+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Russia's Economic Modernization: the Causes of a Failure · 2016. 10. 11. · 17 September 2015, ....

Russia's Economic Modernization: the Causes of a Failure · 2016. 10. 11. · 17 September 2015, ....

Date post: 04-Feb-2021
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
26
Russia’s Economic Modernization: The Causes of a Failure September 2016 Vladislav INOZEMTSEV Notes de l’Ifri Russie.Nei.Visions 96 Russia/NEI Center
Transcript
  • Russia’s Economic Modernization: The Causes of a Failure

    September 2016

    Vladislav INOZEMTSEV

    Notes de l’IfriRussie.Nei.Visions 96

    Russia/NEI Center

  • The Institut français des relations internationales (Ifri) is a research center

    and a forum for debate on major international political and economic

    issues. Headed by Thierry de Montbrial since its founding in 1979, Ifri is a

    non-governmental, non-profit organization.

    As an independent think tank, Ifri sets its own research agenda, publishing

    its findings regularly for a global audience. Taking an interdisciplinary

    approach, Ifri brings together political and economic decision-makers,

    researchers and internationally renowned experts to animate its debate

    and research activities.

    With offices in Paris and Brussels, Ifri stands out as one of the few French

    think tanks to have positioned itself at the very heart of European and

    broader international debate.

    The opinions expressed in this text are the responsibility of the author alone.

    ISBN: 978-2-36567-616-8

    © All rights reserved, Ifri, 2016

    Cover: © Philippe Agaponov

    How to quote this document:

    Vladislav Inozemtsev, “Russia's Economic Modernization: The Causes of a

    Failure”, Russie.Nei.Visions, No. 96, September 2016.

    Ifri

    27 rue de la Procession 75740 Paris Cedex 15 – FRANCE

    Tel.: +33 (0)1 40 61 60 00 – Fax : +33 (0)1 40 61 60 60

    Email: [email protected]

    Ifri-Bruxelles

    Rue Marie-Thérèse, 21 1000 – Brussels – BELGIUM

    Tel.: +32 (0)2 238 51 10 – Fax : +32 (0)2 238 51 15

    Email: [email protected]

    Website: Ifri.org

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]://www.ifri.org/

  • Russie.Nei.Visions

    Russie.Nei.Visions is an online collection dedicated to Russia and the other

    new independent states (Belarus, Ukraine, Moldova, Armenia, Georgia,

    Azerbaijan, Kazakhstan, Uzbekistan, Turkmenistan, Tajikistan and

    Kyrgyzstan). Written by leading experts, these policy-oriented papers deal

    with strategic, political and economic issues.

    The author

    Vladislav L. Inozemtsev is a Russian economist, Doctor of economic

    science and the founder and director of the Centre for the Study of Post-

    industrial Society (founded 1996). Between 2002 and 2012, he was Editor-

    in-Chief of the journals Svobodnaia Mysl and Russia in Global Affairs, as

    well as of the Russian version of Le Monde diplomatique. A professor at

    Moscow State University (MGU) and the Higher School of Economics, he is

    a non-resident Senior Fellow at the Institute for Human Sciences in Vienna

    and at the Center for Strategic and International Studies in Washington.

    He is a member of the Valdai Discussion Club and of the scientific council

    within the Russian International Affairs Council (RIAC). He composed the

    electoral programme for M. Prokhorov in the 2012 Russian Presidential

    elections and took part in the 2011 State Duma elections with the “Pravoe

    Delo” party. He is the author of 16 books and more than 400 articles in

    scientific publications:

    “Russia’s non-Soviet Path”, Aspen Review Central Europe, 2015, No.1,

    p. 82–86;

    “Yes, Sanctions Work”, The American Interest, March-April 2015,

    Vol 10, No.4, p. 33-38;

    “Russia of 2010s: How to Live with It and how to Outlive It”, DGAP

    Kompakt No.7, Berlin, DGAP, June 2015, p. 1-9;

    “Russia's Putin and Putin's Russia: How They Work and What We

    Should Expect” in Hamilton, Daniel & Meister, Stefan (eds.) The Eas-

    tern Question: Russia, the West, and Europe’s Grey Zone, Washington

    (DC), Johns Hopkins Univ. Press, 2016, p. 93-108

  • Summary

    In this short study of attempts that have been made in recent years to

    modernize the Russian economy, the author explains why they have all

    ended in failure. Unlike most experts, he focuses on politics and ideology.

    He stresses that the idea of modernization runs counter to the historical

    vision that is now propagated by the Russian leadership, to the system of

    governance that it has chosen and to Russia’s current path of isolation from

    the West. In his view, such political choices have rendered modernization

    of the Russian economy unfeasible. The author also points to other

    problems: the effects of privatisation, which have made investment in new

    industrial facilities unprofitable, the declining quality of business leaders

    who are chosen for their political loyalty and the lack of independent big

    businesses that could insist on reforms being carried out.

  • Table of contents

    INTRODUCTION .................................................................................... 5

    HISTORICAL FACTORS.......................................................................... 7

    ECONOMIC FACTORS ............................................................................ 9

    FOREIGN POLICY FACTORS ................................................................ 12

    THE RUSSIAN ELITE ........................................................................... 14

    PUBLIC OPINION ................................................................................ 18

    THE GLOBAL SITUATION .................................................................... 20

    CONCLUSION ...................................................................................... 22

  • Introduction

    Assessments of modern Russian politics differ widely: some reject Vladimir

    Putin’s regime out of hand while others support it almost unconditionally.

    This observation holds true not only in Russia but in most European

    countries. However, when discussion turns to economics, the disagreement

    disappears. The vast majority of specialists consider Russia as a relatively

    backward country regarding the structure of its economy, which survives

    mainly by exporting its natural resources and which is therefore critically

    dependent on the state of world commodity markets.

    Meanwhile, not only historians, but also politicians, entrepreneurs

    and ordinary citizens, both in both Europe and in Russia, remember that

    the Soviet Union was an economically self-sufficient country for a long

    time. In Russia, the authorities have tried to remind people of late that they

    ought to take pride in the industrial and technological pre-eminence that

    their country once enjoyed. At the same time, however, it is becoming ever

    clearer that Russia is in no fit state to make a new industrial breakthrough.

    Despite all the talk about “overcoming the raw material curse”, the share of

    oil and gas in Soviet/Russian exports has increased from 37% in 1989

    to 43% in 1998, 58% in 2004 and 66% in 2013.1 Over the same period,

    Russia has become increasingly dependent on imports, not only of high-

    tech goods but also of everyday consumer goods, while its own industrial

    production has declined.

    Leaving aside most modern production and examining only crude

    statistics for heavy industry, it turns out that 89 million tons of steel were

    smelted in 1985 on the territory of the RSFSR, along with 79 m. t. of

    cement, 18m T of fertiliser and 5m T of paper, while by 2015, these figures

    had fallen by 20, 19, 11 and 10% respectively.2 The statistics for investment-

    intensive production and relatively high-tech items for general

    consumption are even more woeful. Between 1985 and 2009, the number

    of lorries, combine harvesters and tractors manufactured in Russia

    Translated from Russian by Cameron Johnston.

    1. V. Inozemtsev: “10 tsifr, kotorye ob’iasniaiut Rossiiu” [10 Figures which explain Russia], Slon,

    17 September 2015, www.slon.ru.

    2. Calculated using: Narodnoye khozyaystvo RSFSR v 1985 g, [Economy of the RSFSR in 1985],

    Moscow, Ed. Finansy i statistika, 1986 and Rosstat data: www.gks.ru, website visited on

    17 May 2016 (since 2010, data on the production of watches and cameras has not been published).

    http://www.slon.ru/posts/56555http://www.gks.ru/

  • Modernization of the Russian Economy Vladislav Inozemtsev

    6

    decreased 6, 14 and 34 times, while production of watches and cameras fell

    by a factor of 91 and 600 respectively.3 According to official data from the

    Ministry of Industry and Trade, 45 classes of items were entirely sourced

    abroad in 2014, while imports accounted for more than 90% of a further

    200 types of goods.4 To conclude, it is worth noting that Russia is even

    losing ground in the field of energy: by the end of 2014, its share of world

    oil and gas extraction had fallen to 12.6% and 16.7% respectively, compared

    to 17.8% and 29% in 1989.5

    The Russian leadership is constantly referring to the need to

    “overcome technological gap”, “reindustrialise” and “get off the oil needle”

    but in fact, no serious attempts have been made to stop the rot. In 2008,

    then-President Dmitry Medvedev insisted that modernization was his top

    priority: but the reform programme and the various milestones were set up

    in such a way that it was clear from the beginning that nothing would come

    of all the hype.6 In countries which have succeeded in modernizing, the

    process has moved “from simple to complex”, with entrepreneurs, workers

    and engineers gradually acquiring new skills and inserting themselves into

    new markets. In Russia, by contrast, they decided that the “breakthrough”

    would mainly be made in complex fields, and in the ones that are largely

    insulated from the free market, such as nuclear energy, space technology

    and pharmaceuticals. Even in the unlikely event that they blossomed, these

    fields could not kick start large-scale economic growth across the country.

    It was no accident that modernization under Medvedev failed or that it

    disappeared almost completely from the agenda after Putin’s return to the

    Kremlin. Rather, this was caused by at least six sets of factors related to

    history, economics, foreign policy, the global situation, society and the

    elites.

    3. V. Inozemtsev, “Nineteen Eighty-Five”, Russia in Global Affairs, 8(4), October-December 2010,

    p. 9.

    4. See: Rosbalt, 16 April 2016, www.rosbalt.ru.

    5. Calculated using BP Statistical Review of World Energy 2015, British Petroleum, June 2015,

    www.bp.com.

    6. For more details, see: V. Inozemtsev and E. Kuznetsova, “Modernizatsiia po ostatochnomu

    printsipu” [Modernising with what is left over], The New Times, 18 January 2010,

    http://newtimes.ru.

    http://www.rosbalt.ru/https://www.bp.com/content/dam/bp/pdf/energy-economics/statistical-review-2015/bp-statistical-review-of-world-energy-2015-full-report.pdfhttp://newtimes.ru/stati/others/40da8535ccafdf64bca8c8b888e92817-modernuzacuya-po-ostatochnomy-pruncupy.html

  • Historical factors

    The fundamental difference between Russia and most successfully

    industrialised countries is that Russia had already been a great industrial

    power. Almost everywhere in the world (in Japan, Korea, China, Malaysia

    and so on), modern industrialisation was a way of overcoming the

    economic processes of an agrarian society and it happened once, never to

    be repeated. Even in China, which experienced several waves of

    industrialisation, the industrial revolution of 1980 to the 2000s began in a

    predominantly agrarian country, although it contained pockets of heavy

    industry. Russia confronted an unusually difficult task at the dawn of

    the 21st century: how to industrialise anew when the 1920s and 1930s had

    destroyed traditional society under the slogan of industrialisation, and

    after Russia had become the world leader in certain sectors and products in

    the 1960s and 1970s. In these circumstances, the challenge of

    industrialising runs up against three main obstacles.

    First, it runs against the grain of public discourse and undermines

    people’s sense of themselves as citizens of a great country and a mighty

    industrial power. It is notable just how much attention the government

    pays, for instance, to supporting the defence sector or big national

    industries. This approach suggests that everything is going fine with

    industrial development and that state policy in recent years has helped it

    take a turn for the better. Any attempt to dispel this myth is anathema to

    the elites who are invested in Russia’s so-called “stability” and who talk up

    the superiority of Russian and Soviet societies. The task of industrialising

    of a industrialized economy is transformed into an oxymoron. This

    problem is not unique to Russia: the 20th century abounded in unfinished

    modernizing projects that “backfired”, making societies unreceptive to new

    modernizing initiatives (Latin America was particularly prone to this

    throughout the 20th century) and leaving them in a state of either

    permanent stagnation, as in Argentina, or prolonged depression, as in

    Venezuela.

    Second, in the mind of Russians, industrialisation is strongly

    associated to the worsening conditions for the population. Whenever rapid

    industrial development has occurred in Russian history, the powers that be

    have destroyed the existing patterns and rhythms of everyday life. From

    Peter the Great to the communist leaders, industrialisation has involved

    deprivation and harnessing all the power that society can muster. This is

  • Modernization of the Russian Economy Vladislav Inozemtsev

    8

    only natural: successful attempts at modernization have nearly always

    implied restrictions on current consumption and tight regulation by the

    state. Simply by examining those Asian countries where, in the first decade

    of their modern industrial revolution, real incomes barely rose, it is clear

    that this policy would not be supported by the current Russian

    government, whose popularity is based on lavish hand-outs, not on the

    ability to mobilise the masses for economic transformations that inevitably

    entail deprivations. As a great social project, industrialisation is

    incompatible with political “stability”: remember that all attempts at

    authoritarian modernization have ended, sooner or later, in radical

    political change.

    Third, a certain type of “historical memory” plays an important part in

    setting the parameters for a potential industrialisation drive, rendering it

    pointless from the very beginning. In the Soviet Union, industrial

    development occurred within a planned economy that always paid little

    attention to efficiency as traditionally understood. The country reached a

    dead end at the time largely because it tried to “tame” nature and territorial

    distances, to pull back manufacturing into the most inaccessible locations

    where it would never have developed had there been a market economy.7

    And if we look today at what “industrialisation” and “modernization” really

    entail, we see almost exactly the same unrealistic projects: from the bridge

    to Sakhalin and the tunnel under the Bering Strait to the modernization of

    the Baikal-Amur Mainline (BAM) and the construction of the Power of

    Siberia pipeline. If you have already experienced one unsuccessful

    industrialisation, it is also too easy to repeat the same mistakes a second

    time round. The more authoritarian the government, the more likely this is

    to happen.

    Russia therefore presents a very unfavourable environment for

    industrialisation; the doubtful experience of its earlier industrial

    revolutions (none of which was natural) exists alongside a certain nihilism,

    which springs from the illusion that Russia is well versed in these matters,

    and is reinforced by the authorities’ unwillingness to destabilise society. All

    this demonstrates that in terms of history, ideology and worldview, Russia

    currently possesses none of the prerequisites for a new round of

    industrialisation.

    7. C. Gaddy and B. Ickes, Bear Traps on Russia’s Road to Modernization, London/New York,

    Routledge, 2013, diagram No.3.1, p. 38.

  • Economic factors

    The second set of obstacles, quite diverse, is due to economic factors,

    although all these are of course connected to political factors and “the

    specificities of the national elite”.

    First, the most important barrier on the road to successful

    industrialisation in Russia is the privatisation that took place in the 1990s.

    Privatisation allowed the new owners to gain control of large assets at very

    low prices (51% of “Norilsk Nickel” was bought for $170m, 51% of

    “Sidanko” [later—TNK] for $130m, 51% of “Sibneft” for $100m, 40% of

    “Surgutneftegaz” for $89m, while many large industrial enterprises were

    acquired for a few million dollars). The problem here is not that the state

    was short-changed during privatisation but that the foundation of the

    economy in the 2000s was made up of assets that were virtually given

    away, with their cost being recouped in just a few years. This acted as a

    powerful brake on investment: every potential investor realised that he

    would have to spend billions of dollars to compete with those who had

    acquired their assets on the cheap. Surviving in this environment

    demanded the most up-to-date management techniques and by no means

    all managers possessed them. Privatisation, in other words, having been

    carried out in the interests of the oligarchs, continues to influence

    economic strategy two decades down the line, discouraging new players

    from investing in industry (it is not surprising that only one new oil

    processing plant has been built in the “energy superpower” since the

    collapse of the Soviet Union). China, whose industrial revolution has been

    overall successful, took a different path by keeping the industrial giants

    under state control but sponsoring the creation of new companies that play

    by market rules.8 This helped to unleash entrepreneurship in industry, as

    opposed to killing it in embryo.

    Second, from the beginning, no strategy was devised for rapid

    industrial growth and no one therefore posed the question of what might

    underpin such a strategy. Across various historical epochs, stimulating

    economic growth in developing countries has generally come in two forms:

    heavily redistributing resources from one sector to others (like Stalin’s

    industrialisation, which ruined the countryside), or artificially depressing

    8. For more details, see: H. Sheng and Z. Nong, China’s State-Owned Enterprises: Nature,

    Performance, and Reform, Singapore, World Scientific Publishing Co., 2012.

  • Modernization of the Russian Economy Vladislav Inozemtsev

    10

    the price of certain resources (labour in China or other South-East Asian

    countries, for instance). Russia possessed two relatively cheap resources

    after the collapse of communism, namely qualified workers and natural

    resources. This meant that it was quite possible to carry out a “new

    industrialisation” but the government did not even consider using either of

    these resources on the cheap. Supplying the economy with cheap raw

    materials might have attracted foreign investment and allowed industry to

    thrive but the government was hand-in-glove with the oligarchs who

    controlled the raw materials and derived most of its income from

    redistributing natural-resource rents. It also needed the support of the

    masses and therefore bought their loyalty by increasing people’s incomes.

    The ability to improve the well-being of unproductive groups by simply

    redistributing income from the extraction and export of raw materials

    became the foundation of the Russian economy, but this did nothing to

    develop manufacturing or shift the main burden of tax onto industry. To

    put it more simply, instead of forcing the people to work, using cheap

    Russian raw materials and accessible foreign technology, the Russian

    government preferred instead to redistribute the proceeds from raw

    materials directly. As one might expect, this enriched state employees and

    raw material barons, but removed the incentive for investors to develop

    production in Russia. Time and again, the authorities gave their seal of

    approval to monopolies that, at times, sold Russian raw materials at higher

    prices at home than abroad (when the Federal Anti-Monopoly Service

    sanctioned the creation of United Company RUSAL in 2007, one condition

    was that the price for aluminium on the Russian market should not exceed

    that on the London Metal Exchange by more than 5%).9 Needless to say,

    the Chinese economic miracle was not repeated in Russia. Indeed, it has no

    chance of being repeated because, at a time of instability on world markets,

    owners of raw materials will try to increase the valuations of their

    companies within the country, driving down competitiveness even further.

    Meanwhile, the environment for doing business in other countries will only

    improve.

    Third, the Russian economy has developed and is still developing

    along relatively autarchic lines. It exports unprocessed raw materials and

    imports ready-made, high-tech goods. As such, industrialisation is seen

    almost exclusively as a way of reducing Russia’s dependence on foreign

    goods—that is, the “import substitution” that is now so popular—but no

    more than that. In recent years, Russia has the distinction of being the only

    country where “free economic zones” were set up to increase the supply of

    9. K. Rybak, “FAS dast dobro ‘Rusalu’” [FAS will give green light to Rusal], Vedomosti,

    18 January 2007, www.vedomosti.ru.

    http://www.vedomosti.ru/newspaper/articles/2007/01/18/fas-dast-dobro-rusalu

  • Modernization of the Russian Economy Vladislav Inozemtsev

    11

    goods on the internal market (like, for example, the free economic zone in

    Kaliningrad oblast) and not for export, as is the custom practically the

    world over.10 This gives rise to a problem that was identified long ago by

    the American economist Jagdish Baghwati: modernization cannot succeed

    in closed economies because autarchy restricts competition, while any

    “new industrialisation” requires greater competitiveness: the statistics bear

    out his conclusion that the key to industrialisation is integrating a national

    economy into the world economy.11 In Russia today, there are no markets

    big enough to absorb enough industrial output to guarantee economies of

    scale and such markets will not appear in the near future (for this reason,

    projects like “Yo-Mobile”12 have not and will not see the light of day). The

    only way to reindustrialise the country, therefore, is to attract foreign

    manufacturers that own wide sales networks and to increase exports of

    ready-made items bearing well-known global brands. However, as we

    already know, the Russian government believes that the country is

    surrounded by enemies and is shaping its policies around the idea of yet

    more autarchy. With Russia’s rapidly shrinking internal market and with

    hopes of a change in political course proving illusory, we can be almost

    certain that attempts at industrialisation will fail. In addition to economical

    factors, foreign policy factors are no less important.

    10. V. Inozemtsev, “Khimery razvitiya. Pochemu provalilsia eksperiment osobykh

    ekonomicheskikh zon” [Chimeras of development. Why the experiment with special economic

    zones failed], Slon, 27 June 2016, https://slon.ru.

    11. J. Bhagwati, In Defense of Globalization: How the New World Economy Is Helping Rich and

    Poor Alike, Oxford/New York, Oxford University Press, 2004, p. 180.

    12. A Russian project for a hybrid vehicle with an electrical transmission.

    https://slon.ru/posts/69600

  • Foreign policy factors

    Foreign policy accounts for a third set of obstacles, the most important of

    which is the character of Russia’s relations with its closest ally.

    Contemporary Russian foreign policy will not be analysed here,

    though it is highly detrimental to the country’s economy and runs against

    the grain of modernization. One factor, however, should be highlighted.

    Every successful attempt at modernization in the modern world has

    required partnership with a country that is not only politically well

    disposed but also acts as the biggest market for its partner’s industrial

    production and as the prime source of the investment and technology

    needed for rapid development. If, in the USA and EU countries, the share

    of exported industrial production accounts for no more than 8-9% of GNP,

    in China in the mid-1990s this figure reached 21%, in Indonesia 22%, in the

    Phillipines 24%, in South Korea 27%, in Thailand 30%, in Taiwan 43% and

    in Malaysia 78%.13 In the 1980s, 42% and 74% of the economic growth

    experienced by South Korea and Taiwan respectively was sustained by

    exports to the United States.14 At the same time, American imports

    accounted for nearly 85% of the positive side of Mexico’s balance of trade.15

    Having a partner like this is a determining precondition for successful

    modernization.

    Russia, however, does not have such a partner. Having turned away

    from Europe—whose market is now the reference point for the successfully

    industrialising countries of the former Warsaw Pact—for purely political

    reasons, Russia turned towards the largest industrial economy in the

    world, China, which has no interest at all in Russia becoming a competitor.

    A whole raft of evidence backs up this view: since the first half of the 1990s,

    China has progressively reduced the proportion of industrial goods in its

    imports from Russia, while increasing the proportion of unprocessed raw

    materials (the former has now fallen below 3% while the latter has reached

    75%, exceeding the corresponding figure for trade between Russia and the

    EU). China is the main potential consumer for Russian oil and gas

    13. M. Goldstein, The Asian Financial Crisis: Causes, Cures, and Systemic Implications,

    Washington D.C., Institute for International Economics, 1998, p. 27.

    14. L. Thurow, Head to Head. The Coming Economic Battle Among Japan, Europe and America ,

    New York, Warner Books, 1993, p. 62.

    15. R. Reich, Tales of a New America, New York, Vintage Books, 1988, p. 56.

  • Modernization of the Russian Economy Vladislav Inozemtsev

    13

    extracted in Eastern Siberia and the Far East but, despite the Russo-

    Chinese “programme of cooperation” adopted in 2009, Russia has failed to

    convince its partner to build even one enterprise on Russian territory that

    can process raw materials from start to finish. In the same way, we are not

    seeing a boom in Chinese investment in industrial facilities in other parts

    of Russia. The lesson is clear: successful industrialisation requires close

    trading and investment links between the industrialising country and a

    state or several states at a much higher level of development, which regard

    it not as a competitor but either as an addition to its own economic systems

    or as an opening for significant investment and technology transfer.

    The alliance between Russia and China, or, to put it more accurately,

    Russia’s following of China’s trajectory, is not based on such cooperation.

    This is almost the only case in the world when a leading (or, at least, larger)

    economy is not interested in developing its satellite and cannot offer

    anything to help that satellite move forward quickly. The most that China is

    capable of is to promote quantitative growth in the Russian economy

    without structural change. This begs the question of whether economic

    issues are at all important to the Russian elite when charting a course in

    foreign policy and choosing allies on the world stage. Positioning in foreign

    policy and the choice of allies is clearly another obstacle on the road to a

    “new industrialisation” of Russia.

  • The Russian elite

    The fourth set of problems is directly bound up with the defining features

    of the Russian political elite and with Russian bureaucrats as a class.

    First, this elite is a “raw materials elite”, focused on maintaining

    control of its own sector of the economy, extracting as much revenue as

    possible for the budget and redistributing budget flows. It should be noted

    that this is not a “timeless characteristic” but a new phenomenon that can

    be traced back to the start of Putin’s presidency. A catastrophic mistake

    was made in 2002 which set this process in train, namely the introduction

    of the Minerals Extraction Tax and a new system of export duties: from

    that time onwards, the state bureaucracy and the oligarchs who controlled

    the raw materials began to merge, while the idea of a “rent economy”

    appeared for domestic consumption and the “energy superpower” for the

    wider world. It was the Putin period of Russian history that witnessed the

    most dramatic rise in the share of Russian exports made up of “mineral

    products”, from 54% in 2000 to 72% in 2013.16 When oligarchs and state

    officials are one and the same, of course, it is difficult to promote the idea

    of industrialisation which, one way or another requires that the oligarchs’

    appetites be curbed. In essence, the very idea of an “energy superpower”

    implies that, under the current leadership, industrialisation and

    modernization cannot be regarded as anything other than fiction or cheap

    propaganda, if only because it is impossible to industrialise the country

    without stepping on the toes of representatives of the raw materials

    companies.

    Second, this elite is “attached” to the Soviet Union, not in terms of

    ideology or intellectual calibre but with respect to the material assets that

    underlie its wealth. Seventy four of the largest 100 Russian firms by market

    capitalisation work almost exclusively with fixed assets dating from the

    Soviet era (for comparison, 14 of the 30 companies that now make up the

    Dow Jones Industrial Average were not part of it the last time it was

    revised in Soviet times, on 6 May 1991), while only 4 of China’s 100 largest

    companies by capitalisation are critically reliant on productive capacity

    16. Rosstat data issued from www.gks.ru..

    http://www.gks.ru/

  • Modernization of the Russian Economy Vladislav Inozemtsev

    15

    brought on line 25 years ago or more.17 The elite’s unwillingness to

    countenance change is therefore understandable, for the greater the

    changes, the higher the risks for old companies that are sure to lose out in a

    competitive contest. Industrialisation does not figure in the Russian elite’s

    plans, not only because it calls into question the role of the raw materials

    sector, but also because it entails greater competition in industry as a

    whole. This explains the generally negative attitude towards foreign

    investment in industry: since the 2000s, when it guaranteed basic

    standards of production in a range of sectors focused on the consumer

    market, the flow of inward investment has almost dried up.

    Third, the Russian bureaucratic machine is constructed in such a way

    that corruption is not a by-product, but its main motive force. The

    effectiveness of the “vertical of power” in modern Russia relies on the

    “vertical of corruption”.18 Corruption on such a huge scale, however, is

    incompatible with industrial development, for two reasons. On the one

    hand, the cut that state employees are prepared to take increases as the

    state grows stronger, but if these bribes come not from redistributing rent

    but by extorting money from industry, the latter quickly becomes

    uncompetitive (for instance, corruption has made building roads and

    infrastructure so expensive that it has all but stopped). In today’s Russia,

    the official tax burden on business is similar to that in developed countries

    but considering that corruption increases that burden by at least a third, it

    is clear that only the most monopolistic of firms can survive in such an

    environment, which is toxic to rapid industrial development (the mass

    creation of state corporations supports this view). On the other hand, the

    bureaucracy must have a pretext to engage in corruption and in Russia, it

    finds these grounds in regulation: the more rules and norms that

    businesses must follow, the easier it is to keep them “under the thumb”.

    This is why 1970s-era technical regulations and standards are still in force

    in Russia. There is no willingness to adopt regulations that would accord

    with those used in Europe or OECD countries while over the past five

    years, taxes have been supplemented or changed once every two weeks, on

    average. The problem here is that the competitive industry should update

    its product lines fast enough that is impossible with the shifting

    regulations. By building its “vertical of power”, therefore, the political elite

    has knowingly condemned Russia to being a mere supplier of raw

    materials.

    17. For more details, see: V. Inozemtsev, “Chto tyanet nas obratno v SSSR? Ne FSB i ne ‘Edinaya

    Rossiya’” [What is pulling us back into the USSR? Not the FSB and not ‘United Russia’”], Slon ,

    20 May 2015, https://slon.ru.

    18. For more details, see: I. Krastev and V. Inozemtsev, “Putin’s Self-destruction”, Foreign Affairs,

    9 June 2013, www.foreignaffairs.com.

    https://slon.ru/posts/51710http://www.foreignaffairs.com/articles/139442/ivan-krastev-and-vladislav-inozemtsev/putins-self-destruction

  • Modernization of the Russian Economy Vladislav Inozemtsev

    16

    Fourth, developed industrial enterprises have always been, and still

    remain, places where relatively well organised workers gather together: the

    modern workers’ and trade unions’ movement was born with the rise of

    industry for the simple reason that industrial production was a collective

    enterprise. The political elite in Russia is able to manipulate society

    because it is divided, while its strategy generally rests on suppressing

    collective action as much as possible.19 There is abundant evidence that the

    Russian authorities are wary of any sign that an independent trade union

    movement might be in the offing and they are hostile to any form of

    professional solidarity. This, then, is yet another reason (not the main one

    but important nonetheless) why the idea of rapid industrialisation is

    discounted. History—in the case of, say, South Korea or Taiwan—clearly

    shows what fate lies in store for members of the ruling elite when

    industrialisation leads to the creation of a strong and independent middle

    class (in Russia, the middle class currently consists largely of state

    employees), the development of democracy and the advent not only of

    economic, but also of political, competition. This helps to explain why

    modernization is not on the agenda in Russia today.

    Fifth and finally, another obvious factor should be noted. Over the last

    decade, Russia’s elite has evolved by “negative selection”, with competence

    sacrificed in the name of loyalty.20 Although this allows the elite to feel that

    it is insured against change, it sharply undercuts efficiency, which is crucial

    for industrial development. It would be no exaggeration to say that modern

    Russian politics neglects efficiency in favour of stability. This approach is at

    odds with modernization (and industrialisation as its most important

    component), which promotes efficiency as the ultimate objective and

    attach less importance to other considerations. In modern Russia, shifting

    the emphasis onto efficiency is taboo for politicians and state servants who

    are unused (and most of whom are unable) to working in an environment

    where efficiency is the main yardstick by which their actions are judged.

    Therefore, the system will almost certainly sacrifice industrialisation and

    efficiency, preferring to keep the old hierarchical structure of governance

    intact.

    We could also discuss at length such weighty problems as official

    accountability, the transparency of contracts and the absence of a truly

    19. V. Inozemtsev, “Russie, une société libre sous contrôle autoritaire” [Russia, a free society

    under authoritarian rule], Le Monde diplomatique, October 2010, No.10, p. 4-5, www.monde-

    diplomatique.fr.

    20. V. Inozemtsev, “Neo-Feudalism Explained”, The American Interest, March-April 2011, Vol. 6,

    No.4, p. 73-80, www.the-american-interest.com.

    https://www.monde-diplomatique.fr/2010/10/INOZEMTSEV/19776https://www.monde-diplomatique.fr/2010/10/INOZEMTSEV/19776http://www.the-american-interest.com/2011/03/01/neo-feudalism-explained/

  • Modernization of the Russian Economy Vladislav Inozemtsev

    17

    independent legal system. All these factors are crucial, but they have been

    amply explored before.

  • Public Opinion

    The fifth set of problems which reduces the likelihood of modernization in

    Russia to near zero is the unprecedented state of public opinion in Russia

    (diligently cultivated by the authorities), which prevents reforms from

    being launched.

    History shows that for modernization to be successful, both the

    elites and the people must recognise that the current state of affairs is

    unbearable and that it must change. Change involves analysing earlier

    mistakes and understanding that modernization is about catching up with

    countries that have been more successful and have pulled ahead. The very

    notion of “modernization” can be understood as “bringing up to date”, and

    it therefore partly implies that the country is currently on the decline.

    Without this awareness, modernization cannot succeed, since it can only

    yield temporary achievements that are easily dismantled as soon as the

    course of politics changes. Russia is an anti-model in this respect: each

    century, it tries to modernize at least once, only to start discussing a new

    round of modernization. The explanation for this recurring pattern lies in

    the fact that the elites do not understand why modernization is needed and

    the people feel that they have no stake in it. Successful modernization

    occurs where the authorities decide that they must break with the past and

    face the future, while also knowing how to excite the people’s interest in the

    changes ahead. Lee Kuan Yew in the 1960s, Den Xiaoping in the 1980s and

    Fernando Cardoso in the 1990s embodied precisely this strategy.

    Moscow has taken the polar opposite approach on both counts. The

    authorities, having bowed to populism, are unable to admit that the

    situation in Russia is bordering on catastrophic (on the contrary, they say

    that the country has “risen from its knees” and will be outstripping its chief

    opponents in no time). This alone is enough to discredit modernization. On

    the ideological level, moreover, the elites are busy searching for a line of

    historical succession that would connect them to the Soviet Union, whose

    positive image is becoming the main tool of official propaganda. Of course,

    if you convince the people that they will soon reach an ideal state, what

    sense does it make to talk about modernization? Why strike out into an

    unknown future when it is much simpler and more comprehensible to

    recreate the past? Populism, moreover, involves focusing on the

    distribution of goods and the paternalistic role of the state, whereas

    modernization always entails huge investment and certain restrictions on

  • Modernization of the Russian Economy Vladislav Inozemtsev

    19

    the growth of consumption. Therefore, the government’s unwillingness to

    demystify the past and the people’s unwillingness to restrict current

    consumption for future benefit constitute the last, but most important,

    reason why modernization will not receive wide support in Russia, either

    now or in the near future.

  • The global situation

    Finally, the sixth set of reasons, which stood out in sharp relief after the

    latest attempt at modernization had failed, is connected to changing

    economic outlook in Russia and the world. Oil prices fell sharply in 2014,

    leading to a decline in export revenues and a dramatic weakening—nearly

    twofold—of the rouble. As the experience of various different

    modernization drives shows, success depends on either large-scale imports

    of technology and equipment, if the goal is to increase exports, or active

    capital investment on the part of foreign companies if they are intent on

    capturing the country’s market. In today’s Russia, neither condition

    applies.

    First, the government must ensure that it can cover its budget

    expenditure, even though expenditure this year is 10-15% lower than

    planned, and pensions, which accordingly the law should be indexed at the

    rate of inflation, have risen by only 4%, while inflation runs at 13%. A weak

    rouble is therefore in the state’s interest because export duties on oil and

    gas, which make up close to a third of budget income, are denominated in

    dollars. The weaker the currency, the more roubles flow into the budget.

    From the point of view of modernization, though, this trend is ruinous

    because over the last two decades, most of the equipment needed to

    improve production was bought abroad, so when the rouble falls, it

    becomes unfeasible for companies to make such investments. All the

    attempts at “import substitution” are unrealistic: Russia is decades behind

    in producing modern industrial equipment and what it does produce is

    often even more expensive than the imported versions. Theoretically,

    therefore, Russia could only have modernized when the price of oil was

    high. However, when the going was good, no one even considered it.

    Second, in the past, an alternative driver of modernization might have

    been investment by Western companies in production for the domestic

    Russian market. This occurred on a limited scale in the 2000s when new

    car factories were built by western corporations. They were interested in

    Russia because of the size of its internal market (it was said that Russia

    would be the largest market for cars in Europe by 2016)21 and its isolation

    21. Based on projections made by Boston Consulting Group in 2013, see: D. Nizhegorodtsev,

    “V 2016 godu Rossiia stanet krupnejshim avtomobil’nym rynkom Evropy” [In 2016 Russia will

    become Europe’s largest market for cars], Vzgliad, 19 July 2013, www.vz.ru.

    http://www.vz.ru/news/2013/7/19/641957.html

  • Modernization of the Russian Economy Vladislav Inozemtsev

    21

    from the WTO, which promised significant cost reductions when localising

    production. Since the start of the economic crisis, however, the Russian car

    market has contracted by more than 45% and costs are not nearly as

    attractive as they were before: the same goes for an array of other products

    which Western investors sought to make in Russia (white goods, TVs and

    radios, construction materials).22 It is not profitable to invest hard currency

    in Russia only to sell products on the internal market in devalued roubles.

    This just goes to reconfirm a surprising paradox: in a country that is

    dependent on exporting raw materials, modernization is only possible

    when the price of these exports is at its height. Besides, it is only achieved

    in places where the authorities are competent enough to grasp this fact. To

    date, only the leaders of the United Arab Emirates have done so.

    22. See: D. Lomakin, “Padal, padaet i budet padat’” [“It fell, is falling and is going to fall],

    Gazeta.ru, 14 January 2016, www.gazeta.ru.

    http://www.gazeta.ru/auto/2016/01/14_a_8021765.shtml

  • Conclusion

    To sum up, modernization is not on the cards at present, with Russia

    increasingly alienated from the wider world, oil and gas prices low, the

    increasingly ineffective ruling class, and ideology clashing with economics.

    Indeed, in the eyes of most Russians, modernization is not even desirable.

    The Putin regime’s greatest political “achievement” has been to convince

    most Russians that following the course of global progress is not only

    pointless but also dangerous for the country. The atmosphere in Russia is

    now such that regression and backwardness are interpreted as evidence

    that the country is succeeding on its special path. In such circumstances,

    discussing modernization is purely theoretical.

    Does this mean that modernization will never happen in Russia or, in

    a phrase widely repeated during the presidency of Dmitry Medvedev, that

    “there is no alternative to modernization”? Both these inferences are

    mistaken.

    Modernization will certainly become a priority in Russia, but only

    after the country has passed through a deep crisis, when the population

    experiences something similar to what happened at the beginning of the

    1990s, when they fell into poverty; when the political class is finally

    convinced that its foreign policy has completely failed; when the country is

    on the verge of collapse and the people lose all faith in the “law

    enforcement oligarchy.” Modernization will begin when Russians look

    ahead and reject the former regime. Since the Kremlin’s current policies

    are leading to this sorry end, there is no doubt that modernization of the

    economy and of society will occur in Russia, though not any time soon.

    On the other hand, in the meantime there undoubtedly is an

    alternative to modernization, which consists of preserving the country

    intact, a gradual decline in living standards, paralysis of the political

    system, an increase in emigration and a stronger role for the state in the

    economy. Venezuela shows where such policies will lead. However, if

    problems build up relatively slowly, the Russian population is prepared to

    put up with them for a long time. Although modernization is bound to

    happen in Russia eventually, therefore, one cannot expect it to take place in

    the next 10-15 years as a factor in economic and foreign policy.

  • The Latest Publications of

    Russie.Nei.Visions

    V. Likhachev, “The Far Right in the Conflict between Russia and

    Ukraine”, Russie.Nei.Visions, No. 95, July 2016.

    D. Trenin, “Russia’s Asia Strategy: Bolstering the Eagle’s Eastern

    Wing”, Russie.Nei.Visions, No. 94, June 2016.

    A. Shumilin, “Russia's Diplomacy in the Middle East: Back to

    Geopolitics”, Russie.Nei.Visions, No. 93, May 2016.

    B. Lo, “The illusion of convergence—Russia, China, and the BRICS”,

    Russie.Nei.Visions, No. 92, February 2016.

    L. Bisson, “Russia’s Immigration Policy: New Challenges and Tools”,

    Russie.Nei.Visions, No. 91.

    L. Polyakov, “‘Conservatism’ in Russia: Political Tool or Historical

    Choice?”, Russie.Nei.Visions, No. 90, December 2015.

    I. Timofeev, E. Alekseenkova, “Eurasia in Russian Foreign Policy:

    Interests, Opportunities and Constraints”, Russie.Nei.Visions, No. 89,

    December 2015.

    I. Bunin, A. Makarkin, “Russia: Business and State”,

    Russie.Nei.Visions, No. 88, November 2015.

    M. Korostikov, “Leaving to Come Back: Russian Senior Officials and

    the State-Owned Companies”, Russie.Nei.Visions, No. 87, August 2015.

    V. Milov, “Russia’s New Energy Alliances: Mythology versus Reality”,

    Russie.Nei.Visions, No. 86, July 2015.

    I. Delanoë, “The Kurds: A Channel of Russian Influence in the Middle

    East?”, Russie.Nei.Visions, No. 85, June 2015.

    If you wish to be notified of upcoming publications (or receive additional

    information), please e-mail: [email protected]

    https://www.ifri.org/en/publications/notes-de-lifri/russieneivisions/far-right-conflict-between-russia-and-ukrainehttps://www.ifri.org/en/publications/notes-de-lifri/russieneivisions/far-right-conflict-between-russia-and-ukrainehttps://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/rnv94_uk_russias_asia_strategy.pdfhttps://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/rnv94_uk_russias_asia_strategy.pdfhttps://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/rnv93_version_uk_final_protege.pdfhttps://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/rnv93_version_uk_final_protege.pdfhttps://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/ifri_rnv_92_bobo_lo_brics-eng_march_2016_0.pdfhttps://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/ifri_rnv_91_lioubov_bisson_eng_january_2016_protege.pdfhttps://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/ifri_rnv_90_eng_poliakkov_protege.pdfhttps://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/ifri_rnv_90_eng_poliakkov_protege.pdfhttp://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/ifri_rnv_89_timofeev_alexeenkova_eng_december_2015_protege_0.pdfhttp://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/ifri_rnv_89_timofeev_alexeenkova_eng_december_2015_protege_0.pdfhttp://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/ifri_rnv_88_bunin_makarkin_eng_november_2015.pdfhttps://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/ifri_rnv_87_eng_mikhail_korostikov_august_2015.pdfhttps://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/ifri_rnv_87_eng_mikhail_korostikov_august_2015.pdfhttps://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/ifri_rnv_86-eng_milov_energy_june_2015.pdfhttp://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/ifri_rnv_85_ru-igor_delanoe_kurdy_vektor_rossiyskogo_vliyaniya_na_blizhnem_vostoke_iyun_2015.pdfhttp://www.ifri.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/ifri_rnv_85_ru-igor_delanoe_kurdy_vektor_rossiyskogo_vliyaniya_na_blizhnem_vostoke_iyun_2015.pdfmailto:[email protected]


Recommended