14 Cf. first set of equations.

Page 17: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

16

deposits benefit from insurance. A larger added value of political connections during the LG

system would indicate that the limited guarantee is credible in that depositors believe that

banks might fail but still expect such specific institutions to benefit from public support. We

use two methods to examine this hypothesis. Firstly, we include a dummy, named LG, which

identifies the period covered by the limited guarantee system, and we interact it with the

political connections variables (second set of equations in tables 1, 2 and 3). The dummy

variable enables us to identify whether the supply of funds is affected by the deposit

insurance regime in place (limited guarantee or blanket guarantee). The interaction variables

enable us to determine if political connections matter as much (or less) during the LG period.

Secondly, we split the time period of our study: we undertake the simultaneous equation

estimations under each regime, BGS and LG15 (tables 4, 5 and 6).

The coefficient of the dummy variable that identifies the explicit insurance system

(LG) is significant and positive. Thus, overall, deposit supply is higher after the

implementation of the limited guarantee system. This is consistent with the general view that

an improvement in the quality of institutions and supervision will improve the overall

confidence in the financial system. The coefficient of the interaction variables, POL*LG, is

significant and positive. Thus political connections still matter after the implementation of

formal deposit insurance, and furthermore banks that are politically connected are even able

to attract more deposits under the limited guarantee regime. The coefficients of the

interaction terms are significant and positive for both state-owned banks (SBPOL*LG) and

private politically connected banks (PBPOL*LG). On the whole, the political connections of

state-owned banks and private banks have a stronger impact on the supply of funds after the

implementation of the limited guarantee system. Our results support the hypothesis that the

added value of political connections is stronger during the LG period. Depositors might have

been more sensitive to political connections since the end of the blanket guarantee scheme. A

higher impact of banks’ political connections during the LG system suggests that the explicit

deposit insurance system with limited guarantee in Indonesia is credible. Depositors seem to

believe that a bank might actually fail. Regulators have reached part of their goal with the

adoption of an explicit insurance providing however more value to political connections

because depositors seem to expect, to some extent, support for such banks. The coefficients

of the other interaction variables show that the impact of connections through current/former

15 As for the dummy variable the LG period starts two quarters before the official start date, and the BGS period finished two quarters before the official end date, as we suppose depositors anticipate the law.

Page 18: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

17

government bureaucrats (GOVOFF) and through politicians on the board of commissioners

or as banks’ owners (PAR) on the supply of funds is higher during the limited guarantee

system. Thus being politically connected through politicians is relevant for private banks

during the blanket guarantee scheme, but is even more valuable under the LG period.

---------------------------- Insert Table 4 here

---------------------------- -----------------------------

Insert Table 5 here ---------------------------- ----------------------------

Insert Table 6 here ----------------------------

Results for split samples are reported in table 4 (POL), table 5 (SBPOL and PBPOL)

and table 6 (SBPOL, GOVOFF, PAR, DIR). The coefficient for politically connected banks

(POL) is significant during the LG period while it is not during the BGS period,

corroborating that depositors have been more sensitive to political connections since the end

of the blanket guarantee scheme.

Considering state-owned banks (SBPOL) and politically private banks (PBPOL), we

also find a positive and significant coefficient for banks’ political connections during the

limited guarantee system, while the coefficient is not significant during the blanket guarantee

scheme. These results confirm our previous findings. Political connections are more valuable

under the LG system. Using the detailed measures of politically private banks, we find that

banks with shareholders or commissioners connected to politicians (PAR) or with directors

connected to politicians (DIR) are able to attract more deposits during the limited guarantee

system. Overall, all our findings corroborate our previous results.

4.2. Robustness Checks16

We conduct several robustness checks. Firstly, instead of estimating the structural

model (equations 5 and 6, equations 7 and 8, and equations 9 and 10), we estimate the

reduced form with panel data similarly to other studies on the deposit market (Park et al.,

1995; Martinez-Peria and Schmukler, 2001; Murata and Hori, 2006; Onder and Ozyildirim, 16All the results are not reported but they are available on request.

Page 19: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

18

2008; Hori et al., 2009; Karas et al., 2010). We include the same four bank fundamental

variables, banks’ political connections, foreign banks, listed banks, banks' loan growth rate,

macroeconomic variables, the deposit insurance variable and interaction terms between

political connections and the deposit insurance system. The results are consistent with those

of the simultaneous equations model. Specifically, we find that political connections are

significant for all politically connected banks, either state-owned or private. This result also

holds when we consider the different kinds of connections, (GOVOFF, PAR and DIR). We

also find that, overall, political connections play a stronger role during the limited guarantee

system.

Secondly, we estimate the same structural model by neutralizing the two quarters

prior to the actual implementation of the limited guarantee system (Q2:2005 and Q3:2005) to

more accurately differentiate the two regimes. Our findings are unaltered.

Thirdly, we use the first difference of the natural logarithm of the deposit variable

(LNDEPt– LNDEPt-1) as a proxy of the supply of funds to replace the natural logarithm of

deposits (LNDEP). We undertake estimations on both the structural model and the reduced

form. Some bank specific variables turn out to be non significant. However we obtain

consistent results with regard to the impact of our variables of interest on the supply of funds

(political connection variables and their interaction with the deposit insurance system).

Fourthly, although the global financial crisis triggered in 2008 did not affect South

East Asia as promptly and as severely as western countries in its early stage, we run our

estimations by ignoring the year 2008 to ensure that our results are not, to some extent, driven

by depositors' loss of confidence in the banking system. The results are still the same.

5. Conclusion

We examine the impact of banks’ political connections on the deposit market before

and after the implementation of formal deposit insurance in Indonesia. For this purpose, we

use quarterly individual data for 109 banks from 2002 to 2008 to estimate a simultaneous

equations panel data model. Specifically, we start by investigating whether politically

connected banks are able to attract more deposits than their non-politically connected

counterparts. We then examine whether banks’ political connections have a different impact

Page 20: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

19

during the blanket guarantee regime, implemented after the Asian financial crisis of 1997/98

(in which deposits were fully insured) and the limited guarantee system introduced in 2005.

We find evidence that the supply of funds is higher for politically connected banks

compared to their non-politically connected counterparts. Being a state-owned bank or a

politically-connected private bank has a strong positive effect on the supply of funds. Going

deeper into different forms of political connections shows that having current/former

bureaucrats, politicians, parliament or political party members on the board of commissioners

or as banks’ owners, and politically connected directors plays a significant role to attract

deposits. Thus, our study highlights the forms of political connections that are important in

attracting deposits.

We also find that the impact of political connections on the supply of funds is stronger

after the removal of the guarantee regime. This result holds for state owned banks and private

banks, in particular for those hiring current/former bureaucrats and politicians. Political

connections have contributed to even better attract deposits since the implementation of

explicit deposit insurance with limited guarantee. Presumably, the implementation of explicit

insurance with limited coverage is perceived as credible in excluding uninsured creditors

from the guarantee. Depositors might be fearing that badly managed and/or risky banks could

actually fail but they also seem to believe that political connections can be of value in case of

distress (selected capital injections, priority bail-out...). Hence, regulators might have

succeeded in reforming the deposit insurance system by introducing a credible threat on

insured creditors. This in turn might have improved market discipline and lowered moral

hazard incentives. But our findings indicate that the side effect of such a change in the

regulatory environment is the higher value attributed to political connections. The

introduction of formal deposit insurance and stronger market discipline might have

exacerbated the issue of political connections in the banking sector.

Page 21: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

20

Table 1. Regressions results on the full sample (equations 5 & 6) This table presents the results of simultaneous equations. LNDEP is the natural log of deposits. INDEP is the ratio of interest expenses to deposits. POL is the dummy variable for politically connected banks. NPL, LATA, ROA, and TEN are proxies of credit risk, liquidity risk, profitability, and bank size, respectively. LISTED is the dummy variable for publicly traded banks. FOB is the dummy variable for foreign banks. INFLATION is the inflation rate, CYCLE is the cycle of GDP per capita, TBILL is the interest rate on 1 month Treasury bill, and HHI is the squares of the market shares (assets) of all banks. LG identifies the limited guarantee system, POL*LG are the interactions of LG and POL. The values in parentheses are standard errors. *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Expected Sign Model

Supply eq.

Demand eq.

Supply (Dep. Variable:

LNDEP)

Demand Dep. Variable:

INTDEP) Supply Demand

Constant 13.16*** 0.012** 12.99*** 0.748**

(0.032) (0.006) (0.037) (0.025)

LNDEP - -0.001*** -0.051***

(0.0003) (0.001)

INTDEP + 3.599*** 6.621***

(0.270) (0.373)

POL + 1.115*** 0.950***

(0.014) (0.022)

LG +/- 0.400***

(0.025)

POL*LG + 0.354***

(0.031)

NPL (-1) - + 0.196* -0.059*** 0.143 -0.059***

(0.107) (0.008) (0.120) (0.008)

LATA (-1) + - 0.390*** 0.001 0.397*** 0.020***

(0.034) (0.002) (0.038) (0.003)

ROA (-1) + - -0.193 -0.014 -0.037 -0.026**

(0.149) (0.012) (0.164) (0.012)

TEN + - 3.475*** 0.013*** 3.454*** 0.173***

(0.021) (0.002) (0.023) (0.005)

Loan Growth + 0.0002 0.0003

(0.0002) (0.0002)

LISTED - 0.006*** 0.039***

(0.001) (0.002)

FOB - 1.245*** 1.293***

(0.018) (0.021)

Inflation +/- 1.867*** -2.073***

(0.330) (0.378)

Cycle + ? -0.001 -0.001*** 0.001*** -0.001***

(0.0001) (0.0001) (0.0009) (0.00007)

T-BILL - + -5.418*** 0.396*** -6.514*** 0.523***

(0.305) (0.024) (0.350) (0.026)

HHI - 0.216*** -0.582***

(0.031) (0.044)

Obs 2248 2248 2248 2248

Adj-R2 0.97 0.58 0.96 0.54

Page 22: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

21

Table 2. Regressions results on the full sample (equations 7 & 8) This table presents the results of simultaneous equations. LNDEP is the natural log of deposits. INDEP is the ratio of interest expenses to deposits. SBPOL is the dummy variable for state-owned banks. PBPOL is the dummy variable for politically private banks. NPL, LATA, ROA, and TEN are proxies of credit risk, liquidity risk, profitability, and bank size, respectively. LISTED is the dummy variable for publicly traded banks. FOB is the dummy variable for foreign banks. INFLATION is the inflation rate, CYCLE is the cycle of GDP per capita, TBILL is the interest rate on 1 month Treasury bill, and HHI is the squares of the market shares (assets) of all banks. LG identifies the limited guarantee system, SBPOL*LG and PBPOL*LG are the interactions of LG and SBPOB, LG and PBPOL, respectively. The values in parentheses are standard errors. *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Expected Sign Model

Supply eq.

Demand eq.

Supply (Dep. Variable:

LNDEP)

Demand Dep. Variable:

INTDEP) Supply Demand

Constant 13.11*** 0.012** 12.97*** 0.567***

(0.032) (0.006) (0.033) (0.019)

LNDEP - -0.001*** -0.039***

(0.0003) (0.001)

INTDEP + 3.586*** 3.917***

(0.273) (0.285)

SBPOL + 1.576*** 1.343***

(0.018) (0.023)

PBPOL + 0.731*** 0.644***

(0.016) (0.022)

LG +/- 0.393***

(0.021)

SBPOL*LG + 0.467***

(0.030)

PBPOL*LG + 0.152***

(0.030)

NPL (-1) - + 0.197* -0.059*** -0.090 -0.059***

(0.107) (0.008) (0.104) (0.008)

LATA (-1) + - 0.395*** 0.001 0.333*** 0.015***

(0.037) (0.002) (0.036) (0.003)

ROA (-1) + - -0.186 -0.014 -0.096 -0.023*

(0.150) (0.012) (0.144) (0.012)

TEN + - 3.526*** 0.013*** 3.549*** 0.134***

(0.021) (0.002) (0.020) (0.004)

Loan Growth +

0.0002 0.0003

(0.0002) (0.0002)

LISTED - 0.006*** 0.031***

(0.001) (0.002)

FOB - 1.335*** 1.355***

(0.019) (0.018)

Inflation +/- 1.875*** -1.293***

(0.331) (0.326)

CYCLE + -0.001 -0.001*** 0.004 -0.001***

(0.001) (0.0001) (0.0008) (0.00006)

T-BILL - + -5.416*** 0.397*** -5.133*** 0.492***

(0.305) (0.024) (0.295) (0.025)

HHI - 0.216*** -0.386***

(0.031) (0.038)

Observations 2248 2248 2248 2248

Adj-R2 0.97 0.58 0.97 0.57

Page 23: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

22

Table 3. Regressions results on the full sample (equations 9 & 10 ) This table presents the results of simultaneous equations. LNDEP is the natural log of deposits. INDEP is the ratio of interest expenses to deposits. SBPOL is the dummy variable for state-owned banks. GOVOFF is the dummy variable for private banks with current/former government official in their board of commissioner. PAR is the dummy for private banks with politicians in their board of commissioner. DIR is the dummy for private banks with politically connected director. NPL, LATA, ROA, and LNTA are proxies of credit risk, liquidity risk, profitability, and bank size, respectively. LISTED is the dummy variable for publicly traded banks. FOB is the dummy variable for foreign banks. FOB is the dummy variable for foreign banks. INFLATION is the inflation rate, CYCLE is the cycle of GDP per capita, TBILL is the interest rate on 1 month Treasury bill, and HHI is the squares of the market shares (assets) of all banks. LG is the dummy variable which identifies the limited guarantee system, SBPOL*LG and GOVOFF*LG, PAR*LG, and DIR*LG are the interactions between LG and SOB, GOVOFF, PAR, and DIR, respectively. The values in parentheses are standard errors. *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Expected Sign Model

Supply eq.

Demand eq.

Supply (Dep.

Variable: LNDEP)

Demand Dep. Variable:

INTDEP) Supply Demand

Constant 13.04*** 0.012** 12.89*** 0.459***

(0.032) (0.006) (0.032) (0.015)

LNDEP - -0.001*** -0.031***

(0.0003) (0.001)

INTDEP + 3.586*** 4.129***

(0.273) (0.290)

SBPOL + 1.661*** 1.434***

(0.018) (0.023)

GOVOFF + 0.770*** 0.672***

((0.017) (0.024)

PAR + 0.687*** 0.626***

(0.020) (0.028)

DIR + 0.363*** 0.504***

(0.038) (0.053)

LG +/- 0.400***

(0.020)

SBPOL*LG + 0.467***

(0.030)

GOVOFF*LG + 0.175***

(0.033)

PAR*LG + 0.121***

(0.039)

DIR*LG + -0.272***

(0.074)

NPL (-1) - + 0.197* -0.059*** -0.073 -0.059***

(0.107) (0.008) (0.105) (0.008)

LATA (-1) + - 0.394*** 0.001 0.330*** 0.013***

(0.037) (0.002) (0.036) (0.003)

ROA (-1) + - -0.186 -0.014 -0.111 -0.021*

(0.150) (0.012) (0.145) (0.012)

TEN + - 3.439*** 0.013*** 3.460*** 0.110***

(0.021) (0.002) (0.021) (0.003)

Loan Growth + 0.0002 0.0003

(0.0002) (0.0002)

LISTED - 0.006*** 0.026***

(0.001) (0.001)

FOB - 1.411*** 1.435***

(0.019) (0.018)

Page 24: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

23

Table 3. Regressions on the full sample (continued)

Expected Sign Model

Supply eq.

Demand eq.

Supply (Dep.

Variable: LNDEP)

Demand Dep.

Variable: INTDEP)

Supply Demand

Inflation +/- 1.874*** -1.364***

(0.331) (0.329)

CYCLE + + -0.0001 -0.001*** 0.001 -0.001***

(0.0001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.00001)

T-BILL - + -5.415*** 0.396*** -5.244*** 0.473***

(0.306) (0.024) (0.298) (0.024)

HHI - 0.216*** -0.269***

(0.031) (0.036)

Observations 2248 2248 2248 2248

Adj-R2 0.97 0.58 0.97 0.58

Page 25: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

24

Table 4. Regression results on split samples (equations 5 & 6) This table presents the results of simultaneous equations. LNDEP is the natural log of deposits. INDEP is the ratio of interest expenses to deposits. POL is the dummy variable for politically connected banks. NPL, LATA, ROA, and TEN are proxies of credit risk, liquidity risk, profitability, and bank size, respectively. LISTED is the dummy variable for publicly traded banks. FOB is the dummy variable for foreign banks. INFLATION is the inflation rate, CYCLE is the cycle of GDP per capita, TBILL is the interest rate on 1 month Treasury bill, and HHI is the squares of the market shares (assets) of all banks. LG identifies the limited guarantee system, POL*LG are the interactions of LG and POL. The values in parentheses are standard errors. *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Expected Sign BGS LG

Supply eq.

Demand eq.

Supply (Dep. Variable:

LNDEP)

Demand Dep. Variable:

INTDEP) Supply Demand

Constant 13.73*** 0.078*** 13.30*** 0.160***

(0.948) (0.022) (0.316) (0.024)

LNDEP - -0.006*** -0.007***

(0.001) (0.001)

INTDEP + -189.8 0.100

(114.1) (2.356)

POL + 0.340 0.998***

(0.509) (0.094)

NPL (-1) - + 2.607 -0.028** -5.851*** -0.011

(3.632) (0.011) (1.258) (0.024)

LATA (-1) + - -5.228 -0.022*** 1.260*** -0.034***

(3.510) (0.004) (0.248) (0.004)

ROA (-1) + - -4.647 -0.034* -0.588 -0.044

(4.412) (0.017) (1.627) (0.031)

TEN + - 8.458*** 0.047*** 3.738*** 0.020***

(3.020) (0.005) (0.140) (0.005)

Loan Growth + 0.0005* -0.0005

(0.0003) (0.0007)

LISTED - 0.007** 0.008***

(0.003) (0.002)

FOB - -3.481 1.314***

(2.909) (0.115)

INFLATION +/- 124.3* -0.074

(76.85) (1.882)

CYCLE + ? -0.014 -0.0001*** -0.0006 0.00003***

(0.009) (0.00001) (0.0007) (0.00001)

T-BILL - + 94.44 0.316*** -2.050 0.136***

(60.01) (0.113) (2.602) (0.049)

HHI - 0.353 -0.078

(0.216) (0.193)

Observations 1049 1049 1142 1142

Adj-R2 0.10 0.46 0.47 0.38

Page 26: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

25

Table 5. Regressions results on split samples (equations 7 & 8) This table presents the results of simultaneous equations. LNDEP is the natural log of deposits. INDEP is the ratio of interest expenses to deposits. SBPOL is the dummy variable for state-owned banks. PBPOL is the dummy variable for politically private banks. NPL, LATA, ROA, and TEN are proxies of credit risk, liquidity risk, profitability, and bank size, respectively. LISTED is the dummy variable for publicly traded banks. FOB is the dummy variable for foreign banks. INFLATION is the inflation rate, CYCLE is the cycle of GDP per capita, TBILL is the interest rate on 1 month Treasury bill, and HHI is the squares of the market shares (assets) of all banks. LG identifies the limited guarantee system, SBPOL*LG and PBPOL*LG are the interactions of LG and SBPOB, LG and PBPOL, respectively. The values in parentheses are standard errors. *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Expected Sign BGS LG

Supply eq.

Demand eq.

Supply (Dep. Variable:

LNDEP)

Demand Dep. Variable:

INTDEP) Supply Demand

Constant 13.45*** 0.089*** 13.90*** 0.158***

(0.937) (0.021) (0.302) (0.021)

LNDEP - -0.007*** -0.008***

(0.001) (0.0009)

INTDEP + -195* -0.939

(95.24) (2.254)

SBPOL + -0.346 1.711***

(0.918) (0.117)

PBPOL + 0.874 0.464***

(0.514) (0.101)

NPL (-1) - + 2.341*** -0.028** -7.455*** -0.010

(3.159) (0.011) (1.217) (0.024)

LATA (-1) + - -4.426* -0.022*** -0.042 -0.034***

(2.331) (0.004) (0.258) (0.004)

ROA (-1) + - -3.979 -0.032* -4.691*** -0.045

(3.826) (0.017) (1.599) (0.031)

TEN + - 8.466*** 0.050*** 3.927*** 0.019***

(2.452) (0.005) (0.136) (0.004)

Loan Growth + 0.0005* -0.0005

(0.0003) (0.0007)

LISTED - 0.007** 0.008***

(0.003) (0.002)

FOB - -3.685 1.503***

(2.505) (0.112)

INFLATION +/- 128.0* -0.445

(66.34) (1.803)

CYCLE + + -0.014* -0.0001*** -0.0006 0.0003***

(0.007) (0.00001) (0.0007) (0.00001)

T-BILL - + 96.62* 0.314*** -1.813 0.137***

(49.83) (0.114) (2.487) (0.049)

HHI - 0.348 -0.074

(0.217) (0.191)

Observations 1049 1049 1142 1142

Adj-R2 0.10 0.46 0.52 0.38

Page 27: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

26

Table 6. Regressions results on split samples (equations 9 & 10) This table presents the results of simultaneous equations. LNDEP is the natural log of deposits. INDEP is the ratio of interest expenses to deposits. SBPOL is the dummy variable for state-owned banks. GOVOFF is the dummy variable for private banks with current/former government official in their board of commissioner. PAR is the dummy for private banks with politicians in their board of commissioner. DIR is the dummy for private banks with politically connected director. NPL, LATA, ROA, and LNTA are proxies of credit risk, liquidity risk, profitability, and bank size, respectively. LISTED is the dummy variable for publicly traded banks. FOB is the dummy variable for foreign banks. FOB is the dummy variable for foreign banks. INFLATION is the inflation rate, CYCLE is the cycle of GDP per capita, TBILL is the interest rate on 1 month Treasury bill, and HHI is the squares of the market shares (assets) of all banks. LG is the dummy variable which identifies the limited guarantee system, SBPOL*LG and GOVOFF*LG, PAR*LG, and DIR*LG are the interactions between LG and SOB, GOVOFF, PAR, and DIR, respectively. The values in parentheses are standard errors. *, ** and *** indicate significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively.

Expected Sign BGS LG

Supply eq.

Demand eq.

Supply (Dep. Variable:

LNDEP)

Demand Dep. Variable:

INTDEP) Supply Demand

Constant 13.48*** 0.085*** 13.86*** 0.159***

(0.933) (0.020) (0.298) (0.021)

LNDEP - -0.006*** -0.007***

(0.001) (0.0009)

INTDEP + -195* -0.968

(97.29) (2.236)

SBPOL + -0.402 1.781***

(1.014) (15.21)

GOVOFF + 1.085* 0.435***

(0.561) (0.110)

PAR + -0.241 0.530***

(0.700) (0.127)

DIR + 0.558 0.399*

(1.127) (0.232)

NPL (-1) - + 2.246 -0.028** -6.787*** -0.010

(3.141) (0.011) (1.215) (0.024)

LATA (-1) + - -4.344* -0.022*** -0.105 -0.034***

(2.342) (0.004) (0.253) (0.004)

ROA (-1) + - -4.286 -0.032* -4.624*** -0.045

(3.883) (0.017) (1.587) (0.031)

TEN + - 8.309*** 0.049*** 3.860*** 0.019***

(2.472) (0.005) (0.137) (0.004)

Loan Growth + 0.0005* -0.0005

(0.0003) (0.0007)

LISTED - 0.007** 0.008***

(0.003) (0.002)

FOB - -3.706 1.554***

(2.612) (0.112)

INFLATION +/- 128.6* -0.454

(67.66) (1.789)

CYCLE + + -0.015* -0.0001*** -0.0006 0.0003***

(0.008) (0.00001) (0.0007) (0.0001)

T-BILL - + 97.08* 0.315*** -1.835 0.136***

(50.89) (0.113) (2.468) (0.049)

HHI - 0.350 -0.076

(0.217) (0.191)

Observations 1049 1049 1142 1142

Adj-R2 0.10 0.46 0.52 0.38

Page 28: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

27

References Adhikari A., Derashid, C., Zhang, H., 2006. Public policy, political connections, and

effective tax rates: Longitudinal evidence from Malaysia. Journal of Accounting and Public Policy 25, 574–595.

Berger, A., 1991, Market discipline in banking, Proceedings of a Conference on Bank Structure and Competition. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 419–437.

Bliss, M.A., Gul., F.A., 2012. Political connection and cost of debt: Some Malaysian evidence. Journal of Banking and Finance 36, 1520-1527.

Boubakri, N., Cosset, J.C., Saffar, W., 2008. Political connections of newly privatized firms.Journal of Corporate Finance 14, 654-673.

Boubakri, N., Guedhami, O., Mishra, D., Saffar, W., 2012. Political connections and the cost of equity capital. Journal of Corporate Finance 18, 541-559.

Buch, C.M., Golder, S.M., 2001. Foreign versus domestic banks in Germany and the US: a tale of two markets? Journal of Multinational Financial Management 11, 341–361.

Carretta, A., Farina, V., Gon, A., Parisi, A., 2012. Politicians “on board”! Do political connections affect banking activities in Italy? European Management Review 9, 75-83.

Chaney, P., Faccio, M., Parsley, D., 2011. The quality of accounting information in politically connected firms. Journal of Accounting and Economics 51, 58–76.

Charumilind, C., Kali, R. and Wiwattanakantang, Y., 2006. Connected lending: Thailand before the financial crisis. Journal of Business 79, 181-217.

Claessens, S., Feijen, L., Schmukler, L., 2008. Political connections and preferential access to finance: The role of campaign contributions. Journal of Financial Economics 88, 554–580

Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Huizinga, H., 2004. Market discipline and deposit insurance. Journal of Monetary Economics 51, 375–399.

Dinc, S. I., 2005. Politicians and banks: Political influences on government-owned banks in emerging markets. Journal of Financial Economics 77, 453–479.

Djiwandono, J.S., 2004. Liquidity support to banks during Indonesia’s financial crisis. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies 40, 59–75.

Faccio, M.,Masulis, R., McConnell, J. J., 2006. Political connections and corporate bailouts. Journal of Finance 61, 2597-2635.

Faccio, M., 2006.Politically-connected firms. American Economic Review 96, 369-386.

Faccio, M., 2010. Differences between politically-connected firms and non-connected firms: a cross country analysis. Financial Management 39, 905-928.

Fan, J. P. H., Wong, T. J., Zhang, T., 2007. Politically connected CEOs, corporate governance, and post-IPO performance of China’s newly partially privatized firms. Journal of Financial Economics 84, 330–357.

Fane, G., McLeod, R.H., 2002. Banking collapse and restructuring in Indonesia, 1997-2001. Cato Journal 22, 277-295.

Page 29: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

28

Finger, H., Hesse, H., 2009.Lebanon-Determinants of Commercial Bank Deposits in a Regional Financial Center. IMF Working Paper WP/09/195.

Fisman, R., 2001. Estimating the value of political connections. American Economic Review 91, 1095-1102.

Francis, B. B., Hasan, I., Sun, X., 2009. Political connections and the process of going public: Evidence from China. Journal of International Money and Finance 28, 696–719.

Fraser, D., Zhang, H., Derashid, C., 2006. Capital structure and political patronage: The case of Malaysia. Journal of Banking & Finance 30, 1291–1308.

Fueda, I., Konishi, M., 2007. Depositors’ response to deposit insurance reforms: Evidence from Japan, 1990–2005. Journal of Financial Services Research 31, 101–122.

Goldman. E., Rocholl, J., So, J., 2009. Do politically connected boards affect firm value? Review of Financial Studies 22, 2331-2360.

Hadad, M.D., Agusman, A., Monroe, G.S., Gasbarro, D., Zumwalt, J.K., 2011. Market discipline, financial crisis and regulatory changes: Evidence from Indonesian banks. Journal of Banking and Finance 35, 1552–1562.

Hamada, M., 2011. Market discipline by depositors: Impact of deposit insurance on the Indonesian banking sector. IDE Discussion Paper No. 292.

Hamada, M., Konishi, M., 2010. Related lending and bank performance: Evidence from Indonesia. IDE Discussion Paper No. 229.

Hilman, A.J., Zardkoohi, A., Bierman, L., 1999. Corporate political strategies and firm performance: Indications of firm-specific benefits from personal service in the U.S. government. Strategic Management Journal 20, 67-81.

Imai, M., 2006. Market discipline and deposit insurance reform in Japan. Journal of Banking and Finance 30, 3433–52.

Hori, M., Ito, Y., Murata K., 2009. Do depositors respond rationally to bank risks? Evidence from Japanese banks during crises. Pacific Economic Review 14, 581–592.

Johnson, S., Mitton, T., 2003. Cronyism and capital controls: evidence from Malaysia. Journal of Financial Economics 67, 351–382.

Karas, A., Pyle, W., Schoors, K., 2010. How do Russian depositors discipline their banks? Evidence of a backward bending deposit supply function. Oxford Economics Papers 62, 36-61.

Khwaja, A. I., Mian, A., 2005. Do lenders favor politically connected firms? Rent provision in an emerging financial market. Quarterly Journal of Economics 120, 1371-1411.

Krueger, A.O., 1974. The political economy of the rent seeking Society. American Economic Review 64, 291-303.

Leuz, C., Oberholzer-Gee, F., 2006. Political relationships, global financing, and corporate transparency: Evidence from Indonesia. Journal of Financial Economics 81, 411–439.

Li, H., Meng, L., Wang, Q., Zhou, L.A., 2008. Political connections, financing and firm performance: Evidence from Chinese private firms. Journal of Development Economics 87, 283–299.

Page 30: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

29

Martinez-Peria, M.S., Schmukler, S.L., 2001. Do depositors punish banks for bad behavior? Market discipline, deposit insurance and banking crises. Journal of Finance 56, 1029–1051.

McLeod, R.H., 2005. Indonesia’s new deposit guarantee law. Working paper, Research School of Pacific and Asian Studies, Australian National University.

Mise, E., Kim, T.H., Newbold, P., 2005. On suboptimality of the Hodrick–Prescott filter at time series endpoints. Journal of Macroeconomics 27, 53–67.

Mobarak, A.M., Purbasari, D.P., 2006. Corrupt protection for sale to firms: Evidence from Indonesia. Unpublished working paper, University of Colorado at Boulder.

Molyneux, P., Thornton J., 1992. Determinants of European bank profitability: A note. Journal of Banking and Finance 16, 1173-1178.

Mondscean, T.S, Opiela, T.P., 1999. Bank time deposit rates and market discipline in Poland: The impact of state ownership and deposit insurance reform. Journal of Financial Services Research 15, 179-196.

Murata, K., Hori, M., 2006. Do small depositors exit from bad banks? Evidence from small financial institutions in Japan. The Japanese Economic Review 57, 260-278.

Nam, S.W., Nam, C.I., 2004. Corporate Governance in Asia: Recent Evidence from Indonesia, Republic of Korea, Malaysia and Thailand. Asian Development Bank Institute.

Park, S., 1995. Market discipline by depositors: Evidence from reduced-form equations. Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 35, 497-514.

Plumper, T., Troeger, V. E., 2007. Efficient estimation of time-invariant and rarely changing variables in finite sample panel analyses with unit fixed effects. Political Analysis 15, 124–139.

Onder, Z., Ozyildirim, S., 2008. Market reaction to risky banks: Did generous deposit guarantee change It? World Development 36, 1415–1435.

Opiela T. P., 2004. Was there an implicit full guarantee at financial institutions in Thailand? Evidence of risk pricing by depositors. Journal of Comparative Economics 32, 519–541.

Sapienza, P., 2004.The Effects of government ownership on bank lending. Journal of Financial Economics 72, 357-384.

Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 1994. Politicians and firms. Quarterly Journal of Economics 46, 995-1025

Shleifer, A., Vishny, R.W., 1998. The grabbing hand: Government pathologies and their cures. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Harvard University Press.

Page 31: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

30

Appendices

Appendix 1.

Table A1. Measures and Sources of Variables Variables Measures Sources

Deposits LNDEP Natural logarithm of deposits Calculated from data in the

banks’ financial statement Interest Rate on Deposits

INTDEP Ratio of interest expenses to deposits

Calculated from data in the banks’ financial statement

Political Connections POL SBPOL

Dummy; 1 = banks with a political connection, 0 = otherwise Dummy (State-owned Bank); 1 = State-owned Banks, 0 = otherwise

Classification of Bank Indonesia

PBPOL Dummy (Politically private bank); 1 = Connected private banks, 0 = otherwise

- Name of commissioners, directors and shareholders of banks from banks’ quarterly financial statements

- Biography of commissioners and directors as well as shareholders of banks from banks’ annual reports, OneSource database, the directory data of Indonesian Banks Association and internet.

GOVOFF PAR DIR

Dummy (Private bank with current/former government official in its board of commissioner); 1 = with current/former government official, 0 = otherwise Dummy (Private bank with politician in its board of commissioner); 1 = with politician, 0 = otherwise Dummy (Private bank with Connected Director); 1 = with politically connected director, 0 = otherwise

- Name of commissioners, directors and shareholders of banks from banks’ quarterly financial statements

- Biography of commissioners and directors as well as shareholders of banks from banks’ annual reports, OneSource database, the directory data of Indonesian Banks Association and internet.

Page 32: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

31

Credit Risk NPL Ratio of non-performing loans

to total loans Calculated by the Bank Indonesia

Liquidity Risk LATA Ratio of liquid assets to total

assets Calculated from data in the financial statement

Profitability ROA Ratio of net income to total

assets Calculated by Bank Indonesia

Bank Size TEN Dummy; 1 = if the bank is one

of the 10 largest bank in Indonesia, 0 = otherwise

Calculated from data in the banks’ financial statement

Listed Banks LISTED

Dummy (1 = Publicly traded banks, 0 = otherwise)

Indonesia Stock Exchange (IDX)

Foreign Banks FOB

Dummy (1 = Foreign banks and Joint venture banks, 0 = otherwise)

Classification of Bank Indonesia

Macroeconomics Variables

Cycle GDP Per Capita (CYCLE)

Cycle GDP per capita (filtered by using Hodrick-Prescott Filter)

Indonesia Statistics Bureau (BPS)

T-BILL 1 month Treasury Bill rate Bank Indonesia Inflation Inflation rate (quarterly data) Bank Indonesia Market Structure HHI

HHI (Herfindahl-Hirschman Index-Squares of the market shares (assets) of all banks)

Authors’ calculation

Deposit Insurance System with Limited Guarantee LG

Dummy (1 = period of limited guarantee, 0 = period of blanket guarantee scheme)

Mc. Leod (2005); Hadad et al. (2011)

Interaction Variables POL*LG SBPOL*LG PBPOL*LG GOVOFF*LG PAR*LG DIR*LG

Interaction between POL and LG Interaction between SBPOL and LG Interaction between PBPOL and LG Interaction between GOVOFF and LG Interaction between PAR and LG Interaction between DIR and LG

Authors’ calculation Authors’ calculation Authors’ calculation Authors’ calculation Authors’ calculation Authors’ calculation

Page 33: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

32

Appendix 2. Simultaneous Equations Panel Data with Dummy Variables

Consider the structural model (eq. 3 and 4) that can be written by using the following equations: Qi,t = αi + αt +βX i,t-1+η2Zi+ µ 2Wt + λPi,t + εi,t……………………………..……………… (9)

Pi,t = α’ i + α’ t + β’X’ i,t-1 + η’2Z’ i+ µ’2W’ t + λ’Q’ i,t + ε’ i,t………………………………….(10)

where Qi,t = quantity of deposits of bank i at time t Pi,t = interest rate of bank i at time t αi = individual fixed effect αt = time fixed effect X i,t-1 = vector of explanatory variables which contains individual and time varying variables from bank i at time t-1 Zi = vector of explanatory variables which contains only individual varying variables for bank i Wt = vector of explanatory variables which contains only time varying variables at time t

Following Plumper and Troeger (2007) methodology, we start by considering system 1 below. We only include regressors which contain individual and time varying (X), our main variables (Qi,t and Pi,t), individual fixed effects (αi) and time fixed effects (αt). System 1

Qi,t = αi + αt +βX i,t-1+ λPi,t + εi,t……………………………………………………………. (11)

Pi,t = α’ i + α’ t + β’X’ i,t-1 + λ’Q’ i,t + ε’ i,t…………………………………………………….. (12)

From those regressions, we obtain the fitted value of the individual effect (�� i and �� i) as well

as the fitted value of the time effect (��t and �′� t). We then conduct regressions of the fitted value on individual-varying (Zi) and time-varying variables (Wt).

�� i = η1 + η2Zi + ζi……………………………………………………………................... (13)

��t = µ1 + µ 2Wt + φt…………………………………………………………….................. (14)

�′� I = η’1 + η’2Z’ i + ζ’ I………………………………………………...……….................... (15)

�′� t = µ’1 + µ’2W’ t + φ’ t……………………………………………………………............. (16)

We obtain unexplained terms (residuals) from those regressions (ζ and φ). Finally, we examine the complete model in system 2 by including such residuals. System 2

Qi,t = α +βX i,t-1+ γZi + δWt+ λPi,t + τζ� i + θ��t + εi,t……………………..…….……………. (17)

Pi,t = α’ +β’X’ i,t-1+ γ’Z’ i + δ’W’ t+ λ’Q i,t + τζ′ i + θ�′� t + εi,t…………………………………

(18)

Page 34: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

33

Appendix 3. Descriptive Statistics

Table A2. Number of banks based on their political connections This table presents the statistics on whether Indonesian commercial banks are politically connected and what kind of connections. NON POL is the non-politically connected private banks. SBPOL is the state-owned banks. PBPOL is the politically private banks. GOVOFF is the private banks with current/former government official in their board of commissioner. PAR is private banks with politicians in their board of commissioner. DIR is the private banks with politically connected director. Number of Banks 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008* SBPOL** 30 30 30 30 30 30 30 PBPOL** 31 33 32 33 34 34 31

- GOVOFF 23 25 25 26 25 26 23 - PAR 12 12 11 11 12 12 10 - DIR 3 3 3 3 3 3 3

NON PBPOL 48 46 47 46 45 45 48 TOTAL BANKS 109 109 109 109 109 109 109

* = until the first quarter; ** POL = SBPOL + PBPOL

Table A3. Descriptive statistics This table presents the descriptive statistics of the variables. LNDEP is the natural log of deposits. INDEP is the ratio of interest expenses to deposits. NPL is the ratio of non-performing loans to total loans, LATA is the ratio of liquid assets to total assets, ROA is return on assets, and Loan Growth is the bank’s rate of loan growth. INFLATION is the inflation rate, CYCLE is the cycle of Indonesian GDP per capita, TBILL is the interest rate on 1 month treasury bill, and HHI is the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index.

Obs. Mean Median

Maximum

Minimum Std. Dev.

LNDEP 2248 14.3382 14.1861 19.1690 8.7777 1.8306 INTDEP 2248 0.0466 0.0374 0.5593 0.0014 0.0375 NPL (-1) 2248 0.0487 0.0312 0.6219 0.0001 0.0647 LATA (-1) 2248 0.4049 0.3920 0.9871 0.0535 0.1903 ROA (-1) 2248 0.0280 0.0264 0.4600 -1.5299 0.0427 Loan Growth 2248 0.1476 0.0518 93.547 -0.0988 2.1141 INFLATION 2248 0.0208 0.0197 0.0997 0.0017 0.0192 CYCLE 2248 -1.1414 -14.858 197.639 -171.451 79.027 TBILL 2248 0.0989 0.0889 0.1574 0.0733 0.0234 HHI 2248 0.0879 0.0823 0.1365 0.0657 0.0211

Page 35: Political Connections, Bank Deposits, and Formal Deposit ...

34

Appendix 4.

Table A4. Correlation matrix This table presents the correlation matrix of the variables. LNDEP is the natural log of deposits. INDEP is the ratio of interest expenses to deposits. NPL is the ratio of non-performing loans to total loans, LATA is the ratio of liquid assets to total assets, ROA is the return on assets, and Loan Growth is the bank’s rate of loan growth. INFLATION is the inflation rate, CYCLE is the cycle of GDP per capita, TBILL is the interest rate on 1 month treasury bill, and HHI is the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index.

LNDEP INTDEP NPL (-1) LATA (-1) ROA (-1) Loan

Growth INFLATION CYCLE TBILL HHI

LNDEP 1 INTDEP -0.0826 1 NPL (-1) -0.0030 0.0555 1 LATA (-1) 0.1282 -0.1160 0.0530 1 ROA (-1) 0.0565 -0.0833 -0.1154 0.0733 1 Loan Growth 0.0258 0.0345 -0.0186 0.0243 -0.0060 1 INFLATION 0.0182 0.1635 -0.0604 -0.0643 -0.0054 -0.0125 1 CYCLE -0.0322 -0.1103 0.0324 0.0175 -0.0071 -0.0046 -0.0130 1 TBILL -0.0606 0.2472 0.1856 0.0865 -0.0315 0.0322 0.0954 0.2156 1 HHI -0.1604 0.2001 0.2532 0.1396 -0.0027 0.0414 -0.1659 0.0691 0.4137 1


Recommended