+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global...

Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global...

Date post: 07-Apr-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 8 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
9
Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global Form in the Presence of the Negative Data in DEA Ghasem Tohidi, 1 Shabnam Razavyan, 2 and Simin Tohidnia 1 1 Department of Mathematics, Islamic Azad University, Central Tehran Branch, Tehran, Iran 2 Department of Mathematics, Islamic Azad University, South Tehran Branch, Tehran, Iran Correspondence should be addressed to Ghasem Tohidi; [email protected] Received 8 January 2014; Accepted 7 August 2014; Published 31 August 2014 Academic Editor: Farhad Hosseinzadeh Lotfi Copyright © 2014 Ghasem Tohidi et al. is is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. is paper first introduces the allocative and profit efficiency in the presence of the negative data and then presents a new circular index to measure the productivity change of decision making units (DMUs) for the case that the dataset contains the inputs and/or outputs with the negative values in data envelopment analysis (DEA). e proposed index is decomposed into four components in the two stages. e range directional model (RDM) and the proposed efficiencies are used to compute the proposed index and its components. e interpretations of the components are presented. Finally, a numerical example is organized to illustrate the proposed index and its components at three successive periods of time. 1. Introduction e Malmquist productivity index which measures the pro- ductivity change over time was introduced by Caves et al. [1]. Fare et al. [2] developed the Malmquist productivity index that was based on data envelopment analysis (DEA). e Malmquist index can be applied in many fields [3, 4]. By using Malmquist index, the productivity growth can be decomposed into the efficiency change and technical change components. e second component measures the shiſt in the technology frontier. Pastor and Lovell [5] suggested the global Malmquist productivity index that is circular and can be decomposed into the circular components. e global index and the meta- Malmquist index developed in Portela and anassoulis [6]. In addition, Hosseinzadeh Lotfi et al. developed the new ideas about Malmquist index in [7, 8]. Maniadakis and anassoulis [9] assumed the input cost vector is known and suggested the cost Malmquist index. Tohidi et al. [10] extended the cost Malmquist index into the profit Malmquist index that is used when the input cost and the output price vector are available. en, Tohidi and Razavyan [11] proposed the global profit Malmquist index. e cost Malmquist index was also developed in Tohidi et al. [12] and is called the global cost Malmquist productivity index. Sometimes in the process of production negative inputs and/or outputs may occur. For example, DMUs may generate undesirable outputs. In such a case, negative values can be considered for these undesirable outputs. Instances of systems with negative inputs and/or outputs are explained in [13, 14]. e traditional DEA models can be applied to compute the Malmquist index with the nonnegative data. ey cannot deal with the negative data. Portela et al. [15] presented an approach named the range directional model (RDM) and solved this problem. ey calculated the meta- Malmquist index using the RDM model in Portela and anassoulis [16]. To investigate the productivity change of DMUs with the negative data, this paper defines the profit and allocative efficiency and introduces an index to measure the productiv- ity changes of DMUs when some inputs and/or outputs are negative and the costs of inputs and the prices of outputs are available. en, the proposed index is decomposed into some components in the two stages. e range directional model (RDM) and the proposed efficiencies are used to compute the proposed index and its components. Hindawi Publishing Corporation Journal of Applied Mathematics Volume 2014, Article ID 276092, 8 pages http://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2014/276092
Transcript
Page 1: Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/jam/2014/276092.pdf · Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global Form in the

Research ArticleProfit Malmquist Index and Its Global Form inthe Presence of the Negative Data in DEA

Ghasem Tohidi,1 Shabnam Razavyan,2 and Simin Tohidnia1

1 Department of Mathematics, Islamic Azad University, Central Tehran Branch, Tehran, Iran2Department of Mathematics, Islamic Azad University, South Tehran Branch, Tehran, Iran

Correspondence should be addressed to Ghasem Tohidi; [email protected]

Received 8 January 2014; Accepted 7 August 2014; Published 31 August 2014

Academic Editor: Farhad Hosseinzadeh Lotfi

Copyright © 2014 Ghasem Tohidi et al.This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License,which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

This paper first introduces the allocative and profit efficiency in the presence of the negative data and then presents a new circularindex to measure the productivity change of decision making units (DMUs) for the case that the dataset contains the inputs and/oroutputs with the negative values in data envelopment analysis (DEA). The proposed index is decomposed into four componentsin the two stages. The range directional model (RDM) and the proposed efficiencies are used to compute the proposed index andits components. The interpretations of the components are presented. Finally, a numerical example is organized to illustrate theproposed index and its components at three successive periods of time.

1. Introduction

The Malmquist productivity index which measures the pro-ductivity change over time was introduced by Caves et al.[1]. Fare et al. [2] developed the Malmquist productivityindex that was based on data envelopment analysis (DEA).The Malmquist index can be applied in many fields [3, 4].By using Malmquist index, the productivity growth can bedecomposed into the efficiency change and technical changecomponents.The second componentmeasures the shift in thetechnology frontier.

Pastor and Lovell [5] suggested the global Malmquistproductivity index that is circular and can be decomposedinto the circular components.The global index and the meta-Malmquist index developed in Portela and Thanassoulis [6].In addition,Hosseinzadeh Lotfi et al. developed the new ideasabout Malmquist index in [7, 8].

Maniadakis and Thanassoulis [9] assumed the input costvector is known and suggested the cost Malmquist index.Tohidi et al. [10] extended the cost Malmquist index intothe profit Malmquist index that is used when the input costand the output price vector are available. Then, Tohidi andRazavyan [11] proposed the global profit Malmquist index.The cost Malmquist index was also developed in Tohidi et

al. [12] and is called the global cost Malmquist productivityindex.

Sometimes in the process of production negative inputsand/or outputs may occur. For example, DMUsmay generateundesirable outputs. In such a case, negative values canbe considered for these undesirable outputs. Instances ofsystems with negative inputs and/or outputs are explainedin [13, 14]. The traditional DEA models can be applied tocompute the Malmquist index with the nonnegative data.They cannot deal with the negative data. Portela et al. [15]presented an approach named the range directional model(RDM) and solved this problem. They calculated the meta-Malmquist index using the RDM model in Portela andThanassoulis [16].

To investigate the productivity change of DMUs with thenegative data, this paper defines the profit and allocativeefficiency and introduces an index to measure the productiv-ity changes of DMUs when some inputs and/or outputs arenegative and the costs of inputs and the prices of outputs areavailable.Then, the proposed index is decomposed into somecomponents in the two stages. The range directional model(RDM) and the proposed efficiencies are used to compute theproposed index and its components.

Hindawi Publishing CorporationJournal of Applied MathematicsVolume 2014, Article ID 276092, 8 pageshttp://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2014/276092

Page 2: Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/jam/2014/276092.pdf · Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global Form in the

2 Journal of Applied Mathematics

The current paper unfolds as follows. Section 2 describesthe RDM. In Section 3 the global Malmquist productivityindex is expressed. Section 4 defines the profit and the alloca-tive efficiency for the DMUs with some negative inputs andoutputs and then suggests a new index. The decompositionand the theorem of circularity property of the proposed indexand its components are presented in Section 5. Section 6prepares some DEA models to compute the proposed indexand its components. Section 7 provides a numerical example.Section 8 concludes.

2. The Range Directional Model

Portela et al. [15] introduced the RDM to compare DMUsunder the negative data. Assume that, in time period 𝑡 (𝑡 =1, . . . , 𝑇) and 𝑗th unit (𝑗 = 1, . . . , 𝑛) consumes an inputvector 𝑥𝑡

𝑗= (𝑥𝑡

1𝑗, 𝑥𝑡

2𝑗, . . . , 𝑥

𝑡

𝑚𝑗) to produce an output vector

𝑦𝑡

𝑗= (𝑦𝑡

1𝑗, 𝑦𝑡

2𝑗, . . . , 𝑦

𝑡

𝑠𝑗). We consider an ideal point (IP) for the

time period 𝑡 with the minimum inputs and the maximumoutputs observed in this time period, where for each input𝑖 (𝑖 = 1, . . . , 𝑚) and IP

𝑖is as min

𝑗{𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑗} and for each output

𝑟 (𝑟 = 1, . . . , 𝑠) throughout IP𝑟is as max

𝑗{𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑗} and the

directional vector is as (𝑔𝑥, 𝑔𝑦) = (𝑔

𝑥𝑡

1

, . . . , 𝑔𝑥𝑡

𝑚

, 𝑔𝑦𝑡

1

, . . . , 𝑔𝑦𝑡

𝑠

).In the RDM this directional vector for DMU

𝑘in time period

𝑡 is as 𝑔𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘

= 𝑅𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘

= 𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘− min

𝑗{𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑗}; 𝑖 = 1, . . . , 𝑚 and

𝑔𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘

= 𝑅𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘

= max𝑗{𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑗} − 𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘; 𝑟 = 1, . . . , 𝑠 that reflects the

ranges of possible improvement for this DMU. The RDM forDMU

𝑘in time period 𝑡 for the case of the VRS technology is

as follows (Portela et al., 2004):

𝛽∗

𝑘= max 𝛽

𝑘

s.t.𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑗𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑗≤ 𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘− 𝛽𝑘𝑅𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘

, 𝑖 = 1, . . . , 𝑚,

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑗𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑗≥ 𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘+ 𝛽𝑘𝑅𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘

, 𝑟 = 1, . . . , 𝑠,

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑗= 1,

𝜆𝑗≥ 0, 𝑗 = 1, . . . , 𝑛.

(1)

The value of 𝛽∗𝑘

in model (1) is an inefficiencymeasure and the RDM efficiency measure of unit 𝑘is RDM𝑡(𝑥𝑡

𝑘, 𝑦𝑡

𝑘, 𝑅𝑥𝑡

𝑘

, 𝑅𝑦𝑡

𝑘

) = 1 − 𝛽∗

𝑘that is defined as

(𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘

−min𝑗{𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑗})/(𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘−min

𝑗{𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑗}) if at the optimal solution

to model (1) a binding constraint corresponds to input 𝑖 or(max𝑗{𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑗} − 𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘

)/(max𝑗{𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑗} − 𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘) if a binding constraint

corresponds to output 𝑟. 𝑥𝑡𝑖𝑘

∗ and 𝑦𝑡𝑟𝑘

∗ are the target inputsand target outputs in time 𝑡, respectively. It is clear that theupper bound of 1 − 𝛽∗

𝑘is 1.

3. The Global Profit MalmquistProductivity Index

The global profit Malmquist index (PM𝐺) is applied tomeasure the productivity changes of DMUs when the inputcosts and output prices are available. Assume that, in timeperiod 𝑡, (𝑡 = 1, . . . , 𝑇), the input cost vector is 𝑐𝑡 ∈ 𝑅𝑚

+and

the output price vector is 𝑝𝑡 ∈ 𝑅𝑠

+; by using these vectors

the common input cost vector 𝑐𝐺 ∈ 𝑅𝑚

+and the common

output price vector 𝑝𝐺 ∈ 𝑅𝑠

+can be defined, respectively,

as 𝑐𝐺 = ∑𝑇

𝑗=1𝜆𝑗𝑐𝑗, ∑𝑇𝑗=1𝜆𝑗= 1, 𝜆

𝑗≥ 0, and 𝑝𝐺 =

∑𝑇

𝑗=1𝜇𝑗𝑝𝑗, ∑𝑇

𝑗=1𝜇𝑗= 1, 𝜇

𝑗≥ 0, where the weights 𝜆

𝑗and

𝜇𝑗(𝑗 = 1, . . . , 𝑇) are the decision-makers’ preferences over 𝑐𝑗

and 𝑝𝑗 (𝑗 = 1, . . . , 𝑇), respectively [12].This paper uses the definition of profit [13] to compute

the global profit and the observed profit of DMU𝑘with

the negative data. The observed profit of DMU𝑗under the

cost and price vectors of time period 𝑡 can be calculatedas OP𝑡(𝑥𝑡

𝑗, 𝑦𝑡

𝑗) = 𝑝

𝑡𝑦𝑡

𝑗− 𝑐𝑡𝑥𝑡

𝑗and the maximum profit of

time 𝑡 under the price vector of this time is defined asMP𝑡(𝑥, 𝑦, 𝑐𝑡, 𝑝𝑡) = max{𝑝𝑡𝑦−𝑐𝑡𝑥 : (𝑥, 𝑦) ∈ 𝑇𝑡, 𝑐𝑡 > 0, 𝑝𝑡 > 0}.The set of activities (𝑥, 𝑦) ∈ 𝑇

𝑡 which corresponds to thescalar MP𝑡(𝑥, 𝑦, 𝑐𝑡, 𝑝𝑡) defines the profit boundary of time 𝑡as MP𝑡 = {(𝑥, 𝑦) : 𝑝𝑡𝑦 − 𝑐𝑡𝑥 = MP𝑡(𝑥, 𝑦, 𝑐𝑡, 𝑝𝑡)}. In this casethe PM𝐺 index for the DMUs with the nonnegative data isdefined as follows:

PM𝐺 =MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) /OP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1)

MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) /OP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡), (2)

where MP𝐺(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) = max{𝑝𝐺𝑦 − 𝑐𝐺𝑥 : (𝑥, 𝑦) ∈

𝑇𝐺, 𝑐𝐺> 0, 𝑝

𝐺> 0} and𝑇𝐺 = conv{𝑇1∪⋅ ⋅ ⋅∪𝑇𝑇} is the global

production technology [5]. The term OP𝐺(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) = 𝑝𝐺𝑦𝑡 −𝑐𝐺𝑥𝑡 is the observed profit of (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) under the common price

vectors 𝑐𝐺 and 𝑝𝐺. The ratio MP𝐺(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺)/OP𝐺(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡)in the denominator of PM𝐺 is the reciprocal to measureof the profit efficiency introduced in Cooper et al. [13] for(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) under the common price vectors.This ratio measures

the distance between the observed profit OP𝐺(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) andthe common profit boundary and will have a minimumvalue of 1. A value greater than 1 of PM𝐺 index indicatesthe productivity regress and a value less than 1 implies theproductivity progress between 𝑡 and 𝑡 + 1. A value of 1indicates that the productivity remains unchanged. Becauseof the limitations of the DEAmodels with the negative inputsand outputs [17, 18], we cannot investigate the productivitychange of DMUs with the negative data by using traditionMalmquist indices. To this end, the next section proposes anappropriate global profit Malmquist index when some inputsor/and outputs are negative.

Page 3: Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/jam/2014/276092.pdf · Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global Form in the

Journal of Applied Mathematics 3

4. The Global Profit Malmquist Index withthe Negative Data

In this section we assume that there are some negativeinputs and/or negative outputs and evaluate the productivitychanges of DMUs by using the PM𝐺 index under the VRStechnology. We denote the profit of the ideal point of timeperiod 𝑡 by IP𝑡 that the superscript 𝑡 on IP𝑡 indicates the profitis computed under the cost and the price vectors of time 𝑡. Byusing the definition of the profit, we will have

OP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) ≤ MP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝑡, 𝑝𝑡) ≤ IP𝑡. (3)

Now we define the profit and allocative efficiency of aDMU with the negative data.

Definition 1. The measure of the profit efficiency for (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡)under the price vectors of time 𝑡 is as

PE𝑡 (𝑦𝑡, 𝑥𝑡, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) =MP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝑡, 𝑝𝑡) − IP𝑡

OP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) − IP𝑡. (4)

By using (3) it is clear that the value of PE𝑡(𝑦𝑡, 𝑥𝑡,𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) is equal to or less than one. As the profit efficiency

is less than 1 it may be because production takes place at thewrong input and/or output mix in light of the input costs andthe output prices; this is captured by using the measure of theallocative efficiency which is defined as follows.

Definition 2. Let (𝑥𝑡∗, 𝑦𝑡∗) be the target DMU of (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) intime period 𝑡 using RDM.The allocative efficiency of (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡)can be defined as follows:

AE𝑡 (𝑦𝑡, 𝑥𝑡, 𝑤𝑡)

=MP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝑡, 𝑝𝑡) − IP𝑡

OP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡∗, 𝑦𝑡∗) − IP𝑡

=MP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝑡, 𝑝𝑡) − IP𝑡

(OP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) − IP𝑡)RDM𝑡 (𝑥𝑡𝑘, 𝑦𝑡

𝑘, 𝑅𝑥𝑡

𝑘

, 𝑅𝑦𝑡

𝑘

)

=

PE𝑡 (𝑦𝑡, 𝑥𝑡, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺)

RDM𝑡 (𝑥𝑡𝑘, 𝑦𝑡

𝑘, 𝑅𝑥𝑡

𝑘

, 𝑅𝑦𝑡

𝑘

)

.

(5)

If profit efficiency is less than 1 and it is because produc-tion is based on excessive input or shortage output usage, wecan capture it by using the RDM efficiency measure that wasdenoted by RDM𝑡(𝑥𝑡

𝑘, 𝑦𝑡

𝑘, 𝑅𝑥𝑡

𝑘

, 𝑅𝑦𝑡

𝑘

).To define the PM𝐺 index under theVRS technology in the

presence of the negative datawe first consider a global idealpoint (GIP) defined over the global technology that, for input𝑖 (𝑖 = 1, . . . , 𝑚), and output 𝑟 (𝑟 = 1, . . . , 𝑠), is as GIP

𝑖=

min𝑡{min𝑗{𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑗}} and GIP

𝑟= max

𝑡{max𝑗{𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑗}}, respectively.

This ideal point is used for computing the range 𝑅GF=

(𝑅GF𝑥𝑡 , 𝑅

GF𝑦𝑡 ) for DMU

𝑘observed in time 𝑡. The 𝑖th component

of 𝑅GF𝑥𝑡 is 𝑅GF

𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘

= 𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘− min

𝑡{min𝑗{𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑗}}, 𝑖 = 1, . . . , 𝑚, and

𝑟th component of 𝑅GF𝑦𝑡 is 𝑅GF

𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘

= max𝑡{max𝑗{𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑗}} − 𝑦

𝑡

𝑟𝑗, 𝑟 =

1, . . . , 𝑠. Now we define the PM𝐺 index in the presence of thenegative data as follows:

PM𝐺 = ((MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) − GIP𝐺)

(OP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1) − GIP𝐺))

× (

(MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) − GIP𝐺)

(OP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) − GIP𝐺))

−1

,

(6)

where GIP𝐺 is the profit of the global ideal point andthe superscript 𝐺 indicates that the profit of this point iscomputed under the common price vectors 𝑐𝐺 and 𝑝𝐺. Theratio (MP𝐺(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺)−GIP𝐺)/(OP𝐺(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡)−GIP𝐺) is theprofit efficiency defined in Definition 1 under the commoncost and price vectors. When the PM𝐺 index has the valuegreater than 1, it means that the productivity of unit 𝑘 hasimproved from the time 𝑡 to 𝑡 + 1. The productivity hasdeclined when the value of the PM𝐺 index is below 1 andremains unchanged if PM𝐺 = 1. The PM𝐺 index is circularand it can be decomposed into four circular components asshown in the next section.

5. Decomposition of the PM𝐺 Index

In the first stage the PM𝐺 index is decomposed into two PEC𝐺

and PTC𝐺 as follows:

PM𝐺 = ((MP𝑡+1 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑐𝑡+1, 𝑝𝑡+1) − GIP𝑡+1)

(OP𝑡+1 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1) − GIP𝑡+1))

× ((MP𝑡(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝑡, 𝑝𝑡) − GIP𝑡)(OP𝑡(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) − GIP𝑡)

)

−1

× [

[

(

(MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) − GIP𝐺)

(OP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1) − GIP𝐺))

× (

(MP𝑡+1(𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑐𝑡+1, 𝑝𝑡+1) − GIP𝑡+1)(OP𝑡+1(𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1) − GIP𝑡+1)

)

−1

× ((MP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝑡, 𝑝𝑡) − GIP𝑡)(OP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) − GIP𝑡)

)

× (

(MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) − GIP𝐺)

(OP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) − GIP𝐺))

−1

]

]

.

(7)

The termoutside the brackets in the right-hand side of (7)represents the profit efficiency change (PEC𝐺) component ofthe unit under evaluation from 𝑡 to 𝑡 + 1 and the term insidethe brackets provides the profit frontier shift (the technicalchange) between the periods 𝑡 and 𝑡 + 1 under the VRSproduction technologies oftwo times t and 𝑡 + 1 (PTC𝐺).

Page 4: Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/jam/2014/276092.pdf · Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global Form in the

4 Journal of Applied Mathematics

The PEC𝐺 and PTC𝐺 components of the PM𝐺 index canthemselves be decomposed.

TheDecomposition of the𝑃𝐸𝐶𝐺.ThePEC𝐺 component can bedecomposed into two components as follows:

PEC𝐺 =(MP𝑡+1 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑐𝑡+1, 𝑝𝑡+1) − GIP𝑡+1) / (OP𝑡+1 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1) − GIP𝑡+1)RDM𝑡+1 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑅GF

𝑥𝑡+1 , 𝑅

GF𝑦𝑡+1)

(MP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝑡, 𝑝𝑡) − GIP𝑡) / (OP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) − GIP𝑡)RDM𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑅GF𝑥𝑡 , 𝑅

GF𝑦𝑡 )

×

RDM𝑡+1 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑅GF𝑥𝑡+1 , 𝑅

GF𝑦𝑡+1)

RDM𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑅GF𝑥𝑡 , 𝑅

GF𝑦𝑡 )

,

(8)

whereGIP𝑡 andGIP𝑡+1 are the profit of the global point underthe costs and prices of the periods 𝑡 and 𝑡 + 1, respectively.The first ratio in the right-hand side of (8) is the allocativeefficiency change (AEC𝐺) components of the PM𝐺 index; andthe second ratio is the RDMwithin-period-efficiency change

(REC𝐺) of the unit that is under evaluation from 𝑡 to 𝑡 + 1;the RDMwithin-period-efficiency change was introduced byPortela et al. [15].

The Decomposition of 𝑃𝑇𝐶𝐺. We can decompose the PTC𝐺into two components as follows:

PTC𝐺 =RDM𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑅GF

𝑥𝑡+1 , 𝑅

GF𝑦𝑡+1)RDM𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑅GF

𝑥𝑡 , 𝑅

GF𝑦𝑡 )

RDM𝑡+1 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑅GF𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑅

GF𝑦𝑡+1)RDM𝐺 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑅GF

𝑥𝑡 , 𝑅

GF𝑦𝑡 )

× [

[

((

MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) − GIP𝐺

(OP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1) − GIP𝐺)RDM𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑅GF𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑅

GF𝑦𝑡+1)

)

×(MP𝑡+1(𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑐𝑡+1, 𝑝𝑡+1) − GIP𝑡+1

(OP𝑡+1(𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1) − GIP𝑡+1)RDM𝑡+1(𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑅GF𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑅

GF𝑦𝑡+1)

)

−1

)

×((MP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝑡, 𝑝𝑡) − GIP𝑡

(OP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) − GIP𝑡)RDM𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑅GF𝑥𝑡 , 𝑅

GF𝑦𝑡 )

)

×(MP𝐺(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) − GIP𝐺

(OP𝐺(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) − GIP𝐺)RDM𝐺(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑅GF𝑥𝑡 , 𝑅

GF𝑦𝑡 )

)

−1

)]

]

.

(9)

The first term in the above decomposition measures thefrontier shift between the VRS frontiers of times 𝑡 and 𝑡 + 1and the technical change (TC𝐺), along the ray (𝑥𝑡+1

𝑗, 𝑦𝑡+1

𝑗)

[16]. The second term is a residual price effect (PE𝐺) part.The numerical values of the components of the PM𝐺 indexobtained in this section are interpreted in the similar manneras the index itself; a value below 1 indicates regress, greaterthan 1 indicates progress, and 1 indicates that performancestayed constant.

5.1. The Circularity Property of 𝑃𝑀𝐺 and All of Its Compo-nents. Circularity is a prominent property of the PM𝐺 indexand all of its components in the presence of the negative data.To show this property, the following theorem is stated.

Theorem3. For everyDMUj (𝑗 = 1, . . . , 𝑛), in three successiveperiods,

(1) 𝑃𝑀𝐺𝑡,𝑡+2

= 𝑃𝑀𝐺

𝑡,𝑡+1×𝑃𝑀𝐺

𝑡+1,𝑡+2(the circularity of PM𝐺),

(2) 𝑃𝐸𝐶𝐺𝑡,𝑡+2

= 𝑃𝐸𝐶𝐺

𝑡,𝑡+1× 𝑃𝐸𝐶

𝐺

𝑡+1,𝑡+2(the circularity of

PEC𝐺),(3) 𝑃𝑇𝐶𝐺

𝑡,𝑡+2= 𝑃𝑇𝐶

𝐺

𝑡,𝑡+1× 𝑃𝑇𝐶

𝐺

𝑡+1,𝑡+2(the circularity of

PTC𝐺),(4) 𝑅𝐸𝐶𝐺

𝑡,𝑡+2= 𝑅𝐸𝐶

𝐺

𝑡,𝑡+1× 𝑅𝐸𝐶

𝐺

𝑡+1,𝑡+2(the circularity of

REC𝐺),(5) 𝐴𝐸𝐶𝐺

𝑡,𝑡+2= 𝐴𝐸𝐶

𝐺

𝑡,𝑡+1× 𝐴𝐸𝐶

𝐺

𝑡+1,𝑡+2(the circularity of

AEC𝐺),(6) 𝑇𝐶𝐺

𝑡,𝑡+2= 𝑇𝐶𝐺

𝑡,𝑡+1× 𝑇𝐶𝐺

𝑡+1,𝑡+2(the circularity of TC𝐺),

(7) 𝑃𝐸𝐺𝑡,𝑡+2

= 𝑃𝐸𝐺

𝑡,𝑡+1× 𝑃𝐸𝐺

𝑡+1,𝑡+2(the circularity of PE𝐺),

Page 5: Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/jam/2014/276092.pdf · Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global Form in the

Journal of Applied Mathematics 5

where, for instance, 𝑃𝑀𝐺𝑝,𝑞

(𝑝 = 𝑡, 𝑡 + 1, 𝑞 = 𝑡 + 1, 𝑡 + 2, 𝑝 = 𝑞)is the profit Malmquist changes between periods 𝑝 and 𝑞 forDMU

𝑗.

Proof. For instance, let PM𝐺𝑝,𝑞

be the profit Malmquistchanges between periods 𝑝 and 𝑞 for DMU

𝑗. Therefore,

PM𝐺𝑡,𝑡+1

× PM𝐺𝑡+1,𝑡+2

= ((

MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) − GIP𝐺

OP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1) − GIP𝐺)

×(

MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) − GIP𝐺

OP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) − GIP𝐺)

−1

)

×((

MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+2, 𝑦𝑡+2, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) − GIP𝐺

OP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+2, 𝑦𝑡+2) − GIP𝐺)

×(

MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) − GIP𝐺

OP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1) − GIP𝐺)

−1

)

= (

MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+2, 𝑦𝑡+2, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) − GIP𝐺

OP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+2, 𝑦𝑡+2) − GIP𝐺)

× (

MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺) − GIP𝐺

OP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡) − GIP𝐺)

−1

= MP𝐺𝑡,𝑡+2

.

(10)

In other words, the global profit Malmquist change fromperiod 𝑡 to 𝑡 + 2 is the product of the successive global profitMalmquist change from period 𝑡 to 𝑡 + 1 and from the period𝑡+1 to 𝑡+2. Similarly, we can show that all of the componentsare circular.

The above properties show that in the presence of the neg-ative data the PM𝐺 index and its components are appropriateindices in the fact that they link in clear way productivitychange indices over successive time periods.

6. The Computation of the Proposed Indexand Its Components

This section prepares someDEAmodels to compute the PM𝐺

index and its components. The observed profit OP𝐺(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡)is computed as ∑𝑠

𝑟=1𝑝𝐺

𝑟𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘− ∑𝑚

𝑖=1𝑐𝐺

𝑖𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘. Similarly, the

observed profits denoted by OP𝐺(𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1), OP𝑡(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡), andOP𝑡+1(𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1) are, respectively,∑𝑠

𝑟=1𝑝𝐺

𝑟𝑦𝑡+1

𝑟𝑘−∑𝑚

𝑖=1𝑐𝐺

𝑖𝑥𝑡+1

𝑖𝑘,

∑𝑠

𝑟=1𝑝𝑡

𝑟𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘− ∑𝑚

𝑖=1𝑐𝑡

𝑖𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘, and ∑𝑠

𝑟=1𝑝𝑡+1

𝑟𝑦𝑡+1

𝑟𝑘− ∑𝑚

𝑖=1𝑐𝑡+1

𝑖𝑥𝑡+1

𝑖𝑘.

We can compute MP𝑡(𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝑡, 𝑝𝑡) for unit 𝑘 by using thefollowing model:

MP𝑡 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝑡, 𝑝𝑡)

= max𝑠

𝑟=1

𝑝𝑡

𝑟𝑦𝑟−

𝑚

𝑖=1

𝑐𝑡

𝑖𝑥𝑖

s.t. 𝑦𝑟=

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑗𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑗≥ 𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘, 𝑟 = 1, . . . , 𝑠,

𝑥𝑖=

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑗𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑗≤ 𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘, 𝑖 = 1, . . . , 𝑚,

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑗= 1,

𝜆𝑗≥ 0, 𝑗 = 1, . . . , 𝑛.

(11)

Similarly, we will have

MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡, 𝑦𝑡, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺)

= max𝑠

𝑟=1

𝑝𝐺

𝑟𝑦𝑟−

𝑚

𝑖=1

𝑐𝐺

𝑖𝑥𝑖

s.t. 𝑦𝑟=

𝑇

𝑡=1

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑡

𝑗𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑗≥ 𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘, 𝑟 = 1, . . . , 𝑠,

𝑥𝑖=

𝑇

𝑡=1

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑡

𝑗𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑗≤ 𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘, 𝑖 = 1, . . . , 𝑚,

𝑇

𝑡=1

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑡

𝑗= 1,

𝜆𝑡

𝑗≥ 0, 𝑗 = 1, . . . , 𝑛, 𝑡 = 1, . . . 𝑇,

MP𝐺 (𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑐𝐺, 𝑝𝐺)

= max𝑠

𝑟=1

𝑝𝐺

𝑟𝑦𝑟−

𝑚

𝑖=1

𝑐𝐺

𝑖𝑥𝑖

s.t. 𝑦𝑟=

𝑇

𝑡=1

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑡

𝑗𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑗≥ 𝑦𝑡+1

𝑟𝑘, 𝑟 = 1, . . . , 𝑠,

𝑥𝑖=

𝑇

𝑡=1

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑡

𝑗𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑗≤ 𝑥𝑡+1

𝑖𝑘, 𝑖 = 1, . . . , 𝑚,

𝑇

𝑡=1

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑡

𝑗= 1,

𝜆𝑡

𝑗≥ 0, 𝑗 = 1, . . . , 𝑛, 𝑡 = 1, . . . 𝑇.

(12)

The termMP𝑡+1(𝑥𝑡+1, 𝑦𝑡+1, 𝑐𝑡+1, 𝑝𝑡+1) can be computed byusing model (11) after replacing the time period 𝑡 with 𝑡 + 1.

Page 6: Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/jam/2014/276092.pdf · Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global Form in the

6 Journal of Applied Mathematics

Table 1: Input, outputs, and their cost and prices for 3 successive periods.

DMU 𝑡 = 1 𝑡 = 2 𝑡 = 3

𝐼 𝑐1

𝑂1 𝑂2 𝑝1

1𝑝1

2𝐼 𝑐

2𝑂1 𝑂2 𝑝

2

1𝑝2

2𝐼 𝑐

3𝑂1 𝑂2 𝑝

3

1𝑝3

2

DMU1 3 2 −2 1 1 3 4 2.3 −1 2 1.1 3.2 6.5 3 −1 3 1.4 4DMU2 7 2 −3 3 1 3 7 2.3 −3 5 1.1 3.2 9 3 −4 5 1.4 4DMU3 2 2 −4 3.5 1 3 4 2.3 −5 6 1.1 3.2 3 3 −4 7 1.4 4DMU4 4 2 −1 1 1 3 3 2.3 −2 2 1.1 3.2 6 3 −2 1 1.4 4

Table 2: The results of the global profit Malmquist, profit efficiency change, and profit technical change.

DMU PM𝐺𝑡,𝑠

PEC𝐺𝑡,𝑠

PTC𝐺𝑡,𝑠

PM𝐺1,2

PM𝐺2,3

PM𝐺1,3

PEC𝐺1,2

PEC𝐺2,3

PEC𝐺1,3

PTC𝐺1,2

PTC𝐺2,3

PTC𝐺1,3

DMU1 1.1611 1 1.1611 1 1.1816 1.1816 1.1611 0.8463 0.9827DMU2 1.3049 0.4695 0.6127 0.9999 0.2704 0.2704 1.3049 1.7366 2.2661DMU3 0.4978 2.009 1 0.9999 1.4038 1.4038 0.4978 1.431 0.7123DMU4 1.1555 0.5363 0.6197 0.9997 0.6657 0.6657 1.1555 0.8057 0.931Avg. 1.0298 1.0037 0.8484 0.9999 0.8804 0.8804 1.0298 1.2049 1.223

For computing RDM𝑡(𝑥𝑡𝑘, 𝑦𝑡

𝑘, 𝑅

GF𝑥𝑡

𝑘

, 𝑅GF𝑦𝑡

𝑘

) that is equal to1 − 𝛽∗

𝑘we first calculate 𝛽∗

𝑘by using model (1) after replacing

𝑅𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘

and 𝑅𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘

with 𝑅GF𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘

and 𝑅GF𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘

, respectively. Similarly,we can compute the value of RDM𝑡+1(𝑥𝑡+1

𝑘, 𝑦𝑡+1

𝑘, 𝑅

GF𝑥𝑡+1

𝑘

, 𝑅GF𝑦𝑡+1

𝑘

)

after replacing the time period 𝑡with 𝑡+1. In order to computeRDM𝐺(𝑥𝑡

𝑘, 𝑦𝑡

𝑘, 𝑅

GF𝑥𝑡

𝑘

, 𝑅GF𝑦𝑡

𝑘

) = 1 − 𝛽∗

𝑘, we first extend model

(1) for the case that the production technology formed fromall DMUs observed in all time periods (𝑇𝐺). The proposedmodel is shown in (13). In fact, the optimal value of model(13),𝛽∗

𝑘, is an inefficiency of DMU

𝑘along direction (𝑔

𝑥, 𝑔𝑦) =

(𝑅GF𝑥𝑡

𝑘

, 𝑅GF𝑦𝑡

𝑘

) under the global production technology 𝑇𝐺:

𝛽∗

𝑘= max 𝛽

𝑘

s.t.𝑇

𝑡=1

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑡

𝑗𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑗≤ 𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘− 𝛽𝑘𝑅GF𝑥𝑡

𝑖𝑘

, 𝑖 = 1, . . . , 𝑚,

𝑇

𝑡=1

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑡

𝑗𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑗≥ 𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘+ 𝛽𝑘𝑅GF𝑦𝑡

𝑟𝑘

, 𝑟 = 1, . . . , 𝑠,

𝑇

𝑡=1

𝑛

𝑗=1

𝜆𝑡

𝑗= 1,

𝜆𝑡

𝑗≥ 0, 𝑗 = 1, . . . , 𝑛, 𝑡 = 1, . . . 𝑇.

(13)

RDM𝐺(𝑥𝑡+1𝑘, 𝑦𝑡+1

𝑘, 𝑅

GF𝑥𝑡+1

𝑘

, 𝑅GF𝑦𝑡+1

𝑘

) iscomputed using model(13) after replacing the time period 𝑡 with 𝑡 + 1.

By replacing the values obtained from the above modelsin the formulations of PM𝐺 index and its components, thevalues of them can be computed. A value greater than 1 ofPM𝐺 index and its components indicates the regress and avalue less than 1 implies the progress between periods 𝑡 and𝑡 + 1. A value equal to 1 indicates that there is not any changebetween two time periods.

7. Numerical Example

This section illustrates the property of PM𝐺 and its compo-nents, for example, the circularity property, using a numericalexample. Table 1 shows units DMU1–DMU4 with one input(I) and two outputs (O1 and O2) and their cost (𝑐𝑡) and prices(𝑝𝑡1and 𝑝𝑡

2) for 3 successive periods.

To compute the PM𝐺 indices and their components byusing the data in Table 1, suppose that the preferences aboutthe input costs and output prices are available and have beenspecified by decision-makers as 𝜆

𝑗= 𝜇𝑗= (1/3) (𝑗 = 1, 2, 3).

Therefore, the common costs and prices are obtained by usingthe decision-makers’ preferences:

𝑐𝐺=1

3𝑐1+1

3𝑐2+1

3𝑐3= 2.4333,

𝑝𝐺=1

3𝑝1+1

3𝑝2+1

3𝑝3= (1.6667, 3.4) .

(14)

By using the data of periods 1, 2, and 3, the inputs andthe outputs of the global ideal point will be 2, −1, and 7,respectively.

Table 2 shows PM𝐺𝑡,𝑠, PEC𝐺𝑡,𝑠, andTEC𝐺

𝑡,𝑠of all of theDMUs

for 𝑡 = 1, 2, 𝑠 = 2, 3, and 𝑠 = 𝑡. For instance, the columns 2, 3,and 4 in Table 2 show PM𝐺

1,2, PM𝐺2,3, and PM𝐺

1,3, respectively.

For DMU2, as an example, we have PMG1,2= 1.3049 > 1.

That is, the productivity of DMU2 in period 2 is more than itsproductivity in period 1 and hence the productivity has beenimproved from the time period 1 to 2.

According to PM𝐺2,3= 0.46951 < 1, the productivity of

DMU2 in period 3 is less than its productivity in period 2. Bythe circularity property of the profit Malmquist change, wecan conclude that PM𝐺

1,3= PM𝐺

1,2×PM𝐺2,3= 1.3049×0.4695 =

0.6127.Looking at the average values in Table 2, for example, we

can see that the average global profit Malmquist index ofall of the DMUs from the first period to the second period(1.0298) is higher than their average global profit Malmquist

Page 7: Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/jam/2014/276092.pdf · Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global Form in the

Journal of Applied Mathematics 7

Table 3: The results of the RDM within-period-efficiency and allocative efficiency change.

DMU REC𝐺𝑡,𝑠

AEC𝐺𝑡,𝑠

REC𝐺1,2

REC𝐺2,3

REC𝐺1,3

AEC𝐺1,2

AEC𝐺2,3

AEC𝐺1,3

DMU1 2.1333 1.5 3.2 0.4688 0.7878 0.3693DMU2 0.9821 0.4156 0.4082 1.0182 0.6506 0.6624DMU3 1.75 2 3.5 0.5714 0.7019 0.4011DMU4 1.3333 0.25 0.3333 0.75 2.6627 1.997Avg. 1.5497 1.0414 1.8604 0.7021 1.2007 0.8574

Table 4: The results of the frontier shift between the VRS frontiers and price effect.

DMU TC𝐺𝑡,𝑠

PE𝐺𝑡,𝑠

TC𝐺1,2

TC𝐺2,3

TC𝐺1,3

PE𝐺1,2

PE𝐺2,3

PE𝐺1,3

DMU1 0.6064 0.5063 0.307 1.9147 1.6715 3.2004DMU2 1.4915 1.5912 2.3733 0.8749 1.0914 0.9549DMU3 0.45 0.8254 0.3714 1.1062 1.7338 1.9178DMU4 0.9 1.6234 1.461 1.2839 0.4963 0.6372Avg. 0.862 1.1366 1.1282 1.2949 1.2483 1.6776

index from the second period to the third period (1.0037).The average of columns 2, 3, and 4 in Table 2 shows that theaverage growth of all of the DMUs from the first period to thethird period is less than their growth from period 1 to period2 and that from period 2 to period 3. A similar discussion canbe made for the other columns of Table 2.

Tables 3 and 4 illustrate the results from the RDMwithin-period-efficiency change, allocative efficiency change, thefrontier shift between the VRS frontiers, and residual pricechange from different periods to the periods 2 and 3, and theaverages are shown in the last row of these tables.

For example, the frontier shift between the VRS frontiersalong the ray (𝑥2

1, 𝑦2

1) from period 1 to period 2 is 0.6064; that

is, there is a decrease in technical progress for DMU1 fromperiod 1 to period 2.

Using the average values in Table 4, for example, we cansee that the average frontier shifts between the VRS frontiersalong the rays (𝑥2

1, 𝑦2

1), (𝑥22, 𝑦2

2), (𝑥23, 𝑦2

3), and (𝑥2

4, 𝑦2

4) of all of

the DMUs from the first period to the second period (0.862)are less than their average frontier shifts between the VRSfrontiers along the rays (𝑥3

1, 𝑦3

1), (𝑥32, 𝑦3

2), (𝑥33, 𝑦3

3), and (𝑥3

4, 𝑦3

4)

from the second period to the third period (1.1366).The valuePE𝐺1,2= 0.8749 < 1, for DMU2 as an example, for the PE𝐺

component, indicates that the effect of input cost changesfrom the first period to the second period is detrimental toproductivity.

8. Conclusions

Under the VRS assumption allocative and profit efficiencieshave been defined for the case that the dataset containsthe inputs and/or outputs with the negative values in dataenvelopment analysis. The definitions could be generalizedwhen the unit cost of the ith input (𝑖 = 1, . . . , 𝑚) orthe unit price of the 𝑟th output (𝑟 = 1, . . . , 𝑠) of all ofDMUs is different. The proposed PM𝐺 index decomposed

into some components in two stages. The RDM and thedefined efficiencies were used to compute the proposed indexand its components. The interpretations of the componentswere presented. A numerical example has been presented forthree successive periods of time to illustrate the propertiesof PM𝐺 and its components in the presence of the negativeinputs and outputs.

Conflict of Interests

The authors declare that there is no conflict of interestsregarding the publication of this paper.

Acknowledgment

Financial support of this research, in a project entitled AnOverall Index to Determine the Progress or Regress of theProductivity of DMUs and Its Global Form in the Presence ofthe Negative Data, Islamic Azad University, Central TehranBranch, is acknowledged.

References

[1] D. W. Caves, L. R. Christensen, and W. E. Diewert, “Theeconomic theory of index numbers and the measurement ofinput, output and productivity,” Econometrica, vol. 50, pp. 1393–1414, 1982.

[2] R. Fare, S. Grosskopf, M. Norris, and Z. Zhang, “Productivitygrowth, technical progress, and efficiency change in industrial-ized countries,” American Economic Review, vol. 84, no. 1, pp.66–83, 1994.

[3] R. Fare, S. Grosskopf, B. Lindgren, and P. Roos, “Productivitydevelopments in Swedish hospitals: a Malmquist output indexapproach,” in Data Envelopment Analysis: Theory, Methodologyand Applications, A. Charnes, W. W. Cooper, A. Lewin, and L.Seiford, Eds., pp. 253–272, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1994.

Page 8: Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/jam/2014/276092.pdf · Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global Form in the

8 Journal of Applied Mathematics

[4] A. Q. Nyrud and S. Baardsen, “Production efficiency andproductivity growth in Norwegian sawmilling,” Forest Science,vol. 49, no. 1, pp. 89–97, 2003.

[5] J. T. Pastor andC.A.K. Lovell, “A globalMalmquist productivityindex,” Economics Letters, vol. 88, no. 2, pp. 266–271, 2005.

[6] M. Portela and E. Thanassoulis, “A circular Malmquist-typeindex for measuring productivity,” AstonWorking Paper RP08-02, Aston University, Birmingham, UK, 2008.

[7] F. Hosseinzadeh Lotfi, G. Jahanshahloo, M. Vaez-Ghasemi,and Z. Moghaddas, “Modified Malmquist productivity indexbased on present time value of money,” Journal of AppliedMathematics, vol. 2013, Article ID 607190, 8 pages, 2013.

[8] F. H. Lotfi, G. R. Jahanshahloo, M. Vaez-Ghasemi, and Z.Moghaddas, “Evaluation progress and regress of balancedscorecards by multi-stage malmquist productivity index,” Jour-nal of Industrial and Production Engineering, vol. 30, no. 5, 2013.

[9] N. Maniadakis and E.Thanassoulis, “A cost Malmquist produc-tivity index,” European Journal of Operational Research, vol. 154,no. 2, pp. 396–409, 2004.

[10] G. Tohidi, S. Razavyan, and S. Tohidnia, “A profit Malmquistproductivity index,” Journal of Industrial Engineering Interna-tional, vol. 6, pp. 23–30, 2008.

[11] G. Tohidi and S. Razavyan, “A circular global profit Malmquistproductivity index in data envelopment analysis,”AppliedMath-ematical Modelling, vol. 37, no. 1-2, pp. 216–227, 2013.

[12] G. Tohidi, S. Razavyan, and S. Tohidnia, “A global costMalmquist productivity index using data envelopment analy-sis,” Journal of the Operational Research Society, vol. 63, no. 1,pp. 72–78, 2012.

[13] W. W. Cooper, L. M. Seiford, and K. Tone, Data EnvelopmentAnalysis: A Comprehensive Text with Models, Applications,References and DEA-Solver Software, Springer, New York, NY,USA, 2nd edition, 2007.

[14] J. T. Pastor and J. L. Ruiz, “Variables with negative values inDEA,” inModeling Data Irregularities and Structural Complexi-ties in Data Envelopment Analysis, J. Zhu andW. D. Cook, Eds.,Springer, Berlin, Germany, 2007.

[15] M. C. A. S. Portela, E. Thanassoulis, and G. Simpson, “Negativedata in DEA: a directional distance approach applied to bankbranches,” Journal of the Operational Research Society, vol. 55,no. 10, pp. 1111–1121, 2004.

[16] M. C. A. S. Portela and E. Thanassoulis, “Malmquist-typeindices in the presence of negative data: an application to bankbranches,” Journal of Banking and Finance, vol. 34, no. 7, pp.1472–1483, 2010.

[17] A. Emrouznejad, A. L. Anouze, and E. Thanassoulis, “A semi-oriented radial measure formeasuring the efficiency of decisionmaking units with negative data, using DEA,” European Journalof Operational Research, vol. 200, no. 1, pp. 297–304, 2010.

[18] J. A. Sharp, W. Meng, and W. Liu, “A modified slacks-basedmeasure model for data envelopment analysis with “natural”negative outputs and inputs,” Journal of theOperational ResearchSociety, vol. 58, no. 12, pp. 1672–1677, 2007.

Page 9: Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global ...downloads.hindawi.com/journals/jam/2014/276092.pdf · Research Article Profit Malmquist Index and Its Global Form in the

Submit your manuscripts athttp://www.hindawi.com

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

MathematicsJournal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Mathematical Problems in Engineering

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com

Differential EquationsInternational Journal of

Volume 2014

Applied MathematicsJournal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Probability and StatisticsHindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Journal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Mathematical PhysicsAdvances in

Complex AnalysisJournal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

OptimizationJournal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

CombinatoricsHindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

International Journal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Operations ResearchAdvances in

Journal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Function Spaces

Abstract and Applied AnalysisHindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

International Journal of Mathematics and Mathematical Sciences

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

The Scientific World JournalHindawi Publishing Corporation http://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Algebra

Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Decision SciencesAdvances in

Discrete MathematicsJournal of

Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com

Volume 2014 Hindawi Publishing Corporationhttp://www.hindawi.com Volume 2014

Stochastic AnalysisInternational Journal of


Recommended