+ All Categories
Home > Documents > SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe...

SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe...

Date post: 03-Mar-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 1 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
21
Faculteit der Economische Wetenschappen en Bedrijfskunde SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA Coping with Uncertainty An Expedition in the Field of New Transport Technology Marina van Ceenhuizen Peter Nijkamp Research Memorandum 2001-9 March 2001 vrije Universiteit amsterdam
Transcript
Page 1: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

Faculteit der Economische Wetenschappen en Bedrijfskunde

SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA

Coping with Uncertainty

An Expedition in the Field of New Transport Technology

Marina van CeenhuizenPeter Nijkamp

Research Memorandum 2001-9

March 2001

vrije Universiteit amsterdam

Page 2: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

COPING WITH UNCERTAINTY

An Expedition in the Field of New Transport Technology

Marina van Geenhuizen *

Peter Nijkamp * *

Abstract

Many decisions of mankind are rational only to a limited extent. This holds for individualtravel behaviour, but also for long-range strategic decisions on transport systems or transporttechnology. In any decision problem coping with uncertainty is the most critical element.The introduction of new transport technology is surrounded by many types of uncertainty. Forexample, there is uncertainty about the pace and extent of adoption of new technology andthere is uncertainty about the impact of new technology in terms of an increased sustainabilityor increased efficiency. This article attempts to map uncertainty surrounding new transporttechnology and to identify ways to deal with uncertainty in policy making. The findings willbe illustrated with electric vehicles, particularly with two specific strategies to deal withuncertainty, i.e. interactive technology watching and experimentation in a market niche. Thearticle concludes with a discussion of success factors that influence the outcomes of suchstrategies.

*Faculty of Technology, Policy and Management, Delft University of Technology, Delft**Department of Spatial Economics, Free University, Amsterdam

Pn893mvg

1

t

Page 3: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

1. Homo Mobilis and Homo Economicus

Conventional wisdom in transport science suggests that transport movements serve to

overcome physical distance barriers. Such movements are - apart from a few rare cases like

leisure trips without a destination - necessary because of the geographical separation of

various activities (residential, employment, social etc.). Since transport is regarded as a

burden, the rational decision-making paradigm then suggests that it is wise to minimise the

transport effort. In particular, welfare theory - one of the comer stones of transport economics

- argues that it is in the interest of the ‘homo economicus’ to minimise travel costs

(pecuniary, time-wise or psychological).

This assumption lies at the basis of many utility-based demand studies (e.g., discrete choice

models) but has also created the foundation of many aggregate transport studies (such as

quadratic assignment models, linear programming models for modal split or route choice and

the like). In fact, the overwhelming majority of transport studies looks into physical

movement as a sacrifice. If this basic assumption were valid, then a series of intricate and

intriguing questions emerges. How come that the action radius of modem men tends to

increase structurally (see, e.g., van Doren, 1991)? How is it possible that the ‘law of

conservation of travel time’ is rather robust (at least in metropolitan areas), but shows an

increasing trend for longer trips? Is the modem ‘homo mobilis’ essentially a ‘homo

economicus’ or is he driven by other - also rational - instincts?

In a recent study on ‘slow motion’ (see Nijkamp and Baaijens, 1999) a review of motives in

favour of other - less fast and (perhaps) more environmentally benign - modes of transport

was given, based on the recently developed concept of a ‘time pioneer’. The argument is that

it may - from both an individual and a collective welfare perspective - be rational to reduce

travel speed. Empirical research however, demonstrated that the willingness among travellers

to choose ‘slow motion’ options is disappointingly low. On the contrary, the trend is towards

more speed and a larger action radius. Does this mean that the ‘homo mobilis’ is not a rational

decision-maker? It should be noted that the basic hypothesis in welfare theory is that the.individual seeks to maximise his (her) own welfare, based on the assumption of perfect

information and on the absence of externalities, bandwagon and image effects, and the like.

There is quite some literature, in particular in the 1960s geography, which convincingly

demonstrates - both conceptually and empirically - that the choice of the actual location of

2

Page 4: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

firms can differ significantly from the theoretical optimal location (see e.g., Wolpert, 1964).

This is then explained by the prohibitive role of high search costs to find the optimum

optimorum. Choice makers tend to be often satisfied with a second-best - or even third-best -

location, as they are not driven by the exclusive goals of profit seeking behaviour. The

theoretical basis of this ‘satisficing’ behaviour has been given by Herbert Simon in this theory

on ‘bounded rationality’ (see Simon 1952).

Apart from the costs involved in gathering perfect information, there is also a social driving

force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an

isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion of the ‘homo socialis’). For

example, the need to live near one’s relatives may lead to a residential location decision that is

not optimal from a cost-minimising viewpoint. Consequently, there is quite some evidence

that travel decisions are not exclusively governed by rational - cost-minimising, utility-

maximising or profit-maximising - behaviour. Theoretically speaking, this would imply a

specification bias in many of our behaviour transport models. In any case, the ‘homo mobilis’

is faced with many uncertainties in his (her) travel choice; perfect information is an illusion.

This recognition may have serious implications for the precise value of transport models and

limits seriously the scope of cybernetics oriented engineering approaches in transport science.

There is still another issue. To assemble proper information may be too costly, but the human

ability to digest all relevant information is also limited. Consequently, the available or

existing information may also be selective and has to be interpreted from the subjective

perspective of the user or decision-maker. Furthermore, if travel information has to be

transmitted to road users, the question is whether a particular road user needs exactly the

given information. In many cases, he may be willing to receive additional or other

information. This is clearly reflected in an early statement of March and Simon: “...the vast

bulk of our knowledge offact is not gained through direct perception but through the second-

hand, third-hand, and nth-hand reports of the perceptions of others, transmitted through the

channels of social communication. Since these,perceptions have already been filtered by one

or more communicators, most of whom have frames of reference similar to our own, theareports are generally consonant without the filtered reports of our own perceptions, and serve

to reinforce the latter” (March and Simon, 1958, pp. 153).

3

Page 5: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

The previous remarks do not only apply to daily or routine decisions. They are equally

relevant for strategic decisions of a long-range nature on transport systems or transport

technology. Coping with uncertainty is essentially the most critical element in any decision

problem. This question extends far beyond stochastic or probabilistic approaches to

uncertainty management. In the sequel of this article we will address in particular uncertainty

issues in the field of transport systems technology, but most remarks apply also to uncertainty

problems in the broader area of transport management and policy.

2. Exploring the Future

In the past decades we have observed a great variety of attempts to come to grips with an

uncertain future. This is clearly exemplified by the path breaking work of Kahn and Wiener

on “The Year 2000”, published in 1967. The question is whether much progress has been

made in the past decades. This provokes in particular a complicated methodological issue, as

it asks whether better understanding does also lead to better forecasting. Some remarks on this

issue are in order now. Explanation is a process of logical deduction and empirical validation,

in particular in the context of repetitive events. In a strict sense it would be impossible to

subject “unique” events to a scientific explanation. In any case, an explanation in a

probabilistic statement of an “if-then” nature, which - given a predetermined domain - is able

to make a scientifically founded statement on the possible or probabilistic occurrence of

events as part or as a result of events which fall outside the a prior, defined domain. Thus, an

explanation has quite some restrictions. Its validity is limited by prior hypotheses and by

methodological constraints.

From a methodological perspective there is not so much distinction between explanation and

forecasting, apart from an obvious difference between prospective and retrospective thinking.

But also forecasting is a process of logical analysis on the basis of empirically verifiable

relationships, with the only exception that exogenous variables - falling outside of the

forecasting domain - cannot be empirically observed, but can at least be hypothesised (e.g. on.the basis of plausible reasoning). But in principle one might argue that forecasting =

explanation.

Page 6: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

In the history of future studies we may distinguish various approaches which aim to offer a

scientific underpinning for statements on future events. Examples are the following:

Blueprint thinking. In this mode of thinking the basic assumption is that it is possible to

define a feasible amount of targets in the future, which can be realised through the right

use of instruments. The idea of a “makeable” society - very popular in the seventies and

eighties- is illustrative for this approach.

Normative thinking. Here the idea is that a society may evolve according to a priori fixed,

normative -sometimes ethical- criteria.

Nested thinking. This is based on the conviction that the future as a whole is difficult to

forecast, but that certain parts or aspects (e.g., demography, technology) may be mapped

out with a sufficient accuracy.

Fiction thinking. This type of future thinking is based on a non-historical approach and

questions the limits posed by past constraints.

Scenario thinking. This has become a popular way of analysing the future. It presupposes

the design or existence of meaningful - not necessarily realistic - future images, but it

demands that such images meet strict methodological requirements such as internal

consistency and a bridging between the present and the future. Such scenarios are

politically not committing, but offer a spectrum of future developments (e.g. Nijkamp and

van Geenhuizen, 1997; Nijkamp et al., 1998).

Evolutionary thinking. This approach is not based on normative or policy views, but

assumes some sort of adjustment mechanism in human behaviour (e.g., resilience), which

drives living organisms or systems towards “continuity in change”. It also draws attention

to a phenomenon named path dependency, meaning that future moves in policy making

are constrained by decisions made in the past.

Learning thinking. This mode of thinking has already a long history (see, e.g. Harvey,

1967) but has recently become fashionable in connection with evolutionary thinking.

Popular concepts in this framework are the learning decision-maker, the learning

organisation, the learning city, etc. This principle forms a contrast with blueprint and

normative thinking and avoids “linear” thinking. It is based on a blend of positive and

negative feedback responses in a dynamic choice environment (e.g. Stacey, 1992).

5

Page 7: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

The previous observations hold also for transport technology. The high risks of new

technologies may hamper a rapid introduction. But also the acceptance attitude of the user

may cause a stumbling block. These issues will be further discussed in the next sections.

3. The Uncertain Roads of Transport Systems

Transport is the spatial projection of societal dynamics. The 21” century will see a variety of

new social and technological trends which will influence the way in which transport is

supplied and utilised (cf. Becker, 1997). At present a wide range of social phenomena,

including rising incomes, increased leisure time, new communication technologies, an ageing

population and a declining role for the traditional family, are changing the nature of the

demands we place on transport. In response to new techniques of production, shipping and the

growth of markets, economic activities are also changing. Institutional reforms such as

privatisation and deregulation have changed transport in ways that are not yet well

understood. At the same time increasing use of petroleum resources for travel and transport

has raised concerns about the eventual depletion of fossil fuels as well as its contribution to

global warming and decreases in urban air quality. But from a methodological perspective we

have to ask ourselves: do we have the scientific apparatus to forecast uncertain future

developments, trends or events, particularly those that are crucial in the adoption of new

transport technology?

New technology may affect the transport system in two different ways. First, there is

optimisation of the current transport system by using existing potentials, and secondly, there

is the much more comprehensive structural change of the transport system. A good example

of the first is the electric vehicle because the concept of individual cars remains unaffected in

merely challenging the type of traction system. However, if electric vehicles are used in new

concepts of carpooling and mixed forms of private and public transport (using busses)

attention moves to structural changes in the transport system (Rutten et al., 1998).

Accordingly, the latter case involves much more uncertainty.

.

Uncertainty can be tackled from various angles. For example, Rowe (1994) in elaborating

uncertainty as the “absence of information”, makes a division into various dimensions (van

Geenhuizen et al., 1998):

6

Page 8: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

l Temporal uncertainty. This refers to the future state of the transport system (prediction

uncertainty) and related systems, but also to the past states of these systems.

l Structural uncertainty. This refers to the complexity of the transport system in modelling.

Structural uncertainty depends on the number of parameters and interaction used in

models to describe a situation or development. The key question is how well the models

represent reality.

l Metrical uncertainty. This is concerned with difficulties in measurement of the system.

Central issues here are precision and accuracy (validity). Such uncertainty plays a role for

example, in measuring preferences of travellers in public transport.

l Translational uncertainty. This refers to the communication of the results of analysis and

modelling in a policy context. Goals and values of the stakeholders are the main issue

because these affect the interpretation of the results and the related effort in consensus

building.

All four dimensions of uncertainty occur in any situation and reinforce each other. The last

dimension - translational uncertainty - indicates the importance of stakeholders in policy

making. Their interests may be different, dependent upon their goals and means, problem

perception and interpretations. An interesting example in this framework is the estimation of

future traffic flow and the estimation of costs of large transport projects (Skamris and

Flyvbjerg, 1997). A compilation of before-and-after-studies of various large projects shows

considerable cost overruns (of 50-100%) and traffic forecasts that are remarkably optimistic

(by 20 to 60%). The differences between forecast and actual costs and traffic cannot be

explained primarily by structural uncertainty. By being strongly consistent and one-sided the

uncertainty that has entered is much more of the translational type and needs to be seen - as

Wynne (1992) puts it - as a “social construct”.

By adopting the perspective of policy making and by conceptualising the relevant part of

reality as a system, four classes of uncertainty can be distinguished (see the introduction of

this special issue):

a

l Uncertainty about the future outcomes of the system

l Uncertainty about the future behaviour of external influences

7

Page 9: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

l Uncertainty about system behaviour, connected with the above mentioned structural and

metrical uncertainty

l Uncertainty in the selection ofpolicy measures, including guiding values.

This classification serves as a framework in our identification of uncertainty in policy making

on the adoption of electric vehicles in the next section.

4. Policy Making concerning Electric Vehicles

The development of electric vehicle technology during the end of the lgti and beginning of

the 20” century exemplifies highly dynamic processes with unexpected outcomes (Isoard,

1996; Cowan and Hulten, 1996). At the start of the market introduction at that time electric

cars were far ahead compared with gasoline cars. The gasoline engine was considered to be

inferior because of the noise it produced, and its unsafe and dirty character. There was also a

need for some additional but complicated technical innovations. However, the strategic

behaviour of a few gasoline car producers - especially their move to a mass market and use of

specific marketing tools - has given the gasoline car a position ahead. Due to subsequent

advantages from increasing returns to scale (and lock-in), the gasoline engine could maintain

this position whereas competing technologies faced progressively greater difficulty in

entering or surviving in the market. This example shows the ill-predictability of the winning

technology - connected with various small events (or actions) - and the non-superiority of the

selected path.

A detailed analysis of the adoption of electric vehicles as it is to-day and of concomitant

policy making brings a differentiated “landscape of uncertainty” to light (van Geenhuizen and

Schoonman, 1999; Mulder et al. 1996; Rutten et al., 1998). The key uncertainty belongs to the

behaviour of the system, i.e. user acceptance, and to the future outcomes of the system (Table

1). Accordingly, it is difficult to select the appropriate policy measures. In fact, we are not

able-to model user acceptance behaviour and policy impacts in such a way that it helps to

predict the adoption of electric vehicles and to get insight into underlying factors. Metrical

uncertainty, of course, contributes to the lack of adequate prediction results. For example,

despite progress there are still measurement problems to solve in studies focusing on stated

preference (of users) (e.g. Golob et al., 1996) and on opinions (of experts) (e.g. Mulder et al.,

8

.‘.

Page 10: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

1996). The uncertainty that stems from the critical user acceptance seems connected with

performance and price aspects of electric vehicles, i.e. a relatively small range, danger of dead

battery and relatively expensive to buy, but there is more. Over the past decades cars have

increased freedom, mobility, prestige, and a whole lot more in the life of individuals (e.g.,

Marsh and Collet, 1986). It may take therefore, a number of years to add the totally different

attribute of environmental ideals to this range. Moreover, electric cars may never attract

drivers that are moved by car appeal going far beyond merely functional transport.

Knowledge of such appeals and their influence is too small to date in order to contribute to

sound predictions. The same holds for uncertainty in the case of mixed private-public

transport using electric busses. Here, we may expect user resistance based on a general

aversion against all modes that are different from the individually used car. On the other hand,

environmental motives may become strong in the segment of second cars in households and

in the segment of business cars. Both are growth markets, and we may be able to predict how

fast these segments will grow in the next coming years.

Table 1 Uncertainty in policy making for electric vehicles

Element Details

Future outcomes

External influences

System behaviour

Selection of policymeasures

*

- Achieving aimed results- Causing negative side-effects- Behaviour of actors in dominant technologies

(resistance from lock-in), such as conventionalcar manufacturers and fuelling industries

- Growth of customer segments with largeopportunities (second cars, business cars)

- The time that high performance batteries andfuel cells are available at a competitive price

- Divides within the technology, such as low andhigh temperature battery systems, leading topotential incompatibilities

- Critical user acceptance: Willingness to payextra and bear inconvenience for environmentalgains; willingness to “lose freedom orindependence” in a shift to non-private transport

- Effectiveness of measures, e.g. of incentives,subsidies

- Missing guiding values

Strength ofuncertaintyStrongStrong

Weak

Weak

W e a k

W e a k

Strong

StrongWeak/strong

The uncertainty in future outcomes of the system can be summarised as follows. Due to

uncertain system behaviour and uncertain inputs, the latter mainly from external factors, we

9

Page 11: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

are not able to predict the outcomes of the system in terms of a move towards reaching policy

aims, such as sustainable energy aims and prevention of externalities (noise, emission). The

same holds for adverse effect, like an increase in overall car mobility, due to the use of

electric cars as second (third) cars in households. Buying electric cars may serve as a kind of

justification, whereas without a pushing policy of electric cars no second or third cars would

have been bought.

As far as technology is concerned, uncertainty seems far less strong. Battery and fuel cell

technology will need some more 5 years before these can be used in high performance and

cost competitive electric vehicles. Research on improved performance and reduction of

production costs of light weight rechargeable solid-state lithium-ion batteries is of particular

interest. Research focuses on the stability, compatibility, and electrical properties of the

battery components. World-wide research also focuses on cost reduction of polymer fuel

cells, among others by reducing the amount of platinum catalyst. The uncertainty that is

involved seems to be “manageable” in that it can be reduced by increased research and

development efforts (van Geenhuizen and Schoonman, 1999).

In terms of guiding values, an important missing link in policy making to date is a clear vision

on the functions of transport, other than the straightforward bridging of distance. These other

functions may be strongly (social) psychological, like a gain of individual freedom, increase

of power, and gain of identity. In a situation in which it is generally accepted that car driving

only serves the functional bridging of distance, designing a policy to enhance the adoption of

electric vehicles is less difficult compared with a situation without such a guiding value.

The above circumstances indicate a large uncertainty in the selection of policy measures to

enhance the adoption of electric vehicles. The way how policy makers may deal with

uncertainty will be discussed in the next section.

5. Strategies to Cope with Uncertainty.

There are many strategies for coping with uncertainties, each using different methods. The

following strategies can be distinguished (e.g., Friend and Hickling, 1997; van Geenhuizen et

al., 1998; van Geenhuizen and Thissen, 2001):

1 0

t

Page 12: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

l To ignore uncertainty, take policy measures, and see what will happen; while this may be

the easiest option for the short term, it means in fact accepting large uncertainty with

respect to the policy outcomes.

l To identify and, if possible, specify uncertainty. This enables the policy maker to act

consciously in the presence of uncertainty. The classifications above may be helpful in

this respect. Methods to identify and specify uncertainties include scenario analysis (e.g.

for uncertainty in the system’s surroundings) (Nijkamp et al., 1998; von Reibnitz, 1998;

Schwartz, 1991), development of alternative system models to account for alternative

structures, and determination of confidence bounds for data and model parameters.

l To do nothing and let uncertainty be reduced by time; this approach means delay, and

involves a good chance that, while some uncertainties will disappear, new ones will

emerge. Doing nothing may be a positive choice, based on a vision in which the self-

organising capacity of society and particular interest groups is given priority and is trusted

to achieve satisfactory outcomes.

l To reduce uncertainty. This can be done in different ways. First, by additional research or

better integration of existing knowledge; this might cover the range from the collection of

new data to the application of advanced methods of integrated modelling and explorative

modelling to more clearly distinguish between possible and impossible developments, and

to identify critical events and bottlenecks. Second, by pushing the uncertainty onto

someone else, which generally will involve costs (e.g., insurance premiums,

compensation). Third, by negotiating with others whose behaviour is uncertain but has a

significant impact on the desired policy outcomes. This may involve processes of

participatory policy development, and/or agreements with policy makers in adjacent

fields.

l To accept uncertainty, and act consciously in its presence. Here, too, different strategies

are possible. A robust policy may be selected, i.e., a policy that will do well in most

possible future circumstances. Or a flexible policy is designed, i.e., a policy that is

adaptable to the future course of events (e.g. Walker et al., 2001).

l To see uncertainty not as a threat, but rather as an opportunity to creatively shape the

future. Rather than emphasising a choice for a presently available policy option, this

approach calls for development of a vision that provides the guiding principles for present

and future action, such as experiments and other learning exercises that may underpin

policy measures (Stacey, 1992).

1 1

:‘.

‘I

I’. _ _-

Page 13: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

It seems self-understanding that the above strategies do not exclude each other but often

complement each other. We now turn to two complementary roles adopted by the Dutch

government in an attempt to identify and specify uncertainty, and learn about the future by

experimentation, i.e. the role of technology watcher and the role of innovation agent (Grin et

al., 1997; Rutten et al., 1998).

The role of technology watcher includes a systematic monitoring of technological

developments and understanding of these developments in terms of repercussions for policy.

The developments are positioned in a frame of five layers which provides the appropriate

background to assess the relevance of the new technology in transport. These layers include

the one of components (such as batteries and fuel cells in the case of electric vehicles), the

application (e.g. concepts of propulsion), the type of vehicle (cars, busses), the transport

concept (short or long distance transport), and the transport system (such as multi-modal

commuter transport systems). The main activities of technology watching are:

(1) to collect useful information on a particular technology and its potential markets

(2) to arrive at a broad interpretation of this information leading to score matrices for the

technology on specific criteria

(3) to establish various rounds of interaction with policy makers, policy analysts and

researchers in order to focus on policy relevance

(4) to establish a synthesis and preliminary conclusions

(5) to distribute the results to policy makers and other stakeholders.

What is new in this approach is the acknowledgement of the fact that each of the above

activities includes a number of choices, for which a solid and transparent argumentation needs

to be provided preferably in interaction with important stakeholders. Apart from the selection

of the technology itself, there is for example the selection of the type of information to be

collected (activity 1) and the criteria to be used in a first interpretation (activity 2). The key

activity of course, is to scan the technology for policy relevunce (activity 3). This includes

both-an assessment of direct impacts and an exploration of (potential) use of the technology

according to various criteria. The latter activities may include various rounds of scenario

analysis in order to learn about the technology. In terms of results, the methodology may not

only clarify the potential role of the technology but also the role of factors that advance or

prohibit this role.

1 2

Page 14: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

It is increasingly acknowledged that a participatory (or interactive) structure is a key

prerequisite for success of the methodology. This means a continuous input from the side of

independent experts and users of the technology at hand. There is a trend to consider a broad

group of stakeholders as relevant, i.e. also including actors on the supply side of the new

technology, like manufacturers and sponsors, and organisations that contribute to the

embedding of the technology (Grin et al., 1997). This broad input serves to cover the

perspectives of all influential players at hand and, accordingly, to increase support of them.

But there is also a danger here. It may happen that results are achieved without sufficient

reflection of real-life power structures, thus being unrealistic in a sense. This calls for a

delicate design of participation to arrive at strong outcomes that have sufficient “authority”.

As previously indicated, in its role of innovation agent the government is actively involved in

a successful implementation of the new technology. One way of doing this is to experiment

with a new technology in a relatively small and protected niche of the market, and this is

exactly the policy for electric vehicles in the Netherlands. The major experiment deals with

daily commuting between the cities of Rotterdam and Zoetermeer, in which electric busses

are used to bring commuters to their work at the location of the Ministry of Transport and

Waterworks in Rotterdam. Such an experiment serves various important goals, like to

demonstrate the use of the technology and to test the technology on user value and

acceptance. Technology experiments in niches like this one, require the identification of the

right market niche, a smart combination of resources and the involvement and interaction of

the right stakeholders. More importantly, network management is involved in terms of

shaping and reshaping the relationships between stakeholders (de Bruijn and ten Heuvelhof,

2000). The ultimate goal of such experimental small scale implementation is to proceed in the

adoption itself, while learning about advancing and hampering factors. The outcomes then

serve as input for a further development and testing. Learning experiments like these match

with a planning culture that is relatively new, i.e. vision-based planning (Figure 1).

An essential difference with conventional ,planning approaches is that there are no

predetermined goals to be achieved by using new technology and no predetermined policy

measures that serve the realisation of these goals. Rather, there is a broad vision on new

technology and transport, and there is a continuous interaction (communication) with

stakeholders. Information from these two sources provides the basis for conducting various

1 3

Page 15: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

experiments. Further, the learning derived from a series of experiments (trial and error) may

arrive at a stage in which it enables to underpin decision making.

Figure 1 Vision-based Planning

Events in the transport system

Ilisten tostakeholders outcome

trial and error

Source: van Zuylen, in van Geenhuizen et al. 1998.

Similar to the previous discussed role of technology watching, the experiments need to be

selected, designed and carried out in such a way that there is a broad coverage of causal

factors as well as a broad support from stakeholders for the results, without losing sense for

real-life power relations. Note that vision-based planning is an interesting alternative to

conventional practices only in specific cases. It is not regarded here as a general solution to

problems of uncertainty in transport policy making, for the simple reason that particular

policy questions are concerned with large scale infrastructure projects like high-speed rail

connections and Maglev systems. In these cases, experimentation in a niche and learning

based on trial and error are not useful.

6. Variation in Europe

There are different national planning methodologies in Europe. For example, in some

countries there is an emphasis on the input of users in technology assessment, whereas in

other countries experts have a prominent role. The importance attached to reduction of

uncertainty in policy making also varies from country to country, based on differences

1 4

Page 16: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

between national cultures (de Jong, 1998; Stough and Rietveld, 1997; van Zuylen et al.,

1998b).

What roles governments actually play with regard to promising transport technology is very

much dependent upon a blend of factors. In policies for introduction of electric vehicles in

various European countries in the mid 199Os, we observe large differences that can hardly be

ascribed to differences in planning culture only (IAEA, 1995; Weber and Hoogma, 1998)

(Table 2). Rather, various meso- and macro economic factors seem to count. For example, the

Netherlands compares with Germany in the dominant type of electricity production. In both

countries, electric vehicles using batteries would be powered with electricity from non-

sustainable sources (coal and gas), a situation in which the environmental gains of the

technology can be questioned and the public image of electric vehicles seems relatively weak.

Note that this might change if hydrogen powered fuel cells are used.

Other important factors that differentiate between countries include price and availability of

electricity, and the match of electric vehicles with accepted problem situations such as the

recognition of air pollution in cities as a severe problem and general environmental problems.

Furthermore, the industry structure seems important with monopoly and oligopoly enabling a

smooth involvement of national governments. There is one factor of which the influence is

not quite clear, namely the structure of the government system. In Germany, a decentralised

system would hamper consensus building on the need for adoption of the new technology, due

to the involvement of different governments on a lower level. However, in the case of

Switzerland a similar government structure would not have a hampering influence, most

probably because the new technology is not questioned due to its zero emission character. The

Swiss government also acts as a conditioning agent in the establishment of a kind of “clean air

act”. According to this policy, a total of 200,000 electric vehicles are planned on the road in

2010, corresponding to about 8% of the number of cars in the country today (AssoVEL,

1998).

.

1 5

Page 17: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

Table 2 Factors in macro (meso) systems and government roles in EV adoption

Country Factors Role of GovernmentFrance Advancing factors

Need for outlet for nuclear Subsidy for EV purchasepower Co-ordination of initiativesRecognition of air pollution in Funding of R&Dcities as a severe problemCentralised governmentIndustry monopoly andoligopoly

Sweden Advancing FactorsEV matches environmental Support of R&Dpolicy Support of demonstration andEV is nearly zero emission procurement programsLow price of electricity

Germany Prohibiting FactorsNon-renewable energy as basis Modest role (recentlyand full emission (coal firing) increasing)Decentralised governmentFragmented electricity industry

The Netherlands Prohibiting FactorsNon-renewable energy as basis Modest role:and full emission (gas firing) Support of R&DFragmented electricity industry Support of experiments in nichebut high co-operation (collective transport)

Switzerland AdvancingEV matches environmental Clean Air Actpolicy Co-ordination and subsidisationEV is zero emission of pilot programs

Subsidy for EV purchase

7. Concluding Remarks

Transport is a complex activity that touches upon many different human activities. As a result,

policy making is subject to uncertainty, a situation that calls for a strong awareness in the

design of policy measures. This article has mapped out the landscape of uncertainty in the

adoption of new technology in transport. In addition, it has considered various ways to deal

with uncertainty, in particular two new roles of the government in the Netherlands, i.e.

technology watching and experimentation in niche markets to advance adoption. What seems

1 6

, --.-

Page 18: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

to be crucial for success of both strategies is the ability to create a sense of urgency among the

relevant stakeholders in involving them in the interaction at hand. At the same time, the

results need to mirror real-life power relationships between stakeholders. This serves not only

a large coverage in terms of influences, but also a sufficient support for and “authority”

assigned to the results. The latter is clearly necessary because the results of this type of new

strategies are often under-used by decision makers.

Moreover, one needs to be aware of the potential dynamics in external factors, meaning shifts

over time in stakeholders and upcoming new technologies. As we have seen in the early

history of electric vehicles, small events may cause a leading position of inferior technology

and a reinforcing of this position over time. The latter phenomenon would have two

implications for technology watching, i.e. to cover a relatively broad spectrum of technologies

and to identify the above indicated small but potentially very important events.

1 7

Page 19: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

REFERENCES

AssoVEL Mendrisio, Large Scale jleet test with lightweight electric vehicle (LEVs) inMendrisio (2nd interim report). Mendrisio (Switzerland), 1998.

Becker, H., Social Impact Assessment, UCL Press, London, 1997.

Bruijn, J.A. de, and E. ten Heuvelhof, Networks and Decision Making. Utrecht, Lemma, 2000.

Cowan, R. and Hulten, S., Escaping Lock-In: The Case of the Electric Vehicle. TechnologicalForecasting and Social Change, 1996,56, pp. 61-79.

Doren, Ch. van, A History of Knowledge, Ballantine Books, New York, 1991.

Dror, Y., Uncertainty. Coping with it and Political Feasibility. In: H.J. Miser and E.S. Quade(eds) Handbook of Systems Analysis: Craft, Issues and Procedural Choices. 1988, pp. 247-281.

Friend, J. and A. Hickling, Planning under Pressure. The Strategic Choice Approach,Butterworth-Heinemann, Oxford, 1997.

Geenhuizen, M. van, Nijkamp, and H. van Zuylen (eds), Limits to Predictability in Trafficand Transport. AVV, Rotterdam, 1998.

Geenhuizen, M. van, and J. Schoonman, Sustainable Transport Technology: A Policy Viewon the Adoption of Electric Vehicles. Proceedings of CONAT ‘99, The ZXth ZnternationalConference. Transilvania University Press, Brasov, 1999.

Geenhuizen, M. van, W. Thissen, Uncertainty and the Adoption of Intelligent TransportSystems: A Policy View, Journal of Technology Policy and Management, 2001(forthcoming).

Golob, T. et al., Forecasting Electric Vehicle Ownership and Use in the California SouthCoast Air Basin. Institute of Transportation Studies, Irvine (CA), 1996.

Grin, J., van de Graaf. H. and R. Hoppe, Interactive Technology Assessment (in Dutch).Rathenau Instituut, The Hague, 1997.

IAEA (The International Energy Agency), Implementing Agreement for Electric VehicleTechnologies and Programs. IAEA, Paris, 1996.

Harvey, D., Models of the Evolution of Spatial Patterns in Human Geography, Models inGeography, R.J. Chorley and P. Haggett, eds., Methuen, London, 1967, pp. 549-608.

Isoarh, S., The Diffusion of Energy Technologies: The Influence of Increasing Returns. TheZPTS Report 1996 (10): 10-15.

Jong, W.M. de, Institutional Transplantation. Eburon Publishers, Delft (PhD thesis), 1998.

Kahn, H. and A.J. Wiener, The Year 2000. MacMillan, New York, 1967.

1 8

,.. ._ --

Page 20: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

March, J.G. and H.A. Simon, Organizations. Wiley, New York, 1958.

Marsh, P. and Collet, P., Driving Passion. The Psychology of the Car. Jonathan Cape,London, 1986.

Mulder, K., Weijer, C. van de, and Marchau, V., Prospects for external sources of vehiclepropulsion. Results of a Delphi study, Futures, 1996, Vol. 28 (lo), pp. 919-945.

Nijkamp, P., and S. Baaijens, Time Pioneers and Travel Behaviour, Growth and Change, vol.30, no. 2, 1999, pp. 237-263.

Nijkamp, P., Ouwersloot, H. and S. Rienstra, Sustainable Urban Transport Systems: AnExpert-based Strategic Scenario Approach, Urban Studies, 1997, Vol. 34 (4), pp. 693-712.

Nijkamp, P. and M. van Geenhuizen, European transport: challenges and opportunities forfuture research and policies, Journal of Transport Geography, 1997,5, pp. 4-l 1.

Nijkamp, P., S. Rienstra and J. Vleugel, Transportation Planning and The Future, JohnWiley, Chichester/New York, 1998.

Reibnitz, U. von, Scenario Techniques. McGraw Hill, New York, 1998.

Rowe, W.D., Understanding Uncertainty, Risk Analysis, 1994, Vol. 14 (5), pp. 743-750.

Rutten, B.J.C.M., Korver, W. and Elzen, B., The importance of monitoring technology andexperimentation (in Dutch) Tijdschrijl Vervoerswetenschup, 1998 (3): 191-211.

Schwartz, P. The Art of the Long View: Planning for the Future in an Uncertain World.Doubleday, New York, 1991.

Simon, H., A Behavioural Model of Rational Choice, Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol.69, 1952, pp. 9-l 18.

Skamris, M.K. and Flyvbjerg, B., Inaccuracy of traffic forecasts and cost estimates on largetransport projects. Transport Policy, 1997,4 (3): 141-146.

Stacey, R.D., Managing the Unknowable, Jossey Bass, San Francisco, 1992.

Stough. R. and P. Rietveld, Institutional Issues in Transport Systems. Transport Geography,1997, 5(30): pp. 207-214.

Walker, W.A., S. Adnan Rahman, and J. Cave, Adaptive Policies, policy analysis, andpolicy-making, European Journal of Operational Research, 128 (2001): pp. 282-289.

.Weber, M. and R. Hoogma, Beyond National and Technological Styles of InnovationDiffusion: A Dynamic Perspective on Cases from the Energy and Transport Sectors,Technology Analysis & Strategic Management, 1998, Vol. 10 (4) pp.545-566.

1 9

Page 21: SERIE RESEARCH MEMORANDA · force. Location and travel decisions are not taken in a Robinson Crusoe economy on an isolated island, but in social interaction with others (the notion

Wolpert, J., The Decision Process in a Spatial Context, Annals of the Association of AmericanGeographers, vol. 34, 1964, pp. 537-558.

Wynne, B. Uncertainty and Environmental Learning, Global Environmental Change, 2, 1992,pp.1 11-127.

Zuylen, H.J. and van Schaick, G.H.J., Towards a technology policy in traffic and transport (inDutch), Tijdschrif Vervoerswetenschap 1998a, (3): 247-265.

Zuylen, H.J., Weber, M., Moon, D.P. and Davison, P., A new European approach totechnology policy in traffic and transport (in Dutch). Tzjdschrif Vervoerswetenschap, 1998b:267-287.

.

2 0


Recommended