+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and...

Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and...

Date post: 30-Apr-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 3 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
59
Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang March 12, 2012 Hai Lu, an associate professor of accounting, and Kevin Q. Wang, an associate professor of nance, are at University of Toronto. Xiaolu Wang is an assistant professor of nance at Iowa State University. Emails: [email protected] (Hai Lu); [email protected] (Kevin Wang); [email protected] (Xiaolu Wang). We are grateful to Qiang Cheng, Siu Kai Choy, Esther Eiling, Raymond Kan, Ryan LaFond, Dongmei Li, Jerey Ng, Lars Norden, Lukasz Pomorski, Gord Richardson, Hollis Skaife, Lakshmanan Shivakumar, Kevin Veenstra, Rodrigo Verdi, Ross Watts, Jason Wei, Franco Wong, Liyan Yang, Bin Zhao, and seminar participants at BlackRock Asset Management, McGill University, MIT, University of Toronto, University of Wisconsin-Madison, China International Conference in Finance, and the Northern Finance Association conference for helpful comments and suggestions. We thank Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada for nancial support.
Transcript
Page 1: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts

Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang∗

March 12, 2012

∗Hai Lu, an associate professor of accounting, and Kevin Q. Wang, an associate professorof finance, are at University of Toronto. Xiaolu Wang is an assistant professor of finance at

Iowa State University. Emails: [email protected] (Hai Lu); [email protected]

(Kevin Wang); [email protected] (Xiaolu Wang). We are grateful to Qiang Cheng, Siu Kai

Choy, Esther Eiling, Raymond Kan, Ryan LaFond, Dongmei Li, Jeffrey Ng, Lars Norden, Lukasz

Pomorski, Gord Richardson, Hollis Skaife, Lakshmanan Shivakumar, Kevin Veenstra, Rodrigo

Verdi, Ross Watts, Jason Wei, Franco Wong, Liyan Yang, Bin Zhao, and seminar participants

at BlackRock Asset Management, McGill University, MIT, University of Toronto, University

of Wisconsin-Madison, China International Conference in Finance, and the Northern Finance

Association conference for helpful comments and suggestions. We thank Social Sciences and

Humanities Research Council of Canada for financial support.

Page 2: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts

ABSTRACT

Motivated by investor disagreement and corporate disclosure literatures, we examine

how stock price shocks in the absence of public announcement of firm specific news affect

future stock returns. We find that both large short term price drops and hikes are followed

by negative abnormal returns over the subsequent twelve months. The asymmetric drifts,

return continuation for negative price shocks versus return reversal for positive ones, are

in sharp contrast to the general findings of symmetric drifts in corporate event studies.

Moreover, price shocks associated with public news events are followed by significantly

weaker downward drifts, suggesting that reduction of information asymmetry/uncertainty

from the disclosures mitigates disagreement-induced overpricing. Our findings give rise to

a revised momentum strategy with an annualized abnormal return of 21%, suggesting that

optimistic investors have suffered substantial losses. Robustness tests indicate that our

findings are inconsistent with other explanations such as speculative preferences of retail

investors, idiosyncratic volatility, risk change and uncertain information hypothesis.

Page 3: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

1. Introduction

Large and sudden idiosyncratic stock price changes often occur when there are no cor-

porate news releases. While they are clearly visible, price shocks without accompanying

corporate information releases are difficult to interpret. Are such no-news price shocks

noises to investors or do they have an impact on subsequent stock returns? Are market

reactions to these shocks significantly different from those to shocks generated by corporate

disclosures such as earnings announcements? In disclosures-oriented studies, is it impor-

tant to separate price-shock effects from disclosure-generated effects? While there exists

an extensive literature on corporate information disclosures (e.g., Ball and Brown [1968],

Fama [1998], Kothari [2001]), sudden price movements without news announcements are

largely overlooked.

Price shocks without accompanying news, however, deserve particular attention. First,

no-news price shocks are likely to be linked to private information. Understanding how

stock prices impound private information not only helps investors for making investment

decisions but also benefits regulators for monitoring market manipulation. On the other

hand, private information is not the only possible cause for price shocks. Liquidity trades

or manipulations, for example, are potential alternatives. The uncertainty about the cause

and the existence of noise trades (Black [1986]) prevent investors from effectively inferring

the information content of large sudden price changes without accompanying corporate

news. These unique features of price shocks provide a natural setting to examine effects of

investor disagreement on asset pricing.

Motivated by the disagreement literature (e.g., Miller [1977], Harrison and Kreps [1978],

Kim and Verrecchia [1994], Scheinkman and Xiong [2003], Hong and Stein [2007]) and the

disclosure literature (e.g., Ball and Brown [1968], Bernard and Thomas [1990], Fama [1998],

Verrecchia [2001]), we investigate effects of price shocks on future returns.1 Specifically,

we contrast price shocks without accompanying news disclosures to those accompanied by

1Price shocks are defined as the maximum/minimum three-day abnormal return (relative to the market)

in a given month.

1

Page 4: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

public news events. The disagreement literature predicts that in the presence of short-sales

constraints, opinion divergence generates a bubble component in asset prices. We hy-

pothesize that the price shocks increase opinion divergence among investors which declines

gradually over a post-shock period, but the disagreement effect is mitigated by news events

due to the reduction of information uncertainty (e.g., Berkman et al. [2009]).2 As a result,

we expect that both positive and negative price shocks are followed by downward drifts in

stock prices and the drifts are stronger for the shocks without accompanying news events.

We carry out an extensive set of tests and the results support these predictions. First, we

seek evidence that price shocks generate investor disagreement. We examine whether idio-

syncratic volatility and trading-based measures (turnover and unexpected volume) exhibit

significant variations that are associated with price shocks. These measures are common

proxies for opinion divergence despite their limitations (Garfinkel [2009]). We find that

these measures increase around the time of a price shock and decline gradually over next

twelve months. Second, using the entire cross-section of stocks, we observe an asymmetric

pattern of abnormal returns after positive and negative price shocks and the asymmetric

drifts are stronger for the shocks without accompanying news events. The corporate news

events included in our tests are analyst earnings forecasts, conference calls, earnings an-

nouncements, seasoned equity offerings, mergers and acquisitions, management earnings

forecasts, analyst recommendations, and dividend declarations. Third, we show that the

post-shock abnormal return drifts are more salient among stocks with strong short-sales

constraints, which are stocks with low mutual fund breadth or low institutional owner-

ship. This result is consistent with the assumption of disagreement models that short-sales

constraints are an essential condition for generating an asset bubble.

We investigate other potential explanations for the asymmetric drifts but do not find

supportive evidence. Our results show that the asymmetric drifts are not a manifesta-

2Some studies suggest that public news events can increase disagreement in the short run (e.g., Kandel

and Pearson [1995], Bamber, Barron, and Stober [1997], Hong and Stein [2007]), while some other studies

reach the opposite conclusion (e.g., Berkman et al [2009]). The argument that news disclosure reduces

information asymmetry and opinion divergence in the long run is consistent with the ultimate purpose of

accounting disclosures.

2

Page 5: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

tion of the post-earnings announcement drifts (Ball and Brown [1968]),3 risk change and

uncertain information hypothesis (Brown, Harlow, and Tinic [1988, 1993]), idiosyncratic

volatility and its change (Ang et al. [2006, 2009], Bali, Scherbina, and Tang [2010]), and

the speculative preferences of retail investors (Kumar [2009], Bali, Cakici, and Whitelaw

[2011]). Particularly, while we observe the post-earnings announcement drifts and the up-

ward drifts predicted by uncertain information hypothesis in a subset of our sample, these

effects are subsumed to the asymmetric drifts predicted by disagreement theory. Moreover,

we do not find significant negative returns around subsequent earnings announcements in

the twelve-month holding period for stocks with extreme positive and negative price shocks.

This evidence is inconsistent with the argument that stock prices reflect expectations of fu-

ture bad news when investors interpret no disclosures as withholding negative information

(e.g., Dye [1985], Diamond and Verrecchia [1987], Lev and Penman [1990]).

Our study contributes to the accounting and finance literature in multiple ways. First,

our focus on no-news price shocks is novel, and the results are surprising. The literature

started by Ball and Brown [1968] and Beaver [1968] has been focused on firms experiencing

certain types of explicit public news disclosures, even though Cutler, Poterba, and Summers

[1989] and Roll [1988] show that a large portion of the variance of the aggregate stock market

return cannot be explained by public news on fundamentals. Recently, Ball and Shivakumar

[2008] show that only five to nine percent of total information incorporated in share prices

over a year is associated with quarterly earnings announcements. So, why do researchers

ignore no-news price shocks in cross-sectional studies over such a long time period? It

is likely due to an implicit hypothesis that no-news shocks have no clear informational

content such that they should be noises to investors. In other words, such shocks have no

implications for future returns and thus they are not important. Thus, a novel contribution

of our paper is that we show that no-news price shocks are important. Such shocks are

followed by significant and long-lasting abnormal returns.

Second, we add empirical evidence supporting disagreement theory (Miller, 1977) and

3Post-earnings announcement drifts exist in our sample (see Section 5.1). The asymmetric drift pattern

that we uncover is mainly from those price shocks that are not associated with earnings announcement.

3

Page 6: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

distinguish our findings from uncertain information hypothesis (Brown, Harlow, and Tinic

1988). No-news price shocks are easily observable but highly intangible signals. The huge

uncertainty associated with the shocks has led us to hypothesize that such shocks provide a

good playing-ground for testing investor disagreement theory. The asymmetric downward

drift pattern that we find is different from the prediction of the uncertain information

hypothesis. While we observe a small short-term upward drift following relatively large

price changes (i.e., above 2.5% in magnitude) as predicted by the uncertain information

hypothesis among a subset of large S&P 500 index firms, the asymmetric downward drifts

dominate among stocks with large price shocks, suggesting that the disagreement effect is

strong and persists. Bali, Cakici, andWhitelaw [2011] find that stocks with extreme positive

price changes in the ranking month have significantly negative returns in the subsequent

month. They argue that it is due to the preference of lottery-like stocks from retail investors.

Testing with retail order imbalances, we find evidence that is inconsistent with the lottery

theory. In addition, lottery theory does not explain the significant and long-lasting drifts

following negative shocks.

Third, our study suggests that the effects of price shocks and news should be treated

differently, i.e., we should control for the price shock effects when examining the role of

disclosures. Tests of disclosure effects in the literature are unconditional, as they do not

differentiate these two effects. In this study, we compare price shocks with and without

accompanying news events. Such a conditional testing design enables us to check news-

generated effects while controlling for price-shocks-generated effects. The separation thus

differentiates our study from other tests in the literatures on corporate disclosures and

opinion divergence (e.g., Kandel and Pearson [1995], Garfinkel and Sokobin [2006], Bali,

Scherbina, and Tang [2010]). We find evidence that news events mitigate disagreement

effects, which is otherwise difficult to demonstrate. The evidence is consistent with the

role of disclosures in reducing information asymmetry (e.g., emphasized by Diamond and

Verrecchia [1991] and Kim and Verrecchia [1994]) and the ultimate objective of corporate

disclosures. At the same time, the study is complement to other studies aiming to separate

4

Page 7: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

the effects of fundamental news and investor recognition (e.g., Richardson, Sloan, and You

[2011]).

Finally, the asymmetric drift pattern is significant in terms of the economic magnitude,

which we show through a set of tests conditional on the momentum effect (Jegadeesh and

Titman [1993]). The results suggest that the drifts can be exploited in portfolio strategies,

leading to significant investment profits. Specifically, one could enhance the profitability

of the regular momentum strategy by modifying the winner portfolios to include only the

winner stocks that have price shocks associated with explicit corporate news disclosures

and modifying the loser portfolio to be composed of the loser stocks that have no-news

price shocks. We show that the difference in the monthly Fama-French three-factor alphas

between the modified winner and loser deciles is equivalent to an annualized abnormal

return of 21%. This result suggests that optimistic investors due to information asymmetry

may suffer substantial losses while news disclosures partially mitigate the wealth transfer.

Overall, the pattern of asymmetric drifts uncovered by our study generates interesting

implications for portfolio and trading strategies.

Section 2 reviews the literature and discusses the predictions and research design. Sec-

tion 3 describes data and portfolio characteristics. Sections 4 and 5 present the long lasting

post-shock effects and the economic significance of the asymmetric drifts. Section 6 explores

other potential explanations. Section 7 concludes.

2. Literature Review and Predictions

2.1 Literature Review

Following the seminal work of Miller [1977] and Harrison and Kreps [1978], there has

been a growing literature on investor disagreement (e.g., Harris and Raviv [1993], Kim

and Verrecchia [1994], Chen, Hong and Stein [2002], Scheinkman and Xiong [2003], and

Banerjee, Kaniel, and Kremer [2009]). Disagreement models have attracted attention due

5

Page 8: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

to their interesting features and realistic assumptions. The main prediction of Miller’s

model is that prices consist of an optimistic bias when differences of opinion exist and

pessimistic investors cannot take adequate short positions. Harrison and Kreps extend

Miller’s model, which is a static one, to a dynamic setting. They show that in the presence

of short-sale constraints and different prior beliefs among investors, the stock price exceeds

the fundamental value by the value of a resale option, which is positive on average. The

presence of short-sales constraints per se, however, does not lead to Miller’s prediction.

Tirole [1982], Milgrom and Stokey [1982], and Diamond and Verrecchia [1987] show that

the resale options suggested by Harrison and Kreps do not arise in asset prices in models

with asymmetric information but identical priors, even if short-sale constraints are imposed.

Thus, a key condition for a price bubble is that heterogeneous priors exist. As long as

investors agree to disagree and there are short-sales constraints, the resale option has

positive value on average. Extending the model of Harrison and Kreps, Scheinkman and

Xiong [2003] use overconfidence as the source of heterogeneous beliefs and assume that

behavioral limitations lead investors to continue to disagree (which is also emphasized by

Hong and Stein [2007]). In our study, we assume the existence of both heterogeneous priors

and short-sales constraints.

The accounting literature on disagreement is centered on earnings announcements.

There are several theoretical studies, but the predictions are mixed. Kandel and Pear-

son [1995] build a model in which agents use different likelihood functions to interpret the

public announcements. Kim and Verrecchia [1994, 1997] construct models in which agents

have different information processing abilities so that some of the agents can process the

announcements into private or informed judgement, creating opinion divergence.4 These

theoretical analyses predict that earnings announcements increase disagreement. In the

model of Kim and Verrecchia [1991], however, investors are diversely informed and differ

in the precision of their private prior information; earnings announcements may remove

informational disadvantage of some investors, so that there may be a decrease in opin-

4Harris and Raviv [1993] also assume that traders have different prior beliefs and different models for

evaluating news.

6

Page 9: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

ion divergence. Sharing the same view on this point, Diamond and Verrecchia [1991] and

Kim and Verrecchia [1994] also emphasize the role of earnings announcements in reducing

information uncertainty and asymmetry, which should mitigate opinion divergence.

Empirical research on investor disagreement associated with earnings announcements

is inconclusive as well. On the one hand, many studies show that trading volume, stock

return volatility, and dispersion in analyst earnings forecasts increase around earnings an-

nouncements (e.g., Beaver [1968], Ziebart [1990], Bamber and Cheon [1995], Barron [1995],

Bamber, Barron, and Stober [1997], Hong and Stein [2007]), suggesting that earnings an-

nouncements increase disagreement in the short term. On the other hand, a few studies

conclude in the opposite direction. For example, Brown and Han [1992] show that analyst

forecast dispersion declines after the announcements. Berkman et al. [2009] find that stocks

with high opinion divergence earn significantly lower returns around earnings announce-

ments. They conclude that earnings announcements reduce opinion divergence because

managers make conscious efforts to communicate information to the market. Rogers, Skin-

ner, and Van Buskirk [2009] show that management earnings forecasts increase short-term

volatility. The effect arises mainly from forecasts that convey bad news, especially when

firms release forecasts sporadically. They show that in the longer run, the uncertainty

declines after the earnings announcements. Patell and Wolfson [1981] and Jennings and

Starks [1985] also discuss and test potential resolution of uncertainty from earnings an-

nouncements and the speed of adjustment of stock prices. In general, the argument that

corporate public disclosures reduce information uncertainty/asymmetry in the long run is

consistent with the intended purpose of accounting disclosures.

Corporate news disclosures play a critical role in explaining the evolution of stock returns

(e.g., Shin [2006]). Over past decades, numerous studies in accounting examine properties

of corporate disclosures and effects of these disclosures such as implications for the cost

of capital and liquidity (see Verrecchia [2001] and Healy and Palepu [2001] for reviews).

However, little attention is paid to separating disclosure effects from price shock effects. For

example, Kandel and Pearson [1995] focus on earnings announcements and naturally they

7

Page 10: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

do not touch the issue of different interpretations about no-news price shocks. Garfinkel

and Sokobin [2006] find that unexpected trading volume at the earnings announcement

positively correlates with future returns. Like other studies on earnings announcements,

the benchmark for comparison in the testing is not set out to control for effects of price

shocks on stock returns.

Cutler, Poterba, and Summers [1989] show that nearly half of the return variance of the

aggregate stock market cannot be explained by public news on fundamentals. The study,

together with Roll [1988] which raised the same point, indicates that more studies are

needed to understand price shocks. These papers are helpful for motivating our study, since

they demonstrate that no-news price shocks are quite common. Our study differs from these

papers in two important ways. First, we provide an investigation of cross-sectional effects

instead of the aggregated time-series variation considered in the above papers. Second, we

demonstrate that no-news price shocks are important and offer a novel angle to examine

disclosure effects. A tantalizing question generated from these studies is whether large price

shocks without accompanying disclosures about fundamentals are important for investors.

In other words, do such shocks have implications for future returns? The question is also in

the spirit of the argument in Richardson, Sloan, and You (2011) which demonstrates that

investor recognition is a distinct and significant determinant of stock price movements.5

Intuitively, stock returns after large price shocks may be related to activities of retail

investors. The role of retail trading has received considerable attention in recent years

(e.g., Barber and Odean [2008], Kumar [2009]). In a related study, Bali, Cakici, and

Whitelaw [2011] argue that retail investors prefer lottery-like stocks, which are stocks that

are experiencing large positive shocks. They find that stocks with extreme positive price

changes in the ranking month have significantly negative returns in the subsequent month.

The lottery explanation is that retail investors prefer such lottery-like stocks and their

post-shock purchases inflate the prices of the stocks, generating the negative returns over

5Our effect can not simply be due to increase of investor recognition. Since news increases recognition,

the asymmetric drifts should be stronger for shocks with news, which is opposite to the empirical evidence

that we document.

8

Page 11: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

the subsequent month. Their motivation and focus clearly differ from ours, as we pursue a

disagreement explanation of price shocks and study effects of news disclosures. In addition,

we extend their study. While we do find the negative returns following positive shocks,

we find there is no strong buying activities of retail investors after these shocks, which is

inconsistent with the explanation based on the retail investor’s preference of lottery-like

stocks.

2.2 Empirical Predictions

We focus on large short-term stock price changes, which are referred to as price shocks

throughout the paper. Based on investor disagreement theories while assuming both the

existence of heterogeneous priors and the presence of short-sales constraints, our first pre-

diction is that a jump in opinion divergence following large price shocks (especially no-news

price shocks) gives rise to negative abnormal returns over a subsequent period. When price

shocks lead to an increase of opinion divergence among investors and the disagreement de-

creases slowly, we should expect asymmetric abnormal return drifts, i.e., a negative shock

is followed by a negative drift but a positive shock is also followed by a negative drift. The

asymmetric drifts are illustrated in Diagrams A and B of Figure 1.

Our second prediction is based on the informational role of disclosure events. We predict

that the negative drifts following price shocks that are not associated with news events are

stronger than those associated with news disclosures. This prediction, depicted in Diagrams

C and D of Figure 1, follows from the hypothesis that corporate disclosures help reduce

information uncertainty/asymmetry, and thus reduce investor opinion divergence. For both

predictions, the key driver behind the novelty of our targets is no-news price shocks, which

is based on an empirical division of stocks with price shocks into two groups. Stocks in

the news group have firm-specific news in the window from three days before to three days

after the price shocks while stocks in the no-news group do not. Corporate news events

used in our study are analyst earnings forecasts, conference calls, earnings announcements,

9

Page 12: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

seasoned equity offerings, mergers and acquisitions, management earnings forecasts, analyst

recommendations, and dividend declarations.6

2.3 Empirical Approach

Price shocks are defined by maximum and minimum three-day abnormal returns in the

ranking month (month ).7 The three-day market adjusted abnormal return for a stock is

the difference between the stock return and the market return over three consecutive trading

days, where the market return is the return of the value-weighted portfolio of all NYSE,

AMEX and NASDAQ stocks. The three-day window of either maximum or minimum

abnormal return could be at any time in the ranking month. We sort all stocks into

deciles based on the maximum three-day abnormal return (positive shock) or the minimum

three-day abnormal return (negative shock). When sorting stocks using the maximum or

minimum three-day abnormal return, we focus on the extreme deciles that contain the

largest positive and negative shocks respectively (i.e., decile 10 ranked on positive shocks

and decile 1 on negative shocks).

Our first step is to examine links between price shocks and disagreement proxies. Using

return volatility, turnover, unexpected volume and analyst earnings forecast dispersion as

proxies for disagreement, we verify whether price shocks generate opinion divergence that

will decrease gradually. We also examine variation in the sidedness measure of Sarkar and

Schwartz [2009], which is available only for a short time period, to seek further evidence

on the link between price shocks and disagreement.

After confirming that price shocks increase investor opinion divergence, we test whether

we can observe asymmetric drifts following negative and positive price shocks. Specifically,

we examine the pattern of stock returns over the twelve months following these shocks. The

overlapping portfolio approach of Jegadeesh and Titman [1993] is applied. Stocks are sorted

6The informativeness of these news events is documented in many studies (see Ecker, Francis, Olsson,

and Schipper [2006]).7Alternative definitions of one-day or five-day abnormal returns are considered. The results are similar.

10

Page 13: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

into decile portfolios, using either maximum or minimum three-day abnormal returns in

the ranking month. The 12-month holding period returns, the alphas with respect to the

Fama-French three factor model (Fama and French [1993]) and the alphas with respect to

the Carhart four factor model (Carhart [1997]), are obtained. We also construct a difference

portfolio by holding a long position on decile 10 and a short position on decile 1.

The decile 1 ranked by negative shocks (containing largest negative shocks) and decile

10 ranked by positive shocks (containing largest positive shocks) are further divided into

news and no-news subgroups, depending on whether at least one news event occurs for the

stock within three days before and three days after the price shock. These sorts and the

regressions tests discussed later on provide a novel way to test disclosures-related effects.

Differing from studies in the extant literature, our tests use the no-news price shocks as

the benchmark to investigate effects of news disclosures that generate large price changes.

A basic presumption for our predictions is that short-sales constraints exist. We check

whether short-sales constraints affect the degree of overpricing such that the post-shock

drifts are stronger for stocks with strong short-sales constraints. Furthermore, we exam-

ine whether our empirical findings are robust to various alternative explanations including

post-earnings announcement drifts (Ball and Brown [1968]), risk change and uncertain in-

formation hypothesis (Brown, Harlow, and Tinic [1988, 1993]), idiosyncratic volatility and

its change (Ang et al. [2006, 2009], Bali, Scherbina, and Tang [2010]), and speculative

preferences of retail traders (Han and Kumar [2009], Kumar [2009], and Bali, Cakici, and

Whitelaw [2011]). Finally, we design a test to show the economic significance of our find-

ings. Putting the price-shock effects in a momentum framework, we demonstrate that the

profitability of the momentum strategy could be significantly improved.

11

Page 14: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

3. Data and Portfolio Characteristics

3.1 Data

We use stock returns, trade sizes, institutional holdings, and various firm-specific news

events in our analyses. The stock data are from CRSP. Our analyses include all stocks

traded on NYSE, AMEX, and NASDAQ. To guard against microstructure effects associ-

ated with the small-cap and low-priced stocks, we exclude stocks in the smallest market

capitalization decile and those with prices lower than $5 at the end of the ranking month.

We collect event dates of a number of firm-specific news events: analyst earnings fore-

casts, conference calls, earnings announcements, seasoned equity offerings, mergers and

acquisitions, management earnings forecasts, analyst recommendations, and dividend dec-

larations. The sample periods for these events vary with the availability of the databases.

These events are collected from the following data sources: Standard and Poor’s Com-

pustat (earnings announcements, 1972 to 2006), CRSP (dividends, 1963 to 2006), IBES

(analyst recommendations, 1993 to 2006), First Call (analyst revisions on annual earnings

and management forecasts, 1989 to 2006), BestCalls.com (conference calls, 1999 to 2006),

and SDC (M&A and SEO, 1978 to 2006). In addition, we use trade sizes to separate retail

trades from non-retail trades. The trade sizes come from NYSE TAQ and ISSM intraday

trading file from 1983 to 2000. We use Thomson-Reuters Mutual Fund Holdings and Insti-

tutional Holdings (13F) databases to compute the breadth of mutual fund and institutional

ownership.

3.2 Portfolio Characteristics

Table 1 presents characteristics of the decile portfolios constructed from sorting on either

negative or positive shocks. The listed variables include firm size, book-to-market ratio, the

ranking month return, and the 12-month return before the ranking month. These variables,

used as control variables in the cross-sectional regressions in Section 5, correspond to the

12

Page 15: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

four known effects of the cross-section of stock returns: the size effect, the value effect,

the short-run return reversal, and the Jegadeesh-Titman momentum effect. Idiosyncratic

volatility (ivol) and retail trading proportion (RTP) are variables that we will use in Section

5 for checking alternative explanations. The magnitude of the minimum/maximum three-

day shocks (−/+) is presented in each panel. For each of these variables, we first

obtain the cross-sectional mean in a given month, and then report the time-series average

of the mean. The average number of stocks in each decile portfolio is shown at the bottom

of each panel.

Panels A1 and A2 in Table 1 are for the decile portfolios from sorting on the minimum

three-day abnormal return (negative shocks). Panel A1 is for negative shocks without

accompanying news events, while Panel A2 is for stocks with news events. Most of the

characteristics display significant variation across the deciles, and the patterns are similar

for both stocks with and without news events. Firm size, for instance, increases monoton-

ically from decile 1 to decile 10. For stocks with negative shocks and without news events,

decile 1 has an average size of $169 million in contrast to $1,511 million for the stocks in

decile 10. For stocks with negative shocks and news events, decile 1 (10) has the average

size of $486 (3,849) million. The ranking month returns are lower for the bottom deciles

than those for the top deciles. However, the pre-ranking 12-month returns are higher for

the bottom deciles than those for the top deciles. There is no significant difference in the

book-to-market ratio. Furthermore, both ivol and RTP decrease monotonically from decile

1 to decile 10. The mean of the minimum three-day abnormal return for decile 1 of the

no-news group (−15.21%) is close to the mean for decile 1 of the news group (−16.12%).

Panels B1 and B2 present cases in which the ranking is based on the maximum three-day

abnormal returns (positive shocks). Panel B1 (B2) is for the case of positive shocks without

(with) corporate news events. Both panels show that there are significant variations in most

portfolio characteristics across the deciles. Stocks in the top deciles (i.e., deciles with large

positive shocks) are smaller in size and stocks with news events are larger in size than stocks

without news events. There is no significant difference in the book-to-market ratio. Both

13

Page 16: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

the ranking month returns and the pre-ranking 12-month returns are higher for the top

deciles than those for the bottom deciles. Decile 10, the portfolio with the largest positive

price shocks, has the largest values of ivol and RTP. The means of the maximum three-day

abnormal returns for decile 10 for the no-news group and the news group are very close,

21.19% and 20.84% respectively.

4. Empirical Tests

4.1 Price Shocks and Investor Disagreement

The hypothesis that price shocks increase opinion divergence is intuitive. It would be

difficult for many investors to immediately assess the precise impact on the future cash

flows when they observe a large sudden change in stock price, especially when there is

no corporate disclosure associated with the price change. To examine whether opinion

divergence responds to price shocks, we investigate variations of several proxies for opinion

divergence around price shocks. We check whether they increase around the time of price

shocks and then decline gradually after the price shocks. We investigate four measures

of opinion divergence: idiosyncratic volatility, stock turnover, unexpected trading volume,

and analyst earnings forecast dispersion. Though each of the measures is subject to certain

limitations (e.g., Garfinkel [2009]), examining all of them may give us a useful view of the

dynamics of opinion divergence around price shocks.

Panels A and B of Table 2 report the change of disagreement proxies in raw value and

percentage, respectively. We focus on stocks with extreme price shocks; that is, stocks

in decile 1 of negative shocks and decile 10 of positive shocks. We do not separately

report negative and positive shocks as they yield similar results. The first number in the

third column of Panel A, under the term − −1, shows that the median idiosyncratic

volatility (ivol) increases from month − 1 to by 0.773, which is significantly different

from 0. The number in Panel B suggests that ivol increases by 30.2% from month − 1 tomonth . Compared to the three-month average before the price shock (−3−1), ivol for

14

Page 17: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

month () is also significantly higher. The difference is with a value of 0.704 (column

4 of Panel A), equivalent to an increase of 26.2% (column 4 of Panel B). For the post-

shock quarters, however, Panel A shows that the signs of all the three-month changes for

idiosyncratic volatility are negative, consistent with the hypothesis that disagreement drops

after the initial jump in ranking month . Panel B indicates that after a 21.4% drop in

the first quarter following the ranking month, ivol continues to drop by about 3.5% in the

second quarter. The incremental drops in ivol in the next two quarters are 2.1% and 1.5%

approximately, which are all statistically significant.

For turnover and unexpected volume, the results are qualitatively similar to those for

idiosyncratic volatility. For example, the median turnover for month increases by 0.089 in

comparison to the value for month − 1, while for unexpected volume, the value increasesby 0.046 from month − 1 to . The post-shock changes for turnover and unexpected

volume are all negative. For unexpected volume, for instance, the largest change is over

the first three-month post-shock period, over which the unexpected volume drops by 0.043.

The three-month changes of unexpected volume over quarters between +3 and +12 are

all negative and statistically significant.

Overall, the results from idiosyncratic volatility, turnover, and unexpected volume are

consistent with the hypothesis that disagreement increases around price shocks and it

decreases over a long post-shock period.

For analyst dispersion, however, all the numbers are insignificant except for the changes

frommonth to the first quarter after the shocks.8 The results are likely due to the fact that

it is problematic to use analyst dispersion in a dynamic setting even though the measure

is viewed by many as an empirical proxy for opinion divergence cross-sectionally. Because

earnings are announced every quarter, the dispersion on annual earnings at month + 3

and at month + 9 for instance may not share the same target. While the former is the

dispersion on earnings for year , the latter may be the dispersion on earnings for year

+ 1. Therefore, the two dispersion estimates may not be directly comparable, and one

8The percentage change in dispersion over the first post-shock quarter is 2.7%, which is quite modest.

15

Page 18: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

may not observe any decline of the dispersion measure even if disagreement actually drops.

This issue is much less serious for studies that focus on cross-sectional variation (rather

than time-variation) of dispersion (e.g., Diether, Malloy, and Scherbina [2002]). Another

issue is that analysts may not adjust their forecasts immediately after price shocks. Given

the large uncertainty about implications from price shocks, analysts may play safe such

that they may be reluctant to adjust the forecasts that are disclosed to the public. Thus

analyst dispersion may not rise even if their opinions diverge.

The sidedness measure of Sarkar and Schwartz [2009] is a new proxy for disagreement.

The measure is constructed using the NYSE TAQ intraday data from 1993 to 2006. We

treat the checks using the sidedness measure as supplementary because the measure is based

on a short estimation period and limited to NYSE firms. The sidedness is estimated as the

correlation between the numbers of buyer- and seller-initiated trades. The correlation is

computed daily, using trades sampled at 5-minute intervals.9 Sarkar and Schwartz argue

that belief heterogeneity is reflected in sidedness. A relatively high value of the sidedness

measure implies that trades are more likely to be driven by disagreement. We average daily

sidedness into monthly sidedness and inspect its variation around large price shocks. The

results are presented in Figure 2.

Panels A and B of Figure 2 correspond to negative and positive shocks respectively,

including both news and no-news cases. Variation in the sidedness measure is shown from

two months before the shock to twelve months after the shock (from − 2 to + 12).

The measure is typically negative, reflecting that large buyer- and seller-initiated trades

tend to occur in different time intervals over the day. The post-shock pattern for no-news

shocks are supportive to the hypothesis that shocks generate or increase disagreement, and

then the different opinions converge gradually after shocks. The post-shock pattern for

shocks with news is somewhat surprising. The sidedness measure goes down over the first

two months after the shocks and then stays fairly flat for a while. It is puzzling that the

9Choy and Wei [2010] construct the measure using all transactions from 9:30am to 4:00pm for each day

and each stock. We thank Siu Kai Choy and Jason Wei for providing us with access to their sidedness

dataset.

16

Page 19: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

measure is relatively high at the end of the holding period. A potential explanation is that

news events tend to be of periodic nature (e.g., quarterly earnings announcements) and one

year is a common cycle that they share. It should be noted that trading-based proxies such

as turnover and sidedness may not capture investors who have negative opinions about a

stock but do not trade it. For example, for mutual funds that have negative views about

a stock but do not own any shares, the funds do not participate in the trading at all. The

existence of such pessimistic investors can create the case in which negative information is

gradually impounded into prices.

In summary, the results of Table 2 and Figure 2 suggest that although there are various

limitations of the disagreement proxies, the variations in the proxies are generally consistent

with our hypothesis that opinion divergence increases around price shocks and decreases

gradually afterward.

4.2 Asymmetric Post-Shock Drifts

In this section, we present findings about how price shocks and news events affect future

stock returns. In Table 3, Panel A presents the results from portfolio sorts using the cross-

section of stocks. Reported in the table are the average monthly returns, the Fama-French

three factor alphas, and the Carhart four factor alphas for decile 1, decile 10, and the

difference portfolio (decile 10 minus decile 1). The difference portfolio is constructed by

taking both a long position on decile 10 and a short position on decile 1. The holding

period consists of 12 months after the ranking month . Columns 3 and 2 show that

the three factor alpha is positive (0.16%) for decile 10 and negative (−0.69%) for decile1 of negative price shocks. The alphas imply annualized abnormal returns of 1.92% and

−8.28% respectively. The evidence suggests that when there is a large price drop, a long

term downward drift indeed occurs following the drop (decile 1). The annualized alpha for

the difference portfolio (column 4) is 10.20%, which is significant with a robust -value of

6.78. In contrast, column 6 shows that stocks in decile 10 of positive shocks (large price

17

Page 20: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

hikes), have a monthly three-factor alpha of −0.40% (i.e., −4.80% annually) with a robust-value of −5.16. Thus, both extreme negative and positive price shocks are followed bynegative abnormal returns over the next twelve-month period.

In addition, untabulated results suggest that negative abnormal returns are not limited

to the extreme deciles. For negative shock deciles, the three factor alphas for deciles 2 and

3 are in annual term equal to −3.96% and −2.04%, with robust -values of −4.95 and −2.83respectively. For positive shocks, both deciles 8 and 9 have significantly negative alphas.

These results further support the robustness of our findings. Finally, the last row of Panel

A shows that the above results are robust to the Carhart [1997] four factor model.

Panel B of Table 3 reports the impact of news events on the price-shock effects. We

focus on large positive shocks (decile 10) and large negative shocks (decile 1) as stocks in

these deciles have the most extreme price shocks. For positive shocks, the news subset of

stocks in decile 10 has significantly higher abnormal return than the no-news subset. The

difference between the monthly three factor alphas (news minus no-news) is 0.48%. The

difference is 0.52% when the alphas are calculated with the four factor model. News stocks

in decile 1 of negative shocks also have significantly higher abnormal returns than no-news

stocks. The difference in the monthly three factor alphas between the two subgroups is

0.12% with robust -value 2.05.

These results are consistent with the argument that news events mitigate the negative

drift associated with the increase of disagreement caused by price shocks. In contrast,

untabulated analysis shows that decile 10 of negative shocks and decile 1 of positive shocks,

which contain stocks having small price shocks (in terms of the magnitude of the shock),

display no significant difference in alphas between the news and no-news groups. Again,

the last row of Panel B shows that all results on the news effect are robust to the Carhart

[1997] four factor model.

The post-shock abnormal returns are persistent. Table 4 reports the average monthly

returns, the Fama-French three factor alphas, and the Carhart four factor alphas for the

18

Page 21: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

difference portfolio (decile 10 minus decile 1) for four three-month intervals (quarters) after

the ranking month . Panel A illustrates the case where the ranking variable is the minimum

three-day abnormal return in month .10 Several conclusions can be drawn from Panel A.

First, regardless of whether there is a news event accompanying the shocks, the difference

portfolio always has significant long-lasting abnormal returns. Over the holding period

from month +1 to month +12, the three-factor and four-factor alphas for the difference

portfolio (either with or without a news event) are positive and statistically significant for

every three-month interval. Second, the alpha for the news group is always lower than the

alpha for the no-news group. The difference in the alphas between the two groups (news

minus no-news) is always negative.

Panel B presents the case where stocks are ranked by the maximum three-day abnormal

return. This panel shows that for the no-news group the three-factor and four-factor alphas

of the difference portfolio are negative and statistically significant for the first three quarters

after positive shocks. But most of the alphas for the news group are insignificant. In the last

quarter (months 9 to 12), the four factor alpha for the news group even becomes significantly

positive. The difference between the alphas from the no-news and news groups is significant

for all three-month intervals. These findings indicate that stocks with large positive shocks

tend to suffer a relatively large, persistent reversal for the 12-month holding period after

the ranking month. This reversal, however, is mitigated by the existence of news events.

In sum, the results from Tables 3 and 4 support our predictions that are laid out in

Figure 1. Diagrams A and B show that there are long-lasting negative abnormal returns

following both negative and positive price shocks. Diagrams C and D show that for both

negative and positive shocks, the effects are stronger for no-news shocks.

4.3 Impact of Short-Sales Constraints

Existence of short-sales constraints is an important assumption of disagreement models.

10Note that for the difference portfolio in Panel A, decile 1 contains largest negative price shocks.

19

Page 22: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

In this subsection, we test whether the post-shock drift pattern varies with the degree of

short-sales constraints. If the drifts are indeed related to opinion divergence, we expect

that they are more significant among stocks with stronger short-sales constraints.

Following Chen, Hong and Stein [2002], we use mutual fund holding breadth as a proxy

for short-sales constraints. The measure is motivated by the fact that many mutual funds

are not allowed to short-sell even if they hold pessimistic views about any of the stocks.

The breadth is defined as the ratio of the number of mutual funds that hold a long position

in the stock to the total number of mutual funds for that quarter reported in Thomson

Financial Mutual Fund Holdings database. We define the smallest (largest) third as "Low

(High) Breadth" sample. In other words, the "Low Breadth" sample consists of stocks in

the lowest third when sorting by the value of their breadth. Based on disagreement models,

we expect that the post-shock abnormal return drifts are more salient among stocks with

low breadth which are associated with stronger short-sales constraints.

In Table 5, Panel A presents the results. In the case where the sorting variable is the

negative shock, the Fama-French three factor alpha for the difference portfolio (decile 10

minus decile 1) for low breadth stocks is 1.13% with -statistic of 6.55. The alpha for high

breadth stocks is 0.61% with -statistic of 3.35. When using the Carhart four factor alphas,

the contrast is more impressive. The four factor alpha for the difference portfolio for low

breadth stock is 0.86% with -statistic of 3.99, while that for high breadth stocks is only

0.05% with -statistic of 0.37. In the case where the sorting variable is the positive shock,

the three factor and four factor alphas for the difference portfolio for low breadth stocks

are −0.49% and −0.47% respectively, with -statistics of −2.73 and −2.55. In contrast,the alphas for high breadth stocks are −0.30% and −0.08% respectively, with -statistics of−1.67 and −0.49. These findings confirm that post-shock drifts are stronger for stocks withstronger short-sales constraints, providing further evidence that the persistent post-shock

abnormal returns are a disagreement-based effect. Panel B of Table 5 presents the news

effect. For negative shocks, the news effect is insignificant in both low and high breadth

groups. For positive shocks, although the news effect is significant in both low and high

20

Page 23: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

breadth groups, the effect is much stronger in the low breadth group.

Motivated by findings of Asquith, Pathak, and Ritter [2005] and Nagel [2005], we also

use institutional ownership as an alternative proxy for short-sales constraints. Stocks with

low institutional ownership are more expensive to borrow. Institutional ownership is the

percentage of shares outstanding owned by institutions as reported in Thomson Finan-

cial Institutional Holdings (13F) database. Stocks are first divided into thirds based on

institutional ownership. The lowest (highest) third is classified as “Low (high) institu-

tional ownership” group. Similar to those in Table 5, untabulated results show that the

price-shock effects are much stronger among stocks with low institutional ownership. For

example, in the case of sorting on negative shocks, the Fama-French three factor alpha for

the difference portfolio (decile 10 minus decile 1) for low institutional ownership stocks is

1.24% with -statistic of 6.44. The alpha for high institutional ownership stocks is 0.61%

with -statistic of 3.94. The results in the case of sorting on positive shocks show that

the alpha for the difference portfolio is significantly negative only for the stocks with low

institutional ownership.

5. Economic Significance of Price Shock Effects

We present a set of conditional tests to demonstrate the economic significance of our

findings in this section. The goal is to show the significance of price shocks conditional

on the well-documented momentum effect (Jegadeesh and Titman [1993]). The test helps

reflect the significance of losses that optimistic investors would incur due to information

uncertainty and how disclosures mitigate such wealth transfer. Our specific predictions

are depicted in Figure 3. We first create momentum portfolios by ranking stocks into

portfolios based on returns from month − 12 to month − 1 to generate the winner andloser portfolios. Table 6 reports the Fama-French three factor alphas and the robust -

statistics. For winner stocks, the alpha is 0.21% per month. For loser stocks the alpha is

−0.70% per month. As expected for the momentum effect, both alphas are statistically

21

Page 24: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

significant. The difference portfolio’s alpha is 0.90% per month, which is also consistent

with findings in the momentum literature.

The winner and loser portfolios are each divided into two groups: one with price shocks

and the other without shocks. The alpha for the losers with price shocks (−1.15%) is sig-nificantly lower than that for the losers without price shocks (−0.60%).11 This is consistentwith our expectation as illustrated in Diagram C of Figure 3. In contrast, the alpha for the

winners with price shocks (−0.02%) is significantly lower than the alpha for the winnerswithout price shocks (0.24%), again supporting the conjecture highlighted in Diagram B

of Figure 3. The evidence from both winners and losers suggests that price shocks add a

significantly negative drift to the return continuation of either winners or losers over the

twelve months following the ranking month.

Table 6 also reports the results from testing the effect of news disclosures. If public news

events reduce opinion divergence, we would expect a significant difference in the alphas

between news and no news sub-groups in both winners and losers with price shocks. The

results support our conjectures illustrated in Diagrams D and E of Figure 3. For loser stocks

with shocks that are not accompanied by any news events, the alpha is −1.29%. However,for those loser stocks with shocks accompanied by news events, the alpha is significantly

higher at −0.90%. For winner stocks, the effect of news events is directionally the same.The alpha for the group with shocks without accompanying news events is −0.16%, whileit is 0.44% for those with the shocks accompanied by news event. The -statistic for the

difference between the two winner portfolio’s alphas is 4.78.

In summary, the evidence in this section is consistent with the argument that price

shocks increase opinion divergence and the convergence of the disagreement may take a

long time. As a result, a negative price drift due to such divergence is added to the

existing momentum effect. News disclosures mitigate the shock-induced increase of opinion

divergence. The economic significance of these effects can be demonstrated by the improved

11All the alphas in Table 6 are from the three factor model. Since the portfolio sorts are conditional on

momentum, we present only the results from the three factor model.

22

Page 25: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

profitability of a revised momentum strategy. Using this revised strategy, one buys winner

stocks having price shocks associated with explicit corporate news disclosures and short-

sells loser stocks that have no-news price shocks. The revised hedge portfolio provides a

three factor alpha of 1.73% (= 044%− (−129%)), equivalent to an annualized abnormalreturn of 21%. With respect to the three factor alpha of the regular momentum strategy

(which equals to 0.90%), the revised strategy improves the profitability by 92%.

6. Other Potential Explanations

In this section, we consider other potential explanations. We first distinguish the asym-

metric drifts documented in our study from the well-known post-earnings announcement

drifts. We then try to reconcile the asymmetric drifts with the findings in Brown. Har-

low and Tinic (1988). Furthermore, we explore whether our findings can be captured by

idiosyncratic volatility or retail trading. Finally we discuss results from the robustness

tests when controlling for multiple effects including changes in risk, microstructure effects,

liquidity, delay, and skewness.

6.1 Post-Earnings Announcement Drifts

Post-earnings-announcement drift (PEAD) is a well known phenomenon documented

in the accounting literature (e.g., Ball and Brown [1968], Bernard and Thomas [1990]). It

refers to the tendency of a stock’s post-announcement cumulative abnormal return to move

in the direction of an earnings surprise. As positive (negative) earnings surprises are more

likely to be associated with positive (negative) price shocks, we expect a symmetric post-

shock drift pattern due to PEAD. Does this symmetric drift pattern exist in our sample? Is

the asymmetric drift pattern following price shocks mainly due to stocks without earnings

announcements around the portfolio formation time? We report the results in Table 7.

In Panel A, we focus on stocks with earnings announcement in the window from three

days before to three days after the price shock. These stocks are ranked into deciles by

23

Page 26: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

the negative and positive shocks. Equal-weighted decile portfolios are formed and held for

12 months, following the overlapping portfolio approach of Jagadeesh and Titman [1993].

Reported in the panel are the Fama-French three factor alphas and the Carhart four factor

alphas for decile 1, decile 10, and the difference portfolio (10 - 1). The difference portfolio

is constructed by taking both a long position on decile 10 and a short position on decile 1.

For this sample, we predict that the PEAD effect dominates the asymmetric drift pattern,

and expect to observe positive (negative) drifts following positive (negative) shocks.

Consistent with our expectation, Panel A shows that price shocks associated with earn-

ings announcement are followed by symmetric instead of asymmetric drifts in the following

year. For example, the monthly Carhart four factor alpha is −0.31% (with a robust -

statistic of −2.21) for earnings announcement associated with largest negative price shock(decile 1 of negative shocks). Earnings announcements associated with large positive price

shocks, on the other hand, have a monthly Carhart four factor alpha of 0.26% (with a

robust -statistic of 2.26). Significantly positive drifts following positive price shocks with

earnings announcement are in contrast to the negative drifts following no-news positive

shocks. These findings present evidence that PEAD exists in our sample, and that the

asymmetric drift pattern identified in Section 4.2 is mainly due to shocks unrelated to

earnings announcements.

In Panel B, we present the drift pattern for stocks with large price shocks (i.e., decile 1

sorted on negative shocks and decile 10 sorted on positive shocks) but without an earnings

announcement from three days before to three days after the shocks. Panel B confirms that

the asymmetric drift pattern following price shocks and the news effect on the post-shock

drift is not due to PEAD. With shocks associated with earnings announcements excluded,

the news group of negative price shocks shows a weaker downward drift (with a three

factor alpha of −0.49% and a four factor alpha of −0.12%), and therefore a stronger newseffect, than that reported in Panel B of Table 3. This result is consistent with the fact

that negative earnings announcements are followed by negative drifts. For the news group

of positive price shocks, we do not find any significant change in post-shock drift after

24

Page 27: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

excluding stocks with earnings announcements, suggesting that PEAD is not the driver for

the significant news effect identified among stocks with large positive price shocks. These

findings are robust to alternative event windows. Specifically, we check two alternative

event windows: seven days before to seven days after the price shock, and 15 days before

to 15 days after the price shock. The results are very similar.

6.2 Risk Change and Uncertain Information Hypothesis

Risk adjustment is a common concern in event studies (e.g., Ball [1978]). It is possible

that extreme price shocks lead to a change in the risk level of the stocks, and investors

rationally revise their expectations to reflect this change. Brown, Harlow, and Tinic [1988,

1993] develop and test an uncertain information hypothesis (UIH), which predicts that risk

averse investors respond to unanticipated price changes by adjusting their risk estimates

and expected returns. Under UIH, we should observe positive drifts following both positive

and negative price shocks. In this subsection, we first examine variation in total risk and

systematic risk around the price shocks. We then replicate the study of Brown, Harlow,

Tinic (1988) and compare the UIH test results with our findings. The tests suggest that

it is unlikely that the asymmetric post-shock drifts that we document are associated with

changes in the risk measures. Although we document some weak positive drift among a

subset of large firms like Brown, Harlow, and Tinic (1988), we find that the asymmetric

drifts following large price shocks (in our extreme deciles) subsume the UIH effect.

Our findings are based on the alphas from the Fama-French three factor (or the four

factor) model, and thus presumably risk change in the post-shock period has already been

accounted for. To provide further insights, we examine patterns of changes in the standard

deviation of stock returns, the loadings of the market, size, and book-to-market factors.

Panel A of Table 8 documents the results. We only present the results from the pooled

sample as the patterns are similar for both positive and negative shocks. The first two

rows in Panel A show that these risk measures (except for the book-to-market factor) for

25

Page 28: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

the stocks with large shocks are higher in the ranking month with respect to the average

values of the previous one or three months. The increase in risk level is consistent with

the findings in various accounting studies (e.g., Bernard and Thomas [1989]) that examine

specific corporate events. However, these changes in risk measures are temporary. The

last row of Panel A compares risk estimates in the twelve months before and after the

ranking month. The results indicate that the difference between the before- and after-

ranking-month magnitudes of the risk measures is insignificant, suggesting that there is no

permanent change in the risk level. Further examination reveals that the increase in the

risk level around price shocks identified in the first two rows is largely offset by a decrease

that occurs in the first quarter after the shocks. Thus, it is unlikely that changes in the

common risk proxies can explain our finding that the asymmetric post-shock drifts persist

over the twelve-month holding period.

In the uncertain information hypothesis (UIH), Brown, Harlow, and Tinic [1988, 1993]

propose that risk averse investors would respond to unanticipated price changes by adjusting

their risk estimates and expected returns. Specifically, UIH predicts positive average returns

following both positive and negative price changes. They test the hypothesis with the

largest 200 stocks in the S&P 500 index, and they find consistent evidence in the first 60

trading days after significant price changes (higher than 2.5% or lower than -2.5%). We

replicate their analysis and report the results in Panel B of Table 8. To be consistent with

BHT, we use the 200 largest S&P 500 firms and also examine returns within the three

months after the price shocks. The first two rows of Panel B show evidence consistent with

the uncertain information hypothesis. The three-month abnormal returns are significantly

positive following both positive and negative price changes (2.5% cutoff). We further

examine the overlap between the BHT sample and our extreme deciles.12 We find that

the asymmetric drifts subsume the UIH effect in this subsample. Reported in the third

and fourth rows, the results show that the three month abnormal returns are negative

following both positive and negative shocks (-0.64% and -2.60%, respectively). The results

12Recall the mean returns in our extreme negative and positive deciles are about -16% and 21%, respec-

tively.

26

Page 29: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

suggest that the effect uncovered in our study is also present among large-cap firms. The

findings from BHT and ours do not seem hard to reconcile, given the possibility that the

disagreement effect may be more relevant in the presence of large price shocks.

We notice that certain indirect evidence is also not in favor of the risk explanation.13

If the post-shock drifts arise from investors’ rational reaction to changes in risk, one would

expect that this effect should be stronger among stocks with higher institutional ownership

since institutional investors tend to be more sophisticated. The results that we have briefly

discussed in Section 4.3, however, are contradictory to this prediction. The analysis shows

that the price shock effects are weaker for the high institutional ownership group, which

provides further support that the price shock effects are not driven by a rational risk story.

6.3 Idiosyncratic Volatility and Its Change

Stocks with large price shocks in the ranking month tend to have large idiosyncratic

volatility (ivol) in the same month. Ang et al. [2006, 2009] document a high idiosyncratic

volatility low return puzzle. They sort stocks on the basis of their idiosyncratic volatility

measure, computed using the Fama-French three factor model. They find that stocks with

high idiosyncratic volatility earn low future returns. Thus, a natural hypothesis is that

the persistent return patterns following price shocks may be just a manifestation of the

idiosyncratic volatility puzzle.

We test this hypothesis using Fama-MacBeth cross-sectional regressions, checking whether

the post-shock return patterns are robust after controlling for the idiosyncratic volatility

effect. The dependent variable is the 12-month holding period stock return. We include

in the regression both negative shocks (−) and positive shocks (+), news event

dummies, and the interaction term of −/ + with the news event to capture the

price shock effects and the disclosure effects. Idiosyncratic volatility (ivol) is included

as a competing variable, along with the four control variables size, book-to-market ratio,

13Such evidence may be interesting, as it does not require measurement of time-varying risk.

27

Page 30: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

stock return in month , and the stock returns in the preceding 12 months. If + and

− remain significant in the predicted direction after ivol is included, we can infer that

asymmetric drifts following price shocks are not a manifestation of the high idiosyncratic

volatility low return puzzle. In such a case, the results would suggest that ivol does not

fully capture opinion divergence triggered by price shocks if both ivol and price shocks are

proxies for disagreement. We also expect that the two interaction terms be significant if

news events have any effect on mitigating disagreement.

We report test results in Table 9. Panel A presents the Fama-MacBeth regressions

with various specifications. Model 1 only consists of ivol and four control variables: size,

book-to-market ratio, ranking month returns, and the returns in preceding 12 months.

The regression replicates high idiosyncratic volatility low return puzzle. The coefficient

on ivol is −1.94 with a robust -statistic of −3.82. Models 2 and 3 separately examinethe negative drifts following either negative or positive shocks after controlling for ivol.

The results show that price shock effect is robust to the control of ivol effect, which is

also significant. The coefficients on − and + are significantly positive (0.36) and

negative (−0.37), respectively, suggesting that both negative and positive price shocks yieldsignificantly negative returns in the holding period. The news effect is significant in the

predicted direction for the positive shocks only.14

Model 4 is a full model, including all the controls, the shocks, and the interaction terms.

The coefficients on all the variables of interest are significant in the predicted directions.

The coefficients on − is 0.30 (=4.66). The coefficients on + and its interaction

term with news event are −0.34 (= −7.24) and 0.32 (=8.10). These results stronglysuggest that negative return drifts follow large price shocks and news events mitigate the

impact of these price shocks. The mitigating role of news events on negative shocks is rela-

tively weaker than that on positive shocks, consistent with the argument in literature that

managers have less incentives to bring investors up to date quickly regarding bad news (e.g.,

14In the portfolio sorting analysis in Panel B of Table 3, we show that the difference portfolio for negative

shocks is also significant although it is not as strong as this for positive shocks. The regression analysis

suggests that the control variables take away the news effect for negative shocks.

28

Page 31: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

Hong, Lim, and Stein [2000], Kothari, Shu, andWysocki [2009]). Importantly, we find that,

when both − and + are controlled for, the coefficient on ivol becomes insignifi-

cant, i.e., the high idiosyncratic volatility low return puzzle disappears. In summary, the

above results indicate that idiosyncratic volatility does not explain the asymmetric drifts

related to positive and negative price shocks.

Bali, Scherbina, and Tang [2010] find that stocks with large changes in the idiosyncratic

volatility (ivol shocks) over the ranking month have negative returns for the subsequent

month + 1. They use ivol shocks to proxy unusual news events and suggest that investor

disagreement created by the unusual news generates negative future returns. In Panel B,

we examine whether the price shock effects are robust when the ivol shocks are included in

the Fama-MacBeth regressions. Model 1 confirms the strong negative effect of ivol shock

on future stock returns. The coefficient on ivol shock is −0.44 with robust -statistic of−10.84. Models 2 and 3 show that both negative and positive post-shock drifts are robustin the presence of ivol shocks. The coefficients on − and + are 0.43 (-stat=1.87)

and −0.39 (-stat=−2.05) respectively. The news effect is significant for the positive priceshocks with a coefficient of 0.31 (-stat=7.90). After introducing either negative or positive

price shocks into the regression, ivol shock, however, becomes only marginally significant

with -values of −1.87 and −1.66, respectively. The full model (Model 4) results indicatethat our findings remain robust after controlling for ivol shocks. When both negative

and positive shocks are introduced into the regression, the ivol shock variable is no longer

significant (with a -stat of −0.84). Therefore, the above results suggest that ivol shocksdo not explain the asymmetric drifts following positive and negative price shocks.

6.4 Retail Trading

Are the price shock effects mainly due to irrational trading of a subset of investors who

prefer volatility and skewness? Kumar [2009] shows that stocks with high volatility and

high skewness are attractive to retail investors who exhibit a greater propensity to gamble.

29

Page 32: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

Han and Kumar [2009] find that stocks with a high proportion of retail trading tend to

earn lower future returns. Bali, Cakici, and Whitelaw [2011] argue that retail investors’

preference for lottery-like stocks leads to negative returns following positive price shocks.

We will explicitly control for skewness later on in the multivariate regressions. Here we

conduct a battery of tests to examine whether the drifts subsequent to stock price shocks

are explained by speculative preferences or heuristic trading of retail investors.

Many empirical studies separate retail trades from institutional trades using the dol-

lar value or the number of shares traded in each transaction. The underlying intuition is

that individuals (institutions) are more likely to trade using small-size (large-size) trades.

The cutoffs vary across different studies. For example, Battalio and Mendenhall [2005]

consider any trades less than 500 shares as small trades, while Malmendier and Shan-

thikumar [2007] classify trades below $20,000 as small trades. Typically, robustness with

different classifications is tested (e.g., Malmendier and Shanthikumar [2007], De Franco,

Lu, and Vasvari [2007], and Mithail, Walther, and Willis [2007]). We have examined

three different classifications yet only report one in Tables 10 and 11. Reported results

are based on $7,000/$30,000 classification, i.e., trades of less than $7,000 as retail trades

and trades of greater than $30,000 as institutional trades (Mikhail, Walther, and Willis

[2007]). The other two classifications we examined are 1,000/10,000 shares (Lee [1992]),

and $5,000/$5,000 (Han and Kumar [2009]). The results on the other two classifications

are similar and not reported for brevity.

To calculate retail trading proportion (RTP), we first sum up the shares of each transac-

tion to get the daily trading volume for retail and institutional traders, respectively, using

the intraday data from TAQ and ISSM databases. The daily RTP is computed as the

total retail trading volume divided by the sum of trading volume of retail and institutional

trades in a given day. We exclude trades between the two cutoffs (e.g., $7,000/$30,000 for

the reported results) since it is much more difficult to attribute trades in the middle to

retail investors or institutions. The monthly RTP is the average of the daily RTP over

the ranking month. In recent years, institutional investors have used algorithmic trading

30

Page 33: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

platforms to execute their orders. When large orders are broken into small orders, the

classification contains significant errors. To mitigate this concern, for RTP based tests, our

sample period stops at year 2000.

In Table 10, we examine whether RTP can explain the price shock effects using cross-

section regressions with the 12-month post-shock return as the dependent variable. The

results show that including RTP and the interaction terms between RTP and price shocks

(− and +) into regression does not take away the significance of price shocks,

suggesting that RTP cannot capture the cross-sectional return effects of price shocks. The

coefficient of RTP is not significant in any of the models. The marginally significant coef-

ficient of the interaction term between RTP and − in the full model (model 3) shows

some evidence that the negative drift following negative price shocks is stronger among

stocks with high RTP.

In Table 11, we use retail order imbalance after price shocks to shed light on retail

investors’ post shock trading activities. The Lee and Ready [1991] algorithm is used to

classify buyer- or seller-initiated trades. The first (last) four columns report the retail

order imbalance following negative (positive) price shocks. During the nine days after

price shocks, the numbers are all significantly positive for negative shocks and negative for

positive shocks, suggesting that retail investors are buying after negative shocks and selling

after positive shocks. If the post-shock negative drift is due to retail investors’ preference

for volatility, skewness, or lottery-like stocks, we should expect that retail investors to buy

after price shocks, especially following positive price shocks. The results in Table 11 are

not consistent with this prediction as suggested by Bali, Cakici, and Whitelaw [2011].

The pattern of retail order imbalance following positive and negative shocks makes it

more difficult to link retail trading with the negative drifts following both types of shocks.

Furthermore, Table 11 shows that the pattern of retail order imbalance is not long-lasting.

The positive retail order imbalance after negative shocks dies out around 20 days after

the shocks. The negative retail order imbalance after positive shocks becomes insignificant

around 60 days after the shocks. Therefore, it is unlikely that the retail trading can explain

31

Page 34: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

the long-lasting post-shock negative drift identified in this study.

In untabulated tests, we include the retail order imbalance in cross-sectional regressions

and find that retail order imbalance cannot take away the significance of the price shocks.

In summary, the results presented in Tables 10 and 11 suggest that retail trading cannot

explain the asymmetric post-shock drifts.

6.5 Other Robustness Checks

In this subsection, we point out some other robustness checks which are not tabulated

for brevity. First, we examine the price shock effects conditioning on abnormal trading

volume. Although there have been numerous studies on trading volume following Beaver

[1968], their findings do not yield a clear view. For example, Verrecchia [1981] and Kim and

Verrecchia [1991] discuss the difficulties associated with interpreting volume reactions to

public announcements and conclude that no unambiguous inferences can be drawn about

investors’ beliefs when a volume reaction is observed. Bamber and Cheon [1995], Kandel

and Pearson [1995], and Kim and Verrecchia [1997] also emphasize that abnormal trading

volume occurs even in the absence of price changes. Including abnormal trading volume in

the multivariate regressions, we find that abnormal trading volume does not capture the

price shock effects.

Second, we perform a cross-sectional regression test to jointly control for multiple effects.

We control for microstructure effects, liquidity, delay, and skewness, together with proxies

for idiosyncratic volatility and retail trading. The empirical proxies are selected following

previous studies: spread (Demsetz[1968]), turnover and volume (Chordia, Subrahmanyam

and Anshuman [2001]), illiquidity (Amihud [2002]), delay (Hou and Moskowitz [2005]), and

skewness (Barbaris and Huang [2008]). The table is omitted for brevity (but available upon

request). The test results show that the post-shock drifts remain robust after controlling

for various effects. None of the effects can account for the asymmetric persistent patterns in

returns after positive and negative shocks. Furthermore, news events in general reduce the

32

Page 35: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

impact of price shocks, although the mitigating effect appears stronger for positive price

shocks.

Finally, we explore the possibility that the price shock effects arise because investors

interpret no disclosure as management withholding negative information. In such a case,

the stock price reflects the expectations of potential bad news (e.g., Dye [1985], Diamond

and Verrecchia [1987], Lev and Penman [1990]). We examine abnormal returns around

the subsequent earnings announcements in the twelve-month holding period for stocks that

are experiencing large positive and negative price shocks. First, we estimate the three day

abnormal return around each of the earnings announcements. Next, we calculate the total

abnormal return over all the announcements in the holding period. The total abnormal

returns are only −0.01% and −0.44% for the portfolios with large negative and positive

shocks. This evidence is inconsistent with the argument that negative information related

to future cash flows has been withheld for those stocks at the time of large shocks.

7. Conclusions

Stock price shocks are visible and often attention-grabbing. The occurrence of stock

price shocks in the absence of public announcement of firm specific news is particularly

puzzling. Private information, liquidity shocks, and manipulations can all generate the

shocks. The existence of noise traders and different interpretations of price signals can

effectively prevent investors from reaching consensus quickly after price shocks. We take

advantage of this natural and yet novel setting to test investor disagreement theory.

The main finding of our study is that no-news price shocks are important such that

they are followed by significant and long-lasting abnormal returns. The drifts that our

tests uncover are asymmetric - return continuation following negative price shocks and re-

turn reversal following positive shocks. This finding is in sharp contrast to what we had

learned in the event study literature. Moreover, we find that price shocks with informa-

tion disclosures, compared to those without public announcements, are followed by weaker

33

Page 36: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

downward drifts. The evidence suggests that reduction of information asymmetry, as a

result of public information disclosures, weakens disagreement-induced overpricing. We

carry out a number of robustness tests. The results are consistent with predictions of dis-

agreement models while inconsistent with other explanations. In particular, the price-shock

effects are not a reflection of either the idiosyncratic volatility puzzle or the overpricing due

to speculative preferences in retail trading.

The importance of price shocks per se suggests the need to separate disclosure effects

from price shock effects. The findings from our conditional tests give rise to an interesting

perspective about the role of regulations on corporate disclosures as the empirical results

suggest that public disclosures actually improve market efficiency through the reduction of

investor disagreement. As for the empirical implementation, we recognize that our news

events are not exhaustive. The disclosures identified in the data are only a subset of all the

disclosures that actually occurred. Moreover, not all of the identified events are informative.

Therefore, the results related to news should be cautiously interpreted. Nevertheless, when

missing any significant news events, some price shocks associated with news would as a

result be misclassified into the no-news group. This omission would work against us as the

misallocation would likely weaken our results.

Our findings also have useful implications for portfolio management. The revised mo-

mentum strategy, an approach to buying winner stocks with price shocks associated with

explicit corporate news disclosure and short-selling loser stocks having no-news price shocks,

would improve the profitability of the simple buying-winner-selling-loser momentum strat-

egy by 92%. The revised hedge portfolio has a three-factor alpha of 1.73%, equivalent to an

annualized abnormal return of 21%. In general, our empirical results suggest that if indi-

viduals chase stocks that recently have had large price shocks, they would suffer substantial

losses. In that sense, corporate disclosures effectively mitigate the wealth transfer.

While we argue that the evidence is consistent with the predictions of disagreement

models, there are caveats that should be noted. First, as emphasized by Fama [1998], it is

important to have a unified theory to explain why the same investors underreact in some

34

Page 37: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

cases but overreact in others. We do not assume an ad hoc combination of underreaction

and overreaction as an alternative explanation for the asymmetric drifts. We pursue a the-

ory that can simultaneously explain the abnormal return patterns following both negative

and positive shocks. Nevertheless, it is difficult, if possible at all, to rule out that the

asymmetric drifts can be explained by a combination of two different theories - a theory

for underreaction and another for overreaction. Second, we conjecture that price shocks

generate opinion divergence and we verify that following price shocks there is a long term

decay process of opinion divergence measures, such as unexpected volume, turnover, and

volatility. However, trading-based disagreement proxies and return volatility may not cap-

ture the existence of investors who have pessimistic views about a stock and currently do

not participate in the trading of the stock. The existence of such investors, however, may

be sufficient to generate the post-shock abnormal returns.

35

Page 38: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

REFERENCES

Amihud, Y., 2002, “Illiquidity and Stock Returns: Cross-Section and Time-Series Effects.” Jour-

nal of Financial Markets 5, 31-56.

Ang, A.; R. J. Hodrick; Y. Xing and X. Zhang, 2006, “The Cross-Section of Volatility and

Expected Returns.” Journal of Finance 61, 259-299.

Ang, A.; R. J. Hodrick; Y. Xing and X. Zhang, 2009, “High Idiosyncratic Volatility and Low

Returns: International and Further US Evidence.” Journal of Financial Economics 91,

1-23.

Asquith, P.; P. Pathak and J. Ritter, 2005, “Short Interest, Institutional Ownership, and Stock

Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics 78, 243-276.

Bali, T.; N. Cakici and R. Whitelaw, 2011, “Maxing Out: Stocks as Lotteries and the Cross-

Section of Expected Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics 99, 427-446.

Bali, T.; A. Scherbina and Y. Tang, 2010, “Unusual News Events and the Cross-Section of Stock

Returns.” Working paper, CUNY Baruch College.

Ball, R., 1978, “Anomalies in Relationships between Securities’ Yields and Yield-Surrogates.”

Journal of Financial Economics 6, 103-126.

Ball, R. and P. Brown, 1968, “An Empirical Evaluation of Accounting Income Numbers.” Jour-

nal of Accounting Research 6, 159-178.

Ball, R., and L. Shivakumar, 2008, “How Much New Information is There in Earnings?” Journal

of Accounting Research 46, 975-1016.

Bamber, L.; O. Barron and T. Stober, 1997 “Trading Volume and Different Aspects of Disagree-

ment Coincident with Earnings Announcements.” The Accounting Review 72, 575-597.

Bamber, L. and Y. Cheon, 1995, “Differential Price and Volume Reactions to Accounting Earn-

ings Announcements.” The Accounting Review 70, 417-441.

Banerjee, S.; R. Kaniel and I. Kremer, 2009, “Price Drift as an Outcome of Differences in Higher

Order Beliefs.” Review of Financial Studies 22, 3707-3734.

Barber, B. and T. Odean, 2008, “All That Glitters: The Effect of Attention and News on the

Buying Behavior of Individual and Institutional Investors.” Review of Financial Studies 21,

785-818.

Barberis, N. and M. Huang, 2008, “Stocks as Lotteries: The Implications of Probability Weight-

ing for Security Prices.” American Economic Review 98, 2066-2100.

Barron, O., 1995, “Trading Volume and Belief Revisions That Differ among Individual Analysts.”

The Accounting Review 70, 581-597.

36

Page 39: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

Battalio, R. and R. Mendenhall, 2005, “Earnings Expectations, Investor Trade Size, and Anom-

alous Returns around Earnings Announcements.” Journal of Financial Economics 77, 289-

319.

Beaver, W., 1968, “The Information Content of Annual Earnings Announcements.” Journal of

Accounting Research 6, 67-92.

Berkman, H.; V. Dimitrov; P. Jain; P. Koch and S. Tice, 2009, “Sell on the News: Differences of

Opinion, Short-Sales Constraints, and Returns around Earnings Announcements.” Journal

of Financial Economics 92, 376-399.

Bernard, V. and J. Thomas, 1990, “Evidence That Stock Prices Do Not Fully Reflect the Im-

plications of Current Earnings for Future Earnings.” Journal of Accounting and Economics

13, 305-340.

Black, F., 1986, “Noise.” Journal of Finance 41, 529-543.

Brown, K.; W. Harlow and S. Tinic, 1988, “Risk Aversion, Uncertain Information, and Market

Efficiency.” Journal of Financial Economics 22, 355-385.

Brown, K.; W. Harlow and S. Tinic, 1993, “The Risk and Required Return of Common Stock

Following Major Price Innovations.” Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis 28,

101-116.

Brown, L. and J. Han, 1992, “The Impact of Annual Earnings Announcements on Convergence

of Beliefs.” The Accounting Review 67, 862-875.

Carhart, M., 1997, “On Persistence in Mutual Fund Performance.” Journal of Finance 52, 57-82.

Chen, J.; H. Hong and J. Stein, 2002, “Breadth of Ownership and Stock Returns.” Journal of

Financial Economics 66, 171-205.

Chordia, T.; A. Subrahmanyam and V. Anshuman, 2001, “Trading Activity and Expected Stock

Returns.” Journal of Financial Economics 59, 3-32.

Choy, S. and J. Wei, 2010, “Option Trading: Information or Differences of Opinion?” Working

paper, University of Toronto.

Cutler, D. M.; J. M. Poterba and L. H. Summers, 1989, “What Moves Stock Prices?” Journal

of Portfolio Management 15, 4-12.

De Franco, G.; H. Lu and F. Vasvari, 2007, “Wealth Transfer Effects of Analysts’ Misleading

Behavior.” Journal of Accounting Research 45, 71-110.

Demsetz, H., 1968, “The Cost of Transacting.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 82, 33-53.

Diamond, D., 1985, “Optimal Release of Information by Firms.” Journal of Finance 40, 1071-

1094.

37

Page 40: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

Diamond, D. and R. Verrecchia, 1987, “Constraints on Short-Selling and Asset Price Adjustment

to Private Information.” Journal of Financial Economics 18, 277-311.

Diamond, D. and R. Verrecchia, 1991, “Disclosure, Liquidity, and the Cost of Capital.” Journal

of Finance 46, 1325-59.

Diether, K.; C. Malloy and A. Scherbina, 2002, “Differences of Opinion and the Cross Section

of Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance 57, 2113-2141.

Dye, R., 1985, “Disclosure of Nonproprietary Information.” Journal of Accounting Research 23,

123-145.

Ecker, F.; J. Francis; P. Olsson and K. Schipper, 2006, “The Effect of the Amount and Configu-

ration of News on Inferences About Firm-Specific Events.” Working paper, Duke University.

Fama, E., 1998, “Market Efficiency, Long-Term Returns, and Behavioral Finance.” Journal of

Financial Economics 49, 283-306.

Fama, E. and K. French, 1993, “Common Risk Factors in the Returns on Stocks and Bonds.”

Journal of Financial Economics 33, 3-56.

Garfinkel, J., 2009, “Measuring Investors’ Opinion Divergence.” Journal of Accounting Research

47, 1317-1348.

Garfinkel, J. and J. Sokobin, 2006, “Volume, Opinion Divergence, and Returns: A Study of

Post-Earnings Announcement Drift.” Journal of Accounting Research 44, 85-112.

Han, B. and A. Kumar, 2009, “Speculation, Realization Utility, and Volatility-Induced Retail

Habitat.” Working paper, University of Texas at Austin.

Harris, M. and A. Raviv, 1993, “Differences of Opinion Make a Horse Race.” Review of Financial

Studies 6, 473-506.

Harrison, J. and D. Kreps, 1978, “Speculative Investor Behavior in a Stock Market with Hetero-

geneous Expectations.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 92, 323-336.

Healy, P. and K. Palepu, 2001, “Information Asymmetry, Corporate Disclosure, and the Capital

Markets: A Review of the Empirical Disclosure Literature.” Journal of Accounting and

Economics 31, 405-440.

Hong, H.; T. Lim and J. Stein, 2000, “Bad News Travels Slowly: Size, Analyst Coverage, and

the Profitability of Momentum Strategies.” Journal of Finance 55, 265-295.

Hong, H. and J. Stein, 2007, “Disagreement and the Stock Market.” Journal of Economic

Perspectives 21, 109-128.

Hou, K. and T. Moskowitz, 2005, “Market Frictions, Price Delay, and the Cross-Section of

Expected Returns.” Review of Financial Studies 18, 981-1020.

38

Page 41: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

Jegadeesh, N. and S. Titman, 1993, “Returns to Buying Winners and Selling Losers: Implications

for Stock Market Efficiency.” Journal of Finance 48, 65-91.

Jennings, R. and L. Starks, 1985, “Information Content and the Speed of Stock Price Adjust-

ment.” Journal of Accounting Research 23, 336-350.

Kandel, E. and N. Pearson, 1995, “Differential Interpretation of Public Signals and Trade in

Speculative Markets.” Journal of Political Economy 103, 831-872.

Kim, O. and R. Verrecchia, 1991, “Trading Volume and Price Reactions to Public Announce-

ments.” Journal of Accounting Research 29, 302-321.

Kim, O. and R. Verrecchia, 1994, “Market Liquidity and Volume around Earnings Announce-

ments.” Journal of Accounting and Economics 17, 41-67.

Kim, O. and R. Verrecchia, 1997, “Pre-Announcement and Event-Period Private Information.”

Journal of Accounting and Economics 24, 395-419.

Kothari, S., 2001, “Capital Markets Research in Accounting.” Journal of Accounting and Eco-

nomics 31, 105-231.

Kothari, S.; S. Shu and P. Wysocki, 2009, “Do Managers Withhold Bad News?” Journal of

Accounting Research 47, 241-276.

Kumar, A., 2009, “Who Gambles in the Stock Market?” Journal of Finance 64, 1889-1933.

Lee, C., 1992, “Earnings News and Small Traders: An Intraday Analysis.” Journal of Accounting

and Economics 15, 265-302.

Lee, C. and M. Ready, 1991, “Inferring Trade Direction from Intraday Data.” Journal of Finance

46, 733-746.

Lev, B. and S. Penman, 1990, “Voluntary Forecast Disclosure, Nondisclosure, and Stock Prices.”

Journal of Accounting Research 28, 49-76.

Malmendier, U. and D. Shanthikumar, 2007, “Are Small Investors Naive About Incentives?”

Journal of Financial Economics 85, 457-489.

Mikhail, M.; B. Walther and R. Willis, 2007, “When Security Analysts Talk, Who Listens?”

The Accounting Review 82, 1227-1253.

Milgrom, P. and N. Stokey, 1982, “Information, Trade and Common Knowledge.” Journal of

Economic Theory 26, 17-27.

Miller, E., 1977, “Risk, Uncertainty, and Divergence of Opinion.” Journal of Finance 32, 1151-

1168.

Nagel, S., 2005, “Short Sales, Institutional Investors and the Cross-Section of Stock Returns.”

Journal of Financial Economics 78, 277-309.

39

Page 42: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

Patell, J. and M. Wolfson, 1981, “The Ex Ante and Ex Post Price Effects of Quarterly Earnings

Announcements Reflected in Option and Stock Prices.” Journal of Accounting Research 19,

434-458.

Richardson, S.; R. Sloan and H. You, 2011, “What Makes Stock Prices Move? Fundamentals vs.

Investor Recognition.” Available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1762376.

Rogers, J.; D. Skinner and A. Van Buskirk, 2009, “Earnings Guidance and Market Uncertainty.”

Journal of Accounting and Economics 48, 90-109.

Roll, R., 1988, “R2.” Journal of Finance 43, 541-566.

Sarkar, A. and R. Schwartz, 2009, “Market Sidedness: Insights into Motives for Trade Initiation.”

Journal of Finance 64, 375-423.

Scheinkman, J. and W. Xiong, 2003, “Overconfidence and Speculative Bubbles.” Journal of

Political Economy 111, 1183-1219.

Shin, S., 2006, “Disclosure Risk and Price Drift.” Journal of Accounting Research 44, 351-379.

Tirole, J., 1982, “On the Possibility of Speculation under Rational Expectations.” Econometrica

50, 1163-1181.

Verrecchia, R., 1981, “On the Relationship between Volume Reaction and Consensus of Investors:

Implications for Interpreting Tests of Information Content.” Journal of Accounting Research

19, 271-283.

Verrecchia, R., 2001, “Essays on Disclosure.” Journal of Accounting and Economics 32, 97-180.

Ziebart, D., 1990, “The Association between Consensus of Beliefs and Trading Activity Sur-

rounding Earnings Announcements.” The Accounting Review 65, 477-488.

40

Page 43: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

TABLE 1

Portfolio Characteristics

deciles: 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

(low) (high)

Panel A1. Ranked by Negative Price Shocks, without News

size 169 224 287 353 453 544 676 841 1056 1511

B/M 0.79 0.84 0.86 0.87 0.89 0.90 0.91 0.91 0.92 0.89

return -3.65 -0.69 0.63 1.49 2.20 2.75 3.29 3.91 4.75 7.71

return 12 49.81 33.96 28.71 24.88 22.62 21.29 20.28 19.57 19.50 20.03

ivol 48.73 36.56 31.64 27.95 24.99 22.34 19.85 17.49 15.09 13.79

RTP 0.54 0.54 0.53 0.51 0.49 0.47 0.44 0.42 0.39 0.32

− -15.21 -9.94 -8.05 -6.81 -5.85 -5.05 -4.33 -3.66 -2.96 -1.99

avg # of stocks 242 259 262 262 262 262 260 258 259 254

Panel A2. Ranked by Negative Price Shocks, with News

size 486 738 974 1193 1535 1808 2132 2532 3044 3849

B/M 0.80 0.84 0.84 0.84 0.85 0.86 0.86 0.86 0.86 0.84

return -8.08 -1.93 -0.40 0.83 1.57 2.34 2.99 3.79 4.71 7.53

return 12 33.39 28.93 24.87 22.43 20.49 19.83 19.40 17.64 18.20 18.65

ivol 45.20 33.93 29.31 26.16 23.46 21.18 19.13 17.16 15.07 13.64

RTP 0.42 0.41 0.39 0.37 0.35 0.32 0.30 0.28 0.26 0.21

− -16.12 -9.95 -8.06 -6.81 -5.85 -5.05 -4.33 -3.65 -2.96 -1.98

avg # of stocks 104 88 85 85 85 86 87 88 88 93

Panel B1. Ranked by Positive Price Shocks, without News

size 1208 977 858 724 588 507 385 304 226 151

B/M 0.89 0.90 0.89 0.88 0.88 0.87 0.87 0.86 0.86 0.87

return -5.56 -2.96 -1.87 -1.09 -0.20 0.70 1.95 3.63 6.49 16.47

return 12 19.33 19.26 19.87 20.64 22.22 24.06 26.83 30.10 34.61 39.16

ivol 12.80 14.54 16.78 19.18 21.56 24.39 27.50 31.39 36.90 52.84

RTP 0.39 0.41 0.43 0.45 0.46 0.47 0.48 0.50 0.51 0.56

+ 1.86 2.94 3.74 4.55 5.45 6.50 7.82 9.59 12.38 21.19

avg # of stocks 258 257 256 255 254 254 254 253 255 256

Panel B2. Ranked by Positive Price Shocks, with News

size 3548 3066 2714 2328 1899 1635 1290 921 669 382

B/M 0.85 0.85 0.85 0.85 0.84 0.84 0.84 0.84 0.87 0.92

return -5.13 -2.45 -1.23 -0.27 0.65 1.85 3.11 5.01 7.70 17.13

return 12 17.58 17.45 18.17 19.12 20.33 22.18 25.47 26.60 30.07 30.85

ivol 12.68 14.23 16.13 18.19 20.42 22.82 25.75 29.44 34.90 50.11

RTP 0.26 0.28 0.29 0.30 0.32 0.33 0.34 0.36 0.39 0.45

+ 1.87 2.94 3.74 4.55 5.45 6.50 7.81 9.59 12.37 20.84

avg # of stocks 88 91 91 92 93 93 93 93 92 90

41

Page 44: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

This table reports summary statistics for decile portfolios sorted on either positive (+) or negative

(−) price shocks. Each decile portfolio is further divided into ‘news’ and ‘no news’ groups, based on

whether a corporate news event occurs in the window from three days before to three days after the shock.

Size is the market capitalization of the firm measured in millions of dollars. B/M is the book-to-market

ratio of the firm. Ranking month stock return and cumulative stock return in the 12-month period prior to

the ranking month are denoted by return t and return 12. Ivol is the idiosyncratic volatility, computed as

the standard deviation of the residual from the Fama-French three-factor regression using daily returns in

the ranking month. RTP is the average daily retail trading proportion, i.e., retail trades/(retail trades +

institutional trades), in the ranking month. Trades smaller than $7,000 (larger then $30,000) are classified

as retail (institutional) trades. The reported values of all variables are first averaged across stocks in a given

month, and then averaged over time. In addition, the average number of stocks in each group is also reported

in the table. The sample period for RTP is 1983.1—2000.12. The sample period for all remaining variables

is 1963.7—2006.12.

42

Page 45: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

TABLE 2

Variation in Disagreement Proxies

Panel A. Change in Disagreement Proxies

− −1 − −3−1 ∆1 ∆2 ∆3 ∆4

ivol Est. 0.773 0.704 -0.765 -0.104 -0.064 -0.047

-stat 28.22 25.64 -26.61 -6.67 -4.31 -3.14

turnover Est. 0.089 0.066 -0.082 -0.025 -0.015 -0.011

-stat 12.21 10.65 -11.16 -6.14 -4.10 -3.14

unexpected volume Est. 0.046 0.034 -0.043 -0.016 -0.011 -0.009

-stat 12.24 10.63 -11.31 -7.43 -6.00 -5.56

analyst dispersion Est. 0.012 0.032 0.219 0.020 -0.038 -0.036

-stat 2.03 1.16 4.43 0.44 -0.98 -0.85

Panel B. Percentage Change in Disagreement Proxies

−−1|−1|

−−33−1|−3−1| %1 %2 %3 %4

ivol Est. 0.302 0.262 -0.214 -0.035 -0.021 -0.015

-stat 36.63 33.68 -42.39 -6.44 -3.82 -2.52

turnover Est. 0.277 0.190 -0.148 -0.048 -0.019 -0.010

-stat 36.31 18.00 -19.37 -4.61 -1.82 -0.88

unexpected volume Est. 0.300 0.252 -0.198 -0.071 -0.046 -0.035

-stat 19.44 13.64 -18.85 -9.05 -6.98 -5.65

analyst dispersion Est. 0.000 -0.002 0.027 -0.002 -0.014 -0.011

-stat 0.33 -0.41 3.83 -0.29 -1.89 -1.48

This table presents the variation in investor disagreement around extreme price shocks. Panels A and B

report the change in disagreement proxies in raw values and percentages, respectively. Columns 2 and 3 in

both panels examine whether price shocks increase investor disagreement in the ranking month relative to

month −1 or the average of months −3 to −1. Column 4 presents the change in disagreement in the firstquarter after month relative to month . The remaining three columns report the change in disagreement

in the second, third, and fourth quarter after month relative to the previous quarter. The sample covers

stocks with extreme price shocks, i.e., positive (negative) shocks in the highest (lowest) decile. We use

four proxies for investor disagreement, (1) ivol, the idiosyncratic volatility measure defined in Table 1; (2)

turnover, computed as the ranking month volume divided by the shares outstanding at the end of the month;

(3) unexpected volume; and (4) analyst dispersion, measured as the standard deviation of annual earnings

estimates by analysts in the ranking month, standardized by absolute mean annual earnings estimates. The

43

Page 46: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

unexpected volume in a given day is measured as turnover in excess of market turnover of the day minus

the average daily excess turnover in a benchmark period, which we choose to be the three months before the

ranking month. The monthly unexpected volume is the average daily measure in that month. The analyst

dispersion measures are included for stocks with at least three analysts. We first compute the cross-section

median of disagreement change. Time series averages of the median are reported in the table. Newey-West

-statistics based on time series are reported in the row below the estimate.

44

Page 47: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

TABLE 3

Post-Shock Drifts

Panel A. Positive and Negative Price Shocks

Negative Shocks Positive Shocks

decile 1 decile 10 10 - 1 decile 1 decile 10 10 - 1

return 0.58 1.23 0.65 1.15 0.85 -0.30

-stat 1.71 6.60 2.74 5.77 2.41 -1.26

(FF-3) -0.69 0.16 0.85 0.01 -0.40 -0.41

-stat -7.93 2.18 6.78 0.16 -5.16 -3.36

(Carhart-4) -0.38 0.17 0.55 0.18 -0.23 -0.40

-stat -3.16 2.82 3.99 2.93 -2.04 -3.39

Panel B. News Effects on Extreme Shocks

Negative Shocks (decile 1) Positive Shocks (decile 10)

No News News News - No News No News News News - No News

return 0.54 0.66 0.11 0.74 1.18 0.44

-stat 1.55 2.11 1.51 2.08 3.68 5.62

(FF-3) -0.72 -0.60 0.12 -0.51 -0.02 0.48

-stat -7.98 -7.27 2.05 -6.37 -0.32 7.11

(Carhart-4) -0.44 -0.24 0.19 -0.34 0.17 0.52

-stat -3.37 -2.23 3.06 -2.86 1.89 7.19

This table presents the price shock effect. Panel A reports post-shock portfolio performance of the two

polar deciles (i.e., decile 1 and 10) ranked on positive and negative shocks respectively. In each case, the

decile with lowest (highest) three-day abnormal return is decile 1 (10). The difference “10-1” denotes the

portfolio that is comprised of a long position on decile 10 and a short position on decile 1. Equal-weighted

portfolios are formed and held for 12 months, following the overlapping portfolio approach of Jegadeesh

and Titman [1993]. Monthly average portfolio returns and alphas from the Fama-French three-factor model

and the Carhart four-factor model are presented. Newey-West -statistics are reported for the performance

measures. The sample period is 1963.7—2006.12. In Panel B, stocks with extreme price shocks, i.e., decile

1 (decile 10) ranked on negative (positive) price shocks, are further divided into “news” and “no news”

subgroups, based on whether a corporate news event occurs in the window from three days before to three

days after the shock. Equal-weighted portfolio performance measures are reported for each group as well as

the “news - no news” difference group.

45

Page 48: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

TABLE 4

Persistence of Post-Shock Abnormal Returns

decile 10 - decile 1

return -stat (FF-3) -stat (Carhart-4) -stat

Panel A. Ranked by Negative Price Shocks

m1 - m3 no news 0.76 2.90 0.93 6.44 0.78 5.33

news 0.67 2.96 0.81 5.91 0.56 3.91

news - no news -0.09 -0.94 -0.12 -1.41 -0.22 -2.42

m4 - m6 no news 0.75 2.99 0.94 6.65 0.66 4.26

news 0.74 3.52 0.91 7.08 0.55 3.69

news - no news -0.01 -0.13 -0.03 -0.29 -0.11 -1.15

m7 - m9 no news 0.69 2.71 0.85 6.32 0.52 2.91

news 0.52 2.54 0.71 6.17 0.34 2.19

news - no news -0.16 -1.69 -0.14 -1.70 -0.18 -1.98

m10 - m12 no news 0.65 2.63 0.86 5.78 0.51 3.40

news 0.42 1.86 0.65 5.28 0.31 2.44

news - no news -0.24 -2.24 -0.21 -2.14 -0.21 -1.76

Panel B. Ranked by Positive Price Shocks

m1 - m3 no news -0.89 -3.30 -0.95 -6.10 -1.09 -9.16

news -0.13 -0.54 -0.17 -1.05 -0.24 -1.77

news - no news 0.77 7.45 0.78 8.46 0.85 9.92

m4 - m6 no news -0.34 -1.44 -0.45 -3.43 -0.46 -3.31

news 0.02 0.10 -0.06 -0.45 -0.07 -0.51

news - no news 0.36 3.71 0.38 4.09 0.39 4.34

m7 - m9 no news -0.29 -1.20 -0.43 -3.16 -0.36 -2.53

news 0.04 0.18 -0.06 -0.53 -0.01 -0.12

news - no news 0.33 4.17 0.36 4.41 0.35 3.77

m10 - m12 no news -0.15 -0.60 -0.29 -2.22 -0.15 -0.85

news 0.24 1.05 0.17 1.43 0.29 2.06

news - no news 0.39 4.84 0.46 5.49 0.43 4.02

At the end of month , stocks are ranked into deciles by either negative or positive price shocks in the

month. Each decile is further divided into “news” and “no news” subgroups. This table reports the average

monthly returns, the Fama-French three-factor alphas, and the Carhart four-factor alphas for the difference

portfolios that have a long position on decile 10 and a short position on decile 1, for different three-month

intervals after the ranking month . For example, the period from month +1 to +3 is denoted as “m1-m3”.

The construction follows the overlapping portfolio approach of Jegadeesh and Titman [1993]. Newey-West

-statistics are reported. The sample period is 1963.7—2006.12.

46

Page 49: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

TABLE 5

Drifts under Low Breadth vs. High Breadth

Panel A. Positive and Negative Price Shocks

Negative Shocks Positive Shocks

decile 1 decile 10 10 - 1 decile 1 decile 10 10 - 1

Low Breadth

(FF-3) -0.79 0.34 1.13 0.12 -0.37 -0.49

-stat -6.00 2.11 6.55 0.76 -2.97 -2.73

(Carhart-4) -0.53 0.33 0.86 0.22 -0.25 -0.47

-stat -2.57 2.31 3.99 1.51 -1.35 -2.55

High Breadth

(FF-3) -0.57 0.04 0.61 -0.08 -0.37 -0.30

-stat -3.61 0.46 3.35 -0.75 -2.53 -1.67

(Carhart-4) -0.04 0.02 0.05 0.09 0.01 -0.08

-stat -0.28 0.21 0.37 1.11 0.09 -0.49

Panel B. News Effects on Extreme Shocks

Negative Shocks (decile 1) Positive Shocks (decile 10)

No News News News - No News No News News News - No News

Low Breadth

(FF-3) -0.79 -0.67 0.12 -0.55 0.14 0.70

-stat -5.57 -5.42 1.20 -4.47 1.19 8.91

(Carhart-4) -0.53 -0.40 0.14 -0.42 0.22 0.64

-stat -2.50 -2.03 1.40 -2.07 1.46 6.13

High Breadth

(FF-3) -0.57 -0.51 0.06 -0.44 -0.24 0.20

-stat -2.88 -3.29 0.55 -2.62 -1.63 2.56

(Carhart-4) -0.05 0.02 0.07 -0.04 0.14 0.19

-stat -0.27 0.13 0.63 -0.27 1.07 2.38

This table compares the price shock effects across two subgroups: the one with low breadth vs. the

one with high breadth. Stocks are sorted into thirds based on the breadth measure (Chen, Hong, and Stein

[2002]) in month . The lowest (highest) third is defined as the “Low (High) Breadth” group. Each group

is further sorted into deciles based on positive and negative price shocks. Panel A reports the Fama-French

three-factor alphas and the Carhart four-factor alphas for decile 1, decile 10, and the “10-1” difference

portfolio. In Panel B, decile 1 (decile 10) for negative (positive) shocks is further divided into “news” and

“no news” subgroups. Equal-weighted portfolio alphas are presented for each group as well as the “News

- No News” difference portfolio. Newey-West -statistics are reported in the row below the performance

estimates.

47

Page 50: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

TABLE 6

Price Shock Effects in a Momentum Setting

momentum stocks with price shocks no shocks shock - no shock

all news no news diff

losers alpha -0.70 -1.15 -0.90 -1.29 0.39 -0.60 -0.55

-stat -6.77 -7.93 -5.68 -9.02 3.67 -6.13 -6.00

winners alpha 0.21 -0.02 0.44 -0.16 0.61 0.24 -0.26

-stat 2.15 -0.13 2.85 -1.03 4.78 2.70 -2.48

W - L alpha 0.90 1.13 1.41 1.13 0.30 0.84 0.29

-stat 6.31 6.37 6.65 6.34 1.98 6.07 2.60

This table examines price shock effects in a momentum setting. At the end of the ranking month ,

stocks are ranked into deciles based on the cumulative return from month − 12 to month − 1. Stocksin the highest (lowest) decile are classified as winners (losers). Equal-weighted portfolios are formed for

winners and losers, and held for 12 months, following the overlapping construction of Jegadeesh and Titman

[1993]. Column 3 reports Fama-French three factor alphas for the winner portfolio, the loser portfolio, and

the winner minus loser (“W - L”) difference portfolio. The winner and loser groups are further divided into

two groups: stocks with price shocks and those without. Stocks in decile 1 (decile 10) ranked on negative

(positive) price shocks are classified as stocks with price shocks. Fama-French alphas are reported for the

price shock portfolio, the no price shock portfolio, and the “shock - no shock” difference portfolio in Column

4, 8 and 9. The two price shock groups are classified into news and no news subgroups, based on whether a

corporate news event occurs in the window from three days before to three days after the price shock. Three

factor alphas are reported for the news portfolio, the no news portfolio, and the news minus no news (“diff”)

difference portfolio in Column 5—7. Newey-West -statistics are presented for all alphas in the table.

48

Page 51: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

TABLE 7

Earnings Announcements

Panel A. Price Shocks Associated with Earnings Announcements

Negative Shocks Positive Shocks

decile 1 decile 10 decile 10 - decile 1 decile 1 decile 10 decile 10 - decile 1

(FF-3) -0.69 0.10 0.79 0.00 0.10 0.11

-stat -6.22 1.15 5.30 -0.03 1.18 0.73

(Carhart-4) -0.31 0.12 0.43 0.16 0.26 0.09

-stat -2.21 1.65 2.67 2.08 2.26 0.67

Panel B. Excluding Shocks Associated with Earnings Announcements

Negative Shocks (decile 1) Positive Shocks (decile 10)

No News News News - No News No News News News - No News

(FF-3) -0.72 -0.49 0.23 -0.51 -0.03 0.49

-stat -7.98 -5.14 3.01 -6.37 -0.32 5.93

(Carhart-4) -0.44 -0.12 0.32 -0.34 0.20 0.56

-stat -3.37 -1.04 3.89 -2.86 1.88 6.44

Panel A tests the price shock effects in the sample with earnings announcements. The negative (positive)

shock sample includes stocks with earnings announcements occurring in the window from three days before

to three days after the negative (positive) shocks. Earnings announcements associated with both positive

and negative price shocks are excluded from the sample. The negative (positive) shock sample is then sorted

into deciles based on negative (positive) shocks. The Fama-French three-factor alphas and the Carhart four-

factor alphas are reported for decile 1 and decile 10 as well as the “decile 10 - decile 1” difference portfolio.

Newey-West -statistics are presented in the table. The sample period is 1972.1—2006.12. Panel B is similar

to Panel B of Table 3. However, we exclude stocks with earnings announcements in the window from three

days before to three days after the negative (positive) shocks from the news group.

49

Page 52: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

TABLE 8

Risk Change and Uncertain Information Hypothesis

Panel A. Pattern of Changes in Risk Measures

std mkt smb hml

Est. -stat Est. -stat Est. -stat Est. -stat

− −1 0.009 26.70 0.143 11.85 0.260 18.94 -0.009 -0.62

− −3−1 0.010 24.44 0.152 12.87 0.283 18.69 -0.014 -0.93

+1+12 − −12−1 0.000 0.19 -0.013 -0.79 -0.019 -1.15 -0.020 -0.76

Panel B. Uncertain Information Hypothesis

+1 +2 +3 +1+3

Est. -stat Est. -stat Est. -stat Est. -stat

positive 2.5% events 81,966 −0.03% −1.17 0.03% 1.31 0.06% 2.24 0.05% 1.15

negative 2.5% events 79,196 0.04% 1.50 0.07% 2.63 0.06% 2.06 0.16% 3.46

positive shocks 879 −0.44% −1.15 0.11% 0.30 −0.19% −0.49 −0.64% −0.98negative shocks 1,709 −1.68% −6.20 −0.47% −1.66 −0.46% −1.68 −2.60% −5.61

This table investigates whether the uncertain information hypothesis proposed in Brown, Harlow, and

Tinic (BHT, 1988) can explain the price shock effects. Panel A presents the variation of risk around extreme

price shocks. The sample includes stocks with large price shocks, i.e., positive (negative) shocks in the

highest (lowest) decile. Four measures of risk, stock return standard deviation (“std”) and the three factor

loadings (“mkt”, “smb”, “hml”) from the Fama-French three factor model, are computed each month using

daily stock returns. For notation, 12 denotes the average monthly value of the variable over month 1

to 2, while is the value of the variable in the ranking month . For each difference, we first compute

the cross-sectional mean. Time series averages of the mean and Newey-West -statistics are reported in the

table. Panel B focuses on the 200 largest stocks in S&P 500 as in BHT (1988). “Positive (negative) 2.5%

events” include stocks with positive (negative) price shock greater than 2.5% in month . “Positive (negative)

shocks” are the stocks with positive (negative) shocks in the highest (lowest) decile (sorted using stocks in

the whole sample). Cumulative abnormal returns relative to the value-weighted CRSP market return are

obtained after month . Number of observations (), average CAR and the corresponding -statistics are

reported in the panel.

50

Page 53: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

TABLE 9

Idiosyncratic Volatility and Idiosyncratic Volatility Shock

Panel A. Idiosyncratic Volatility

model 1 model 2 model 3 model 4

Est. -stat Est. -stat Est. -stat Est. -stat

Intercept 0.23 5.80 0.23 6.02 0.23 6.00 0.24 6.06

news− 0.00 -0.23 0.00 0.12

− 0.36 5.18 0.30 4.66

−×news− -0.02 -0.42 0.04 0.72

news+ -0.01 -3.34 -0.01 -3.25

+ -0.37 -7.31 -0.34 -7.24

+×news+ 0.32 8.06 0.32 8.10

log(size) -0.01 -3.03 -0.01 -3.09 -0.01 -3.18 -0.01 -3.15

B/M 0.02 3.21 0.02 3.22 0.02 3.24 0.02 3.21

return 0.14 7.75 0.09 4.27 0.20 8.24 0.14 6.18

return 12 0.03 3.76 0.03 3.96 0.03 3.85 0.03 3.99

ivol -1.94 -3.82 -1.10 -2.50 -0.93 -2.20 -0.30 -0.75

Panel B. Idiosyncratic Volatility Shock

model 1 model 2 model 3 model 4

Est. -stat Est. -stat Est. -stat Est. -stat

Intercept 0.17 3.67 0.21 4.95 0.21 4.99 0.22 5.18

news− 0.00 -0.18 0.00 -0.01

− 0.43 1.87 0.29 1.89

−×news− -0.04 -0.65 0.03 0.60

news+ -0.01 -3.48 -0.01 -3.30

+ -0.39 -2.05 -0.29 -2.02

+×news+ 0.31 7.90 0.30 8.07

log(size) -0.01 -1.96 -0.01 -2.45 -0.01 -2.62 -0.01 -2.75

B/M 0.03 3.12 0.02 3.37 0.02 3.36 0.02 3.44

return 0.14 6.51 0.08 1.63 0.20 4.97 0.13 5.46

return 12 0.03 3.34 0.03 3.81 0.03 3.58 0.03 3.79

ivol shock -0.44 -10.84 -0.23 -1.87 -0.23 -1.66 -0.15 -0.84

Fama-MacBeth cross-section regressions are conducted to test whether idiosyncratic volatility (Panel

A) and idiosyncratic volatility shock (Panel B) can capture the price shock effects. The average regression

coefficients and the corresponding Newey-West -statistics are reported. The dependent variable is the 12-

month holding period return. The independent variables are variables computed at the end of the ranking

month : − and + are the minimum and the maximum three-day market-adjusted returns (i.e.,

51

Page 54: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

negative and positive price shocks) in month ; news− (news+) is a dummy variable indicating whethera corporate news event is associated with the negative (positive) price shock; log(size) is the log market

capitalization in millions of dollars; B/M is the book-to-market ratio; return is the ranking month return;

return 12 is the cumulative return from month − 12 to − 1; ivol is the idiosyncratic volatility; and ivolshock is the idiosyncratic volatility shock (Bali, Scherbina, and Tang [2010]), which is defined as the residual

from the cross-sectional regression of ivol in month on the average ivol from month − 27 to − 4 and tenindustry dummies. The sample period is 1963.7 — 2006.12.

52

Page 55: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

TABLE 10

Retail Trading

model 1 model 2 model 3

Est. -stat Est. -stat Est. -stat

Intercept 0.15 3.08 0.15 3.04 0.17 3.32

news− 0.00 -0.64 0.00 -0.55

− 0.79 3.64 0.44 3.67

−×news− -0.15 -2.22 -0.06 -1.20

news+ -0.01 -2.2 -0.01 -1.99

+ -0.75 -4.06 -0.53 -4.01

+×news+ 0.34 9.12 0.32 8.78

log(size) 0.00 0.27 0.00 0.15 0.00 -0.09

B/M 0.02 1.40 0.02 1.43 0.02 1.39

return 0.04 0.82 0.29 7.72 0.18 7.53

return 12 0.04 2.92 0.04 2.92 0.05 3.01

RTP 0.02 0.83 -0.01 -0.36 0.00 0.09

RTP×− 0.25 1.58 0.24 1.86

RTP×+ 0.18 1.02 0.23 1.42

This table examines the effect of retail trading proportion on the price shock effect. The table is similar

to Table 9, but we replace ivol with RTP to investigate the effect of retail trading on the 12- month holding

period return in the cross-sectional regressions. The interaction terms between RTP and the two price shocks

(− and +) are also included in the regression. The sample period is 1983.1—2000.12.

53

Page 56: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

TABLE 11

Retail Order Imbalance

extreme negative shocks extreme positive shocks

No News News No News News

day Est. -stat Est. -stat Est. -stat Est. -stat

1 0.145 11.61 0.192 10.65 -0.006 -0.70 -0.036 -2.87

2 0.125 8.19 0.171 8.19 -0.024 -3.21 -0.045 -3.52

3 0.084 5.53 0.131 7.30 -0.016 -1.66 -0.043 -3.59

4 0.063 4.48 0.100 5.12 -0.020 -2.28 -0.038 -2.53

5 0.052 4.32 0.094 5.24 -0.015 -1.46 -0.029 -2.50

6 0.046 3.88 0.091 4.84 -0.016 -1.70 -0.035 -2.85

7 0.032 2.77 0.081 4.37 -0.026 -2.18 -0.044 -2.65

8 0.036 3.55 0.065 3.36 -0.016 -1.53 -0.033 -2.60

9 0.025 1.90 0.070 4.25 -0.017 -1.70 -0.029 -2.12

0.042 4.63 0.081 5.32 -0.025 -3.24 -0.035 -3.77

10-19 0.000 0.01 0.030 2.22 -0.025 -2.77 -0.033 -3.65

20-29 -0.005 -0.42 0.017 1.25 -0.024 -2.51 -0.033 -3.73

30-39 -0.006 -0.53 0.011 0.85 -0.022 -2.21 -0.033 -3.36

40-49 -0.003 -0.22 0.019 1.48 -0.020 -1.79 -0.024 -2.21

50-59 -0.007 -0.42 0.024 1.77 -0.016 -1.23 -0.009 -0.70

This table reports retail order imbalance after extreme price shocks, i.e., decile 1 (decile 10) sorted on

negative (positive) price shock. The Lee and Ready [1991] algorithm is used to classify trades as either

buyer- or seller-initiated. Daily retail order imbalance is computed as: (retail buy - retail sell)/(retail buy

+ retail sell). We first obtain cross-sectional median retail order imbalance. Time series averages and the

corresponding Newey-West -statistics are reported. Retail order imbalance is reported for each day in the

nine days after the extreme price shock. In addition, average daily retail order imbalance is reported for

different 10-day intervals after the price shock. The sample period is 1983.1—2000.12.

54

Page 57: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

Figure 1. Persistent drifts after large price shocks

In Diagram A, stocks are sorted by the minimum three-day abnormal return (negative shock). In this

case, decile 1 contains stocks with large negative price shocks (or most extreme negative shocks). In

Diagram B, stocks are sorted by the maximum three-day abnormal return (positive shock). In this case,

decile 10 contains stocks with large positive price shocks (or most extreme positive shocks). Diagrams C

and D show that for both negative and positive shocks, the effects are stronger for no-news shocks.

55

Page 58: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

Figure 2. Post-shock variation in the sidedness measure

Sidedness is estimated by the correlation between numbers of buyer- and seller-initiated trades, using the

TAQ data from 1993 to 2006 for NYSE firms. The correlation is computed daily, using trades sampled at

5-minute intervals. Daily sidedness is averaged over the month to generate a monthly measure. Panels A

and B correspond to negative and positive shocks respectively, including both news and no-news cases.

Variation in the sidedness measure is shown from two months before the shock to twelve months after

the shock (from t-2 to t+12).

56

Page 59: Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts · Price Shocks, News Disclosures, and Asymmetric Drifts Hai Lu, Kevin Q. Wang, and Xiaolu Wang ∗ March 12, 2012 ∗Hai Lu,

Figure 3. Post-shock drifts in a conditional setting

Within a momentum setup, the figure illustrates disagreement-induced overpricing. The winner stocks

are divided to form subsets: those associated with price shocks right before the holding period starts and

those without price shocks. The winners with price shocks are further divided, depending on whether or

not the price shock is associated with news (public disclosures). The loser stocks are divided similarly.

57


Recommended