+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Regional Economist - April 2011

Regional Economist - April 2011

Date post: 08-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: federal-reserve-bank-of-st-louis
View: 223 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 15

Transcript
  • 8/7/2019 Regional Economist - April 2011

    1/15

    A Quarterly Reviewo Business andEconomic Conditions

    Vl. 19, N. 2

    April 2011

    Dierent Gvernments,Dierent Respnses

    The Federal reserve Bank oF sT. louis

    CenTral t ameriCas eConomy

    Banking Crises

    around the World

  • 8/7/2019 Regional Economist - April 2011

    2/15

    c o n t e n t s

    James Bullard, Pr ceo

    Frl Rrv Bk s. L

    Headline vs. Core Infation: A Look at Some Issues

    P R e s i d e n t s m e s s a g e

    Banking Crises around the WorldBy Silvio Contessi and Hoda El-Ghazaly

    Over the past 40 years, there have been more than 120 banking crises

    around the world. Dierent governments have responded in dierent

    ways. Te gross and net costs as a percentage o GDP range wildly,

    anywhere rom less than 1 percent to well beyond 30 percent.

    10

    he Regional

    conomistIL 2011 | VoL.19,no.2

    3 PRes i d en t s m es s a g e

    4 Chinese Revaluation:

    No Magic Bullet

    By Brett Fawley

    and Luciana Juvenal

    Even i China does revalue its

    currency, jobs arent likely to

    come ooding back to the United

    States. Much o what China

    exports to the U.S. originates in

    other Asian countries; the U.S.

    trade decit with Asia is likely to

    persist as long as U.S. domestic

    preerences or savings and

    investment remain unchanged.

    6 Education and Health:

    Exploring the Connection

    By Rubn Hernndez-Murillo

    and Christopher J. Martinek

    Better-educated people appear

    to be in better health than less-

    educated people. But does more

    education cause better health?

    Tere are other actors at play,

    such as income and access to

    inormation.

    8 Are Small Businesses

    Biggest Jobs Producers?

    By Kevin L. Kliesen

    and Julia S. Maus

    Its oen said that small businesses

    generate the most jobs in the U.S.

    Tis is true i one looks at the

    gross number o jobs. But because

    small businesses have a high ail-

    ure rate, they are not the largest

    producers o jobs at the net level.

    17 n a t i o n a L o VeRV i ew

    Econom Strengthens,

    But Risks Remain

    By Kevin L. Kliesen

    GDP is rising. Financial markets

    have healed. Te worst o the

    housing crisis appears to be

    over. But the large decit o

    the ederal government poses

    multiple risks to a sustained

    recovery.

    18 Jobless Recoveries:Causes, Consequences

    By Natalia Kolesnikova

    and Yang Liu

    Among the causes is the decline

    o middle-skill jobs over the past

    30 years in this country. Among

    the less-obvious consequences are

    an increase in crime, poorer eat-

    ing habits and ewer marriages.

    2 0 d i s t R i c t o VeRV i ew

    District Falls Behind

    U.S. in Job Growth

    By Michelle Armesto

    and Maria E. Canon

    Tree o the our major metro-

    politan statistical areas (MSAs)in the District perormed better

    than the country as a whole in

    restoring jobs ollowing the 2001

    recession. Tats not the case,

    though, in the wake o the latest

    recession.

    2 2 c o m m u n i t y PRo F i L e

    Bedord, Ind.

    By Susan C. Tomson

    Te auto-parts industry isnt

    what it used to be in this southern

    Indiana town, but a new commit-

    ment by GM to its plant here is

    allowing townspeople to hang onto manuacturing even as they

    seek their niche in the new service

    economy.

    26 economy at a gLance

    27 ReadeR exchange

    Regional Economist pbl

    rrl b Rr Pbl

    r pr Frl

    rv Bk s.L. i r

    l,rl rl

    ,prlrl

    ppl e

    rl Rrv dr. V

    r rl

    s.L F r Frl

    rv s.

    r r

    Bp 314-

    7425 r b -l b.

    [email protected]. y

    r r bl.

    lr r

    r p r b

    /r pbl The Regional

    nomistl rr

    r. w rrv r

    r r lr l.

    ctor of ResearchprJ.wllr

    or Policy Adviser

    rh. R

    uty Director of Researchc.cl

    ctor of Public Affairs

    Br

    orBp

    naging Editorbrk

    Directorwll

    l-p brp r r.

    brb,-l rl..r

    .rb.r r p v .

    .r/pbl. y

    r The Regional Economist,

    ar o,Frl Rrv

    k s.L,B 442,s. L,

    63166.

    Eighth Federal Reserve District

    ll ark,r

    r, r ill i,

    r Kk t,

    rmpp. te dr

    r Ll Rk, Lvll,

    p s.L.

    Monetary policymakers are responsibleor maintaining overall price stability,which is usually interpreted as low and stable

    ination. In order to decide on appropriate

    policy actions given their objective, policy-

    makers need to know the current rate o

    ination and where it is headed. What make s

    or a reliable predictor o uture ination

    has been debated throughout the years and

    continues to be the subject o economic

    analyses today. One debate that has receivedattention recently is whether the ocus should

    be on headline or core ination. Te ormer

    is calculated rom an all-item index, whereas

    the latter is commonly calculated rom a

    price index that excludes the highly volatile

    ood and energy components.

    Central bankers around the world have

    taken both sides o the debate. For instance,

    the ination goals o the European Central

    Bank and the Bank o England are explic-

    itly stated in terms o headline measures,

    and their policymakers pay less attention

    to core measures. In contrast, the Federal

    Open Market Committee (FOMC) ocuses

    on ination that is derived rom the personal

    consumption expenditures price index

    excluding ood and energy (core PCE).

    Tis does not mean, however, that the

    FOMC ignores headline PCE. In act, since

    2008 the FOMC has reported its orecasts

    or both core and headline ination in the

    semiannualMonetary Policy Report to the

    Congress. At the end o the day, the Feds

    main concern is long-run headline inationand the prices people actually pay.

    A natural question to ask, then, is: I the

    Fed ultimately cares about overall prices, why

    would it ever look at core ination, thereby

    excluding items on which Americans spend

    a nontrivial portion o their income? Te

    reason is because, historically, the ood and

    energy components were highly variable (or

    example, due to temporary supply disrup-

    tions), and their large price uctuations were

    usually expected to correct themselves within

    a relatively short period o time. Conse-

    quently, the FOMC ocuses on core PCE as

    a measure o underlying ination trends

    and, thus, a predictor o uture headline PCE

    ination. Assuming core PCE is an appro-

    priate measure to use, we would expect to see

    headline ination uctuate above and below

    core ination over the short run.

    As I discussed in a 2007 commentary,

    the relationship seemed to break down inthe mid-2000s when there was persistent

    divergence in headline and core ination

    rates.1 Measured on a year-over-year basis,

    headline PCE remained higher than core

    PCE rom 2002:Q4 to 2006:Q3. During that

    period, the divergence was largely driven by

    rapid economic growth in Asia; the rising

    global demand or commodities caused their

    prices to rise aster than other prices, putting

    upward pressure on headline ination.

    During the nancial crisis and recession,

    the expected patterns re-emergedheadline

    PCE ination uctuated around core PCE

    ination. But now that the economy is recov-

    ering again, do we see the mid-2000s trendreasserting itsel? Since June 2010, the two

    measures have been diverging slowly, with

    core ination below headline. It is too early

    to tell i the divergence reects another per-

    sistent increase in the relative prices o global

    commodities or i the divergence is more

    temporary. Given the strong growth rates

    o emerging economies during the global

    recovery, though, the divergence in the two

    ination measures deserves close attention.

    What would it mean or moneta

    analysis i the FOMC does expect h

    and core ination to continue dive

    2011 and 2012? As I asserted in my

    ous commentary, one interpretatio

    during times o continuous increas

    relative price o energy, perhaps cor

    misleading indicator o underlying

    trends. Tis implies that core PCE

    be a good predictor o uture headl

    tion aer all. Under these circumsheadline PCE ination should prob

    more weight in policymaking decis

    core PCE ination.

    O course, i the evidence shows

    PCE is not the best measure to ocu

    policy purposes, exploring other op

    make sense. One alternative measu

    include all components but put less

    those that have highly volatile price

    measure would avoid systematicall

    ing certain prices and would more

    reect consumers expenditur es. A

    ally, studies have shown that other

    core measures, such as PCE trim

    or PCE weighted-median ination,

    better predictors o headline PCE in

    than core PCE.2 In the end, the pol

    ers goal is to use the ination mea

    helps them achieve low and stable h

    ination in the long run.

    cover illustration images.com/corbis

    1 Bullard, James B.; and Pande; Geetanjali.Prices: In the Mix or Swept Under the RugReserve Bank o St. Louis National EconomApril 2007.

    2 For example, see Smith, Julie K. PCE InCore Ination. Unpublished manuscriptment o Economics, Laayette College, EasJanuary 2010.

    a ,

    F r

    l-r l f

    pr ppl

    ll p.

    The Reginal Ecnmist | April 2011 The Reginal Ecnmist | www.stlo

  • 8/7/2019 Regional Economist - April 2011

    3/15

    Why Fixing ChinasCurrency Is No Quick Fix

    Brett Fawley and Luciana Juvenal

    On net, the U.S. economy added zerojobs over the past decade: Eightillion jobs gained rom 2003-07 were

    untered with eight million jobs lost rom

    08-09. Te recent recession, despite its

    verity, cannot shoulder all blame or this

    utcome. Average job growth during the03-07 expansion was 60 percent slower

    an average job growth over previous eco-

    omic expansions ollowing World War II.

    Te sluggish growth was likely driven by

    combination o internal actors (increased

    oductivity) and external actors (job

    utsourcing and large sustained trade

    mbalances). For example, Figure 1 shows

    at rom 1994 to 2006 the U.S. multilat-

    al trade decit in goods grew rom 2.5 to

    5 percent o GDP. o the extent that this

    end reects diminished U.S. competitive-

    ss in international goods markets, some

    S. manuacturing jobs may have been lost

    oreign competitors.

    Meanwhile, the U.S. reasury is threaten-

    g to label China as a currency manipula-

    r or allegedly using oreign exchange

    tervention and currency controls to x

    e value o its currency (the renminbi) to

    e dollar in order to prevent appreciation

    its currency and to gain a trade advantage

    rough lower international prices or its

    ports. As revealed in Figure 1, the U.S.lateral trade decit with China accounts

    r a nontrivial (and growing) share o t he

    S. total trade decit. Does this mean that

    increase in the value o the renminbi

    ould reverse declines in U.S. trade compet-

    veness due to biased terms o trade and,

    turn, create jobs in the United States?

    nortunately, the answer is probably not

    any meaningul degree.

    Its Not Just U.S. vs. China

    Assuming that the renminbi is underval-

    ued,1 any eect its revaluation would have

    on U.S. labor markets depends entirely on its

    impact on the U.S. multilateral trade decit

    with all countries, not on the bilateral trade

    decit with China taken in isolation. Smaller

    U.S. trade decits with China, oset by larger

    bilateral decits with other countries, cannot

    be expected to provide material job growth.

    A renminbi revaluation is unlikely to

    seriously impact the multilateral trade

    decit or two reasons. First, multilateral

    trade balances are in part determined by

    domestic preerences that may not hinge on

    the exchange rate. For example, a country

    importing more than it exports must und

    this spending with inows o oreign capital.

    Te magnitude o capital inows is primarily

    determined by the gap between gross domes-

    tic investment and gross domestic savings.

    Revaluing the renminbi is unlikely to un-

    damentally shi U.S. domestic preerences

    or saving and investment. Se cond, regional

    specialization patterns in Asia suggest that a

    major component o t he U.S. bilateral trade

    decit with China is a persistent trade decit

    with Asia. Te price, and hence quantity, o

    Chinese exports may be surprisingly resilient

    to changes in the value o the renminbi.

    In 2003, tension was equally high withrespect to Chinas dollar peg, and the U.S.

    Congress was also considering retaliatory

    measures. Te Congressional Budget Oce

    (CBO), however, concluded that a revalua-

    tion o the renminbi would have little eect

    on U.S. manuacturing employment. In

    particular, China, owing to cheap labor

    costs, unctioned primarily as a place o

    assembly or the Asian region. Intermediate

    goods were exported to China rom other

    Asian countries; these goods were then

    assembled and exported to the United

    States. As evidence o this emerging spe-

    cialization pattern, the CBO reported that

    rom 2000-02 a large portion o the increase

    in imports rom China was oset by declin-

    ing imports rom Japan. Among developingAsian countries (outside o China), nearly

    all showed declining exports to the United

    States during this period.

    Accurately estimating the size o this

    regional trade eect over a longer period o

    time is essential or U.S. trade policy, but

    such estimation is not without obstacles. In

    particular, the CBO analysis beneted rom

    looking at a period o U.S. recession. Dur-

    ing times o economic expansion, imports

    rom nearly all trading partners increase,

    making it hard to distinguish between the

    eects o increasing globalization and the

    potential redirection o exports within

    trading partners.

    o help disentangle the two eects,

    consider what bilateral exports would be,

    had countries export growth been evenly

    distributed across all trading partners.

    Specically, we compute or 174 countries

    what exports to the United States and China

    would have been in 2007, had each shipped

    the same raction o its total exports to the

    United States and China as it did in 1994.We then compare this hypothetical number

    to actual exports and plot the dierences

    in Figure 2. Interestingly, the countries

    that stick out with the largest unpredicted

    increases in exports to China (and corre-

    spondingly largest unpredicted decreases

    in exports to the United States) are, in act,

    the Asian countries implicated by the CBO

    as moving their assembly to China. Tis

    is in stark contrast to the high density o

    points centered at zero-zero, revealing that

    most countries trade shares with the United

    States and China remained roughly con-

    stant. Incidentally, a simple linear regres-

    sion reveals that the relationship between

    greater-than-predicted exports to China and

    less-than-predicted exports to the United

    States is strongly statistically signicant.

    o the extent that Chinese exports to

    the United States originate beyond Chinas

    borders, such trade ows are generally insen-

    sitive to the value o the renminbi: Most

    o the value o the goods is added in other

    countries and denominated in other cur-

    rencies. Specically, the 2003 CBO report

    cites estimates that only 20-30 percent o the

    total value added o Chinese exports occurs

    in China. Hence, only 20-30 percent o the

    value o Chinese exports is subject to the

    eects o a renminbi revaluation. Te dollar

    value o the remaining 70-80 percent o thegoods would remain unaected. Chinese

    manuacturers could import intermediate

    inputs or less money ollowing a renminbi

    revaluation and pass the cost savings directly

    through to the nal price, la rgely osetting

    any increase in the price due to the higher

    value o the renminbi. Such results conrm

    that persistent global trade imbalances will

    require multilateral solutions.

    Revaluation Ma Be Inevitable

    China will probably have to revalue its

    currency in the near uture even without

    the threat o U.S. retaliation. Te true

    relative purchasing power o two countries

    is determined not by the nominal exchange

    rate (the price o one currency in terms

    o another as reported on a currency

    exchange), but by the real exchange r ate,

    which takes into account relative changes

    in domestic price levels. When China sells

    renminbi or U.S. dollars in order to aect

    the exchange rate, it adds currency to its

    domestic money supply. All else equal,the increase in the currency base increases

    domestic prices, canceling out any change

    in the real exchange rate due to nominal

    depreciation o the renminbi.2 Countries

    can absorb some o the additional liquidity

    through sterilization, i.e., buying back

    the currency by selling bonds, but only to a

    point. Te dependence between monetary

    and oreign exchange policy will ultimately

    orce Chinas hand, but the United States

    cannot expect any quick labor market

    xes due to Chinese currency revaluation.

    Instead, the United States would be best

    advised to ollow Chinas suit in identiy-

    ing and exploiting its own comparative

    advantages.

    Luciana Juvenal is an economist and BrettFawley is a research associate at the FederalReserve Bank o St. Louis. See http://research.stlouised.org/econ/juvenal/ or more on Juve-nals work.

    E N D N O T E S

    1 Consensus estimates are that the

    is undervalued by 25-40 percent

    are reasons (like a still developin

    banking sector) why even i allow

    the renminbi could depreciate, r

    appreciate.2 I the renminbi loses hal o its v

    the dollar, but domestic prices in

    ble, the cost o a Chinese good, in

    remains the same. No eect on

    be expected rom the nominal d

    R E F E R E N C E

    Holtz-Eakin, Douglas. Te Chine

    Rate and U.S. Manuacturing Em

    Congressional Budget Oce test

    the Committee on Ways and Me

    House o Representatives, Octob

    imaginechina/corbis

    R a d e

    FIGURE 2

    Asian Exports Have Shited Toward China, Awa rom U.S.

    FIGURE 1

    U.S. Balance o Trade in Goods

    1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 0

    1

    2

    3

    4

    5

    6

    7

    Decit with China

    Remaining Decit

    %O

    FGDP

    18% 20% 22% 25% 23% 21% 1 9% 2 0% 22% 23% 25% 26% 28% 32%

    source: imF D td s (Dots) d b e a.

    source: imF D td s (Dots) d .

    note: t f p pd 2007 xp ud s d c w w

    d d 1994 xp w d p. a

    xp c w d xp ud s.

    xp d f d pdd d

    10 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 7

    10

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

    70

    KoreaHong Kong

    Singapore

    Thailand

    Malaysia

    Philippines

    2007 EXPORTS TO CHINA LESS VALUE PREDICTED BY 1994 SHARE OF EXPORTS TO CHINA (BIL. $)

    2007

    EXPORTS

    TO

    U.S.

    LESS

    VALUE

    PREDICTED

    BY

    1994

    SHARE

    OF

    EXPORTS

    TO

    U.S.

    (BIL.

    $)

    The Reginal Ecnmist | www.stloThe Reginal Ecnmist | April 2011

  • 8/7/2019 Regional Economist - April 2011

    4/15

    Which Came FirstBetter Educationor Better Health?

    Rubn Hernndez-Murillo and Christopher J. Martinek

    he more you learn, the more you earn!Tis phrase has been used by educationoponents to encourage young students to

    y in school or pursue higher education.

    t higher lietime earnings are not the only

    sitive outcome rom increased schooling.

    it turns out, the more you learn, the moreu live in good health. For example, in

    07, the age-adjusted mortality r ate (mea-

    red in deaths per 100,000 people) among

    merican males between 25 and 64 years was

    5.2 or individuals without a high school

    ploma, 600.9 or individuals who com-

    eted high school and 238.9 or individuals

    th some college or higher.1 In terms o

    althy behaviors, the estimated incidence

    smoking among American males over the

    individuals with better access to inorma-

    tion and improves critical thinking skills. 7

    What this means is that people with more

    education tend to be better-inormed and

    make better use o the inormation theyacquire when making health-related deci-

    sions. Tese attributes o education are, in

    turn, reected in health-related choices. For

    example, people with more education seem

    to understand more clearly the dangers o

    smoking, are more likely to be inormed

    about new drugs or complex medical pro-

    cedures and seem to better understand dis-

    charge instructions aer emergency room

    visits. Te authors estimate that cognitive

    skills account or up to 30 percent o the

    education eect on health behaviors.

    Passing Good Health on to Children

    On top o its association with adult health,

    greater educational attainment also promotes

    the transmission o health rom parents to

    children. Economist Janet Currie provides a

    recent overview o the economics literature

    addressing two ways this occurs. First, she

    nds evidence that parental socio-economic

    status (measured by income or education)

    has a strong relationship with childhood

    health. Te reasons or this are very intuitive.Wealthier amilies can aord better quality

    health care and general consumption that

    promotes better health (better ood, saer toys

    and so on). Children o poorer amilies, in

    contrast, tend to suer more adverse health

    shocks than children o richer amilies; the

    ormer also recover more slowly. In the case

    o chronic diseases, such as asthma, poorer

    children are less likely than r icher children

    to manage their condition properly.

    Second, she nds strong evidence that

    childhood health plays an important role in

    uture outcomes. In act, some economists

    believe the observed relationship between

    income and health in adulthood may have itsroots in childhood.8 Currie reports that in

    developing countries there is a lot o evidence

    indicating that individuals with poor health

    during childhood also tend to achieve lower

    education levels later in lie. A similar rela-

    tionship is ound in developed countries; in

    particular, low weight at birth (a strong pre-

    dictor o childhood health) has been associ-

    ated with lower uture test scores, educational

    attainment levels, wages and probabilities o

    being employed.

    Understanding the role o health in the

    intergenerational transmission o socio-eco-

    nomic status is a promising avenue or policy.

    Currie notes that the evidence supporting a

    causal relationship between parental socio-

    economic status and child health and a causal

    relationship between child health and uture

    outcomes is or now still limited. As noted

    earlier, distinguishing between simple correla-

    tion and causality is important or designing

    eective public policy. I parental socio-

    economic status does not impact child health,

    then public policies aimed at improving socio-economic status o the parents will not neces-

    sarily improve their childrens health.

    Rubn Hernndez-Murillo is an economist andChristopher J. Martinek is a research associateat the Federal Reserve Bank o St. Louis. Seehttp://research.stlouised.org/econ/hernandez/

    or more on Hernndez-Murillos work.

    E N D N O T E S

    1 See National Center or Health S

    2010a.2 See National Center or Health S

    2010b.3 See Cutler and Llera s-Muney, 204 See Cutler and Lleras-Muney, 205 Te authors use sel-reports o th

    o disease as opposed to objectiv

    (doctor diagnosis). For some o t

    serious diseases considered, such

    conditions and cancer, sel-repo

    indicate that individuals have be

    diagnosed, however.6 Cutler and Lleras-Muney report

    additional year o education is a

    a reduction in the probability o

    3 percentage points, a reduction

    ability o being obese o 1.4 perc

    and a reduction in the probabilit

    heavy drinker (dened as drinki

    o ve or more drinks when a pe

    o 1.8 percentage points.7 Te most common o these cogn

    authors consider is reading.8 Economists Anne Case, Darren

    Christina Paxson nd that gap i

    health status between children o

    economic status and high socio-

    status grows with age. Children

    income amilies enter adulthood

    lower socio-economic status and

    R E F E R E N C E S

    Case, Anne; Lubotsky, Darren; and

    Christina. Economic Status an

    Childhood: Te Origins o the G

    American Economic Review, Dec

    Vol. 92, No. 5, pp. 1,308-34.

    Currie, Janet. Healthy, Wealthy, a

    Socioeconomic Status, Poor Hea

    hood, and Human Capital Devel

    Journal o Economic Literature, M

    Vol. 47, No. 1, pp. 87-122.

    Currie, Janet; and Hyson, Rosemar

    Impact o Health Shocks Cushio

    Socioeconomic Status? Te Case

    Birthweight. American Econom

    March 1999, Vol. 89, No. 2, pp. 2

    Cutler, David M.; and Lleras-Mune

    Education and Health: Evaluati

    and Evidence. National Bureau

    Research (NBER) Working Pape

    June 2006.

    Cutler, David M. and Lleras-Muney

    Understanding Dierences in H

    iors by Education. Journal o He

    January 2010, Vol. 29, No. 1, pp.

    National Center or Health Statistic

    Final Data or 2007. National VReports, Vol. 58., No. 19. Hyatts

    May 20, 2010a. able 26. See ww

    nchs/data/nvsr/nvsr58/nvsr58_

    National Center or Health Statistic

    United States, 2009: With Specia

    Medical echnology. Hyattsvil

    ary 2010b. able 61. See www.c

    data/hus/hus09.pd

    u B L i c P o L i c y

    Mortalit Rates or People Ages 25 to 64, b Sex and Level o Education, 2007

    Less Th an H ig h School D ip loma o r No GED Hig h School D ip loma o r GE D S om e Co ll eg e or Col lege Deg ree

    800

    700

    600

    500

    400

    300

    200

    100

    0

    Female

    Male

    DEATHS

    (PER

    100,

    000

    PEOPLE)

    600.9

    336.8

    238.9

    156.8

    665.2

    387.4

    source:nvsrp,2007

    note:D 22 pd Dc 2003 u.s.sddcfD. D

    1989 u.s.sddcf D,wfd d ,

    xd.

    2007, -j rl r (r

    r 100,000 ppl) ar l ... 665.2 r

    vl l pl, 600.9 r vl

    pl l 238.9 r vl

    ll r r.

    e o 25 with a bachelors degree or higher

    as 10.4 percent, while this gure among

    ales with a high school degree or less was

    out 30 percent.2 Similar dierences exist

    r obesity and or alcohol use.3

    I more education can lead to better

    alth, addressing the processes by which

    erences in education translate into di-

    ences in health can be useul to public

    licymakers. Identiying a causal relation-

    ip is o crucial importance in the design

    policy. For example, i more education

    uses better health, then policies to

    crease education might also be eective

    improving health in the population.

    However, i the association (oen called

    correlation) between education and health

    exists because better health allows individu-

    als to attain a better education (reverse cau-

    sation) or because the correlation between

    education and health results rom the cor-

    relation o education with other actors t hatalso improve health (such as income o the

    parents), then education-improving policies

    might not be eective at improving health.

    Better Education=Better Behaviors

    Economists David Cutler and Adriana

    Lleras-Muney are among those analyzing the

    education-related health disparities.4 Te

    authors examine responses to the National

    Health Interview Survey in the United States

    and nd a statistically signicant eect o

    education on various measures o health,

    including mortality (measured as death

    within ve years o the sur vey) and incidence

    o common acute and chronic diseases (suchas heart condition, stroke, hypertension, high

    cholesterol, diabetes, asthma and so on). Te

    authors report that more-educated people

    are less likely to suer rom these diseases.

    Interestingly, some common diseases, such as

    cancer, do not seem to exhibit an eect rom

    education (which indicates that incidence

    does not vary with education).5

    A major reason or the dierences in health

    outcomes is, not surprisingly, dierences in

    healthy behaviors. For example, in the United

    States, the incidence o smoking, obesity and

    heavy drinking is lower among the better

    educated.6 More-educated people are more

    likely to exercise and obtain preventive care

    (u shots, vaccines, mammograms). More-

    educated people are also more likely to use seatbelts and have smoke detectors in the house.

    Dierences in behavior, however, do not

    explain all the dierences in health outcomes

    by education, but they do explain a signi-

    cant proportion: Cutler and Lleras-Muney

    nd that the eect o education on mortality

    is reduced by 30 percent when they control

    or exercise, smoking, drinking, seat belt use

    and use o preventive care.

    Income, Inormation

    Cutler and Lleras-Muney consider several

    alternative mechanisms or why education

    aects health. Perhaps the most obvious ac-

    tor to explain dierence in health outcomes

    would be dierences in income. More

    education generally leads to higher income,

    which, in turn, allows or better access to

    better health care. However, they argue

    that it is unlikely that income and health

    care can account entirely or the association

    between education and health as many o the

    behaviors they analyze occur independent o

    health-care access. Te authors estimate thatdierences in income account or about 20

    percent o the impact o higher education on

    health behaviors. Price dierences are also

    unlikely to be an important determinant,

    considering that unhealthy behaviors such as

    smoking, drinking and overeating are costly

    but are, nevertheless, more prevalent among

    less-educated individuals.

    An interesting theory developed by Cutler

    and Lleras-Muney is that education provides

    JlP/Jose l. Pelaez/corbis

    The Reginal Ecnmist | April 2011 The Reginal Ecnmist | www.stlo

  • 8/7/2019 Regional Economist - April 2011

    5/15

    t is oen claimed that small rms are

    responsible or a disproportionately large

    are o new jobs that are created in the U.S.

    onomy. I true, this speaks well o the

    trepreneurial spirit o the U.S. economy,

    hereby newcomers introduce new ideas or

    oduction processes that lead to new andproved products or services. Te rise o

    obal companies like Wal-Mart, Microso

    d Google rom small beginnings is a testa-

    ent to the importance o small businesses

    d the economic orces they sometimes

    leash. However, the claim that small

    sinesses generate a large percentage o new

    bs must be evaluated careully. First, there

    uses the ollowing breakdown o rm size:

    1-19 employees; 20-99 employees; 100-499

    employees; and 500 or more employees.

    Job Gains b Firm Size

    Te table shows average gross and net job

    gains at all private business establishments

    rom the third quarter o 1992 through the

    rst quarter o 2010.5 Over this roughly

    18-year period, gross job gains per quarter

    averaged a little less than 2.8 million, or

    about 929,000 per month. Since the 2007-

    2009 recession was extremely severe, the table

    includes a separate column that excludes the

    data rom that period. Te lower hal o the

    table shows that businesses with ewer than

    20 employees provided the largest percentage

    o gross job gains (about 30 percent). Busi-

    nesses with between 20 and 99 employees

    accounted or the next largest share (about

    27 percent), with the largest rms (500 or

    more) accounting or a somewhat smaller

    percentage (about 26 percent). Te remain-

    ing categorybusinesses with between 100and 499 employeesaccounted or a smaller

    percentage o gross job gains. All o these

    percentages are little-changed i we exclude

    the recession period.

    Te analysis in the table seems consistent

    with the conventional wisdom that small busi-

    nesses are the largest source o job creation in

    the economy. Howeve r, as suggested by pre-

    vious studies, the conclusion tends to change

    when the ocus switches to netjob creation.

    Te two right-hand columns in the table

    examine net job gains. Net job gains are

    dened as job gains minus job losses. Tree

    ndings are apparent rom the table. First,

    net job gains were signicantly smaller than

    gross job gains. Te net gains per quarter

    averaged only 105,000, or 35,000 per month.

    Second, the table shows that the recession

    dramatically reduced the rate o net job

    creation. Once net job losses during the

    recession are removed rom the ca lculation,

    the number o net jobs rose to 173,000 per

    quarter (about 58,000 per month). Finally,

    and perhaps most importantly, the BED

    data show that since 1992, net job creation

    tended to be largest among the largest rms:

    Tese rms accounted or about 38 percent

    o the total. Te smallest rms showed the

    smallest percentage o net jobs created. Tis

    result does not change i the past recession is

    excluded rom the sample.

    In short, small businesses showed higher

    rates o gross job creation, but they also

    exhibited high rates o job destruction.Looked at rom this standpoint, net job cre-

    ation matters most.

    Kevin L. Kliesen is an economist and Julia S.Maus is a research associate at the FederalReserve Bank o St. Louis. Linpeng Zheng

    provided research assistance. Se e http://research.stlouised.org/econ/kliesen/ or moreon Kliesens work.

    E N D N O T E S

    1 Birch ollowed up his original stu

    several subsequent studies (not c2 One drawback o this study is tha

    on the manuacturing sector, whi

    tively small share o the economy

    probably not a good representatio

    job creation.3 See Neumark, Wall and Zhang.4 Te BED is a quarterly series that

    on the Quarterly Census o Empl

    and Wages, which uses state unem

    insurance records. See Spletzer e

    inormation about the BED.5 Changes in employment can aris

    opening or expanding businesses

    or contracting businesses. Gross

    include the sum o all jobs added

    ing and at expanding establishm

    job losses, then, include the sum

    at both closing establishments or

    establishments.

    R E F E R E N C E S

    Armington, Catherine; and Odle, M

    Small Business: How Many Jobs

    Brookings Review, Winter 1982, V

    pp. 14-17.

    Birch, David L. Te Job Generation

    Cambridge, Mass.: MI Program

    borhood and Regional Change, 1

    Brown, Charles; Hamilton, James; a

    James. Employers Large and Sma

    bridge, Mass.: Harvard Universit

    Davis, Stephen J.; Haltiwanger, John

    Schuh, Scott. Job Creation and D

    Cambridge, Mass.: MI Press, 19

    Haltiwanger, John .C.; Jarmin, Ron

    Miranda, Javier. Who Creates J

    vs. Large vs. Young. NBER Wor

    16300, August 2010. See www.nb

    papers/w16300

    Neumark, David; Wall, Brandon; an

    Junu. Do Small Businesses Cr

    Jobs? New Evidence or the Unit

    the National Establishment ime

    Review o Economics and Statisti

    2011, Vol. 93, No. 1, pp. 16-29.

    Spletzer, James R.; Faberman, R. Jas

    Akbar; alan, David M.; and Cla

    L. Business Employment Dyna

    Data on Gross Job Gains and Los

    Labor Review, April 2004, pp. 29

    Average job gains (in thousands) per quarter, 1992:Q3 to 2010:Q1

    Gross Job Gains Net Job Gains

    SizeTotal Sample Period Excluding 2007-09

    RecessionTotal Sample Period Excluding 2007-09

    Recession

    1 19 821 828 16 28

    20 99 747 758 25 40

    100 499 496 505 25 37

    500 722 739 40 68

    total 2,787 2,831 105 173

    Percent of Total

    1 19 29.5% 29.3% 15.0% 16.1%

    20 99 26.8% 26.8% 23.6% 23.1%

    100 499 17.8% 17.8% 23.4% 21.3%

    500 25.9% 26.1% 37.9% 39.4%

    total 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%

    source:adb lsbepDd.spd 100d d.

    Gross and Net Job Gains b Firm Si ze

    lr r ll b r q . ar

    Br Lbr s, l b l b-

    p 1994 r ll pr v r lr.

    t a universal agreement on the deni-

    n o a small business. Furthermore, the

    lure rates o small business are quite high.

    cording to the Bureau o Labor Statistics,

    ly about hal o the businesses that opened

    1994 were still operating ve years later.

    us, when one accounts or job destruc-

    n, small businesses appear to account

    r a signicantly smaller share o net newbs created in the private sector than many

    ople might believe.

    hat Do Past Studies Reveal?

    Te importance o small businesses to

    b creation has been part o the economic

    licy narrative or some time. In 1979,

    en-Massachusetts Institute o echnology

    oessor David Birch claimed that rms

    th 20 or ewer employees accounted or

    two-thirds o all new jobs created between

    1969 and 1976; rms with 100 or ewer

    employees accounted or 82 percent o all

    new jobs created. Conversely, he ound

    that large rms (500 or more employees)

    accounted or only 15 percent o net job

    growth. Birchs nding challenged theconventional wisdom about job creation at

    the time and, accordingly, had enormous

    inuence on policymakers and researchers.1

    Some economists soon began to challenge

    Birchs ndings. Using the same data as

    Birch, Catherine Armington and Marjorie

    Odle ound in 1982 that businesses with

    100 or ewer employees accounted or only

    39 percent o net new jobs. Several years

    later, Charles Brown, James Hamilton and

    James Meddo pointed out that 40 percent

    o jobs created in small businesses in 1980 no

    longer existed in 1986. A more up-to-date

    assessment o the job-creation characteristic

    o small businesses can be ound in work

    published by Stephen Davis, John Haltiwan-

    ger and Scott Schuh in 1996. Tese authorsnoted that a common conusion between

    net and gross job creation distorts the overall

    job creation picture and hides the enormous

    number o new jobs created by large employ-

    ers.2 Te authors ound that although

    gross job creation is high or smaller rms

    (100 or ewer employees), so is job destruc-

    tion. Slowly, researchers were coming to the

    conclusion that small businesses did create

    a lot o new jobs, but the high ailure rate o

    these businesses suggested that their net job

    creation was much lower.

    Earlier this year, a study designed to look

    at the entire economy was published.3 Te

    researchers ound that small rms create

    more net jobs than do large rms, which is

    consistent with the conventional wisdombut generally not the thrust o past research.

    However, they concede that Birch overesti-

    mated the importance o small business in

    job creation and ound that there is a much

    smaller dierence between the net number

    o new jobs created by large rms and small

    rms than Birch originally suggested.

    Business Emploment Dnamics

    Researchers who want to assess the claim

    that small businesses account or a dispropor-

    tionate percentage o new jobs must rst con-

    ront several issues. First, what is the best data

    source or the hypothesis to be tested? Second,

    how should a small business be dened? ( Te

    Small Business Administration says a business

    is small i it employs ewer than 500 people.

    However, it may not be wise to lump together

    a Silicon Valley startup with a relatively large,

    established manuacturer.) Tird , should the

    ocus be on the gross number o jobs cre-

    ated or the net number o jobs created? Te

    research suggests the latter. Why? Because

    even during the depths o the 2007-09 reces-sion, businesses were still adding an average

    o nearly 800,000 new jobs a month. But they

    were shedding an even larger number o jobs

    per monthabout 971,000.

    In this article, we use the Business Employ-

    ment Dynamics (BED) dataset rom the

    Bureau o Labor Statistics.4 One drawback

    o the BED is that it has less than 20 years o

    history, which may limit the ability to draw

    rm conclusions. Te analysis in this article

    m P L o y m e n t

    Are Small Businesseshe Biggest Producers o Jobs?

    Kevin L. Kliesen and Julia S. Maus

    John henley/corbis

    The Reginal Ecnmist | www.stloThe Reginal Ecnmist | April 2011

  • 8/7/2019 Regional Economist - April 2011

    6/15

    Banking Crisesaround the WorldDierent Governments, Dierent Responses

    By Silvio Contessi and Hoda El-Ghazaly

    he latest U.S. nancial crisis is one o many in the recenteconomic history o both advanced and emerging economies.Each crisis is somewhat unique and is t riggered by dierent

    processes and events. However, some common elements can be

    identied in the way dierent governments intervene to help

    nancial sectors return to health and to soen the economy-wide

    impact o the crisis.

    Central banks tend to adopt measures that provide liquidity to

    the system and that can be considered as part o a broader mandate

    to carry out monetary policy. In contrast, governments and parlia-

    ments tend to design and implement programs that provide more

    direct support to specic i ndustries and occasionally to specic

    institutions; these programs are more properly associated with s-

    cal policy intervention. Tis article will ocus on the latter: direct

    support to commercial banks and savings institutions. Te article

    will compare the United States Capital Purchase Program (part o

    the roubled Asset Relie Program) with capital-injection programs

    enacted by other countries around the world during banking crises.

    Fuse/gettyimages

    Deanturner/istock

    The Reginal Ecnmist | April 2011 The Reginal Ecnmist | www.stlo

    a n K i n g c R i s e s

  • 8/7/2019 Regional Economist - April 2011

    7/15

    Most o these programs are oen justied

    politically by the objective o preventing or

    reducing lending declines and recapitalizing

    nancial institutions, with the ultimate goal

    o alleviating strains in nancial markets and

    restoring their unctioning. But instead o

    providing general liquidity to the nancial

    system, they target specic nancial insti-

    tutions. Perhaps this is one o the reasons

    whyeven when they are necessary and

    eventually prove useulthey requently ace

    vocal opposition rom the public. axpayers

    worry that the costs o the support programs

    may outweigh their benets and may eventu-

    ally lead to higher taxes. Economists worry

    that government intervention may plant the

    seed o uture crisis by exacerbating moral

    hazard problems.1

    It is air to say that there is no consensus

    among economists and policymakers on

    the optimal resolution mechanisms o bank-

    ing crises.

    How To Defne a Banking Crisis

    Tanks to its expertise in monitoring

    and analyzing a large number o countries,

    the International Monetary Fund (IMF) is

    particularly well-positioned to collect, study

    and disseminate inormation about banking

    crises in a comparative perspective. IMF

    economists Luc Laeven and Fabian Valen-

    cia analyzed crises between 1970 and 2007

    among a large set o countries, and much o

    what ollows derives rom their work.

    Banking crises can occur either indepen-

    dently or concurrently with a currency crisis

    (a so-called twin crisis) or with a sovereign

    debt crisis, or both.

    How are these crises dened? In a

    systemic banking crisis, a countrys nan-

    cial and banking industry experiences a

    signicant number o deaults while

    nancial entities ace vast problems ul-

    lling nancial contracts on time. As a

    consequence, a country experiences a largeincrease in nonperorming loans, and a

    large part o the capital in the banking

    system is reduced. Sometimes, these events

    ollow a all in asset prices (or example,

    in the real estate market) and sometimes

    overlap with runs on banks, but in order to

    be dened as systemic, such crises must

    involve a large number o institutions or

    cover a large portion o the banking system.

    Sweden and Latvia experienced such crises

    in the 1990s. (A more detailed account o

    the mechanisms involved is provided later

    in this article.)

    A currency crisis is oen dened as a

    situation in which a country experiences

    a nominal depreciation o its currency o

    at least 30 percent, while at the same time

    the rate o depreciation increases by at least

    10 percent compared with one year ea rlier.

    Te collapse o the Tai baht during the

    Asian Crisis o 1997-98 is a prime example

    o a large currency crisis: Te currency had

    depreciated by more than 30 percent less

    than two months aer the xed exchange

    rate was abandoned in the summer o 1997.

    In a sovereign debt crisis, a government

    ails to pay its own debt, either in part or in

    ull. For example, in 1998 Russia deaulted

    on its Soviet-era debt and began restruc-

    turing the components o its sovereign

    debt. Notice that at least partial deault is

    required to meet the denition o sovereign

    debt crisis used by the IMF. Tat means

    the current diculties experienced by some

    European countries would not qualiy as a

    sovereign debt crisis.

    During the recent nancial crisis, no twin

    or triple crisis (as just dened) has occurred so

    ar. Some European countries have experi-

    enced diculties in managing and renancing

    their debt, but so ar none has deaulted.

    Many countries have experienced com-

    binations o these types o crises in recent

    history. Economists Laeven and Valencia

    identied 124 systemic banking crises, 208

    currency crises and 63 sovereign debt crises;

    the two economists observed that some

    countries were repeatedly aected by these

    events between 1970 and 2007. One such

    country is Argentina. Its prosperity rivaled

    that o the United States in the beginning o

    the 20th century. Yet in the past 30 years,

    Argentina has experienced our banking

    crises (1980, 1989, 1995 and 2001). All but

    the 1995 crisis were also currency crises,and one (2001) was contemporaneous to a

    sovereign debt crisis.

    Argentina is not an isolated case. Te

    IMF study identies 26 twin crises (banking

    and currency) and eight triple crises. Over-

    all, banking and currency crises were more

    requent in the 1990s, while sovereign debt

    crises were more requent in the 1980s.

    Te recent global nancial crisis wit-

    nessed many countries experiencing

    banking crises. Aer 2007, there were 13

    cases o systemic banking crises in which

    all countries experienced extensive liquid-

    ity support, increases in guarantees on

    liabilities and signicant nationalizations.

    In some cases, the countries also experi-

    enced signicant asset purchases (as in the

    United Kingdom and United States) and

    sizable restructuring costs.2 During the

    same period, a smaller group o 10 countries

    experienced serious problems in its ba nk-

    ing sectors that entailed extensive liquidity

    support and increases in guarantees on

    liabilities; in these 10 countries, there was

    only one case o asset purchases (Switzer-

    land) and there were no cases o signicant

    nationalization.3

    Luckily, none o these countries has experi-

    enced either a currency crisis or a sovereign

    debt deault since 2007.

    Options or Direct Support

    in Banking Crises

    Commonly adopted resolution policies

    include various types o large-scale govern-

    ment intervention, such as bank closures,

    nationalizations, mergers, sales to oreigners,

    the creation o a bank restructuring agency

    and/or an asset-management company, and

    recapitalization. Sometimes, these actions

    are accompanied by orbearance that allows

    the suspension or reduction o loan payments

    under certain circumstances and or speci-

    ed lengths o time; sometimes, changes in

    loan classication and loan-loss provisioning

    are also allowed.

    Oen, direct government support to

    ailing nancial institutions takes the orm

    o recapitalization, a process in which the

    amount o debt and assets o a particular

    entity are reorganized in order to meet a

    nancial goal. Te goal may be an attempt

    to limit the amount o tax owed on assets in

    hand or, as part o a reorganization, to avoid

    bankruptcy.Financial institutions can be recapitalized

    using a variety o measures: cash transer,

    government bonds, issuance o subordinated

    debt, issuance o preerred shares, govern-

    ment purchase o bad loans, assu mption o

    bank liabilities or the purchase o ordinary

    shares by the government.

    Governments intervened with some orm

    o recapitalization or capital injection in 32 o

    the 42 banking crises identied by the IMF

    economists between 1970 and 2007 or which

    detailed comparable inormation could be

    gathered. Recovery programs during the

    global nancial and banking crisis o 2007-09

    were no dierent: 16 countries opted or out-

    right recapitalization, with some combining a

    wide variety o asset guarantees and liquidity

    programs similar to some o the programs

    implemented in the United States.

    A Sample o Past Crises Abroad

    Sweden

    Various economic policies adopted by

    Sweden in the 1970s and 1980s encouraged

    a sizable credit and real estate boom, in

    which house prices more than doubled

    between 1981 and 1991. At the same time,

    the economy was becoming much more

    exposed to exchange rate risk.

    Because o Swedens exchange rate tiewith Germany, when interest rates in

    Germany increased in 1990 as a result o

    unication, Swedens interest rates also

    experienced a rapid increase. Tis tipped

    Swedens economy into crisis. Real estate

    prices dropped dramatically, with commer-

    cial real estate prices dropping 42 percent in

    ve years and nonperorming loans increas-

    ing to as high as 11 percent o GDP in 1993.4

    Swedens largest banks were unable to meet

    capital requirements and required assistance

    rom the state. I nstead o maintaining private

    large banks and injecting capital through a

    direct support program, the Swedish govern-

    ment nationalized two o Swedens largest

    banks and supported a third by providing it

    with a loan guarantee. Te ownership o these

    banks allowed the government to provide

    equity to ailing borrowers and restructure

    deaulting companies. Liqu idating bad assets

    took the government less than six years and

    ended up costing Sweden less than 2 percent o

    its GDP (with some estimates close to zero).

    Latvia

    In 1991, Latvia gained independence rom

    the Soviet Union and transitioned rom a

    centrally planned economy to a market econ-

    omy. With in our years o its independence,

    Latvia had more than 60 licensed banks or

    a population o 2.3 million.5 As government

    policy established the right or any person or

    entity to establish a bank, the motivation or

    ounding a bank quickly became the ability

    vr rv

    r rp-

    lz r pl j

    32 42 bkr b imF

    b 1970

    2007. ...

    The Reginal Ecnmist | April 2011 The Reginal Ecnmist | www.stlo

  • 8/7/2019 Regional Economist - April 2011

    8/15

    than one year aer the initial problems

    in the nancial system had emerged. For

    the rst year o the crisis (which began in

    August 2007), there were no signicant

    legislative changes, perhaps because the risk

    o a major crisis seemed minimal or because

    sucient institutional exibility seemed to

    guarantee the ability to intervene with exist-

    ing instruments.

    However, the existing toolkit o support

    programs was substantially expanded soon

    enough. By October 2008, in the midst o the

    panic that ensued aer the ailure o Lehman

    Bros., the reasury proposed to Congress

    the idea o purchasing troubled assets to

    stabilize the nancial system, through ARP,

    an essential component o the Emergency

    Economic Stabilizat ion Act. Within a week

    o approving the legislation, the core sup-

    port was reocused toward buying equity in

    nancial institutions, using a new instrument

    o support, the Capital Purchase Program

    (CPP), which ell under the big umbrella pro-

    vided by ARP. Within weeks, nine major

    banks received a capital injection o $145billion, and the idea o purchasing troubled

    assets was temporarily set aside in avor o

    buying equity.

    In November 2008, one o the benecia-

    ries o the CPP, Citigroup, received a second

    round o government assistance, under

    another program o the ARP, and in Janu-

    ary 2009, Bank o America also was given

    additional government support. Te new

    administration dened a set o criteria or

    stress tests aimed at determining the capital

    adequacy o the largest banks and presented a

    new program aimed at purchasing assets (the

    Public-Private Investment Program), which

    makes up a small percentage o ARP unds.

    Similar to other countries, U.S. authorities

    adopted a complex strategy to support the

    economy during the nancial crisis; almost

    all o the policy options deployed in the U.S.

    were attempted in Japan during the 1990-

    2003 period.8

    ARP eventually included 13 programs

    implemented by the U.S. reasury. Te

    reasury allocated $250 billion or CPP,

    which represents a large part o the total

    allocation o government unds under

    ARP ($700 billion). O the $250 billion

    allocated, approximately $205 billion was

    distributed to 707 institutions, largely

    toward the end o 2008 and the beginning

    o 2009, with the last disbursements occur-

    ring Dec. 29, 2009. Figure 1 plots the

    monthly number o beneciaries (red bar),

    the total amount o gross disbursements

    (gold line) and the value o outstandingdisbursements (gross payment net o repay-

    ment, blue dots) until the end o 2010. It

    should be noted that some nancial institu-

    tionsCitigroup, Bank o America, GMAC

    and Chrysler Financialwere supported

    with other ARP programs, as well.

    Te pool o eligible institutions that

    could apply or CPP unds included more

    than 8,000 commercial banks, savings and

    loan institutions, and some other nancial

    source: aw dd tp. tcpPP(cPP)d

    tdarP(tarP).

    URE 1

    RP-CPP Disbursement

    to access cheaper unding rather than go

    through more-established channels. Tese

    private banks continued to grow with little

    supervision rom the Central Bank o Latvia

    and, as a result, much bad lending took place.

    Te precipitating actor o the crisis

    occurred in early 1995 when the Central

    Bank o Latvia requested that all banks

    present their audited nancial statements.

    Te largest Latvian bank in terms o assets

    and depositsBank Baltijaailed to pres-

    ent its statements, revealing its potential

    insolvency. Te central bank took control

    o Bank Baltija in July 1995, and a liquida-

    tor took control in 1996. Other mid-size

    and smaller banks also aced diculties

    during this time, and several were catego-

    rized as insolvent. About 40 percent o the

    banking systems assets and liabilities were

    impacted.6

    During the tra nsition period, nonper-

    orming loans increased throughout the

    banking sector as banks granted loans even

    to high-risk borrowers, and collect ions were

    made dicult by a lack o laws governingloan collateral. However, a swi stabiliza-

    tion policy helped restore viability to the

    banking system with the liquidation o cer-

    tain banks, oreign help rom the European

    Bank or Reconstruction and Development,

    and a new banking law strengthening the

    central banks regulatory powers. Te coun-

    try also established a deposit insurance sys-

    tem, and the government decided to reu nd

    lost deposits to depositors up to a certain

    amount and conditioned on the existence o

    proceeds rom the bank liquidation process.

    Argentina

    Argentina has experienced our banking

    crises since the 1980s, with one tr iple crisis

    in 2001. During the 1990s, the government

    transormed the banking sector through

    privatization and consolidation and allowed

    or increased entry by oreign institutions, all

    o which improved the banking systems e-

    ciency. However, bank protability remained

    low, and more than 20 percent o total assets

    in 2000 were represented by government

    debt, which le banks vulnerable in the case

    o government deault.7

    Te triple crisis broke in 2001 when, out

    o ear rom the deteriorating economic cli-

    mate, people rushed to withdraw their pesos

    rom the banks in order to convert them

    into dollars and ship them abroad. Tealready ailing banks were urther devastated

    when the government deaulted on its debt

    in December 2001.

    As a result o the nancial distress, the

    country was orced to exit its currency board

    regime, a convertibility program that tied the

    peso to the dollar at parity. At the same time,

    the government responded to the bank runs

    by restricting withdrawals, essentially reez-

    ing all accounts. In addition, private deposits

    and credit to the private sector declined

    dramatically, which urther weakened the

    ailing economy. Te resolution o the bank-

    ing crisis was part o a larger set o policies

    that had to deal with the economy-wide

    crisis. Te government ended the currency

    board regime in early 2002 (allowing a mas-

    sive devaluation o the peso) and eventually

    restructured its debt.

    Besides reezing bank accounts, the

    government intervention took several

    additional orms, including converting

    dollar-denominated loans and deposits rom

    dollars to pesos at dierent rates, authoriz-

    ing regulatory orbearance and a temporary

    decrease in banks capital, and nationalizing

    three banks and closing another.

    The U.S. Experience

    In the United States, the main instrument

    o direct support to banks by the U.S. rea-

    sury is within the roubled Asset Relie

    Program. ARP was established at the peak

    o the crisis in the all o 2008, a bit more

    source:l,l;d v,F.sbc:anw D. imFd (imF)WPp

    08/224,n2008.

    FIGURE 2

    Governments Gross and Net Costs o Restructuring the Financial Sector

    40

    35

    30

    25

    20

    15

    10

    5

    0

    Gross Recapitalization Cost to Government (% of GDP) Net Recapitalization Cost to Government (% of GDP)

    PERCENT

    Argentina(95)

    Argentina(01)

    Bolivia(94)

    Brazil(94)

    Bulgaria(96)

    Chile(81)

    Colombia(82)

    Colombia(98)

    Croatia(98)

    CzechRepublic(96)

    Ecuador(98)

    Estonia(92)

    Finland(91)

    Ghana(82)

    Jamaica(96)

    Japan(97)

    Korea(97)

    Indonesia(97)

    Lithuania(95)

    Malaysia(97)

    Mexico(94)

    Norway(91)

    Paraguay(95)

    Philippines(97)

    SriLanka(89)

    Sweden(91)

    Thailand(97)

    Turkey(00)

    UnitedKingdom(

    07)

    Uruguay(02)

    Venezuela(94)

    Vietnam(

    97)

    United

    States

    (2009)

    Average

    (1970-

    2007)

    Oct.

    08

    Dec.

    08

    Feb.

    09

    April09

    June

    09

    Aug.

    09

    Oct.

    09

    Dec.

    09

    Feb.

    10

    April10

    June

    10

    Aug.

    10

    Oct.

    10

    Dec.

    10

    250

    200

    150

    100

    50

    0

    800

    700

    600

    500

    400

    300

    200

    100

    0

    Number of Beneciaries Disbursement Net of RepaymentsDisbursement

    NUMBEROFINSTITUTIONS

    t h e u n i t e D s t a t e s ( 2 0 0 9 ) c o m P a r e D W i t h 3 0 c o u n t r i e s ( 1 9 7 0 - 2 0 0 7 )

    The Reginal Ecnmist | April 2011 The Reginal Ecnmist | www.stlo

  • 8/7/2019 Regional Economist - April 2011

    9/15

    termediaries. However, onlyqualifed

    ancial institutions, those deemed strong

    ough to survive the crisis, were considered

    r direct support. As later events showed,

    ry ew o the CPP beneciaries ailed in the

    riod between 2008 and 2010.9

    Te application process or the CPP

    volved several stages, which involved con-

    ltations with primary regulators, analysis

    their regulatory ratings and nal approval

    the reasury. Investment amounts ini-

    lly varied rom 1 percent to 3 percent o

    e institutions risk-weighted assets (up to a

    aximum o $25 billion).

    Aer May 2009, some nancial institutions

    unteered to return their capital injections

    rlier than expected. Te position o repay-

    ents is clear in Figure 1. By the end o 2010,

    ly one-h o the original pledged unds

    d yet to be returned by the beneciaries.

    mparing U.S., Other Countries

    In the 42 aorementioned banking crises

    tween 1970 and 2007, the estimated cost

    direct support recapitalization varies sub-

    ntially, with gross costs (not accounting

    r repayments) ranging rom an estimated

    28 percent o GDP in Argentina during

    e 1995 crisis to 37 percent in Indonesia

    ring the 1997-98 crisis.

    Initial estimates or the 2007-09 nan-

    al crises, available in another study by

    onomists Laeven and Valencia, place gross

    sbursements o scal outlays in a range

    tween 0.7 percent o GDP (Sweden) to

    percent o GDP (Iceland). As some o

    ese crises are still unolding, it is possible

    at these gures will be revised upward in

    e uture.10

    Te study also provides interesting details

    out the median costs o a banking crisis

    governments. While pre-2007 crises

    tailed a smaller median scal cost in

    vanced economies relative to emerging

    arkets (3.7 percent o GDP compared with.5 percent o GDP), they also increased

    e ratio o public debt to GDP more in

    vanced economies (36.2 percent versus

    .7 percent o GDP). Output lossesthe

    rcentage deviation o actual output rom

    trendassociated to crises in advanced

    onomies were also larger than in emerg-

    g economies (32.9 percent o GDP versus

    .4 percent o GDP), although output losses

    e notoriously dicult to measure.

    Te gross direct scal cost o nancial sec-

    tor restructuring during the recent nancial

    crisis has been estimated at roughly 5 percent

    o GDP or the U.S. (counting the $700 billion

    that was the total budget or ARP), close

    to the median across advanced countries

    that implemented similar programs during

    this crisis. While countries like the Neth-

    erlands and Iceland had sizable direct scal

    costs (reaching between 12 and 13 percent o

    GDP), some other advanced economies had

    substantially smaller outlays because they

    had ewer troubles in their banking systems.

    France, Germany and Sweden, or example,

    had direct scal costs o less than 2 percent o

    their GDP. I only the CPP were considered

    or the U.S., the ratio or the U.S. would all

    to approximately 1.4 percent o 2009 GDP.

    A more-inormative measure o the cost

    o direct support programs looks at the net

    costs, calculated as the dierence between

    the amount o unds disbursed and those

    repaid to the government. Te median net

    cost across 42 banking crises between 1970

    and 2007 was 3.4 percent o GDP. Its dis-

    tribution across some o these countries or

    which data are available is plotted in Figure

    2. In the U.S., in the unlikely case that no

    more unds are returned, the net cost o the

    CPP will remain at most 0.266 percent o

    2009 GDP, substantially lower than in previ-

    ous banking crises.11

    Compared with Japan (the only other large

    economy that has experienced a widespread

    banking crisis ollowing a housing crisis),

    the United States appears to be transitioning

    out o the crisis relatively quickly. Although

    the U.S. has had more bank ailures (mostly

    small institutions), banks have more swily

    repaid the majority o their CPP unds than

    have banks in Japan and other countries

    aected by banking crises.

    Silvio Contessi is an economist and HodaEl-Ghazaly is a research associate at the FederalReserve Bank o St. Louis. See http://research.stlouised.org/econ/contessi/ or more onContessis work.

    E N D N O T E S

    1 Moral hazard is when an individual or a com-

    pany does not entirely bear the consequences

    o its decisions and, thereore, acts less care-

    ully than it otherwise would, leaving another

    party (e.g., the government) to bear part or all

    o the cost o the eects o those decisions.2 Te 13 countries are Austria, Belgium, Den-

    mark, Germany, Iceland, Ireland, Latvia, Lux-

    embourg, Mongolia, Netherlands, Ukraine,

    United Kingdom and the United States.3 Te 10 countries are France, Greece, Hungary,

    Kazakhstan, Portugal, Russia, Slovenia, Spain,

    Sweden and Switzerland.4 See Ergungor.5 See Bank o Latvia.6 See Fleming and alley.7 See IMF.8 See Hoshi and Kashyap.9 See Aubuchon and Wheelock.

    10 See the 2010 study by Laeven and Valencia.11 Tis gure is computed using the 1-4-11

    ransaction Report or the period ending

    Dec. 31, 2010, which we accessed on Jan. 18,

    2011. Te report computes the total purchase

    amount ($204.9 billion), the total repaid ($167.9

    billion), the losses ($2.6 billion) and the total

    outstanding CPP investment ($34.4 billion).

    R E F E R E N C E S

    Aubuchon, Craig P.; and Wheelock, David C. Te

    Geographic Distribution and Characteristics o

    U.S. Bank Failures, 2007-2010: Do Bank Failures

    Still Reect Local Economic Conditions? Fe d-

    eral Reserve Bank o St. Louis Review, Septem-

    ber-October 2010, Vol. 92, No. 5, pp. 395-415.

    Bank o Latvia. Origi ns o the Banking Crisis.

    Te Annual Report. 1995. See www.bank .lv/eng/

    main/all/pubrun/lbgadaparsk/1995gadpars/

    ku/originsbankcrisis/

    Congressional Oversight Panel. April Oversight

    Report, April 2009.

    Contessi, Silvio; and Francis, Johanna. ARP

    Beneficiaries and Teir Lending Patt erns

    during the Financial Crisis. Federal Reserve

    Bank o St. Louis Review, March/April 2011,

    Vol. 93, No. 2, pp. 105-25.

    Ergungor, O. Emre. On the Resolution o Finan-

    cial Crises: Te Swedish Experience. Federal

    Reserve Bank o Cleveland Policy Discussion

    Papers, No. 21, June 2007.

    Fleming, Alex; and alley, Samuel. Latvi an Bank-

    ing Crisis: Stakes and Mistakes. Te World Bank

    Beyond ransition, 2001. See ww w.worldbank.

    org/html/prddr/trans/m&a96/art2.htm

    Hoshi, akeo; Kashyap, Anil K. Will the U.S.

    Bank Recapitalization Succeed? Eight Lessons

    rom Japan. Journal o Financial Economics,

    September 2010, Vol. 97, No. 3, pp. 398-417.

    Internationa l Monetary Fund. Lessons rom theCrisis in Argentina. Oct. 8, 2003. See www.im.

    org/external/np/pdr/lessons/100803.pd

    Laeven, Luc; and Valencia, Fabian. Systemic

    Banking Crises: A New Database. International

    Monetary Fund (IMF) Working Paper 08/224,

    November 2008.

    Laeven, Luc; and Valencia, Fabian. Resolution

    o Banking Crises: Te Good, the Bad, and the

    Ugly. International Monetary Fund (IMF)

    Working Paper 10/146, June 2010.

    Oce o the Special Inspector General or the

    roubled Asset Relie Program. Quarterly

    Report to Congress, Jan. 26, 2011.

    The Reginal Ecnmist | April 2011

    During the rst year and a hal o thebusiness expansion, the U.S. recoverywas characterized by below-average growth

    o real GDP, anemic job creation and a high

    unemployment rate. It was airly weak by

    historical standards. Early this year, however,

    the U.S. economy seemed poised to grow by

    more than the roughly 2.75 percent growth oreal GDP registered last year. Tis strength-

    ening, which is consistent with the projec-

    tions o the Federal Open Market Committee

    and the consensus o private-sector proes-

    sional orecasters, likely reects a ew key

    actors. Tese include the economys natural

    built-in corrective orces and the expansion-

    ary monetary and scal policies put in place

    to jump-start the economy. In addition,

    nancial markets have healed, and the worst

    o the housing crisis appears to be behind us.

    Ke Trends Remain Positive

    Last year, real GDP increased by about

    2.75 percent. Tis increase was signicantly

    larger than in t he previous year (0.2 percent),

    but still only about equal to the economys

    estimated growth o potential real GDP.

    When actual real GDP and potential real

    GDP are growing at about the same rate,

    there is not much scope or improving labor

    market conditionsparticularly aer a deep

    recession. I ndeed, job gains were decid-

    edly lackluster last year, as nonarm payrollemployment rose by an average o 76,000 per

    month. Likewise, the unemployment rate

    averaged 9.6 percent in the ourth quarter

    o last year, down only modestly rom a year

    earlier (10 percent).

    Growth o real GDP was strengthening

    over the second hal o last year aer a

    springtime lull that saw the nations out-

    put growth slip to about 1.75 percent in

    the second quarter. Broadly speaking, the

    economys momentum at the end o 2010

    appears to have carried over into 2011, as

    many o the nations key indicators are point-

    ing to a quickening in the pace o economic

    activity this year. First, the Conerence

    Boards Index o Leading Economic Indica-

    tors increased by nearly 8 percent in 2010,

    which was the largest annual increase since1983. Second, productivity growth remains

    quite strong. One immediate maniestation

    o this is reected in strong growth o cor-

    porate prots, which then helps to increase

    stock prices. Rising stock prices against the

    backdrop o an improving outlook provide

    rms with an incentive to expand their capi-

    tal stock. Rising stock prices also increase

    household wealth, which may provide a boost

    to consumption spending.

    At some point, strong productivity growth

    should lead to aster growth o real income

    and, thus, rising employment. Indeed,

    according to the February 2011 Survey o

    Proessional Forecasters, nonarm payrolls

    are projected to increase by an average

    o 200,000 per month over the nal nine

    months o this year.

    Despite this robust job growth, orecasters

    expect that the nations unemployment rate

    will remain quite high this year (9.1 percent)

    and next year (8.5 percent). Larger declines

    in the unemployment rate are possible, but

    probably only i real GDP increases by morethan the roughly 3.25 percent growth that

    orecasters expect or this year and next.

    Risks to the Outlook

    Financial crises tend to have long-lasting

    eects. One notable legacy o a nancial

    crisis is a large increase in government debt

    to GDP. Te Congressional Budget Oce

    (CBO) now projects that the ederal bud-

    get decit will average about 8.5 percent

    o GDP or scal years 2010 to 201

    compares unavorably with an aver

    percent rom 1960 to 2007. ypica

    economy strengthens, the decit nlessens as tax revenues increase be

    rising real incomes, and governm

    decline as ewer individuals requir

    ployment benets or other orms o

    tance. However, the CBO estimat

    lions share o the decit in 2010 w

    to these cyclical actors. Tus, som

    more than a strengthening o the e

    is required to reduce the budget de

    longer-term levels.

    Unless addressed promptly, thes

    budget decits present several risks

    economy. First, large decits tend

    upward pressure on interest rates, a

    government absorbs more o the u

    able or private-sect or investment.

    the threat o rising interest rates ma

    investors to either sell t heir existin

    o government securities or rerain

    chasing newly issued securities. Fi

    prospect o large uture budget de

    cause households to save more in th

    in anticipation o higher uture tax

    prospect o higher uture corporate

    might also cause businesses to canc

    capital investment projects.

    Te sooner that governments at

    return their nances to sustainabl

    the better o the economy will be

    long haul.

    Kevin L. Kliesen is an economist at thReserve Bank o St. Louis. See http://stlouised.org/econ/kliesen/ or more o

    By Kevin L. Kliesen

    Te Economy Continueso Strengthen, but Risks Remain

    n a t i o n a L o V e R V i e w

    The Reginal Ecnmist | www.stlo getty images/Dave cutler

  • 8/7/2019 Regional Economist - April 2011

    10/15

    n e m P L o y m e n t

    obless Recoveries:Causes and Consequences

    economic downturns experience a large,

    negative and persistent eect to their lietime

    opportunit ies. Young workers who enter the

    job market during a jobless recovery may

    experience temporary unemployment and

    are more likely to accept less-attractive and

    lower-skill jobs due to limited opportunities.

    On average, their initial wage is signicantly

    lower than the initial wage o their counter-

    parts who graduate when the job market is

    strong. Tis disadvantage persists; even 15

    years aer graduation, their wages and career

    attainment remain lower than those o their

    luckier counterparts.

    Te social consequences o a prolonged

    jobless period may be as signicant as the

    economic consequences. For example, the

    majority o studies on unemployment and

    crime suggest that a high unemployment rate

    is positively linked to increases in property

    crime.4 What is more, economists Naci

    Mocan and uran Bali ound that the connec-

    tion between joblessness and property crime

    is asymmetric: An increase in the unemploy-

    ment rate is accompanied by soaring property

    crime, while a decline in the unemployment

    rate is ollowed by only a gradual drop in

    property crime. Serious property crimes may

    urther damage the economic development

    and social welare in urban areas, especially

    in inner-city neighborhoods.

    A recent study by economists Dhaval

    Dave and Inas Rashad Kelly ound that an

    increase in the u nemployment rate results

    in negative changes in eating habits among

    a studied group o people with a high risk o

    unemployment. A 1 percent increase in the

    unemployment rate is associated with a 2-4

    percent reduction in the consumption o ruit

    and vegetables. Such a reduction in healthy

    ood potentially aects workers health in the

    long run. In low-income amilies, inadequate

    nutrition could aect the physical and mental

    development o children; the stress that aects

    the jobless parents also aects their children.Te welare o children in some communi-

    ties could be urther undermined because a

    high unemployment rate may aect amily

    stability by reinorcing the retreat rom

    marriage.5 In less-afuent communities,

    economic status has been a requirement or

    marriage. Less-educated people are even

    less likely to have a job when the unemploy-

    ment rate is high. Because o that, they nd

    it harder to meet the material threshold or

    marrying. Persistent joblessness may result

    in a permanent cultural change in some com-

    munities i marriage becomes a luxury good.

    A Long Road Ahead

    Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke

    said last all that job creation is probably

    the most important problem acing the U.S.

    economy. 6 As o January 2011, the U.S.

    economy needed roughly 6.8 million jobs to

    return to a 5 percent natural unemployment

    rate.7 Tis estimate is more complicated i

    population growth, the discouraged worker

    eect and the extension o unemployment

    benets are taken into account.

    Unemployed individuals who stop looking

    or a job are cal led discouraged workers and

    are not considered part o the labor orce.

    Discouraged workers may re-enter the labor

    market when the economic activity bounces

    back. A massive re-entry would temporarily

    raise the number o unemployed workers so

    that the unemployment rate could remain

    unchanged or rise even as payroll employ-

    ment increases.

    An extension o unemployment insurance

    would probably produce mixed eects on

    the job market.8 Such an extension could

    improve the eciency o matching workers

    with appropriate jobs. On the other hand,

    extended benets could discourage jobless

    workers rom accepting unattractive jobs,

    thus keeping the unemployment rate rela-

    tively high.

    aking these additional actors into

    account, i the economy immediately gener-

    ates 350,000 jobs a monththe pace o the late

    1990sour years would be needed to reach

    an unemployment rate o 5 percent, whereas

    at a rate o 210,000 jobs a monththe 2005

    pace11 years would be needed to achieve a

    5 percent unemployment rate.9 Regardless, the

    current recovery may be remembered as the

    third consecutive, and likely the most severe,

    jobless recovery. Te social consequences maybe as painul as economic consequences. A

    generation o childhoods, career paths, eating

    habits and marriage culture may be perma-

    nently altered.

    Natalia Kolesnikova is an economist andYang Liu is a research associate at the FederalReserve Bank o St. Louis. See http://research.stlouised.org/econ/kolesnikova/ or more onKolesnikovas work.

    Although the Great Recession ended inJune 2009 and overall economic activitys exhibited signs o recovery, labor market

    nditions remain disappointing. Payroll

    mployment has been recovering slowly; the

    erage duration o unemployment remains at

    historical high; and the unemployment rate

    projected to remain above 7.8 percent until

    13.1 Economists are concerned that the U.S.

    onomy is mired in another jobless recovery

    when economic activity experiences growth

    t the unemployment rate remains high.

    o determine the severity o current job-

    sness, it is useul to compare the current

    te o the labor market with that during

    evious economic recoveries. Te gure

    ows the U.S. unemployment rate during

    e past our recoveries alongside the cur rent

    covery. In the rst two cases, shortly aer

    e 1973-75 and 1981-82 recessions ended,

    e unemployment rate started to decline;

    months aer the end o these two reces-

    ns, the unemployment rate had dropped

    signicantly lower levels. Tese were not

    nsidered jobless recoveries. In contrast, in

    e wake o the t wo recessions in the 1990s

    d early 2000s, t he unemployment rate con-

    ued to increase 15 months aer the end o

    e recessions. Tese were jobless recoveries.

    Current developments in the labor market

    e similar to the jobless recovery cases. Sincee Great Recession ended in June 2009, the

    employment rate has remained high. It

    pped 10 percent in late 2009, remained

    ove 9.4 percent in 2010 and was still at

    9 percent in February 2011much higher

    an during any other recovery since the

    70s. Persistent and unusually high unem-

    oyment suggests that this jobless recovery

    ght be more painul than the previous two.

    12 9 6 3 0 3 6 9 1 2 15 1 8 21 2 4

    11

    10

    9

    8

    7

    6

    5

    4

    3

    1973-75

    1990-91

    PER

    CENT

    MONTHS FROM RECESSIONS END

    1981-82

    2001 Current

    Unemploment Rates ater Recent Recessions

    source: u.s. b l s

    Potential Causes o a Jobless Recover

    Many researchers have pointed to a labor

    market mismatch as one o the reasons or

    persistently high unemployment. Job growth

    polarization, industrial reallocation and

    organizational restructuring create a severe

    mismatch between available workers and

    appropriate job opportunit ies. Unemployed

    workers are orced to look or jobs in dierent

    occupations, industries and locations.

    MI Proessor David Autor examined

    U.S. employment opportunities over the

    past three decades. He ound that the U.S.

    employment growth has polarized into

    relatively high-skill, high-wage jobs and

    low-skill, low-wage jobs while middle-skillroutine jobs have diminishe d. So me routine

    jobs, such as administrative and operative

    positions, have been replaced by computer

    automation. Other routine jobs, such as

    bill-processing and manuacturing positions,

    have been moved overseas to take advantage

    o lower wages. Te Great Recession acceler-

    ated this trend: Employment in middle-skill

    and middle-wage occupations declined 7-17

    percent during the recession.2

    Job opportunities were also signicantly

    reallocated between industries, suggests

    a study by economists Erica Groshen and

    Simon Potter. Te 2007-09 nancial turmoil

    and housing crisis had severe impacts on

    industrial structure: During the recession,

    employment in the construction industrydropped 20 percent, and job opportunities

    in the nancial industry declined 6 percent.

    Tese industries continued to shrink aer the

    recovery began. By December 2010, payroll

    employment dropped an additional 7 percent

    in construction and 2 percent in the nancial

    industry. Manuacturing and inormation

    service industries were also badly aected.

    Demand in these industries may never return

    to prerecession levels; a portion o their job

    losses are likely to be permanent.

    Organizational restructuring, which leads

    to an elimination o unneeded labor, espe-

    cially by small rms, also creates structural

    change in job opportunities. During the

    Great Recession, small rms lost proportion-

    ately more jobs than larger rms: Te small

    rms accounted or about 10 percent o total

    net job loss despite their 5.3 percent employ-

    ment share.3 Small rms also take longer

    than large rms to rehire. Moreover, small

    rms are more likely to close during eco-

    nomic contraction; some o their job losses

    might be considered permanent. Re-c reatingthese jobs takes more time than rehiring.

    Consequences o a Jobless Recover

    Long periods o high u nemployment are

    without a doubt detrimental to u nemployed

    workers and to the health o the economy.

    However, there are other, less-known

    consequences.

    Yale economist Lisa Khan ound that col-

    lege graduates entering the job market during

    E N D N O T E S

    1 Te predicted unemployment rat

    the Survey o Proessional Foreca

    Federal Reserve Bank o Philadel2 Te statistics are adapted rom Au3 Relevant data are rom Business E

    Dynamics o the Bureau o Labor4 A good summary can be ound in

    and Ott.5 See Edin and Kealas or details.6 See Di Leo.7 Te Congressional Budget Oce

    that natural rate o unemploymen

    U.S. is 5 percent. It denes the na

    unemployment as the rate o un

    arising rom all sources except u

    aggregate demand. See Congres

    Oce.8 See El-Ghazaly.9 Te calculation is perormed base

    assumptions that population gro

    1 percent annual rate and labor o

    cipation rate returns to 66 percen

    2007 level). More inormation is

    upon request.

    R E F E R E N C E S

    Autor, David. Te Polariz ation o

    nities in the U.S. Labor Mar ket.

    Project, April 2010.

    Bureau o Labor Statistics Business E

    Dynamics. See www.bls.gov/bdm

    Congressional Budget Oce. Te B

    Economic Outlook: Fiscal Years 20

    January 2007.

    Dave, Dhaval M.; and Kelly, Inas Ra

    Does the Business Cycle Aect E

    NBER Working Paper No. 16638

    Bureau o Economic Research, D

    Di Leo, Luca. Bernanke: Job Creat

    Problem. Real ime Economics,

    Street Journal. Nov. 30, 2010.

    Edin, Kathryn; and Kealas, Maria.

    I Can Keep: Why Poor Women P

    hood beore Marriage. Berkeley:

    o Caliornia Press. 2005.

    El-Ghazaly, Hoda. Te Ins and Ou

    ployment Insurance. Federal Re

    o St. Louis Liber8 Economic Ino

    Newsletter, November 2010.

    Federal Reserve Bank o Philadelph

    Proessional Forecasters, First Qu

    See www.philadelphiaed.org/res

    data/real-time-center/survey-o-

    orecasters/2011/survq111.cm

    Garrett, Tomas A.; and Ott, Lesli S

    ness Cycles and Crime. Federal

    o St. Louis Working Paper 2008-

    July 2009.

    Groshen, Erica L.; and Potter, SimoStructural Change Contributed to

    Recovery? Fe deral Reserve Ban

    YorkCurrent Issues, August 2003

    No. 8, pp. 1-7.

    Kahn, Lis


Recommended