+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Regional Inequality and Branch Employment in Russia Between 1990 and 1995

Regional Inequality and Branch Employment in Russia Between 1990 and 1995

Date post: 21-Dec-2016
Category:
Upload: michael-paul
View: 213 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
13
This article was downloaded by: [Aston University] On: 29 January 2014, At: 09:59 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Post-Communist Economies Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cpce20 Regional Inequality and Branch Employment in Russia Between 1990 and 1995 Michael Paul Sacks Published online: 19 Aug 2010. To cite this article: Michael Paul Sacks (1999) Regional Inequality and Branch Employment in Russia Between 1990 and 1995, Post-Communist Economies, 11:2, 149-159, DOI: 10.1080/14631379995959 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14631379995959 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content. This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access
Transcript

This article was downloaded by: [Aston University]On: 29 January 2014, At: 09:59Publisher: RoutledgeInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number:1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street,London W1T 3JH, UK

Post-Communist EconomiesPublication details, including instructions forauthors and subscription information:http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/cpce20

Regional Inequality andBranch Employment in RussiaBetween 1990 and 1995Michael Paul SacksPublished online: 19 Aug 2010.

To cite this article: Michael Paul Sacks (1999) Regional Inequality and BranchEmployment in Russia Between 1990 and 1995, Post-Communist Economies, 11:2,149-159, DOI: 10.1080/14631379995959

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/14631379995959

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of allthe information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on ourplatform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensorsmake no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy,completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinionsand views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views ofthe authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis.The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should beindependently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor andFrancis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings,demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoeveror howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, inrelation to or arising out of the use of the Content.

This article may be used for research, teaching, and private studypurposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution,reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in anyform to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access

and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Ast

on U

nive

rsity

] at

09:

59 2

9 Ja

nuar

y 20

14

Post-Communist Economies, Vol. 11, No. 2, 1999

Regional Inequality and Branch Employment in Russia

Between 1990 and 1995

MICHAEL PAUL SACKS

Abstract

This article is based on 1990 ± 95 data on the number of workers in 14 branches of

the economy for most of Russia’ s regional divisions. This was a period during which

the total labour force shrank substantially, but change was clearly uneven across

branches. Branches that grew were likely to show an increase in the concentration

of workers in a limited number of regions, that is, growing regional inequality. A

closer look at the important area of credit, ® nance and insurance revealed the

extremely favourable position of Moscow and St Petersburg. Limited data on gender

differences suggest that, as in the past, men appear to bene® t more from change than

do women.

During the 1990s Russia experienced very dramatic change associated with the

dissolution of the former Soviet Union and the rapid movement toward a market

economy and privatisation. The bene® ts and losses associated with the change were

spread unevenly. This article explores evidence of regional disparities in economic

change as manifested by broad shifts in the labour force over the period from 1990

to 1995 and points to ways in which men and women may have contributed

differently to this regional inequality.

Entering the Post-Soviet Era

Political change came quickly at the beginning of the decade. Under El’ tsin’ s

leadership, as the new chairman of the presidium of the republic Supreme Soviet,

Russia declared its sovereignty in June 1990. The failed coup in August 1991, aimed

partly at stopping the course of economic reform, strengthened El’ tsin’ s position and

led to a policy of `radical political and social transformation’ . The Communist Party

was banned and its property con® scated. `The new liberal leadership promised

speedy marketisation and privatisation of the means of production. The new radical

leadership under El’ tsin did not negotiate with the deposed communist elite, they

Professo r Michael Paul Sacks, Department of Sociology , Trinity College, 300 Summit Street,Hartford , Connecticut 06106-3100 , USA. This is a revised version of a paper presented at the94th Annual Meeting of the Associatio n of American Geograph ers, 25±29 March 1998 , Boston,Massachuse tts. The autho r would like to express his apprecia tion to Carol Clark for very usefu lcomments on an earlier draft.

1463-1377/99/020149-11 Ó 1999 Centre for Research into Post-Communist Economies

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Ast

on U

nive

rsity

] at

09:

59 2

9 Ja

nuar

y 20

14

150 Michael Paul Sacks

destroyed it’ (Lane, 1996, p. 131). Gorbachev’ s resignation came on 25 December

1991; the USSR of® cially ceased to exist on 31 December.

Between 1992 and 1995 very signi ® cant privatisation took place. `The result was

that about two-thirds of the labour force was by late 1994 of ® cially employed outside

the state sector, on which, as recently as two years before, theyÐ as well as their

parents and, largely, their grandparentsÐ had been totally dependent’ (Connor, 1996,

p. 146). The change was of an entirely different dimension from the tentative reform

in this direction under Gorbachev that affected only small-scale enterprises, rarely

located outside Moscow and St Petersburg (Connor, 1996, p. 13). Large factories and

enterprises began to be privatised by late 1992 through a variety of programmes of

ownership transfer. Economic problems worsened in part because most of the

transfers did not bring increased cash resources for the ® rms. Connor has noted the

irony that clearing a space for entirely new economic institutions would probably

have required precisely what reformers sought to reverse: strong state intervention

(Connor , 1996, p. 148): `Yesterday’ s state enterprises, now joint-stock companies,

were largely run by insiders. Outside shareholders, individual or investment funds,

had less leverage and access than they would in a mature market economy’ . Burawoy

& Krotov (1992, p. 17) have similarly argued that there has been a `withering away

of the state’ without a revolutionary change in economic institutions.

The weakening of the role of the centre has certainly provided for greater

regional political autonomy, and this in turn has had signi ® cant economic conse-

quences. Clark (1996, p. 91) notes that regional elites have shaped privatisation

programmes and their local implementation in an effort to maintain control over the

region’ s resources. Regional groups have formed lobbies to promote their economic

interests and in¯ uence policies of the centre. Becker & Hemley (1996, p. 78) contend

that, in contrast with the situation during the Soviet period, when leverage on the

centre played a more critical role, regional growth should be more closely tied

to `endowment of scarce resources’ . Thus, `the regions with booming industr ial

and housing construction are, in many cases, oblasti which were not previously

favoured’ . Le Houerou & Rutkowski (1996) found that as government ® scal respon-

sibilities shifted from the centre to regions, there had been a sharp increase in

regional differences in per capita revenue and expenditure. They provide evidence

that intergovernmental transfers have failed to reduce regional inequality.

Contemporary regional differences, however, surely stem in large part from

fundamental features of the Soviet economic system. Clark (1996, p. 91) predicts that

restructuring should bring about signi ® cant regional disparities, because

industr ial activity and employment structures in the former Soviet Union

were both relatively highly concentrated and relatively specialised at the

regional level. Hence, as a consequence of the combined effects of

anticipated sectoral shifts in GDP and the highly specialised regional

production of the Soviet period, the potential for economic growth should

differ signi ® cantly across regions (Clark, 1996, p. 91).

Data

Recently published data for 14 branches of the economy make it possible to measure

the unevenness of regional change. The data are less precise than information on

occupations, as the same occupations can appear across many different branches

(Sacks, 1986, pp. 98±99). Some change over time can result from a reclassi® cation

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Ast

on U

nive

rsity

] at

09:

59 2

9 Ja

nuar

y 20

14

Regional Inequality and Employment in Russia 151

of workers. Privatisation is likely to have resulted, for example, in some service

sector workers previously counted in the industr ial branch of the economy now being

counted in trade or housing or other branches. A virtue of the data set, however, is

that it is available for detailed regions and for all years between 1990 and 1995.

The Russian Federation is divided into 89 regions1

grouped into nine divisions

plus Kaliningrad oblast’ . There were no data for branch employment for nine of the

10 autonomous okruga , although in most cases the employed populat ion of the

autonomous okrug was included among those in the respective krai or oblast’ of

which the autonomous okrug was a constituent part.2

The now separate Chechen and

Ingush republics were combined, reducing the number to 79. Selecting only those

regions for which data were available for all years between 1990 and 1995 further

reduced the number to 72.3 These 72 regions accurately re¯ ect the situation in

Russia, as the 7 omitted regions accounted for less than 2% of the country’ s total

labour force.

More problematic, however, is the fact that the total employed for Russia was

greater that the sum of the total employed in the constituent regional divisions.4 The

discrepancy appears to be attributable to an undercount in the number of workers in

agriculture distributed across regional divisions. Agriculture was the only one of the

14 branches where the sum of the ® gures for the regional divisions (plus Kaliningrad

oblast’ ) was lower than the ® gure recorded for Russia as a whole.5

In 1990 11% of

agricultural workers were missing; this grew each year to reach 19% by 1995. In

other words, information on the regional location of nearly one in ® ve agricultural

workers was missing by 1995. These missing agricultural workers, however,

amounted to only 1.4% of Russia’ s total labour force in 1990 and 2.8% in 1995. It

could have been that these agricultural workers were migrants and were not counted

in any single region, but there was neither acknowledgement of the discrepancy nor

explanation for it in the statistical publications.

In 1990 there were 8.6 million employed in agriculture in the selected 72 regions

of Russia. This rose to 8.7 million in 1993 before falling by 1 million in 1995.

Between 1990 and 1995 the percentage of all employed who were in agriculture

grew slightly from 11.7% to 12.1%. The ® gures for Russia as a whole, by contrast,

showed 9.7 million in agriculture in both 1990 and 1995 (with a slight rise in the

intervening years); the percentage in agriculture rose from 12.9% to 14.7%. Thus,

regional comparisons of agriculture may not be as accurate as they are for other

branches of the economy.

A Change in the Labour Force and Regional Variation

Between 1990 and 1995 Russia’ s labour force declined from 75.3 million to 66.4

million, a decrease of 11.8%. This compared with a 13.7% decrease (from 73.8 to

63.7 million) in the 72 selected regions. The difference in the percentage declines can

largely be attributed to the discrepancy in the count of agricultural workers. This

section uses the data from the 72 regions to show the interconnection between the

change over time in the number of workers by branch of the total economy and the

change in the way branch workers were distributed across Russia’ s regions. In other

words, how did growth or decline in a branch in¯ uence the regional concentration of

branch workers?

The ® rst three columns of Table 1 show the distribution of the employed

population across the 14 branches of the economy at three points in time: 1990, 1992

and 1995. The branches were sorted by the change in the number working in the

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Ast

on U

nive

rsity

] at

09:

59 2

9 Ja

nuar

y 20

14

152 Michael Paul Sacks

branch between 1990 and 1995 (column 4). Most signi ® cant were the declines in

industry (down 5.7 million) and construction (down 2.8 million) . Between 1990 and

1992 the two branches combined fell from 43% to 41% of the labour force and were

down to 36% by 1995. Change overall, as the discussion above suggests, was far

more rapid after 1992. The ® rst four branches, all in the service sector, showed the

largest increases in their share of the labour force (column 5). General business was

not even listed as a branch until 1992.

The coef® cient of variation is a common measure of dispersion and is used here

for each branch. The measure is simply the standard deviation divided by the mean

and thus permits comparison across branches where the average numbers of workers

differ substantially (Silver, 1974; Le Houerou & Rutkowski, 1996) . Columns 7 to 9

show the coef® cients by branch for 1990, 1992 and 1995. Column 11 shows that

between 1990 and 1995 the coef® cients increased in nine of the 14 branches as well

as for the labour force as a whole.

There is another measure of change that is also useful here: the index of

dissimilarity. Change in the coef® cient of variation measures the degree to which

branch workers have become more or less concentrated in a limited number of

regions; the index of dissimilarity shows simply the extent of change in the way

branch workers were distributed across regions when comparing two points in time.

The two measures need not be related. For example, there can be a large shift of

branch workers across regions without any change in overall dispersion; more

concentration of branch workers in a few regions could be associated with a

relatively large change or with a small change over time in the regions where branch

workers were found. The measure of dissimilarity in Table 1 (column 12) can be

interpreted as the propor tion of workers in the particular branch in 1995 that would

have to move to another region if the workers were to be distributed exactly as they

had been in 1990 (or 1992 in the case of general business).6

The direction of change was unmistakable. First, the more change between 1990

and 1995 in the regional location of branch workers, the greater the dispersion of

workers across regions. The index of dissimilarity by branch (column 12) showed a

0.98 correlation with branch increases in the coef® cient of variation (column 11).

Second, increased overall labour force concentration in a branch was directly

associated with greater regional dispersion of the workers in that branch. Over the

period from 1990 to 1995 this was shown by a 0.49 correlation (0.55 over the period

1992±95) between increase in the coef® cient of variation (column 11) and column 6,

change in the propor tion of the labour force concentrated in the branch (expressed

as a percentage increase or decrease over the 1995 ® gure). Put simply, shifts over

time in the geographical and branch location of the labour force were increasing

regional differences.

Credit, Finance and Insurance

A closer look at credit, ® nance and insurance (line two of Table 1) shows the regions

that have bene® ted most from the change. What makes this branch particularly

worthy of consideration is the fact that between 1990 and 1995 the coef® cient of

variation increased sharply and that the branch showed a large increase (second

highest) in the number of workers (up 409 000).

Table 2 shows the 15 regions that contained the largest numbers of workers in

credit, ® nance and insurance in 1995. Fourteen of these regions were also among

those with the largest gain in workers in the branch between 1990 and 1995.7

Data

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Ast

on U

nive

rsity

] at

09:

59 2

9 Ja

nuar

y 20

14

Regional Inequality and Employment in Russia 153

Ta

ble

1.

Dis

trib

uti

on

acro

ssbra

nch

es

of

the

eco

nom

yfo

rth

e72

reg

ions

an

dm

easu

res

of

ch

an

ge

an

dv

ari

abil

ity

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10

)(1

1)

(12)

Co

ef®

cie

nt

Ind

ex

of

Dis

trib

uti

on

(%)

Ch

ang

eC

han

ge

inD

istr

ibuti

on

of

Vari

ati

on

(V)

Chan

ge

inV

dis

sem

ilari

ty

(in

000

s)co

mp

arin

g

Bra

nch

of

the

eco

no

my

19

90

199

21

99

51

99

95

199

95

**

199

95

**

*19

90

19

92

199

51

99

95

19

90±

95

19

90

wit

h19

95

Tra

de,

pu

bli

cca

teri

ng

,sa

les

7.9

08

.00

10.3

67

72

.32

9%

31%

0.8

50

.85

1.1

60

.30

0.3

117

Cre

dit

nan

ce,

insu

rance

0.5

40

.70

1.2

74

09

.38

2%

13

4%

0.7

30

.77

1.4

20

.65

0.6

926

Genera

lbu

sin

ess*

0.0

00

.30

0.6

23

96

.111

0%

11

0%

2.3

85

.50

3.1

23

.12

86

Adm

inis

trati

on

2.4

32

.14

3.1

01

80

.24

5%

27%

1.0

21

.06

0.8

12

0.2

52

0.2

116

Heal

th,

ph

ysi

cal

trai

nin

g,

socia

lse

curi

ty5

.70

5.9

66.8

71

71

.11

5%

21%

0.8

50

.80

0.8

10

.02

20

.04

7

Fo

rest

ry0

.32

0.3

30.4

016

.32

1%

24%

0.6

30

.62

0.6

20

.00

20

.02

14

Info

rmati

on

and

com

pu

tin

gse

rvic

es0

.25

0.1

70.1

22

106

.22

29

%2

52%

2.0

41

.86

3.1

01

.23

1.0

638

Hou

sin

g,

ev

eryd

ay

serv

ices

4.3

34

.23

4.6

12

258

.29

%6%

0.8

60

.80

0.8

60

.05

0.0

08

Tra

nsp

ort

and

com

mu

nic

atio

ns

7.8

37

.95

8.1

52

586

.13

%4%

0.8

10

.79

0.8

40

.05

0.0

38

Oth

er

bra

nch

es2

.64

2.5

62.1

42

588

.02

17

%2

19%

1.1

50

.89

1.4

40

.54

0.2

926

Agri

cult

ure

11

.67

12

.41

12.1

32

885

.72

2%

4%

0.7

30

.74

0.7

70

.03

0.0

49

Ed

ucat

ion

,art

s,sc

ien

ce13

.50

13

.89

13.9

52

10

79

.30

%3%

1.3

11

.24

1.1

42

0.1

02

0.1

79

Co

nst

ruct

ion

12

.13

11

.15

9.6

32

28

24

.92

14

%2

21%

0.8

20

.86

1.1

10

.25

0.2

920

Indu

stry

30

.74

30

.22

26.6

52

57

16

.82

12

%2

13%

0.7

90

.77

0.8

00

.03

0.0

17

To

tal

emplo

yed

100

.00

10

0.0

010

0.0

02

10

099

.90.7

90

.77

0.8

50

.09

0.0

75

So

urc

e:

Go

sko

mst

at

Ross

ii,

Tru

di

Za

nyato

st’

vR

oss

ii(M

osc

ow

,1

99

6),

pp.

20

,2

28

±3

16

.

*D

ata

for

the

bra

nch

of

genera

lbu

sin

ess

are

mis

sin

gfo

r1

99

0.

Co

mp

aris

on

sof

199

2and

19

95

are

sub

stit

ute

dfo

rcom

pari

son

sof

199

0and

19

95

.

**T

he

chang

ebetw

een

199

2(c

olu

mn

2)

an

d19

95

(co

lum

n3

)ex

pre

ssed

asa

perc

enta

ge

of

the

®g

ure

in19

92

.

**

*T

he

chang

ebetw

een

199

0(c

olu

mn

1)

an

d19

95

(co

lum

n3

)ex

pre

ssed

asa

perc

enta

ge

of

the

®g

ure

in19

90

.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Ast

on U

nive

rsity

] at

09:

59 2

9 Ja

nuar

y 20

14

154 Michael Paul Sacks

Table 2. Fifteen regions with the largest number in credit, ® nance and insurance in

1995

Credit, ® nance, insurance Total employed

Number (in 000s) Index (1990 5 100) Number (in 000s) Index (1990 5 100) Rank

in

Region 1990 1992 1995 1990 1992 1995 1995

Moscow City 28.5 127 466 5196.6 91 100 1

St Petersburg city 8.9 147 365 2653.0 90 88 3

Sverdlovsk oblast’ 11.3 123 231 2423.6 92 84 4

Krasnodar krai 13.3 135 196 2297.9 90 87 5

Tyumen’ oblast’ 10.7 117 226 1769.4 91 96 9

Moscow oblast’ 12.2 144 191 2926.5 93 83 2

Samara oblast’ 8.7 131 259 1690.3 97 92 11

Rostov oblast’ 12.3 116 166 2256.4 98 84 6

Krasnoyarsk krai 11.1 110 175 1880.6 83 74 13

Bashkortostan 10.2 122 179 1953.7 97 89 8

Nizhnegorod oblast’ 9.5 121 182 1935.2 96 91 7

Tatarstan 9.4 120 183 1894.3 97 89 10

Kemerovo oblast’ 9.0 114 173 1611.6 96 84 15

Novosibirsk oblast’ 7.1 130 210 1414.5 96 85 18

Perm’ oblast’ 7.9 120 184 1575.0 96 87 14

15 regions above 170.1 125 250 33 478.6 93 89

57 other regions 229.6 118 167 40 377.2 95 84

All 72 regions 399.7 121 202 73 855.8 94 86

42.6% 44.0% 52.6% 45.3% 44.8% 46.6%15 as a % of all 72

Source: as Table 1.

for the 72 regions show that the number of workers in credit, ® nance and insurance

in 1990 was very closely correlated (r 5 0.83) with the increase in the number in the

next ® ve years. The growth in the branch was also highly correlated with the total

labour force size in both 1990 (r 5 0.80) and 1995 (r 5 0.85). Thus, large regions

were clearly favoured in this important emerging sector of the economy. (Change in

the total labour force of a region between 1990 and 1995, however, was unrelated to

change in the number in this branch [r 5 2 0.025]) .

The regions in Table 2 are sorted by size in 1995. The rank order was different

in 1990 (see column 1), but the only substitute would have been Chelyabinsk oblast’

instead of Perm’ oblast’ . The most signi ® cant change in ranking was the movement

of St Petersburg from thirteenth place in 1990 to second place in 1995. The index

® gures in columns 2 and 3 show again that real growth occurred primarily after

1992.

To put the branch growth in perspective, the right half of Table 2 contains ® gures

for the total employed population in each of the regions. Moscow’ s work force

increased by two-tenths of a percent between 1990 and 1995. Moscow was the only

region among all 72 that witnessed growth in its labour force. The 15 regions ranked

among the top 18 in size of the total labour force in 1995 (see the last column).

The contrast between these 15 regions and the remainder of Russia is shown by

® gures in the bottom lines of Table 2. Credit, ® nance and insurance increased

2.5-fold in the 15 regions, compared with only 1.6-fold in the remaining 57 regions.

Consequently, the percentage of all those employed in credit, ® nance and insurance

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Ast

on U

nive

rsity

] at

09:

59 2

9 Ja

nuar

y 20

14

Regional Inequality and Employment in Russia 155

who were located in the 15 regions increased by 10 points to 53% between 1990 and

1995. The labour force as a whole, by contrast, became only slightly more concen-

trated in these regions.

Aggregating the 15 regions understates the narrowness of change. By 1995 the

top three regions in size of total labour force were Moscow, Moscow oblast’ (minus

the city of Moscow) and St Petersburg, in that order. These three regions alone

clearly accounted for a great deal of the increase in regional inequality. Those

employed in credit, ® nance and insurance who resided in the three regions combined

rose from one-eighth (12.4%) in 1990 to nearly one-quarter (23.3%) by 1995.

Other branches also show the importance of these three regions. The very high

coef® cient of variation for general business can be explained by the fact that the

three regions were home to one-third of those employed in this branch in 1992; a

® gure which rose to 72% by 1995. Information and computing services had the third

largest increase in the coef® cient of variation, and here again the three regions were

important. For reasons which are not clear, this seemingly important branch actually

showed a sharp decline in size between 1990 and 1995. Over the same period there

was an increase from 30% to 44% of all information and computing service workers

located in the three regions.

Gender and Change

Finally, there is an important gender dimension to the change that has taken place,

although the data permit only a very partial examination of this. Past research on the

former Soviet republics showed greater regional variation in the male labour force

than among females, and that men and women did not bene® t equally from economic

change (Sacks, 1982) . These trends are also likely to exist across Russia’ s regions.

During the 1990s gender differences have been enhanced in Russia by the

rejection of the more egalitarian ideology of the Soviet period and the curtailment

and increased cost of many social services. Women are also having to cope with

problems that have carried over from the Soviet period. State priorities had left an

atrophied service sector and consequently an enormous burden of domestic labour

that women continue to shoulder. Women were squeezed out of key industr ial areas

that afforded greater prestige, higher pay and greater opportunity for advancement.

High-achieving women often ended up in white-collar sectors deeply imbedded in

the state bureaucracy and thus most imbued with the defects of the systemÐ sti¯ ed

personal initiative and little room for exercising or building upon professional

training. `Working women’ , according to a Russian source, `were the ª most social-

istº element of Soviet society’ (Babaeva, 1996, p. 25).

For many women this past was a serious liability in a market economy. In the

least ef® cient sectors of state employment (health, education, culture, scienti® c

institutions as well as government planning), areas ® rst to be cut as the economic

crisis worsened, the majority of workers were women (Babaeva, 1996, p. 45).

Rzhanitsina & Sergeeva (1995, p. 57) note that industr ies that employ a large

propor tion of women have tended to decline sharply, while those branches of

industry with a preponderance of men have either grown or remained stable.

Discrimination against women certainly existed in the past, but today it can be

open and explicit (Bridger, Kay & Pinnick, 1996, p. 80):

A casual glance at the `situation vacant’ columns and specialist jobs

supplements con® rms the proposition that there is marked preference for

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Ast

on U

nive

rsity

] at

09:

59 2

9 Ja

nuar

y 20

14

156 Michael Paul Sacks

men on the part of employers in the new Russian labour market. Nearly all

the most prestigious professional jobs advertised baldly state that they are

looking for male applicants only. In addition, many vacancies for skilled

manual workers, such as joiners, lathe-operators, ® tters and technicians

have similar men-only speci® cations. Where women are designated as

preferred applicants it is usually for secretarial jobs and other relatively

low-level of ® ce staff.

The regional data on the numbers by branch of the economy show no breakdown by

gender. Changes for men and women are available for Russia as a whole, although

the branches are somewhat different from those used above (see Table 3). Particu-

larly important was the overall difference in the way economic decline has affected

men and women. Between 1990 and 1995 the number of employed females fell by

19%, compared with a 5% decline for men.

More importantly, women who remained employed shifted their distribution

across branches in a way that was very different from men. Industry shrank more

than any other branch, but this was largely due to women leaving (see columns 5±7).

Women comprised three-quarters of the 5.6 million fall in the number of industr ial

workers. Industry had been nearly half female in 1990, but the percentage female fell

by nearly 12 points by 1995. The largest male decline was from construction,

although the out¯ ow of women was suf ® cient to reduce females among construction

workers from 27% to 23%.

The largest increase for males was in trade, public catering and sales. This was

the branch which had the greatest increase in the total number of workers. While

growing by 1.3 million men, however, it shrank by half a million women. As a

consequence, the percentage female fell by 17 points between 1990 and 1995, more

than any other branch.

Credit, ® nance and insurance was the area with the next highest growth. Though

the numerical growth of females exceeded that of males, males were starting at a far

lower number. Males showed a 5-fold increase, compared with slightly more than a

doubling of females. The result was that the percentage female fell by 15 points.

The second largest growth of females was in education, culture and artsÐ an area

where there was a net male loss. The only other area with a substantial female net

gain was in health, physical training and social security. It is signi ® cant that these

two are branches with a falling coef® cient of variation for the 72 regions. While the

number of women did grow in credit, ® nance and insurance, where the coef® cient of

variation increased, in this branch males showed a propor tionately far greater

increase.

Unfortunately data on the gender composition are missing for the two categories

with the largest growth in coef® cient of variation: general business and information

and computing services. However, other sources suggest that women have had very

low representation among the new entrepreneurs (Babaeva, 1996, Chapter 3; Bruno,

1997; Bridger, Kay & Pinnick, 1996, Chapter 6).

Overall, women are far more likely than men to be displaced from the labour

force and men appear to be shifting much more rapidly than women into newly

expanding branches. Thus, regional variation is likely to be far more attributable to

the employment patterns of men than of women.

Conclusion

Although there is only limited information provided by the very broad branch

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Ast

on U

nive

rsity

] at

09:

59 2

9 Ja

nuar

y 20

14

Regional Inequality and Employment in Russia 157

Ta

ble

3.

Gen

der

co

mpo

siti

on

by

bra

nch

of

the

eco

no

my

inR

uss

ia,

19

90

±19

95

Nu

mber

(in

00

0s)

Men

Wom

enC

hang

e1

99

0±9

5P

ercen

tag

efe

mal

e

Bra

nch

of

the

econ

om

y1

99

01

99

519

90

19

95

Mal

es

Fem

ales

Tota

l1

99

01

99

5P

oin

tch

ange

Ind

ust

ry11

86

110

38

21

09

48

68

00

21

47

92

41

48

256

27

48

.03

9.6

28

.4

Con

stru

ctio

n6

58

54

77

324

35

14

35

21

81

22

10

00

228

12

27

.02

3.1

23

.9

Ag

ricu

lture

and

fore

stry

607

96

64

338

86

33

60

56

42

526

38

39

.03

3.6

25

.4

Tra

nsp

ort

370

03

25

812

34

11

20

24

42

21

14

25

56

25

.02

5.6

0.6

Oth

erb

ran

ches

171

21

69

44

34

16

02

18

22

74

22

92

20

.28

.62

11

.6

Edu

cati

on

,cu

ltu

re,

and

arts

161

31

54

656

18

57

70

267

152

85

77

.77

8.9

1.2

Ho

usi

ng

,ev

eryd

ayse

rvic

es1

55

71

67

916

60

13

00

12

22

360

22

38

51

.64

3.6

28

.0

Sci

ence

and

scie

nti

®c

serv

ices

131

882

714

86

86

12

491

26

25

211

16

53

.05

1.0

22

.0

Tra

de,

pu

bli

cca

teri

ng,

sale

s1

17

42

50

146

95

41

78

132

72

517

81

08

0.0

62

.62

17

.4

Hea

lth,

ph

ysi

cal

trai

nin

g,

socia

lse

curi

ty72

081

835

18

36

28

98

110

20

88

3.0

81

.62

1.4

Ad

min

istr

atio

n59

679

812

10

12

15

20

25

20

76

7.0

60

.46.6

Com

mun

icati

on

s25

628

96

28

58

63

32

42

29

71

.06

7.0

24

.1

Cre

dit

nan

ce,

insu

ran

ce4

020

53

62

61

516

52

53

41

89

0.0

75

.02

15

.0

Tota

lem

plo

yed

37

21

135

41

33

81

14

31

02

82

179

82

70

86

288

84

50

.64

6.7

23

.9

So

urc

e:G

osk

om

stat

Ross

ii,

Tru

di

Za

nya

tost

’v

Ro

ssii

(Mo

sco

w,

199

6),

pp.

20,

228

±31

6.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Ast

on U

nive

rsity

] at

09:

59 2

9 Ja

nuar

y 20

14

158 Michael Paul Sacks

categories, the data point strongly to an association between current labour force

change and growing regional differences. Moscow and St Petersburg have been

especially favoured, but there is evidence of an economic advantage associated with

the scale of a region’ s employed populat ion. Finally, gender differences are increas-

ing. Men appear more involved in the changing sectors of the economy and,

therefore, variation across regions may be much greater among males than among

females.

Notes

1. These consis t of `21 republic s, 50 oblasti , 6 kraya (nativ e lands) , and 10 autonomous

okruga , plus two metropoli tan cities (Moscow and St Petersbur g)’ (Le Houerou &

Rutkowski, 1996 , p. 22).

2. Data were availabl e only for the Chukotk a autonomous okrug , althoug h ® gures were

missing for both 1990 and 1991.

3. The region s for which data were missing for eithe r or both 1990 and 1991 were Adygei

Republic , Karachai- Cherkess Republic, Altai Republic , Khakass Republic , Jewish

Autonom ous oblast’ and Chukotka Autonomous okrug . In addition , data for Chechen -

Ingush Republic were availabl e only for 1990 .

4. This is not due to missing data for any of the regions . Using the sum of the major

regiona l units plus Kaliningrad avoids the problem of some omitted regiona l division s,

as each regiona l division apparent ly included the total number of worker s in all the

constituent regions, whether or not separate data were shown for them.

5. For branches other than agriculture there were some small discrepancies between the sum

of the regiona l division s and the ® gures for Russia as a whole. These could easily be

explained by roundin g errors , as the numbers employed for the region s were availabl e to

the neares t hundred and the numbers for Russia were to the neares t thousand .

6. The index of dissimilarity is calculate d from the difference between the proport ion of

branch worker s at one poin t in time and the proport ion of the worker s of the same branch

at a second poin t in time in each of the 72 regions . The index equals one-hal f the sum

of these absolute differences times 100 (see Duncan & Duncan , 1955).

7. Omsk oblast’ replaced Kemerovo oblast’ among those with the largest increase .

References

Babaeva , L.V., Zhenshchi ny Rossii v usloviya kh sotsial ’ nogo pereloma: Rabota, politika ,

povsedne vnaya zhizn’ (Moscow, Rossiiski i obshches tvenny i nauchyi fond , 1996) .

Becker, Charles M. & Hemley, David D., `Interregional Inequali ty in Russia During the

Transitio n Period ’ , Comparative Economic Studies, 38, 1, 1996 , pp. 55±81.

Bridger , Sue, Kay, Rebecca & Pinnick, Kathryn , No More Heroines? : Russia , Women and the

Market (London , Routledge, 1996) .

Bruno, Marta, `Women and the Culture of Entrepreneurship’ , in Mary Buckley (ed.) ,

Post-Sovi et Women: From the Baltic to Central Asia (Cambridge, Cambridge University

Press, 1997) , pp. 56±74.

Burawoy, Michael & Krotov, Pavel, `The Soviet Transition from Socialism to Capitalism:

Worker Contro l and Economic Bargaining in the Wood Industry’ , American Sociological

Review , 57, February 1992 , pp. 16±38.

Clark , Carol L., `The Transfor mation of Labor Relations in Russian Industry : The In¯ uence

of Regiona l Factor s in the Iron and Steel Industry’ , Post-Sovi et Geography and

Econom ics, 37, 2, 1996, pp. 88±112.

Connor, Walter D., Tattered Banners: Labor Con¯ ict and Corporati sm in Postcommunist

Russia (Boulder , Colorado , Westview Press, 1996) .

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Ast

on U

nive

rsity

] at

09:

59 2

9 Ja

nuar

y 20

14

Regional Inequality and Employment in Russia 159

Duncan, Otis D. & Duncan , Beverly , `A Methodological Analysis of Segregati on Indexes ’ ,

American Sociolog ical Review , 20, 1955 , pp. 210±217.

Goskomstat Rossii, Trud i zanyatos t’ v Rossii. Statistic heskii sbornik (Moscow, 1996) .

Lane, David , The Rise and Fall of State Socialism (Cambridge , Polity Press, 1996) .

Le Houerou , Phillipp e & Rutkowski, Michal, `Federa l Transfer s in Russia: Their Impact on

Regiona l Revenues and Incomes’ , Comparative Economic Studies, 38, Summer/Fall,

1996 , pp. 21±44.

Rzhanitsi na, L.S . & Sergeeva , G.P., `Zhenshchi ny na Rossiisko m rynke truda ’ , Sotsiolo gich-

eskie issledovaniya, 1995, 7, pp. 57±62.

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Ast

on U

nive

rsity

] at

09:

59 2

9 Ja

nuar

y 20

14


Recommended