+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments:...

Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments:...

Date post: 22-Mar-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 1 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
132
West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 71483 Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized
Transcript
Page 1: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT

February 28, 2007

71483

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Page 2: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized
Page 3: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

Table of Contents

1. INTRODUCTION............................................................................................................................... 1

2. THE SETTING FOR LOCAL GOVERNMENT FINANCE IN WEST BENGAL ...................... 3

LOCAL GOVERNMENT STRUCTURE ............................................................................................................. 3 FISCAL AUTONOMY .................................................................................................................................... 3 STATE FINANCE COMMISSIONS. ................................................................................................................. 5

3. III. RURAL LOCAL GOVERNMENT FINANCES ....................................................................... 8

BUDGET SHARES .......................................................................................................................................... 8 EXPENDITURE STRUCTURE ........................................................................................................................... 9 CONCENTRATION BY POPULATION SIZE ....................................................................................................12 COMPOSITION OF EXPENDITURES BY POPULATION SIZE CLASS .................................................................13

4. REVENUE STRUCTURE ................................................................................................................15

OWN SOURCE REVENUES ..........................................................................................................................15 GRANTS AND TRANSFERS ..........................................................................................................................17 CENTRALLY SPONSORED SCHEMES ...........................................................................................................18 GRANTS AND TRANSFERS: STATE GOVERNMENT ...........................................................................................21

5. ANALYSIS OF THE DISPARITIES IN GRAM PANCHAYAT FINANCES ............................23

EXPENDITURE DISPARITIES .......................................................................................................................24 EXPLAINING EXPENDITURE VARIATIONS ..................................................................................................26 OWN SOURCE REVENUES ............................................................................................................................28 EXPLAINING THE DISTRIBUTION IMPACT OF INTERGOVERNMENTAL TRANSFERS ......................................31

6. FINANCIAL CONDITION ..............................................................................................................34

DO MANY GRAM PANCHAYATS HAVE A NEGATIVE RECURRENT REVENUE GAP? ....................................35 DO THE RESULTS FOR SURPLUS GPS INDICATE AN INABILITY TO ABSORB THE FUNDS? ...........................35 TO WHAT EXTENT DO “DEFICIT” GRAM PANCHAYATS DRAW ON THEIR CASH BALANCE RESERVES TO COVER

THE COST OF DELIVERING SERVICES? .........................................................................................................36 DO THE CLOSING BALANCES CHANGE OVER TIME, AND HOW DO WE EXPLAIN THIS? ARE THESE

CLOSING BALANCES “TOO LARGE”? .........................................................................................................37 WHAT DETERMINES FINANCIAL CONDITION? ...........................................................................................37

7. THE FISCAL POSITION OF BLOCK AND DISTRICT LEVEL GOVERNMENTS ..............40

EXPENDITURES ..........................................................................................................................................40 OWN-SOURCE REVENUES ..........................................................................................................................41 INTERGOVERNMENTAL TRANSFERS ...........................................................................................................42 FINANCIAL CONDITION..............................................................................................................................43 SUMMARY .................................................................................................................................................44

8. STATE GOVERNMENT AND FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION ..............................................45

STATE TAXATION ......................................................................................................................................46 REDIRECTION OF EXISTING FUNDS ............................................................................................................46 THE GRANTING OF MORE FISCAL DISCRETION..........................................................................................47

9. REFORM OPTIONS AND EVALUATION ...................................................................................49

DECIDE ON AN OPTIMAL TIER FOR LOCAL SELF GOVERNMENT ................................................................49 EXPENDITURE ASSIGNMENT ......................................................................................................................53 INCREASED OWN SOURCE REVENUE .........................................................................................................57

Page 4: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

INCREASED STATE GRANTS: DETERMINING THE VERTICAL SHARE ...........................................................59 A Formula Approach. ..........................................................................................................................63 Increased, Untied Grants: A Formula Distribution .............................................................................63

10. FINANCING THE FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION PROGRAM ........................................67

REFERENCES ..........................................................................................................................................126

Page 5: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

1. INTRODUCTION

1. This report is about the fiscal performance of rural local governments in the state

of West Bengal. Specifically, our goal is to develop a comprehensive fiscal information

system for all rural local governments, and to use these data to evaluate the

intergovernmental finance structure in the state. The work is of significant policy

importance, given the need to develop programs to respond to the constitutional

amendments mandating fiscal decentralization1

, and to support central and state

government initiatives to use the PRI system as an important part of its poverty

alleviation strategy. A more immediate need in West Bengal (and other states as well) is

to support the work of the State Finance Commissions to better integrate rural local

governments into the intergovernmental fiscal framework.

2. Many observers of fiscal federalism in India have pointed out that fiscal

decentralization to the third tier has not progressed very far since the constitutional

amendments of the early 1990’s. State governments have held on to budgetary control

and State Finance Commission recommendations to strengthen local government

finances have in large part been ignored. Underlying this state of affairs is the fact that

neither the central nor state governments have data that allow them to accurately evaluate

and monitor the fiscal performance of the Panchayat Raj Institutions (PRIs).

3. At present, there is no accurate, official record of the fiscal activities of PRI in

West Bengal. The existing data base is not comparable across local government units, is

not readily available in one place or in electronic form, is incomplete, and is not linked to

amenity or demographic databases. Every time the Department of Rural Development in

West Bengal (or the State Finance Commission) carries out an analysis of gram

panchayat finances, it must resort to doing a special survey2. The results presented in

this report, based on primary data for nearly all PRIs in West Bengal, give arguably the

first-ever look at the overall picture of rural local government finances in the state. The

situation as regards socio-economic data is somewhat better in that there is a 2001

census. But even here, census data are missing for a substantial number of gram

panchayats and the so-called “amenity data” have not been aggregated into a usable data

1 Article 40 of the Constitution directs states to endow village panchayats with such powers as necessary to

function as units of self government. This is reaffirmed in the 73rd amendment to the constitution (1992),

which defines the governance of the PRIs, and calls for the assignment of expenditure responsibilities and

taxing powers to them. 2 See, for example, SRD (undated).

Page 6: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

2

base3. This is because the base measurement unit of the census is the sub-village level

and aggregation to the gram panchayat level has not been done properly in every case.

4. In this report, we use data from a newly developed fiscal information system to

study the fiscal performance of PRIs in West Bengal. The general outline of the data

base upon which this report is built, and the methodology used in collecting and

organizing these data are included in Annex A.

5. The first three sections of this report describe the structure of rural local

government finance in West Bengal. More specifically, we describe the expenditure

responsibilities and financing powers of local governments, and carry out an empirical

study of how they use these responsibilities and powers. In Section IV, we focus on own

source revenue and grants and transfers to PRIs from the central and state level

governments. In Section V, we study fiscal disparities among gram panchayats in West

Bengal and model an explanation of these variations. The concern in Section VI is with

fiscal balance among the gram panchayats, i.e., with the extent to which they run deficits

on current account and the extent to which they carry significant balances. A parallel

analysis for block and district level governments is the subject in Section VII. In Section

VIII, we examine the pivotal role of the state government in determining whether fiscal

decentralization will take place. In the final two sections of this report, we evaluate some

options for reform and the cost implications of these reform packages. While this work

does profile the fiscal activity of all three levels of PRI, the focus is on gram panchayats.

This is because of the view in West Bengal (and in many other quarters) that gram

panchayats are the best candidate for local self-government.

6. This study can be a significant compliment to the work of the Third State Finance

Commission in West Bengal, which is due to report in 2007. An added benefit from this

study, hopefully, is that it may lift the level of the discussion about PRI finances among

political leaders, technical experts, private sector leaders and voters in the state. It might

also be useful as a model for similar work being carried out in other states.

3 The “amenity” data include measures of community infrastructure -- such as school capacity, miles of

permanent roads, street lighting -- and measures of community development such as the presence of

commercial banks or telecommunication services. For an example of how these data may be used, see the

Karnataka and Kerala case studies in Sethi, ed. (2004).

Page 7: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

3

2. THE SETTING FOR LOCAL GOVERNMENT FINANCE

IN WEST BENGAL

7. In terms of budget responsibilities and resources, each of the three levels of local

government within the rural sector is assigned a set of expenditure responsibilities,

revenue raising powers, and entitlements from the grant system. These assignments are

made by the State government under the guidance of the Constitution and the Panchayat

Act. The expenditure responsibilities of rural local governments are spelled out in some

detail in Government of West Bengal (2005). PRI finances also are impacted by the

recommendations of the State Finance Commission concerning the distribution of fiscal

resources between the state government and the local governments4. Finally, there are

direct, conditional transfers from the central government to the PRIs and these constitute

the major revenue flow to the local bodies. The impact of these three influences is

described below.

Local Government Structure

8. The PRI system in West Bengal consists of 18 districts (zilla), 341 blocks

(panchayat samatis) and 3,324 gram panchayats, as described in Figure 1. The urban

stream of local governments, which includes municipalities and city corporations, is

separate from the rural stream. The rural and urban local governments operate under

different enabling legislation, and each is allocated a specified share of the state

government revenue sharing pool.

9. Perhaps as befits a state with more than 80 million people, the structure of rural

local government is a hierarchical one. Local officials report up to the next highest level.

Moreover, the flow of most intergovernmental transfers passes through the district and

block levels before reaching the gram panchayats. Budget approval by PRIs, however,

does not have to be sought from a higher tier of local government.

Fiscal Autonomy

10. The data presented in this report describe the pattern of spending and financing by

rural local governments. But, data alone cannot reveal the degree of autonomy that local

governments have in making fiscal decisions. There are elected local governments in

4 The State Finance Commissions are required to sit once in every five year period.

Page 8: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

4

West Bengal and each has the power to approve their budget. In fact, however, the

degree of fiscal discretion that is underneath the making of these budgets is limited by

expenditure mandates and by constraints on revenue-raising powers.

11. Local governments are given no powers to exceed their assigned complement of

employees, nor do they have any power to determine the rate of pay of their employees.

So, the wage bill of local governments is fixed from above.5 In addition, there are

expenditure mandates, e.g., the central schemes are conditional grants with narrowly

prescribed expenditure targets.

12. The gram panchayats (GPs) are thought by some to be more like autonomous

local governments than are districts or blocks. For decades, the idea of village

government with some degree of autonomy has been discussed in India. Gandhi’s vision

of village swaraj has influenced subsequent discussions of the need for local self-

governance (Alok, p. 207). Moreover, there is provision for this in Article 40 of the

Constitution. With the passage of the 73rd

constitutional amendment, local governments

were again recognized, and more explicit provision was made for planning and service

delivery responsibility and for revenue raising powers. In most states, the gram

panchayats have been given more fiscal autonomy than districts and blocks, including

some independent power to levy certain taxes6. However, in West Bengal, this has led to

only about 6 percent of GP expenditures being financed from local sources. On the side

of expenditure composition, GPs play a role in project selection; hence to some extent

they can be responsive to special needs in various locations within the gram panchayat.

Otherwise, most of their expenditure budget is driven by mandates from higher level

governments.

13. The blocks and districts have less fiscal discretion on the revenue side than do the

gram panchayats, even though they sit higher in the local government hierarchy. They

may raise revenues from fees and charges, and have the authority to set the rate for some

of these charges, but they have no taxing power. They rely primarily on grants and

transfers for their general purpose finances (only about 3 percent of their revenues are

raised from own sources). Therefore, the size of the block and district budget is mostly

determined by higher-level governments.

14. On the expenditure side, districts and blocks face the same restraints on their

budget choices as do gram panchayats. The expenditure discretion that they do exercise

is in the capital budget, and it relates mostly to project selection and implementation with

respect to centrally sponsored schemes. With respect to State grants, only a small

proportion is unconditional (untied). Most state grants and transfers in West Bengal are

conditional and give local governments little room to rearrange the priorities laid down

by the state government. Though governed by elected councils, the districts and blocks

appear to function largely as spending agents of the state and central governments.

5 An exception is that local governments may hire employees on a contract or a daily wage basis, without

permission from up-level governments. 6 This “discretion” is perhaps overstated. As is discussed below, the rates and bases of these local taxes are

prescribed by the State government.

Page 9: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

5

State Finance Commissions.

15. The State of West Bengal has received reports from two State Finance

Commissions (SFC)7. The first SFC was constituted in 1994 and reported in 1995. The

“period of recommendation” was 1996-2001. The second SFC was constituted in 2000

and made an interim report in 2001, with a period of recommendation of 2001-2006. The

third SFC is now sitting with a report expected in 2007.

16. According to the West Bengal Panchayat Act and The Constitution, the charge of

the SFC is far-reaching. Its report is to contain recommendations:

“…on the principles that should govern the distribution of state revenue between

the state and the Panchayats and the allocation between the Panchayats, at all

levels, of their respective shares of such proceeds. The Commission was also

required to recommend the principle that should govern the distribution of the

revenue resources between the state and the Municipalities and the allocation

between the Municipalities of their respective shares. The Commission would

also determine the taxes, duties, tolls and fees which could be raised by the

Panchayats and the Municipalities. The Commission would also recommend

measures needed to improve the financial position of the Panchayats and the

Municipalities.”

17. In effect, the SFC is empowered to recommend a complete overhaul of the system

of state and local government finance. Though there were numerous recommendations

made by both West Bengal Commissions as regards intergovernmental finance, the focus

has been heavily, if not exclusively, on the revenue side. This is similar to the approach

that has been taken by State Finance Commissions in other states (Subrahmanyam, 2004),

and it is consistent with the charge given to the SFCs in the constitutional amendments.

Still, if the focus of the SFC is to be on ensuring adequate financing, a strongly implied

responsibility is to determine optimal expenditure assignments. Otherwise, how could

adequacy in “revenues” be determined?

18. Arguably, the most important proposal of the first two State Finance

Commissions was for a vertical share of 16 percent of state taxes as a grant entitlement of

local governments. Acceptance of this proposal would have led to a very significant

increase in fiscal decentralization. It was also proposed that these grants be “untied”, i.e.,

that the recipient local governments be given the discretion to spend this money in any

way they choose.

19. This primary recommendation of the Second SFC was not accepted by the state

government8. Instead, they decided on a program where a fixed allocation would be

7 The 73

rd Amendment made provision for the appointment of the State Finance Commissions.

8 The West Bengal State Second Finance Commission submitted their report to the government on

February 6, 2002. The corresponding ‘Action Taken Report’ was filed by the State Government on 15th

July 2005 before the State legislation.

Page 10: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

6

made to a PRI revenue sharing pool each year, depending on the financial condition of

the state. In fact, even this approach was not acted on by the State government in 2004

and 2005. In these two years, the State government did not distribute finance

commission grants to the local bodies. In 2006, the vertical share was set at Rs 278 crore,

which is about one-half the amount recommended. The sharing of this pool of funds

among local governments, however, is done by formula, and in this regard, the

recommendations of the SFC have been followed.

20. Other important recommendations of the State Finance Commission were in the

area of own-source revenues of PRIs, where the need for a revenue increase and the need

for more autonomy were seen to be important. The First SFC proposed to devolve

entertainment tax revenues fully to local governments and to give rate setting powers to

the local bodies. The Second SFC called for full devolution of entertainment tax

revenues to local governments, but not for rate-setting powers. The State Government

has chosen to hold the power to set rates but to transfer 90 percent of the revenues raised

to local governments. Both State Finance Commissions argued for devolving the powers

to set for the level of various charges. State government has not moved very far in this

direction.

21. One could make the argument that the West Bengal State Finance Commissions

have not been very successful9. Their major recommendation, that a general revenue

sharing program with a 16 percent vertical share be established for local governments,

was not accepted. There are many reasons for this, with the precarious fiscal position of

the state government being the most common explanation. There were, perhaps, other

shortcomings. A reasonable critique of the principal recommendation is that the 16

percent share was not justified by a hard analysis of the expenditure needs of the local

governments. To date, neither of the SFCs nor the State Government has based their

recommendations for a vertical share on expenditure needs. Oommen (2006) studied the

outputs of five other State Finance Commissions and found that none estimated the

vertical gap based on a hard analysis of expenditure needs. Correcting this problem is

arguably the next important step that the SFCs should take to improve the acceptability of

their recommendations.

22. Another critique of the SFC work in West Bengal (though this problem was out of

their control) was that neither commission had access to a reliable data base of PRI

finances, as has been developed here. The extent to which the absence of fiscal

information constrained the work is well-described by the following quote from

“Recommendations of the Second State Finance Commission” (p. 26):

“Data regarding resources of the different tiers of the Panchayats were not

available at the State level. In view of this we circulated a questionnaire to all the

Panchayats. Responses to this questionnaire were not uniform. Seven hundred

and nineteen (719) out of 3362 gram panchayat sent replies but the data in respect

9 In fact, one could make the argument that very few of the SFCs have had a favorable impact on the

finances of PRIs. A good review of the recommendations and results of the State Finance Commissions is

in Subrahmanyam (2004). Also see Oommen (2006), and Rao and Singh (2006).

Page 11: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

7

of only 170 gram panchayat could be used. We also received information from

142 PSs out of a total of 341 while 10 out of 17 ZPs responded to our

questionnaire. In spite of better administrative infrastructure available at the ZP

level, it is difficult to understand why larger number of ZPs could not respond.

We are aware of the inadequacy of the data and the problems of generalization

from the same. While in respect of PSs and ZPs, the data could be taken to be

fairly representative, in respect of gram panchayat this would at best give an

indication of their state of finance.”

23. The combination of this absence of data and very limited staff resources made it

difficult (impossible) for the SFC to fully evaluate the impacts of its proposed reforms.10

Whether a better evaluation of impacts would have led to a different proposal, or to a

different response from the state government, is something that we may only speculate

about. The Third Finance Commission in West Bengal faces this same data constraint.

10

The same problem has been emphasized in a number of other SFC reports. Subrahmanyam, 2004, notes

(section 1.4.3) that “ Absence of district/microlevel data on panchayat finances on which the State-level

data would be based could lead to the conclusion that the statistical particulars furnished by the States to

the Central Finance Commission are nothing short of a kind of ‘guestimates’ ”.

Page 12: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

8

3. III. RURAL LOCAL GOVERNMENT FINANCES

24. The data base developed for this project is used here to investigate the fiscal

importance of rural local governments in West Bengal, the structure of their expenditure

outlays, and the sources of their finances. The goal is to develop a fiscal profile for

different levels of rural local government, with special attention paid to the gram

panchayats. Such information can be used by government to track rural local government

finances in the state, and to evaluate reform options. It is an essential piece of evidence

that heretofore has been missing from the policy analysis.

Budget Shares

25. The place to start this investigation of rural government finances is with an

understanding of the relative importance of the PRIs in the state fiscal system. In Table 1

we show the fiscal shares of different levels of government in West Bengal. Note that 72

percent of the state population is resident in rural areas, but less than 17 percent of

government expenditures are made by rural local governments11

. The point to be taken

from this comparison of population concentration and expenditure concentration is not

that rural residents are being discriminated against by the fiscal system (the State

government vertical programs may or may not emphasize rural benefits), but that rural

local governments are quite small players in the state fiscal system, and they are much

smaller players than are urban local governments. In total, expenditures by rural local

governments are equivalent to less than one percent of state GDP. One could safely say

that there is not much local self governance in rural areas of West Bengal.

26. The 17 percent share of expenditures managed through panchayats in West

Bengal is not so far out of line with that in at least some other Indian states where data

are reliable. Rao, et. al., (2004) estimate that about 20 percent of expenditures are

channeled through panchayats in Karnataka, while Oommen, et. al. (2004) estimate the

share at closer to 30 percent in Kerala.

27. West Bengal’s system of government finance is even more centralized on the

financing side of the budget equation: 96 percent of all revenues raised are at the state

government level. Rural local governments account for less than one percent of all own-

source revenues raised. Even this small amount is an overstatement of their importance

in revenue mobilization because local governments have limited discretion to determine

the amount they will raise.

11

All population data in this report are drawn from the 2001 Census.

Page 13: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

9

28. Another way to describe the small role of rural local governments in public

financing is to note that local government expenditures are Rs 452 per person for urban

residents as compared to Rs 138 per person for those who live in rural areas.12

Voice in

fiscal decisions at the community level is a benefit that would appear to be more

important for urban voters than for rural voters.

29. We also may ask about the relative importance of the three tiers of PRI in terms

of expenditures and own source revenues. From Table 1, we can see that the district

governments account for about 45 percent of the spending of all PRIs13

. More important

is the finding that the gram panchayats in aggregate account for only about one-third of

spending.14

Thus about two-thirds of PRI expenditures are made by districts and blocks,

who under the present structure, might be better thought of as spending agents of the state

government. Under this interpretation, we may say that of all state and local government

expenditures made in West Bengal in 2005, only about one-third was made by the level

of government that that many would argue comes closest to approximating local self

governance15

.

30. On the side of own source revenues, districts raise approximately the same share

as the gram panchayats (who have access to both tax and non tax sources). The revenue

raised by districts is a mixture of licenses, fees and charges such as fees to oversee

tenders or the work of contractors, and revenues from district-owned enterprises. The

block level raises very little own source revenue (Table 1).

Expenditure Structure

31. How do rural local governments spend their money, and how much variation is

there across local governments? Interestingly, the budgets are dominated by spending for

capital purposes at all three levels (Table 2). District governments report that 85 cents of

every rupee spent is for capital purposes. The capital expenditure share in blocks and in

gram panchayats is closer to 60 percent. In a sense, this is a correct representation of the

expenditure pattern in that these reported capital expenditures are made to purchase or

create assets with a longer life than that of the annual budget.16

But, the percentages

shown in Table 2 are surely an overstatement. Much of this expenditure carries the

objective of job generation hence might be thought of as part of an income maintenance

package and therefore as a current expenditure. Moreover, the assets created by these

public works projects may be more akin to maintenance and repair than to new

12

These estimates of per capita expenditures in 2005 are based on 2005 fiscal data and 2001 population

data, hence are an overestimate. 13

Note that these samples are less than 100 percent coverage because of missing data for some districts,

blocks, and gram panchayats. These missing units are small enough, however, that we do not believe that

their inclusion would markedly change the results shown in Table 1. 14

An interesting comparison is Karnataka where Rao, et. al. (2004), estimate that gram panchayats

accounted for only about 5 percent of total PRI spending in 2003. 15

An interesting comparison is Karnataka where Rao, et. al. (2004), estimate that gram panchayats

accounted for only about 5 percent of total PRI spending in 2003. 16

Capital expenses are defined in the data base as follows: “Any expenditure resulting in the creation of

physical assets like land, buildings, machinery and equipment is regarded as capital expenditure. This

includes centrally sponsored schemes, state sponsored schemes and other schemes/welfare programs which

involve capital expenditure.” (See Annex A.)

Page 14: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

10

construction. Also suggesting the temporary nature of some of these projects is the fact

that the use of machinery in the work is prohibited, as is the use of contractors

(Government of India, 2006).

32. Some flavor of this capital expenditure activity in the PRI can be gained from the

guidelines for the SGRY (employment generation) program. The SGRY specifies that

the grant must be spent for the creation of durable assets, particularly those that would

assist in drought-proofing such as soil and moisture conservation works, watershed

development, promotion of traditional water resources, and afforestation, as well as

construction of village infrastructure and link roads, primary school building

dispensaries, veterinary hospitals, and marketing infrastructure (Government of India,

2006). While the assets created under this program may or may not be long-lived, they

do seem to be more in the vein of development than consumption expenditures.

33. So, one can argue that rural local governments emphasize capital spending, but

the numbers reported in Table 2 should be interpreted in the context given above.

34. A second thing to note about the pattern of rural local government expenditures is

that there is specialization among the tiers of rural local governments in terms of

functional assignment. As shown in Table 3, block governments are more involved in

delivering social services through their budgets than are either districts or gram

panchayats. Health, education, and welfare programs account for one-third of block-level

budgets, by comparison to 10 percent or less for districts and gram panchayats. Block

spending in the health area covers a range of responsibilities such as maintenance and

upgrading of community health centers, supervision of primary curative services,

implementation of immunization and safe drinking water programs, and monitoring and

planning (Government of West Bengal, 2005). With respect to education, the blocks

manage the mid-day meal program and with respect to welfare they are responsible for

beneficiary selection for a number of programs. However, block level governments in

West Bengal have been little involved in housing programs. And again, it should be

emphasized that they have little discretion in deciding how to spend these funds.

35. The reported data (Table 3) show districts to spend primarily for housing,

infrastructure, and employment generation (77 percent of total expenditures), a finding

that seems reasonable for the level of government that can best handle service delivery

responsibility when the benefit zone covers multiple blocks and gram panchayats. The

budgetary expenditures of districts appear to be dominated by those programs financed as

centrally and state sponsored schemes. This seems consistent with the idea that district

governments are primarily spending arms of higher level governments.

36. The much smaller gram panchayat’s comparative advantage is in delivering

services and implementing schemes where the benefit zone is local. For the most part,

their expenditure assignments reflect this comparative advantage. Though there is some

responsibility for education, e.g., implementing continuing education programs, the

budgetary expenditures of gram panchayats are dominated by development programs (61

percent of total expenditures) that are mostly financed under the centrally sponsored

Page 15: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

11

schemes. Again, there is the issue of whether these are capital expenditures related to the

creation of long-lived assets, or current expenditures to support an income maintenance

program. Arguably the most noteworthy observation to make about gram panchayats is

the 20 percent share of the budget devoted to administration and salaries (Table 4),

compared to less than 3 percent for districts and blocks. This reflects some combination

of the labor intensive nature of the services delivered by gram panchayats, the large

amount of responsibility for management type activities, and apparently a high fixed cost

associated with operating small local governments. This fixed cost effect is described in

Box 1.

Box 1

The Fixed Cost of Rural Local Governments

There is a fixed cost of local government that is independent of population size. All local

governments have in common the need for a secretary, bill collector, support for the local

assembly, a basic level of physical faculties, etc. In fact the State of West Bengal assigns

the same number of posts for each GP, and determines the compensation rate for these

posts. To the extent that all posts are filled, salaries may be viewed as a fixed cost of

local government, and do not vary much with the population size of the local

government.

To test this hypothesis, we have pulled a sample of the 20 largest (population) and 20

smallest GPs. The average population for the 20 largest GPs is over 10 times that of the

20 smallest. The calculations of the average fixed costs of each group are reported in the

table below.

The overall level of administration expenses is higher in the larger GPs, but on a per

capita basis, the fixed cost argument is very apparent. The smaller GPs spend 4 times as

much as the large GPs (per capita) on administration expense. The lower value for the

larger GPs reflects the ability to spread these costs over a larger resident population.

In the case of salary expenditures, the total amounts are about the same, for large and for

small GPs. The per capita amounts in the smaller GPs, however, are about 15 times

higher.

Table Box 1

Fixed Cost Effects: For 20 Largest and Smallest GPs

(in Rs)

20 Largest 20 Smallest

Administration Expenses Per GP 128,103 67,606

Salary Expenses Per GP 347,798 375,377

Administration Expenses Per Capita 6.8 27.7

Salary Expenses Per Capita 10.3 146.0

Source: Source: PRI-West Bengal data base: The World Bank (see Annex A)

Page 16: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

12

Concentration by Population Size

37. An important question has to do with the concentration of expenditures among

local governments with different population sizes. In particular, we are interested in the

extent to which the expenditures of rural local governments in West Bengal are

dominated by their larger members.

38. One might begin with the null hypothesis that the small gram panchayats have too

little capacity to play a significant role in the rural local government fiscal system. If

this is the case, one would expect that the per capita expenditures of smaller GPs would

be lower. To test this, we examine the expenditure pattern for 2,959 gram panchayats,

divided into four population size categories, and report the results in the bottom panel of

Table 5.17

The percent of spending by gram panchayats in each size class is then

compared to the percent of population in that size class. These results (Columns 2 and 3)

do not support the null hypothesis. They show that the smallest gram panchayats (under

15,000 in population) are more important in the local fiscal structure than their population

share would suggest. The 849 gram panchayats in this size class account for only 18.6

percent of the rural population, but for 24 percent of the total spending by all gram

panchayats. In all other population size classes, the share of population equals or exceeds

the share of expenditures.

39. If more heavily populated local governments are more developed, and have the

better capacity to deliver services, this is not the pattern that one would expect. In fact,

the notion that more heavily populated GPs in West Bengal are more prosperous is not

fully supported by the data. As may be seen from the matrix of simple correlation

coefficients in Annex Table B-3, larger GPs tend to have significantly lower literacy

rates, suggesting less wealth. However, they also have significantly lower proportions of

SC/ST populations, smaller shares of female population, and lower percentages of

marginal workers. These patterns suggest that more heavily populated gram panchayats

have higher levels of income. Unfortunately, there are no income or product data

available for GPs, so we cannot directly test for a relationship between each of these

factors and the level of development of a GP.

40. Another explanation of the seemingly counter-intuitive result presented in Table 5

is that the transfers associated with centrally sponsored schemes are distributed away

from more heavily populated gram panchayats, and this is the source of the negative

relationship between population size and per capita expenditures. In fact, the data are

consistent with this hypothesis in that the simple correlation between population size and

17

Of the 3,354 gram panchayats in West Bengal, fiscal data are reported in this study for 3,016. However,

population data are available for only 2,973. Our maximum sample size, when using population data, is 86

percent of the total number of gram panchayats.

Page 17: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

13

per capita revenues from centrally sponsored schemes is negative and significant (Annex

Table B-3).

41. Finally, we may attribute part of this result to an economies of size effect that

leads smaller local governments to spend more in per capita terms. This is explained in

Box 1.

42. In Column 4 of Table 5, we report the distribution of own source revenues raised,

according to population size class. Our expectation is that larger population suggests

agglomeration effects, such as regional markets or entertainment events, or more

developed infrastructure. All of these suggest a greater capacity to levy taxes and assess

user charges. Again, the result is surprising. The largest gram panchayats (over 25,000

in population) account for about 19 percent of the total population but for only about 15

percent of own source revenues raised. The fact that own source revenues are more

concentrated among the gram panchayats with fewer than 25,000 in population suggests

that either the more heavily populated gram panchayats are less developed than might be

supposed, or that they do not make as much effort in revenue mobilization as do the

smaller places.

43. We have repeated this analysis for blocks and districts, as shown in the top panels

of Table 5. For the 288 blocks examined, the results are much the same as for gram

panchayats. The smallest size class accounts for only about 22 percent of the population

but over 29 percent of total spending. The largest block governments (those with

populations above 250,000), by contrast, account for a greater share of population than of

expenditures. And, as in the case of the gram panchayats, the largest blocks account for a

small share of total own source (non-tax) revenues mobilized relative to their population.

The hypothesis that larger populations lead to better capacity to spend and to raise

revenues is not consistent with these statistical results.

44. For the 17 districts studied, the same pattern holds with respect to the

concentration of expenditures (Table 5). The four districts with the smallest populations

(less than 2.5 million) account for a disproportionately large share of expenditures. The

reverse is observed for the four largest districts. This result is almost certainly due to the

allocation formulae for centrally sponsored schemes. However, unlike the case of GPs

and blocks, these four largest districts account for about 40 percent of the population but

over 50 percent of own source revenues raised. In terms of user charges and license

collections, and perhaps revenues generated from assets owned by these governments,

larger districts would appear to have some comparative advantage and perhaps more

willingness to make use of their revenue-raising powers.

Composition of Expenditures by Population Size Class

45. Is there much variation across gram panchayats with different populations in

terms of the distribution of their expenditures by function? The issue of most interest

here is whether the smaller local governments are forced to restrict their spending to more

Page 18: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

14

administrative functions, perhaps because they have a limited capacity to deliver services.

The answer we get from the results reported in Table 6 is that there is a population bias in

the functional distribution of gram panchayat spending. The share of capital expenditures

in total expenditures (mostly for employment generation and low income housing

assistance) rises with population size18

. Two possible explanations for this pattern are

that there are greater needs for housing in more heavily populated gram panchayats, and

that funds available for housing and other infrastructure investment are allocated

disproportionately to more heavily populated places. (These two possibilities are

examined in more detail in the discussion below.) A third explanation is that the fixed

costs of operating a local government force smaller gram panchayats to allocate a larger

share of their budgets to administrative functions. In fact, the data in Table 6 show that

the smaller gram panchayats do allocate a disproportionately large share of their budgets

to administrative and salary expenditures.

46. The results for blocks, and particularly for districts, also show a dominance of

capital expenditures in the budgets (Table 6). This pattern would be consistent with the

view that districts are primarily involved in the implementation of central and state

schemes, and are much less a local government than a spending agent of the state.

18

A somewhat surprising result revealed in this table is that the expenditures on the housing programs

(IAY) exceed the expenditures on employment generation programs (SGRY) for all population groupings

of gram panchayats. Further investigation shows that this is not the case for 2003 nor for 2004 -- in both of

those years, employment generation program expenditures are larger than housing program expenditures.

Page 19: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

15

4. REVENUE STRUCTURE

47. “How do rural local governments finance their budgets? To what extent do they

pay for services from own sources of revenues and to what extent do they pay from

central and state grants and transfers?” About 6 percent of all revenue of gram

panchayats is derived from own sources (Tables 7 and 8). This is less than the 20 percent

estimated by Rao, et. al. (2004), for Karnataka for 2001, and the 17 percent estimated by

Oommen et.al. (2004) for Kerala in 1999.

48. The share of revenues raised from own sources (including tax and non tax

revenues) is less for smaller gram panchayats than for larger places (Table 7). From the

data in this table, we can see a general pattern of gram panchayats of all sizes raising

more revenue from non-tax fees and charges than from tax revenues. The dependence of

blocks and districts on intergovernmental transfers is slightly higher than that of gram

panchayats (Table 7). This is because districts and blocks have no taxing powers. These

measurements underscore the finding that there is a very strong degree of revenue

centralization in West Bengal state.

Own Source Revenues

49. The Constitution provides for gram panchayats to have the power to tax, i.e., to

determine the effective rate at which certain bases will be charged. However, it is left to

the state governments to determine which taxes a local government may levy, as well as

the nature of the autonomy that local governments will have in determining their level of

taxation. The broad-based taxes are denied panchayats, in all states, and this seems

appropriate given their limited administrative capabilities. Otherwise, states differ in

terms of the revenue sources they assign to local governments, and there is by now a long

list of taxes that are locally administered in India. In their review of the practice in

Kerala, Gujarat, and MP, Subrahmanyam and Annamalai (2004, p. 275-276) report 14

different categories of tax that are in use.

50. Rural local government taxes in most countries tend to be narrow-based and

administratively difficult. But even so, they have the potential to significantly increase

the level of revenues available to the local governments. By one estimate, rural local

governments in West Bengal raise a per capita amount of own source revenue that is

equivalent to about one-fourth the all-India average (Alok, 2006, Table 6.6). Based on

this interstate comparison, it would seem that there is significant potential for additional

revenue mobilization by local governments in West Bengal.

Page 20: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

16

51. The term “own source revenue” requires some explanation in the case of rural

local governments in West Bengal. The normal definition requires that local

governments have the power to at least set the tax rate (Bahl and Linn, 1992, chapter 12;

Bird, 1999). For the property taxes and the entertainment tax in West Bengal, the rate

and base are prescribed by the State Government in the Panchayat Act. The gram

panchayats have the power to set a property tax rate, but may not exceed the ceiling rate

set by the state. Gram panchayats do have some discretion, however, in their

administration of the property tax and in terms of setting the rates of certain non-tax fees

and charges.

52. Property and Land Taxes. The gram panchayat level in India has been

empowered in most states to levy a land and building tax. In theory, the base of the tax is

the annual rental value of land and buildings.19

In practice, the tax is levied on an area

basis, or a housing unit basis, or on some other notional basis. At least one study in West

Bengal reports a “backward” method where the amount of tax is determined first and then

taxable property value is calculated as a residual (Pal and Adak, undated). It seems fair

to say that the current practice is one where there is no valuation process by which some

scientific method is used to estimate a market value. Neither is there a method to revalue

properties in a systematic way. The local governments are responsible for keeping the

tax rolls and for collections and enforcement.

53. In West Bengal, unlike in many other states, the tax base includes both

agricultural and non-agricultural property. Properties with a value less than Rs 250 are

exempt from tax. The maximum tax rates, set by the state government, are one percent

for properties with an annual value less than Rs 1000 and two percent for properties with

an annual value greater than Rs 1000. In addition, the gram panchayat may levy a

property transfer tax on immovable property. The tax rate is 2 percent and the base is the

selling price (consideration) in an arms length transaction.

54. We do not have data on property tax revenue. However, a reasonable guess is

that most of the tax revenue reported for gram panchayats in West Bengal is property tax.

Per capita total own source revenues for GPs is about Rs 8. Property tax performance is

very weak.20

55. One might offer a number of explanations for this poor revenue performance.

First, properties may be dramatically under assessed. We have no direct evidence on this

but can report a widespread belief in West Bengal that valuation practices are very ad

hoc. Second, collection rates can be very low. Pal and Adak (undated) estimated a ratio

of collections to demand (assessed liability) of 26 percent in 2001. A recent SRD study

(undated) made a similar estimate of the collection rate, based on data taken from a

sample of gram panchayats21

. Low collection rates may be traced to several factors:

19

Annual rental value is defined to be the equivalent of 6 percent of market value. 20

Rao, et. al. (2004) reports about the same level for Karnataka. 21

Rao, et. al. (2004), estimate a 69 percent collection rate in Karnataka in 2003, but noted that this is

against a base that has not been revised in 30 years.

Page 21: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

17

lax or inept administrative practices

inadequate staffing and poorly trained staff

residents do not see the value of paying taxes in terms of the

services they receive from the GP, and therefore resist payment.

GP leaders are hesitant to enforce the tax on the local elite.

56. Entertainment Tax. The entertainment tax is levied on admissions to various

events. The Act defines entertainment as exhibitions, movies, performances,

amusements, and games or sports to which persons are charged admission. The tax rate

is 10 percent.

57. In West Bengal, the tax is levied and collected by the State government with 90

percent of the proceeds returned to local governments. The return is by formula: 80

percent to urban local bodies and 20 percent to rural local governments. Therefore, the

entertainment tax is really an intergovernmental transfer, i.e., the tax rate and base are

determined by the central government, collections are made by the central government,

and the central government decides on how the proceeds will be divided among local

governments.

58. The first SFC recommended turning this tax over to local governments, and

giving them discretion to set the rates. The state government did not accept this proposal.

The Second State Finance Commission did not call for full conversion to a local tax, but

did hold to the recommendation that revenues be fully devolved. The State government

has for the most part accepted the recommendation of the second SFC. It argues that an

intergovernmental transfer is a better approach than a local entertainment tax because it

(a) can reflect the superior ability of the state government to collect the tax, and (b) can

allow rural local governments (whose residents may travel to urban entertainment events)

to share in the revenue proceeds.

Grants and Transfers

59. About 94 percent of total revenues of the gram panchayats come from grants and

transfers. The share for districts and blocks is even higher. The composition of these

grants and transfers is described in Box 2, with revenue distributions for 2005

summarized in Tables 8 and 9.

Box 2

The Components of Intergovernmental Transfers

1 State Government

Finance Commission Grants

Untied Grantsa

Salary Grants

Other Grants

Page 22: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

18

BEUP

State Sponsored Schemes (Minideep, PROFLAL, other)

2. Central Government

Finance Commission Grants

Centrally sponsored schemes (SGRY, IAY, NSAP, IMY, midday meal, SSA,

other)

MPLAD, other

a

Untied grants include funds devolved to the Panchayats from the Government, the use of which is not

restricted to any specific purpose. In some GP statements, untied funds are termed as ‘Shartaheen Fund’.

Untied funds include the following: (a) ‘Lump grant’ which is a lump sum amount received by the

panchayats from the Government and can be used by the panchayats for any development purpose, (b)

‘Matching grants’ which are funds received from the Government to bridge any deficit faced by the

panchayats in meeting their expenses; matching grants are also termed as ‘Paripurak Anudan’ or

‘Sampurak Anudan’ in some statements, (c) Other untied funds.

Centrally Sponsored Schemes

60. The centrally sponsored schemes are by far the largest share of revenues, as may

be seen in Table 8. About 75 percent of PRI transfers and 70 percent of PRI revenue is

from the centrally sponsored schemes. Over two-thirds of this total for gram panchayats

is accounted for by the IAY and SGRY schemes (Table 9). The share of centrally

sponsored schemes for blocks and districts is even higher (in the range of 80-90 percent

as indicated in Table 8), emphasizing again the agency role they play in implementing

central government programs.

61. SGRY. The SGRY is an employment generation programme for rural areas that

is targeted to benefit the poorest segment of the rural population (Government of India,

2006). The stated objectives of the program are to provide wage employment in rural

areas and to create a durable social and economic infrastructure. The program is

administered by the PRI, who have some discretion in deciding on the type and location

of public works projects that will be carried out. There are limits on this discretion.

Since this is a conditional grant, certain rules are prescribed on the use of these funds.

Moreover, the action plan of each PRI must be approved by the next level up, e.g., gram

by blocks, blocks by districts, etc.

62. The total funding for the programme for each year is decided on by the central

government in the course of the normal budget process. There is no fixed formula

defining the SGRY entitlement as a share of central taxes or of the central budget. In

recent years (2003-2005) the national plus state allocation has been Rs 6000 crore plus 50

lakh tons of food grains. The entitlement (vertical share) for each state is decided upon

by the central government, based on a formula that ranks states according to their share of

the rural poor population in India.

Page 23: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

19

63. The Central Government amount22

for each state is paid directly to districts. This

is done according to a formula that gives equal weight to the proportion of SC/ST

population and to the inverse of production per agricultural worker. The Central

Government prescribes how the revenues will be shared among PRI within a district: 20

percent to the district governments, 30 percent to the blocks and 50 percent to the gram

panchayats. A matching requirement from the state government is mandated in the ratio

of 75 percent central and 25 percent state. The state government uses the same formulae

as the center in allocating its 25 percent share across rural local governments.

64. The districts make the allocations among blocks and among gram panchayats, but

again according to formulae laid down by the Central Government. The 30 percent

entitlement of blocks is distributed half by the proportion of SC/ST population and half

by the proportion of rural population, with both variables measured relative to that of the

district. The 50 percent share of gram panchayats is allocated by formula, subject to a

minimum entitlement of Rs 25,000 per local government23

. In fact, the gram panchayat

share of SGRY can be even larger than is indicated by these formulas. This is because

some district and block schemes are implemented at the GP level and the funds

associated with these schemes pass through the GPs. We cannot identify these amounts

separately.

65. The gram panchayat shares also can be smaller than these formulae suggest. This

is because some GPs do not spend the funds fast enough to trigger the full release of the

entitlement during the fiscal year.

66. Certainly the PRI have no discretion in determining the amount of their

entitlement under SGRY. Nor do they have discretion to shift this money toward

expenditures for other purposes. The discretion of gram panchayats in using this money

is also limited by the requirement that it must be spent on infrastructure projects that

employ unskilled labor, and that 50 percent of the funds be used for infrastructure

development work in localities with a larger SC/ST population.

67. In theory, the PRI do have discretion in project selection. They are charged with

developing an action plan that lays out the projects to be undertaken. (These plans must

be approved by the next higher level of government). In practice, the discretion that PRI

have in implementation may be very limited. One study argues, with respect to SGRY

that “… the role of PRIs in planning and implementation is insignificant” (World Bank,

2005, p6). It is argued that line department officials take on a supervisory role and that

central guidelines lead all key decisions about projects.

68. As may be seen in Table 9, SGRY transfers are a larger share of

intergovernmental transfers in districts than in either blocks or gram panchayats. This is

22

Actually, only 95 percent of the full entitlement is allocated in this way. The Ministry retains 5 percent

to allocate to areas of acute distress arising out of extraordinary seasonal conditions. 23

After 2004, the allocation to each gram panchayat was made in proportion to their previous year’s

allocation.

Page 24: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

20

a surprising finding in that districts are supposed to retain only 20 percent of the total

received, and the gram panchayat share is 50 percent.

69. IAY. The Indira Awaas Yojana (IAY) is a flagship scheme of the Ministry of

Rural Development to provide houses to the poor in the rural areas (Government of India,

2006). The objective of the program is primarily to help construction/upgrading of

dwelling units of members of Scheduled Castes/Scheduled Tribes, freed bonded laborers,

others below the poverty line, and other needy groups24

by providing them with financial

assistance. The construction of the house is the sole responsibility of the beneficiary.

70. The IAY is a Centrally Sponsored Scheme funded on a cost-sharing basis between

the Government of India and the State Governments, in the ratio of 75:25.

71. Central assistance under the Indira Awaas Yojana was originally allocated to the

States/UTs on the basis of poverty ratio and housing shortage, with each of these

variables being given equal weightage. Since 2005-2006, the weightage is 75 percent

housing shortage and 25 percent poverty. The estimated poverty ratios prepared by the

Planning Commission are used for this purpose, while housing shortage is determined on

the basis of the most recent census data available. The proportions of rural SC/ST

population (25 percent) and housing shortage (75 percent) in a district, relative to that of

the State/UT, are the criteria for the allocation of the Indira Awaas Yojana funds within a

State/UT. The numbers of houses to be constructed for each block and gram panchayat

within a district are decided in the same way, but by the district government rather than

by a strict formula. Once the block or gram panchayat is notified about the number of

beneficiaries, it may decide on the specific beneficiaries, according to the guidelines of

the program. Hence there is some discretion for the local government to decide on the

distribution of benefits.

72. As may be seen in Table 9, IAY transfers are a larger share of intergovernmental

transfers in gram panchayats than in districts. Block level governments in West Bengal

were little involved in the IAY program in 2005. These results do not suggest a pattern in

terms of the involvement of PRIs of different population sizes.

73. Other Central Schemes and Grants. There are a number of other types of central

transfers to rural local governments. The “other schemes” category shown in Table 9

includes several assistance programs that are targeted on various sectors. Together, these

amount to about 10 percent of total central transfers in the case of districts and blocks,

and 7.5 percent in the case of gram panchayats.

74. The Member of Parliament Local Area Development Scheme (MPLAD) has the

goal of enabling members of parliament to suggest and facilitate execution of

development works based on local needs. The amount of MPLAD allocations are not

trivial, especially by comparison to state government allocations to PRIs, as may be seen

in Table 9. The funds go primarily to the block level.

24

The program benefits have been extended to the families of ex-servicemen killed in action, and to

physically and mentally challenged persons.

Page 25: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

21

75. The Twelfth Finance Commission grants, earmarked for operating costs of water

and sanitation, account for a significant share of transfers. This award continues a

tradition begun by the Eleventh State Finance Commission. The distribution among

districts, blocks, and gram panchayats is shown in Table 9.

Grants and Transfers: State Government

76. The state government provides financial transfers to the PRIs through three types

of programs: State grants, State sponsored schemes, and BEUP. These assistance

programs, to the extent they carry conditions, allow the state government to influence the

pattern of spending by the PRI. State government transfers are a relatively small 25

percent of gram panchayat revenues and an even smaller share for districts and blocks.25

77. State Grants. There are several state government transfers in the financing

structure in West Bengal, but they take on most significance as a share of revenues in the

case of gram panchayats (See Table 8)26

. The State Finance Commission grant has the

feature of being unconditional, hence it is in step with a decentralized fiscal strategy. It is

this program that has drawn the attention of the two State Finance Commissions and led

to the recommendation of a 16 percent vertical share. But, as may be seen in Table 10,

the state government made no distributions under this program in 2004 and 2005. In

2006, the amount distributed was fixed at Rs 278 crore, and it is reported that the intent is

to distribute this same amount in 2007.

78. The most important component of state grants is the salary grant. This is a cost

reimbursement allocation to PRIs based on their number of approved posts. Since the

state government approves posts, and sets pay grades, this transfer leaves the local

governments with little discretion in terms of how the grant can be spent. The salary

grant is equivalent in amount to nearly 80 percent of all state transfers received by gram

panchayats and nearly 60 percent in the case of districts (Table 10).

79. Third, there are the so-called “untied grants”. The untied grants are a collection

of unconditional grants (e.g., the lump sum grant, matching grants) that are of primary

importance to district governments.

80. Finally, there are the BEUP grants made through state legislatures. As may be

seen in Table 10, these grants (similar to the central MPLAD grants) are most important

as methods of financing block level expenditures.

81. State Sponsored Schemes. In addition to the State Finance Commission and the

salary grants, the State provides funding to the PRIs for various specific schemes. These

schemes are targeted programs, for which the PRIs have little expenditure discretion.

The schemes include:

25

The state matching share for the CSS is not included in the state transfer category reported in Table 9. 26

This is because salaries comprise an important share of the gram panchayats budget, and these are

financed by the salary grant.

Page 26: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

22

“Minideep”, which is an irrigation scheme to promote groundwater

irrigation. The mini deep tubewells that are supported by the program are

operated by electricity and all the operation and maintenance costs are

borne by the State government.

PROFLAL or Provident Fund for Landless Agricultural Laborers is a

social security scheme for the landless agricultural laborers

The fiscal importance of the state intergovernmental transfers is described in Table 10.

These constitute less than 3 percent of the total amount of state transfers received by

gram panchayats.

Page 27: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

23

5. ANALYSIS OF THE DISPARITIES IN GRAM

PANCHAYAT FINANCES

82. There are significant variations in the socio-economic conditions existing in gram

panchayats, blocks and districts. These underlying conditions are the basic determinants

of expenditure needs, fiscal capacity, and the ability to attract central government

transfers, and should help us explain fiscal disparities among local governments. Most

empirical studies begin with per capita GDP as a standard for measuring variations in the

capacity to finance services. In West Bengal, however, we have no data on per capita

GDP below the district level. As an alternative, we might use the data available on socio

economic condition to justify some proxy measures of poverty and economic

development.

83. Various analyses in West Bengal have used four proxy measures of the

concentration of poverty in gram panchayats: (a) the percent of population in scheduled

castes and tribes, (b) the percent of the population female, (c) the percent of marginal

workers, and (d) the rate of illiteracy.27

In this study, we use population to measure size,

and to measure the level of economic development, we use the literacy rate and the

percent of employment in non-agricultural labor.

84. The variations across PRIs in these indicators are shown in Table 11. The mean

values are reported in the first column of each panel, with the number of units reporting

shown in parenthesis.28

The next three columns show the range and relative variation in

each indicator. For example, for the second row, we can see that for the 17 districts

reporting, the average share of SC/ST in the total population is 32.1 percent. The lowest

share is 13.3 percent and the highest is 55.6 percent, with a coefficient of variation of

37.2.29

85. Note from the minimum and maximum values in the table that the variation

across gram panchayats is quite large in the case of some of these measures. For

example, the literacy rate among gram panchayats ranges from a low of 12.5 percent to a

high of 79.4 percent. Such variations may be telling for variations in fiscal performance.

Literacy is likely to be associated with stronger economic development and therefore

revenue mobilization. We expect that gram panchayats with low levels of literacy will

27

See, for example, State Finance Commission (2002). 28

All means are unweighted. 29

The coefficient of variation is the standard deviation as a percent of the mean, hence it is a measure of

relative variation. By this measure, for example, there is more variation across districts in the percent of

SC/ST population than there is variation in the literacy rate.

Page 28: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

24

obtain less own source revenue than those with higher literacy rates.30

The disparities in

literacy rates are also a reflection of expenditure need, which is likely to be much more

acute in those gram panchayats with low levels of literacy31

. This should be reflected in

the flow of revenue from central schemes for poverty alleviation. The percent of

marginal workers in the population also shows large disparities across gram panchayats.32

While the average percent of marginal workers among GPs is 11 percent, in one GP, it is

over 40 percent. In gram panchayats where there are larger proportions of marginal

workers, there tends to be a significantly larger share of SC/ST population, a larger share

of females in the population, and a lower literacy rate. The percent of marginal workers,

then, seems a reasonable proxy for the backwardness of a gram panchayat, and an

indicator of greater expenditure needs.

86. There also are substantial differences among districts in their level of economic

well being. Note from Table 11 that the richest district has a per capita GDP that is

roughly twice the level of the poorest district. We have developed an inter-correlation

matrix for districts on these same measures for the 15 of 18 districts for which data are

available. We find that in richer districts (measured by per capita gross product), there

tends to be a significantly smaller share of SC/ST population, and a significantly higher

literacy rate.

Expenditure Disparities

87. There are great disparities across local governments in West Bengal in the

amounts they spend. An accounting of these disparities will give a baseline for

determining the equalization job that the intergovernmental transfer system will be

required to do.

88. District Aggregates. The disparity between the highest and lowest income

districts in West Bengal is about 1.8 (Table 12). We examine whether rural local

government expenditure disparities are as large by computing an aggregate per capita

expenditure of district, block, and gram panchayats governments. The results, shown in

Column (2) of Table 12 show a disparity of 3.1 between the highest and the lowest

districts. Spending disparities are nearly twice as great as income disparities.

89. We examine the pattern of disparities in Figure 2 with aggregate per capita

expenditures on the vertical axis. The pattern we observe suggests equalization. The

four poorest provinces are among the highest spenders on a per capita basis and three of

the four richest are among the lowest.

30

The simple correlation between the literacy rate and per capita own source revenue is positive and highly

significant (see Annex B). 31

The simple correlation between the literacy rate and the percent of SC/ST population is negative and

highly significant (See Annex Table B-3). 32

A ‘marginal worker’ is one who has not worked in the past six months.

Page 29: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

25

90. Gram Panchayats. To study the variation across gram panchayats, we have

computed Table 13, which shows the overall variation in per capita total expenditures of

gram panchayats. As above, we report mean values as well as variations.

91. Gram panchayats spend very little on a per capita basis, only about Rs 138 per

person on average, i.e., US $3.14 per capita. The level of per capita expenditures fell

from 113 rupees per person in 2003 to 102 in 2004 but then increased from 102 to 138

between 2004 and 2005. This continuing, very low level of expenditures suggests that

gram panchayats are “under-assigned” expenditure responsibilities with the result that the

services they do provide may not have much affect on the quality of life in the local

government area. The result is that voters might not be very interested in getting

involved to influence the level and structure of local government expenditures. In fact,

some studies point to the non-functioning gram sabha as evidence of little citizen

participation in budgeting decisions (Institute of Social Sciences, 2005). This is a major

obstacle to realizing the local self-governance outcomes sought by the constitutional

amendment. To address this problem, government could rethink the role of gram

panchayats in delivering services, in the direction of giving them additional assignments

of expenditure responsibility, as well as access to additional resources.

92. The large variation among gram panchayats in per capita spending level, in 2005,

is shown by the frequency distribution in Figure 3. We first rank GPs from lowest to

highest per capita expenditure (2005). We then create groups of per capita expenditures

in 20 rupee increments (0 to 20, 20 to 40, 40 to 60, and so on) and fit each GP into their

respective group. The second to last group is 480 to 500 rupees per person and the very

last group is “more than 500 rupees.” The level of per capita expenditure is plotted on

the X-axis and the cumulative frequency (number of GPs) is plotted on the right vertical

axis, while the absolute frequency (actual number of GPs in an expenditure category) is

plotted on the left vertical axis. For example, there are 591 GPs in the per capita

expenditure group “80 to 100 rupees per person.”

93. Over 83 percent of all GPs spend 180 or less rupees per person. The distribution

has a “long tail” meaning that there are a number of individual GPs that spend more than

180 rupees per person, but the level of spending for those GPs is not concentrated in any

one expenditure group. The higher spending amounts range from 180 rupees to 4,515

rupees. In such cases, the services delivered are likely to be meaningful. Understanding

the reasons for these wide disparities may be the key to developing a strategy to increase

the fiscal importance of gram panchayats. We argue that these disparities are due either

to the way in which grants and transfers are distributed, or to higher levels of own source

revenues in some gram panchayats, or to an inadequate capacity to absorb expenditure

responsibility on the part of some gram panchayats.

94. The distribution of per capita expenditures across population size classes, as

shown in Table 13, is surprising. On average, the smallest gram panchayats spend more

per person than do the more heavily populated gram panchayats33

. As noted above, this

33

A regression analysis on gram panchayats in Kerala also found a significant negative relationship with

population size (Oommen, et. al., 2004).

Page 30: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

26

could be a fixed cost effect, i.e., local governments must spend a certain amount to satisfy

the basics of operating a local government and when this total is spread over a larger

population, the per capita amount falls. But, the fact that 80 percent of gram panchayat

spending is for capital and income maintenance purposes suggests that there are other

explanations. Chief among these is the possibility that the formulae to allocate grant

funding and other transfers may favor local governments that are less heavily populated.

95. We recalculate the relationship between per capita spending and population size,

with fixed costs removed from the expenditure variable. Since the state government

provides approximately the same salary grant for all gram panchayats, we might take

salary expenditures as a measure of fixed costs (See also Box 1). We subtract salary

grants received from the state government from total expenditures of gram panchayats,

reproduce the calculations from Table 13, and report the results in Table 14. The pattern

is much the same as reported in Table 13. The per capita expenditures of gram

panchayats are higher for the less heavily populated local governments. This result, then,

is due to more than the fixed cost effect. A hypothesis consistent with this finding is that

there is a bias in the allocation of central and state transfers that favors gram panchayats

with smaller populations.

Explaining Expenditure Variations

96. About 5 percent of the GPs report per capita expenditures that are very small—

averaging 50 rupees per person. The top 5 percent of GPs (in terms of per capita

spending) spend at least 2 ½ times that of the average GP. The very top of the

distribution—those GPs in the top 1 percent of the distribution -- spend over 584 rupees

per person. Understanding the determinants of this wide variation is a first important step

toward developing a financing structure that will allow the provision of a minimum level

of services in every gram panchayat.

97. As a first step, we calculate the simple correlation coefficients between selected

fiscal variables and selected socio-economic variables. This simple correlation matrix is

presented in Annex B (separately for districts, blocks, and gram panchayats). There are a

number of significant covariates. In particular, we can see that per capita expenditures for

gram panchayats are significantly higher where there are smaller populations, where there

is a larger percent of SC/ST population, where the percent of marginal workers is larger,

and where there is a greater share of agricultural population. Expenditure needs do seem

to matter. These simple correlations suggest that the joint impact of these population

characteristics on per capita expenditures is complicated, and involves more than first

order correlations. Therefore, we use a multi-variable regression to explain inter-

governmental differences in per capita expenditures.

98. We estimate OLS regressions separately for gram panchayats, blocks, and

districts, where per capita total expenditures is the dependent variable, and the

independent variables are justified as follows:

Page 31: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

27

Population size should be negatively related to per capita spending, because for

smaller local governments, cet. par., the fixed cost effects will weigh heavily on

budgets. Moreover, central scheme revenues may be allocated in disproportionate

amount to local governments with a smaller population.

The percent of SC/ST population should be positively related to per capita

expenditures because this implies a heavier concentration of poor citizens who are

more costly to serve. For this reason, greater amounts of CSS transfers will flow

to local governments with heavier concentrations of SC/ST in the population and

these grants will result in higher per capita expenditures.

We do not have a prior on the marginal effect of variations in the literacy rate on

per capita expenditures. The effect should be positive if literacy signals more

willingness to pay on the part of residents and a greater capacity to deliver

services on the part of government. If a greater rate of literacy equates with more

poverty and therefore a greater inflow of transfers to support employment

generation programs, a negative effect might be expected.

The share of workers in the agricultural sector might indicate more need for

services because services currently provided in the more remote areas may be

more deficient and more costly to provide34

. It also may be positively related to

the level of per capita expenditures because of the likelihood that larger shares of

agricultural workers indicate a more agrarian economy and more demand for

employment generation programs. The simple correlations reported in Annex B

suggest that where the agricultural share of employment is high in a gram

panchayat, we can expect significantly less literacy, a greater percent of SC/ST

population, and a larger percent of marginal workers.

We have included a dummy variable to take account of district of location for

blocks and gram panchayats, and a dummy variable to take account of block

location in the gram panchayats analysis. This should pick up the impact of some

qualitative factors such as location, political power, and different attitudes and

levels of efficiency at the district and block levels. We expect that, all else being

the same, there will be “district effects” and “block effects”. To construct the

dummy variables, we have omitted Uttar Dinajur district and one randomly

chosen block in each district. The remaining district and block coefficients should

be interpreted as the “effect” of a particular district on the dependent variable,

relative to the omitted district (block).

99. The results of this OLS analysis are presented in Table 15. About 81 percent of

the variation in per capita expenditures among the 2,098 gram panchayats in the sample

can be explained by these variables. Population size exerts the expected significant and

negative size effect. The proxy measure for the concentration of poverty (SC/ST

34

Data on the share of workers in the agricultural sector are available for gram panchayats but not for

districts or blocks.

Page 32: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

28

population) is significant in leading to higher levels of per capita expenditures. This is an

expected result because higher proportions of SC/ST population draw in more

intergovernmental transfers to address the greater expenditure needs. All else held

constant, a ten percentage point higher share of SC/ST population may be associated with

a 1.8 percent higher level of per capita spending by a gram panchayat35

. The literacy

rate exerts a positive marginal effect on spending. For any given level of population,

SC/ST population, etc., a higher literacy rate leads to a higher level of expenditures.

Better education leads to more demand for public resources and at the margin to a greater

willingness to pay for services. We might think of this as the impact of a higher rate of

economic development. A larger share in agricultural employment leads to significantly

higher levels of per capita expenditures, as hypothesized.

100. Gram panchayats in all districts spend more than those in Uttar Dinajpur, even

after account is taken of these explanatory variables. Seventy four of the 325 block

dummy variables were significant (23 percent), indicating that there are important

differences in spending levels within districts, even after we account for district effects

and for the socioeconomic characteristics included in Table 15. Based on this, one might

argue that there are important management and political factors to be considered in

explaining inter-GP variations in per capita expenditures.

101. One might conclude from this analysis that expenditures are significantly higher

in less populated and more backward GPs, suggesting that a considerable degree of

equalization is built into the system. At the margin, however, higher rates of literacy are

associated with higher levels of spending.

102. We repeat this analysis with the salary grant removed from the dependent

variable. This should allow an estimate of determinants, independent of the fixed cost

effects (See Box 1). The results, shown in Table 16, do not change the conclusions very

much. Population size remains a dampening influence on per capita expenditures, though

the elasticity is low compared to that reported in Table 15.

Own Source Revenues

103. Rural local governments in West Bengal raise very little revenue from own

sources. The average for gram panchayats is only about Rs 8 in per capita. However,

the variation is great. Some gram panchayats raise 20 to 30 times the average amount,

while 200 GPs report raising no own source revenue—with 140 of those GPs in the two

lowest population classes. This result is shown in Table 17 by population size class for

districts, blocks, and gram panchayats. Interestingly, the average level of per capita own

source revenue declines with population size for the gram panchayats36

.

104. We might turn to a more systematic approach to explain the considerable

variation in per capita own source revenues across gram panchayats, i.e., to estimate an

35

The alternate poverty measure, the percent of females in the population, was not significant, so was

dropped from the regression. 36

The simple correlation between population size and per capita own source revenue is negative, but not

significant, as is shown in Annex B.

Page 33: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

29

OLS regression of the determinants of per capita own source revenues. Our question is,

“Why do some gram panchayats raise more own source revenues than do others?” The

answer to this question may be important to helping formulate an incentive policy for

stimulating revenue mobilization. The dependent variable in this analysis is per capita

own source revenues, including tax and non-tax sources. The independent variables are

included based on the following a priori reasoning:

Population size should be positively related to per capita own source

revenues because agglomerations of population suggest greater taxable

capacity. With a larger population, there should be greater levels of

economic activity, regional markets that would draw non-resident buyers

and sellers to the GP, more commercial dwelling units to tax, and more

services financed by user charges. On the other hand, if smaller GPs draw

more intergovernmental transfers, this may dampen enthusiasm for

revenue mobilization and a negative relationship might be expected.

A larger percent of SC/ST population suggests a greater concentration of

poor households, less taxable capacity, and a negative relationship with

per capita own source revenues. This might be reinforced if the

concentration of SC/ST population draws more transfers, and reduces the

incentive to mobilize more revenues.

A higher literacy rate suggests a greater taxable capacity and a positive

relationship with the level of own source revenue. This hypothesis is based

on the premise that more education leads to higher wages on the part of

the local population, and arguably to a greater willingness to pay taxes.

The percent of agricultural workers in the economy will signal more

difficulty in tax collection and arguably a weaker taxable capacity. We

expect a negative relationship with per capita own source revenue.

District and block effects are included in the GP regression and district

effects are included in the block regression.

105. The results of the analysis are reported in Table 18. About 55 percent of the

variation in per capita revenues across 2,067 gram panchayats can be explained by this

model. The literacy rate variable is significant and has the expected positive sign. This

would appear to measure the positive marginal effect of economic development and voter

awareness on the mobilization of own source revenues. The elasticity is relatively high,

i.e., if the literacy rate is 10 percent higher, the level of own source revenue collections

will be about 9 percent higher.

106. Greater percents of workers in the hard-to-tax agriculture sector do in fact dampen

the level of own source revenues, as hypothesized. Neither of the poverty variables are

significant determinants. The population effect is negative, i.e., there is no evidence of

agglomeration effects on revenue mobilization. However, the “population effect” may

Page 34: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

30

have been obscured by the inclusion of the district and block dummy variables. There are

a number of district effects with Bankura and Hugli reporting higher per capita own

source revenues than the omitted district of Uttar Dinajpur (which is a relatively low

income district). In the case of several other districts a negative effect is observed (See

Table 18). Block effects are observed in about 17 percent of the cases, suggesting the

importance of qualitative factors as discussed above.

107. Intergovernmental transfers play so large a role in financing rural local

governments that they may have an impact on local revenue mobilization. Transfers may

dampen the enthusiasm of local governments to be aggressive about collecting tax and

non tax revenues. Alternatively, larger inflows of transfers might stimulate more local

revenue mobilization, i.e., they might generate a kind of local match to accommodate the

cost of larger government. To test this hypothesis, we repeat the regression analysis

described above but add per capita total grants and transfers as an (exogenously

determined) independent variable. The results (Table 19) show that for gram panchayats,

per capita grants and transfers are positively and significantly related to own source

revenues per capita. The latter results suggest that own source revenues and

intergovernmental transfers do not substitute for one another but rather are

complementary, i.e., the more grants received, the more own source revenue raised. The

result is not so far-fetched. The cash payment inflow under the schemes and grants may

well lead to increased tax and non-tax payments by beneficiaries and by those supplying

inputs in the implementation of programs. Note that when we introduce

intergovernmental transfers as an independent variable, neither the population nor the

poverty variables are significant.

108. In summary, we might interpret this analysis as showing that per capita own

source revenues in gram panchayats are higher where there is more literacy, where a

smaller share of the population employed in the hard-to-tax agricultural sector, and where

there is a greater inflow of transfers.

109. Measuring Tax Effort. One reason why this estimation of the determinants of

revenue mobilization is important is that we might use these results to monitor the

revenue mobilization efforts of gram panchayats. This would allow the State to identify

low performing gram panchayats where additional training and other technical assistance

is necessary to enhance collections. Or, an index of tax effort might be used in an

intergovernmental transfer distribution formula to provide an incentive for better tax

effort and a penalty for poor tax effort.

110. We may use the results generated above to develop an index of tax effort for gram

panchayats. The idea is to identify those GPs that are raising own source revenues at a

level above expectations and those that are performing below expectations. This is a

good alternative to using the average per capita amount raised as the “expectations” for

every gram panchayat. Fiscal capacities vary widely and some GPs should raise more

revenues than others, even if they exert the same effort. To control for this, we use the

following methodology:

Page 35: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

31

From the equation shown in Table 18, we estimate the “expected” level of

own source revenues for each gram panchayat, based on the socio-economic

characteristics of that gram panchayat. For example, for the first gram

panchayat shown in Table 20 (Domahana), we would expect a per capita level

of own revenues of Rs 4.47.

The actual level of taxes divided by the estimated level is the index of tax

effort. This is shown as “effort” in Table 20. For example, the first gram

panchayat actually raises Rs 2.77 in per capita own source revenues, hence its

effort index is 0.62.

An effort index, for example of 0.62, indicates that Domahana gram

panchayat is raising own source revenues at a rate that is 38 percent below

expectations, based on a statewide comparison. By contrast, the gram

panchayat of Oldabari exerts a tax effort that is 107 percent above

expectations. The results for 10 of the more heavily populated gram

panchayats shown in Table 20, indicate an above average effort in three cases.

Explaining the Distribution Impact of Intergovernmental Transfers

111. The “rules” for vertical and horizontal sharing of intergovernmental transfers is

discussed at some length above. Now we turn to an analysis of the variations among

local governments in the actual amounts of transfers received. In particular, we want to

identify the “implicit formula” for the distribution of intergovernmental transfers across

gram panchayats and across districts and blocks. That is, we examine the actual

relationship between transfers distributed and measures of need such as the size of the

SC/ST population, population size, etc. We are especially interested in whether there is

any empirical evidence that this distribution is or is not equalizing.

112. To begin to answer this question, we have estimated an OLS regression with the

major components of per capita transfers and grants as the dependent variables. We study

the major components of the transfer system, because it seems to be the case that

different programs carry different objectives and are structured in different ways. We

would therefore expect the determinants of the amounts received by gram panchayats to

vary from one grant type to another. In each case, the idea is to tease out an “implicit”

grant formula, and in particular to see if per capita transfers are systematically allocated

to favor poorer jurisdictions.

113. Centrally Sponsored Schemes. We might begin with an analysis of variations in

the per capita amounts received from the two major centrally sponsored schemes: SGRY

and IAY. In the first regression analysis, the dependent variable is per capita SGRY

transfers. The explanatory variables include:

The percent of SC/ST population, which is an indicator of the

concentration of poor families. A positive association with per capita

Page 36: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

32

transfers would be consistent with equalization. We expect a positive

association because of the poverty alleviation goal of the program and

because SC/ST population is a factor that government includes in its

distribution rules.

The literacy rate is expected to have a negative effect on the level of per

capita transfers received, because it is hypothesized that literacy is

associated with a smaller concentration of below-poverty-line population,

and therefore with a smaller inflow of transfers.

Population size is introduced as a control variable. We expect a negative

relationship with gram panchayats, in part, because there is a required

minimum allocation of Rs 25000 to each GP.

The percent of agricultural labor may indicate a larger rural sector and

therefore more demand for employment generation programs.

A district effect and a block effect. This might pick up some effects such

as better program administration, more political skill in attracting

transfers, etc.

114. The results for the SGRY scheme, presented in Table 21 show that the SC/ST

variable has the expected positive sign and is a significant determinant in the case of

gram panchayats. A one percent higher SC/ST population share, cet. par., is associated

with a 0.38 percent higher level of per capita SGRY transfers received. This result is

consistent with equalization. Gram panchayats with smaller populations also receive

significantly more. The unexpected finding is that the literacy rate is significant and

positive, suggesting a counter-equalizing influence in the distribution. The share of

agricultural labor is not significant. There are 8 significant district effects, and 12 percent

of the block dummies are significant, suggesting that other factors are at work in

determining the level of per capita SGRY receipts. In total, we can explain about two-

thirds of the variation in per capita SGRY receipts across gram panchayats.

115. We repeat this analysis for per capita IAY transfers, with the results shown in

Table 22. The percent of SC/ST population has the expected positive sign and is

significant. Per capita IAY transfers are also significantly higher in gram panchayats that

have smaller populations, and a larger percent of agricultural labor.

116. We find that, at the margin, a higher literacy rate is associated with a greater level

of receipts of IAY transfers. This runs counter to the backwardness hypothesis. About

65 percent of the variation in IAY transfers might be explained.

117. We carry out a similar analysis for total central schemes (Tables 23). The results

are much the same as those found for the IAY per capita grants. In the case of GPs, 79

percent of the variation is explained in the regression. Smaller GPs and those with more

Page 37: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

33

backward populations (higher SC/ST) receive more central scheme funds per capita.

However, there is again a counter intuitive result regarding the literacy rate.

118. State Grants and Schemes. In Table 24, we analyze total per capita state

government transfers as a function of the same set of variables as reported in Table 22.

The dependent variable is the per capita amount received from all state grants and

schemes (Table 10). The goal here is to identify the determinants of per capita state aid,

and to compare these results against those for central schemes.

119. The independent variables in this analysis are the same as in the centrally

sponsored schemes. We are interested in the extent to which the distribution responds to

backwardness (percent of SC/ST population), population size, the share of agricultural

workers, and the literacy rate. A district and block effect are added to test for the possible

influence of intangibles such as location, political influence, or a more efficient public

administration.

120. The results of this analysis show that for gram panchayats, per capita state aid is

distributed significantly more toward those with smaller populations and larger shares of

agricultural employment (Table 24). The SC/ST, and literacy coefficients are not

significant. We may compare these results for state aid with those for centrally

sponsored schemes. In particular we might be interested in the question of whether state

transfers or central transfers are more equalizing. As the SC/ST coefficient is not a

significant determinant in the case of state transfers, we can conclude that the central

schemes are more equalizing. That is, if a gram panchayat has a 10 percent greater

concentration of SC/ST population (all else held constant) it does not receive a

significantly greater amount of per capita state aid but it does receive about a 3 percent

higher amount of per capita central scheme revenue.

121. Total Grants and Transfers. Finally, we use the per capita level of total state

grants and transfers as the dependent variable. This includes both central schemes and

state aid. The basic hypotheses are as above: per capita total grants and transfers should

be positively related to the percent of SC/ST population, and to share of employment in

agriculture, and negatively to the literacy rate, if the overall grant system features

equalization.

122. The results presented for gram panchayats in Table 25 show that about 82 percent

of the variation in per capita total transfers can be explained by this model. The percent

of SC/ST population is significant and positive, suggesting equalization in the

distribution of total grants and transfers. As noted above, this is due to the equalizing

influence of central transfers. There would appear to be a bias in favor of GPs with a

smaller population, and those with a larger share of employment in agriculture. These

findings are also consistent with the equalization hypothesis. As in most of this analysis,

these results show that the marginal impact of higher rates of literacy is positive.

Page 38: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

34

6. FINANCIAL CONDITION

123. In this section, we examine the budgetary position of gram panchayats. We use a

simple pro forma (presented in Box 3) to describe budgetary position and assess the

magnitude of fiscal gaps, i.e., situations where annual revenues received (excluding

opening balances) do not cover expenditures made. We then turn to the issue of opening

balances. If these are adequate in amount to cover the recurrent fiscal gap, then the

opening balance can be viewed as a pre-funding of the annual budget. In this case, the

annual drawdown might be thought of as a recurrent revenue. In cases where opening

balances are inadequate to close the annual fiscal gap, the fiscal health of local

governments may be comprised. In studying this issue, we use data for three years (2003,

2004, and 2005).

Box 3

Pro Forma to Describe Budgetary Position

1. Total Revenues

1a. Own Source

Tax Revenue (property tax, amusement tax, other)

Non-tax Revenue (sale of property, leases, donations, other)

1b. Intergovernmental Transfers

Untied Grants

Salary Grants

Other Grants

Finance Commission Grants

Union

State

Centrally sponsored schemes (SGRY, IAY, NSAP, IMY, midday meal, SSA,

other)

State Sponsored Schemes (Minideep, PROFLAL, other)

Others (BEUP, MPLAD, other)

2. Less: total expenditures

2a. Current

2b. Capital

3. Equals: total annual surplus or deficit

Page 39: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

35

4. Equals: difference between opening and closing balance

124. Based on this identity, we have calculated the indicators of financial condition

that are summarized in Table 26. These indicators are very simple, but might be useful in

profiling the financial condition of rural local governments in West Bengal. We draw on

these data to raise (and answer) four questions.

Do Many Gram Panchayats Have a Negative Recurrent Revenue Gap?

125. In fact, about one-half the gram panchayats reporting incurred a deficit in 2005

(Table 26). There was not much change in this number over the 2003-2005 period. The

deficits during this period were (on average) equivalent to about 13 percent of total

revenues. The other half of gram panchayats reported a surplus that also averaged about

13 percent of total revenues. There would appear to be a great unevenness in the fiscal

condition of gram panchayats, i.e., about half do not balance their current budgets and the

other half do not spend all of their recurrent annual revenues. In other words, about half

of GPs are able to add to their cash balances at the end of the fiscal year, and about half

find it necessary to draw from their balances to meet the gap between recurrent

expenditures and recurrent revenues available.

Do the Results For Surplus GPs Indicate an Inability to Absorb the Funds?

126. This is an especially important issue if a reform direction is to increase the flow of

resources to GPs. In fact, there are serious capacity problems at the GP level which may

indicate an inability to spend the money now available. An alternative explanation for

the accumulation of balances is that the conditionality and bureaucratic processes

associated with spending transfers from centrally sponsored schemes significantly limit

the chances that a rural local government can move the money in the year in which it is

received. Whatever the reason for this inability to absorb funds, it suggests the existence

of financial surpluses alongside deficiencies in public service levels in some gram

panchayats. We can note, however, that the same pattern of unspent balances was

observed for gram panchayats in Kerala and Karnataka (Sethi, 2005).

127. There is another possible reason for the surpluses. The receipt of

intergovernmental transfers late in the fiscal year makes it impossible to spend the money

in the year when the funds are received. Many GPs allege this to be a serious problem.

Some state officials see this timing issue as being overstated. The evidence presented

here points to the timing of receipts being part of the problem in West Bengal. Oommen,

et. al. (2004, p. 241-242), reach a similar conclusion in their study of Kerala.

“A rational transfer system should be predictable and ensure

an even flow throughout the fiscal period. This is especially important in view of

the existing situation in which grant receipts are bunched at the end of the fiscal

Page 40: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

36

year, distorting the spending pattern and contributing to high closing/opening

balances. At present, the income-expenditure pattern is so uneven that the fiscal

balance fluctuates from a 200 percent deficit in August to a 40 percent surplus in

March. Closing treasuries for business on working days or imposing oral or

written instructions to restrict treasury transactions have exacerbated the problem.

Resolving the problems of the state-local transfer system in Kerala and resolving

the fiscal problems of the state government are, clearly, connected issues.”

128. The persistence of deficits is explored in Table 21a. During the 2003-2005

period, 199 GPs had deficits in all three years, but only a handful had deficits larger than

their opening balances. This suggests that while some GPs are regularly in a deficit

position, the size of the deficit relative to funds that are carried over is not large. About

one-third of the GPs had at least 2 years of deficit and another one-third had one year of

deficit. There does not appear to be any systematic relationship between the pattern of

deficits and spending levels. For example, we cannot see a relationship between “years

of deficit” (or surplus) and the average level of per capita expenditures for the GPs in this

category (Table 27). More GPs had surplus in all three years (257) than had deficits in all

three years. Failures in the area of financial indiscipline is not a widespread problem in

West Bengal.

129. If the deficit and opening balance problem is one of timing, the surplus should

remain about constant over a period of years (or should grow about in proportion to the

distributable pool). Local governments would bank the money received at the end of the

fiscal year, and then spend it down at the beginning of the next. Unless the flow of

transfers was reduced, one would expect balances to remain at about the same level over

time. This is the pattern we observe in West Bengal. Note from Table 26 that the size of

closing balances relative to total expenditures has remained between 20 and 30 percent

during this three year period. For those GPs running a surplus, the amount has stayed at

about 12 to 14 percent of total revenues. For those running a deficit, the amount has

ranged from 11.7 to 15 percent of total revenues. This analysis suggests that gram

panchayats are “pre-funded” by higher level governments and carry balances that are

sufficient for them to avoid year-end shortfalls.

To What Extent Do “Deficit” Gram Panchayats Draw On Their Cash Balance Reserves

to Cover the Cost of Delivering Services?

130. The approximately 1,500 GPs that annually operate recurrent account deficits, do

so in amount equivalent to around 11-15 percent of total recurrent revenue. As may be

seen for the reported ratio of deficit to balances in Table 28, these GPs have the resources

to balance their budgets.

131. We also can use these data to determine the extent to which opening balances are

adequate to cover the recurrent fiscal shortfall. In all but a handful of gram panchayats,

the balances are adequate. In most “deficit” GPs, the more accurate story would be that

certain recurrent expenditures undertaken in any given year were financed from transfers

received in the preceding year. From this analysis, we might conclude that financial

discipline problems, such as borrowing or deferring creditors to balance the budget, are

Page 41: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

37

an issue for only a small number of gram panchayats in West Bengal. Dealing

individually with these is a manageable task for the fiscal monitoring and evaluation unit

of the State government.

Do the Closing Balances Change Over Time, and How Do We Explain This? Are

These Closing Balances “Too Large”?

132. The closing balances did not change very much in aggregate over the 2003-2005

period. They stayed in a range between 22 and 28 percent of total expenditures. We

might conclude from this, and from the analysis reported in Table 27, that, on average,

the closing balances are more than adequate to cover the shortfalls that deficit GPs face.

The question is whether these balances are too large and an indication that the gram

panchayats are receiving more in transfers than they can absorb. Balances between 20

and 30 percent of expenditures do seem large in a state where services in rural areas are

deficient and where the expenditures made by rural local governments are so meager.

133. Note from Table 26 that large balances are not the case in every GP. About 10

percent of all GPs closed their year with a balance lower than 5 percent of total

expenditures.

What Determines Financial Condition?

134. The state government should be interested in whether financial condition varies

among gram panchayats according to population size and concentration of poverty. Is

there a way to use data on the socio-economic makeup of GPs to develop an early

warning signal for fiscal distress? Or, might we use such data to classify GPs according

to whether they are “high-risk”? Such quantitative measures can help the state determine

where it might need to provide technical assistance in budget management, where it may

need closer surveillance, and/or how it might need to adjust intergovernmental transfers

to better fit the need for budget support. We might raise two questions in this research.

The first is, “What are the factors that lead some gram panchayats to incur a deficit?”

The second is, “What determines the size of the current account deficit?”

135. To analyze the propensity for GPs to be in deficit, we used a probit model, where

we define a “deficit GP” according to our pro forma in Box 3. The dependent variable is

(D=1) for deficit GPs and (D=0) for surplus GPs. We take two definitions of deficit GPs.

First, using data from Table 21a, we define “chronic deficit” GPs as a GP that has a

deficit for each year, 2003, 2004, and 2005. In the second case, we simply define a

deficit GP as any GP that posted a deficit for 2005.

136. The coefficients in Table 29 are estimates of the probability of incurring a deficit.

Our results show that the probability of choosing to run a current account deficit are

different for chronic deficit GPs than for all GPs that posted a deficit in 2005. We

hypothesize that a GP with a larger opening balance could “afford” to overspend against

Page 42: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

38

current revenues, and so we might expect to see a positive correlation between opening

balance and the probability of a deficit. Interestingly, we see this for “regular” deficit

GPs (third column) but not for “chronic deficit” GPs. In fact, for chronic deficit GPs, we

observe an improbable relationship, that the probability of choosing a deficit is inversely

related to the size of the opening balance. The expectation is that the deficit choice for

the “chronic deficit” GPs would be driven more by underlying structural factors than by

cash on hand. For example, the percent SC/ST population might reflect a harsher

economic environment and therefore lead to higher deficits. We do observe this pattern

for chronic deficit GPs. Also, we note that in “regular deficit” GPs, own source revenues

per capita are associated with a smaller probability of deficit, which is an expected effect.

137. To answer the second question, we have estimated an OLS regression with the

dependent variable expressed as the per capita deficit (excluding any use of cash

balances). What we explain in this analysis is the variation in the size of the

revenue/expenditure imbalance, across those gram panchayats that ran a deficit in 2005.

“Surplus” GPs are excluded from this analysis. The independent variables and their

justifications are:

The per capita level of the opening balance. The hypothesis is that the

larger the available opening balance, the more likely is a gram panchayat

to incur a large current account deficit. Hence we expect a positive

regression coefficient.37

In estimating the relationship between the deficit and the opening balance,

we control for both population size and the percent of SC/ST population,

which we have shown above to be significant determinants of expenditure

levels. A priori, we would expect more backward gram panchayats to face

more budget pressures and to be more prone to run a deficit. To the extent

that more backward places are less able to absorb funds, there is another

rationale for expecting a positive relationship.

The per capita level of centrally sponsored schemes is introduced as an

explanatory variable. A positive coefficient would indicate that deficits

are driven up by higher transfers because of overspending. A negative

coefficient indicates that more scheme money dampens the deficit, a

finding consistent with the story that more transfers encourage increased

own source revenue mobilization.

There may be a “district effect” on financial condition. Some districts

may be more effective than others in tracking expenditure needs, training

local officials, and passing resources to GPs where needs are greatest. To

account for the district effect, we include a set of district dummy variables.

37

The dependent variable, per capita deficit (measured in rupees) is expressed as a positive number.

Page 43: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

39

138. The results of the regression analysis (Table 30) confirm the null hypothesis. We

do find the hypothesized positive relationship between the size of the opening balance

and the size of the deficit, i.e., we find that gram panchayats that carry a larger opening

balances run significantly larger deficits. This finding indirectly suggests that larger

opening balances dampens the enthusiasm for higher levels of revenue mobilization. We

also find some evidence of a district effect, i.e., the size of the deficit in Darjiling and

Koch Bihar districts is significantly larger than in Uttar Dinapuri district. This finding

confirms the belief that the management of fiscal affairs in some districts is significantly

different than in others. The poverty variables are not significant determinants. About 55

percent of the variation is explained with this model.

Page 44: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

40

7. THE FISCAL POSITION OF BLOCK AND DISTRICT

LEVEL GOVERNMENTS

139. Block and district level governments are more in the nature of implementing

agents of the state than they are local self-governments. Nevertheless, they manage about

two-thirds of PRI spending. The focus in this report is on the gram panchayat level.

However, to get a complete picture of PRI fiscal activity, it is also important to

understand the structure of finances of blocks (panchayats samitis) and districts (zillas).

140. The richest district in West Bengal has about twice the level of per capita gross

product as the poorest. They range in population size from 1.9 million to 9 million. The

simple correlations in Annex Table B-2 show that higher income districts tend to have a

significantly lower percent of SC/ST population and female population, and a higher

literacy rate.

141. The variation in the population of blocks also is large, from under 70 thousand to

over 400 thousand (Table 11). The simple correlations in Annex Table B-1 show that

larger blocks have significantly greater shares of SC/ST and female population, and a

larger percent of marginal workers. Larger blocks, apparently, are lagging in terms of

economic development and have a larger concentration of poor females.

142. The question we raise here is whether these variations in socio-economic

performance explain the different levels of fiscal activity.

Expenditures

143. On average, districts spend about 12 percent more on a per capita basis than do

gram panchayats. Block level governments spend well less than either (Table 31). The

variation in per capita spending across districts, however, is less than that across either

blocks or gram panchayats (note the size of the coefficients of variation). The pattern

found for gram panchayats, that smaller local governments spend more on a per capita

basis than do more heavily populated local governments, also holds true for districts and

blocks (Table 31).

144. We have carried out roughly the same analysis for districts and blocks as we did

for gram panchayats, with regression results reported in Table 32. The results for

districts are similar to those found for gram panchayats, as reported above. We use only

two variables in the district equation: population size and percent of SC/ST population.

Page 45: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

41

About 63 percent of the per capita expenditure variation across 17 districts can be

explained, with the percent of SC/ST population the dominant determinant. Population

size has the expected negative coefficients, but is not significant at the .05 level.38

What

we can conclude from this is that per capita spending by district level governments is

significantly higher in districts where there is a greater concentration of poverty. As in

the case of gram panchayats, we might attribute this to the heavy weight attached to

backwardness in the distribution formulae for the centrally sponsored schemes. What is

interesting in these findings is that the percent of SC/ST population exerts a greater

marginal effect on per capita expenditures in the case of districts than in the case of gram

panchayats.

145. For the block level governments we can explain about 50 percent of the variation,

with both population size (negative) and the percent of SC/ST population (positive)

significant determinants. Note also that we find a significant “district effect”, with blocks

located in Koch Behar, Gopiballarpur, and Purulia districts spending significantly more

than those in Uttar Dinajur district. This suggests that some factors, unique to districts,

are important in explaining why some blocks spend more than others.

146. We might summarize these findings on the determinants of rural local

government expenditures in West Bengal with the following stylized conclusions:

Larger block governments spend less on a per capita basis than do smaller

block governments. There is no significant relationship between

population size and spending by district governments39

.

The greater the concentration of poor families, the higher will be per

capita expenditures. This conclusion holds for all three levels of rural

local government, and it suggests that the intergovernmental fiscal system

is dominated by an equalization objective.

Own-Source Revenues

147. Districts and block governments have no taxing powers, but can raise own

revenues from non tax sources. As may be seen in Table 33, the level of non-tax

revenues raised by block governments is very small. The average is less than Rs 3 on a

per capita basis and the largest amounts raised are less than Rs 40. The level of per

capita own source (non tax) revenues declines with the population size of the block and

the variation within each population size group is great. (Table 33).

38

The analysis in Table 32 was repeated with the dependent variable expressed net of salary grants. The

results were little different (See Table 32a). 39

To test whether this is due solely to a fixed cost effect, we reduced the dependent variable by the size of

the salary grant. There was very little change from the results (See Table 32).

Page 46: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

42

148. With respect to districts, the pattern for per capita non tax revenues is

more in line with what one would expect. The more heavily populated districts, where

one would expect to see the greatest level of economic activity, show higher levels of per

capita collections than do the smaller districts. On average, however, only about Rs 5 per

capita is raised by district governments.

149. Since blocks and districts act as implementing agents of the central and state

governments, this poor revenue performance suggests little commitment to cost recovery

at any level.

150. There are variations in this generally low rate of revenue mobilization. We test

the hypothesis that the variation can be explained by the level of economic development

using an OLS regression analysis with per capita own source revenue as the dependent

variable. We use the various measures of economic development and backwardness that

are available, but cannot explain a significant amount of the variation for either blocks or

districts (Tables 34 and 35). We conclude that there is a large random element in the

pattern of variation in own source revenue per capita.

Intergovernmental Transfers

151. State and central transfers are distributed downward through the PRIs, first to

districts, then to blocks, and finally to gram panchayats. The question we raise here is the

extent to which central and state transfers are distributed in an equalizing way among

these PRIs.

152. Centrally Sponsored Schemes. We can explain about 60 percent of the variation

in per capita SGRY receipts for blocks and districts (Table 36). In the case of blocks,

those units that are more heavily populated receive significantly less in employment

generation grants. A higher share of SC/ST population draws more SGRY transfers per

capita. At the margin, the literacy rate is associated with greater SGRY transfers per

capita, which is a surprising result.

153. The results for districts, also reported in Table 36 are mostly in step with

expectations. On a per capita basis, SGRY transfers are allocated in greater amounts to

GPs with a heavier concentration of SC/ST population and a lower literacy rate. Oddly,

however, we find that the marginal effect of per capita gross product on per capita SGRY

is positive.

154. If we use the percent of SC/ST population as the basic measure of poverty, we can

say that the SGRY scheme is driven by equalization at both the block and district level.

155. In the case of blocks, we can explain a significant percent of the variation in IAY

transfers but cannot learn much about the determinants of the per capita distribution

(Table 37). At the district level, we can explain about 60 percent of the variation (Table

37). The implicit distribution seems heavily weighted toward indicators of

Page 47: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

43

backwardness, i.e., percent of SC/ST population, and the illiteracy rate. Per capita IAY

scheme amounts are transferred with a bias in favor of districts with a larger population.

What we can say from this result is that the goal of the center -- to distribute housing

scheme revenue toward pockets of poverty -- seems to work better at the district level

than at the block level.

156. The next question is how this all plays out in terms of the per capita distribution

of total central scheme revenues. For blocks, we can explain only about 35 percent of the

variation. Both population size (negative) and SC/ST population (positive) are

significant (Table 38). Overall, there is an equalizing feature in the system.

157. For districts, SC/ST population and the literacy rate variables are significant with

directions of effect that are consistent with equalization. Again, however, we find that at

the margin, higher income districts receive more in per capita central transfers. Over 80

percent of the variation can be explained.

158. State Grants and Schemes. The regression results for per capita state government

transfers are reported in Table 39. For blocks, the variation would appear to be random,

except for a number of significant district effects. The explanation for why some blocks

receive more state government transfers may be driven more by political and

management factors than by the makeup of the population. For districts, we see some

conflicting equalization results. Literacy is positively correlated with per capita state

transfers, but a larger female population is positively related to state grants and per capita

GDP is negative.

159. Total Grants and Transfers. The last question is this all plays out in terms of the

distribution of total transfers from higher level governments. The results for districts and

blocks for per capita total transfers are shown in Table 40. The only significant

determinant of inter-district variations in per capita grants and transfers is the share of

SC/ST population, a result that is consistent with the equalization hypothesis. We find

essentially the same result for blocks, but note the much greater equalizing effect in the

case of districts. Overall, we find that the regression explains less of the variation for

blocks (48 percent) and districts (61 percent) than for GPs.

Financial Condition

160. The fiscal balance problem does not appear to be restricted to gram panchayats.

This is an unexpected finding since districts and blocks function more as spending agents

of the state than as autonomous local governments. As reported in Table 41, most district

governments closed the years 2003, 2004 and 2005 in a deficit position40

. The size of the

deficits, relative to total revenues of the district, were larger than in the case of gram

panchayats, as were the closing balances. The story seems to be much the same as for the

GP, i.e., districts carry large balances, presumably to pre-fund expenditures. We could

find only one district with a closing balance as small as 5 percent of total expenditures.

40

We use the pro forma in Box 3 to measure the deficit.

Page 48: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

44

161. The financial position of blocks showed a great deal of variation. About half

incurred deficits, by our definition, and the amounts were in the range of 30 percent of

revenues. However, blocks carried balances that were substantially greater than that for

gram panchayats. The balances carried appear to be more than adequate to cover the

deficits. In general, the size of the deficit chosen is directly related to the size of the

opening balance that is carried into the fiscal year (Table 42). Again, the story seems to

be one of using allocations from the previous year to fund expenditures.

Summary

162. Though districts and blocks are more spending agents of the state and central

governments than local self-governments, they do exhibit variation in their spending and

financing patterns. Together, they account for a considerably greater share of

government expenditures than do gram panchayats.

163. The variations across the block and district levels show many of the same

characteristics that were found for gram panchayats. Per capita spending is higher in

blocks with smaller populations and in both blocks and districts where there is a heavier

concentration of SC/ST population. These expenditures are financed primarily by

intergovernmental transfers (97 percent) and there is no significant pattern of cost

recovery through fees and charges.

164. Centrally sponsored schemes are distributed among districts and blocks on an

equalizing basis, assuming that the percent of SC/ST population is an appropriate way to

measure equalization. There is less of a pattern of equalization in the distribution of per

capita state government assistance.

165. About half of all block level governments and nearly all districts show a shortfall

between recurrent revenues and annual expenditures. These gaps appear to be easily

covered by drawing on cash balances. As in the case of gram panchayats, the practice

seems to be one of pre-funding the budgets by permitting districts and blocks to carry

large balances.

Page 49: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

45

8. STATE GOVERNMENT AND FISCAL

DECENTRALIZATION

166. From the above discussion, one can draw the conclusion that the fiscal system in

West Bengal is heavily dominated by the state government. By itself the state accounts

for 76 percent of direct expenditures, and raises 96 percent of all revenues. A recent

analysis by Oommen (2006) estimates that the local government expenditure share in

West Bengal is only about one-half of the national average.

167. It is also the case that the state government in West Bengal has chosen to limit the

amount of fiscal discretion given to its local units, so by this measure we also can

characterize West Bengal as a very centralized fiscal system:

Gram panchayats have some power to tax, but the tax rates and the legal

tax base are determined by the state government. Local governments have

discretion mostly in terms of how they administer the tax.

To a large extent, expenditures are dictated by the conditions associated

with receipt of state and central grants and transfers. The untied amounts

received by local governments are limited.

The vertical share of local governments -- their “entitlement” -- is

determined by the central and state governments, annually and in an ad

hoc way. This limits possibilities for efficient fiscal planning by local

governments.

168. How could the state begin to move this situation toward fiscal decentralization?

The PRIs in West Bengal might be “upgraded” in two ways: (a) by increasing the size of

their expenditure budgets, and (b) by giving them more discretion to make fiscal

decisions. The first of these paths will be costly, if an enhancement in the scope and

quality of public services is envisioned, and if a corresponding net increase in local

government funding is given. The second would also imply new costs in the form of

investments to upgrade the capacity of local governments and the transition costs

necessary to get PRIs “on the learning curve”. The transition cost might include a short-

term outlay to cover temporary service level shortfalls. One way or another, fiscal

decentralization will imply a drain on the state budget.

169. The two avenues open to the state government to find the necessary resources to

finance decentralization are: an increase in state government tax revenue, and a

redirection of existing funds.

Page 50: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

46

State Taxation

170. The state could enact a new tax or a general tax increase with revenues dedicated

to the PRIs. For example, a specified amount could be dedicated to fund an increased

amount of unconditional grants. Though not explicitly stated, something similar to this

was implied by the SFC recommendation for a 16 percent share in the state taxes

dedicated to revenue sharing with local governments.

171. Whether the resources necessary to finance fiscal decentralization can be found

will depend in part on whether the economy of West Bengal has grown fast enough to

generate the necessary surplus or fiscal space. Though West Bengal is a poor state in

terms of average per capita GDP, it has grown well above the all-India rate over the past

decade, thanks in large to robust growth in the agricultural sector (CMIE, 2006).

172. There also would seem to be room for a tax increase. West Bengal’s rate of

revenue mobilization is low by comparison with other states, and has declined over the

1998-2004 period. A number of research studies have reached this conclusion

(Government of India, 2004; Coondoo, et. al., 2005, The World Bank, 2005a). West

Bengal’s relatively weak tax performance is longstanding (Jha, et. al., 1999).

173. One could also make the case that the West Bengal State Government is not

presently in a good place to finance such an upgrading. The budget situation is still

emerging from a significant imbalance. Over the past decade, West Bengal’s fiscal

position was one of the weakest in the country (Rajmal, 2006; Purfield, 2004,

Government of India, 2004). Though the fiscal deficit is down from its 9 percent level in

2000, even the projected 2007 deficit level of 5 percent of GDP presents a significant

hurdle to overcome. Some significant and perhaps painful discretionary measures will

need to be taken to reduce this deficit. As Rajmal (2006) has pointed out, the state

government may have limited discretion to address the issue. Between 2002 and 2004,

interest payments and pension payments together were equivalent in amount to about 70

percent of revenue receipts. Moreover, there are significant subsidy programs that are

not easily cut back or withdrawn. Finally, there is the commitment to a large wage bill

for state government employees and the possibility of another fiscal hit by the next pay

commission.41

Redirection of Existing Funds

174. Redirection as a strategy would involve shifting resources from other programs

toward the support of local governments. The issue here is less about funding new

monies than it is about rearranging priorities.42

41

One research report estimates that the next (sixth) pay commission has the potential to create more stress

on state budgets than did the fifth pay commission. Crisil (2006) estimates an impact of as much as 3

percent of state GSP by 2011, an amount that is well above the 2.6 of the previous commission and above

the 1 percent targeted by the Twelfth Finance commission. 42

We do not consider the alternative of replacing centrally sponsored schemes with state assistance

programs. For a discussion, see Rajamaram (2001).

Page 51: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

47

175. Redirection may be a very difficult strategy to implement. The budget speech of

2006-2007 (Government of West Bengal, 2006) makes the case that there are many other

important and high priority claims on budgetary resources that will constrain any budget

redirection:

debt burden relief is a high priority,

rural unemployment is a major issue to be addressed, and

many social and physical infrastructure needs are pressing.

176. Fiscal decentralization certainly would address the last two items on this list. The

question at hand, however, is whether state government vertical programs would do a

better job of service delivery. If so, redirection would not be a good strategy choice.

Those who push hard for more decentralization will argue that some better balance

between state and local government involvement will give a better result. There does not

appear to be any hard evidence to support one position or the other.

177. Certainly the state government has not disowned the strategy of fiscal

decentralization. The 2006-2007 budget speech underlines the need to strengthen

panchayats, but no concrete, immediate plan is offered. An obvious choice is to redirect

some of the expenditures made by state line agencies toward the gram panchayats.

Though this “offloading” strategy would impose no revenue cost on the state, it would

raise other questions such as the capacity of the local governments to absorb the

additional responsibility and whether this offloading would be accompanied by

restrictions as to how the money should be spent. Otherwise, per capita expenditures of

the local governments would be increased but there might not be an improvement in

service levels or even budgetary discretion.

The Granting of More Fiscal Discretion

178. Another part of the reform package to address fiscal decentralization could be to

increase the spending and tax discretion of local governments, particularly gram

panchayats. This may be done in two ways. First, the state government could “untie” its

grants and schemes. This has already been done for the Rs 278 crore SFC grant. This

model could be extended to the salary grant which at present is no more than a cost

reimbursement to local governments for state-determined posts and compensation. An

unconditional grant would simply award the funds to local governments on a formula

basis and allow them to decide between salary and non salary expenditures. Under this

scenario, a local government might decide to move funds from teachers (where salaries

might be deemed too high) to health professionals (where they might be deemed too

low). In fact, all state grants and schemes might be converted to an unconditional status.

This strategy is considered in the next section of this report.

179. The unconditional grant route is not without risk. This strategy will impose a cost

on the state, in terms of the direction over public investment that it will give up. It will

carry a risk in that the money might not be spent “wisely” and the result may be

Page 52: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

48

deterioration in service levels and a loss in confidence on the part of taxpayers. If some

gram panchayats fell into a pattern of fiscal indiscipline, it would be left to the state to

cover this.

Page 53: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

49

9. REFORM OPTIONS AND EVALUATION

180. As the government of West Bengal moves toward the goals of better service

delivery and more local self governance laid down in the Constitutional amendments, it

will need to continuously rethink the structure of its intergovernmental fiscal system.

The work of the Third State Finance Commission will be an appropriate opportunity to

begin such a rethinking. In this regard, it is important to note that reform choices that

would lead to a functioning third tier of government in West Bengal are not being held

hostage by central laws and regulations. To the contrary, the Constitution strongly

endorses fiscal decentralization. The wherewithal to implement changes in the system is

clearly in the hands of the state government.

181. In the discussion below, we suggest and evaluate a number of reform directions

that are in step with the intent in the Constitutional amendments. Some are consistent

with ideas that have been offered by the first two State Finance Commissions, though in

each case we take a different approach than did the SFC. Some are more far-reaching,

and would require major structural changes. However, bringing some less feasible

options to the table might be a useful way to enrich the debate about fiscal

decentralization in West Bengal. Some other reform options hold promise but are not

fully developed here because they involve changes in the method of financing urban local

governments, which is a subject that this paper does not directly address.

182. We evaluate three general directions for reform: (a) a change in the structure of

local government, (b) enhanced expenditure assignment and fiscal autonomy for gram

panchayats, and (c) a revamped system of state government transfers.

Decide on an Optimal Tier for Local Self Government

183. The Constitutional amendments call for a third tier of government where voters

can have both a voice in the decision about the quality of local public services that they

will receive, and a responsibility for directly financing some of these services. While the

intent is to involve the PRI as autonomous local governments there is no pronouncement

in the amendments about the balance among the three tiers of PRI in terms of the degree

of fiscal autonomy that they should be given. The costs and benefits of the various

options should be weighed. The state government may retain the present hierarchical

arrangement, or move the focus to gram panchayats (or to either of the other two levels).

The principal instruments for shifting the emphasis from one level to the other are

revenue assignment, expenditure assignment, and the distribution of intergovernmental

transfers. All of these can be changed at the discretion of the state government. So, it

Page 54: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

50

falls to the state government to decide whether and how the roles and relative importance

of the three levels of PRI ought to be changed.

184. The right structure of local government in West Bengal depends on the goals that

government most wants to accomplish. In terms of capturing the economic efficiency

benefits of decentralization (which requires moving government decisions closer to the

people), the gram panchayat is the best candidate for autonomous local government. It is

small enough to force elected leaders to pay attention to the preferences of voters, and

this relatively small size gives the local population the sense that their vote will matter.

In West Bengal, the average population size of the gram panchayat is 14,254 versus

181,000 for blocks and 4.4 million for districts. The gram panchayats in West Bengal are

about three times larger than the all-India average, and are not small by world standards

for local governments (See Box 4). Unlike the case in many Indian States, the gram

panchayats in West Bengal may be small enough to move government close to the people

but large enough to avoid some of the diseconomies of small size, and the efficiency

losses due to spillover effects.

Box 4

Gram Panchayats in India

The average population size of a gram panchayat in West Bengal is not small,

either relative to that in other states in India or relative to many other countries. See the

comparison below.

Average Population of Total Population

Local Governments (in millions)a

All India (gram pachayats) 4,386 1028.6

West Bengal State 14,254 80.2

Karnataka 8,872 52.8

Kerala 26,793 31.8

United Kingdom 126,128 59.7

Denmark 18,760 5.4

Poland 15,561 38.5

Finland 10,870 5.2

Spain 4,930 43.1

Hungary 3,242 10.1

a

Source: Non-India data from Fox and Gurley (2006). India results are author estimates based on data

from various services.

Page 55: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

51

185. An argument that favors the choice of the gram panchayat as the best candidate

for local government is that it is a longstanding choice of many analysts and decision

makers. In fact, under the present system, the gram panchayats already have some fiscal

independence. Budgets are approved by the elected local councils, rather than by a

higher level government, and this is perhaps the most essential element of fiscal

autonomy. GPs have some budget discretion on the expenditure side, but they do not

have the power to hire, fire, or determine the compensation rates of their employees.

Moreover, they are saddled with a significant number of budget mandates in that most of

the intergovernmental transfers that they receive are conditional upon a particular use of

the funds. Gram panchayats receive little by way of untied grants43

. The gram

panchayats also have some independent powers to raise revenues through taxation, as

well as through user charges and fees. However, gram panchayats do not have discretion

in setting the tax rate or determining the tax base. Such discretion will be important if the

GP is to become a focal point for local self government. Districts and blocks are saddled

with the same restrictions on the expenditure side of their budgets, and neither has taxing

power. Some have argued that districts and blocks behave more like spending agents of

the state than like autonomous local governments.

186. On balance, a strong case can be made on efficiency grounds for the gram

panchayats as the principal unit of local government. However, economic efficiency is

not the only criteria that may be used in choosing an optimal size local government, and

other choice criteria may point to advantages of emphasizing the block or district level as

an autonomous local government. Four advantages of larger local governments would

seem particularly important.

187. First, both districts and blocks are large enough to capture the cost savings from

economies of scale in the delivery of services. For many public services, gram

panchayats may not be large enough to take advantage of size economies. This is

especially the case for services that require large capital costs, because there is not an

adequate population over which to spread these costs. To allow delivery of such services

by gram panchayats, in such cases, might be to invite cost increases, and perhaps a lower

quality of public services. However, the methods of service delivery for many types of

rural service (e.g., water supply, sanitation) do not require the level of capital investment

that is the case in urban areas.44

Unfortunately, there is little evidence on size economies

in the delivery of local public services in rural areas in LDCs and the results of studies for

industrialized countries likely are not relevant45

. Still, it seems reasonable to believe that

consolidation to the block level would eliminate some duplication and reduce

administrative costs.

43

The general purpose grants that they receive -- untied grants and State Finance Commission grants --

accounted for less than one percent of their revenue in the years studied for this report. 44

For a discussion of this aspect of service delivery by rural local governments in South Africa, see

Schroeder (2003). 45

For a review of the available evidence, see Fox and Gurley (2006).

Page 56: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

52

188. Second, block and district governments have a larger benefit zone and therefore

can internalize spillover effects from certain public services better than can gram

panchayats. Examples are environmental and transportation services. This suggests that

such services should be delivered by districts, blocks, or by the State government. There

is an alternative to shifting assignment of such functions to a higher level government. A

conditional grant could be given to gram panchayats to stimulate their spending on

functions with spillover benefits. However, this can be an expensive way to deal with the

externality issue. Moreover, there is the issue of estimating the expenditure response of a

local government to a particular level of conditional grant funding, and the high cost of

effectively monitoring local compliance with the conditions. So, for a number of

important services, delivery by gram panchayats is not justified, even on efficiency

grounds.

189. Third, many gram panchayats have not shown themselves to have good capacity

to deliver services. Districts and blocks are larger, and likely could offer more

specialization in work assignments, and might be able to recruit a more skilled

managerial staff.

190. Fourth, there are 3,354 gram panchayats in West Bengal, and this is an unwieldy

number to control from the state government level. Even in a decentralized government

system, there is need for such controls. The necessary controls might involve, for

example, audit, enforced accounting standards, civil service rules, grant distribution

formulae, following up on compliance with mandates and tax limitations, etc. The 341

block level governments, or the present hierarchical arrangement, would seem a better

choice for a workable structure of local government, when the span of control issue is

considered.

191. There is no easy answer to this question. There has long been a debate about the

optimal size government, and the debate has not led to the conclusion that any one

population size is “best”. The optimal size government depends on what objective one

wants to emphasize. If the spirit of the Constitutional amendments is read as calling for

more emphasis on the economic efficiency objective of fiscal decentralization, the case is

strong to upgrade the role of the gram panchayat and make it the primary unit of

autonomous local government.

192. If strengthening the gram panchayat as an autonomous local government turns out

to be the best choice for West Bengal, should the block and the district tiers of

government take on a different role? There are two general approaches that might be

taken in response to this question.

193. A first approach would be to create a unitary system with two levels (state

government and gram panchayat) and formally designate districts and blocks as

deconcentrated arms of the State administration. Under this scheme, gram panchayats

would be the only sub-state government unit that represented local voters.

Page 57: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

53

194. In some ways, this would not involve much change. Districts and blocks already

act like agents of the state. On the other hand, if this is to be a restructuring, it suggests

major changes in revenue and expenditure assignment, and in the degree of autonomy

assigned to gram panchayats46

. In particular, responsibility for some of the expenditures

presently made by blocks and districts (about two-thirds of total PRI expenditures) would

be either shifted downward to the gram panchayats, or in the case of services

characterized by significant scale economies or externalities, would become

deconcentrated state expenditures (vertical programs). The net impact of this approach to

decentralization would be to heighten the fiscal importance of the gram panchayats

relative to blocks and districts. In the case of services presently administered by blocks

and districts, there is not much autonomy in any case, so this solution would likely lead to

a net gain in welfare. In order to move toward this approach, the expenditure mapping

presently in place (Government of West Bengal, 2005) would need to be redone with an

increased emphasis on the gram panchayat level.

195. The main advantage of this approach is that it clarifies which PRIs are local

governments and which are state and central government implementing agents. With the

roles clarified, the stage would be set for an assignment of expenditure responsibility that

the state government felt would best match its decentralization objectives.

196. A second approach is to leave things as they are, with three levels of PRI, and to

assign functions to the up-levels according to factors such as service delivery capability,

economies of scale and the possibility of spillover effects. Certainly this would be the

least disruptive approach, and the expenditure mapping could be redone to enhance

economic efficiency by assigning more “local benefit” functions to gram panchayats. The

gram panchayats could be given increased autonomy in the areas of both taxation and

expenditure delivery, much as proposed in the case of the unitary program above.

197. The main differences in these two approaches are that in the case of the present

structure, gram panchayats will likely end up with less responsibility than under the

unitary regime, and that a hierarchical arrangement among gram, block and district

panchayats will remain in place. In short, there will continue to be less gram panchayat

participation in service delivery. Another drawback is leaving in place the likelihood of

overlapping service responsibility among three levels of PRI.

Expenditure Assignment

198. Expenditure assignment should be a priority reform concern for the State

government and for the State Finance Commission. If gram panchayats are to play a

meaningful role as local self governments, their expenditure responsibilities must be

upgraded. In 2005, GP expenditures accounted for about one-third of the PRI total, about

Rs 138 per capita ($US 3.13), and about 5.3 percent of all government expenditures. It is

not likely that gram panchayats will deliver services that will matter greatly to the local

quality of life when the amounts are so small. Nor is it likely that voters will get deeply

involved in budget decisions when the amounts involved are so small. The situation is

46

It also may suggest changes in the political structure that are beyond the reach of the state government.

Page 58: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

54

not much better for the other levels of PRI. Districts account for only about 7 percent of

government spending in the state, and blocks for only about 3.6 percent. All together, the

PRI manage about 17 percent of state and local government spending in West Bengal.

199. To move toward the type of fiscal decentralization envisioned in the Constitution,

it will be necessary for the State government to ratchet up the spending of gram

panchayats (or all PRIs) and to involve them more heavily in delivering services that

matter deeply to their constituent populations. This might be done with a strategy that

involves the state government taking three types of action (a) the assignment of increased

expenditure responsibility and fiscal autonomy to the local governments, (b) assistance in

developing an enhanced capacity of local governments to deliver these services, and (c)

provision for higher levels of funding to enable delivery of these assigned

responsibilities. The state government might look to the SFC for leadership in

developing a strategy to achieve this objective.

200. Clarify and Upgrade Expenditure Responsibility. There is need for more clarity

in the assignment of expenditure responsibilities. In theory, this is not an issue among

local governments in West Bengal, because the state has done an extensive expenditure

mapping (Government of West Bengal, 2005) that defines the sub-functional

responsibilities of each level of PRI. The mapping contains a detailed and clear

statement of how the state government believes that expenditure responsibilities ought to

be assigned among the three tiers of PRI. As is so often the case, however, practice

departs from theory and the actual division of responsibilities has lead to confusion and

overlap.

201. The even bigger problem in West Bengal is the murkiness in the division of

responsibilities between the state government and the local governments47

. The

Constitution defines a list of 29 objects of expenditure that may be either assigned to

local governments or may be concurrent responsibilities with the State government. The

State of West Bengal has chosen the concurrent route for all 29 functions, and this has led

to three problems: (a) too limited an involvement of PRIs in service delivery, (b) some

confusion as to whether the state or the local governments are responsible for certain

services, and (c) an inability at the State level to rationally determine the amount of

resources necessary for PRI to deliver assigned services at an adequate level.

202. The World Bank (2005) offers an interesting approach to resolving the

expenditure assignment issue. The argument is that for each expenditure sector, there are

five activities that are (better or worse) candidates for decentralization: policy and

standards, planning, asset creation, operation, and monitoring and evaluation. In the case

of schools, water, sanitation, and employment generation, they argue for assignment of

operational responsibility to the gram panchayat level. This would include a transfer of

functionaries to the control of the local government in order to increase the accountability

of local officials.

47

This vagueness in the assignment of expenditure responsibility is a problem throughout India. For a

discussion, see Subrahmanyam and Annamaloi (2004, p. 223-224).

Page 59: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

55

203. Neither of the first two SFCs in West Bengal have taken on the issue of

expenditure assignment in a comprehensive way. Both Commissions have argued to

increase the share of untied grants in the State budget. While this would give PRIs more

resources, and more autonomy, it would (presumably) leave in tact their expenditure

responsibilities and their discretion in making decisions about how these funds should be

used. The third SFC might consider addressing this larger issue directly, by considering

the need to upgrade the expenditure assignments of local governments. The first step

would be to determine for each of the 29 objects of expenditures, which sub-functions or

sub-activities will be assigned exclusively to rural local governments. Then it would

redo the mapping exercise to assign subfunctions of these expenditure categories to each

of the three levels of PRI. Somehow, delivery would need to be monitored in order to

ensure proper involvement by the PRI and to avoid duplication.

204. The second step would be to clarify the assignments that go with this

classification of expenditure responsibilities by sub-activity. For example, if The World

Bank (2005) model were to be followed, school operations and teachers would be shifted

to gram panchayats, and water supply and sanitation in rural areas would become a gram

panchayat function. Such changes would significantly upgrade the place of rural local

governments in public service delivery.

205. The third step would be to define a target level of spending for GPs that would be

great enough to stimulate voter interest and involvement in the process of budget making,

and at the same time would enhance the quality of services available. The target level of

spending would reflect both the minimum standards of service desired, and the fiscal

limitations faced by the state government.

206. Fiscal Autonomy. The goal of enhanced local self governance requires more than

just assigning new expenditure responsibilities to local governments. So long as the State

of West Bengal (and the Central Government) continue to dictate how the money should

be spent, local governments will not have the ability to adjust service delivery to match

citizen preferences. As noted above, if the local population thinks of their elected local

government as being little more than a spending agent of some higher level government,

they will not hold their elected local council responsible for the quality of services

delivered. Local governments must be given more autonomy to make budget decisions if

local government officials are to be accountable to their constituents. Unless this

happens, local voters/constituents will have little incentive to be involved.

207. There are a number of areas where increased autonomy might be given. First,

those officials involved in the delivery of local public services could be assigned as local

government employees. Their hiring, firing and the determination of their compensation

levels can be made local government decisions. The power of this approach is illustrated

by the case of education in Madhya Pradesh where teacher control was shifted to the

local governments (The World Bank, 2006). The PRIs were given the power to hire and

fire teachers (but not to determine wage rates). The result has been a remarkable

improvement in the rate of teacher absenteeism and an expansion in the coverage of the

school system.

Page 60: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

56

208. Second, conditionalities could be removed on the distribution of state grants to

local governments. These could become untied funds with expenditure made at the

discretion of the local governments. Whenever this reform option is proposed (in nearly

all countries), the criticism raised is that government funds will be diverted from what the

upper levels of government consider the highest priority, and that corruption and waste

will necessarily follow. The response to these observations is, first, a diversion of funds

to projects with a heavier orientation toward local benefits will almost certainly happen.

As local politicians and local voters learn about accountability, the budget will begin to

show more “local choice” investments, and a better implementation of these projects.

This is the essence of the fiscal decentralization story. In fact, the shift in the package of

service delivered would be evidence that the fiscal decentralization strategy is working.

209. Unfortunately the corruption and waste story is also probably a valid one. Gram

panchayat officials are not skilled in service delivery and local management. The books

of account may not be kept well, staff may be untrained and there is probably little by

way of skill in the area of tax administration. As local officials learn their new

responsibilities, money may not be spent as wisely as if it were in more experienced

hands. On the question of whether decentralization leads to more corruption, there is not

yet a general agreement. In the scholarly research, Brueckner (1999) finds a direct

relationship, but Fisman and Gatti (1999) find the opposite. They argue that corruption

under decentralization can be lower if both revenue raising powers and expenditure

responsibility are decentralized.

210. The spirit of the Constitutional amendments and of the recommendations of the

State Finance Commissions is that of local self government. The implication here is that,

in so far as is possible, grants should be unconditional and expenditure mandates should

be removed. Therefore, the reform goal might be to move towards elimination of

conditions associated with State government grants to GPs, in favor of unconditional

grants with a defined vertical share48

. Such a reform would be consistent with the

recommendations of both the First and the Second State Finance Commissions in West

Bengal. Both recommended a dramatic increase in untied grants to local governments.

The state has not followed this recommendation and the present level of untied state

grants is equivalent in amount to less than 2 percent of state government taxes.

211. Third, local governments could be given more independence in choosing their

level of taxation, rather than have the tax rate and the tax base determined at the state

level. This is an important part of the reform package. Local government officials could

be made more accountable to their constituents if services were financed at least partially

by taxation. In this regard, it would be important that the local government has the power

to set at least the rate of a local tax. The state could set a minimum tax rate for GPs, but

could leave open the ceiling rate. Under this arrangement, the local council will be more

responsible to the local population for the quality of the service delivered.

212. Enhanced Capacity at the GP Level. It would be self-defeating to assign new

responsibilities to GPs if they could not deliver these services in an effective way. And,

48

The vertical sharing dimension of such a grant system is discussed in detail in Bahl and Wallace (2007).

Page 61: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

57

every indication is that there are serious capacity problems at the local level. But not to

assign more responsibility to the GP because their capacity is weak is to create a self-

fulfilling prophesy. If GPs are not put on a learning curve as regards service delivery,

they will never develop the capacity to absorb more responsibility.

213. The state could take a number of steps to improve the service delivery capacity of

gram panchayats. Though this subject is beyond the scope of this work, a stylistic listing

of some possibilities that have been offered elsewhere are below:

In many gram panchayats, there is a need to increase the size of the gram

panchayat staff and upgrade the quality of the staff.

Panchayat secretaries often are not trained in the rules, procedures and

statutory provisions of the panchayats. Short training courses should be

provided (Subrahmanyam and Annamalai, 2004).

GPs should be given authority to buy services from the private sector or

contract with higher level governments in cases where they do not have

adequate capacity to deliver services. Resource pooling by several gram

panchayats for a specialized service might be considered. (World Bank,

2005).

Automation in the case of more advanced GPs, should be encouraged, at

least for record keeping purposes.

Provision should be made for annual audits of local government books of

account by external parties.

Re-assessment for purposes of local property tax should be made by

external valuers.

214. The first step to be taken here is to assess the need for training and staffing at the

GP level. The goal would be to assess the capacity of GPs to assume new responsibilities

and to design the technical assistance necessary to put this capacity in place. Second, a

transition plan should be put in place whereby the new expenditure responsibility of gram

panchayats would be passed to them when they are deemed ready. Until that time the

services, and the finances that go with these services, would be delivered by blocks and

districts. Third, a system to monitor and evaluate the performance of gram panchayats

would be put in place.

Increased Own Source Revenue

215. Much has been made of the need for gram panchayats to increase their own

source revenues (Rao and Singh, 2001). Success in this area will come from three kinds

of initiative. First, some potentially productive tax bases must be assigned to gram

Page 62: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

58

panchayats, along with the power to set the tax rate49

. There are many options for rural

local government taxation that either are now used in West Bengal or are used in other

states and might be considered in West Bengal. These include:

Land and building tax. This is the mainstay of local taxation in rural India

and in most countries. The needs in West Bengal are to remove any rate

ceiling in favor of a policy of local governments setting their own rates, and

state support for an upgrading of property tax administration.

Property transfer tax. Local governments may levy a tax against the

consideration in the transfer of property. In many countries around the world,

this is an important source of local revenue. However, administration of a

property transfer tax is beyond the reach of rural local governments. A better

route is for the local government to be allowed to set a sur-rate against the

state government stamp duty 50 . A sur-rate is preferable to a share of

collections, because it forces the local government to make a tax choice and to

be accountable to taxpayers for the expenditure of that money.

Entertainment tax. In West Bengal, the entertainment tax is actually an

intergovernmental transfer to local governments. The tax rate and base, and a

sharing rate on collections with local governments, is set by the state

government. Since most/all revenues are shared locally, the state government

has little incentive for vigorous collection efforts. The entertainment tax

might be a candidate for local taxation (or at least local rate setting). It is a

local tax in some Indian states, e.g., Rajasthan, Karnataka, and MP (though

rates are still set by the state).

Professions tax. A tax on professions, trades, and employment is levied in

several states. In at least Rajasthan, Assam, Punjab, and Bihar the tax is

administered by the panchayats. This is a kind of rudimentary income tax that

reaches those in rural areas with a greater ability to pay. Administration of the

tax is difficult, especially for rural local governments.

Land cess surcharge. State governments levy a cess against land for a

variety of purposes. In some states, panchayats are allowed to levy a

surcharge against these cesses, with the revenues returned on an origin basis.

This approach to taxation is consistent with the accountability maxim of

decentralization, so long as the panchayat sets the sur-rate.

216. Second, the capacity of states to better administer local taxes should be upgraded

so that tax effort might be increased. With respect to the property tax, a number of steps

should be taken:

The state could develop a circular of guidelines on assessment and

collections.

49

Analogous reforms should be put in place for user charges, licenses, and fees. 50

See for example, the practice in Kerala as described in Subrahmanyam and Annamalai, 2004.

Page 63: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

59

The creation of an independent valuation authority should be

considered. It should be staffed with trained values.

GP Secretaries will be trained so as to develop basic valuation

skills.

Tax mapping, showing all properties and land uses in the local

government area, should be completed.

217. The ability to improve the collection rate on other tax and non tax sources should

be strengthened. In this regard, the staff support of the panchayat secretary could be

upgraded. The collection of non tax revenues may have been pushed aside in order to

comply with the ever increasing compliance issues associated with the schemes. With

respect to the assignment of other taxes and more efficient collection of these, a number

of possibilities for improvement have been suggested:

More complete tax rolls for each levy (e.g., professions and trade

tax, entertainment tax, land cess) should be compiled and annually

updated.

Enforcement should be more vigorous and proper sanctions should

be applied. The names of delinquents might be publicly posted.

Where permitted, surcharges on state government levies should be

imposed. This allows the GP to bypass the entire administrative

process.

Where there is an organized sector, and where the GP is permitted

to levy a tax on professions and trades, tax deductions at source

should be allowed, as is done in Kerala and A.P.

218. Third, rural local governments might be given some significant incentives to

upgrade their level of tax effort. This might be done in three ways. One is to put no

restrictions on how the money can be spent. A second is to increase the taxing powers of

gram panchayats either by assigning them additional taxes or removing any tax rate

limits. The third approach is to reward tax effort through the system of transfers with a

kind of incentive grant. The programme would work by matching local collections (or

increases in local collections) with some amount of state grants. Such an approach has

been tried in both Tamil Nadu and Goa (Subrahmanyam, 2004).

Increased State Grants: Determining the Vertical Share

219. Even if gram panchayats are assigned more responsibility, and even if this

capacity is upgraded, it will come to naught unless adequate financing is provided.

Increased own source revenues are an important element of the reform, but will at best be

Page 64: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

60

only a small part of the financing needs. If local governments are to provide a

meaningful level of services, a significant increase in state grants must be provided.

Moreover, the local governments must have some discretion over how these funds are

spent; otherwise they will tilt toward being spending agents of the state rather than

autonomous local governments.

220. Both the First and Second State Finance Commissions recommended an increase

in state funding of local governments. The recommendation of the first SFC was to

institute a program for rural and urban local bodies with a vertical share equivalent to 16

percent of State government taxes. At the time of this recommendation, and at present,

there is no specified percent of State taxes that is guaranteed for revenue sharing with

local governments. The vertical share is determined annually on an ad hoc basis. It can

vary from year to year depending on the financial circumstances of the State

Government.

221. A second dimension of grant policy is whether the additional funds will be

conditional upon use for certain types of expenditures, as might be prescribed by the

State, or whether they will be untied (unconditional) funds. The SFCs have

recommended untied grants as a way of giving local governments more discretion in

establishing spending priorities. The view here is that the general spirit of the State

Finance Commission recommendations is correct. We propose and evaluate a reform

package that is similar in intent to that of the SFC, but is structurally different.

222. We begin this analysis by establishing a target level of gram panchayat

expenditures to be financed. Properly calculated, the target amount will depend on the

expenditure assignment decided upon. It also will depend upon the minimum level of

expenditures that is set by the state. As a matter of good policy, it is essential to assign

expenditure responsibility and service level targets before determining the vertical share

of transfers to be allocated51

. This follows the well-traveled principle that “finance

follows function”. The failure to follow this maxim might have been a problem with the

model developed by the earlier State Finance Commissions52

. The 16 percent proposal

for the vertical share of all local governments appears to have been more of an arbitrary

decision than one based on objective analysis.

223. It is not in the scope of work here to develop a new set of expenditure

assignments or to develop a set of minimum expenditure requirements53

. Rather, we

simply assume a target level of per capita local government expenditures in order to

demonstrate the impact of a new state grant system. We set an illustrative target for GP

minimum per capita expenditures of Rs 414 (three times the current average level of per

capita expenditures) and alternatively at Rs 276 (two times the current average level).

We make the assumption that all of this increment above the present level of per capita

51

For a discussion of the rationale for this sequencing, see Bahl and Martinez-Vazquez (2006). 52

To be fair, it almost certainly was the case that neither SFC had the resources or the data to do this

expenditure requirements analysis. 53

Expenditure assignments for various tiers of PRI under the present system are laid out in detail in

Government of West Bengal (2005).

Page 65: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

61

expenditures (Rs 138) would come from state government grants and transfers to gram

panchayats. We further assume there will be no reductions in central transfers. Note that

this analysis is portable to different expenditure targets.

224. In this first example, we propose a minimum expenditure approach to revenue

sharing where the vertical share for gram panchayats is based on a guaranteed minimum

level of spending for each GP. This might be viewed as a transition to a more traditional

formula-based system, as is described below54

. The revenue sharing rules for the

transition system -- which do not feature a formula based on socio-economic variables --

are as follows:

Each gram panchayat will be brought up to a minimum per capita

expenditure of Rs 414 (or, alternatively Rs 276 under the more

modest target).

Any gram panchayat with a present spending level that is higher

than Rs 414 (Rs 276) will be held harmless at their present level.

However, those GPs will not receive additional state grants.

225. The calculations for this hypothetical level of local government expenditures and

its financing are shown in Table 43. Reaching the target minimum expenditure level of

Rs 414 per capita would require that GP expenditures be higher than at present by Rs

15.8 billion (row 3 of column 1). The result is that the transfer from the state government

would rise to over Rs 17 billion (row 5), or to an amount equivalent to about 10.6 percent

of state government own source revenue collections (row 7). If the target was a less

ambitious doubling of minimum per capita expenditures by GP, the vertical share would

be 5.7 percent of state government tax collections (see the calculations in Column (2) of

Table 43). In either case, the amounts are well above the present level (there was no

distribution in 2005), but well below the 16 percent of state taxes recommended by the

State Finance Commission.

226. Had this program been enacted at the higher level in 2005, the majority of GPs

would have seen an increase in per capita total state grants of over 90 percent (Table 44).

As may be seen in Table 25, 591 of the 3,074 gram panchayats in the sample would

realize an increase in state aid of more than 95 percent. If the less ambitious minimum

expenditure were used, most GPs would witness an increase in per capita state grants of

80 percent or more (See Box 5).

54

There are several reasons why a government might want to transition to a new formula system rather than

do it in one “reform” year. The transition period gives the opportunity to set up a system of hold-harmless

where no local government receives less than under the previous system, and none receives too large an

increment. This minimizes the shock associated with the new system and gives some time for preparing to

absorb the phase-in of the new system where the distributive shares will change.

Page 66: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

62

Box 5

Explanatory Note on Simulation Exercise

This simulation is to show the impact of an unconditional state grant program,

where the vertical share is equal to the target amounts described in Table 24, and the

horizontal shares are according to the formula described. The data used in the simulation

are for the year 2005.

The counterfactual in this analysis is the amount of state government transfers

distributed in 2005 as unconditional grants. Note that the state did not distribute the State

Finance Commission grant in 2005, hence the comparison here is against a very low

base.1

We can say, however, that the target level in this analysis implies a vertical share

of Rs 1729 crores in 2005 under the high scenario, and Rs 938 crores under the low

scenario. The 2005 amounts for all state grants used in this baseline were equivalent to

Rs 147 cr in this baseline. Therefore, we are evaluating an increase of 1582 crore (791 in

lower case) for gram panchayats in the total grant pool.

1The State did distribute the Finance commission grants in 2006, with a vertical share of Cr 278, but data

describing the actual distributions are outside the data base available here, which is for the years 2003-

2005.

227. With respect to the horizontal distribution, we ask if the proposed minimum

expenditure system is more or less equalizing than the present system. The answer

depends on how one defines equalization. Certainly the expenditures of most gram

panchayats are dramatically increased under this approach. Moreover, the gap between

the high spending GPs (who are held harmless under this scenario) and the low spending

GPs is narrowed considerably. Many would see this as a favorable outcome and one that

is consistent wit the idea of reducing disparities.

228. On the other hand, equalization might also be defined as developing a system that

compensates GPs with low fiscal capacity or with high expenditure needs, so that they

are on an equal footing with better situated local governments. Proponents of this vision

of equalization might ask, for example, if the relative revenue shares of the more

backward GPs greater or smaller than under the present system? If the latter, the

minimum expenditure approach would not pass this version of the equalization test.

229. To compare the distribution effects of the present system with the minimum

expenditure system, we have computed the simple correlations shown in Table 45. In

column 1, we show the correlation between selected variables and the per capita

distribution of the 2005 state aid system, and in column two with the proposed minimum

expenditure system. If the percent of SC/ST population is the barometer for poverty, the

Page 67: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

63

proposed minimum expenditure system is no more equalizing than the present system.

Neither shows a significant correlation with the percent of SC/ST population.

230. What we may conclude here is that a minimum guarantee program will eliminate

low spending gram panchayats. However, this system will not favor poorer gram

panchayats, over those that are less poor, with larger per capita allocations. Another

disadvantage of the minimum expenditure approach is that it gives local governments no

incentive for revenue mobilization.

A Formula Approach.

Increased, Untied Grants: A Formula Distribution

231. The analysis above describes a program with a guaranteed minimum allocation

and with a hold harmless provision to protect any gram panchayat from losing revenues

at the time of the introduction of the new system. Otherwise, it has not built-in features

that would enable it to address specific issues, such as equalization or allocating funds

more heavily to gram panchayats with a particular population make-up.

232. An alternative approach or perhaps the second step in the transition would be to

adopt a new formula-based system but with the new vertical share maintained. In this

section, we analyze the impact of one version of a formula distribution with the vertical

share based on an entitlement of 5.7 percent of state government own source revenues.

The question becomes one of settling on a formula that fits the goals of the state towards

its rural local governments. The SFCs have suggested an objective formula, which is

reported to have been mostly adopted by the State government for distribution under its

present grant program. There are two ways in which the formula distribution among GPs

might be improved over this system. First, it could be made simpler. Second, the

revenue mobilization incentive might be made more effective.

233. There is no single “best” formula for distribution of a grant. The allocation

formula chosen should be driven by the goals that the State government most wants to

accomplish with its system of grants. There would seem to be three likely candidates for

the appropriate goals:55

ensuring a resource flow that would allow an adequate (minimum) level of

local public services to be delivered,

equalizing for differences in expenditure needs and fiscal capacity, and

providing an incentive for revenue mobilization.

Moreover, the choice of a formula should also be influenced by acceptability at the local

level, and by transparency. Both of these considerations would seem to argue for a less

complex formula. Finally, any new formula must be politically acceptable, a

consideration that will significantly constrain the policy choices.

55

See also the discussion in Singh and Srnivasan (2006, p. 349).

Page 68: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

64

234. Note that some of the goals outlined above reinforce one another, but others may

conflict. For example, the goals of equalization and ensuring a minimum level of

services in all GP areas probably are reinforcing. The revenue mobilization goal,

however, may draw resources away from poorer jurisdictions and reduce the equalization

emphasis of the formula. Likewise, the minimum service level objective may conflict

with the goal of formula simplicity. Finally, any proposed change will produce winners

and losers, even if only in relative terms, and therefore will have political opponents.

235. Deciding on a new formula is no easy matter. In the end, it will come down to

weighing the balance between equalization and investing in GPs with greater immediate

growth potential, and to the outcome of a political bargaining process that always plays a

major role in formula determination. The State should begin with a clear statement of the

objectives to be accomplished, and design a formula that best matches these objectives.

Then it should move on to the art of political compromise. The casual search for

formula variables based on data availability and guesswork about what they might mean,

should be avoided.

236. There are many possible formula distributions that might be considered. The

proposal we offer here is for purposes of illustration, but it does suggest how a new

system might be developed. Developing such a formula involves four considerations.

237. Eligibility. If the GP is chosen as the primary unit of autonomous local

government, State government grants in aid could be allocated directly to gram

panchayats, bypassing the districts and blocks. Under this method, districts and blocks

would be part of the vertical programs of the state. They might have responsibility for

monitoring the performance of the gram panchayats, but they would not participate in the

grant system as local governments. This is the approach we take in this example.

238. Vertical Sharing Pool. The vertical sharing pool would be established as 5.7

percent of State government own source revenues. Of this total amount of state grants,

approximately 75 percent would be distributed by general formula, and 25 percent would

be distributed from an incentive fund for local revenue mobilization. The state would

commit to full distribution of the entitlement in a timely matter. All funds would be

untied.

239. General Fund Distribution. The general fund (75 percent of the total) would be

distributed by a formula with equal weights for two variables: population size and SC/ST

population. The first element of this formula would recognize general expenditure needs

while the second would recognize the special needs of more backward GPs and would

add an equalization component. Data used to make this allocation would be drawn from

the census. This approach is transparent, easy to understand, and is objective.

240. Revenue Mobilization Component. Of the vertical share for State grants (5.7

percent of State government own source revenue), 25 percent (1.44 percent of State

government own source revenue) would be allocated to a fund that would be used as an

Page 69: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

65

incentive to encourage revenue mobilization by local governments. The distribution of

the revenue mobilization sharing pool among GPs would be 50 percent according to the

per capita amount of tax and non tax revenue collections in the preceding year, and 50

percent according to the increase over the preceding year.

241. Ideally, the distribution would be based on an index of tax effort, i.e., a measure

that makes allowance for one GP having a greater capacity to tax than another. (Such an

index is estimated and reported above.) But these indexes are difficult to use and to

defend, so we resort here to a shorthand measure. The inclusion of per capita tax

collections rewards those who make a greater effort, irrespective of their capacity to tax,

and provides an incentive to maintain that effort. The inclusion of the increase in per

capita tax collections rewards those GPs who respond to the incentive by raising their

efforts at revenue mobilization.

242. Minimum Guarantee. A constraint would be placed on the distribution of this

revenue-sharing pool. No gram panchayat would receive an amount less than Rs 276 per

capita. This level would be taken to represent the guaranteed minimum level of support

for per capita expenditures. If the minimum was not attained after distribution of the

general pool and revenue mobilization components, the general fund pool would be

reduced to ensure that the minimum per capita expenditure supported reached Rs 276.

The maximum that any GP could receive is Rs 1500.

243. Simulation Results. We have simulated the distribution of the full system--

general grant, revenue mobilization, and minimum expenditure for GPs --, with the

results shown in Tables 46-48.

244. An important feature of this proposal is that there are no “losers” among the gram

panchayats. No local government would receive less than it presently receives because

the total vertical share is ratcheted up from 1 percent to 5.7 percent of State government

own source revenue, and because a minimum guarantee is put in place.

245. The “fully phased in system” would give a different distributional result than the

minimum expenditure approach simulated above in that it includes the general

component, the revenue mobilization component and the minimum expenditure

component. We have simulated the distribution according to this formula system across

all gram panchayats for which we have data. Less than 2 percent of the GPs would

receive an increase in per capita grants of less than 10 percent. About 80 percent of the

GPs will see an increase in per capita state grants of 50 percent or more by comparison

with the current system (Table 46). The per capita distribution of the general fund

component is similar for small and large GPs (Table 47) but the revenue mobilization

component provides more grants per capita to the smaller GPs. The implication here, that

smaller gram panchayats have been more active in revenue mobilization, is surprising.

246. This formula system has several features that fit with the goal of stimulating the

involvement of GPs in service delivery. First, the base of the proposed state transfer

system would be more elastic, i.e., the vertical pool will automatically increase with tax

Page 70: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

66

collections. The growth in tax collections in recent years in West Bengal has been

robust. Second, the new system would be relatively simple, with only a two factor

formula and a guaranteed minimum expenditure level. It would give government the

capacity to periodically upgrade the minimum per capita expenditure guarantee, or to

increase the weight of the equalization component, in a simple way.

247. Third, the proposed system would have an equalizing component. We estimate

the relationship between selected measures of equalization and the new grant and report

the results in Table 48. The formula system does not favor gram panchayats with a

higher proportion of SC/ST population, hence is no more equalizing than the present

system. Both, however, favor less populated GPs. The literacy rate, which may be an

indicator of relative wealth in a GP, is positively correlated with state government

intergovernmental transfers under the current system but is unrelated under the proposed

system. What we can conclude here is that it will probably take a significant movement

away from the revenue mobilization incentive to develop a formula with a strong

equalization component.

248. Finally, the proposed system has a revenue stimulation package that is large

enough to provide a significant incentive. Based on the results of this simulation we

show a wide disparity in the amounts received for achieving higher levels of revenue

mobilization. On average, a Rs 10 per capita higher level of revenue mobilization is

associated with a Rs 3 higher level of grants received.

249. There are major disadvantages to this proposal. First, about 3 percent of gram

panchayats do not gain from this scheme compared with the present system, and there are

wide variations in the increases received by various GPs. One would need to understand

this pattern and any anomalies that might be hidden here. Second, we have all of the

necessary data for only 2,098 gram panchayats, but any new grant system would have to

cover all 3,324 of the gram panchayats.56

Third, the census data that populate this

formula are available only every ten years. Fourth, there is a question about whether

some gram panchayats could absorb the very large increases in resources that they would

see under this new system. Fifth, exclusion of blocks and districts from this program

presupposes that the expenditure assignments of GPs are most in need of increased

emphasis. Finally, no parallel program for upgrading the finances of urban local bodies

is offered here.

56

SC/ST population is the most limiting factor in terms of data availability.

Page 71: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

67

10. FINANCING THE FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION

PROGRAM

250. Where would the West Bengal State government find the additional funds to

cover such a program? Based on 2005 levels, the gap to be financed is equivalent to

about Rs 16 billion under the high scenario, and Rs 8 billion under the low scenario.

There are several possibilities for raising these additional funds, six of which are

discussed below:

251. The government could encourage (require) GPs to generate more own source

revenue. If this strategy were successful, it could reduce the amount of state grants

necessary to reach the target level of expenditures. However, the revenue potential of

this option may not be very great. The average level of GP own source revenue is about

Rs 8 per capita. If this were increased by 50 percent, the result would be an additional Rs

201 million. This would be equivalent to about 1.2 percent of the Rs 16 billion gap to be

covered under the high scenario and 2.5 percent under the lower scenario. Certainly this

does not cover a major share of the cost of this fiscal decentralization program, but it

does significantly increase the PRI contribution to rural local government financing, and

so is well in step with the goals of the constitutional amendments. A good argument can

be made that this is an essential part of the reform program.

252. A second scenario is to assign additional taxing powers to urban local bodies, and

shift a commensurate amount of the distributable grant pool from urban local

governments to gram panchayats. In 2005, urban local bodies in West Bengal received

Rs 698 million in state grants. If Rs 349 million (50 percent of this amount) was

redirected to gram panchayats, it would cover about 1.6 percent of the Rs 16 billion

required under the scenario of a threefold increase and 3 percent in the case of a twofold

increase. Urban governments might make up for this Rs 349 million revenue reduction

by increasing property and land taxes and the entertainment tax, if such powers for

making tax increases were granted to them57

. This reform is in the right policy direction

in that it moves municipalities and municipal corporations toward local self governance,

but does not go very far toward covering the necessary funding for PRI upgrading.

Moreover, it could exacerbate the financing problems of urban local bodies, which are

already acute, and would have significant political costs.58

57

The revenue potential of urban local bodies in India is significant, and they are less prominent in public

financing than is the case in many large countries. For a review of the fiscal performance and potential of

selected urban local bodies, see World Bank (2004). For a discussion about organizing a fiscal package for

urban local bodies, see Mathur (2001, Chapter 5). 58

For a discussion of urban government financial condition in India, see Mathur (2006).

Page 72: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

68

253. The state government could increase its tax effort and earmark this additional

amount to the GPs. If the State government increased taxes by one percent of GSP, it

would raise an amount equivalent to 95 percent of the needed revenue for the high

scenario case and nearly twice that needed for the low scenario case.59

254. Certainly there is tax space in West Bengal. Own source revenues in the State

were about 4.26 percent of GSP in the 2000-2003 period, and this ratio has declined since

the 1993-1996 period (Government of India, 2004). As the Twelfth Finance Commission

reports (Government of India, 2004, p. 44), this ratio increased in most Indian states. The

policy question to be considered here is whether fiscal decentralization would be a

priority expenditure, even if tax effort were to be increased. West Bengal is one of the

most heavily indebted states, and in the 2000-2003 period, over 35 percent of revenue

receipts were allocated to interest payments.

255. Part of the necessary funding for a decentralization program could be covered by

a reallocation of expenditure responsibility and revenue receipts to the gram panchayat

level. For example, if 20 percent of district and block responsibilities were allocated to

the gram panchayats, and if the supporting revenues followed this reallocation, the

additional amounts would cover about 17 percent of the financing necessary for the high

scenario program and 33 percent for the low scenario program. There would be no net

cost to the state if this were done, but neither would there be an increase in the vertical

share of the PRI sector. This would be simply a reallocation of expenditure

responsibilities to gram panchayats. A good argument can be made that this is an

essential part of the reform program.

256. There is a fine line between the offloading of expenditure responsibilities by a

higher level government and the reassignment of expenditure responsibilities to lower

level governments. In some countries, the offloading has come without funding and is a

not too veiled shifting of the deficit.60

What we propose here is a reassignment that would

be accompanied by full funding, probably in the form of central or state transfers.

257. Funds could be directed away from state vertical programs to the untied grant

pool for gram panchayats. This would imply that gram panchayats would assume

responsibility for certain programs that are now delivered as state vertical programs. This

strategy would not amount to a net increase in funding of local governments, or a drain

on the state budget. Basically, it would be an offloading of expenditure responsibilities

from the state to the local governments. However, it would shift the locus of expenditure

responsibilities from the state government to the rural local governments, and in that

sense would be consistent with a fiscal decentralization strategy. It would differ from the

strategy outlined immediately above in that it would make the money available on an

59

This is based on data from the India Economic Survey, 2004-05 that lists West Bengal state domestic

product at Rs173,674 crore (http://indiabudget.nic.in/es2005-06/esmain.htm, Table 17). 60

An interesting case is Russia, where there was a significant “offloading” of expenditure responsibilities

by the federal government. These responsibilities included capital investment, social welfare, and price

subsidies for social goods. The funding for the offloading was to be a combination of privatization and

subnational government budgets (Martinez-Vazquez, Timofeev, and Boex, 2006, chapter 4).

Page 73: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

69

unconditional basis and the gram panchayats could move the expenditures toward what it

considers higher priority areas.

258. In order to make an estimate of the extent to which this form of redirection would

contribute to the Rs 16 billion target, it would be necessary first to do the detailed work

on expenditure assignment. It seems clear, however, that a noticeable part of the gap

could be covered in this fashion.

259. The government might find external assistance to support the state budget during

the period of transition to a decentralized structure. There are a number of issues here.

First, all gram panchayats will not be prepared to assume all responsibilities in the reform

year. A period of training and other capacity building activities will be required. Even

when responsibilities are decentralized, there is a possibility of service breakdowns in the

“hand-off” years, therefore a contingency fund will need to be put in place. The

contingency fund and the capacity building could be candidates for external support.

260. Second, the enhancement of the own source revenue capabilities of local

governments will take time and technical assistance from the state level. It may take a

period of years before the new, higher levels of revenue can be reached. External support

might be sought to backfill during the transition.

261. Third, the redirection strategy cannot be accomplished quickly. This involves

moving some functions and functionaries from the state, district, and block levels to the

gram panchayat level. To minimize the chance of a service level breakdown, this

redirection will need to be phased in, perhaps over a five-year period. Even then, a

contingency fund may be required.

262. Fourth, it seems clear that some form of tax support will be required to finance the

increase in state transfers implied by this program. Even if the government were to

commit to this, it would take a period of years to reach the target. External financing

could cover the gap in the interim.

Page 74: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

70

Annex

Page 75: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

71

Annex

Table A-1

Matrix of Simple Correlation Coefficients:

Blocks a

POP SC/ST FP LR MW

Population (POP) ---

Percent of SC/ST

Population

(SC/ST)

.0762*

(2142)

---

Percent of Female

Population (FP)

.1328*

(2463)

-.2221

(2142)

---

Literacy Rate

(LR)

.1333*

(2456)

-.2052*

(2142)

-.0330

(2456)

---

Percent of

Marginal Workers

(MW)

.2425*

(2142)

0.1729*

(2142)

.0906

(2456)

-.0950

(2456)

---

Percent of

Agricultural Labor

(AL)

-0.020

(2453)

.2546*

(2139)

.0321

(2453)

-.2876*

(2453)

0.247*

(2454)

a>

* denotes significance at .05 level. The number in parenthesis is sample size.

Table A-2

Matrix of Simple Correlation Coefficients:

Districts a

POP SC/ST FP LR

Population (POP) ---

Percent of SC/ST

Population

(SC/ST)

-0.4492

17

---

Percent of Female

Population (FP)

-0.2826

17

0.3316

17

---

Literacy Rate

(LR)

0.3701

17

-0.2750

17

-0.2054

17

---

Page 76: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

72

Per Capita GSP 0.181

15

-0.515*

15

-0.088

15

0.832*

15

a>

* denotes significance at .05 level. Number in parenthesis is sample size.

Annex Table A-3

Matrix of Simple Correlation Coefficients:

Gram Panchayats a

POP SC/ST FP LR MW

Population (POP) ---

Percent of SC/ST

Population

(SC/ST)

-0.0649*

2100

---

Percent of Female

Population (FP)

-0.1505*

2409

-0.0320

(2100)

---

Literacy Rate

(LR)

-0.1384*

2456

-1969*

(2100)

-.0330

(2456)

---

Percent of

Marginal Workers

(MW)

-0.2408*

2456

0.1658*

2100

.0906

(2456)

-.0950

(2456)

---

Percent of

Agricultural Labor

(AL)

-0.0287

2453

0.2503*

2099

.0321

(2453)

-.2876*

(2453)

0.247*

(2454)

a>

* denotes significance at .05 level. number in parenthesis is sample size.

Page 77: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

73

Figure 1

Government Structure in West Bengal

a Percent of total population

b Not including 3 notified areas

State Government

18 Districts 6 Municipal corporations

117 Municipalitiesb

341 Samitis

3,324 Gram

Panchayats

Urban (28)a

Rural (72)a

Page 78: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

74

Figure 2

Per Capita GDP and Per Capita PRI Expenditures:

By District

0

200

400

600

800

1000

1200

1400

1600

1800

UTTA

R D

INAJP

UR

KOCH B

IHAR

BIRBHUM

PURULI

A

MURSHID

ABAD

NORTH

TW

ENTY

FOUR P

ARGAN

AS

DAK

SHIN

DIN

AJPUR

MALD

AH

JALP

AIG

URI

BANKU

RA

SOUTH

TW

ENTY F

OUR P

ARGANAS

NAD

IA

DAR

JILI

NG

HUGLI

HAO

RA

District

Pe

r C

ap

ita

Ru

pe

e A

mo

un

t

Per Capita Gross State Product

Per Capita Expenditures

Page 79: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

75

Figure 3

Distribution: per capita expenditure

0

100

200

300

400

500

600

700

20 60 100 140 180 220 260 300 340 380 420 460 500

per capita expenditure

freq

uen

cy

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

cu

mu

lati

ve %

Frequency cumulative %

Page 80: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

76

Table 1

Distribution of Public Finances Among Levels of Government in West Bengal: 2005

Percent of Total

Expenditure

Percent of Own

Revenues

Percent of

Populationa

Exhibit: Per

Capita

Expenditures

State

Government

75.8 95.8 100 1218.2

Urban Local

Governments

7.89 3.7 28.0 452.5

Rural Local

Governments

16.26 0.5 72.0 138.4

Of which

Districts

45.0 41.8 155.8

Blocks 21.9 14.2 94.8

Gram

Panchayat

33.1 44.0 137.8

a Total population in Kolkata Metropolitan Area is 14.96 million in 2001; of which 88.4 percent is urban

(Administrative Report of the Municipal Affairs Department, page 2).

Sources:

Population: Census of India, available at:

http://www.wbcensus.gov.in/DataTables/02/FrameTable4_1.htm

Expenditures:

o PRI-West Bengal data base, The World Bank (See Annex A): accounts for 94 percent

(17 out of 18) of the districts, 84.4 percent (288 out of 341) of the blocks, and 87.7

percent (2,941 out of 3,354) of the gram panchayats.

o Urban – Administrative Report of Municipal Affairs Department, 2005, Government of

West Bengal.

o State – Finance Department, Government of West Bengal, Budget Publications 2006-07

(http://www.wbfin.nic.in/) total expenditure heads (revenue account) minus line 3604

compensation and assignments to Local Bodies and PRIs (page 14)

Own Revenue:

o PRI- West Bengal data base, The World Bank (see Annex A)

o Urban – Administrative Report of Municipal Affairs Department, 2005, Government of

West Bengal (pages 25 and 26).

o State - Finance Department, Government of West Bengal, Budget Publications 2006-07

(http://www.wbfin.nic.in/): tax revenue plus non tax revenue (pages 1 and 3)

Page 81: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

77

Table 2

Capital and Current Expenditure Shares by PRI: 2005

Capital Current Total

Districts

(N=17)

85.50 14.50 100

Blocks

(N=288)

62.41 37.59 100

Gram

Panchayats

(N=3,016)

63.16 36.84 100

Total 63.4 36.6 100

Source: PRI-West Bengal data base: The World Bank (See Annex A).

Page 82: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

78

Table 3

Expenditure Shares by PRI Type: 2005

Education Housing Infrastructure Employment

Generation

Panchayat

Administration

Poverty

Alleviation

Health Other

Districts

(N=17)

1.6 18.1 28.6 30.6 3.9 1.3 1.0 14.9

Blocks

(N=293)

15.2 2.9 20.8 28.3 3.8 10.0 5.6 13.4

Gram

Panchayats

(N=3,082)

0.9 30.1 6.2 24.8 25.4 6.7 2.8 3.1

Total 2.1 27.7 7.6 25.1 23.5 6.9 3.1 4.0

Source: PRI-West Bengal data base: The World Bank (See Annex A).

Page 83: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

79

Table 4

Administration and Salary Costs:

by Level of Rural Local Government in 2005

Districts Blocks GPs Total

Administration 0.5 0.9 0.6 0.6

Salary 2.2 1.4 19.2 17.6

All Other

Expenses

97.3 97.7 80.2 81.8

Source: PRI-West Bengal data base: The World Bank (See Annex A).

Page 84: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

80

Table 5

Expenditures and Revenues of Districts, Blocks, and Gram Panchayats:

by Population Size Group: 2005

Population

Size

Number in

sample

Percent of

Total

Population

Percent of

Total

Expenditures

Percent of

Total Own

Source

Revenue

Districts

Less than

2,500,000

4 11.8 15.2 6.8

2,500,001-

5,000,000

9 48.8 56.1 40.4

Greater than

5,000,000

4 39.4 28.6 52.8

Total 17 100 100 100

Blocks

Less than

150,000

93 21.5 29.1 27.0

150,001-

250,000

156 56.4 53.1 60.1

Greater than

250,000

39 22.1 17.8 13.0

Total 288 100 100 100

Gram Panchayats

Less than

15,000

849 18.6 23.9 20.9

15,001-20,000 1,075 34.7 34.8 38.4

20,000-25,000 681 28.1 26.1 25.7

Greater than

25,000

356 18.7 15.3 15.1

Total 2,961 100 100 100 Source: PRI-West Bengal data base (See Annex A).

Page 85: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

81

Table 6

Percent Distribution of Expenditures by Gram Panchayats:

by Population Size in 2005

Source:

PRI-West

Bengal

data base

(See

Annex

A).

Population

Size

Number

in

Sample

Percent of

Population

Education Housing Infrastructure Employment

Generation

Panchayat

Administration

Poverty

Alleviation

Other Total

Districts

Less than

2,500,000

4 11.8 2.2 13.6 26.1 39.9 4.3 1.5 12.4 100

2,500,001-

5,000,000

9 48.8 1.0 22.4 26.9 30.2 3.3 1.4 14.8 100

Greater

than

5,000,000

4 39.4 2.1 13.1 34.4 22.4 4.8 0.7 22.5 100

Blocks

Less than

150,000

93 21.5 14.3 2.3 19.7 29.7 3.8 10.9 19.3 100

150,001-

250,000

156 56.4 15.7 3.0 21.0 26.6 3.9 9.8 20.0 100

Greater

than

250,000

39 22.1 14.8 3.6 22.9 32.1 3.4 8.5 14.7 100

Gram Panchayats

Less than

15,000

849 18.6 0.8 29.0 5.5 23.9 27.9 6.5 6.4 100

15,001-

20,000

1,075 34.7 1.1 28.3 6.3 24.6 27.3 7.0 5.4 100

20,000-

25,000

681 28.1 0. 30.9 7.0 25.7 23.4 6.8 6.2 100

Greater

than

25,000

356 18.7 0.7 33.5 6.4 26.4 21.7 6.6 4.7 100

Page 86: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

82

Table 7

Percent Distribution of Revenues of Gram Panchayats by Source

and by Population Size in 2005a

Own Source Revenue Intergovernmental

Transfers

Population

Size

Percent of

Total

revenue

OSR Tax

as a

Percent

of Total

Revenue

OSR Non-tax

as a Percent

of Total

Revenue

Percent of Total

Revenue

Less than

2,500,000 2.6 0 2.6 97.4

2,500,001-

5,000,000 3.2 0 3.2 96.8

Greater than

5,000,000 7.1 0 7.1 93.0

Total 4.0 0 4.0 96.0 Less than

150,000

2.9 0 2.9 97.1

150,001-

250,000

3.1 0 3.1 96.9

Greater than

250,000

2.5 0 2.5 97.5

Total 3.0 0 3.0 97.1

Less than

15,000

5.4 2.2 3.2 94.6

15,001-20,000 6.4 2.8 3.6 93.6

20,000-25,000 6.1 2.6 3.5 93.9

Greater than

25,000

6.2 2.9 3.3 93.8

Total 6.0 2.6 3.4 94.0 a Unweighted means

Source: PRI-West Bengal data base: The World Bank (See Annex A).

Page 87: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

83

Table 8

The Composition of Intergovernmental Transfers by Source: 2005a

Population

Size

Total Grants

and Transfers

as a Percent of

Revenue

From Central

Government

From State

Government

Districts 94.3 87.6 6.7

Blocks 96.0 80.9 15.6

Gram

Panchayats

93.8 68.8 24.9

Total 94.0 70.0 24.0 a Unweighted means

b The data file contains a category of “other transfers.” This category includes “Other Continuing

Education”, “transfers for the Village Education Committee”, and “Other development programs”.

The file does not include these as separate data entries so they cannot be distributed between

central and state transfers. They are therefore excluded from the entire analysis.

Source: PRI-West Bengal data set, World Bank (See Annex A)

Page 88: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

84

Table 9

Percent Distribution of Central Transfers to Local Governments: 2005

Schemes

Population

Size

Total SGRY IAY Other Union

Finance

Commission

MPLAD

Districts

Less than

2,500,000

100 68.1 21.3 4.5 4.9 1.2

2,500,001-

5,000,000

100 48.1 30.4 12.3 8.7 0.6

Greater

than

5,000,000

100 40.5 19.2 17.9 21.2 1.2

Average 100 51.0 25.6 11.8 10.7 0.9

Blocks

Less than

150,000

100 35.2 0.9 46.1 13.0 4.9

150,001-

250,000

100 36.9 0.3 46.3 9.2 7.3

Greater

than

250,000

100 42.5 0.0 41.5 12.4 3.6

Average 100 37.1 0.5 45.6 10.9 6.0

Gram Panchayats Less than

15,000 100 32.7 40.4 19.9 6.8 0.2

15,001-

20,000 100 32.9 38.6 20.4 7.8 0.3

20,000-

25,000 100 31.6 40.9 19.5 7.8 0.2

Greater than

25,000 100 31.2 43.1 18.3 7.3 0.02

Average 100 32.4 40.2 19.8 7.5 0.2 Source: PRI-West Bengal data set, World Bank (See Annex A)

Page 89: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

85

Table 10

Percent Distribution of State Transfers to Local Governments: 2005

Population

Size

Total Untied Salary State

Finance

Commission

State

Sponsored

Schemes

BEUP

Districts

Less than

2,500,000

100 27.4 41.6 0.0 0.0 15.3

2,500,001-

5,000,000

100 28.1 61.1 0.6 0.5 0.4

Greater

than

5,000,000

100 13.1 70.6 0.0 1.1 1.2

Average 100 24.4 58.8 0.3 0.5 4.1

Blocks

Less than

150,000

100 1.3 25.5 0 2.1 46.0

150,001-

250,000

100 1.4 20.7 0 1.8 51.8

Greater

than

250,000

100 3.7 23.9 0 4.8 44.0

Average 100 1.7 22.7 0 2.3 48.9

Gram Panchayats Less than

15,000 100 0.8 80.1 0.2 2.1 1.3

15,001-

20,000 100 1.0 78.8 0.0 2.6 2.2

20,000-

25,000 100 0.9 77.8 0.01 2.7 2.4

Greater than

25,000 100 1.2 77.4 0.08 1.9 2.6

Average 100 0.9 78.7 0.07 2.4 2.0 Source: PRI-West Bengal data set, World Bank (See Annex A)

Page 90: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

86

Table 11

Characteristics of Districts, Blocks, and Gram Panchayats: 2005 Districts Blocks Gram Panchayats

Indicator Mean

(N=17)

Min Max CV Mean

(N=288)

Min Max CV Mean

(N=2,432)

Min Max CV

Total

Population

3,986,591 1,503,178 8,934,286 50.0 180,663 69,587 418,461 33.8 18,198 1,065 47,360 31.4

Percent of

population in

Scheduled

caste and

tribe

32.1 13.3 55.6 37.2 33.0 1.4 72.7 48.8 36.0 0.6 96.7 53.4

Percent

Female

Population

48.5 47.5 49.1 0.73 48.7 45.4 51.1 1.15 48.8 42.4 52.9 1.51

Literacy rate 57.0 37.8 80.0 19.8 54.2 24.2 75.9 18.0 54.5 12.5 79.4 19.67

Workers as a

percent of

population

40.7 32.5 87.1 31.7 38.0 27.1 59.0 16.9 38.8 23.1 69.4 19.6

Percent of

total workers

in

agriculture

34.0 1.0 67.1 38.8

Percent of

total

marginal

workers

11.1 1.1 40.7 58.2

Gross State

Product Per

Capita

11,595 8,682 15,621 16.8

Source: PRI-West Bengal data set, World Bank (See Annex A)

Page 91: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

87

Table 12

Per Capita Income and

Per Capita Expenditures of PRI: By District in 2005

District Name Per Capita

Per Capita

Expenditures

Gross State

Product

For all levels of

PRI

Uttar Dinajpur 868.2 419.49

Koch Bihar 961.2 725.88

Birbhum 1028.4 407.12

Purulia 1036.1 682.82

Murshidabad 1073 231.18

North Twenty Four 1094.1 278.89

Dakshin Dinajpur 1098.3 430.48

Maldah 1102.9 273.18

Jalpaiguri 1111.4 676.64

Bankura 1115.4 403.63

South Twenty Four

Parganas 1200.7 292.26

Nadia 1219.4 255.98

Darjiling 1449.2 490.53

Hugli 1472.2 310.73

Haora 1562.1 231.7 Note: The following districts are not included due to lack of gross state product data: Paschim

Medinipur, Purba Medinipur, and Barddhaman

Page 92: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

88

Table 13

Per Capita Expenditures by Population Size for Gram Panchayats: 2005

Population

Size

Per capita

expendituresa

(in Rs)

Minimum Maximum Coefficient of

Variation

Gram Panchayats Less than

15,000 183.6 30.9 1,423.3 83.5

15,001-20,000 125.9 19.3 580.1 59.8 20,000-25,000 117.1 17.7 538.2 67.1 Greater than

25,000 102.8 14.9 373.1 61.4

Total N=2,961 137.7 14.9 1,423.3 78.2 a Unweighted mean

Source: PRI-West Bengal data set, World Bank (See Annex A)

Page 93: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

89

Table 14

Per Capita Expenditures (Minus Salary Grant) by Population Size, 2005

Population Size Per capita

expenditures

excluding fixed

costsa

(in Rs)

Minimum Maximum Coefficient of

Variation

Districts Less than

2,500,000 176.7 103.9 225.5 29.2

2,500,001-

5,000,000 169.7 68.7 288.3 44.3

Greater than

5,000,000 103.7 79.3 116.7 16.6

Total N=17 155.8 68.7 288.3 42.0

Blocks Less than 150,000 121.8 14.6 394.5 62.7 150,001-250,000 83.0 15.7 349.6 55.8 Greater than

250,000 70.4 20.0 178.3 55.4

Total N=288 93.8 14.6 394.5 64.2

Gram Panchayats Less than 15,000 150.5 11.0 1,145.8 92.0 15,001-20,000 105.2 2.7 559.4 71.5 20,000-25,000 101.1 5.7 521.7 77.5 Greater than

25,000 90.4 7.3 360.6 69.4

Total N=2,961 115.4 2.7 1,145.8 70.0

a Expenditures exclude reported salary grant.

Source: PRI-West Bengal data set, World Bank (See Annex A)

Page 94: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

90

Table 15

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita Total Expenditures

of Gram Panchayats: 2005

(Log Per Capita Expenditures)

Level of Government Gram Panchayat

Constant 9.96**

(41.64)

Log Population -0.432**

(14.62)

Log Percent SC/ST

Population

0.184**

(13.7)

Log Literacy Rate 0.291**

(5.50)

Log Percent of

Agricultural

0.090**

(7.81)

Labor

R2 0.81

N 2,098 a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported.

* Significant at the 95% level or higher

** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive: Darjiling, Jalpaiguri, and Koch Bihar

Negative: Bankura, Birbhum, Haora, Pachim Medinipur, Purba Medinipur,

Nadia, Purulia, North Twenty-four Parganas, South Twenty-four Parganas,

Dakshin Dinajpur

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Seventy four of the 325 block dummy variables were significant (23 percent).

This indicates that they are important, indicating that there are differences in

spending levels within districts, even after we account for socio-economic

characteristics included in Table 13. A random block was omitted for each

district.

Page 95: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

91

Table 16

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita Total Expenditures

(minus salary grants) of Gram Panchayats: 2005

(Log Per Capita Total Expenditures)

.

Level of Government Gram Panchayat

Constant 8.85**

(30.63)

Population -0.335**

(13.22)

Percent SC/ST

Population

0.240**

(15.07)

Literacy Rate 0.282**

(4.40)

Percent of Agricultural 0.042**

(2.39)

Labor

R2 0.80

N 2,079 a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported.

* Significant at the 95% level or higher

** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Postive: : Darjiling, Jalpaiguri, and Koch Bihar

Negative: Bankura, Barddhaman, Birbhum, Haora, Hugli, Maldah, Paschim

Medinipur, Purba Medinipur, Nadia, Purulia, North Twenty Four Paraganas,

South Twenty Four Parganas, and Dakshim Dinajpur.

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Sixty two of the 325 block dummy variables were significant (19 percent).

This indicates that they are important, indicating that there are differences in

spending levels within districts, even after we account for socio-economic

characteristics included in Table 13a. A random block was omitted for each

district.

Page 96: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

92

Table 17

Per Capita Own Revenues for Gram Panchayats by Population Size: 2005

Population

Size

Per capita own

source revenue

(in Rs)a

Minimum Maximum Coefficient of

Variation

Gram Panchayats Less than 15,000 8.5 0.0 238.6 146.0 15,001-20,000 8.0 0.0 190.2 160.5 20,000-25,000 6.6 0.02 87.7 116.5 Greater than

25,000 5.8 0.05 37.0 101.0

Total N=2,943 7.6 0.0 238.6 146.3 a 3 GPs report values of per capita own source revenues less than 0.001 and 4 report values greater than

100.

Source: PRI-West Bengal data set, World Bank (See Annex A)

Page 97: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

93

Table 18

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita Own Source

Revenue of Gram Panchayats: 2005

(Log of dependent variable)

Level of Government Gram Panchayata

Constant 5.27**

(6.28)

Log Population -0.221**

(2.97)

Log Percent SC/ST 0.090*

Population (1.93)

Log Literacy Rate 0.924**

(4.86)

Log Percent of

Agricultural

-0.145**

Labor (2.56)

R2 0.55

N 2,067

a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported; t-statistics in parenthesis.

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive effects: Bankura and Hugli

Negative effects: Birbhum, Darjiling, Haora, Purba Medinipur, Purulia

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Significant Block Effects:

The block dummy variable is significant for 55 blocks—approximately 17 percent of the cases, split almost

evenly between negative and positive coefficients. A random block was omitted for each district.

Page 98: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

94

Table 19

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita Own Source

Revenue of Gram Panchayats: 2005

(Log of dependent variable)

Level of Government Gram Panchayata

Constant 2.091*

(1.74)

Log Population -0.080

(0.97)

Log Percent SC/ST 0.027

Population (0.54)

Log Literacy Rate 0.858**

(4.50)

Log Percent of

Agricultural

-0.164**

Labor (3.15)

Log Per Capita Grants

and Transfers

0.370*

(3.70)

R2 0.55

N 2,067

a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported; t-statistics in parenthesis

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive: Bankura, Barddhaman, Hugli

Negative: Birbham, Darjiling, Purba Medinipur, Purulia

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Significant Block Effects:

The block dummy variable is significant in 22 percent of the cases (71 blocks). A random block was

omitted for each district.

Page 99: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

95

Table 20

Tax Effort, Gram Panchayats, 2005

GP Name Own Source

revenue per capita

Estimated Own

Source Revenue per

capita

Tax Effort

Domahana 2.77 4.47 0.62

Dutta Pulia 2.89 4.25 0.68

Patharghata 15.03 19.92 0.75

Haripur 2.12 2.79 0.76

Chuprijhara 1.53 1.83 0.83

Bansra 4.12 4.77 0.87

Lalgarh 1.30 1.46 0.89

Prusadpur 2.52 2.22 1.13

Oldabari 8.49 4.10 2.07

Kalia Chak 9.53 2.39 3.99 Source: Calculated from the PRI-West Bengal data base: The World Bank (see Annex A).

Page 100: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

96

Table 21

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita SGRY

of Gram Panchayats: 2005

(Log of dependent variable)

a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported; t-statistics in

parenthesis

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive effects: Darjiling and Haora

Negative effects: Bankura, Barddhaman, Jalpaiguri, Koch Bihar, Paschim

Medinipur, Nadia, North 24, South 24

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Significant Block Effects:

The block dummy variable is significant for 38 blocks—approximately 12 percent

of the cases. A random block was omitted for each district.

Level of Government Gram Panchayata

Constant 7.179**

(14.96)

Log Population -0.326**

(7.59)

Log Percent SC/ST 0.377**

Population (14.15)

Log Literacy Rate 0.264*

(2.50)

Log Percent of

Agricultural

0.029

Labor (1.31)

R2 0.64

N 2,066

Page 101: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

97

Table 22

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita IAY

of Gram Panchayats: 2005

(Log of Dependent Variable)

a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported; t-statistics in parenthesis

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive: Darjiling, Jalpaiguru, Koch Bihar

Negative: Purulia

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Significant Block Effects:

There are few significant block effects. Of 325 block dummies, only 10 were significant. A random block

was omitted for each district.

Level of Government Gram

Panchayat

Constant -5.85**

(10.61)

Log Population -0.250**

(5.07)

Log Percent SC/ST

Population

0.322**

(10.35)

Log Literacy Rate 0.285*

(2.05)

Log Percent

Agricultural Labor

0.132**

(5.16)

R2 0.65

N 1,984

Page 102: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

98

Table 23

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita Total Central

Schemes

of Gram Panchayats: 2005

(Log of Dependent Variable)

Level of Government Gram Panchayata

Constant 8.405**

(25.12)

Log Population -0.287**

(9.83)

Log Percent SC/ST

Population

0.293**

(15.87)

Log Literacy Rate 0.281**

(3.85)

Log Percent

Agricultural Labor

0.102**

(6.67)

Log Percent Marginal

Workers

-0.037*

(1.79)

R2 0.79

N 2,097

a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported; t-statistics

in parenthesis

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or

higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive effects: Darjiling

Negative effects: Bankura, Barddhaman, Birbhum, Haora, Hugli, Maldah,

alpaiguri, Koch Bihar, Paschim Medinipur, Pubra Medinipur, Nadia, North

Twenty Four Parganas, South Twenty Four Parganas, Dakshin Dinajur

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Significant Block Effects:

The block dummy variable is significant for only 12 blocks. A random block

was omitted for each district.

Page 103: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

99

Table 24

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita State Transfers to

Gram Panchayats: 2005

(Log of Dependent Variable)

Level of Government Gram Panchayata

Constant 11.46**

(34.30)

Log Population -0.820**

(27.26)

Log Percent SC/ST 0.018

(0.93)

Log Literacy Rate 0.141*

(1.76)

Log Percent

Agricultural Labor

0.050**

(3.42)

R2 0.61

N 2,022

a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported; t-

statistics in parenthesis

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level

or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive effects: Barddhaman and Hugli

Negative effects: Paschim Medinipur and South Twenty Four Parganas

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Significant Block Effects:

The block dummy variable is significant for 58 of the block dummy

variables—18 percent of all block effects. A random block was

omitted for each district.

Page 104: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

100

Table 25

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita Total Grants and

Transfers of Gram Panchayats: 2005

(Log of Dependent Variable)

Level of Government Gram Panchayata

Constant

9.21**

(38.31)

Log Population -0.452**

(20.90)

Log Percent SC/ST 0.195**

(14.30)

Log Literacy Rate 0.271**

(4.72)

Log Percent Agricultural

Labor 0.087**

(7.93)

R2 0.82

N 2,022 a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported; t-statistics in parenthesis

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive effects: Darjiling, Jalpaiaguri, Kock Bihar, Maldah, and Purulia

Negative effects: Bankura, Birbhum, Paschim Medinipur, and Nadia

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Significant Block Effects:

Among the block effects, we find 71 significant coefficients—about 22 percent of the total

block dummy variables. A random block was omitted for each district.

Page 105: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

101

Table 26

Indicators of Financial Condition for Gram Panchayats: 2003-2005

2003 2004 2005

Gram Panchayats

Number of GPs with

an overall deficit (not

including opening

balance)

1,494 1,334 1,501

Number of GPs with

an overall surplus

(not including

opening balance)

1,491 1,703 1,510

Total surplus (not

including opening

balance) as a percent

of total revenue for

surplus GPs

12.0 14.0 13.0

Total Deficit (not

including opening

balance) as a percent

of total revenue for

deficit GPs

15.0 13.6 11.5

Closing balance as a

percent of total

expenditures ALL

21.8 28.3 23.5

Closing balance as a

percent of grants and

transfers ALL

19.5 26.1 21.5

Number of GPs with

closing balance equal

-5 percent to +5

percent of total

expenditures

428 242 363

N 2,985 3,038 3,012 a Eliminating one outliers, this is 72.3 for closing balance and 83.4 for deficit/total revenue

Source: PRI-West Bengal data base, World Bank (See Annex A)

Page 106: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

102

Table 27

Gram Panchayats with Chronic Current Account

Surplus or Deficit

Number Number with Deficit Greater than

Opening Balance

Average Per Capita

Expenditures in 2005

2003 2004 2005

Deficit for

all 3 Years

199 5 3 4 129.0

Deficit for 2

Years

1,209 31 20 17 134.0

Deficit for 1

Year Only

1,313 23 17 7 141.3

Surplus for

all 3 Years

257 97.7

Surplus for

2 Years

1,313 141.3

Surplus for

1 Year Only

1,209 134.0

Source: PRI-West Bengal data base, World Bank (See Annex A).

Page 107: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

103

Table 28

Ratio of Current Account Deficit

to Opening Balance: 2005

Number of Gram Panchayats

More than 100 percent 27

50-100 percent 608

25-50 percent 483

0-25 percent 383

Source: PRI-West Bengal data base, World Bank (See Annex A)

Page 108: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

104

Table 29

Probit Analysis

Gram Panchayat Deficits

Variable Chronic Deficit GPs (2005)a Deficit GPs (2005)

Constant -1.41**

(13.61)

-0.118*

(1.85)

Opening Balance per capita -0.011**

(3.73)

0.016**

(11.82)

Percent SC/ST population 0.368*

(1.69)

-0.718**

(4.45)

Own Source Revenue per

capita

-0.006

(1.06)

-0.011**

(3.85)

N 2,098 2,095

Likelihood ratio 22.8 184 a Chronic deficit GPs are defined as those with deficits for each year, 2003, 2004, and

2005 (199 GPs).

Source: PRI-West Bengal data base, World Bank (see Annex A).

Page 109: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

105

Table 30

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita Deficitsb

of Gram Panchayat Governments: 2005

(Log Dependent Variable)

Level of Government Gram Panchayata

Constant -0.003

(0.01)

Log Population -0.171

(1.17)

Log Percent SC/ST 0.129

Population (1.43)

Log Opening balance 1.51**

(18.8)

Log Central Sponsored

Schemes Per Capita

-0.172*

(1.95)

R2 0.55

N 996

a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported; t-statistics in

parenthesis b Deficits expressed as positive numbers.

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive effects: Darjiling and Koch Biharrddhaman and Hugli

Negative effects: Paschim Medinipur and South Twenty Four Parganas

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Significant Block Effects:

The block dummy variable is significant for just 16 of the block dummy variables

out of a total of 325 block dummy variables. A random block was omitted for

each district.

Page 110: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

106

Table 31

Per Capita Expenditures by Population Size for Districts and Blocks: 2005

Population

Size

Per capita

expendituresa

(in Rs)

Minimum Maximum Coefficient of

Variation

Districts Less than

2,500,000 176.7 103.9 225.5 29.2

2,500,001-

5,000,000 169.7 68.7 288.3 44.3

Greater than

5,000,000 103.7 79.3 116.7 16.6

Total N=17 155.8 68.7 288.3 42.0

Blocks Less than

150,000 123.1 14.7 396.3 62.7

150,001-

250,000 84.0 16.3 349.9 55.8

Greater than

250,000 71.1 20.5 177.0 55.4

Total N=288 94.8 14.7 396.3 64.2 a Unweighted mean

Source: PRI-West Bengal data set, World Bank (See Annex A).

Page 111: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

107

Table 32

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita Total Expenditures

of Districts and Blocks: 2005

(Log Per Capita Total Expenditures)

Level of Government Blocka District

Constant 8.07** 9.24**

(7.52) (3.96)

Log Population -0.309** -0.227

(3.59) (1.42)

Log Percent SC/ST 0.158** 0.695**

Population (2.81) (3.73)

R2 0.50 0.63

N 288 17 a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported.

* Significant at the 95% level or higher

** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes: For the block regression, positive, significant district effects are

found for the following districts: Koch Bihar, Purulia, and Paschim

Meninipur.

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Page 112: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

108

Table 32a

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita Total Expenditures

(minus salary grants)

of Blocks and Districts: 2005

(Log Per Capita Total Expenditures)

Level of Government Blocka District

Constant 7.89** 9.13**

(7.14) (4.13)

Log Population -0.295** -0.221

(3.32) (1.41)

Log Percent SC/ST 0.166** 0.722**

Population (2.88) (4.00)

R2 0.48 0.63

N 288 17 a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported

* Significant at the 95% level or higher

** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes: For the block regression, positive, significant district effects are found

for the following districts: Koch Bihar, Purulia, and Paschim Meninipur.

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Page 113: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

109

Table 33

Per Capita Own Revenues for Districts and Blocks by Population Size: 2005

Population

Size

Per capita own

source revenue

(in Rs)

Minimum Maximum Coefficient of

Variation

Districts Less than

2,500,000 5.1 0.62 16.6 150.1

2,500,001-

5,000,000 4.6 1.80 8.1 53.3

Greater than

5,000,000 7.2 2.73 15.0 77.8

Total N=17 5.3 0.62 16.6 86.0

Blocks Less than 150,000 3.7 0.1 32.3 165.2 150,001-250,000 2.7 0.1 39.8 153.2 Greater than

250,000 1.5 0.02 6.1 96.3

Total N=288 2.7 0.02 39.8 160.0 Notes: 3 GPs report values of OSRPC less than 0.001 and 4 report values greater than 100.

Source: PRI-West Bengal data set, World Bank (See Annex A).

Page 114: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

110

Table 34

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita Own Source

Revenue of Blocks: 2005

(Log of dependent variable)

a Coefficients on district dummy variables not reported; t-statistics in parenthesis

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive effects: Barddhaman The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Level of Government Blocka

Constant 1.33

(0.40)

Log Population -0.116

(0.43)

Log Percent SC/ST -0.102

(0.61)

R2 0.12

N 277

Page 115: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

111

Table 35

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita Own Source

Revenue of Districts and Blocks: 2005

(Log of dependent variable)

Level of Government Blocka

District

Constant -2.13 -8.50

(0.60) (1.02)

Log Population 0.149 0.396

(0.52) (0.76)

Log Percent SC/ST -0.097 -1.097*

Population (0.54) (1.79)

Log Per Capita Grants

and Transfers

0.339** 1.419*

(1.93)

(3.61)

R2 0.14 0.11

N 277 17 a Coefficients on district dummy variables not reported; t-statistics in parenthesis

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive: Barddhaman

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Page 116: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

112

Table 36

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita SGRY

of Districts and Blocks: 2005

(Log of dependent variable)

a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported; t-statistics in parenthesis

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive effects: Bankura, Jalpaiguri, Koch Bihar, and Purulia

Negative effects: Murshidabad

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Level of Government Blocka District

Constant 6.05** -48.39*

(1.92)

(17.28)

Log Population -0.218** -0.415

(6.44) (0.81)

Log Percent SC/ST 0.424** 2.37**

Population (23.76) (3.36)

Log Literacy Rate 0.195* -5.84**

(2.06) (3.07)

Log Per Capita GSP 6.14*

(2.81)

R2 0.60 0.69

N 266 15

Page 117: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

113

Table 37

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita IAY

Of Blocks and Districts: 2005

(Log of Dependent Variable)

a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported; t-statistics in parenthesis

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive: Barddhaman

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Level of Government Blocka

District

Constant 23.44

(1.05)

-12.00

(1.55)

Log Population -2.49

(1.55)

0.839**

(2.39)

Log Percent SC/ST

Population

0.383

(0.47)

2.07**

(4.26)

Log Literacy Rate -2.47

(0.65)

-4.63**

(3.09)

Log Per Capita GDP 3.25**

(2.74)

R2 0.40 0.59

N 229 14

Page 118: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

114

Table 38

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita Total Central

Schemes

of Districts and Blocks: 2005

(Log of Dependent Variable)

Level of Government Blocka

District

Constant 10.118*

(4.76

15.59**

(3.14)

Log Population -0.509**

(3.09)

0.069

(0.35)

Log Percent SC/ST

Population

0.381**

(3.55)

1.564**

(5.73)

Log Literacy Rate -0.347

(0.76)

-2.24**

(3.07)

Log Per Capita GDP 1.75*

(2.06)

R2 0.35 0.81

N 288 15

a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported; t-statistics in

parenthesis

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive effects: Darjiling

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Page 119: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

115

Table 39

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita State Transfers to

Districts and Blocks: 2005

(Log of Dependent Variable)

Level of Government Blocka

District

Constant 3.873

(1.33)

14.36*

(1.07)

Log Population -0.181

(1.53)

Log Percent SC/ST 0.067

(0.87)

-0.257

(0.92)

Log Literacy Rate 0.189

(0.57)

1.92*

(2.39)

Log Percent Female

Population

-2.80

(0.86)

35.96*

(2.15)

Log Per Capita GSP

-2.42*

(2.70)

R2 0.27 0.43

N 288 15

a Coefficients on district and block dummy variables not reported; t-statistics in parenthesis

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive effects: Bankura, Barddhaman, Paschin Medinipur, and Purulia

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Page 120: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

116

Table 40

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita Total Grants and

Transfers of Districts and Blocks: 2005

(Log of Dependent Variable)

Level of Government Blocka District

Constant 8.15** 7.508**

(6.97) (2.97)

Log Population

-0.327**

(3.46)

-0.113

(0.65)

Log Percent SC/ST 0.177** 0.775**

Population (2.98) (3.92)

Log Literacy Rate -0.154

(.56)

R2 0.48 0.61

N 281 15 a Coefficients on district dummy variables not reported; t-statistics in parenthesis

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Positive effects: Koch Bihar, Paschim Medinipur, and Purulia

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Page 121: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

117

Table 41

Indicators of Financial Condition for Districts and Blocks: 2003-2005

2003 2004 2005

Districts

Number of districts

with an overall

deficit (not including

opening balance)

15 13 14

Number of districts

with an overall

surplus (not

including opening

balance)

2 5 3

Total surplus (not

including opening

balance) as a percent

of total revenue for

surplus districts

11.6 21.7 13.4

Total Deficit (not

including opening

balance) as a percent

of total revenue for

deficit districts

103.7a

36.7 16.2

Closing balance as a

percent of total

expenditures ALL

67.4 74.9 47.0

Closing balance as a

percent of grants and

transfers ALL

130.0a

83.9 52.0

Number of districts

with closing balance

equal -5 percent to +5

percent of total

expenditures

1 1 1

N 17 17 17

Blocks

Number of blocks

with an overall

deficit (not including

opening balance)

166 192 123

Number of blocks

with an overall

surplus (not

including opening

balance)

110 89 155

Page 122: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

118

Total surplus (not

including opening

balance) as a percent

of total revenue for

surplus blocks

17.6 15.3 16.9

Total Deficit (not

including opening

balance) as a percent

of total revenue for

deficit blocks

35.7 37.4 22.4

Closing balance as a

percent of total

expenditures ALL

76.2 74.7 69.3

Closing balance as a

percent of grants and

transfers ALL

80.8 83.0 66.6

Number of blocks

with closing balance

equal -5 percent to +5

percent of total

expenditures

1 3 1

N 276 281 278 a Eliminating one outliers, this is 72.3 for closing balance and 83.4 for deficit/total revenue

Source: PRI-West Bengal data base, World Bank (See Annex A).

Page 123: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

119

Table 42

OLS Estimation of the Determinants of Variations in Per Capita Deficitsa

of Districts and Blocks: 2005

(Log Dependent Variable)

Level of Government Block District

Constant -1.27 12.90

(0.32) (0.67)

Log Population 0.100 -0.801

(0.36) (0.81)

Log Percent SC/ST 0.398 1.015

Population (1.37) (0.77)

Log Opening balance 0.567** 1.672*

(2.97) (1.88)

Log Central Sponsored

Schemes Per Capita

0.120

(1.38

-0.922

(0.71)

R2 0.38 0.18

N 123 13

a Deficits expressed as positive numbers

* Significant at the 95% level or higher, ** Significant at the 99% level or higher

Notes:

Significant District Effects:

Negative effects: Jalpaiguri

The omitted district is Uttar Dinajpur.

Page 124: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

120

Table 43

Reform Options: Alternative Expenditure Levels

(Amounts in Rs)

Three times current

per capita

expenditures

Two times current per

capita expenditures

1. Present spending levela 7,909,652,530 7,909,652,530

2. Proposed spending level 23,728,957,590 15,819,305,060

3. Increase 15,819,305,060 7,909,652,530

4. Present State Fundingb 1,451,315,982 1,451,315,982

5. Required Total State Funding 17,270,621,042 9,360,968,512

6. Required Increase 15,819,305,060 7,909,652,530

7. Required State Funding as a

Percent of State Own Revenue

10.59% 5.74%

a Calculated for all gram panchayats system using the mean per capita expenditure for gram panchayats in

the PRI-West Bengal data base, World Bank (see Annex A) times the total gram panchayat population

(57,734,690). The data base contains data for 3,074 gram panchayats for 2005. This accounts for

approximately 92 percent of gram panchayats by population base or by number of gram panchayats. b Based on the amount of state sponsored schemes to gram panchayats and state grants to gram panchayats

from the PRI-West Bengal data base, World Bank, increased by 8 percent to reflect the total of all state aid

to all gram panchayats in West Bengal.

Page 125: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

121

Table 44

Distribution of Per Capita Receipts from State Grants

Under A Minimum Expenditure Proposals

Number of Gram Panchayats

Percent Gain in state aid

as a share of current plus

additional state aid

ThreeTimes Current

Per Capita Expenditures

Two Times Current Per

Capita Expenditures

0-75 249 385

75-80 54 221

80-90 604 1,405

90-93 850 568

93-95 726 196

Greater than 95 591 299

Total number of GPs 3,074 3,074 Source: PRI-West Bengal data base, World Bank (See Annex A).

Page 126: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

122

Table 45

Selected Coefficients of Correlation

Variable Per Capita State Grants in

2005

Per Capita Grants Under

the Proposed Minimum

Expenditure System

Percent SC/ST population 0.065 -0.004

Literacy Rate 0.113** 0.039

Percent agricultural

workers

-0.003 -0.132**

Percent marginal workers 0.183** 0.039

Own source revenue per

capita

0.133* 0.111*

Source: PRI-West Bengal data set, World Bank (See Annex A).

* Significant at the 95% level, ** significant at the 99% level.

Page 127: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

123

Table 46

Distribution of Per Capita Receipts from State Grants

Under A Formula Proposal

Percent Increase in

State Aid

Number of GPs

0-50 456

50-60 595

60-65 335

65-70 308

70-80 332

Greater than 80 72

Total number of GPs 2,098 Source: PRI-West Bengal data set, World Bank (See Annex A)

Page 128: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

124

Table 47

Impacts of the General Fund and Revenue Mobilization Components

Under a Formula Proposal

GP Population Size

Class

Number of GPs Mean Per Capita

Amount Received

from General

Fund

Mean Per Capita

Amount Received

from Revenue

Mobilization

0-15,000 617 112.2 69.3

15,000-20,000 760 104.6 36.1

20,000-25,000 475 105.4 20.7

Greater than 25,000 246 105.1 13.7

Total 2,098 107.0 40.0 Source: PRI-West Bengal data set, World Bank (See Annex A)

Page 129: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

125

Table 48

Selected Coefficients of Correlation

Variable Per Capita State Grants

(current system)

Per Capita Grants

(proposed system

including general and

revenue mobilization

components and 2X

minimum expenditure

guarantee)

Percent SC/ST population 0.065 -0.005

Literacy Rate 0.113** 0.015

Percent agricultural

workers

-0.003 -0.040*

Percent marginal workers 0.183** 0.081**

Own source revenue per

capita

0.133* 0.412**

Population -0.505** -0.263** Source: PRI-West Bengal data set, World Bank (See Annex A).

Page 130: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

126

REFERENCES

Alok, V.N. (2006). Local Government Organization and Finance: Rural India. In A. Shah

(Ed.), Local Governance in Developing Countries. Washington: The World Bank.

Bahl, R. & Linn, J. (1992). Urban Public Finance in Developing Countries. New York:

Oxford University Press.

Bahl, R. and Martinez-Vazquez, J. (2006). Sequencing Fiscal Decentralization, Policy

Research Working Paper 3914. May 2006: The World Bank, Poverty Reduction and

Economic Management Network, Public Sector Governance Group.

Bahl, R. and Wallace, S. (2007). Intergovernmental Transfers: The Vertical Sharing

Dimension. In J. Martinez-Vazquez and B. Searle (Eds.), Fiscal Equalization:

Challenges in the Design of Intergovernmental Transfers. Springer Publishers.

Bird, Richard (1999). Rethinking Subnational Taxes: A New Look at Tax Assignment IMF

Working Paper 99/165. Washington DC: International Monetary Fund.

Brueckner, J. (1999). Fiscal Decentralization in LDCs: The Effects of Local Corruption

and Tax Evasion. Department of Economics, University of Illinois at Urbana,

mimeograph.

CMIE (2006). Annual Review of the West Bengal Economy: 2004-2005. Kolkata: Center

for Monitoring Indian Economy.

Coondoo, D., Majumder, A., Mukherjee, R. and Neogi, C. (2005). Relative Tax

Performances: Analysis for Selected States in India, Economic Research Unit, Calcutta:

Indian Statistical Institute.

Fisman, R. & Gatti, R. (1999). Decentralization and Corruption: Cross-country and

Cross-State Evidence. World Bank, mimeograph.

Fox, W. F. and Gurley, T. (2006). Will Consolidation Improve Sub-National

Governments? In Policy Research Working Paper 3913, Poverty Reduction and

Economic Management. The World Bank, Public Sector Governance Group.

Government of India (2006). Annual Report of the Ministry of Rural Development, 2005-

2006.

Page 131: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

127

Government of India (March 2005). Concurrent Evaluation of Sampoorna Grameen

Rozgar Yojana. Center for Management Development: Thiruvananthapuram.

Government of India (2004). Report of the Twelfth Finance Commission, (2005-2010).

Government of West Bengal (2005). Assignment of Responsibilities on Three Tier

Panchayat Raj Institutions and Mapping of Activities of P.R. Bodies. Kolkata:

Department of Panchayats and Rural Development.

Government of West Bengal (2006). Budget Speech.

Guruswamy, M., Sharma, K. & Mohanty, J.P. (2005). Economic Growth and

Development in West Bengal: Reality versus Perception. In Economic and Political

Weekly, Perspectives, May 21.

Institute of Social Sciences (2005). Impact of Assessment Study of Rural Develoment

Programmes in Bhavnagar District, Gujarat. New Delhi: Ministry of Rural

Development.

Jha, R., Mohanty, M.S., Chatterjee, S., & Chitkara, P. (1999). Tax Efficiency in Selected

Indian States, In Empirical Economics. Volume 24,(pp. 641-654).

Martinez-Vazquez, J., Timofeev, A., & Boex, J. (2006). Reforming Regional-Local

Finance in Rusia. Washington, DC: The World Bank Institute.

Mathur, On Prakash (2001). Approach to State-Municipal Fiscal Relations: Options and

Perspectives. New Delhi: National Institute of Public Finance.

Oommen, M.A. (2006). Fiscal Decentralisation to the Sub-State Level Governments. In

Economic and Political Weekly, Vol. LXI, No 10, March 11.

Oommen, M.A. (2004). Fiscal Decentralization in Kerala. In G. Sethi (Ed.), Fiscal

Decentralization to Rural Governments in India. New Delhi: Oxford University Press.

Pal, M. & Adak, S. (Undated). Assessment and Collection of Land and Building Tax: A

Case Study in Bankura District of West Bengal, mimeographed.

Purfield, C. (2004). The Decentralization Dilemma in India. Working Paper WP/04/02,

Washington: International Monetary Fund.

Rajaraman, I. (2001) Growth Accelerating fiscal Devolution to the Third Tier.

Conference Paper, “India: fiscal Policies to Accelerate Economic Growth” (NIFPF: New

Delhi.), May.

Rajmal (2006). State Finances and Effectiveness of Policy Measures: An Analysis of

Indian States. Reserve Bank of India Occasional Papers.

Page 132: Public Disclosure Authorized 71483 · West Bengal: Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments: ANALYSIS AND REFORM OPTIONS MAIN REPORT February 28, 2007 Public Disclosure Authorized

128

Rao, M. G., H.K. Amar Nath, and B.P. Vani (2004). Fiscal Decentralization in

Karnataka. In G. Sethi (Ed.) Fiscal Decentralization to Rural Governments in India, New

Delhi: Oxford University Press.

Rao, M. G. and N. Singh (2001). Federalism in India: Political Economy and Reform.

Presented at, India: Ten Years of Economic Reform. Danielson Institute, University of

Michigan, September.

Singh, N. and T.N. Srnivasan (2006). Indian Federalism, Economic Reform and

Globalization. In J. Wallack and T.N. Srnivasan (Eds.) Federalism and Economic

Reform: International Perspectives (pp. 301-363). New York: Cambridge University

Press.

SRC (undated). Resource Mobilization by the Panchayati Raj Institutions: A Study of Six

Districts. Post Design Studies for SRD, Government of West Bengal.

State Finance Commission (2002). Recommendations of the Second State Finance

Commission: West Bengal (unpublished).

Subrahmanyam, K. S. (2004). Performance of SFCs, Impact of their Recommendations,

Suggested Framework for the TFS. Hyderabad: National Institute of Rural Development.

Subrahmanyam, K. S. & Annamalai, V. (2004). Innovative Features in Panchayati Raj

in Select States & Scope for Their Replication: A Quick Study. Hyderabad: National

Institute of Rural Development.

World Bank (2006). Reforming Public Services in India: Drawing Lessons from Success

Report No. 35041- IN, Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Sector Unit, South

Asia Department.

World Bank (2005a). State Fiscal Reforms in India: Progress or Prospects. Delhi:

MacMillian.

World Bank (2005). India: Rural Governments and Service Delivery, Agriculture and

Rural Development Unit, South Asia Region, June 14.

World Bank (2004). Urban Finance and Governance Review Report No. 32253-

IN,Energy and Infrastructure Unit, South Asia Region, December


Recommended