+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts...

Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts...

Date post: 18-Jul-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
184
Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development in the Early PRC by Zyler Zexi Wang A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto © Copyright by Zyler Zexi Wang 2017
Transcript
Page 1: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development in the Early PRC

by

Zyler Zexi Wang

A thesis submitted in conformity with the requirements for the degree of Master of Arts

Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto

© Copyright by Zyler Zexi Wang 2017

Page 2: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

ii

Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development in the

Early PRC

Zyler Zexi Wang

Master of Arts

Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto

2017

Abstract

My thesis focuses on national industrialization in the early decades of the People’s Republic of

China (PRC). The industrialization project connected the following: histories and impacts of

Western imperialism, the distinctive form of Third World socialism, and the importance of

economic and technological development to the early PRC. I explore the above set of

connections in order to answer my motivating question: What is particularly socialist about the

early PRC’s industrialization project? I begin with histories and plans. Western depictions of

state planned economies rely on tropes of irrationality. I retrieve the logical content of early PRC

plans by piecing together historical data, the text of plans, and narratives from early PRC leaders

and planners. I then turn to the formulation and implementation of state plans. I trace these

processes through events in the state railway sector—a system that evolved in tandem with the

project of early PRC industrialization.

Page 3: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

Acknowledgments The completion of this thesis owes a great deal to many people. First and foremost is my

supervisor, Prof. Alana Boland. You’re open to and knowledgeable about everything that I could

have wanted to study. I don’t think I would be here otherwise. I’ve really appreciated your

combination of openness and rigour, though I may grumble about the second. Thank you also for

how much you pushed and were there during the final weeks of writing.

Many thanks to the committee members, Prof. Alan Walks and Prof. Tong Lam. I am deeply

grateful for how closely you read the thesis, especially given the short and changing timeframe

(sorry!). Thank you for bringing your vast expertise, and for asking very crucial questions. I

should also mention Prof. Yiching Wu (the almost-committee-member). You have been both

incredibly encouraging and honest since the beginning. Your work, I think, made it possible for

me to ask the questions that I wanted to. This thesis carries the influence of all the other faculty

who have taught and mentored me, during my graduate and undergraduate studies at UofT. (I

had forgotten how much that Michael Jackson piece shaped my entire approach to research.)

Thank you also to the staff in the Department, who, in my experience, go above and beyond.

I benefited from help, advice, and encouragement from a number of higher-year students in

Geography and other departments. Thank you (multiple you) for answering lists and lists of

questions, and telling me that I wasn’t alone in my concerns and apprehensions. This process

would have been much less manageable (and dare I say fun?) without the other members of my

cohort, and other classmates. Thank you especially to Andy, Cindy, Liz, Kevin, Meghan, and

Rebecca for the chats, work sessions, driving all the way to Boston, helping me look for my iPod

at 1 am, and all the forms of commiseration (which were kind of fun…right?).

I owe profound debts of gratitude to Prof. Zhang Yuhong, Prof. Chen Xumei, Prof. Han

Baoming, and Sabrina Xu, for enabling my time at Beijing Jiaotong University. BJTU was the

perfect home base for my research. Thank you to Prof. Han for many things: being so easygoing

and welcoming, taking an interest in this project, sharing your time and knowledge, and

connecting me to others. Prof. Zhang Qikun and Prof. Gao Gao: I learned so much from you. I

really enjoyed our conversations. Thank you for making available your time and resources.

Interviews also played a crucial part in this thesis. To the interviewees: I am not naming you due

to the University’s rules around privacy and ethics in research. Your contributions are every bit

iii

Page 4: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

iv

as important as those made by everyone who is named. Thank you for sharing your time,

knowledge, and experiences; thank you also for your kindness and patience with me.

Some other great people: I am very grateful to Prof. Judith Farquhar, Ms. Beth Bader, Mr. Yuan

Ji, and the staff at the UChicago Center in Beijing. The Center gave me all that I needed badly at

the time: space, coffee, yoga, and great company. Thank you to the staff at Interlibrary Loans at

Robarts, who have been wizards at locating somewhat odd volumes. Thank you also to the

helpful and kind staff at the Universities Services Centre for China Studies at the CUHK.

Finally, I am thankful for financial support received through the Social Sciences and Humanities

Research Council of Canada (SSHRC), the Department of Geography and Planning, and the Dr.

David Chu Scholarship in Asia Pacific Studies (from UofT’s Faculty of Arts and Sciences).

I could not have done this without my friends. Each of you has always been there, and told me

that I was doing okay in ways that I needed to hear. I am excited to be there for the new chapters

in your lives. Thank you to my partner. You’ve heard me since the beginning. You have given

me both the support and space needed to grow. You are, I think, one of my favourite humans.

Thank you, from the bottom of my heart, to my family in China—uncles, aunts, grandaunts,

granduncles, cousins, and everyone else. Thank you for all the ways that you have been there for

me, and have helped me with this project. Thank you for, in these past years, listening through

my gibberish and at times atrocious mispronunciations, and hearing what I meant to say. You

make coming back feel like coming home. Thank you to my parents. There is too much to say

here, so I will keep it brief. This project comes out of an attempt to understand your lives and

mine. Finally, in the course of doing this research, I have been thinking about my grandfather—

who passed away before I had a chance to truly come back. I saw the note that you wrote me;

you wanted me to know that there are beautiful places in this country.

Page 5: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

Table of Contents

Contents

Acknowledgments ........................................................................................................................ iii

Table of Contents ...........................................................................................................................v

Chapter I. Introduction .................................................................................................................1 1. Introduction ...................................................................................................................1 2. Topics and questions .....................................................................................................3 2.1 Socialist industrialization in the early PRC ...................................................3 2.2 Discourses on state socialist ‘failure’ ............................................................8 2.3 Chinese railways: As topic, method, and site ..............................................18 3. Methods and sources ...................................................................................................22 3.1 Reading and textual analysis ........................................................................23 3.2 Interviews .....................................................................................................26 4. Thesis structure and content ........................................................................................30 4.1 A key concept: On efficiency ......................................................................30 4.2 The main argument in three chapters ...........................................................33

Chapter II. The Red passion for economizing, part one: The erased logic of plans ..............35 1. Introduction .................................................................................................................35 2. Imperialism, the erased trace ......................................................................................36 3. Materializing history: The early PRC in context ........................................................38 4. (Five Year) Planning for the ongoing revolution ........................................................47 5. ‘Irrational’ planners—or their irrational critics? .........................................................63 6. Conclusion ..................................................................................................................67

Chapter III. The bridge: The PRC railway sector in formation .............................................70 1. Introduction .................................................................................................................70 2. Chinese railways: Early histories ................................................................................72 3. Chinese railways: The PRC system in formation .......................................................76 3.1 Tracks from the Republic .............................................................................77 3.2 In the battle for a new beginning..................................................................80 3.3 “Learn from the advanced experience of the Soviet Union” .......................88 3.4 An assemblage .............................................................................................97

4. Conclusion ................................................................................................................101

Chapter IV. The Red passion for economizing, part two: State plans and railway sector accounting in the early PRC.................................................................................................103

1. Introduction ...............................................................................................................103 2. Early PRC state planning in process .........................................................................104

Page 6: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

vi

3. Critical projections: The distorted reflection of American corporations ...................110 4. The ‘central link’ of the plan: Economic accounting in the PRC railway sector ......115 5. Conclusion .................................................................................................................134

Chapter V. Conclusion ..............................................................................................................136 1. Rewind: Summary and arguments ............................................................................136 2. Stakes, part one: On knowledge 3. Stakes, part two: Between capitalism, socialism, and efficiency .............................140

3.1 The aftermath of ‘capitalist victory’ ..........................................................140 3.2 A step back: The unconcluded debate ........................................................142

4. Towards unpaused histories ......................................................................................155

Bibliography ...............................................................................................................................157

Page 7: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

1

Chapter I. Introduction

The history of mankind is one of continuous development from the realm of necessity to the realm of freedom. […] In the fields of the struggle for production and scientific experiment, mankind makes constant progress and nature undergoes constant change; they never remain at the same level. Therefore, man has constantly to sum up experience and go on discovering, inventing, creating and advancing. Ideas of stagnation, pessimism, inertia and complacency are all wrong. They are wrong because they agree neither with the historical facts of social development over the past million years, nor with the historical facts of nature so far known to us.

--Mao Zedong, December 19641

1. Introduction In the broadest telling, my thesis tracks the afterlife of what began as perhaps the most optimistic

and audacious social project seen by the world in the twentieth century. The project in question

is Chinese socialism. In 1949, the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) embarked on a quest. State

leaders in the newly-formed People’s Republic of China (PRC) sought to transform an agrarian

nation of over 600 million people—marked, at the time, by a century of colonial exploitation and

decades of warfare—into a model of socialist modernity. The CCP’s vocabulary of

‘development’ and ‘progress’ likely did not raise too many eyebrows among Western leftist and

critical circles at the time. But we live in a different time today. In the contemporary era, we—I

count myself among the critical set here—have absorbed insights produced by decades of

structuralist and post-structuralist analysis. To speak of ‘progress’ reeks of teleology and top-

down authority. Mao’s tying, in the above quote, of progress to science and technology is

perhaps even more suspicious. This thesis grew out of my initial puzzlement about why the

project of Chinese socialism would place at its center goals of economic and technological

development.

1 “Premier Zhou Enlai’s Report on the Work of the Government to the First Session of the Third National People’s Congress of the People’s Republic of China, December 1964,” in Main Documents of the First Session of the Third National People’s Congress of the People’s Republic of China (Peking: Foreign Languages Press, 1965).

Page 8: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

2

My project consequently studies economic and technological systems in the early PRC. I

examine the operations of these systems, as well as ways of narrating them within the PRC and

in the West. I am interested in how leaders in the early PRC conceived of and implemented

routes to alternative forms of modernization. I am also interested in the results and limits of these

approaches. I am moreover curious about the relationship between Third World modernization

trajectories, and how projects of economic and technological development have become narrated

in the West. Antipathy to notions of ‘progress’ is at the center of the most nuanced contemporary

Western discourses about development.2 My project was, in a sense, prompted by the different

ways that development and technology have been positioned by Chinese socialism and by

contemporary Western calls for radical redistribution and equality. I did not quite get to this topic

in my research and writing. As I proceeded with research, I found rather more fundamental

questions to address about the workings of early PRC economic and technological systems, and

how these have been conceived.

The subsequent thesis begins by discussing plans for national industrialization in the

early PRC. I approach the PRC’s industrialization project by juxtaposing two sets of narratives.

These are contemporary Western discussions of the early PRC economy, and accounts from

early PRC leaders and planners. Contemporary Western discussions largely understand state

socialist economies to be irrational and inefficient, by virtue of their reliance on state planning. I

show these discussions to operate as a set of self-reproducing discourses that exclude ‘outside’

information. The excluded information ranges from the historical and economic contexts

produced by imperialism, to early PRC planners’ narrations of their own rationales and limits, to

processes of state and local plan formulation and implementation in the PRC, as well as their

results. I use these excluded elements to build my subsequent account of industrialization in the

early PRC. I first discuss the historical contexts that gave rise to the PRC’s national development

and industrialization plans. These plans constituted an active and deliberate response to their

contexts; plans, and the processes of their implementation, were also shaped by these contexts. I

2 See for example: Jonathan Crush, Power of Development (Psychology Press, 1995); James Ferguson, The Anti-Politics Machine: ’Development’, Depoliticization and Bureaucratic Power in Lesotho (Cambridge University Press, 1990); James C. Scott, Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed (Yale University Press, 1998); Nanda R. Shrestha, In the Name of Development: A Reflection on Nepal (University Press of America, 1997).

Page 9: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

3

then turn to examine a system that had been key to the early PRC’s industrialization project—the

state railway system. I track the interplay between historical remnants, early PRC state plans, and

their local sector implementation through the events of the early PRC railway system.

The rest of this introductory chapter is divided into three sections. In the first section, I

discuss the research topics and relevant literatures that my project engages with. I also ask a set

of research questions. In the second section, I provide information on my research methods. I

discuss sources of evidence and how I use these. The final section of the chapter acts as a segue

to the rest of the thesis. I outline the main argument that threads together Chapters 2, 3, and 4. I

also provide brief descriptions of these chapters. Lastly, I address a key preoccupation that holds

together the different elements of my thesis: this is the concept of efficiency.

2. Topics and questions

This thesis revolves around three research topics. These are: (1) socialist industrialization in the

early PRC, (2) discourses on state socialist ‘failure’, and (3) the Chinese railway system. In the

following section, I discuss each of these three topics. For each topic, I cover existing literature

on relevant subjects, how and where my approach fits in, and the set of questions that guide my

research into the specific topic. I also draw out the set of relationships that connect these topics

to each other. Finally, I briefly comment on how I pursued researching these topics. The

discussion of how continues into the next section on Methods and sources.

2.1 Socialist industrialization in the early PRC

The primary topic for my research concerns industrialization in the early PRC. After founding

the People’s Republic of China (PRC) in 1949, the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) prioritized

the project of national economic development. In the period between 1949-1958, 66% of the

Page 10: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

4

over 4,000 statutes and regulations issued by the new PRC state concerned economic matters.3 In

1965, twenty-nine of the thirty-six existing state ministries operated in areas of economic

planning, production, distribution, and exchange.4 In the first two decades of the PRC, state

leaders identified industrialization as the primary task for national economic development.5 In

1949, China had been a largely agricultural society, with over 80% of its population residing in

the countryside.6 In other words, China was largely non-industrial. China therefore stood apart

from ‘First World’ nations at the time. First World nations had mostly already undergone

processes of industrialization. These processes equipped their home nations with the

infrastructural components of modern (industrial) societies, which included energy production

and circulation systems, transportation systems, and industries for producing construction

materials and machinery.7

If projects of industrialization have historically been pursued by nations of all ideological

stripes, then is there anything particularly Marxist or socialist about the CCP’s drive to

industrialize? The CCP had been founded on the ideology of Marxist-Leninism, which remains a

guiding doctrine for the party today.8 Texts produced by the early PRC state suggest that a

connection did exist between the state ideology of socialism and practices of industrialization.

Contained within the PRC’s First Five Year Plan (FFYP), for instance, is this passage: “The

founding of the People’s Republic of China, led by the working class […] [has] made it possible

for us, in accordance with our aim of building socialism, to develop and transform our national

economy in a planned way, so as to convert China, step by step, from a backwards, agricultural

3 Gene Hsiao, “The Role of Economic Contracts in Communist China,” California Law Review 53, no. 4 (October 31, 1965): 1030. 4 Ibid., 1031. 5 PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957. (Beijing: Foreign Languages Press, 1956), 15–17. 6 Albert Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, 1870-1949 (Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1995), 87–89; John Friedmann, China’s Urban Transition (University of Minnesota Press, 2005), 11. 7 Walt Whitman Rostow, The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto (University Press, 1960), 60–67. 8 CCP, “Constitution of the Communist Party of China: Revised and Adopted at the 18th National Congress of the Communist Party of China on November 14, 2012,” ChinaToday.com: A China Information Base, November 14, 2012, http://www.chinatoday.com/org/cpc/china_communist_party_constitution.htm.

Page 11: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

5

country into an advanced, socialist, industrial state.”9 According to state planners in the early

PRC—or at least those involved in formulating the FFYP—the building of socialism paralleled

the building of national industrialization.

The knowledge gap

Many Western (or English-language) researchers of the early PRC have taken its state

ideology of socialism seriously. This description applies to works where the author considers and

finds value in, rather than dismissing, how PRC leaders and other people in China have narrated

events and processes. Both official and popular discussions in the early PRC (i.e. those taking

place in its first two decades) frequently made use of socialist analytic frameworks.10 Western

authors who have taken these narrations seriously have tended to study subjects such as political

leaders, political practices, campaigns, social moments, and cultural productions. Writings in this

genre include Esherick’s work on topics such as the Cultural Revolution and CCP base areas;

Dittmer’s on political theory and practice (e.g. ‘line struggle); Gao’s on the Cultural Revolution;

Harding’s on bureaucratization; Howard’s on the mass line and other communications practices;

Meisner’s on Li Dazhao and the early history of the PRC; Selden’s on CCP activities in the

Yan’an base area; and Wu’s on the Cultural Revolution.11

9 PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957,13. 10 State plans, as well as the writings and speeches of early PRC leaders (e.g. Mao, Zhou Enlai, Li Fuchun, Liu Shaoqi, etc.), can be taken as examples of official discourses at the time. The Hundred Flowers Campaign (1957) and the Cultural Revolution (1966-?) tend to be characterized as moments that make audible less-official conversations. Chan, Goldman, and Wu have investigated these ‘other’ (and in Wu’s case, ‘marginal’) conversations. These do not tend to challenge state socialism; they often depart from more official discourses by calling for increased redistribution, nation-building, etc. See: Sylvia Chan, “The Image of a ‘Capitalist Roader’--Some Dissident Short Stories in the Hundred Flowers Period,” The Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs, no. 2 (1979): 77–102; René Goldman, “The Rectification Campaign at Peking University: May--June 1957,” The China Quarterly, no. 12 (1962): 138–53; Yiching Wu, The Cultural Revolution at the Margins (Harvard University Press, 2014). 11 Joseph Esherick, “On The ‘Restoration of Capitalism,’” Modern China 5, no. 1 (1979): 41–77; Joseph W. Esherick, “Deconstructing the Construction of the Party-State: Gulin County in the Shaan-Gan-Ning Border Region,” The China Quarterly, no. 140 (1994): 1052–79; Mobo C. F. Gao, The Battle for China’s Past: Mao and the Cultural Revolution (Pluto Press, 2008); Harry Harding, Organizing China : The Problem of Bureaucracy, 1949-1976 (Stanford University Press, 1981); Pat Howard, Breaking the Iron Rice Bowl: Prospects for Socialism in China’s Countryside (M.E. Sharpe, 1988); Maurice J. Meisner, Li Dazhao and the Origins of Chinese Marxism (Harvard University Press, 1967); Maurice J. Meisner, Mao’s China: A History of the People’s Republic (Free Press, 1977); Mark Selden, China in Revolution: The Yenan Way Revisited (M.E. Sharpe, 1995); Wu, The Cultural Revolution at the Margins, 2014.

Page 12: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

6

In contrast, Western research on the economic aspects of the early PRC often do not

consider how the events under study had been narrated by those inside China. This orientation is

particularly true of Western research produced after the Cold War (i.e. post-1990). For instance,

Naughton, in an authoritative overview of the Chinese economy published in 2007, characterizes

economic policy changes in the early PRC as a series of erratic and sudden swings.12 Naughton

attributes these changes to political and personal whims; he explains that “Mao Zedong himself

repeatedly changed economic policies in accordance with his own revolutionary ideals or

personal wishes.”13 Naughton’s characterization here—of early PRC policy-making as individual

and particular—elides entire sets of events, processes, and discussions that had shaped

trajectories of the early PRC economy. In the upcoming chapters, I will discuss in detail the

forms of dismissal and elision that Naughton’s above description partakes in. I will also provide

an account of the events and processes that have become erased. For now, I will just say that

Naughton is far from being unique in his approach.

Naughton’s disregard for how the early PRC economy was conceived and understood by

its architects is rather axiomatic for his field. Authors who have shared Naughton’s approach in

their recent (post-1990) writing about the early PRC economy include Ash and Nolan, Lin et al.,

Rawski, Walder, and Wong.14 This list is not long: not many Western researchers today are

specifically interested in the economic operations of Mao-era China. This disinterest is at least

partly rooted in how the subject is considered understood and therefore closed to further study.

But the conclusions of Naughton and his cohort are far from marginal. Their shared

understanding of the early PRC economy as being personality-driven and otherwise shaped by

political directives (rather than economic rationality) pervades both Western academic and

popular understandings of Mao-era China. These understandings in turn shape how China’s post-

1976 reforms—and consequently its present—are understood in Western discussions.

12 Barry Naughton, The Chinese Economy: Transitions and Growth (MIT Press, 2007). 13 Ibid., 62. 14 Peter Nolan and Robert F. Ash, “China’s Economy on the Eve of Reform,” in China’s Transitional Economy, ed. Andrew George Walder (Oxford University Press, 1996), 18–36; Justin Yifu Lin, Fang Cai, and Zhou Li, The China Miracle: Development Strategy and Economic Reform (Chinese University Press, 2003); Thomas G. Rawski, “Chinese Industrial Reform: Accomplishments, Prospects, and Implications,” The American Economic Review 84, no. 2 (1994): 271–75; Christine Wong, “Rebuilding Government for the 21st Century: Can China Incrementally Reform the Public Sector?,” The China Quarterly, no. 200 (2009): 929–52.

Page 13: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

7

In the next section, I further address Western narratives about the early PRC economy.

These narratives become a research topic in and of themselves. For now, the focus is on the topic

of socialist industrialization in the early PRC. While early PRC state plans insist on the existence

of a productive relationship between socialism and industrialization, the possibility of this

connection is largely absent from English-language scholarship. There is, on the one hand,

literature that is interested in tracking the realization of state socialism. These works tend to

focus away from the early PRC economy. There is, on the other hand, literature specifically

focused on the PRC economy—these tend to dismiss the state’s ideology of socialism. In the

second set of accounts, ideology only impacted the early PRC economy insofar as to steer it

away from proper functioning.15 Consequently, one of the objectives of my research is to

understand the role of state socialist ideology in producing—rather than only disrupting—plans

and processes of industrialization in the early PRC. To this end, I ask the following questions:

What were the objectives of early PRC development and industrialization plans? How did

these objectives relate to the ideology of state socialism? What were relationships between

plans and visions, processes of implementation, and their results?

Introducing railways as method

To answer the above-posed questions, I look broadly at plans for and processes taking place in

the early PRC at large. I also zoom in on the operations of a particular—and important—

component of the early PRC economy: the state railway system. Railways have been crucial to

projects of national industrialization, both in the PRC and elsewhere.16 Anchoring my research in

the operations of one key state system has been particularly useful when investigating the third

question posed above, about the relationships between state plans, processes of implementation,

and their results. The events of the early PRC railway sector shed light on what happens when

state plans ‘hit the ground’, so to speak. While conducting my research, I discovered another

reason for centering Chinese railways in the attempt to understand early PRC industrialization.

This second reason is tied to the history of these railways. China’s railway system, with its

15 Some pre-1990 English-language research on the PRC economy do take state narrations more seriously than more contemporary works. Their engagements however stop short of my questions, which ask what is particularly socialist about early PRC industrialization. I discuss these earlier works in more detail in the next topic section. 16 Philip Sidney Bagwell, The Transport Revolution (Routledge, 1988); Rostow, The Stages of Economic Growth, 60–67; Adrian J. Smith, Privatized Infrastructure: The Role of Government (Thomas Telford, 1999), 8–42.

Page 14: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

8

enduring form, acts as a kind of repository for national history. Railway histories make visible

the processes and events that motivated Chinese socialism and its plans for national

industrialization. Chinese railways consequently feature in my thesis in two ways: (1) I discuss

aspects of early PRC railways to shed light on how PRC state plans had been formulated and

implemented; and (2) I discuss Chinese railway histories in order to establish a key set of

contexts. These include the broad contexts that gave rise to Chinese state socialism and its plans,

and the more specific contexts that shaped railway-sector implementation of state plans.

2.2 Discourses on state socialist ‘failure’

The second topic for my research concerns a set of Western discourses about development

trajectories in the early PRC. These discourses in fact extend beyond the PRC. These discourses

consider the economies of all (former) socialist states to have been, both generally and

intrinsically, dysfunctional. Economic dysfunction is then positioned as the linchpin in narratives

about the overall ‘failure’ of state socialist projects. In labelling this set of discourses as

‘Western’, I index several related aspects of their constituent discussions. These aspects include:

these discussions happen in English-language, their authors have received post-graduate training

in North Atlantic institutions, and their texts are published or otherwise circulated by North

Atlantic institutions (e.g. universities, publishing houses, etc.).

Western discourses about socialist failure are not restricted to the academic sphere or its

institutions. However, their popularization has been tied to the widespread circulation of

academic or quasi-academic works, such as those by Fukuyama and Friedman. In the next

paragraphs, I show how a shared set of narratives about socialist failure animate the works of

Fukuyama, Friedman, and those by PRC specialists. I then interpret these narratives through the

Foucauldian notion of discourse. Finally, I pose a set of questions that guide my subsequent

study and analysis of this particular set of discourses.

Narrating socialist failure

The post-Cold War era have been heralded in the West as the ‘end of history’: democracy has

triumphed over socialism as the superior form of state political organization. In these accounts,

Page 15: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

9

democracy is not merely a form of political organization—it is crucially intertwined with private

ownership and the ‘freedom’ of market exchange.17 The victory of democracy is also the victory

of capitalism. Capitalism has proven itself to be not only more efficient than the alternative; it

has also shown itself to be better at raising standards of living for the average person. Or so says

authors like Fukuyama and Friedman. Fukuyama shakes his head at the “[t]errible waste and

inefficiency that central planning had brought about.”18 Friedman meanwhile offers the pithy

nugget: “Communism was a great system for making people equally poor.”19 Here, the defeated

alternative to capitalism is of course state socialism and its centrally planned economy.

Much of post-Cold War Western academic research on Mao-era China (1949-1976)—and

its centrally planned economy—would seem to agree with Fukuyama and Friedman. In fact, ‘in-

depth’ studies on the economic operations of the PRC and the former USSR often provide the

details that substantiate Friedman-esque sound bites. Nolan and Ash, for example, find that

“China’s economic development has been uniquely, if not consistently, influenced by [Mao’s]

personal prejudices and idiosyncratic view of how to realize the country’s development

potential.”20 Nolan and Ash then expand on the ills of the PRC’s planned economy. Their

discussion captures several key elements of Western discourses on state socialist economies, so I

will quote it here in length:

“[The planned economy] had generated powerful negative economic consequences. Decisions were frequently taken by Party members, who lacked appropriate training and skills. Ideological orthodoxy constrained economic debate—for example, insisting that “planning” provided a framework in which resource allocation could take place without reference to such fundamental economic concepts as price, cost, and profit. […] [I]nstead of eliminating the shortcomings of the capitalist system, planning exhibited many of the same deficiencies in an even more acute form. Far from abolishing waste, it generated waste on a grand scale. It abolished production for profit, but failed to replace it with production for use. It eliminated the short-termism of competitive capitalism only to substitute the short-termism of current plan fulfillment.”21

17 See for instance: Thomas L. Friedman, The World Is Flat 3.0: A Brief History of the Twenty-First Century (Macmillan, 2007), 49–50. 18 Francis Fukuyama, The End of History and the Last Man (Penguin Books Limited, 1993), 41. 19 Friedman, The World Is Flat 3.0, 2007, 50. 20 Nolan and Ash, “China’s Economy on the Eve of Reform,” 1996, 18. 21 Ibid., 18–19.

Page 16: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

10

Nolan and Ash are not unique in how they understand the early PRC’s economy. Lin et

al. repeat the story about socialist irrationality and waste, using rather more economic jargon:

“Giving priority to heavy-industry development ran counter to China’s comparative advantage and distorted the economic structure so much that development was slower than it could have been.”22 “Distorted prices of production factors and products resulted in a shortage economy.”23 “In the price-distorting macro-policy environment, profits ceased to be an indicator of enterprise management and performance and no objective substitute could be found.”24 And finally, “instead of enabling China to catch up with and overtake developed countries, [the early PRC system] impeded economic growth and resulted in low living standards for the Chinese people.”25

In quoting extensive from Nolan and Ash and Lin et al., I do not mean to single these

authors out for some exceptional way in which they discuss state socialist economies. Their

research provides valuable insights and analyses on the PRC’s economy—I certainly learned

much from their discussions. These authors merely articulate more explicitly the assumptions

and frames that sometimes remain half-buried. Other recent scholars of the PRC economy

certainly agree on the deficiencies of the planned system. In Walder’s study on post-socialist

political transitions, he notes that “Few will dispute the fact that the political changes of recent

years are rooted in the long-term failure of Soviet style economic institutions.”26 Naughton, also

from his overview of the PRC economy, states that for the Chinese leaderships, “The disasters of

the GLF and the Cultural Revolution led to disillusionment with socialism as a development

strategy and to the growing conviction that the market could be a superior instrument of

development.”27 Naughton then reiterates that “the market is the superior way to organize

economic transactions.”28

22 Lin, Cai, and Li, The China Miracle, 2003, 69. 23 Ibid., 399. 24 Ibid., 340. 25 Ibid. 26 Andrew G. Walder, The Waning of the Communist State: Economic Origins of Political Decline in China and Hungary (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995), 2. 27 Naughton, The Chinese Economy, 2007, 5. 28 Ibid., 7. I pause here to clarify the periodization of socialist ‘failure’ in the above-quoted accounts. Naughton’s last quote (footnote 27) constructed ideas of Chinese socialist failure around events of the Great Leap Forward (GLF, 1958-1960) and Cultural Revolution (CR, 1966-1976). References to these two periods often surface in discussions about ‘irrational’ Chinese socialism. It is important to note that however, for Naughton—as the current quote shows—the dysfunction of Chinese socialism was rooted in the very operations of its planned economy. The idea here is not that the Chinese socialist economy had mostly functioned, aside from aberrant events. The GLF and

Page 17: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

11

Narratives tying the failure of state socialism to the inefficient planned economy are

similarly present in works about other historically-existing socialist states. These lines of

discussion are even reproduced by authors who profess Marxist sympathies, such as Verdery.29

In her study of Romanian socialism, Verdery observes that the very logic of planned economies

is to establish and maintain paternalistic control.30 In the planned economy, transactions are

dominated by ‘clientelism’ and bargaining, thereby producing widespread shortages and

practices of hoarding.31 It is one thing to observe inefficiencies in the operations of planned

economies. It is quite another to claim that planned economies are more inefficient than capitalist

(unplanned?) economies—and that this comparative lack culminated in the demise of state

socialism. But the later is exactly what is argued. For Verdery, “socialism with its emphasis on

large-scale heroic production of means of production, its resources frozen by hoarding [,] […] its

lack of a systemic impetus towards innovation, [….] its neglect of consumption and its flat-

footed definition of “needs,” [and] its constipated and secretive flows of information” could not

complete against a capitalism that was becoming ever more flexible.32

As discourses

From the above accounts, a certain picture emerges of state socialist—or centrally planned—

economies, such as what existed in the early PRC. This picture contains three elements: (1) that

planners had been idiosyncratic and produced irrational plans; (2) that resource allocation had

been inefficient due to the absence of economic mechanisms; and (3) that economic planning

produces the waste of resources, materials, and labour. These problems may in fact have been

present in centrally planned economies. However, as Nove argues in his discussion of socialist

economics, critics of socialism tend to assume that “capitalism and optimum resource allocation

CR are rather positioned as extending ‘normal’ forms of planned economic dysfunction. The set of quotes from Nolan and Ash, Lin et al., and Walder show that they, perhaps even more so than Naughton, root their accounts in the ‘normal’ operations of the early PRC economy. When addressing Western narratives in the rest of the thesis, I often discuss events transpiring between 1949-1957. This period saw the set-up and normalization of the PRC’s planned economy; it is therefore a large part of what Western narratives draw on and construct as the period of early PRC socialist economic ‘failure’. 29 Katherine Verdery, What Was Socialism, and What Comes Next? (Princeton University Press, 1996), 9–14. 30 Ibid., 24–25. 31 Ibid., 20–23. 32 Ibid., 34.

Page 18: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

12

go together.”33 Studies on the operations of Western capitalist economies have pointed to the

immense waste generated by events and practices such as de-industrialization;34 financial crises

and bailouts;35 the industrial-military complex and war economy;36 planned obsolesces;37

processes of crop selection, transport, and retail;38 and the increasing production of garbage.39

In fact, Nolan and Ash themselves mention that the early PRC’s average growth rate had

been the highest amongst low-income countries. China’s GNP per capita had grown at an

average rate of 5% per year between 1960-1981. The PRC’s growth rates in 1950-1959 are

assumed to be even higher.40 Nolan and Ash point out that a relevant benchmark for comparison

is GNP per capita growth rates in India during the same period, which had been 1.4% per year.41

One comparison that Nolan and Ash do not make is between the PRC and the U.S.’s growth

rates in the same time period. U.S. GDP per capita had, in 1960-1981, grown at under 3% per

year.42 Perhaps it would more sense to compare the PRC’s 1960-1981 growth rates to an earlier

(‘less developed’) time in U.S. history. U.S. GDP per capita had grown at an annual rate of under

2% in 1870-1890.43 Given these comparative growth rates—and the above-discussed research on

33 Alec Nove and Domenico Mario Nuti, Socialist Economics: Selected Readings (Penguin, 1972), 7. 34 Richard D. Wolff, Capitalism Hits the Fan (Interlink Publishing, 2012); Steven High, Industrial Sunset: The Making of North America’s Rust Belt, 1969-1984 (University of Toronto Press, 2003). 35 Charles Ferguson, Inside Job, Documentary (Sony, 2010); Michael Moore, “The Rich Are Staging a Coup This Morning” Common Dreams, September 9, 2008, https://www.commondreams.org/views/2008/09/29/rich-are-staging-coup-morning-message-michael-moore. 36 Seymour Melman, The War Economy of the United States: Readings on Military Industry and Economy (St. Martin’s Press, 1971). 37 Neil Maycroft, “Consumption, Planned Obsolescence and Waste,” University of Lincoln, no. Working paper (2009); Vance Packard, The Waste Makers (D. Mckay, 1960). 38 Buzby, Jean C., Jeffrey Hyman, Hayden Stewart, and Hodan F. Wells. “The Value of Retail- and Consumer-Level Fruit and Vegetable Losses in the United States.” Journal of Consumer Affairs 45, no. 3 (September 1, 2011): 492–515; Hall, Kevin D., Juen Guo, Michael Dore, and Carson C. Chow. “The Progressive Increase of Food Waste in America and Its Environmental Impact.” PLOS ONE 4, no. 11 (November 25, 2009): e7940; Gunders, Dana. “Wasted: How America Is Losing up to 40 Percent of Its Food from Farm to Fork to Landfill.” National Resources Defense Council, 2017. 39 Heather Rogers, Gone Tomorrow: The Hidden Life of Garbage (New Press, The, 2006). 40 Peter Nolan and Robert F. Ash, “China’s Economy on the Eve of Reform,” in China’s Transitional Economy, ed. Andrew George Walder (Oxford University Press, 1996), 19. 41 Ibid. 42 Amadeo, Kimberly. “The Strange Ups and Downs of the U.S. Economy Since 1929.” The Balance. https://www.thebalance.com/us-gdp-by-year-3305543. 43 LK. “US Real Per Capita GDP from 1870–2001.” http://socialdemocracy21stcentury.blogspot.com/2012/09/us-real-per-capita-gdp-from-18702001.html.

Page 19: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

13

the operations of capitalism—it may seem somewhat surprising that tropes of irrationality and

waste play such a large role in Western understandings of planned economies.

The insistence of Western commentators—despite contradictory and complex

information—on the irrationality and inefficiency of state socialist economies suggest that what

is in operation is in fact a set of self-reproducing discourses. For Foucault, discourse shapes what

becomes visible and excludes incommensurate information.44 Said’s subsequent analysis of the

geographical operations of Western discourse is quite relevant here. Said uses the term

Orientalism to identify a set of European and North American discourses about their imagined

‘East’. It may seem odd to apply Said’s analysis to discourses about ‘irrational’ socialism. A

prime target of these discourses is of course the Soviet Union, which is only sometimes imagined

to be a part of the ‘East’ (in other words, it is not-quite-East). But Said’s discussions have

broader relevance for how Western discourses construct their ‘other’. Said says of the knowledge

produced through Orientalism that it “respond more to the culture that produced it than to its

putative object”. Moreover, this knowledge is made real “by virtue of its having excluded,

displaced, made supererogatory any such real thing as ‘the Orient.’” 45

While much of the Western scholarship under discussion emerged after the Cold War

was declared over, the ideas that they seized on—about ‘irrational’ socialism—date to an earlier

period. This was the dawning era of the Soviet project. The Austrian economist Ludwig von

Mises was the first to argue, in 1920, that the economy of a socialist society would operate

irrationally. Mises hypothesized that any short-term semblance of economic functionality under

socialism would proceed through some people making and imposing decisions onto others.46

Mises gave his account before the Soviet Union had drawn up what became the model for state

socialist economies in the twentieth century. It is then quite remarkable that when studying the

actual operations of subsequently-formed state socialist economies, contemporary Western

researchers have found realities corresponding almost exactly to what Mises had predicted.

44 Foucault, Michel. “The Order of Discourse.” In Untying the Text: A Post-Structuralist Reader, edited by Robert Young, 48–78 (Routledge, 1981), 50-56. 45 Edward W. Said, Orientalism (Vintage Books, 1979), 22. 46 Mises, Ludwig von. “Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth.” In Collectivist Economic Planning: Critical Studies on the Possibilities of Socialism, edited by Frederich Hayek, 87–130. Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1967[1920].

Page 20: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

14

Perhaps Mises had bucked a trend that economists are somewhat known for—of making

erroneous forecasts.47 But perhaps not.

The knowledge gap: from the outside

I initially approached my research with curiosity about what constituted a (state) socialist

approach to projects of development and industrialization. My primary interest lies in

understanding the concept and practices of socialist industrialization in the early PRC, rather

than in the a priori advocacy for or critique of these practices. But my quest to learn has been

stymied by the very works that I should be learning from. The most up-to-date English-language

accounts of early PRC economic development tend to obfuscate and misrepresent the processes

under study, instead of making their contents accessible.

English-language research on aspects of the PRC economy that were published prior to

the mid-1980s tend to contain more information about actual events and processes. These include

works by Donnithorne, Howe, Hsiao, Kwang, Lardy, Lieberthal, Lippit, Perkins, and Riskin.48

These accounts are immensely useful. In my thesis, I rely on these and sources from inside the

PRC for details about its early economy. The most useful aspect of these accounts is that they

tend more towards factual than theoretical. However, I do not frame my project in explicit

relationship to these works for a couple of reasons. One is that my project is interested in

thinking through connections between state socialism and development trajectories. More recent

works (e.g. Naughton, Nolan and Ash) are more likely to make this connection, if in the

47 Barbara Kiviat, “Why Are Economists So Bad at Forecasting?,” Time, July 17, 2009, http://content.time.com/time/business/article/0,8599,1911011,00.html; Adam Shaw, “Why Economic Forecasting Has Always Been a Flawed Science,” September 2, 2017, sec. Money, http://www.theguardian.com/money/2017/sep/02/economic-forecasting-flawed-science-data; Nate Silver, The Signal and the Noise: Why So Many Predictions Fail-but Some Don’t (Penguin, 2012). 48 Audrey Donnithorne, China’s Economic System (Praeger, 1967); Christopher Howe, Wage Patterns and Wage Policy in Modern China 1919-1972 (Cambridge University Press, 1973); Hsiao, “The Role of Economic Contracts in Communist China,” October 31, 1965; Ching Wen Kwang, The Economic Accounting System of State Enterprises in Mainland China (Committee on the Economy of China, Social Science Research Council, 1966); Nicholas R. Lardy, “Economic Recovery and the 1st Five-Year Plan,” in The Cambridge History of China, ed. Roderick MacFarquhar and John K. Fairbank (Cambridge University Press, 1987), 144–83; Kenneth Lieberthal, “The Great Leap Forward and the Split in the Yenan Leadership,” in The Cambridge History of China, ed. Roderick MacFarquhar and John K. Fairbank (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1987), 291–359; Victor D. Lippit, “Development of Transportation in Communist China,” The China Quarterly, no. 27 (1966): 101–19; Dwight Perkins, China’s Modern Economy in Historical Perspective (Stanford University Press, 1975); Carl Riskin, China’s Political Economy: The Quest for Development since 1949 (Oxford University Press, 1987).

Page 21: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

15

negative. The second and more important reason is that the contemporary state of the knowledge

field— on PRC economic history—represents (or is supposed to) the synthesis of earlier research

with insights deriving from hindsight and newly-available information. It therefore makes more

sense to frame my argument around how these earlier works are made sense of and mobilized (or

not) in the contemporary field.

Due to the existing state of research on the early PRC economy, my engagement with

scholarly literatures takes a perhaps unique form. This engagement does not begin or end with

pointing out content and analytical gaps. I instead begin by understanding how contemporary

English-language literature on the early PRC economy have constructed an image of its subject. I

then juxtapose this image with other information, including what has been collected ‘in the field’

(e.g. data and narratives from texts published in the PRC). Mapping out the contours of Western

discourses on early PRC development made it possible to see the processes and events that have

been elided. Part of what becomes unmentioned are precisely the stakes of the (socialist)

industrialization project. My discussion on the first topic of this thesis—socialist

industrialization—therefore unfolds in dialogue with my discussion on the second topic, on

discourses about socialist ‘failure’.

To study the second topic, I begin with a question that was posed earlier: What were

relationships between plans and their results in the early PRC? Then: What were intervening

factors? What is meant by the ‘failure’ of state socialism? What are relationship between

discourses of socialist failure—and the actual trajectories and results of early PRC plans? The

investigative trajectories spawned by these questions would also shape the scope of possible

answers for earlier questions, such as the question about what relationship exists between early

PRC development trajectories and the state ideology of socialism. A crucial question in this

second set is what ‘intervened’ between early PRC plans and their results. The concept of this

intervention is absent from Western discourses on socialist failure, which assume the intrinsic

irrationality of state socialist economies. What is the content of this absence, and what is its

relationship to discourses of socialist failure?

Global histories and geographies on the outside

The use of absence to map out discourse is at the heart of the Derridean practice of

deconstruction. Derrida argued that a text is both held together and can be undone by finding

Page 22: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

16

what it excludes—or traces, the presence of an absence.49 What is crucially excluded from the

discourse of ‘socialist inefficiency’ are historical and persisting structures of global inequality, as

well as their material legacies. These structures are produced and maintained through the

operations of Western imperialism. Imperialism produces what Said attributed to Orientalism,

which is the “systematic discipline by which European culture was able to manage—and even

produce—the Orient politically, sociologically, militarily, ideologically, scientifically, and

imaginatively during the post-Enlightenment period.”50 Said said less however about the

economic and material productions of imperialism. These have been discussed by authors such

as Barrat-Brown, Kemp, and Wallerstein.51 A set of theorists—including Sun Yat-sen—have

also analyzed how Western imperialism unfolded specifically in China’s case. I engage with

their work in Chapter 2.

Accounting for imperialism makes visible the historical and geopolitical contexts that

defined and shaped twentieth-century projects of state socialism, including that of the PRC.

Capitalism and state socialism were not separate projects that unfolded on equal playing fields,

where the better system would ‘win’ by virtues of achieving superior economic and social

organization. In the first half of the twentieth century, China had been a largely agrarian nation

with much of its industries owned by foreign capitalists. To imagine that the new PRC could

have established an independent domestic ‘free market’ economy; that the state could have

avoided issues of shortage and achieved higher growth rates by pursuing its ‘comparative

advantage’ in the international economy—these are the exercises of an imagination freed from

historical realities. This ‘choice’ would have likely sent China further down its existing path at

the time—of becoming increasingly incorporated into the capitalist world economy as an

exporter of raw resource. I discuss the economic realities of pre-1949 China in Chapter 2.

49 Jacques Derrida, “Translator’s Preface,” in Of Grammatology, trans. Gayatri Chakravorty Spivak (JHU Press, 1998), xviii–xx. 50 Said, Orientalism, 3. 51 Michael Barratt-Brown, The Economics of Imperialism, (Harmondsworth: Penguin Books, 1975); Tom Kemp, Theories of Imperialism (Dobson, 1967); Immanuel Wallerstein, “The Rise and Future Demise of the World Capitalist System: Concepts for Comparative Analysis,” Comparative Studies in Society and History 16, no. 4 (September 1974): 387–415.

Page 23: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

17

The operations of state socialism indeed make little sense when abstracted from historical

and geopolitical contexts. It is perhaps unsurprising that it is precisely histories—particular those

connecting the West and China—that form the excluded outside of discourses on socialist

failure. These discourses champion, after all, the ‘end of history’. My approach in this thesis is

indebted crucially to the works of Foucault, Derrida, Said, and their impact on subsequent

scholarship. But if these authors have taught me to perceive and find the outside of discourses,

they were, for many reasons, not concerned about making coherent accounts from the discursive

outsides. The movement towards coherence in this thesis is very much influenced by how Wu

describes his study of the Cultural Revolution: as both an attempt to and being motivated by the

search for logical content amidst narrated irrationality.52 Wu’s work also models another aspect

of this thesis, which is the turning to PRC history as a way to rethink elements of the closer

present.

Railways as method and site

While my thesis centers the topics of socialist industrialization and Western discourses on state

socialist failure, I spend a substantial amount of time discussing aspects of China’s pre-1949

history. This historical context provides ways to look outside of dominant Western discourses on

the early PRC; it points therefore to the realities of early PRC development. My discussions of

Chinese history are often anchored in the structures and operations of the nation’s railways. In

the next and final part of this section on Topics and questions, I turn to these railways. I will

briefly discuss some aspects of these infrastructures. Chinese railways form the central object in

my study—they link together its different elements. These railways play a set of related roles in

this thesis. Chinese railways constitute a research topic, a method for studying socialist

industrialization and surrounding discourses, and finally, a site that makes visible the operations

of transnational history.

52 Wu, The Cultural Revolution at the Margins, 2014, 2–3, 8–9.

Page 24: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

18

2.3 Chinese railways: As topic, method, and site

In the beginning stages of my research, I read broadly about plans, structures, and processes

related to Chinese railways. I read both English- and Chinese-language studies of Chinese

railways. This set of Chinese-language literature proved much more bounded and manageable

than Chinese-language writing on the early PRC economy. I did not attempt to enter the broader

topic of the early PRC economy through writing in both languages.

My preliminary survey of research on Chinese railways covered the following areas: the

geographical distribution of Chinese railways;53 histories of Chinese railway construction and

operations;54 the role of imperialism in early Chinese railway development;55 Republican era

53 Some works in the following lists straddle more than one content category. I try to group works according to the aspect of their discussions that I learned the most from. Dylan Brady, “Forging the Nation through Rails: Transportation Infrastructure and the Emergence of Chinese Nationalism” (MA Thesis, University of Oregon, 2013); Chi-Keung Leung, China, Railway Patterns and National Goals (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1980); Cheng Lin, The Chinese Railways: A Historical Survey (China United Press, 1935); Qikun Zhang, “浅谈中国铁路发展 [An Overview of Chinese Railway Development]” (Beijing Jiaotong University, 2016). 54 Mongton Chih Hsu, Railway Problems in China (New York: AMS Press, 1968); Jin Shixuan, 铁路史话 [A brief history of Chinese railways] (中华书局, 1965); C W Kinder, “Railways and Colleries of North China,” Minutes of the Proceedings of the Institution of Civil Engineers 103, no. 1891 (January 1, 1891): 278–306; Percy Horace Braund Kent, Railway Enterprise in China: An Account of Its Origin and Development (E. Arnold, 1907); Norman Miners, “Building The Kowloon-Canton-Hankow Railway,” Journal of the Royal Asiatic Society Hong Kong Branch 46 (2006): 5–24; Edward Hulme Rigby and William Orr Leitch, “Railway Construction in North China,” Minutes of the Proceedings of the Institution of Civil Engineers 160, no. 1905 (1905): 271–314; William Barclay Parsons, An American Engineer in China (McClure, Phillips & Company, 1900); Harold Stringer, The Chinese Railway System (Shanghai, 1922); H. Stringer, “Railway Economics for China,” The Far-Eastern Review XXV, no. 7 (July 1929): 300–301; Yonggang Yang, 中国近代铁路史 [History of Chinese Railways in the Modern Period], (Shanghai: 新华书店上海发行所, 1997). 55 Clarence Baldwin Davis, “Railway Imperialism in China, 1895-1939,” in Railway Imperialism, ed. Clarence Baldwin Davis, Kenneth E. Wilburn, and Ronald Edward Robinson (Greenwood Press, 1991), 155–74; Bruce Elleman and Stephen Kotkin, Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China: An International History (M. E. Sharpe, 2015); Ralph William Huenemann, The Dragon and the Iron Horse: The Economics of Railroads in China, 1876-1937 (Council on East Asian Studies, Harvard University, 1984); En-han Lee, China’s Quest for Railway Autonomy, 1904-1911: A Study of the Chinese Railway-Rights Recovery Movement (Singapore: Singapore University Press, 1977); Arthur Rosenbaum, “Railway Enterprise and Economic Development: The Case of the Imperial Railways of North China, 1900-1911,” Modern China 2, no. 2 (1976): 227–72; Jean-François Rousseau, “An Imperial Railway Failure: The Indochina—Yunnan Railway, 1898–1941,” The Journal of Transport History 35, no. 1 (June 1, 2014): 1–17; Smith, Privatized Infrastructure; E-tu Zen Sun, “The Pattern of Railway Development in China,” The Far Eastern Quarterly (Pre-1986); Ann Arbor 14, no. 2 (February 1955): 179.

Page 25: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

19

governance and operations;56 Chinese visions and plans for national railway development;57

Chinese railways and regional development;58 relationships between socialist theories and

railway development;59 early PRC plans and processes;60 recent (post-1990) railway reforms and

56 Kia-ngau Chang, China’s Struggle for Railroad Development (The John Day Company, 1943); Jui-te Chang, 中國近代鐵路事業管理的研究--政治層面的分析 1876-1937 [Railroads in Modern China: Political Aspects of Railroad Administration (1876-1937)] (Institute of Modern History, Academia Sinica, 1991); Jui-te Chang, “Technology Transfer in Modern China: The Case of Railway Enterprise (1876-1937),” Modern Asian Studies 27, no. 2 (1993): 281–96. 57 Richard Louis Edmonds, “The Legacy of Sun Yat-Sen’s Railway Plans,” The China Quarterly 111 (September 1987): 421–443; Lippit, “Development of Transportation in Communist China”; Yat-sen Sun, The International Development of China. (New York: Putnam, 1929). 58 Elisabeth Köll, “Chinese Railroads, Local Society, and Foreign Presence: The Tianjin-Pukou Line in Pre-1949 Shandong,” in Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China: An International History: An International History, ed. Bruce Elleman and Stephen Kotkin (M. E. Sharpe, 2015), 123–48; Barry Naughton, “The Third Front: Defence Industrialization in the Chinese Interior,” The China Quarterly, no. 115 (1988): 351–86; Harold Tanner, “Railways in Communist Strategy and Operations in Manchuria, 1945-48,” in Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China: An International History, ed. Bruce Elleman and Stephen Kotkin (M. E. Sharpe, 2015), 149–70; Zhu Congbin, 铁路与社会经济: 广西铁路研究 (1885-1965) [Railways and the economics of society: Research on Guangxi Railways] (合肥工业大学出版社 [Hefei University of Technology Press], 2012). 59 Beijing Railway School, 铁路经济活动分析 [An Analysis of Railway Economic Operations] (Beijing, China: 北京铁道学院 [Beijing Railway School], 1956); 马克思恩格斯列宁斯大林论交通运输业 [Marx, Engels, Lenin and Stalin on the Transportation Industry] (人民铁道出版社 [The People’s Railway Press], 1965); Bingyuan Wu et al., eds., 毛泽东哲学思想与中国铁路建设 [Mao Zedong’s Philosophical Thought and China’s Railway Construction] (Beijing, China: 文津出版社 [Wenjin Press], 1993). 60 Yung-hsin. Chao, Railways in Communist China (Kowloon, H.K.: Union Research Institute, 1956); Tongwei Liu, ed., 铁路修建史料第三集 1949-1962 [The Third Series of Historical Materials on Railway Construction, 1949-1962], vol. 第一册 [Volume one] (Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1964); Tongwei Liu, ed., 铁路修建史料第四集 1963-1980 [The Fourth Series of Historical Materials on Railway Construction, 1963-1980], vol. 第一册 [Volume one] (Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1991); Covell Meyskens, “Third Front Railroads and Industrial Modernity in Late Maoist China,” Twentieth-Century China 40, no. 3 (2015): 238–60; Zenglin Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, eds., 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999] (Beijing: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1999); Yun ’e Peng, 第一个五年计划中的铁路建设 [Railway Construction in the First Five Year Plan] (Beijing, China: 中华全国科学技术普及协会出版 [Nation-wide society for the popularization of science and technology], 1956); Song Yongfu, ed., 中国铁路建设史 [The construction history of Chinese railways] (中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 2003).

Page 26: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

20

developments;61 arguments for and against railway-sector privatization;62 and discussions that

link recent developments to questions of sustainability and access.63 One large area of Chinese

railway-related research that I initially skipped over were highly technical accounts related solely

to railway science and technology, e.g. the shape and thickness of glass used for different rolling

stock, levels of acceptable sound pollution caused by railway operations, etc.

After my preliminary survey of research on Chinese railways, I narrowed in on a set of

railway-related topics that seemed best positioned to answer my questions about early PRC

economic development and surrounding Western discourses. My questions on these topics—

asked in the preceding sections—are the following: What were the objectives of early PRC

development and industrialization plans? How did these objectives relate to the ideology of

state socialism? What were relationships between plans and visions, processes of

implementation, and their results? What were intervening factors? What is meant by the

‘failure’ of state socialism? What are relationship between discourses of socialist failure—and

the actual trajectories and results of early PRC plans?

61 Zhenhua Chen and Kingsley E. Haynes, Chinese Railways in the Era of High-Speed (Emerald Group Publishing, 2015); Michael Y. Chuang and William H. A. Johnson, “‘Hop on Board’: The Importation and Future Development of High-Speed Rail (HSR) in China,” Journal of Technology Management in China 6, no. 3 (2011): 232–41; Fengjun Jin, “Transportation Development Transition in China,” Chinese Geographical Science 22, no. 3 (June 1, 2012): 319–33; Rongfang Liu, “The Role of State: High Speed Rail Development in China,” Advances in Management 8, no. 3 (March 2015): 1–16; Katrin Luger, Chinese Railways: Reform and Efficiency Improvement Opportunities (Springer Science & Business Media, 2008); Linda Tjia Yin-nor, Explaining Railway Reform in China: A Train of Property Rights Re-Arrangements (Routledge, 2015). 62 Chong-En Bai and Yingyi Qian, “Infrastructure Development in China: The Cases of Electricity, Highways, and Railways,” Journal of Comparative Economics 38, no. 1 (2010): 34–51; Ron Kopicki and Louis Thompson, “Best Methods of Railway Restructuring and Privatization” (The World Bank, August 31, 1995); OECD, “Railway Reform in China Promoting Competition: Summary and Recommendations of an OECD/DRC Seminar on Rail Reform in Beijing 28-29 January 2002,” January 2002, http://www.oecd.org/regreform/sectors/34566769.pdf; Russell Pittman, “Chinese Railway Reform and Competition: Lessons from the Experience in Other Countries,” Journal of Transport Economics and Policy 38, no. 2 (2004): 309–32; World Bank, “Tracks from the Past, Transport for the Future: China’s Railway Industry 1990-2008 and Its Future Plans and Possibilities” (The World Bank, May 1, 2009); Hong Yu, “Railway Sector Reform in China: Controversy and Problems” 24, no. 96 (November 2, 2015): 1070–91. 63 Xueming Chen, “A Sustainability Analysis on the Wuhan-Guangzhou High-Speed Railway in China,” International Journal of Sustainable Transportation 9, no. 5 (July 4, 2015): 348–63; Jingjuan Jiao, Jiaoe Wang, and Michael Dunford, “Impacts on Accessibility of China’s Present and Future HSR Network,” Journal of Transport Geography, January 1, 2014; Shiwei Lu, “Impacts of High-Speed Rails on the Accessibility Inequality of Railway Network in China,” 2014 22nd International Conference on Geoinformatics, June 1, 2014, 1–5; Jiaoe Wang et al., “Spatiotemporal Evolution of China’s Railway Network in the 20th Century: An Accessibility Approach,” Transportation Research Part A 43, no. 8 (2009): 765–78; James Jixian Wang, Jiang Xu, and Jianfeng He, “Spatial Impacts of High-Speed Railways in China: A Total-Travel-Time Approach,” Environment and Planning A 45, no. 9 (September 1, 2013): 2261–80.

Page 27: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

21

In order to track these questions and potential answers through the operations of the

Chinese railway system, I narrowed my railway-related investigation to the following set of

topics. These were: (1) relationships between imperialism and the forms and functions of pre-

and early-PRC railways; (2) the role of railways in socialist theories and early PRC development

plans; (3) railway sector contributions to processes of early PRC development and

industrialization; and (4) plans, processes, and results of railway sector development in the early

PRC. I pursued each of the above railway-related topic through a set of smaller questions.

Examples of these smaller questions are: What railways were constructed—and where—during

the Qing, Republican, and early PRC periods? What developments were planned for the railway

sector during the first three Five Year Plans? What was transported by the railway system in the

early PRC and to and from where? What were major changes to the structures and operations of

the railway sector in the early PRC?

I do not ultimately aim to engage in a set of scholarly discussions specific to Chinese

railways. But in the course of conducting research, it was important for me to try to comprehend

the entire system as a whole, including how the different components work(ed) together.

Otherwise it may be tempting to read into and draw significance from one element of the railway

sector without placing it into how the overall system functions (e.g. the significance of military

presence in the early PRC railway sector). My approach here is informed by that of researchers

who track and linger on the internal logic and operations of technical systems; this lingering

often produces new ways of understanding larger political narratives and processes. This

approach is indebted to but also departs from dominant paradigms in Science and Technology

Studies, which tend to emphasize—and stop at—the key insight that scientific and technical

processes are socially constructed.64

Scholars such as Collier, Mukerji, and Swyngedouw have begun their work by attending

to technical aspects, in their respective studies of systems in post-Soviet Russia, early modern

France, and late modern Spain.65 An approach grounded in the exploration of technical and

64 Latour is perhaps the seminal author in this genre. See for example: Bruno Latour and Steve Woolgar, Laboratory Life: The Construction of Scientific Facts (Princeton University Press, 1979). 65 Stephen J. Collier, Post-Soviet Social: Neoliberalism, Social Modernity, Biopolitics (Princeton University Press, 2011); Chandra Mukerji, Impossible Engineering: Technology and Territoriality on the Canal Du Midi (Princeton

Page 28: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

22

specialized systems is particularly suited to researching the early PRC, given the state’s

commitment to—and experiments in—producing systems suited to alternative (Third World)

forms of modernity. Studies of the early PRC that have employed this approach include Boland’s

on waste-water management, Ghosh’s on statistical systems, Lu’s on the spatial planning of

work units, and Schmaltzer’s on scientific farming.66

In the above paragraphs, I have positioned Chinese railways as a research topic (or a set

of topics), and as method (or a kind of approach for researching other questions). Chinese

railways take on a third function in my thesis. This system is also used as a kind of site: one that

registers, displays, and carries forward the effects of transnational history. In Chapter 3, I explore

the mutual making of Chinese history and the nation’s railway system. This chapter adds to the

discussion in Chapter 2 about Western imperialism and Chinese plans, and establishes the

context and background for Chapter 4, which concerns the co-production of state plans and

railway sector development in the early PRC.

3. Methods and sources As discussed in the Topics and questions section, a key method in my project consists of

studying aspects of the Chinese railway system in order to answer larger questions about

processes of socialist industrialization in the early PRC and surrounding Western discourses.

Consequently, I spent a large portion of my research process learning about Chinese railways.

This research process spanned over a year and a half; most of it happened in three locations:

Toronto, Beijing, and Hong Kong. I primarily learned through two sets of activities: reading

books and documents, and conducting interviews.

University Press, 2009); Erik Swyngedouw, Liquid Power: Contested Hydro-Modernities in Twentieth-Century Spain (MIT Press, 2015). 66 Alana Boland, “From Factory to Field: Waste-Water Irrigation in China’s Early Socialist Cities,” Global Environment 9, no. 1 (April 1, 2016): 219–39; Arunabh Ghosh, “Making It Count: Statistics and State-Society Relations in the Early People’s Republic of China, 1949-1959” (PhD thesis, Columbia University, 2014); Duanfang Lu, Remaking Chinese Urban Form: Modernity, Scarcity and Space, 1949-2005 (Taylor & Francis, 2006); Sigrid Schmalzer, Red Revolution, Green Revolution: Scientific Farming in Socialist China (University of Chicago Press, 2016).

Page 29: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

23

3.1 Reading and textual analysis

In my thesis, I mainly use evidence gathered from books and other primarily textual documents

(e.g. newspaper articles, reports, lists, budgets). I used methods of reading, accompanied by

document and textual analysis, to gather information from these sources. I approached books and

documents with my overarching research questions (e.g. What were the objective of early PRC

plans? What were their results? How did early PRC development objectives relate to the state

ideology of socialism?). I was also armed with sets of more specific questions that resulted from

decomposing larger inquiries (e.g. What was planned for the railway sector in the PRC’s FFYP?

What was transported by the early PRC railway sector? What was socialist about railway sector

operations, according to early PRC accounts?).

To guide my reading and keep track of the information learned, I made Microsoft Word

documents for each topic (e.g. socialist industrialization). Each topic document had sections

corresponding to specific research questions (e.g. what were the objectives of early PRC plans?).

The section for each research question was broken down into a set of sub-sections, each

corresponding to a more specific question. I took reading notes using these documents. Finally, I

read texts for both what is said (e.g. facts, policies, explanations), and how it is said—including

what is unsaid. The later elements can point to the presence of assumptions, contexts, particular

political strategies, etc.

In this and the next paragraph, I discuss how I gained access to the books and documents

under study, and what kind of texts they are. I began my research in the beginning of 2016, with

collections in the University of Toronto library system, including its East Asian Library. I then

spent from September 2016 to February 2017 as a visiting student based in the School of Traffic

and Transportation at Beijing Jiaotong University (BJTU). BJTU was first founded in 1909, as

the Beijing Railway Management Institute (北京铁路管理传习所). While in Beijing, I accessed

collections held at China’s National Library, several university libraries, the BJTU archives, and

the Beijing Municipal Archives (BMA). Through my campus and National Library accounts, I

accessed online collections of Chinese newspapers and research articles. I also perused used

book stores and purchased several volumes. In addition, I spent over a week in fall 2016 at the

Page 30: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

24

Chinese University of Hong Kong (CUHK). The University Services Centre for China Studies at

CUHK hosts an extensive and curated collection of books and other sources on the early PRC.

After returning to Toronto in February 2017, I made extensive use of UofT’s interlibrary loan

system, in order to access collections held in other North American university libraries.

As described earlier, I began my railway-related studies by reading English- and Chinese-

language research on Chinese railways. The majority of these scholarly publications were found

through the UofT library system, the National Library, and the USC at CUHK. Once I narrowed

my focus to specific aspects of the Chinese railway system (and had produced correspondingly

specific sets of questions), I turned to primary sources, or what came close. These included

technical and specialist manuals (e.g. on how to make accounting calculations, how to make a

procurement plan, steps involved in surveying railway routes, etc.); meeting proceedings and

records; policy directives from central and local governments; and collected volumes on railway-

sector policies, practices, and statistics (e.g. volumes on PRC railway statistics, volumes on

historical materials related to PRC railway construction, annals of the different railway bureaus).

These items were found in archives, and in collections held by the National Library, various

university libraries, and at the USC at CUHK. A couple of North American universities hold the

annals of several Chinese railway bureaus. While researching specific aspects of the Chinese

railway system, I also searched through and read newspaper articles and issues of specialist

journals published during the early PRC (e.g. Chinese Railways 中国铁路, Bulletin of Surveying

and Mapping 测绘通报).

I now turn to how I interacted with and used textual sources. My reading materials ranged

widely in their distance and relationships to early PRC events. Introductory guides to the

research process often distinguish between primary sources, which constitute direct and first-

hand record of events (e.g. statistics, memoirs, reports), and secondary sources, which

incorporate interpretation and reorganization (e.g. scholarly works, some newspaper articles).67

This simple distinction is of course complicated by how society constructs what becomes

perceived and recorded as events and information. Statistics, for instance, are generally

67 See for example: Whitney Kemble, “Research Guides: Finding Primary Sources: Primary & Secondary Sources Explained,” accessed September 27, 2017, http://guides.library.utoronto.ca/c.php?g=250552&p=1671086.

Page 31: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

25

considered to be primary sources. Rose has however shown that Western statistical facts (e.g.

population and national income) became constructed in the very process of their collection.68

Lam has traced how statistical constructions evolved in China during the first half of the

twentieth century; Ghosh continues this study into the early PRC period.69

Awareness of the constructed nature of data is crucial to the research process; a key

theme in this thesis does, after all, revolve around the construction of knowledge. It can however

still be useful to divide sources into more direct vs. more interpreted accounts, while

acknowledging that this distinction is contingent upon certain politically-produced realities.

While researching, I read and gathered information from sources ranging from more direct

records (e.g. budgets, policy directives, reports, speeches, conference proceedings, statistics), to

intermediate accounts (e.g. technical and specialist manuals, newspaper articles, compilations of

records), to more interpreted accounts (e.g. scholarly works). The texts that I read also ranged in

languages and dates. For purposes of researching socialist industrialization and railway sector

development in the early PRC, more direct accounts would be those in Chinese and produced in

1949-1970. More interpreted accounts would be those in other languages (e.g. English, French),

and produced after 1980.

The above process of sorting has been done retroactively, in order to communicate the

scope and range of my reading. During the research process, I did not approach texts with pre-set

ideas about what order (primary or secondary) of information they contained, or how their

information was to be accordingly used. Reading widely made it possible for me to compare and

synthesize across different kinds of sources. Flick refers to this process—of using multiple forms

of data—as triangulation. Triangulation suggests verification when information from two or

more sources agree; it also calls for attention to context, especially in cases of disagreements.70

Important points in the thesis (e.g. that early PRC leaders prioritized economic efficiency; that

economic accounting systems were key to and implemented around the time of the PRC’s First

68 Nikolas Rose, “Governing by Numbers: Figuring out Democracy,” Accounting, Organizations and Society 16, no. 7 (January 1, 1991): 673–92. 69 Tong Lam, A Passion for Facts: Social Surveys and the Construction of the Chinese Nation-State, 1900–1949 (University of California Press, 2011); Ghosh, “Making It Count: Statistics and State-Society Relations in the Early People’s Republic of China, 1949-1959,” 2014. 70 Uwe Flick, Managing Quality in Qualitative Research (SAGE, 2008), 37–53.

Page 32: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

26

Five Year Plan) were generally arrived at after reading similar information across a range of

sources (e.g. multiple books; newspaper article and specialist manual and compilation of

records; etc.). In addition to using textual sources, I also conducted a small number of interviews.

I discuss the interview process in more detail in the next section. For now, it suffices to say that I

had initially incorporated interviews in order to add another layer to the triangulation process.

The interviews served this purpose and more.

During the research and writing process, I have been quite careful around questions of

data reliability and use. Conventional distinctions drawn between primary and secondary

research suggest that the most caution should be applied to contemporary Western writing about

the early PRC. In the writing of my thesis, I have attempted to follow this convention. In the

earlier research process however, it was likely the early PRC sources that had received

disproportionate scrutiny. These texts were often in traditional characters or a mix of traditional

and simplified, which required that I pore over them for a length of time. Once deciphered, their

grammar structures and meaning were quite strange, even—foreign. It took reading across many

accounts and conversations to understand and find credibility in these texts.

3.2 Interviews

I conducted seven interviews in Beijing, involving nine people. One interview was conducted via

telephone. Interviewees were recruited and interviews conducted according to a set of procedures

that received prior approval from UofT’s Research Ethics Board. Interviewees included former

and current railway researchers, archivists, and those who had been employed in the PRC

railway sector. Interviews ranged from an hour to four hours. I took notes during the interviews.

Most interviews conducted in person were also recorded with the consent of participants, which

has allowed me to revisit what was said.

I conducted interviews in order to contextualize and complement information gained

from reading books and documents. My research relied primarily on textual sources. Documents

are generally easier to access than people, contain more information than could be stored in

memory, and are not distorted by memory. However, books and documents can contain silences,

half-explanations, and puzzling logical short-cuts that are particular to their time or context.

Page 33: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

27

Interviews, especially with researchers and archivists, often took the form of teaching sessions (

请教). I approached the interviews with a list of question produced through my readings. These

questions were additionally specific to the expertise and experiences of each set of interviewees.

The interviews were some of the best parts of my research experience. Participants were

incredibly generous with their knowledge and time. They were also encouraging and seemed

quite willing to answer my questions, even though my project was somewhat odd. My research

fell into a bit of a crevice between different knowledge fields. Historians working in the PRC

today tend to study subjects related to politics, culture, philosophy, etc. Railway researchers, on

the other hand, are focused on solving current and practical problems.

One important exception to the above is Professor Zhu Congbin in the Department of

History at Suzhou University. In 2012, Prof. Zhu published Railways and the economics of

society—research on Guangxi railways (1885-1965) (铁路与社会经济——广西铁路研究

(1885-1965)). The focus and approach of Prof. Zhu and his students are somewhat different than

mine. But what really prevented fruitful learning from them was my location in Beijing.

Fortunately, another scholar keenly interested in Chinese railway histories was Professor Han

Baoming in the School of Traffic and Transportation at Beijing Jiaotong University. Prof. Han

was my liaison and supervising teacher at BJTU. His academic research focuses on resolving

logistical issues in the contemporary Chinese railway system (e.g. modelling optimal freight

flow, assessing station design, analyzing bottleneck issues). Prof. Han however also had an

‘extracurricular’ interest in railway histories, and was in the past the Chief Librarian for the

BJTU library system, which hosts an extensive collection of documents related to Chinese

railways. Needless to say, Prof. Han was immensely helpful.

So it was not the case that my research received no interest or understanding ‘in the

field’. But I definitely had to navigate impressions of its ‘oddness’ during chats and interviews.

Almost all interviewees asked me, directly or more subtly, why I was interested in railway

development during such a ‘backwards’ (落后) time in Chinese history. I got the sense that this

focus was disconcerting, perhaps especially so because I write in English and primarily for an

audience outside of China. One interviewee—who was among the most generous with their

knowledge and time—assumed in the beginning that the topic was assigned to me by my

Page 34: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

28

research supervisor in Canada. Interviewees and other people asked me: Why did I not instead

focus on impressive recent developments in China’s railway system? In the short period since

2002, China has constructed what has become the world’s largest high-speed rail network.71

Additionally, it was almost a non-sequitur to ask about the relationship between socialist

ideology and railway development. It is my impression that for many, if not the majority, of

people in China, socialism is fundamentally conceived as a system of development and economic

progress (社会主义发展). It therefore made no sense to ask about the relationship of socialism

to development, or how the state socialist ideology shaped development trajectories in unique

ways. The idea that state socialism is incompatible with economic progress or development—an

idea that is almost unquestioned in the contemporary West—literally makes no sense in China.

Interviews were therefore an occasion where I grappled with difference, contexts, and

incommensurability. How could I, having received the majority (post-age 7) of my education in

the West, know something about China—and in a way that does justice to how this information

is known and understood by those who are more intimately acquainted with the Chinese context?

At the same time, I cannot take their knowledge as my knowledge, and assume their positionality

and views. Growing up in the West has given me—for better or for worse—a purchase on

Western discourses. Questions and information (e.g. about the dynamics of socialist

industrialization) that might seem crucial to me might not spark the same interest for the people

that I converse with in China; these bits might be passed over as axiomatic or meaningless. This

(perhaps initial) reaction does not necessarily mean that these questions are in fact meaningless.

Awkward moments should of course not be taken out of context. Most conversations that

I had in Beijing were productive and illuminating. During interviews, I mostly felt that I and the

other party ‘got’ where each other came from, or at least as much as possible. But this process

demonstrated clearly to me that, as the interviewees knew, knowledge is not inert. Knowledge

does not merely exist ‘in the field’, awaiting its discovery and processing.72 Continuing

71 Virginia Lau, “Record Breaker: China’s Incredible North-South High-Speed Train Line Plan,” CNN Travel, January 8, 2015, http://www.cnn.com/travel/article/china-high-speed-north-south-rail/index.html. 72 Authors from a range of disciplines and theoretical perspectives have written about how power shapes the research process, especially across axes of difference. Many of these accounts also suggest or model thoughtful ways of engaging in research. Ones that I am probably the most influenced by include: Pierre Bourdieu, “Participant

Page 35: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

29

structures of Western power means that knowledge will be taken and abstracted from Chinese

context to fit Western narratives, regardless of how complicated it is to understand what these

pieces of information actually mean. The interviewing process therefore asked me to hold my

research in ongoing tension with larger questions about what it meant to be doing English-

language research about China.

While the interviews were crucial, there are only a couple of places in my thesis where I

cite information derived from interviews. A large part of the reason is because something close

to 80% of what I learned while conducting research did not make it into this thesis. Another part

of the reason is because interviewees often helped me by explaining processes that I had read bits

about, and by pointing me to other textual sources. The people that I interviewed also sometimes

framed events and processes in a way that changed and shaped how I thought about these after.

These moments came from, for instance, interviewee discussions about the roles and functions of

different kinds of post-secondary education in the Chinese context; about how the availability of

liquid capital shaped patterns of construction stoppage and ‘waste’; and about relationships

between work, discipline, and socialism.

Sometimes these moments came from conversations that were not interviews. One that

shaped how I thought about relationships between the early PRC state apparatus and projects of

economic development came from a conversation with my father, while we were driving through

upstate New York. The conversation was in Chinese. My father worked in a factory in China’s

interior, before applying to university at the close of the Cultural Revolution. I had asked him

about the roles of ganbu (干部, usually translated as ‘cadre’) in industrial workplaces and their

relationship to party politics. My father described a set of fairly routine and useful administrative

functions. I was confused. English-language literature generally connect the presence of ganbu to

Objectivation,” The Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute 9, no. 2 (2003): 281–94; Michael Jackson, “Whose Human Rights? Suffering and Reconstruction in Post-War Sierra Leone,” Sites: A Journal of Social Anthropology and Cultural Studies 2, no. 2 (2005): 141–59; bell hooks, “Marginality as Site of Resistance,” in Out There: Marginalization and Contemporary Cultures, ed. Russell Ferguson et al. (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press, 1990), 341–43; Laura Nader, “Up the Anthropologist: Perspectives Gained from Studying Up.,” 1972; Linda Tuhiwai Smith, Decolonizing Methodologies: Research and Indigenous Peoples (Zed Books, 1999); Kamala Visweswaran, Fictions of Feminist Ethnography (University of Minnesota Press, 1994).

Page 36: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

30

political control and reproduction—and not the basic functioning of workplaces.73 I asked what

the English-language equivalent of ganbu was; my father paused and finally settled on

‘manager’. He knew that the usual translation gives ‘cadre’.

Most moments of these kinds of frame change are not recorded in my thesis. Some are

more applicable to arguments that I toyed with and discarded before starting to write. But

interviews and conversations shaped the very dynamics of how I approached my topics, how I

understood them, and how I came to write about them.

4. Thesis structure and content

In the following section, I outline the structure and contents of this thesis. I first define and

contextualize ‘efficiency’, a concept that links together early PRC concerns with what is

allegedly at stake for critics of state socialism economies. In the second part of this section, I set

out the main argument of this thesis. I position each of the body chapters (Chapters 2, 3, and 4)

in relation to the main argument, and briefly describe the content covered in each chapter.

4.1 A key concept: On efficiency

What is efficiency? Is it important? To whom, and why? It is instructive here to turn to the

Austrian economist Mises, the first critic of socialism’s alleged irrationality and inefficiency, for

what he meant by ‘efficiency’. In Mises’s account, the economic efficiency of capitalism rests on

private ownership. All economic interactions proceed by exchange, which gives rise to a system

of exchange values, or prices. It is prices that make possible rational calculations and thus the

73 See for example: Harry. Harding, Organizing China : The Problem of Bureaucracy, 1949-1976 (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1981), 28–31; Hong Yung Lee, From Revolutionary Cadres to Party Technocrats in Socialist China (University of California Press, 1991), 5–12; Maurice Meisner, Mao’s China and After: A History of the People’s Republic, Third Edition (Simon and Schuster, 1999), 245–76.

Page 37: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

31

“economic use of available resources”.74 Bracketing for the moment that Mises’s conception of

capitalism (pure exchange) can only exist in a utopia where every person has equal sociopolitical

power and ability, the end goal of the system—and what is touted as an efficiency only

achievable by capitalism—seems to be the “economic use of available resources.”

I think that if we were to further define the “economic use of available resources” as

maximizing the desired output for a given amount of input (resources, materials, labour, time,

etc.), it would not venture too far from how Mises used the phrase. This is also the definition of

economic efficiency provided by Weber, who had, shortly after Mises, also written about the

inefficiencies of socialist economic systems.75 But it is important to note that for Mises, planning

itself is socialist—and socialism entails planning.76 If a planned economic system were to

achieve the maximization of output for a given amount of input, this process would still be

irrational—because planning itself is irrational. Mises would find it absurd the attempt to define

‘efficiency’ on its own, separate from capitalism. In the rest of the thesis, there is sometimes the

conflation of ‘socialism’ and ‘planning’ (e.g. socialist economy; planned economy) in both my

writing and the quotes pulled from others. This is because this conflation has been quite common

to Western discussions of state socialism.

To foreground efficiency presumes an assumption of scarcity. Mises is concerned that

socialism “will squander the scarce factors of production both material and human”.77 Marx, on

the other hand, had been less concerned. The revolution (will) happens at a time (and place) with

the full development of the forces of production, when plenty abound.78 Lu—in her study of

post-1949 spatial planning in the PRC—points out that Marxists tend to conceive of scarcity as

74 Hayek, Frederich. “The Nature and History of the Problem.” In Collectivist Economic Planning: Critical Studies on the Possibilities of Socialism, edited by Frederich Hayek, 1–40 (Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1967), 26, 32-37 (quote on p. 32); Mises (1967[1920]), 92-101. 75 Andors discuses Weberian efficiency: Stephen Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution: Politics, Planning, and Management, 1949 to the Present (New York: Pantheon Books, 1977), 252. 76 Ludwig Von Mises, Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis (Yale University Press, 1951), 296. 77 Ibid., 585. 78 Marx wrote, for instance, that “No social order is ever destroyed before all the productive forces for which it is sufficient have been developed” (A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy (C. H. Kerr, 1904), 12–13). Here Marx is saying that the transition from capitalism to socialism will only occur after the full development of productive forces in capitalism.

Page 38: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

32

being politically produced; the result of unequal distribution.79 Lu argues that scarcity had

mattered; it had been an important material and psychological condition that shaped post-1949

developments. Lu attributes conditions of scarcity to the legacies of imperialism, to Western

blockade and embargo against China since post-1950, and to the PRC’s programs for

industrialization and modernization.80

Scarcity had been a ‘real’ issue in the PRC precisely because both the concept and

condition had been politically produced—through the workings of the world economic system.

That national scarcity had been of crucial consideration in the PRC state’s development choices

does not figure into the accounts of most Western scholars. This silence is due in part to how

erasing colonialism erases, to an extent, China’s deprivation. Also key here is how Western ideas

about socialism tend to be tied to Marx’s vision, which presume an already industrialized society

where scarcity ‘matters’ less. But conditions of scarcity are precisely what drew PRC leaders to

the route of socialist industrialization.

State socialism suggested the possibility of a collective project: that the PRC’s population

could be united in a coordinated effort to achieve national industrialization and economic

growth. A domestic capitalist system had been rejected not only for the system’s tendency

towards inequality and domination, but also for how it was perceived to disperse and make

anarchic the exertion of effort.81 It is important to note that the PRC’s leaders were perhaps even

more concerned with efficiency than Mises, and their solution had been state socialism. A 1963

editorial in the People’s Daily puts it thus: “the running of enterprises with industry and thrift is

not a question of method but of policy. It is not a question of management, but of political

79 Lu, Remaking Chinese Urban Form, 2006, 7. 80 Ibid., 8–9. 81 Economics-related literature in the early PRC often discuss the comparative efficiency of socialism. This topic is sometimes accompanied by further discussion on how to separate economic methods and techniques (e.g. calculations) from how they become applied in capitalist systems. See for example: Beijing Railway School, 铁路经济活动分析 [An Analysis of Railway Economic Operations]; Ying Fu, “为什么苏联工业发展如此迅速? [Why has industry in the Soviet Union developed so quickly?],” 世界知识 [World Affairs], no. 47 (1952): 9–11; Jiafeng Ning, “社会主义企业中流动资金的组织和计划工作 [The organization of liquid funds and planning work in socialist enterprises],” 中国金融 [China Finance], no. 12 (1953): 1–4; Peixin Yang, “第一个五年计划的资金积累问题 [The question of capital accumulation in the First Five Year Plan],” 经济研究 [Economics Research], no. 04 (1955): 12–35; Daijie Zhu, 铁路材料技术供应计划 [Plans for Supplying Railway Materials and Technology] (Beijing, China: 人民铁道出版社 [The People’s Railway Press], 1957).

Page 39: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

33

orientation.”82 In other words, the pursuit of economic efficiency was at the core of proper

political practice; to be efficient was at the very heart of what it meant to be socialist.

4.2 The main argument in three chapters

The subsequent chapters of this thesis take as their starting point the set of discourses about

‘socialist inefficiency’ and the consequent failure of state socialist projects. I discuss the logic

and processes of socialist industrialization in the early PRC in relation to—and after accounting

for—Western discourses about the early PRC economy. As noted previously, discourses about

the economic deficiencies of state socialist (or centrally planned) economies revolve around

three themes: (1) that planners had been idiosyncratic and produced irrational plans; (2) that

resource allocation had been inefficient due to the absence of economic mechanisms; and (3) that

economic planning produces the waste of resources, materials, and labour. Chapter 2 in this

thesis is primarily concerned with the first theme, while Chapter 4 addresses the second and

third. Chapter 3 provides context to set up the discussion in Chapter 4; it also bridges the first

and second halves of the thesis. I provide brief descriptions of each chapter in the paragraphs

below.

In Chapter 2, I argue that ideas about ‘irrational’ socialist plans and planners are

produced through and reproduce the erasure of Western imperialism. I first discuss how

contemporary Western accounts of the PRC are often predicated on the erasure (or exclusion) of

the nation’s colonized history. I then present some aspects of this excluded history—I highlight

in particular the economic operations and impacts of imperialism on China. After restoring

historical and material contexts to early PRC state decisions, I proceed to locate and explicate

forms of logic operating through the PRC’s First Five Year Plan (FFYP). I discuss the FFYP in

conversation with accounts that insist on its irrationality. In the final part of Chapter 2, I shift the

onus of rationality from early PRC planners to their critics. I scrutinize the internal logic (and

82 People's Daily Editorial, “发扬勤俭办企业的革命精神 实行严格的经济核算制度 [Develop the Revolutionary Spirit of Diligence and Thrift in Enterprise Operations, Rigorously Carry out the Economic Accounting System],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], July 7, 1963, sec 1.

Page 40: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

34

lack thereof) found in the works of Ludwig von Mises—an economist known to be the

progenitor of discourses on ‘irrational’ socialism.

Chapters 3 and 4 move away from discourses and towards events ‘on the ground’.

Chapter 3 traces the formation of the early PRC railway sector. The early system incorporated

infrastructures inherited from the Nationalist (GMD) government of late-Republican China,

approaches shaped by the CCP’s history of labour activism and war-time experiences, and the

results of learning from Soviet railway operations. Interactions between the USSR, GMD, and

CCP also compelled the Chinese Communists to innovate a new approach to projects of

industrialization, encapsulated in the idea of the ‘People’s Railway’. The grounds covered in

Chapter 3 provide the context and background for the events and processes later discussed in

Chapter 4.

Chapter 4 focuses on the mechanisms of early PRC state planning and their

implementation in the state railway sector. I begin with an account of the state planning process

in the early PRC. I use evidence from this process to challenge the second and third sets of ideas

about ‘irrational’ socialism, which revolve around its alleged lack of economic mechanisms,

inefficiency of resource allocation, and corresponding waste. In the last part of this chapter, I

turn to the local realizations of central state plans. I trace the implementation of the economic

accounting system in railway-sector workplaces. This system functioned as a ‘central link’ that

connected state plans to local production. The unfolding of state plans in the early PRC

highlight, once again, the kinds of realities existing outside of Western discourses on ‘irrational’

socialism. Against the backdrop of events discussed in Chapters 3 and 4, I also consider a set of

questions about what was ‘produced’ through the early PRC’s budding state socialist economy. I

am curious in particular about how the new system reshaped what it meant to be a human person

(subject) in the Chinese context. This later set of questions can only be conceived and asked—

rather than engulfed and distorted—when imperialist discourses about state socialism are first

identified and held in their place.

Page 41: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

35

Chapter II. The Red passion for economizing, part one: The erased logic of plans

1. Introduction In Chapter 1, I identified a set of discourses centered on the failure of historically-existing state

socialist projects. These discussions link the failure of socialism to the economic inefficiency (or

irrationality) of the state planned economy. As discussed previously, discourses about socialist

inefficiency include three sets of ideas: (1) that planners had been idiosyncratic and produced

irrational plans; (2) that resource allocation had been inefficient due to the absence of economic

mechanisms; and (3) that economic planning produces the waste of resources, materials, and

labour. This chapter is primarily concerned with the first set of ideas, while the next chapter

(Chapter 4) more substantially addresses the second and third sets.

In this chapter, I argue that ideas about ‘irrational’ socialist plans and planners are

produced through—and reproduce—the erasure of Western imperialism. This chapter has four

subsequent sections, followed by the conclusion. In the first section, I discuss how contemporary

Western writing on the PRC is often predicated on the erasure (or exclusion) of its colonized

history. In the second section, I present some aspects of this excluded history. Having

rehabilitated the historical and geopolitical contexts of CCP and early PRC decisions, I proceed

to, in the third section of this chapter, discuss the logic of the PRC’s First Five Year Plan

(FFYP). I explore the FFYP in conversation with what has been written by a particular set of

critics: those who view state planning and planners in the early PRC as irrational. What emerges

from this exploration is that ideas about ‘irrational’ plans—in fact, the whole set of narratives

about ‘irrational’ socialism—have little to do with actual plans or processes of planning in

socialist states.

At this point, it became clear to me that if a fair understanding of socialist state planning

is the objective, it is of little use to retrieve the logic of plans and planners. These should have

never been in question. Discourses about ‘irrational’ socialism are not particularly grounded in

logic or rationality. Therefore in the fourth section of this chapter, I turn to the logic (and lack

Page 42: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

36

thereof) of the ‘irrational’ socialism discourse itself, found in the works of its progenitor—

Ludwig von Mises. It is perhaps unsurprising that what is excluded from contemporary

discourses on ‘irrational’ socialism—which is imperialism, or the global operations of

capitalism—is precisely what was at stake for Mises.

2. Imperialism, the erased trace In her article published in 1993, Barlow shows how Cold War-era research had constructed

China anew—by distorting and removing the nation’s history of having been colonized.1 What

has been erased is now almost gone from memory. In a recent survey of the China field,

Vukovich finds that most English-language accounts assume a China that is abstracted from its

colonial and revolutionary history.2 Peck and Esherick, writing during the Vietnam War, had

called attention to the ongoing rhetorical excision. The term ‘imperialism’ still held a certain

logic at the time. To counter its logic, Western scholars rewrote operations of imperialism as

mutual exchange—and as assistance offered to China by the West at a time when the former had

been confronted with the inevitable course of (modernizing) history.3

The erasure of China’s colonial history shapes contemporary Western accounts of

Chinese state socialism and its political and economic institutions. For Nolan and Ash, Mao and

his “idiosyncratic ideas” had determined the PRC’s early course of economic development.4

Here Ash and Nolan express a view common to China scholarship—that the PRC’s adoption of

socialist institutions was an odd—‘ideological’ rather than rational—choice. Naughton, for

instance, characterizes the PRC’s Mao-era institutions as “peculiar”. For Naughton, the early

PRC had been an “outlier” among both socialist and developing countries. Developing countries

do not have socialist institutions; socialist countries were not plagued by “the problems of a poor,

1 Tani E. Barlow, “Colonialism’s Career in Postwar China Studies,” Positions 1, no. 1 (March 20, 1993): 224–67. 2 Daniel Vukovich, China and Orientalism: Western Knowledge Production and the PRC (Routledge, 2013), 5–6. 3 Joseph Esherick, “Harvard on China: The Apologetics of Imperialism,” Bulletin of Concerned Asian Scholars 4, no. 19 (1972): 9–16; James Peck, “The Roots of Rhetoric: The Professional Ideology of America’s China Watchers,” Bulletin of Concerned Asian Scholars 2, no. 1 (1969): 59–69. 4 Nolan and Ash, “China’s Economy on the Eve of Reform,” 1996.

Page 43: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

37

predominantly rural economy”.5 In other words, socialism was incompatible with China’s

realities. The PRC’s choice of state socialism had been motivated by something other than

‘normal’ considerations of its Third World circumstances.

But the appeal of Marxist (or perhaps more accurately, Marxist-Leninist) programs to

Chinese reformers lay precisely in how well these ideas matched common observations and

understandings of China’s ‘Third World’ realities—and the global processes producing these

realities. Geopolitical jostling during World War I led Lenin to theorize imperialism as the global

process of capitalist exploitation by the Great Powers.6 Marxism became known to Chinese

thinkers through the actions and ideas of the Russian Bolsheviks. One of the first Marxist-

influenced Chinese language texts had been published by Li Dazhao in 1918. Li wrote about the

events of the Russian Revolution and World War I, Li extolled the strength demonstrated by

Russian workers against imperialist powers.7 Li, who became one of the founding architects of

the CCP, played a crucial role in how Marxism was understood and acted upon in China. It was

Li who had first conceptualized China as a ‘proletarian nation’.8 In the milieu of early twentieth

century China, it was not only Marxists who attributed China’s ‘Third World’ status to Western

imperialism. Sun Yat-sen, known as the father of Republican China—who had co-founded

Nationalist Party (GMD) that the CCP struggled against in the Chinese civil war—wrote

extensively about imperialism’s impact on China.9 Sun had promoted Chinese nationalism as the

antidote to imperialist domination.10 The CCP had insisted instead that the economic oppression

borne by China’s population could not be resolved by mere political or cultural empowerment.

5 Barry Naughton, The Chinese Economy: Transitions and Growth (MIT Press, 2007), 8. 6 Vladimir Ilych Lenin, Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism (International Publishers, 1937). 7 Dazhao Li, “Bolshevism 的胜利 [The Victory of Bolshevism],” in 李大钊选集 [Selected Works of Li Dazhao] (Beijing: Beijing Renmin Press, 1962), 117–18. 8 Maurice J. Meisner, Li Dazhao and the Origins of Chinese Marxism (Harvard University Press, 1967), 144. 9 Yat-sen. Sun, San Min Chu I: The Three Principles of the People, ed. L. T. Chen, trans. Frank W. Price (Shanghai: Commercial Press, 1929), 33–53. 10 Ibid., 55–76.

Page 44: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

38

3. Materializing history: The early PRC in context In the next paragraphs, I turn to the scene that the CCP and GMD had both observed. What had

been the impact of Western imperialism on China in the late nineteenth and early twentieth

century? The account of course begins with opium. When the Qing government had resisted the

special merchandise of British traders, the British government declared war on China. The

British military—equipped with the products of heavy industry—defeated China in 1842.

Military defeat opened China to a series of unequal treaties. The first—Treaty of Nanjing—had

been signed between China and Britain in 1842. The rest of the Great Powers, including the U.S.,

France, Germany, Belgium, Russia, and Japan, soon followed Britain’s lead. In these treaties,

foreign nations had claimed rights to items such as extraterritoriality, concessions and

settlements, leased territories, favourable trade terms, and controls over certain Chinese state

organs, such as the Maritimes Custom Service.11 Many treaty terms remained in force until the

1940s.12

Western domination of China had proceeded in the absence of unified political control by

a single imperialist state. The mobilizing of this absence has been crucial to projects of erasing

China’s colonial history.13 Meanwhile, as Barlow also points out, much ado has been made about

foreign presence and excesses in the areas of extraterritoriality—the treaty ports.14 To conflate

foreign domination with the spectacular treaty ports provides cover for a particular strategy of

colonial dismissal: Western scholars have often suggested that Chinese discussions of

imperialism have little to do with its actual effects—but rather stem from the population’s

(erroneous) perception of its impacts.15 That imperialism attempts to erase itself was already

11 Jonathan D. Spence, The Search for Modern China: A Documentary Collection (Norton, 1999), 158–64. 12 Dong Wang, China’s Unequal Treaties: Narrating National History (Lexington Books, 2005), 10. 13 Barlow, “Colonialism’s Career in Postwar China Studies,” 238–47. 14 Ibid.; John K. Fairbank, Trade and Diplomacy on the China Coast: The Opening of Treaty Ports, 1842-1854, 1964; John K. Fairbank, “The Early Treaty System in the Chinese World Order,” in The Chinese World Order: Traditional China’s Foreign Relations (Harvard University Press, 1968), 257–75; Rhoads Murphey, The Treaty Ports and China’s Modernization: What Went Wrong? (University of Michigan, Center for Chinese Studies, 1970). 15 Peck points out the trope of Chinese overreaction in the works of John K. Fairbank and Joseph Levenson. Peck, “The Roots of Rhetoric: The Professional Ideology of America’s China Watchers,” 60–62. ). Nathan also reproduces this trope in his response to Peck. Andrew J. Nathan, “Imperialism’s Effects on China,” Bulletin of Concerned Asian Scholars 4, no. 19 (1972): 6; Lorenz M. Lüthi, The Sino-Soviet Split: Cold War in the Communist World (Princeton

Page 45: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

39

noted by Chinese thinkers like Sun Yat-sen. For Sun, the main form of domination exercised by

the foreign powers had not been through flashy displays—but rather through economic actions.

Sun had argued that economic oppression is more dangerous than political oppression—“[w]hile

the latter is visible and can be recognized at once, the former is not visible and as a consequence

usually is not noticed.”16

Heeding Sun’s logic, I will point out some of imperialism’s economic impacts on China.

To begin with, China had been ordered to pay large indemnities after events such as the two

Opium Wars (1839-1842; 1856-1860), the First Sino-Japanese War (1894-1895), and the Boxer

Rebellion (1899-1901). According to treaty terms, China had paid 58 million taels (silver

dollars)—50 million to Britain, and 8 million to France—after the two Opium Wars.17 Later

indemnities grew astronomically in value. The Sino-Japanese War indemnity had been 250

million taels, while the Boxer indemnity had been 900 million taels.18 The Chinese state needed

to borrow from foreign creditors in order to pay these larger amounts, which added interest to the

amount owing. China had also borrowed from foreign creditors to finance its increasing military

and defense spending. For instance, China had armed itself with the assistance of European

creditors during the First Sino-Japanese War. Feuerwerker calculates that from 1895-1911,

China paid over 476 million taels on the principle and interest of indemnities, and over 70

million in repayment of military loans.19

In the years after the Second Opium War, China’s debt to the West had rapidly grown.

China’s increasing indebtedness evolved with growing foreign control over its state finances and

financial sector. In the 1840s, the Qing state had created China’s Maritime Customs Service in

order to increase its tax revenues—for purposes of paying off indemnities from the First Opium

War.20 Control and administration of this body—including the funds that it collected—was

University Press, 2008), 33–35; Richard Curt Kraus, The Cultural Revolution: A Very Short Introduction (Oxford University Press, 2012), 82. 16 Sun, San Min Chu I;, 37, 42–43. 17 Spence, The Search for Modern China, 181–82; Zhihong Shi, Central Government Silver Treasury: Revenue, Expenditure and Inventory Statistics, Ca. 1667-1899 (BRILL, 2016), 33. 18 Sun, San Min Chu I;, 52. 19 Albert Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, Ca. 1870-1911 (Ann Arbor, MI: Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1969), 70–71. 20 Ibid., 64–65.

Page 46: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

40

turned over to Western powers after the Second Opium War.21 Starting in the 1860s, customs

levied on foreign goods were limited to 5%, while Chinese goods were taxed at higher rates.22

The Chinese salt tax system came under similar control in 1913.23 Most banks in China in the

late Qing and early Republican periods had also been foreign-owned. Foreign banks largely

sought to make profit through speculation. When these banks invested in Chinese enterprises, it

was often in the interest of taking over.24

Foreign capitalists had set up extractive and manufacturing industries in the treaty ports

and concession areas, thereby profiting from Chinese resources and labour. Chesneaux estimates

that over 40% of Chinese urban workers had been employed by foreign enterprises in 1919.25 In

the 1930s, the Chinese-owned share of capitalization in China’s manufacturing industry had been

37%.26 Prior to the 1860s, China did not have urban industrial centers per se. Cities had mainly

served the needs of state administration and trading.27 Manufactured products—such as

ceramics, tapestry, silk, preserved foods, mined minerals—had been produced by craftsmen and

peasants in their non-farming time.28 Chinese industries, often based on Western models, had

emerged during China’s Self Strengthening Movement (1861-1895). In response to repeated

military defeats, the ‘Self Strengtheners’—largely Qing state officials and members of the

Chinese gentry—had advocated for adopting Western technology and forms of political and

economic organization. Their goal was for the nation to accrue capital and strengthen its defense

capacity.29

21 Jean Chesneaux, The Chinese Labor Movement, 1919-1927, trans. H. M. Wright (Stanford: Stanford University Press, 1968), 6; Shi, Central Government Silver Treasury, 53. 22 Nathan, “Imperialism’s Effects on China,” 3–4; Sun, San Min Chu I;, 42. 23 Chesneaux, The Chinese Labor Movement, 1919-1927., 6. 24 Esherick, “Harvard on China: The Apologetics of Imperialism,” 12. 25 Chesneaux, The Chinese Labor Movement, 1919-1927., 42. 26 Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, Ca. 1870-1911, 116–17. 27 Terry McGee et al., “‘Seeing like a State’: The Urbanization Project in Post-1978 China,” in China’s Urban Space: Development Under Market Socialism (Routledge, 2007), 31–33. 28 Chesneaux, The Chinese Labor Movement, 1919-1927., 11–13; Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, Ca. 1870-1911, 110; Kenneth Pomeranz, The Great Divergence: Europe, China, and the Making of the Modern World Economy (Princeton University Press, 2000), 86–90. 29 Leung, China, Railway Patterns and National Goals, 1980, 20–25; David Scott, China and the International System, 1840-1949: Power, Presence, and Perceptions in a Century of Humiliation (SUNY Press, 2008), 52. Also see Young for a discussion of how, in several non-Western states, modernization had been pursued in order to

Page 47: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

41

In early twentieth century China, Western-owned enterprises had enjoyed several key advantages

over their Chinese counterparts. Chinese-owned enterprises were charged higher maritime tariffs,

and were also subject to the internal circulation tax (likin) that Western enterprises had been

exempted from.30 Chinese enterprises often had trouble accruing necessary start-up and

operating capital. Foreign banks resisted investing in Chinese enterprises; investment also came

with high rates and other consequences. When the price of silver rose on the world market in

1933, Western-owned banks in China exported over 80% of their silver holding. 25% of Chinese

textile factories in Shanghai suspended their operations due to the credit crunch. Many then sold

their operations to foreign businesses.31 In addition, much of the modern transportation and

energy sector—shipping, railways, mining—had been under foreign ownership or control.32 For

instance, foreign-owned mines had extracted 99% of pig iron, 99% of the iron core, and 76% of

coal produced in China in 1920.33 Foreign domination of the transportation and energy sectors

correlated to the high capitalization needs of these industries. As a consequence, Chinese-owned

industries often encountered high tariffs and administrative difficulties in fueling their operations

and transporting their products.34

Using data from 1921, Sun had calculated China’s annual loss to foreign powers to be at

least 1.2 billion Hong Kong dollars. Sun’s calculation includes 500 million dollars from the

annual trade deficit, 100 million dollars foreign bank operations, 100 million dollars from

foreign monopoly on transportation, 500 million dollars from the foreign occupation of land, and

more than 100 million dollars from indemnities and other kinds of special business.35 Another

source of numbers for China’s trade deficit—or the aggregate value of how much China had

been importing more than exporting—comes from Hsiao’s compilation of the pre-1949 records

of the Custom Maritime Service. Hsiao’s data shows China’s trade deficit in 1921 to be just over

defend against imperialist encroachment (Crawford Young, “Ideas of Progress in the Third World,” in Progress and Its Discontents, ed. Gabriel Abraham Almond and Marvin Chodorow (University of California Press, 1985)). 30 Esherick, “Harvard on China: The Apologetics of Imperialism,” 12. 31 Ibid.; Sun, San Min Chu I;, Part III, Lecture 4. 32 Chesneaux, The Chinese Labor Movement, 1919-1927., 10–11; Albert Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, 1870-1949 (Center for Chinese Studies, University of Michigan, 1995), 116–17; Sun, San Min Chu I;, Part III, Lecture 4. 33 Esherick, “Harvard on China: The Apologetics of Imperialism,” 11. 34 Chesneaux, The Chinese Labor Movement, 1919-1927., 11; Sun, San Min Chu I;, Part III, Lecture 4. 35 Sun, San Min Chu I;, 43–53.

Page 48: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

42

320 million taels, which would convert to just over 480 million Hong Kong dollars.36 To provide

some additional numerical context: Sun’s calculated annual loss of 1.2 billion HK dollars in the

early 1920s would have been the equivalent of 600 million U.S. dollars. The average annual

expenditure of the Chinese Republican government between 1928 and 1937 had been 806

million Chinese dollars (yuan), the equivalent of 274 million U.S. dollars—or under half of

Sun’s estimated annual loss.37 In may also be worthwhile to mention that in these nine years, the

Republican government had spent on average 31.9% of its total budget on payments towards

indemnities and loans, and 42.8% of its total budget on military expenses.38

While Sun’s numbers are obviously inexact, they do give a general sense of the different

kinds of Western economic extraction at play in pre-1949 China. Sun’s numbers also do not

include certain items. One is increased military spending and losses incurred during wars. War-

related economic loss became much greater in the decade after Sun’s death, when Japan invaded

mainland China (1937-1945). Another item is the profit that Western enterprises had been

making from China. Sun and Esherick both note Republican China’s trade deficit. By 1924,

China had been importing (buying) several hundred million taels’ worth of goods than it had

been exporting (selling). But a significant amount of China’s exports—considered as bringing

payment into the nation—were in fact making profit for Western capitalists. In addition to

foreign domination of China’s energy, transportation, mining and heavy industries in Republican

China, an estimated 60% of factories producing tobacco products, 35% of factories producing

cotton products, and 50% of factories producing vegetable oils had been foreign-owned.39 In

1924, exports transported on Chinese-owned ships had made up only 35% of total exports

moving through China’s ports.40

36 Liang-lin. Hsiao, China’s Foreign Trade Statistics, 1864-1949 (Cambridge, Mass.: East Asian Research Center, 1974). The trade deficit is calculated from the trade in commodities (p. 24), and in silver and gold (p. 128). Hsiao also provides data for currency conversion (p. 192). 37 Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, Ca. 1870-1911, 160–61. Conversion rates are from Hsiao, China’s Foreign Trade Statistics, 1864-1949, 192–93. Records for state expenditures during the Nanjing Decades (1928-1937)—when the GMD had governed Republican China—are more complete than those from 1912-1927. The earlier period is known as the Warlord Era: conflicts between different military factions often disrupted state governance. 38 Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, Ca. 1870-1911, 160–61. 39 Chesneaux, The Chinese Labor Movement, 1919-1927., 30–33; Esherick, “Harvard on China: The Apologetics of Imperialism,” 12. 40 Hsiao, China’s Foreign Trade Statistics, 1864-1949, 222–23.

Page 49: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

43

Furthermore, as Chesneaux, Esherick, and Sun all point out: the economic value extracted from

China had been increasing.41 In 1937, China had owed foreign debt on the principal value of

over 4 billion taels.42 This number is over 300 times the amount—under 11 million taels—that

had been owed in 1894.43 China’s railway-related debt had grown from under 150 thousand USD

in 1894, to approx. 150 million USD in 1911.44 This amount had again increased to 420 million

USD by 1937.45 In the railway sector, the value that China had derived from foreign loans had

decreased post-1911. The 150 million USD borrowed from 1894-1911 had produced approx.

8500 km of tracks constructed with foreign funds. The additional 270 million borrowed from

1912-1937 produced just under 7100 km of foreign-funded tracks in 1912-1948.46 In other

words, the cost of foreign-assisted railway construction had increased from 17,600 USD/km to

38,000 USD/km between 1911 and 1948.

On top of accumulating loans, China was also losing an increasing amount of money

through trade. The international trade balance had changed from a slight surplus for China of 2.5

million taels in 1864, to a deficit of 94 million in 1911, to the pre-war maximum deficit of 733

million in 1933. After the Second Sino-Japanese War, China’s trade deficit had reached the

equivalent of 4.3 billion taels in 1947.47 China’s exports were also increasingly ‘low value’, in

the eyes of the global economy. Raw materials were making up an ever-rising percentage of

China’s exports. Meanwhile, the price of raw materials had decreased in the international market

in comparison to manufactured products. Esherick calculates that in 1935, China needed to

export 160% of what it exported in 1870 in order to be able to purchase the same amount of real

goods.48

41 Chesneaux, The Chinese Labor Movement, 1919-1927., 6–7; Esherick, “Harvard on China: The Apologetics of Imperialism,” 11; Sun, San Min Chu I;, 43–60. 42 Arthur Nichols Young, China’s Nation-Building Effort, 1927-1937 (Stanford, CA: Hoover Institution Press, 1971), 140. 43 En-han Lee, China’s Quest for Railway Autonomy, 1904-1911: A Study of the Chinese Railway-Rights Recovery Movement (Singapore: Singapore University Press, 1977), 19. 44 Ibid.; Leung, China, Railway Patterns and National Goals, 1980, 44. 45 Kia-ngau Chang, China’s Struggle for Railroad Development (The John Day Company, 1943), 147–49, 170–72. 46 Leung, China, Railway Patterns and National Goals, 1980, 40, 72–73; Zhang, “浅谈中国铁路发展 [An Overview of Chinese Railway Development].” 47 Hsiao, China’s Foreign Trade Statistics, 1864-1949, 24. 48 Esherick, “Harvard on China: The Apologetics of Imperialism,” 11.

Page 50: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

44

Another point of contention in Western literature is whether foreign imperialism had actually

impacted the lives of China’s population. Nathan, for instance, posits that China’s economic

losses—though they existed—had been slight and non-consequential, only “making some

incremental contributions to [the people’s] poverty.”49 One line of inquiry into the question of

imperialism’s impact on China’s population is to investigate changing tax burdens. In

Feuerwerker’s account, he finds that the Qing state’s central collection of funds had been under

50 million taels prior to 1842. Local collection had not added much in addition.50 After 1842,

both the central government and provincial governments had increased taxes and added new

forms of taxation. By 1900, China’s central and local governments together collected an annual

sum of around 300 million taels.51 State collections again rose after 1900, due to dramatic

increases in the balance that China had owed in indemnities and loan repayment. The Qing

government had been overthrown in the Xinhai Revolution of 1911. In the half-decade before

1911, the Chinese state paid over 46 million taels annually to foreign powers, and collected from

its population an estimated annual amount of 350 million taels.52

Most historians agree that the Qing government had encountered resistance when raising

taxes. Feuerwerker comments that the state’s post-1900 collections had “only [been] possible in

the extraordinary circumstance of a de facto occupation of North China by foreign armies.”53

What had been the average distributed effects of tax increase on China’s population? Studies

suggest that China’s population had decreased significantly in the late Qing period, due to events

such as the Taiping Rebellion.54 But even assuming that population numbers (estimated to be

400 million in 1840) had remained stable over the next decades, the average tax burden on each

person in China had increased by 0.75 taels between 1842 and 1911. Most of this increase can be

49 Nathan, “Imperialism’s Effects on China,” 5. 50 Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, Ca. 1870-1911, 64–65. 51 Ibid., 67. 52 Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, 1870-1949, 1995, 80–83. 53 Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, Ca. 1870-1911, 70. 54 Ye Ma and Herman de Jong, “Unfolding the Turbulent Century: A Reconstruction of China’s Historical National Accounts, 1840–1912,” Review of Income and Wealth, 2017; Kent Deng, “China’s Population Expansion and Its Causes during the Qing Period, 1644–1911,” 2015; H. Li, “Population Remains Top Priority for China,” Joicfp News, no. 286 (April 1998): 1–2.

Page 51: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

45

attributed to events after 1880.55 Common estimates of China’s GDP per capita in the 1800s

hovers around 12 taels, with little increase before 1911.56 These numbers suggest that after China

had been ‘opened’ the West, each average person in the population had seen the loss of 6+% of

their small annual income.

The above calculations provide a way to start thinking about how imperialism had

impacted the ‘average person’ in China. It is worthwhile to recall Sun’s analysis here. Sun had

argued that China’s losses through payments on loans and indemnities had constituted a small

portion—under 10%—of the nation’s overall loss. Other forms of economic extraction had more

concentrated effects on certain portions of China’s population. By the late 1800s, the import of

factory-processed cotton into China had eliminated home spinning as a source of income for

peasants in areas such as Guangdong.57 The foreign demand in tea and silk—which had made up

over 90% of China’s exports in the mid-1800s—had induced large numbers of Chinese peasants

to switch from other livelihood pursuits. These peasants had lost their income after 1910, when

Chinese tea and silk could no longer compete with products from plantations and factories.58 For

China’s population, the effects of becoming integrated into the global economy had only been

growing. Japan’s invasion of China’s mainland—beginning with Manchuria in 1931—is only the

logical extension of imperialist activities that had begun one century before.

Furthermore, the impact of foreign imperialism—and need for Chinese resistance—had

been articulated in the words and actions of all sectors of Chinese society. In the words of

Wakeman: “the rural areas in which the decline of cottage industry seemed most marked were

precisely those areas which were most antiforeign. It was almost as if the peasantry rationally

blamed their plight on foreign imports.”59 Anti-foreign sentiments and organizing had been at the

55 Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, Ca. 1870-1911, 78–85. 56 Ma and de Jong, “Unfolding the Turbulent Century,” 4. 57 Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, Ca. 1870-1911, 29; Frederic Wakeman, Strangers at the Gate: Social Disorder in South China, 1839-1861 (University of California Press, 1997), 180–88. 58 Esherick, “Harvard on China: The Apologetics of Imperialism,” 11; Chi-ming. Hou, Foreign Investment and Economic Development in China, 1840-1937. (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1965). 59 Wakeman, Strangers at the Gate, 188. Also quoted in: Esherick, “Harvard on China: The Apologetics of Imperialism,” 11.

Page 52: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

46

root of both of the Taiping Rebellion (1850-1864) and the Boxer Rebellion.60 Both events had

then been used by foreign powers to increase their demands on China. Epstein finds that the

earliest and largest strikes in the pre-1949 period had been directed against foreign

administrators and enterprises.61 China’s railways—being almost entirely foreign-controlled—

had been a key locus of workers’ antagonism. Prior to being driven out cities by the GMD, the

CCP had focused on urban labour organizing. The Party had been the most active in three areas:

schools, mines, and railways.62 Perry calls the 1923 workers’ walkout on the Beijing-Hankou

line “[t]he largest Communist-directed strike of the period.”63

Whereas Marx had focused on how capitalism operated in Europe—a scene where

European capitalists had exploited workers residing largely within their nation-states—Lenin had

started to articulate the global operations of a capitalist system centered in Europe. Chinese

intellectuals and reformers, not to mention Chinese workers and peasants, had seen their own

realities and analyses articulated in the theories of Marx and Lenin. Western scholars often

express bemusement about the mismatch between socialism—a theory about workers’ struggles

against capitalism—and the social and economic context of the CCP’s activities. By 1949, China

was still largely agrarian, with around 10% of its population living in cities.64 But the seeming

existence of this mismatch is in fact the presence of a double erasure. Imperialism has been

erased from both its operations in China, and from Marxist-Leninist theories—about the global

operations of capitalism. What Marxism had offered Chinese reformers is a way to understand

and act on the foreign structures that were increasingly encasing China. Confucius and Mencius

likely had little to say on the subject. It is only by abstracting capitalism from its historical and

geographical logic—visible in processes of imperialism—that Chinese state socialism becomes

seen as an ‘odd’ project.

60 Ssu-yu Teng, Taiping Rebellion and the Western Powers: A Comprehensive Survey (Oxford University Press, 1971). 61 Israel Epstein, “Main Directions in Chinese Labor,” Science & Society 13, no. 4 (1949): 318. 62 Odoric Y. K. Wou, “The Chinese Communist Party and the Labor Movement: The May 30th Movement in Henan,” Chinese Studies in History 23, no. 1 (October 1, 1989): 85. 63 Elizabeth J. Perry, Patrolling the Revolution: Worker Militias, Citizenship, and the Modern Chinese State (Rowman & Littlefield, 2007), 37. 64 Kam Wing Chan and Xeuqiang Xu, “Urban Population Growth and Urbanization in China since 1949: Reconstructing a Baseline,” The China Quarterly, no. 104 (1985): 584; John Friedmann, China’s Urban Transition (U of Minnesota Press, 2005), 11.

Page 53: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

47

Erasing the historical context of imperialism erases the logic in Chinese reformers’ turn

to Marx analysis. As perhaps is common for thinkers, Marx had been immensely more detailed

in his analysis of capitalism than in his proposed solutions.65 Marx had also been limited by a

certain Eurocentrism (and related urban-centrism) in both his analyses and hypotheses.66 In the

twentieth century, most projects with revolutionary anti-capitalist aspirations had happened in

places outside of Marx’s field of vision.67 Even Russia had been on the periphery of Europe and

relatively ‘backwards’ in 1917. Revolutionary groups took what they could—which had been an

immense amount—from Marx’s analysis. Their subsequent paths to socialism bear traces of

what Marx had hypothesized about the post-capitalist transition process and its results. But

actually-existing (state) socialist projects had been confronted with two issues outside of Marx’s

scope. These are: (1) the need to defend against (well-funded) military aggression from core

capitalist countries, and relatedly, (2) the need to industrialize without relying on funding from

the same capitalist core. These two needs fundamentally shaped the trajectory of state socialist

projects. They overshadowed the importance of most forms of anti-capitalist praxis discussed by

Marx—and Western Marxists.

4. (Five Year) Planning for the ongoing revolution Chinese reformers had not been irrational—or detached from reality—when applying the ideas

of Marx and Lenin to understand the political and economic circumstances of early twentieth

century China. But if the CCP’s understanding of China’s circumstances had not been irrational,

then what about the actual content of the PRC’s state plans and consequent trajectories of

economic development? I stated earlier that this entire section focuses on the first of three

charges against state socialist—or centrally planned—economies: that planners had been

65 Gene Hsiao, “The Role of Economic Contracts in Communist China,” California Law Review 53, no. 4 (October 31, 1965): 1029. Groups such as the Russian Bolsheviks engaged in extensive debates about how to translate Marx’s work into a revolutionary plan. See for instance: Vladimir Ilych Lenin, What Is to Be Done? (International Publishers, 1969). 66 See, for instance, Said’s discussion of Marx: Said, Orientalism, 13–16, 153–60, 323. 67 See, for instance, discussions in: Helen Desfosses and Jacques Lévesque, Socialism in the Third World (Praeger, 1975).

Page 54: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

48

idiosyncratic and produced irrational plans. Here it may be useful to revisit the charges of

irrationality levied against the PRC’s plans and planners.

Nolan and Ash state that “China’s economic development has been uniquely, if not

consistently, influenced by [Mao’s] personal prejudices and idiosyncratic view of how to realize

the country’s development potential”.68 Party members also eschewed economic sense, instead

“insisting that “planning” provided a framework [for] resource allocation”.69 Lin et al. do not tie

the PRC’s trajectories to the alleged idiosyncratic tendencies of one person. The authors even

show that the PRC’s heavy industry-oriented development strategy had been employed by other

socialist and developing countries.70 But Lin et al. still emphasize the economic irrationality of

the PRC’s early plans, arguing that “giving priority to heavy-industry development ran counter to

China’s comparative advantage and distorted the economic structure so much that development

was slower than it could have been.”71

Based on the above descriptions, discourses about the ‘irrationality’ of the early PRC’s

planned trajectory can be broken down into three ideas. Firstly, that PRC state planning—and

consequent plans—had been tied to the “idiosyncrasies” of one person or a group of people.

Secondly, that the practice of planning itself runs counter to achieving economic efficiency. And

thirdly, that state plans in the early PRC—characterized by their focus on heavy industry—

contradicted a rational course of action. These three ideas are connected and mutually

reinforcing, though one does not—as Lin et al. show—have to partake in all three to reproduce

discourses about ‘irrational’ state planning. The first idea is easily dispelled by turning to

existing research on the CCP; I will discuss this briefly. The third idea is my main focus in the

following section: I argue for the logic of the PRC’s focus on heavy industry. The claim that it is

irrational for a developing nation to prioritize heavy industry in state economic plans seems quite

pervasive, even in research that otherwise takes seriously the development objectives of Global

South states (e.g. Lin et al.). This claim is of course produced through the bracketing of Western

68 Nolan and Ash, “China’s Economy on the Eve of Reform,” 1996, 18. 69 Ibid., 18–19. 70 Justin Yifu Lin, Fang Cai, and Zhou Li, The China Miracle: Development Strategy and Economic Reform (Chinese University Press, 2003), 60–67. 71 Ibid., 69.

Page 55: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

49

imperialism. Arguments about the PRC’s ‘irrational’ focus on heavy industry also provides

weight for the second idea above, that planning itself contradicts economic efficiency. Ideas

about Mao’s ‘idiosyncrasy’ (though perhaps somewhat widespread in the West) do not hold

much water elsewhere. That economic planning is necessarily irrational is a capitalist axiom that

can be traced back to the work of von Mises. I discuss the operations and assumptions of this

axiom at this end of this section.

An abundance of research exists suggesting that economic development trajectories in the

early PRC cannot be attributed to the ideas of one person. It is well-known that since the Yan’an

rectification movement (整风活动) of 1942, CCP decision-making had been guided by the

principle of consensus.72 The earliest split in the PRC leadership is usually traced to

disagreements over the Great Leap Forward (GLF), manifesting in the events of the 1959 Lushan

Conference.73 But even the existence of this split—thought to have isolated the left Maoists from

the rest of the CCP’s leadership—is somewhat questionable. Takahara finds that on the eve of

the GLF, CCP leaders had generally sorted into four camps on the question of how best to

incentivize higher levels of production. The most ‘left’ camp had advocated the abolishment of

unequal (graded) wages. This group included Chen Boda. More ‘right’ had been what Takahara

calls the ‘developmental leftists’, who advocated mass mobilization without abolishing the

system of wage distribution. This group had included Mao, Liu Shaoqi, and Deng Xiaoping.

More ‘right’ of this group had been the ‘central controllers’, who favoured centralization and

planned growth. This group had included Zhou Enlai, Chen Yun, and Li Fuchun. The most

‘right’ group had the smallest numbers. They were leaders in the All-China Federal Trade Union,

who had most strongly supported increasing material incentives.74 Even the GLF had been far

from Mao’s personal (or ‘idiosyncratic’) project.

72 Pat Howard, Breaking the Iron Rice Bowl: Prospects for Socialism in China’s Countryside (M.E. Sharpe, 1988); Lieberthal, “The Great Leap Forward and the Split in the Yenan Leadership”; Selden, China in Revolution, 1995. 73 Lowell Dittmer, “‘Line Struggle’ in Theory and Practice: The Origins of the Cultural Revolution Reconsidered,” The China Quarterly, no. 72 (1977): 675–712; Lieberthal, “The Great Leap Forward and the Split in the Yenan Leadership”; Roderick MacFarquhar and Michael Schoenhals, Mao’s Last Revolution (Harvard University Press, 2006). 74 Akio Takahara, The Politics of Wage Policy in Post-Revolutionary China (Springer, 1992), 44–47.

Page 56: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

50

I turn now to the logic of the PRC’s FFYP. To give a broad overview of how the FFYP

had shaped the early PRC economy, I turn to a perhaps unexpected source. A (formerly

classified) CIA economic intelligence report produced in 1959 marvels at the success of the

PRC’s FFYP. According to the report, overall output in the PRC had grown at an annual rate of

7%—a rate equal to or higher than the USSR during its FFYP.75 The author had been especially

impressed by three aspects of the PRC’s performance. Firstly, that the state had achieved its

growth rates with a smaller amount of input than the USSR; secondly, that growth had happened

without producing significant imbalances in the economy or major disruptions for the

population; and thirdly, that all of this had transpired in less than ten years after the conclusion of

the Chinese Civil War.76 In terms of overall economic growth between 1952-1978: conservative

estimates place the PRC’s annual GDP per capita growth rate in this period at around 3.6%.77

The World Bank, on the other hand, estimates that the PRC’s annual GNP per capita growth rate

in 1960-1981 had been 5%.78 The World Bank’s interval excludes the 1950s, a decade generally

thought to have produced the fastest growth rates in Mao-era China. The early PRC’s economic

growth rates marked a significant departure from China’s earlier experiences. Researchers

generally agree that China’s GDP per capita had not grown during the Republican period.79

But the above information is a non-sequitur for critics of the early PRC’s planned

economy. Economic growth in the early PRC had been quite significant, especially when placed

within the context of China’s own history. But Lin et al., for instance, seem often to prefer

abstractions to history and context. The authors are not particularly concerned with what the

planned economy had produced (other than its ‘distortions’). They are more interested in how

economic development in the early PRC had deviated from a more rational choice—that of states

pursuing their ‘comparative advantage’. Lin et al. start from the premise that the FFYP had been

75 CIA Office of Research and Reports, “Comparison of the First Five Year Plans of Communist China and the USSR,” Economic Intelligence Report (Central Intelligence Agency, June 1959), 2–10. 76 Ibid., 3–6. 77 Anton Cheremukhin et al., “The Economy of People’s Republic of China from 1953” (National Bureau of Economic Research, 2015), 12; Xiaodong Zhu, “Understanding China’s Growth: Past, Present, and Future,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 26, no. 4 (2012): 103–124. 78 World Bank, World Development Report 1983 (The World Bank, 1983), 148–49. 79 Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, 1870-1949, 1995, 98.

Page 57: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

51

dominated by its focus on heavy industry.80 The authors note that at the time of the FFYP, the

PRC had been short on funds, lacked foreign exchange, and had a low export capacity.81 The

authors also describe heavy industry, a set of processes characterized by a long construction

cycle, the need to import equipment, and the need for a large amount of initial investment.82 It

may be useful here to point out that for Lin et al., both the PRC and heavy industry have a set of

essential characteristics that are abstracted from the global and historical processes that have

produced them. According to the characteristics that the authors have ascribed, heavy industry

and the early PRC are a mismatch. PRC planners had struggled against nature, in order to

connect the incompatible: “If resources had been allocated by the market mechanism, investment

would not have flowed to heavy-industry sectors. Rather, industrialization featuring light

industry would have occurred”.83

Before proceeding further, I want to emphasize again that my disagreement is not with

Lin et al. and their work in particular. The early PRC’s ‘irrational’ focus on heavy industry is

discussed or alluded to in much of English-language writing on China.84 The work of Lin et al.

lays out—in clear and often lucid writing—several key tenets of this particular discourse. This is

an achievement that has, perhaps unfortunately, earned the authors a degree of prominence in

this chapter. Lin et al. describes how, in the struggle of early PRC planners against economic

nature, the planners had implemented a series of top-down (irrational, constraining) measures.

These included setting a fixed interest rate and exchange rate, setting low wages and prices, and

creating a nationalized system for the financial sector, industry, and agriculture.85 These

measures are by no means unique to planned economies; they also seem more correlated with the

PRC’s lack of capital rather than its investment in heavy industry per se. Regardless, for Lin et

al., these measures produced ‘distortion’ in the PRC economy, the effects of which are either

vague, do not exist aside from their presence in economic literature, or more attributable to the

early PRC’s general state of poverty. These effects included: “development was slower than it

80 Lin, Cai, and Li, The China Miracle, 2003, 30–37. 81 Ibid., 38. 82 Ibid., 36–37. 83 Ibid., 37. 84 See for instance: Naughton, The Chinese Economy, 2007; Lüthi, The Sino-Soviet Split, 2008. 85 Lin, Cai, and Li, The China Miracle, 2003, 39–59.

Page 58: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

52

could have been”, “[constrains on] the full play of comparative advantage in labour resources”,

“[fortification of] the dual structure of traditional and modern sectors”, “slow improvement in

people’s living standards”, “[suppressing of] people’s incentive to work”, and “an extremely low

economic efficiency.”86

Lin et al. argue that what the PRC should have done instead is to allow the ‘free’ and

‘rational’ circulation of capital into its light industries. This had been the economic strategy

pursued by Taiwan, Hong Kong, Singapore, and South Korea (known as the Asian Tigers or

Little Dragons), beginning in the 1960s. Taiwan and South Korea had prioritized the

development of their science and technology sectors (e.g. computers, robotics, medical

equipment, etc.), while Singapore and Hong Kong had become centers of banking and foreign

exchange.87 From 1965-1973, these economies had average annual GDP growth rates of 8-

13%.88 It is possible that the PRC could have pursued this route of economic development—

perhaps if it had been one-two hundredth of its actual geographic size, bordered a very large and

newly socialist state, and wanted to host American military forces. But I digress.

In order to in good faith engage with what Lin et al. propose—a more ‘rational’ course of

economic development in the early PRC—I take a closer look at the group of processes known

as ‘heavy industry’ and their role in the PRC’s FFYP. In his 1973 article, Teubal gave the

neoclassical economic definition of heavy vs. light industry. Heavy industry is used to describe

forms of manufacturing that are more capital intensive (e.g. ship making), while light industry

refers to forms that are more labour than capital intensive (e.g. textiles, paper-making).89

Neoclassical economics prescribes that in the course of economic development, light industry

should come before heavy industry—the former produces the accumulation of capital for the

86 Ibid., 69–70. 87 Stephan Haggard, “The Politics of Industrialization in the Republic of Korea and Taiwan,” in Achieving Industrialization in East Asia, ed. H. Hughes (Cambridge University Press, 1988), 274–75; Dariusz Wójcik, “The Dark Side of NY–LON: Financial Centres and the Global Financial Crisis,” Urban Studies 50, no. 13 (October 1, 2013): 2736–52; “Hong Kong Overtaken by Singapore as Third Leading Global Financial Centre,” South China Morning Post, April 7, 2016, http://www.scmp.com/news/hong-kong/economy/article/1934559/hong-kong-overtaken-singapore-third-leading-global-financial. 88 Lin et al. do not mention the PRC’s average annual GDP growth rate in the same period, which was higher than its average annual GDP per capita growth rate. Conservative estimates put the former around 5.6%. 89 Morris Teubal, “Heavy and Light Industry in Economic Development,” The American Economic Review 63, no. 4 (1973): 588–96.

Page 59: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

53

later.90 Historians—particularly Marxist historians—and political economists have pointed to

how large-scale European industrialization was funded by sources of surplus other than light

industry, such as accumulation by dispossession and profits from the triangular trade in sugar

and indentured labour.91

The neoclassical definition obscures how heavy and light industries function in national

and global economies. These functions become more clear when looking at how Soviet

economists—in the course of planning state industrialization—had drawn the distinction. For

Soviet planners, heavy industry produces ‘producer goods’, whereas light industry produces

consumer goods.92 In other words, the products of heavy industry form the infrastructural base

for an industrialized economy. Following Soviet conceptions, the PRC’s FFYP differentiates

between “industries manufacturing means of production” and “consumer good industries”.93

Neoclassical distinctions would encounter further challenges in the Chinese context.

Industrialization—or the development of heavy industry—in the early PRC is known to have

been particularly labour-intensive.94

The PRC’s FFYP discusses the following items in the section on heavy industry: iron and

steel, non-ferrous metals, power, coal, oil, machine-building, chemicals, building materials, and

lumber.95 In the absence of heavy industry, there would be no factories or electricity, and no

large-scale production of light industry goods. The economies of Qing and Republican China had

in fact prioritized light industry over heavy industry. What had been widespread in pre-1949

90 William Rostow, The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto (Cambridge University Press, 1990), 17–58; Teubal, “Heavy and Light Industry in Economic Development,” 588–90. 91 Michael Barratt Brown, The Economics of Imperialism (Penguin Books, 1975); Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, 2000; Eric Eustace Williams, Capitalism & Slavery (University of North Carolina Press, 1944). 92 Harry G. Shaffer, The Soviet Economy: A Collection of Western and Soviet Views (Appleton-Century-Crofts, 1969), 201–2. 93 PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957. (Beijing, China: Foreign Languages Press, 1956), 31. 94 Early PRC industrialization projects used labour to substitute for the relative lack of machines and technology. This was discussed by interviewees, and also present in the following accounts: Covell Meyskens, “Third Front Railroads and Industrial Modernity in Late Maoist China,” Twentieth-Century China 40, no. 3 (2015): 238–60; Xining Railway Bureau, 土方工程机械化半机械化施工经验 [The Experience of Mechanizing and Half-Mechanizing Earthwork Construction] (Beijing, China: 人民铁道出版社 [The People’s Railway Press], 1960). 95 PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957., 1956, 55–86.

Page 60: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

54

China—the small-scale handicraft production of manufactured goods (e.g. tea, silk, textiles)—is

the only form of light industry that exists in the absence of heavy industry. When China began to

develop ‘modern industry’ in the late nineteenth and early twentieth century, the vast majority of

these new enterprises had operated in light industry.96 China could not develop its own heavy

industry due to a lack of funds. In turn, Chinese-owned factories in light industry had been

hampered by their relative lack of access to heavy industry goods, such as fuel, machinery, and

modern transportation. Suffice it to say, the ‘free’ operations of market forces in pre-1949 China

did not direct capital flow into its light industries. Global market forces had instead caused great

destruction to these enterprises.

The more ‘economically efficient’ course that Lin et al. have in mind for the early PRC

seems to be one that follows what Rostow outlines in The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-

Communist Manifesto. For Rostow, non-industrialized economies should produce and export the

items for which they have a ‘comparative advantage’, in order to accrue the surplus needed to

industrialize.97 This is in fact the strategy that had been attempted by the Chinese state after

1842. This strategy had not produced national economic growth—it had instead left China

increasingly indebted and subject to the control of Western powers. Chinese reformers since the

Self-Strengtheners had understood that in order to resist increasing Western domination, China

needed to own and control its own industries—particularly industries such as mining, steel

production, and modern transportation. In other words, the ‘proletarian nation’ needed to have

ownership and control over its own means of production. The analysis of Chinese reformers is

also articulated by dependency theory. Vernengo states that common to dependency theorists is

the understanding that “at the core of the dependency relation between center and periphery lays

[lies] the inability of the periphery to develop an autonomous and dynamic process of

technological innovation. […] The Center countries controlled the technology and the systems

for generating technology.”98

96 Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, 1870-1949, 1995, 117. 97 Rostow, The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto, 17–25. 98 Matias Vernengo, “Technology, Finance, and Dependency: Latin American Radical Political Economy in Retrospect,” Review of Radical Political Economics 38, no. 4 (2006): 551–68.

Page 61: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

55

Many Chinese reformers had also understood that the “inability” of the periphery to

generate its own technology lies not in some intrinsic defect common to those on the periphery.

The core rather enforces this ‘inability’ through its control and use of heavy industry. The

Chinese state had not lacked capital prior to the Opium Wars. It was instead Britain that had been

concerned about the flow of silver from Europe into China. Britain—with the assistance of other

Western powers—had then engineered China’s scarcity through the use of ‘gunboat diplomacy’

(or mostly just gunboats). Consequently, the emphasis placed by the USSR and the PRC on

heavy industry is not only because heavy industry provides the backbone for industrialized

economies.

Heavy industry also produces the items needed for national defence. Lenin had been

concerned about “the imperialist states bordering on Russia to the West and the East, which

command enormous military forces”.99 These nations had sent troops to assist anti-Bolshevik

forces in the Russian Civil War (1917-1922).100 Lenin consequently urges industrialization: “All

our efforts must be exerted to the very utmost to […] bring about an economic revival, without

which a real increase in our country’s defence potential is inconceivable.”101 Mao was also quite

clear about the functions of heavy industry, stating: “The purpose of adopting a positive policy of

industrialization, that is, a policy which gives priority to the growth of heavy industry, is to

provide a material basis on which to strengthen our national defence, meet the needs of the

people, and bring about the socialist transformation of our national economy.”102

But if state industrialization relies on the development of heavy industry, and

industrialization is key to national economic growth—rather than becoming increasingly

exploited as an exporter of raw resources and light industry goods—then what about the Asian

Tiger states? How were they able to achieve high growth rates without prioritizing heavy

industry development? First of all—as can be seen from a chart that Lin et al. include—South

99 Vladimir Ilyich Lenin, “The Immediate Tasks of the Soviet Government,” in Collected Works, vol. 27 (Progress Publishers, 1972), 237–38. 100 Michael Jabara Carley, “Allied Intervention and the Russian Civil War, 1917-1922,” ed. Michael Kettle et al., The International History Review 11, no. 4 (1989): 689–700. 101 Lenin, “The Immediate Tasks of the Soviet Government,” 237–38. 102 PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957., 1956, 16.

Page 62: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

56

Korea had prioritized building heavy industry in the 1960s and 1970s.103 Heavy industry

development in Taiwan occurred in 1895-1945, under Japanese colonial rule. Japan—intending

Taiwan to be a ‘model colony’—had developed transportation and energy infrastructures on the

island.104

Secondly, since the 1950s, South Korea, Taiwan, and Hong Kong have relied almost

exclusively on imports to meet their energy needs.105 To import rather than produce its fuel was

neither practical nor feasible for the early PRC. An industrializing (or industrialized) nation of

the early PRC’s size and population has immense energy needs. In addition, the U.S. had led and

enforced a global trade embargo against the PRC, beginning in 1952 and lasting until the early

1970s.106 The U.S. had conversely assisted the international trade activities of South Korea and

Taiwan, by providing aid and fixing favourable exchange rates.107 Hong Kong and Singapore

had likewise benefited from their historical relationship with Britain.108

Finally—unlike the USSR and the PRC—the Asian Tigers had not been under military

threat from Western imperialists. The U.S. has offered military assistance to both South Korea

and Taiwan through bilateral treaties that have existed since the 1950s.109 It is perhaps not

remiss to say that the main ‘comparative advantage’ that the Asian Tiger economies had enjoyed

had been the infusion of Western capital. But could the PRC have benefited from the same

‘comparative advantage’, instead of ‘distorting’ its economy through socialist planning? Again,

103 Lin, Cai, and Li, The China Miracle, 2003, 110. 104 Japan, in contrast to European colonial powers, was also generally not adverse to developing heavy industry in its colonies. The small presence of heavy industries in pre-1949 China can largely be attributed to Japanese construction in Manchuria. Japan had needed to accrue resources and artillery for its subsequent invasion of the rest of China. See: Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, 1870-1949, 1995, 116. 105 “Singapore,” U. S. Energy Information Administration, accessed August 1, 2017, https://www.eia.gov/beta/international/analysis.cfm?iso=SGP; “South Korea,” U. S. Energy Information Administration, accessed August 1, 2017, https://www.eia.gov/beta/international/country.cfm?iso=KOR; “Taiwan,” U. S. Energy Information Administration, accessed August 1, 2017, https://www.eia.gov/beta/international/country.cfm?iso=TWN. 106 Aiguo Lu, China and the Global Economy Since 1840 (London: Palgrave Macmillan UK, 2000); Duanfang Lu, Remaking Chinese Urban Form: Modernity, Scarcity and Space, 1949-2005 (Taylor & Francis, 2006), 8–9. 107 Haggard, “The Politics of Industrialization in the Republic of Korea and Taiwan,” 267–71, 275–77. 108 Wójcik, “The Dark Side of NY–LON,” 2742; “Hong Kong Overtaken by Singapore as Third Leading Global Financial Centre.” 109 William T. Tow, Assessing US Bilateral Security Alliances in the Asia Pacific’s “Southern Rim”: Why the San Francisco System Endures (Institute for International Studies, Stanford University, 1999).

Page 63: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

57

China’s pre-1949 history suggests that the answer is no. Without the existence of the socialist

PRC, the U.S. would have had little need to produce (small) models of free market success in

Asia.

Planners in the early PRC had very logical reasons for prioritizing heavy industry

development. In contrast to what Lin et al. argue., the attention given to heavy industry in early

PRC plans also does not seem disproportionately large. When introducing the role of heavy

industry in FFYP, Lin et al. cite the statistic that investment in basic construction of heavy

industry took up 85% of the total industrial investment in basic construction.110 This number is

not contextualized by two other sets of relevant information, that (1) light industry infrastructure

accounted for almost all existing industrial infrastructure in China at the time, and that (2) the

FFYP had a number of other priorities. I will quickly address (2) first, by giving a brief overview

of the PRC’s FFYP.

To first contextualize the statistic provided by Lin et al. within the FFYP: the line item

that the authors refer to is the amount specifically earmarked for industrial capital construction.

85% of this item amounts to just under 30% of the entire FFYP’s total budget of 76,640 million

RMB.111 Industrial items in total—both heavy and light industry—accounted for 40.9% of the

FFYP’s budget. Other line items include agriculture, water conservancy, and forestry

departments (8%); transport and communications (11.7%); trade, banking, and stockpiling

departments (2.8%); cultural, educational and public health departments (18.6%); urban public

utilities (2.8%); and circulating capital for economic departments (9%).112 The FFYP is divided

into 11 chapters, of which one chapter—chapter 3—discusses industry. Heavy industry is

discussed in section III of chapter 3. Other sections of chapter 3 include light industry, local

industries, and industrial production. Other chapters of the FFYP address agriculture, transport

and communications, commerce, labour, educational, and people’s welfare. The last chapter—

chapter 11—is on “Practicing strict economy and eliminating waste”. The FFYP sets out 12

general objectives that support its overall task of socialist state construction. The first is about

110 Lin, Cai, and Li, The China Miracle, 2003, 37. 111 PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957., 1956, 27–31. 112 Ibid., 28.

Page 64: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

58

heavy industry. Objectives 2 and 3 refer to both heavy and light industry. The rest of the 12

objectives address different sectors of the economy.113

It is true that the FFYP had allocated much more funding to heavy industry when

compared to light industry. But logical reasons for this are given in the FFYP itself: “The

percentage of investments allocated to the heavy industry […] is especially high. This is so

because China must rapidly expand her heavy industrial base in order to promote an all-round

development of her national economy. It is also because our light industry, operated either by the

state or private concerns, still has considerable unused capacity while the huge productive forces

represented by our handicraft industry is also able to serve as an important auxiliary to it. It can

therefore be taken that the percentages of capital investments allocated under the FFYP to heavy

and light industry are appropriate.”114 As the FFYP here alludes to, private enterprises—with

means of funding outside of state allocations—had existed in the early PRC. The vast majority of

these had operated in light industry.

The PRC’s provisional constitution—the Common Program of 1949—had divided the

economy into five sectors: the state, cooperative, private (consisting of small private enterprises,

such as handicrafts, individual farms, etc.), capitalist (large privately-owned enterprises), and

state capitalist (joint state-private enterprises) sectors.115 Light industry made up the vast

majority of the capitalist sector in the early PRC. These are enterprises that had been established

and operated by Chinese capitalists during the Qing and Republican periods. In 1933, light

industry produced over 93% of output in the Chinese-owned portion of China’s modern

industry.116 In the 1950s, the PRC proceeded to nationalize the capitalist sector of its

economy.117 But by the end of 1956, there were still over 430,000 private industrial and

113 Ibid., 21–26. 114 Ibid., 31. 115 The Common Program and Other Documents of the First Plenary Session of the Chinese People’s Political Consultative Conference. (Beijing: Foreign Languages Press, 1950); Kuo-chün. Chao, Economic Planning and Organization in Mainland China: A Documentary Study, 1949-1957. (Cambridge, MA: East Asian Research Center, 1963). 116 Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, 1870-1949, 1995, 99. 117 Xingyuan Feng, Christer Ljungwall, and Guangwen He, The Ecology of Chinese Private Enterprises (World Scientific, 2015), 6–7; Ching Wen Kwang, The Economic Accounting System of State Enterprises in Mainland China (Committee on the Economy of China, Social Science Research Council, 1966), 63.

Page 65: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

59

commercial enterprises in the country.118 In addition, the early PRC had also inherited a sizeable

‘non-modern’ industrial sector. In 1933, handicraft methods had produced 64% of China’s output

in 14 different product groups, including lumber and wood products, transport equipment,

ceramics, textiles, clothing, food products, and paper products.119 One could perhaps even say

that in 1949, the PRC had inherited a national economy characterized by a significant ‘distortion’

towards light industry. If early PRC state planners had ‘overinvested’ in heavy industry, it is

perhaps only to correct earlier imbalances.

But in what sense did early PRC planners ‘overinvest’ in heavy industry? First of all—

what percentage of the state budget in the FFYP had in fact gone to heavy industry? Using Lin et

al.’s earlier statistic, we can assume there was a ratio of 85:15 for basic construction investment

into heavy vs. light industry. If we apply this ratio to the total amount allocated to industry in the

FFYP—31,320 million RMB or 40.9% of the total budget—it would suggest that 34.8% of funds

in the FFYP had gone to heavy industry. Is this ‘too much’ for a state to invest into heavy

industry? This is an extremely complicated question, so it is odd that Lin et al.—and the large

body of literature making similar arguments—would unequivocally say yes. Budgets of Western

states in the 1950s would have looked fundamentally different from that of the early PRC.

Western states in this period would not have budgeted for processes of national industrial

development. But as I argued previously, heavy industry development is inextricable from

processes of national defense. We can perhaps start to approach the question of heavy industry

‘overinvestment’ by looking at the national defense budgets of other states.

While not budgeting for heavy industry per se, Western states in the 1950s—and at other

times—have allocated state funds to military expenditures (e.g. production of machinery,

artillery, transportation, etc.). U.S. spending on defense made up 40-50% of its annual federal

budget in the 1950s and 1960s, and 20-30% of its annual budget in the 1970s.120 State-owned

industries in Japan had produced mainly for the navy and army after 1880.121 One set of

118 Feng, Ljungwall, and He, The Ecology of Chinese Private Enterprises, 7. 119 Feuerwerker, The Chinese Economy, 1870-1949, 1995, 110. 120 Michael E. O’Hanlon, “U.S. Defense Strategy and the Defense Budget,” Brookings, November 18, 2015, 2, https://www.brookings.edu/research/u-s-defense-strategy-and-the-defense-budget/. 121 Henry Rosovsky, Capital Formation in Japan, 1868-1940 (New York: Free Press of Glencoe, 1961), 190.

Page 66: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

60

estimates shows that between 1919 and 1923, military expenditures accounted for, on average,

43.6% of the annual state budget in Japan.122 Outside of state spending, U.S. private sector

spending on heavy industry, when compared to spending on light industry, is likely quite high.

Heavy industry products have historically dominated—and continue to dominate—U.S.

industrial output. In recent years, the petroleum, steel, automobile, and aerospace industries have

together produced more than 70% of the U.S.’s industrial output.123 These operations all fall

under heavy industry.

The PRC’s heavy industry sector is also intertwined with its defense sector. For the

FFYP, the USSR had agreed to assist the PRC with the design and construction of 156 industrial

construction projects. These projects had been budgeted for in the FFYP.124 Of the 150 projects

completed, 44 had been in the military sector.125 It is difficult to ascertain how heavy industry

and defense spending had intersected in the early PRC, though early PRC leaders had been

adamant that no single department would receive more than 30% of overall state budget.126 It is

also difficult to ascertain, for example, what proportion of total state and private funding had

gone into America’s heavy industry and defense sectors in the 1950s. In addition, the amount of

money that the two states had been working with were substantially different. The economic

circumstances of the two nations at the time had also been quite different—though these

differences had been related by their production through particular sets of global processes. But

ultimately, it seems like it would be difficult to say that state and private sector spending on

heavy industry as a proportion of total spending had been lower in the U.S. than in the PRC in

the 1950s.

122 Ibid., 189. 123 CIA, “United States of America: Industries,” in The World Factbook (Masterlab, 2015); IHS Economics, “Aerospace and Defense Economic Impact Analysis: A Report for the Aerospace Industries Association,” April 2016; American Petroleum and Institute, “Economic Impacts of the Oil and Natural Gas Industry on the US Economy in 2011,” July 2013; Kim Hill, Adam Cooper, and Debra Menk, “Contribution of the Automotive Industry to the Economies of All Fifty State and the United States,” n.d., accessed October 2, 2017; Peter Warrian, A Profile of the Steel Industry: Global Reinvention for a New Economy (Business Expert Press, 2012). 124 PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957., 1956, 38–40. 125 Lawrence C. Reardon, The Reluctant Dragon: Crisis Cycles in Chinese Foreign Economic Policy (University of Washington Press, 2015), 56; Hong Zhou, Jun Zhang, and Min Zhang, Foreign Aid in China (Springer, 2014), 80. 126 Shambaugh, “Building the Party-State in China, 1949–1965: Bringing the Soldier,” in New Perspectives on State Socialism in China, ed. Timothy Cheek and Tony Saich (Routledge, 2016), 141.

Page 67: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

61

Discussions of the ‘distortions’ caused by the PRC’s ‘overinvestment’ in heavy industry

seem to be very much an ideological discourse. The likes of Said, Butler, and Spivak have

argued convincingly that discourses are not only insidious, self-perpetuating, and resisting of

their ‘outside’. Perhaps more importantly, discourses are ‘productive’—in the sense that they

produce and reproduce political and social realities. What is achieved through discussions of

state planners and their ‘irrational’ focus on heavy industry? My tracing of how heavy industry

products have operated in national and international economies suggests that this discourse

functions to reproduce the political and economic structures of Western imperialism. Ideas about

the ‘irrationality’ of state planners and their ‘overinvestment’ in heavy industry make it difficult

to conceive that ‘Third World’ nations could develop and control their own infrastructures for

industrialization and national defense. These discourses also legitimate the Western channeling

of resources and aid into particular kinds of non-Western economic projects. In turn, the

selective channeling of resources both hides and justifies Western ideological and material

resistance to Global South industrial development.

But despite the overwhelming emphasis that critics of socialist planned economies have

placed on heavy industry—and its ‘dominating’ aspects—the crux of their issue does not concern

heavy industry per se. In Lin et al.’s account, ‘overinvestment’ in heavy industry had occurred

due to the irrationality of early PRC plans and planners. Socialist state planners’ focus on heavy

industry had been irrational because the practice of planning is itself irrational. For authors

sharing the set of discourses with Lin et al., it is likely that any planned route of economic

development pursued by the PRC would have been dissected and interrogated for its inherent

‘irrationality’. The fundamental sin of state socialism is its basic practice of planning; the

ultimate form of irrationality is daring to plan for a different world than what exists. In closing

this chapter, I examine the discourse of ‘irrational’ planners in its Platonic form, separated from

its incoherent attachment onto the realities of the early PRC. The earliest invocation of this

discourse is in the work of Ludwig von Mises. But before proceeding to Mises, I first wrap up

my discussion of the PRC’s FFYP.

If actually judging by the rubrics of economic efficiency—maximizing output for a given

set of input—and the application of reason to plan development and implementation, the PRC’s

FFYP had done remarkably well. It is known that the leaders of the PRC had themselves

considered the FFYP to be a great success. The targets set by the plan in areas such as industry,

Page 68: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

62

agriculture, transportation, education, etc. had been considered “fulfilled or overfulfilled” by the

end of the plan.127 During the period of the FFYP, the PRC’s railway network had grown by

6439 km.128 3,284 km of trunk line expansion had been planned, while 4,861 km had been

constructed.129 This constituted overfulfillment of the trunk line expansion plan by 48%. Railway

track expansion during the FFYP reached 69% of the total distance added during China’s

Republican period.130 The 3825 km of foreign-funded railways constructed during China’s Qing

period costed the equivalent of 153,270 USD/km, while tracks constructed during the FFYP—

almost doubling the earlier length in one-third of the time—costed the equivalent of 146,880

USD/km.131

Audiences outside of the PRC had agreed that the PRC had achieved well-rounded

national economic development through the FFYP.132 It is also somewhat illuminating to

compare PRC state spending during the FFYP to U.S. state spending in the 1950s. Annual

spending during the PRC’s FFYP was equivalent to 6.1 billion USD per year, while the federal

expenditure of the U.S. government had been 444 billion USD in 1955. Again, much of

economic spending in the U.S. would have happened outside of its state budget. Conservative

estimates of average annual GDP per capita growth for the PRC during the entire Mao-era is

3.6%; the average annual GDP per capita growth in the U.S. in 1950-1960 had been 1.6%.133

127 Robert R. Bowie and John K. Fairbank, Communist China 1955-1959: Policy Documents with Analysis (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1962), 305–8; PRC State Statistics Bureau, Ten Great Year: Statistics of the Economic and Cultural Achievements of the People’s Republic of China (Beijing: Foreign Languages Press, 1960). 128 Leung, China, Railway Patterns and National Goals, 1980, 101; Song, 中国铁路建设史 [The construction history of Chinese railways], 288–91. 129 PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957., 1956, 145; Leung, China, Railway Patterns and National Goals, 1980, 101. 130 Leung, China, Railway Patterns and National Goals, 1980, 72–73, 101. 131 Adjusted for inflation to 1955 USD value equivalents. Data on the distance and cost of Qing era railway construction are from: Lee, China’s Quest for Railway Autonomy, 1904-1911, 1977, 13, 19. Data on distance and cost of FFYP railway construction are from: Leung, China, Railway Patterns and National Goals, 1980, 91–103; PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957., 1956, 139. 132 CIA Office of Research and Reports, “Comparison of the First Five Year Plans of Communist China and the USSR,” June 1959; Lardy, “Economic Recovery and the 1st Five-Year Plan.” 133 Lars Anell and Birgitta Nygren, The Developing Countries and the World Economic Order (Bloomsbury Publishing, 2013), 47.

Page 69: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

63

This is of course not to say that mistakes—even substantial ones—had not been made in

the course of developing and implementing the FFYP. The PRC’s leaders themselves had

discussed certain mistakes in public. Zhou Enlai had reported to the Fourth Session of the

National People’s Congress in June 1957 that “in the second and third quarters of 1956 we began

to discover the tense situation in the supply of certain materials resulting from excessive

investment in capital construction. We adopted certain remedial measures and prevented

continued development of the tension in supply.”134 State planners had also acknowledged their

limitations in the FFYP itself, stating: “Since our original productive forces were so weak, it is

inevitable that we should come up against difficulties in carrying out our large-scale construction

in the FFYP period. […] Because of our technical backwards in the past, we must be ready to

cope with any difficulties arising from shortages of technical personnel or supplies of equipment

lagging behind the needs of construction. […] At the same time, our lack of experience in

planning and the incompleteness of our statistical data are bound to affect the accuracy of our

plans.”135

5. ‘Irrational’ planners—or their irrational critics? Any genuine discussion of the economic efficiency of state-planned vs. market-driven

development would need to take into consideration the historical and material contexts of

socialist state planning, as well as how such contexts shaped the trajectories of planned economic

development. But discussions of ‘irrational planning’, when subject to analysis—either against

their internal logic or against external data—show a cavalier concern with actual economic

efficiency. These accounts rather proceed from the assumption that state planning is, by its very

nature, inefficient. This line of thinking can be traced back to the work of Ludwig von Mises.

Writings on the advantages of free market capitalism (e.g. its ‘invisible hand’) pre-dated

Mises. But Mises, writing a half-century after Marx, is known to be the first to question the

134 Bowie and Fairbank, Communist China 1955-1959, 307. 135 PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957, 1956, 18–19.

Page 70: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

64

economic operations of the Marxist project. In his 1920 article—Economic Calculation in the

Socialist Commonwealth—Mises argued that socialism, the project of collective ownership, is

not economically feasible. For Mises, monetary calculation is only possible given a system of

private ownership. In this system, every man decides for himself what he values and what he is

accordingly willing to pay for each consumer good. Every man also takes stock of his

preferences, time, and the resources, and decides accordingly what to produce. The market

amalgamates individual choices, producing prices.136 For Mises, a system of collective

ownership means that people will no longer be able to make individual choices. Without

individual choice, the price system cannot exist. Without prices, there is no way of coordinating

consumption and production in society. One group of people would have to decide for the rest of

the population what they will consume and produce. But it is impossible for the decision-makers

to know and coordinate between the individual preferences of all people.137 Therefore, socialism

is economically irrational—and moreover, actually impossible.138

Mises expanded his argument in the book Socialism: An Economic and Sociological

Analysis, first published in 1922. Mises revised this book several times before the most widely

available English translation was published in 1951. One important implication of Mises’s

original article is that the fledgling project of Russian socialism would soon crumble.139 But

Russian socialism did not crumble. Socialism—or at least one form of it—was actually possible.

Between 1920 and 1951, the USSR had also proceeded to establish a new economic system

founded on collective ownership. This system is of course the centrally planned economy.

Confronted with the existence of the USSR, the rational course of action would have been for

Mises to rethink his original argument. But Mises instead doubled down on his earlier

convictions.

Before proceeding to how Mises understood Soviet socialism, it is worthwhile to pause

and revisit certain assumptions in his original argument. Mises imagined that if more than one

136 Ludwig von Mises, “Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth,” in Collectivist Economic Planning: Critical Studies on the Possibilities of Socialism, ed. Frederich Hayek (Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1967), 95–109. 137 Ibid., 116–22. 138 Ibid., 107–10, 128–30. 139 Ibid., 122–30.

Page 71: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

65

person had claims to an item—producing shared, or collective, ownership—then it would either

be impossible to determine the value of that item (and related processes), or one person would

necessarily dominate over others in determining its price. In the world outside of Mises’s

imagination, many items are shared—even in Western society—despite private ownership. A

small list includes houses, land, the air, etc. Given forms of shared ownership in the West, the

logical conclusions are (1) that Mises was wrong: items can have specific value even given

shared ownership; or (2) that specific values in the West are created through one person

dominating over others. In both cases, Mises would be wrong in his conception of capitalism—it

would not be a system of free and equal exchange between individuals. It is also quite likely that

both scenarios had—and do still—exist within the broader system of Western capitalism.140

Confronted with the continued existence of the USSR, Mises merely extended his

original argument. If collective ownership did in fact exist in the USSR, then its economy must

operate through a minority making decisions for the majority: in other words, through

domination. In 1951, Mises says of socialism: “The Socialist Community is a great authoritarian

association in which orders are issued and obeyed. This is what is implied by the words ‘planned

economy’ and ‘abolition of the anarchy of production’.” Mises adds that “It would be waste of

time to describe such conditions. They are the common knowledge of every citizen of a

bureaucratic state.”141 Mises also extended his earlier assertions about the ‘irrationality’ of

socialism. In Mises’s 1920 text, he used the concept of ‘irrationality’ to index the very

impossibility of socialism. Facing the actual-existence of state socialism, Mises, rather than

retiring the term, proceeds to paint the entire enterprise of planning as ‘irrational’. The concept

of planning had largely been absent in Mises’s original article, aside from his comment that it is

impossible to plan economic undertakings without the use of prices.142 By 1951, Mises had

evolved an entire argument about how planning contradicts nature. He says: “to seek to organize

society is just as crazy as it would be to tear a living plant to bits in order to make a new one out

140 See for instance discussions in: Catherine Gibson and Julie Graham, The End of Capitalism (as We Knew It) (Oxford: Blackwell, 1996). 141 Mises, Socialism, 1951, 185. 142 Mises, “Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth,” 107–8.

Page 72: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

66

of the dead parts. An organization of mankind can only be conceived after the living social

organism has been killed. The collectivist movements are therefore fore-doomed to failure.”143

For Mises at first, socialism had only been ‘irrational’. In his later accounts, both

socialism and planning became characterized as ‘irrational’ and moreover, despotic. Why was

Mises so attached to his ideas about ‘irrational’ socialism? Suffice it to say, Misesean

understandings of socialism and planning have little to do with the actually-existing operations

of socialist projects. Trouillot has argued that Western imaginations of the ‘other’ are in fact

Western projections of the ‘dark side’ of its self-image—or the ideas that the West has rejected

about itself.144 The making and imposing of decisions by one group onto the rest of the

population—that Mises attributes to socialism and planning—is by and large how capitalism

works. To make China into an opium market involved an immense amount of planning and

coordination. British officials and merchants had to first create a consumer base in China, then

incentivize and enforce the production of opium in India, and then engage in a complicated

system of auctions and smuggling in order to get the product into China, where it had been

banned.145 The relationships of domination and exploitation within capitalism are obfuscated by

the very discourses that Mises draws on—about the ‘natural’ operations of society. The market,

featuring prominently in Misesean narratives, is where decisions made by powerful parties

become de-personalized and abstracted. Mediation via the market makes it possible for

individuals to experience the operations of power as the aggregate force exerted by ‘equal’

individuals engaging in ‘free’ exchange.

The Misesean discourse only begins to make sense when placed within what Marx—and

others, including Chinese peasants—had understood about the operations of capitalism. Read on

their own, the texts of Mises and those who share his ideas are filled with assumptions, internal

contradictions, and ellipses. On the actual operations of state socialism, Mises largely stands by

what I quoted from him earlier: “It would be a waste of time to describe these conditions”. What

143 Mises, Socialism, 1951, 296–97. 144 Michel-Rolph Trouillot, Global Transformations: Anthropology and the Modern World (Palgrave Macmillan, 2003), 6–28. 145 Diana L. Ahmad, The Opium Debate and Chinese Exclusion Laws in the Nineteenth-Century American West (University of Nevada Press, 2007), 19–22; Amitav Ghosh, Opium financed British rule in India, June 23, 2008.

Page 73: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

67

emerges from the Misesean account is that socialist planning is ‘irrational’ and ‘despotic’

because they contravene the ‘natural’ course of the world. The natural course that Mises had in

mind is of course capitalism. But there is nothing particularly ‘natural’ about capitalism—a fact

that becomes abundantly clear when studying the course and impact of imperialism on

nineteenth and twentieth century China.

How Mises analyzes socialism and planning becomes increasingly incoherent in later

editions of Socialism. At the same time, the elements driving his analysis become increasingly

visible. In the 1951 edition, Mises offered the following: “The incomparable success of Marxism

is due to the prospect it offers of fulfilling those dream aspirations and dreams of vengeance

which have been so deeply embedded in the human soul from time immemorial.”146 For 1981

version, published posthumously, Mises added: “in Asia [socialism] is the banner around which

the antagonists of European civilization gather. If the intellectual dominance of Socialism

remains unshaken, then in a short time the whole cooperative system of culture which Europe

has built up during thousands of years will be shattered.”147 In the aftermath of all the hoopla

about superior markets, irrationality, and despotism—the stakes finally start to emerge.

6. Conclusion The Misesean discourse has persisted. The burying of imperialism continues to shape

contemporary discussions about the early PRC’s planned economy. In the first part of this

chapter, I discussed the erasure of imperialism from contemporary Western writing on China. I

proceeded to trace some elements of this excluded history. I then argued that imperialism and its

impact on China had been a key reason for why early twentieth century Chinese reformers turned

to socialism. This context also played a crucial role in shaping the early PRC’s course of planned

industrial development. It is unsurprising that when imperialism is excluded from accounts of

early PRC development, the remaining events lose their coherence. In the second part of this

chapter, I followed the logic of two sets of texts: the PRC’s early plans for state economic

146 Mises, Socialism, 1951, 17. 147 Ludwig von Mises, Socialism (Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Classics, 1981), 511.

Page 74: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

68

development (namely the FFYP), and discussions of the ‘irrationality’ of these plans. I have

been—and am still—curious about the ways in which state socialism did not work, or fell short

of what had been envisioned. This kind of research is crucial, I think, for any project of

envisioning a better world than the one that currently exists. I had thought that some answers

might be found in discussions of the drawbacks of state economic planning. But as it turns out,

most Western accounts on the subject have little to do with the actual processes and outcomes of

socialist planning. These works show little concern with actual economic efficiency. Their basic

assumptions and premises can in fact be traced back to a set of most irrational discussions—

those of Ludwig von Mises.

What is at the heart of Mises’s discussions is not a rational argument about systems of

economic (or really, social) organization and their relative efficiencies. The crux of the matter

(‘heart of darkness’) is rather his conviction that resources cannot be shared, and that planning

will lead to a reverse of existing historical trends, thereby producing others’ domination over

him. In arguing that this set of convictions is at the center of discourses about ‘irrational’

socialism, I am certainly not suggesting that all authors in the genre—or even Mises—wish to

reproduce and sustain imperialism. I am sure that if the question were asked point-blank, many

authors would say no—and mean it. However, texts in the ‘irrational’ socialism genre build on

knowledge structures that are rooted in the protection and reproduction of imperialist capitalism.

What these works consequently (re)produce is the naturalization of capitalism and the

obfuscating of any other possibilities, rather than any actual understanding of state socialist

projects.

The above state of affairs is extremely disappointing for people—like myself—who want

to learn about the operations of socialist planned economies, and learn from rational assessments

of these systems. The objective for my thesis was—and is—to learn about railway development

in the early PRC and its relationship to the operations of a planned economy. But the existing

English-language canon on socialist states and their economic development has made it

impossible for me to directly approach my subject. It has rather been necessarily to first grapple

with layers of assumptions and misdirects. Having done some of this ‘unpeeling’, I turn, in the

next chapter, to the early PRC railways. In Chapter 3 I begin by investigating the forming of the

early PRC railway system. I then bring together the railways and the planned economy in

Page 75: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

69

Chapter 4: I discuss a particular set of changes—or developments—that central planning had

brought about in the railway sector.

The currently concluding chapter revolved around questioning the first of three sets of

ideas about ‘irrational’ socialism: that (1) planners had been idiosyncratic and produced

irrational plans. The second and third set of ideas are as follows: that (2) resource allocation had

been inefficient due to the absence of economic mechanisms; and that (3) economic planning

produces the waste of resources, materials, and labour. While contesting the notion of ‘irrational’

planners, I have shown that the entire discourse about ‘irrational’ socialism have little to do with

the operations of actually-existing state socialist projects. In Chapters 3 and 4, I delve into the

actual operations of state socialism. I discuss in Chapter 4 relationships of state economic

planning to resource allocations, marks, and waste in the early PRC. Perhaps not surprisingly,

these relationships—shaped particularly by the historical and ongoing contexts of Western

imperialism—are not exactly what is assumed in discussions of ‘irrational’ socialism.

Page 76: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

70

Chapter III. The bridge: The PRC railway sector in formation

1. Introduction This chapter offers somewhat of a break from the main argument of the thesis. The main

argument addresses the Western discourse about ‘irrational’ socialism. I have previously argued

that this discourse contains three sets of ideas: that (1) planners had been idiosyncratic and

produced irrational plans; that (2) resource allocation had been inefficient due to the absence of

economic mechanisms; and that (3) economic planning produces the waste of resources,

materials, and labour. The previous chapter—Chapter 2—specifically addressed the first set of

ideas. While addressing ideas about ‘irrational’ plans, I argued that the entire discourse of

‘irrational’ socialism has little to do with actual events and processes in historically-existing

socialist states. This discourse rather revolves around the reproduction of what it rhetorically

excludes—the operations of Western imperialism.

In order to begin approaching early PRC developments on their own terms, I had to first

engage in the above-described process of discursive unpeeling. It has been important for me to

understand how early PRC developments are most often narrated in the English-language

literature and why—in order to take what is relevant from these accounts and discard the rest.

This chapter and the next move away from discourses and towards events on the ground. This

chapter traces the formation of the early PRC railway sector. I first sketch out the very

beginnings of the Chinese railway system, from its origins to what existed in the early twentieth

century. I then describe components of the early PRC railway system and their process of

coming together. The early PRC railway system incorporated infrastructures and systems

inherited from Republican China, the CCP’s history of labour activism and war-time

experiences, and a period of learning from Soviet railway operations. Interactions between the

USSR, GMD, and CCP also compelled the Chinese Communists to innovate a new approach to

projects of industrialization, encapsulated in the idea of the ‘People’s Railway’.

Page 77: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

71

I stated earlier that this chapter steps away from the main argument of my thesis. In this

chapter, I do not explicitly address ideas about ‘irrational’ socialism. Some events that I detail—

such as the CCP’s thrifty operation of railways in China’s Northeast during the Civil War—do

provide evidence against assumptions about ‘irrational’ socialism. These details will be picked

up again in Chapter 4, which discusses the mechanisms of early PRC state planning and their

implementation in the state railway sector. Chapter 4 uses ‘on the ground’ evidence from the

PRC—and especially its railway sector—to challenge the second and third sets of ideas about

‘irrational’ socialism, which revolve around its alleged lack of economic mechanisms, inefficient

resource allocation, and corresponding waste. This current chapter forms the context and

background for understanding the events discussed in Chapter 4. The context that is provided

here pertains to both China’s railway system and its immediate pre-PRC history. The two

items—railways and history—are closely intertwined, at least in the Chinese context.

While this chapter provides the backdrop for an argument about state socialist efficiency,

it also starts to set up another direction of discussion. I start to probe at the question of what

made Chinese socialism distinct from its Soviet counterpart. This discussion also required a prior

step—of establishing the context and contours of imperialist discourses. These discourses like to

conflate all projects of socialism.1 Even worse, imperialist discourses will take the comparison of

socialist projects out of context, and read discussions of differences as condemnations of this or

that project (e.g. Soviet socialism oppressed workers; Chinese socialism was erratic). The

condemnation of either the Soviet or the Chinese project is not what I have in mind. Rather, I am

interested in pointing out the Third World and populist character of Chinese socialism. These

characteristics set up Chinese socialism in a slightly different relationship to the question of

economic efficiency, when compared to Soviet socialism. These differences also have

implications for how people were incorporated into—and mattered to—projects of state

socialism.

The current chapter consequently sets up for a two-pronged argument in the next. Chapter

4 both contests imperialist discourses about ‘irrational’ socialism, and turns to the internal

1 See for instance: Thomas L. Friedman, The World Is Flat 3.0: A Brief History of the Twenty-First Century (New York: Macmillan, 2007), 47–52; Mises, Socialism, 1951, 16–24.

Page 78: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

72

dynamics of the early PRC project. One question that emerges in Chapter 4 is how the state

socialist pursuit—and achievement—of efficiency shaped the PRC’s national subjects. But first,

I trace the formation of the early PRC railway sector in the upcoming pages.

2. Chinese railways: Early histories Though Chinese inventors had experimented with steam-powered vehicles in as early as 1681, it

was the Great Power states who had begun to construct railways in China during the late Qing

period.2 Therefore, the history of railways in China begins elsewhere. The advent of the railway

is inseparable from the events of the British Industrial Revolution. In the late 1700s, the

expansion of cotton and coal industries in Britain beget the desire for a more reliable method of

transporting large volumes over long distances.3 Decades of experimentation gave rise to the

modern railway, defined as carriages pulled exclusively by steam-powered locomotives. The first

modern railway connected Liverpool and Manchester.4 Its opening on September 1830 ushered

in the Railway Age.

If the modern railway was called into existence by the Industrial Revolution, it in turn

spurred the economic developments of the times. The modern railway cemented key aspects of

the relations of production under industrial capitalism. The need for reliable long-distance

transport arose from a spatial division of labour; railway transportation in turn increased the

profits to be made through this division. In the late 1700s, merchants in the port city of Liverpool

turned to importing cotton.5 Britain’s first cotton mills sprung up concurrently, clustering around

the inland city of Manchester. The early Manchester mills made use of water wheels powered by

nearby rivers and streams. An important function of the Liverpool and Manchester Railway was

2 Burgess Wise 1974 in Smith, Privatized Infrastructure, 17; Kenneth Pomeranz, The Great Divergence: Europe, China, and the Making of the Modern World Economy (Princeton University Press, 2000), 61–62. 3 Bagwell, The Transport Revolution, 76–80; Pomeranz, The Great Divergence, 2000, 60–61. 4 Bagwell, The Transport Revolution, 80; Michael Robbins, The Railway Age (Manchester University Press, 1998), 10; Smith, Privatized Infrastructure, 20; Eric Eustace Williams, Capitalism & Slavery (University of North Carolina Press, 1944), 105. 5 Mike Williams and D. A. Farnie, Cotton Mills in Greater Manchester (Carnegie, 1992), 162.

Page 79: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

73

to haul cotton between the two cities.6 After the L&M Railway began operating, the number of

mills in Manchester peaked at 108 in the year 1853. Manchester became the world’s largest and

most profitable textile production centre and remained so for decades after.7

British merchants were no less busy outside of Britain. Much of British cotton production

in fact took place through a transnational triangular trade. British manufactured goods (e.g.

clothes) were first exchanged for slaves in Africa; slaves were then exchanged for raw goods

(e.g. cotton fibre) in British colonies of the ‘New World’.8 These raw goods were finally

transported to Britain, to be received at ports such as Liverpool. Starting in the late 1700s, British

merchants devised another triangular trade route. This new trade operated between Britain, its

colonies in Asia, and China. Nearby-grown opium flowed into China, while silver flowed out.9

In 1839, the Chinese state acted to stop the opium trade by seizing 20,000 chests (almost 3

million pounds) of opium from foreign traders.10 Britain reacted to this seizure by sending

warships. The products of British industrialization secured victory for their homeland in 1842.

Chinese defeat opened the state to the operations of Western imperialism.

The next question became how to leverage Europe’s new access for increasing profit. I

discuss the economic operations of imperialism and their impacts on China in Chapter 2. The

focus in this section is on how Chinese railways have been produced through the operations of

transnational history. Smith writes that starting in 1845, British merchants agitated for railway

development in China in order to, in his words, “change the Chinese economy and thus to enable

them to exploit the Chinese market”.11 In 1858, MacDonald Stephenson, who had recently

completed a railway in British-occupied India, presented his plan of an east-west system linking

China with India and Burma.12 Broomhall suggests that Stephenson formulated his route—and

6 W. T. Jackman, The Development of Transportation in Modern England (Cambridge University Press, 2014), 510–18. 7 Williams and Farnie, Cotton Mills in Greater Manchester, 13–15. 8 Williams, Capitalism & Slavery, 1944, 5–29; Barratt-Brown, The Economics of Imperialism, 73–126. 9 David Scott, China and the International System, 1840-1949: Power, Presence, and Perceptions in a Century of Humiliation (SUNY Press, 2008), 13–23; Ghosh, Opium financed British rule in India. 10 Spence, The Search for Modern China, 152. 11 Smith, Privatized Infrastructure, 45. 12 Leung, China, Railway Patterns and National Goals, 1980, 19; Smith, Privatized Infrastructure, 44–47.

Page 80: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

74

received approval from the British Crown—based on a plan to capitalize and expand on the

existing opium trade.13 After railways were invented, they were often used by Western powers to

expand and secure their control over dominated territories.14 Davis, Wilburn and Robinson write

about these events in an edited volume; the authors call the process one of “railway

imperialism”.15

In the mid-1800s, Chinese officials had largely rejected the idea of railways. Railway

plans were viewed as a bid to increase foreign control.16 China experienced a series of defeats in

the decades after 1842. Starting in the 1880s, a group of Chinese reformers—known as the Self-

Strengtheners—advocated domestic construction and ownership of railways, for key purposes of

consolidating the nation and strengthening its defense.17 The reformers’ ideas gained traction

with the Qing court. Their attempts at construction were however frustrated by difficulties in

raising capital.18 Prior to the First Sino-Japanese War (1894-95), only 408 km of railways had

been built in China.19 China’s defeat in the First Sino-Japanese war sparked a period of intense

competition among the Great Powers for additional concessions, including railway rights. This

was the great colonial ‘scramble’ to partition China.

In order to build railways, the Great Powers each pressed upon the Qing government a

series of loans. The initial loan agreements gave the foreign parties a great deal of control over

railways in China. Lending bodies determined how much railway construction would cost.20 The

railways were to be built by foreign engineers; their operations supervised by foreign managers.

13 Broomhall 1988 in Smith, Privatized Infrastructure, 49–50. 14 Davis, “Railway Imperialism in China, 1895-1939”; Jamie Monson, Africa’s Freedom Railway: How a Chinese Development Project Changed Lives and Livelihoods in Tanzania (Indiana University Press, 2009), 17; Rousseau, “An Imperial Railway Failure.” 15 Clarence B. Davis, Kenneth E. Wilburn, and Ronald. Robinson, eds., Railway Imperialism (New York: Greenwood Press, 1991). 16 Hsu, Railway Problems in China, 20; Leung, China, Railway Patterns and National Goals, 1980, 22; Zhang, “浅谈中国铁路发展 [An Overview of Chinese Railway Development],” 2. 17 Leung, China, Railway Patterns and National Goals, 1980, 20–25; Spence, The Search for Modern China, 640. 18 Lee, China’s Quest for Railway Autonomy, 1904-1911, 1977, 13. 19 Ibid. 20 “Imperial Peking-Kalgan Railway,” The Far-Eastern Review VI, no. 6 (November 1909): 320–30; Miners, “Building The Kowloon-Canton-Hankow Railway,” 2006; George Bronson Rea, “Railway Loan Agreements and Their Relation to the Open Door,” The Far-Eastern Review VI, no. 6 (November 1909): 215–27; Stringer, “Railway Economics for China,” 58–68.

Page 81: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

75

Materials and equipment were to be purchased from the lending country. Purchases were

accompanied by commission rates of at least 5%, with additional fees charged for currency

conversion and remittance.21 As for the loans themselves, Lee says that the Chinese side had

been “exploited heavily”.22 The Chinese state—the borrowing body—had generally received

90% of the loans’ face value, and had been responsible for repayment on the entire amount. The

annual interest rate was 5%. The creditors also claimed an additional 20% of the net profit of the

railways. The loans were usually for a duration between 30 to 50 years.23 By 1928, most of the

initial railway loans had been in default.24 Foreign-initiated railway lines had been built with

foreign interests in mind. Local economic needs—and the profitable use of China’s railways by

its populations—had received little consideration.25

In the early 1900s, almost all of China’s railway system was under foreign control either

directly, or via loans and their conditions.26 The Russians had been responsible for the

construction of the China Eastern Railway in China’s North and assumed control over its initial

operations. Beginning with the Russo-Japanese War (1904-1905), Russia and Japan vied over

control of railway lines in China’s North. In the area south of the Great Wall, the Germans had

control over the Qingdao-Jinan Railway in Shandong Province; the French had control over the

Yunnan-Vietnam Railway in China’s southwest; the British had control over the Kowloon-

Canton Railway in China’s south, the Shanghai-Nanjing Railway and the Shanghai-Hangzhou

Railway in China’s east; control over the Tianjin-Pukou Railway had been split between the

British and the Germans; the Americans had control over the Chaozhou-Qinzhou line in China’s

south.27

21 “Imperial Peking-Kalgan Railway,” 328; Rea, “Railway Loan Agreements and Their Relation to the Open Door,” 218. 22 Lee, China’s Quest for Railway Autonomy, 1904-1911, 1977, 24. 23 Ibid., 24–25; Rea, “Railway Loan Agreements and Their Relation to the Open Door,” 215. 24 Chang, China’s Struggle for Railroad Development, 1943, 91–95. 25 Miners, “Building The Kowloon-Canton-Hankow Railway,” 2006; Rousseau, “An Imperial Railway Failure.” 26 Leung, China, Railway Patterns and National Goals, 1980, 35. 27 Chang, China’s Struggle for Railroad Development, 1943, 170–72; Stephen Kotkin, “Preface,” in Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China: An International History, ed. Bruce Elleman and Stephen Kotkin (M. E. Sharpe, 2015), xii–xvi; Jin, 铁路史话 [A brief history of Chinese railways]; Stringer, The Chinese Railway System, 1–106; Zhang, “浅谈中国铁路发展 [An Overview of Chinese Railway Development].”

Page 82: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

76

Foreign ownership of railways in China sparked the Railway Rights Recovery Movement

of the early 1900s. Several provinces attempted to gain rights to the railways in their territories;

some met with a degree of success.28 In the same period, provincial governments and Chinese

merchants had also funded and constructed a small number of railway lines. By 1910, some 9000

km of main line and 560 km of branch line existed in China.29 The Qing government decided to

nationalize regional railway lines in 1911, in order to centralize planning and speed up the

development of national networks. But as this process of nationalization was underway, the

Chinese state faced pressure to settle increasingly escalating amounts of foreign debt.30 The

government consequently entered into more loan agreements with foreign powers, thereby

conceding more railway rights.31 The loss of railway rights at the very moment that these lines

were being nationalized led to widespread protests in China. These protests culminated in the

Xinhai Revolution of 1911, which toppled the Qing government. With the closing of the Xinhai

Revolution, Sun Yat-sen declared—in January 1912—the founding of the Republic of China.

3. Chinese railways: The PRC system in formation The operations of earlier histories had bestowed a physical legacy. In 1949, mainland China had

over 22,000 km of railway tracks.32 Historical events had also produced other aspects of the

Chinese railway system, such as issues with capital shortage and decentralized management.

These problems first greeted the railway administrators of Republican China (1912-1948). The

PRC inherited these issues and some early solutions. The CCP first approached China’s railway

system through organizing workers in the 1920s. During the Chinese Civil War, the PLA’s

Northeast Field Army developed a close symbiotic relationship with railway lines and workers in

China’s Northeast. Histories of activism and resistance left important imprints on China’s post-

28 Lee, China’s Quest for Railway Autonomy, 1904-1911, 1977, 20–56. 29 Leung, China, Railway Patterns and National Goals, 1980, 40. 30 Spence, The Search for Modern China, 345; Wang, China’s Unequal Treaties, 65–70. 31 Lee, China’s Quest for Railway Autonomy, 1904-1911, 1977, 251–60; Wang, China’s Unequal Treaties, 65–70.

32 Leung, Chi-Keung. China, Railway Patterns and National Goals. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1980.; Zhang, 来仪. “论新民主主义经济核算制度.” 厦门大学学报(财经版), no. 01 (1952): 59–64.

Page 83: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

77

1949 railway system. Finally, the Russian government had controlled a set of railways—the

China Eastern Railway (CER, or Zhongchang Railway)—in China’s Northeast since 1897. The

CER came under joint Sino-Soviet management for a period before it was handed back to the

PRC in 1952. The Zhongchang Railway became a ‘model railway’ in the early PRC system,

passing on aspects of its operations and management to other railway enterprises.

3.1 Tracks from the Republic In the 1911 Xinhai Revolution that led to the downfall of the Qing empire, the Beiyang Army led

by Yuan Shikai had emerged as the most powerful entity in China. Sun Yat-sen declared the

establishment of the Republic of China on January 1, 1912. To secure the support of the Beiyang

Army for the new state, Sun named Yuan as President of the Republic in March 1912. When

Yuan died in 1916, the Beiyang Army split into a number of cliques. Each clique subsequently

vied for control of the government. Beginning in 1926, the GMD led by Chiang Kai-shek

embarked on a series of military campaigns against the Beiyang warlords. In 1928, the GMD

emerged as the victorious governing party of the re-united Chinese Republic. Under GMD

leadership, the Chinese government brought a degree of centralization and order to the nation.

This period, known as the Nanjing Decade (1928-1937), ended with the outbreak of the Second

Sino-Japanese War in 1937. GMD governance of the Chinese state formed an important

precursor for later project of CCP central governance.

The Nationalist government established China’s first Ministry of Railways in 1928.33

Chang Kia-Ngau, who had gained prominence through his activities in China’s banking industry,

became the Minister of Railways in 1935. Chang had been forced out from his position by the

encroaching Japanese invasion in 1942. In the decade in between, Chang had focused his efforts

on reforming and consolidating the financial and administrative system of Chinese railways.

Upon taking his post, the most pressing issue that Chang had faced was one of cash flow. Much

of China’s railway debt had fallen into arrears. Foreign-initiated railway lines had been built with

33 Yang, 中国近代铁路史 [History of Chinese Railways in the Modern Period], 130–35. Railway-related matters had previously fallen under the purview of the Ministry of Communications in the Beiyang and late Qing governments.

Page 84: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

78

foreign interests in mind. Local economic needs—and the profitable use of China’s railways by

its populations—had received little consideration.34 To resume borrowing from foreign sources,

Chang had rehabilitated over 260 million USD of railway debt in 1935.35 Chang had then

negotiated an additional 157 million USD in loans by 1937.36

Chang had also been faced with disorganization in railway management and operations.

The new Ministry had assumed supervisory powers over most railway lines in Republican China.

But due to their financial histories, each railway line had to be administered separately,

regardless of its length or volume of traffic.37 Each loan agreement had come with its own set of

conditions and restrictions, on items such as how the funded line was to be administered and how

profit was to be calculated and remitted.38 To fulfill the terms of borrowing, each railway line

had to carefully track its own income and outflow, which imposed barriers for transporting items

across more than one railway line. In addition, each railway line had been constructed and

operated according to standard procedures in its crediting nation. Nearly all aspects of railway

operations—equipment, procedures, prices, communication systems, etc.—differed from one

line to another.39

The lack of standardization in China’s railway system had added greatly to the costs of

operation and administration. Each railway had operated with its own specialized personnel,

procedures, and facilities. Rosenberg observes that in 1909, China’s railways had made use of 40

categories of cars when 6 standardized categories would have sufficed.40 Each railway line had

34 Norman Miners, “Building The Kowloon-Canton-Hankow Railway,” Journal of the Royal Asiatic Society Hong Kong Branch 46 (2006): 5–24; Rousseau, “An Imperial Railway Failure,” 10–13. 35 Chang, China’s Struggle for Railroad Development, 1943, 172. 36 Ibid., 147. 37 Chang, “Technology Transfer in Modern China,” 1993, 286–88; Chang, 中國近代鐵路事業管理的研究--政治層面的分析 1876-1937 [Railroads in Modern China: Political Aspects of Railroad Administration (1876-1937)], 78–101. 38 Rea, “Railway Loan Agreements and Their Relation to the Open Door”; Stringer, The Chinese Railway System, 1922, 37–73; “铁路部门实行经济核算制前作了一系列必需的准备工作 [A Series of Preparatory Work Is Required Before Implementing the Economic Accounting System in the Railway Sector],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], July 19, 1951, sec 2. 39 Chang, “Technology Transfer in Modern China,” 1993, 283–88; Stringer, The Chinese Railway System, 37–73. 40 Rosenbaum, “Railway Enterprise and Economic Development,” 242.

Page 85: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

79

its own processes of procurement, linked to its own set of factories and workshops.41 The

separate administration of railway lines also impeded economical transport. Cars belonging to

one line had to travel back to their origin upon reaching their destination, instead of being

reloaded and dispatched to where needed.42 Foreign control of China’s railways made it difficult

to plan efficient use of existing railways. Furthermore, by limiting and controlling the surplus

generated from China’s railway operations, foreign creditors also made it impossible for China to

pursue—according to its own needs—the rational and systematic development of its railway

system. Any surplus had gone to repaying foreign debts; any new loans would prioritize the

geopolitical interests of the lender.

In 1935, the MOR had invited the advice of Brigadier General F. D. Hammond, a British

railway expert. General Hammond recommended that China improve its railway system in

accordance with three basic principles. These were: (1) that the railways should be operated as

business enterprises, to pursue maximum returns with minimum expenditure; (2) that the

railways should be administered in accordance to rational standards for matters such as

personnel, engineering, supplies, operations, etc.; and (3) that railway operations should assist in

national and regional industrial and commercial development.43 Chang comments—perhaps

wryly—that while “These three broad principles serve admirably as the guiding rules in the

administration of railroads in general”, the MOR’s attempts to implement these principles often

ran into “practical difficulties” arising from the historical legacies of China’s railways.44

Chang had in fact prioritized the economically efficient operations of China’s railways;

his options were however limited. The measures that he took towards achieving economic

efficiency had been: (1) financial reform through new accounting procedures and use of

statistics, (2) procurement reform through centralizing purchase, and (3) personnel reform

through the reduction of railway staff.45 In terms of financial reforms, Chang introduced a new

41 Chang, China’s Struggle for Railroad Development, 1943. 42 Chang, “Technology Transfer in Modern China,” 1993. 43 F. D. Hammond, Report by Brigadier-General F. D. Hammond on the National Railways of the Republic of China., 1937. See also the discussion in: Chang, China’s Struggle for Railroad Development, 1943, 170–75. 44 Chang, China’s Struggle for Railroad Development, 1943, 173. 45 Ibid.

Page 86: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

80

standardized format for railway budgets in 1937. The new format required detailed listing of

different budgets, accounts, and schedules; it facilitated calculations of items such as profit, loss,

and surplus.46 In the same year, Chang presided over the introduction of a system of statistical

measurement and reporting. The system included 69 articles and 130 forms and schedules,

covering items such as traffic, operations, engineering, stores, finance, and administration

statistics.47

The implementation of Chang’s new systems had been disrupted by the outbreak of war.

But these and similar systems had been picked up again after CCP victory in 1949. These

systems would become widely implemented in the railways of the PRC. But perhaps the

historical continuity here is not surprising: there is more than a slight trace of Lenin in Chang’s

repeated emphasis on ‘accounting and control’.48 At the root of Chang’s reforms had been his

attempt to achieve “centralization of control”. 49 Chang saw centralization as key to the

economically efficient operations of China’s railways. Of Chang’s priorities and methods, there

are perhaps only two major area where the CCP might disagree: these are the reliance on foreign

loans, and the effort to produce efficiency through cutting personnel. These can of course form

the grounds for substantial disagreements.

3.2 In the battle for a new beginning The CCP’s road to governance spanned almost three decades after its founding in 1921. In the

intervening decades, the party and its members gained experience in many sectors of China’s

economy. Early CCP experiences in China’s railway system preceded those of Chang Kia-Ngau.

The CCP came back to the nation’s railways after Chang had left, during the Chinese Civil War

of 1946-1949.

46 Ibid., 174; Ministry of Railways, ed., 鐵道年鑑 [Railway Yearbook] (Nanjing: 鐵道部秘書處 [Ministry of Railways Recording Office], 1936), 8–20. 47 Chang, China’s Struggle for Railroad Development, 1943, 175–175; Ministry of Railways, 鐵道年鑑 [Railway Yearbook]. 48 The GMD had been a Leninist party. See: Benjamin Isadore Schwartz, Chinese Communism and the Rise of Mao (Harvard University Press, 1951), 49–51. 49 Chang, China’s Struggle for Railroad Development, 1943.

Page 87: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

81

In the early and mid-1920s, the CCP—receiving tutelage from the Soviet-backed

Comintern—had prioritized labour organizing in China’s cities.50 CCP-affiliated organizing had

proliferated in China’s foreign-dominated railway system.51 Nine railway unions had existed by

May 1925, with total membership of 4,200 people.52 Offices of two railway unions—the Beijing-

Hankou General Union and All-China Railway Workers’ Union—had served as operational

bases for the CCP.53 Beginning in 1927, the GMD’s campaign of militarized violence drove the

Communists out of China’s Nationalist-controlled cities. At this time, many CCP members and

sympathizers in the railway system went underground. During the Second Sino-Japanese War

(1937-1945) and subsequent Chinese civil war, underground workers provided the party with

crucial assistance. Activities of underground railway cells included organizing anti-Japanese

resistance, organizing workers’ welfare collectives, collecting and transmitting intelligence,

shipping military and medical supplies, and sabotaging enemy transport orders and equipment.54

The CCP’s own military forces—the People’s Liberation Army—became well

acquainted with China’s railway system during the Chinese Civil War. In the closing days of the

Second Sino-Japanese War, the Soviet Union declared war on Japan in China’s Northeast. Japan

surrendered to the USSR on August 14, 1945. In the ensuing peace treaty, the Soviet Union

recognized Chinese state sovereignty in the Northeast.55 The Soviet Union had temporary

assumed political and administrative control of China’s Northeast. These were soon to be

transferred to China’s official governing party, the GMD. But the Soviet government had been

concerned about American presence and influence in area close to its territories. America had

sent troops to China during the Sino-Japanese War, ostensibly to aid in the fight against Japan.

50 Schwartz, Chinese Communism and the Rise of Mao, 64–90; Meisner, Li Dazhao and the Origins of Chinese Marxism, 1967, 90–110. 51 Epstein, “Main Directions in Chinese Labor”; Perry, Patrolling the Revolution; Schwartz, Chinese Communism and the Rise of Mao, 36. 52 Wou, “The Chinese Communist Party and the Labor Movement,” 83. 53 Ibid. 54 Chunshan Wang, ed., 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987] (Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1995), 1220–23; Kejing Fan, ed., 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988] (Chengdu, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1995), 802–3; Yongjie Xie and Wenping Yu, eds., 兰州铁路局志 1956-1995 [Annals of the Lanzhou Railway Bureau, 1956-1995] (Lanzhou, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 2001), 849–53. 55 Tanner, “Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China,” 149–50.

Page 88: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

82

But American forces had also attacked CCP troops and base areas.56 Once Japanese defeat had

been expected, American troops maintained Japanese presence in occupied areas to forestall the

advance of the CCP.57 100,000 American troops remained in China in 1946.58 The U.S. military

used its planes and ships to transport GMD forces into China’s North and Northeast.59 In

response to American backing for the GMD, retreating USSR forces had encouraged CCP

advances into the Northeast. USSR personnel made available to the CCP military equipment that

had been left behind by the Japanese; they also handed over key administration points on railway

lines.60

But initial CCP control over railways in China’s Northeast did not hold. The GMD

launched both diplomatic and military campaigns in late 1945. In November 1945, the Soviets

instructed the CCP to leave the main cities and trunk lines in China’s Northeast, so that control

could be passed to the GMD. The CCP had complied with Soviet instructions.61 CCP troops

attempted to maintain presence in the smaller cities and branch lines of Southern Manchuria. But

after a series of military defeats between fall 1945 and summer 1946, CCP troops had retreated

to Northern Manchuria by June 1946.62 In Northern Manchuria—the area around Harbin—CCP

forces set up a new base area. Railway networks and infrastructures were less developed in

Northern Manchuria than in Southern Manchuria. But it was in this new base area that the CCP

would practice the building and organizing of a railway system. Beginning in mid-1946, CCP

activities in the railways of Northern Manchuria laid the foundations for later military victories

in China’s North and Northeast.

56 William Blum, Killing Hope: US Military and CIA Interventions since World War II (Zed Books, 2003), 20–22. 57 Ibid., 22. 58 Ibid. 59 Ibid., 22–23; Tanner, “Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China,” 153–54; Steven I. Levine, Anvil of Victory: The Communist Revolution in Manchuria, 1945-1948 (Columbia University Press, 1987), 39; Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 22. 60 Tanner, “Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China,” 151–52. 61 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 22–24; Tanner, “Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China,” 153–54. 62 Tanner, “Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China,” 157–58; Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 22–24.

Page 89: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

83

In July 1946, the CCP formed the Northeast Railway Central Bureau (东北铁路总局),

with Chen Yun serving as Bureau Chief.63 The Northeast Bureau took control of railways around

Harbin. These lines had been severely damaged by fighting. All sides in the post-1937

conflicts—the Soviets, Japanese, Americans, Communists and Nationalists—had destroyed

railway infrastructures when it suited their strategic needs.64 In order to restore railway service in

Northern Manchuria, the CCP had received some assistance from the USSR and North Korea.

Soviet technicians trained Chinese soldiers; North Korea had sent shipments of locomotives and

equipment.65 But most of the work had relied on local initiative. The CCP mobilized local

workers in a mass campaign to repair and restore tracks, locomotives, and cars. Cadres and

workers collected damaged and abandoned equipment and rolling stock. Dead locomotives and

cars were dismantled; their functional parts used to refurbish new models, such as the ‘Mao

Zedong’ and ‘Zhu De’ locomotives produced by the Harbin Locomotive Deport in fall 1946.66

36 locomotives had been restored to operation in 1946, and 232 in 1947.67

The Northeast Bureau had faced a severe shortage of fuel, materials, and equipment. To

restore service to the area’s railways, cadres and workers had acted resourcefully and practiced

strict economy. When coal was burning low, train crews supplemented with soybeans and scrap

wood. To clean locomotives and engineers, workers brought old clothes and rags from home.68

The CCP’s objectives in restoring railway operations gained traction due to local cooperation.

The party began to pledge “wherever the PLA reaches, [is] wherever the railways will be fixed (

解放军打到哪里,铁路修到哪里)”.69 Once the railways were back in working order, the

63 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 22–23. 64 Song, 中国铁路建设史 [The construction history of Chinese railways], 23–50; Tanner, “Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China,” 157. 65 Tanner, “Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China,” 158. 66 Shuqing Gong and Shutian Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994] (Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1996), 1343–60; Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 22–25. 67 Tanner, “Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China,” 158. 68 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 23. 69 Ibid.; “认真实行铁路军运条例 [Conscientiously Carry out the Regulations for Military Transport],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], April 23, 1949, sec 1.

Page 90: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

84

Northeast Bureau restructured their administration and operating structures, and promulgated a

new set of rules and regulations. These new systems had the dual purpose of supporting war-time

needs and fostering local economic development. In 1948, Chen had insisted that military

shipment be subject to regular tariffs.70 Military shipments were also to be planned in advance—

as to not interfere with goals of establishing a rational and efficient railway transportation

system.71

CCP troops in north Manchuria had also gained the support of some local militias and

former soldiers of the Japanese puppet state in Manchuria. These bodies together organized a

railway protection unit (护路军) whose main task had been recovering and protecting railway

infrastructures and equipment.72 The railway protection unit—consisting of several thousand

people in the beginning—formed the base for what became the Northeast PLA Railway Column

in early 1948. The Northeast Railway Column had four branches in 1948, consisting of over

20,000 people.73 This body was reorganized as the PLA’s Railway Corps (解放军铁道兵) in

1949. The PLA’s specialized units had performed the majority of railway recovery and repairs

during the Civil War and in its aftermath. These groups had also been sent to assist with railway

reconstruction and transport during the Korean War (1950-1953). By 1954, the PLA’s Railway

Corps contained some 80,000 people.74 The Railway Corps had operated until their

decommissioning in 1983.75 In the interim, the Railway Corps had carried out the construction

70 陈云年谱 [The Life and Times of Chen Yun], vol. 1 (Beijing: Central Literary Publishers [中央文献出版社], 2000), 533. 71 “认真实行铁路军运条例 [Conscientiously Carry out the Regulations for Military Transport]”; Fuyin Bai, ed., 铁道部第十四工程局志 1948-1995 [Annals of the Ministry of Railways Engineering Corps Fourteenth Division, 1948-1995] (Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1998), 3–20. 72 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 23–25; CRSHMC, “历史沿革 [Historical Background],” 中铁上海工程局集团市政工程有限公司 [Shanghai Construction Bureau of China Railway Engineering Corporation Ltd], accessed July 9, 2017, http://www.crshmc.com/index.php?catid=13. 73 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 24–25; Pujin Wen and Zhizhong Wang, eds., 铁道部第十三工程局志 1948-1995 [Annals of the Ministry of Railways Engineering Corps Thirteenth Division, 1948-1995] (Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 2000), 4–25. 74 CRCC, “中国人民解放军铁道兵 [PLA Railway Corps],” 中国铁建股份有限公司 [China Railway Construction Corporation Ltd], June 7, 2017, http://www.crcc.cn/g754/s1859/t26177.aspx. 75 Ibid.

Page 91: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

85

and repair of railway infrastructures—tracks, bridges, tunnels, etc.—in some of China’s most

challenging terrains.76

In late 1946, the tide began to turn against the GMD in China’s Northeast. Between

December 1946 and March 1948, CCP forces gained control over much of the Northeast,

including its railway lines. In Mach 1948, GMD presence in the Northeast became limited to the

cities of Changchun, Shenyang, and the Jinzhou area.77 In the meantime, the PLA’s railway units

had repaired railway lines in areas secured by the CCP. In November 1948, the Northeast

Railway Column was dispatched for the first time to areas south of Manchuria—to repair

recently gained railway lines in China’s North.78 The CCP’s newfound ability to transport

troops, artillery, and supplies with adequate speed and reliability came to play a decisive role in

two of the three major campaigns that ended the war. These were the Liaoshen campaign

(Liaoning-Shenyang; 辽沈战役) of September-November 1948, and the Pinjing campaign

(Beiping-Tianjin; 平津战役) of November 1948-January 1949.79

In early 1949, Communist victory on China’s mainland had been on the horizon. China’s

railways had also proved themselves to be indispensable to the CCP’s military and governing

objectives. On January 10, the CCP Central Committee established a department for overseeing

national railway development and operations—the Ministry of Railways under the command of

the Military Affairs Commission (中国人民革命军事委员会(军委)铁道部). Teng Daiyuan was

appointed as Minister. The MAC MOR gathered a group of cadres and specialists who had

accrued experience working in China’s railways. This group together decided on structures and

policies governing national railway operations under the new MOR.80 When the PRC was

founded on October 1, 1949, the Military Affairs Commission MOR became the MOR under the

76 Xie and Yu, 兰州铁路局志 1956-1995 [Annals of the Lanzhou Railway Bureau, 1956-1995], 30–87; Liu, 铁路修建史料第三集 1949-1962 [The Third Series of Historical Materials on Railway Construction, 1949-1962], 1964. This aspect of Railway Corps activities was also discussed by interviewees. 77 Tanner, “Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China,” 161. 78 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 24–26. 79 Ibid. 80 Ibid.; “全国铁道职工临代会上 滕部长报告任务及方针 [At the Nation-Wide Workers’ Representative Meeting, Minister Teng Reports on Tasks and Directions],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], July 4, 1949, sec 1.

Page 92: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

86

Central People’s Government (中央人民政府铁道部). The ratification of the PRC’s first

constitution in 1954 created the State Council. At this time, the MOR came under the authority

of the State Council, becoming the MOR of the PRC (中华人民共和国铁道部). The PRC MOR

remained the governing body for the nation’s railways until 2013.81

From its beginning, the MOR emphasized the creation of a nationally unified system.

Immediately after its founding, the MOR held a series of work meetings to set national priorities

and procedures. At the end of January, persons in charge of railway operations in each of the

CCP-controlled areas of China’s Northeast, Northwest, North, East, and Central Plains had met

to discuss how to unify operations to support war-time transport and national economic

development.82 The first meeting on national transport procedures was held in April 1949. The

first meeting on national railway scheduling was held in May 1949. The first meeting on national

railway tariffs was held in May-June 1949. These meetings produced regulations and procedures

that were then acted upon by the MOR and its subordinate bodies.83 The MOR also began to

promulgate standardized systems for finances and accounting; material acquisition; the

construction, use, and maintenance of equipment; and other railway-related matters.84

Besides the unification and rationalization of the national railway system, the MOR

prioritized three sets of activities in the immediate aftermath of CCP victory, or during the post-

war recovery years (1949-1952). One set of activities was the repair and reconstruction of

81 The MOR was dissolved with components incorporated into the Ministry of Transportation (MOT) for a part of the Cultural Revolution (1966-1976). 82 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999]; Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1996. 83 Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1996; Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 110–16. 84 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 25–27, 29–31; People’s Railway News Group, “军委铁道部制定办法 搜集保护铁路交通器材 全国军民应一致协助各路局收集 [MOR Formulates Measures to Gather and Protect Railway Transport Equipment, All Mobilized Masses Asked to Help Railway Bureaus with Collection],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], August 18, 1949, sec 1; Lin Wang, “天津铁路局财务工作显著进步 [The Tianjin Railway Bureau Has Made Significant Progress in Its Financial Work],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], November 19, 1949, sec 2.

Page 93: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

87

railway infrastructures. This was mostly carried out by the PLA Railway Corps.85 The entire

22,800 km length of China’s railway network had been restored by 1952.86 The Railway Corps

and other military elements (e.g. decommissioned personnel assigned to railway workplaces)

continued to play a key role in the development of early PRC railways.87 Until the 2000s—and

perhaps even now—the style of management in the PRC railway system was known as ‘half

military management’ (半军事化管理).88

Another set of MOR-prioritized activities during the post-war recovery period was

finding, collecting, and systematizing records of materials and equipment.89 The importance of

this process was due to both non-systematic record keeping in the pre-PRC period, and the

PRC’s post-war state of scarcity. The third set of prioritized activities was the reform of railway

workplaces. When taking control of state-owned enterprises (and those left behind by private

owners), the new PRC government operated by a policy of keeping existing workers (包下来).90

The reform of railway workplaces in the post-war recovery period had two main objectives. One

85 Wen and Wang, 铁道部第十三工程局志 1948-1995 [Annals of the Ministry of Railways Engineering Corps Thirteenth Division, 1948-1995]; Song, 中国铁路建设史 [The construction history of Chinese railways]. 86 Chi-Keung Leung, China, Railway Patterns and National Goals (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1980), 80–98; Liu, 铁路修建史料第三集 1949-1962 [The Third Series of Historical Materials on Railway Construction, 1949-1962], 1964. 87 Fan, 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988], 1995, 590–92; 中国人民解放军铁道兵司令部 [PLA Railway Corp Headquarters], ed., 铁路职工专业教材:混凝土及钢筋工 [Specialized Education Material for Railway Work: Concrete and Steel-Reinforcing Work] (Beijing, China: 人民铁道出版社 [The People’s Railway Press], 1959). 88 This was discussed by interviewees. The militarized aspect of early PRC railways is also mentioned in: Lida Junghans, “Industrial Involution: Recruitment and Development within the Railway System,” in How China Works: Perspectives on the Twentieth-Century Industrial Workplace, ed. Jacob Eyferth (London: Routledge, 2006), 74–90. 89 Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987]; People’s Railway News Group, “军委铁道部制定办法 搜集保护铁路交通器材 全国军民应一致协助各路局收集 [MOR Formulates Measures to Gather and Protect Railway Transport Equipment, All Mobilized Masses Asked to Help Railway Bureaus with Collection]”; MOR Materials Bureau Communications Group, “清理资材,核定资金,反对浪费![Sort Materials, Determine Available Capital, Fight Waste!],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], August 13, 1951, sec 2; MOR Technology Research Communications Group, “铁道部铁道技术研究所介绍 [Introducing MOR Technology Institute],” 科学通报 [Chinese Science Bulletin], May 1950. 90 Fan, 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988], 1995, 603–5; Mark W. Frazier, The Making of the Chinese Industrial Workplace: State, Revolution, and Labor Management (Cambridge University Press, 2002), 92; Kenneth Lieberthal, Revolution and Tradition in Tientsin, 1949-1952 (Stanford University Press, 1980), 47–50; Barry M. Richman, Industrial Society in Communist China: A Firsthand Study of Chinese Economic Development and Management (Random House, 1969), 433.

Page 94: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

88

was to root out GMD agents, gang bosses, and other categories of counter-revolutionaries.91 The

other was to establish ‘people’s ownership’ (工人作主人) of the railway system through

democratic reforms. These reforms included the establishment and initial governing through

workers’ representative assemblies (职工代表会).92 During this period, the PRC’s railway

system became known as the People’s Railway (人民铁道).93 This label remained in place for

several decades. It gained particular salience during certain periods (e.g. the Great Leap

Forward).

3.3 “Learn from the advanced experience of the Soviet Union”

Key forces that contributed to the form of early PRC railways include Western imperialism, the

GMD, and the CCP. Another important party has so far only been mentioned in passing. This is

of course the USSR.94 While the existence of the USSR had, in many ways, enabled the very

91 Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1996, 1073; Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 31–33. For more general discussions on early PRC workers’ assemblies, see: Stephen Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution: Politics, Planning, and Management, 1949 to the Present (New York: Pantheon Books, 1977), 50–52; Franz Schurmann, Ideology and Organization in Communist China (University of California Press, 1971), 248–50. 92 Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 796, 1073–1073; Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 29–31. 93 This was discussed by interviewees. Also see: “要办好人民铁道 须解决六个问题 [For Well-Functioning Chinese Railways, Resolve Six Problems],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], July 4, 1949, sec 1; 全党全民办铁路 [The party and all people make the railway run] (人民铁道出版社 [The People’s Railway Press], 1959). 94 In terms of contexts and legacies for early PRC industrial and railway development, one important party that does not receive special focus in my thesis is Japan. In China’s Northeast, some railways had operated with Japanese systems and regulations for over a decade (1931-1946) (See for instance: Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1202–6). The relationship between Japanese imperialism and Western imperialism is somewhat complicated. Japan’s industrialization and modernization, pursued during the Meji era (1868-1912), can also be considered as ‘defensive’—occurring in response to Western aggression. To consider the form and significance of Japanese imperialism is outside the scope of this thesis (in that vein, I also bracket an actual discussion of similarities and differences between Soviet international policies and imperialism). For purposes of discussions in this thesis, I consider Japan neither the same as Western imperialist powers, nor as specifically different. When I use the term ‘Western’, I generally refer to NATO states, which can include Japan and/or how these states have acted through Japan. I do not intend to conflate Western and Japanese imperialism; I am under the impression that I do not have to specifically address this issue in order to make my set of arguments.

Page 95: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

89

possibility of Chinese state socialism, Soviet presence in China had also reflected the operations

of global political and economic systems. The ensuing set of relationships between the CCP and

the Communist Party of the Soviet Union (CPSU) had been complicated and tumultuous at

times.95 This set of complicated relationships left their defining imprint on the course of early

PRC industrial development, and on the structures and operations of the early PRC railway

system.

In the aftermath of the Russian Revolution (1917), Lenin had thought that socialist

revolutions would soon spread in Europe.96 When these revolutions did not materialize, Russia

found itself isolated and sandwiched between aggressive imperialist powers.97 The Bolsheviks

spearheaded the formation of the Communist International (Comintern) in 1919—an

organization composed of the communist parties of various states. Facing dimming prospects for

revolution in Europe, the Comintern turned its attention to Asia.98 Asian revolutionary

movements had been considered one step behind their European counterparts. According to

Soviet historiography, the Russian Revolution had unfolded in a two-stage process. The first

stage had been the February Revolution, a democratic bourgeois revolution that overthrew

Tsarist rule. The second stage was the October Revolution, a socialist revolution that replaced

the capitalist-dominated Provisional Government with control by Soviets (or workers’

councils).99 Leaders in the Comintern had understood Asian anti-colonial movements to be

nationalist—and therefore bourgeois democratic—in character.100

95 See accounts in: Thomas P. Bernstein and Hua-Yu Li, China Learns from the Soviet Union, 1949-Present (Rowman & Littlefield, 2010); Austin Jersild, The Sino-Soviet Alliance: An International History (UNC Press Books, 2014); Hua-Yu Li, Mao and the Economic Stalinization of China, 1948–1953 (Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, 2006); Lorenz M. Lüthi, The Sino-Soviet Split: Cold War in the Communist World (Princeton University Press, 2008). 96 Alfred B. Evans, Soviet Marxism-Leninism: The Decline of an Ideology (ABC-CLIO, 1993), 20–21. 97 Lenin, “The Immediate Tasks of the Soviet Government.” 98 Schwartz, Chinese Communism and the Rise of Mao, 30. 99 Alexander Rabinowitch, The Bolsheviks Come to Power: The Revolution of 1917 in Petrograd (Pluto Press, 2004), 151–200; Evans, Soviet Marxism-Leninism, 20–22. 100 Schwartz, Chinese Communism and the Rise of Mao, 30. The Leninist understanding is reflected in Mao’s following speech, originally made in 1940: Zedong Mao, On New Democracy, 2d ed. (Beijing: Foreign Languages Press, 1960).

Page 96: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

90

But the Bolshevik’s need for allies had outweighed their concerns about the challenges of

working with revolutionaries in ‘backwards’ Asian countries. In the early 1920s, the Comintern

dispatched representatives to China. Comintern representatives quickly became important

advisors to the CCP.101 However, key Comintern interests lay outside of advising what had been,

in 1921, a budding study group of scholars and students. The Bolsheviks needed to develop an

alliance with states governed by socialist, or at least socialist-sympathetic, parties. The

Comintern consequently formed a close relationship with the GMD, prompting, among other

measures, the GMD’s structural reorganization into a Leninist party in 1924.102 Comintern

representatives also brokered an alliance—known as the First United Front—between the CCP

and the GMD that began in 1923.103 Under alliance terms, CCP members had joined the GMD

and carried out their activities (labour organizing, outreach, organizing welfare, etc.) as GMD

members.

The First United Front ended in 1926, when Chiang Kai-shek purged both Soviet

advisors and CCP members from the GMD.104 The purge culminated in GMD violence against

CCP members and suspected affiliates. Ryan estimates that 5,000-10,000 Communists had been

killed in the Shanghai Massacre of April 1927.105 At this time, many active Communists escaped

to China’s countryside, where the GMD had less reach.106 For many Chinese Communists, the

purge and rural exodus also created distance from the Comintern. The CCP’s post-1927

circumstances necessitated forms of experimentation that broke with Comintern directives.107

Key characteristics of Chinese Communism, such as rural mobilization and guerilla warfare,

101 Schwartz, Chinese Communism and the Rise of Mao, 28–45; Hans J. van de Ven, From Friend to Comrade: The Founding of the Chinese Communist Party, 1920-1927 (University of California Press, 1992). 102 Schwartz, Chinese Communism and the Rise of Mao, 49–51. 103 Ibid., 37–45. 104 Elizabeth J. Perry, Shanghai on Strike: The Politics of Chinese Labor (Stanford University Press, 1993); Patricia Stranahan, Underground: The Shanghai Communist Party and the Politics of Survival, 1927-1937 (Rowman & Littlefield, 1998). 105 Tom Ryan, China Rising: A Study in Revolution (Melbourne: History Teachers Association of Victoria, Limited, 2009), 77. 106 Howard, Breaking the Iron Rice Bowl, 1988, 17–19; Stranahan, Underground. 107 Schwartz, Chinese Communism and the Rise of Mao, 73–110; Howard, Breaking the Iron Rice Bowl, 1988, 17–25.

Page 97: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

91

developed during this time. These activities and strategies are often seen as crucial components

of later CCP victories.108

After defeating the GMD in 1949, the CCP returned to China’s cities—to the setting of

large-scale modern industrialization. The most pressing task for the ‘proletarian nation’ in 1949

was one that had been unaccounted for by Marx. The early PRC needed to develop its own

means of production. The nearby presence of the American military suggested that

industrialization in the PRC needed to proceed immediately and rapidly.109 Faced with the task

of rapid industrialization, the PRC turned to its more experienced neighbour—the USSR. In the

early 1950s, the relationship between the CPSU and the CCP was at a high point.110 The CPSU

had been pleased that another socialist state had joined the world system, while the CCP had

been determined to learn from the USSR. The two governments signed a series of cooperation

agreements in the early 1950s.

According to these agreements, the USSR provided the PRC with loans, in return for

Chinese exports at discounted prices.111 The USSR also dispatched a large number of specialists

knowledgeable in areas such as economic planning, financial and monetary policies, technical

design and construction, etc.112 Soviet advisers helped their Chinese counterparts set up

institutions and enterprises. The most notable among these had been the 156 projects in strategic

industrial sectors planned for construction during the PRC’s First Five Year Plan (FFYP).113 The

PRC benefited immensely from Soviet experience in state economic planning. The structure and

operations of the USSR’s planned economy had emerged through years of debate, research, and

108 Tetsuya Kataoka, Resistance and Revolution in China: The Communists and the Second United Front (University of California Press, 1974); Mark Selden, China in Revolution: The Yenan Way Revisited (M.E. Sharpe, 1995). 109 Blum, Killing Hope: US Military and CIA Interventions since World War II, 23–27; Stanley B. Weeks and Charles A. Meconis, The Armed Forces of the USA in the Asia-Pacific Region (Allen & Unwin, 1999), 6–29, 82–98. 110 Lüthi, The Sino-Soviet Split, 2008, 29–35. 111 Lawrence C. Reardon, The Reluctant Dragon: Crisis Cycles in Chinese Foreign Economic Policy (University of Washington Press, 2015), 53–56. 112 Jersild, The Sino-Soviet Alliance, 2014, 25–40; Ghosh, “Making It Count: Statistics and State-Society Relations in the Early People’s Republic of China, 1949-1959,” 2014, 61–99. 113 Takahara, The Politics of Wage Policy in Post-Revolutionary China, 1992, 10–11; Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution, 1977, 53; PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957., 1956, 15–16.

Page 98: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

92

experimentation.114 The USSR’s FFYP began in 1928, nine years after the October Revolution in

1917. In the early 1950s, the PRC had been able to set up the administrative structures of a

centrally planned economy in its state industrial departments. These structures had not been fully

present in the USSR until its Second FYP (1933-1937).115

Soviet assistance played a prominent role in the early PRC railway sector. The origins

and form of Soviet assistance in the early PRC railway sector demonstrates quite clearly how

historical development trajectories in the two states had been linked. After annexing a part of

Chinese territory in the 1850s, Russia extracted a number of unequal treaties.116 During the Great

Powers’ scramble for Chinese territory (1985-1900), the Russian government pressed for railway

concessions in China’s Northeast. Russia wanted to build a shortcut for the Trans-Siberian

Railway on Chinese territory. This shortcut would link the Siberian city of Chita in the west to

the port of Vladivostok in the east.117 The entire length of the shortcut would be in Chinese

territory, passing through Northeastern cities such as Harbin. In 1896, China granted this

concession. Work on the Russian shortcut—which was known as the China Eastern Railway

(CER)—began in 1897.118 The CER was under Russian control until 1935, when the Soviet

government sold its rights to the Japanese colonial administration in Northeast China.119

Japanese defeat in 1945 returned CER control to the USSR. At this time, the USSR agreed to

joint control of the CER with the Chinese Republican government.120 The CER was renamed to

the Chinese Changchun Railway (中国长春铁路 or 中长铁路; Zhongchang Railway).

114 Mark R. Beissinger, Scientific Management, Socialist Discipline and Soviet Power (I.B.Tauris, 1988), 19–58; Bernstein and Li, China Learns from the Soviet Union, 1949-Present; CIA Office of Research and Reports, “Comparison of the First Five Year Plans of Communist China and the USSR,” Economic Intelligence Report (Central Intelligence Agency, June 1959), 1–8. 115 CIA Office of Research and Reports, “Comparison of the First Five Year Plans of Communist China and the USSR,” June 1959, 2. 116 G. Patrick March, Eastern Destiny: Russia in Asia and the North Pacific (Westport, CT: Greenwood Publishing Group, 1996). 117 Vladivostok had been a part of Chinese territory until its annexation in the 1850s. 118 R. Edward Glatfelter, “Russia, the Soviet Union, and the Chinese Eastern Railway,” in Railway Imperialism, ed. Clarence Baldwin Davis, Kenneth E. Wilburn, and Ronald Edward Robinson (Greenwood Press, 1991), 121–36; Fisher Y. C. Yu, “The Chinese Eastern Railway,” The Far-Eastern Review XXII, no. 2 (February 1926): 55–61. 119 Nikita Sergeevich Khrushchev and Sergei Guriev, Memoirs of Nikita Khrushchev, vol. 3 (Penn State Press, 2007), 433. 120 Ibid.

Page 99: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

93

The USSR and the PRC signed several treaties in February 1950, including the important

Sino-Soviet Treaty of Friendship and Alliance. In these treaties, the Soviet government agreed

to, by September 1952, transfer to the PRC all rights and properties of the Zhongchang Railway

free of charge.121 In the thirty-two months transition period, the Zhongchang Railway would be

under joint Soviet and Chinese management. The USSR sent over 1,500 management and

technical specialists to participate in the joint project.122 Chinese staff and workers had been

dispatched from various railway management bureaus in the Northeast, including the Harbin

Railway Bureau, the Qiqihar Railway Bureau, and the Changchun Railway Bureau. The total for

Chinese participation numbered over 5,000.123 A key goal of the joint exercise was for the

Chinese side to learn Soviet systems for railway management and operations. The two groups

were also expected to work together to adapt Soviet systems to the Chinese context. Zhongchang

Railway was to become a “model railway” (模范铁路) in the early PRC system.124 The Chinese

side had aimed to—in the words of a phrase widely used during the period— “learn from the

advanced experience of the Soviet Union” (学习苏联先进经验).125

Operations of the Zhongchang Railway proceeded through a three-level structure. The

two entities involved were the Zhongchang Railway Company (ZRC), and the Zhongchang

Railway Management Bureau (ZRMB).126 Based on operating information from the management

bureau, the company set annual targets in areas such as transportation volume, turnaround time,

locomotive production and repairs, labour efficiency rates, profits, etc. These targets were then

transmitted to the management bureau. The management bureau was responsible for drafting

121 Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1996, 1070–82; Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 36–39. 122 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 38. 123 Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1996, 1070–82, 1203–10. 124 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 38. 125 中长铁路经验介绍 [Introducing Experiences on the Zhongchang Railway] (Beijing, China: 人民铁道出版社 [The People’s Railway Press], 1953); Chongpu Lu, “怎样认识与学习苏联电焊技术 [How to Recognize and Learn Soviet Electric Welding Technique],” 机械制造 [Machinery], no. 8 (1953). 126 Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1996, 170–83.

Page 100: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

94

quarterly and annual plans for meeting these targets. Drafted plans would also include specific

tasks and targets for the bodies under bureau management, such as stations, construction teams,

and factories. After their drafting, plans from the management bureau were submitted to and

required the approval of the company. Once approved, the management bureau—and its

subordinate bodies—were responsible for carrying out these plans.127

The Soviet production system—including its railway system—emphasized division of

labour, specialization, and centralized responsibility. One person at each level (company,

management bureau, factory) took ultimate responsibility for the completion of its assigned

tasks. This person was also invested with the corresponding authority to direct operations and

ensure task completion.128 The division of labour and assigning of responsibilities had enabled

coordination within the Soviet economy. Delineated responsibility and coordination are also the

very mechanisms that make possible projects of economic planning.129 The Soviet-based system

of centralized individual responsibility became known as the one-leader system (一长制) in the

Chinese context.130

Existing accounts suggest that the Zhongchang Railway experiment was viewed as an

unequivocal success at the time. In the two-and-a-half years of its operation, the Zhongchang

Railway fulfilled or overfulfilled its annual targets. The ratio of transport volume (km-ton) to

personnel number—a ratio used to measure productivity—increased 27.8% between 1950 and

1951, and 22.5% between 1951 and 1952. The cost per km-ton of items transported decreased

127 Ibid., 1070–83; Tongwei Liu, ed., 铁路修建史料第三集 1949-1962 [The Third Series of Historical Materials on Railway Construction, 1949-1962], vol. 第三册 [Volume three] (Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1964), 1–18. 128 Andors and Schurmann discuss general structures and processes of Soviet management systems, especially what had been carried over to the early PRC: Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution, 1977, 47–55; Schurmann, Ideology and Organization in Communist China, 253–60. 129 Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution, 1977, 54. 130 Schurmann, Ideology and Organization in Communist China, 253–54; Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 791.

Page 101: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

95

13.5% between 1950 and 1951, and 27% between 1951 and 1952. The railway’s profit increased

by 110% from 1950 to 1951, and 97% from 1951 to 1952.131

Starting in 1953—the first year of the PRC’s FFYP—there was a push within the railway

system to “learn from and spread the experience of the Zhongchang Railway” (学习与推广中长

铁路经验). Chinese personnel who held leadership positions within the ZRC and ZRMB were

asked to synthesize and share their experiences. These cadres produced a document that distilled

their experiences into twelve lessons (12 条经验) for the PRC railway system. These included:

learn from the work styles (工作作风) of Stalin and Lenin; make use of new ways of organizing

labour and determining capacity; promote the use of collective contracts; integrate processes of

production and financial planning; implement the economic accounting system; establish a

method for calculating liquid capital; establish methods for organizing technology; and improve

the material livelihoods of workers and staff.132

Starting in June 1953, all enterprises that reported to the MOR (railway management

bureaus, construction teams, etc.) were asked to develop a plan and timeline for the study and

implementation of the twelve lessons from Zhongchang Railway. Railway enterprises generally

took into consideration their specific needs and circumstances, before selecting relevant lessons

and planning for their implementation.133 In 1954 and 1955, the MOR also organized

opportunities for months-long work-study sessions at the Harbin Railway Management Bureau,

which inherited much of the administrative and organizational structures of the ZRMB in

1952.134 High-level administrative and technical managers (cadres) in the PRC railway system—

131 Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1996, 1078–80; Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 38. 132 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 43–45; 中长铁路经验介绍 [Introducing Experiences on the Zhongchang Railway]. 133 Fan, 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988], 1995, 817–18; Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 1235–36; Xie and Yu, 兰州铁路局志 1956-1995 [Annals of the Lanzhou Railway Bureau, 1956-1995], 859–61. 134 Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1996; Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 43–45.

Page 102: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

96

including MOR department heads, railway management bureau chiefs, head engineers, head

accountants, department heads, station masters—were generally required to attend these

sessions. Over 1,300 people attended in total.135

In the PRC railway system, the push to learn from Zhongchang Railway died down

towards the end of the FFYP. There is no question that, at least in the early 1950s, PRC leaders

had viewed the USSR as an indispensable ally. But even in the early post-war years, some PRC

leaders had expressed a certain unease about Soviet methods and presence in China.136 This

unease was not restricted to top leadership. Certain railway enterprises—such as the Beijing

Railway Management Bureau and the Kunming Railway Management Bureau—did not

implement the one-leader system of enterprise management, even after receiving MOR

directives.137 Earlier—and crucial—forms of CCP victory had relied on mass initiative; on, in

Mao’s words, “everybody taking a hand”.138

The centralized and specialized production system imported from USSR had been highly

efficient. I suggested this efficiency in the last chapter, and will return to this question in the

second half of this chapter. But towards the end of the FFYP period, an increasingly important

question for PRC leaders concerned the balance between—or integration of—specialized

expertise and mass initiative.139 For this new question, the PRC’s leaders could no longer turn to

the USSR for a fast answer. The CCP had to go back to the drawing board; back to (sometimes

painful) experimentation. A substantial discussion of the PRC’s subsequent experiments is

outside the scope of this thesis. But in the next section—which is the last in my discussion of the

135 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 45; Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 794–97. 136 Jersild, The Sino-Soviet Alliance, 2014, 27–53; Reardon, The Reluctant Dragon, 2015, 50. 137 Fan, 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988], 1995, 93; Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 791. 138 Zedong Mao, A Talk to the Editorial Staff of the Shansi-Suiyuan Daily (April 2, 1948) (Beijing: Foreign Languages Press, 1968). 139 Questions about relationships between mass initiative and specialized expertise is an important theme for the early PRC. This theme was present in the discussions of state leaders and contents of plans; it has also been the focus for outside scholars. See: Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution, 1977; Joel Andreas, Rise of the Red Engineers: The Cultural Revolution and the Origins of China’s New Class (Stanford University Press, 2009); Kojima Retsu, “The Bearers of Science and Technology Have Changed,” Modern China 5, no. 2 (1979): 187–230.

Page 103: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

97

PRC railway system’s origins—I draw out some elements of the specialist vs. mass question, and

its relevant to projects of state socialism. For now, suffice it to say: though the push to learn from

Zhongchang Railway died down after 1955, Zhongchang’s lessons had been, and would continue

to be, learned.140 These lessons contributed to key aspects of early PRC railway management and

operations.

3.4 An assemblage The parties discussed in this section—the GMD, CCP, and the USSR—did not only each bring a

separate component to what would become the early PRC railway system. These groups also

interacted with each other, in ways that were often shaped by the complex dynamics of

imperialism. These interactions set particular chains of events into motion. The interactions

between the GMD, CCP, and the USSR had produced, for example, the early trajectory of the

CCP. This trajectory would have crucial implications for the course of early PRC development.

In the decade after its founding, the CCP had been defined by its urban-based activities

and learning from the Comintern. Circumstances forced the party and its members to the Chinese

countryside. While mounting revolution, other revolutionaries—including Lenin and Sun Yat-

sen—had also been exiled by establishment forces. But whereas Lenin and Sun had the options

of (and chose to) go abroad, CCP leaders retreated into China itself. The survival of the CCP

became intertwined with the lives and fates of China’s vast majority at the time—its rural

peasants. The rural exile produced fundamental changes for the CCP. In my discussion, I

highlight the changing relationship between the party (and its members) and projects of

industrialization. Industrial spaces—the sites of foreign incursion—had been both the raison

d’etre of Chinese Communist resistance and its weak spot; its unknown. What had changed for

the CCP, between 1927 and 1949? To survive persecution and war, party members acquired new

sets of embodied experiences in relation to industrialization and its products. These experiences

gave rise to new ways of understanding and acting on industrialization.

140 For instance, the setting up of economic accounting systems in all levels of railway enterprises continued into the 1960s. I discuss this in further detail in the next chapter.

Page 104: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

98

In the 1920s, the CCP’s relationship to modern industrialization had been defined by the

key task of organizing resistance. Chinese workers’ experiences of industrial projects, in places

such as the railways and the mines, were structured by relationships of top-down extraction and

exploitation. Modern industrial work had been imposed onto Chinese workers; it also took its

profits from them. Relationships between ownership, industrial projects, and work had been

structured similarly in Chinese-owned enterprises of the early twentieth century. Epstein

observes that wages were often lower and conditions more difficult in Chinese-owned factories,

precisely because Western enterprises dominated access to capital and technology.141 The CCP’s

early estrangement from modern industrialization also came from the intellectual origins of the

party. For core CCP organizers in the 1920s, their experience of industrial projects was not that

of workers, whose work simultaneously demonstrated their competence, produced their wages,

and extracted value from them. Initially, core party members’ experiences of industrial work—

much like that of most Western Marxists—had been structured by idealist ideas about

exploitation.142

But Nationalist violence, which had initially defeated the CCP in 1927, would force the

Chinese Communists to take up arms. In the two subsequent decades, Chinese Communism

would come to find its own relationship with industrialization and its products. In the 1920s, the

Comintern had instructed CCP members to stay away from the Chinese military, due to its

bourgeois composition.143 In the aftermath of GMD violence, CCP members—including Mao—

began to organize militias. In fall 1927, Mao led an armed uprising in rural Hunan, against GMD

troops and landlords.144 This event had not succeeded and caused some embarrassment for the

CCP. Mao was even removed from the Politburo.145 Mao retreated with a small army to the

Jinggang Mountains between Hunan and Jiangxi. In the next year, Zhu De—founder of the

Chinese Red Army—joined Mao, bringing the troops under his command. Under Mao and Zhu’s

leadership, Communist forces expanded and moved south from the Jinggang Mountains to the

141 Epstein, “Main Directions in Chinese Labor,” 318. Despite difficult conditions in domestic-owned factories, the vast majority of disruptive labour action by Chinese workers in 1895-1949 had targeted Western-owned enterprises. 142 I use the word idealist not in the sense of having ideals; but rather idealism vs. materialism. 143 Schwartz, Chinese Communism and the Rise of Mao, 80. 144 Perry, Patrolling the Revolution. 145 Schwartz, Chinese Communism and the Rise of Mao, 100–101.

Page 105: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

99

area around Ruijin in Jiangxi Province. Here, Mao and Zhu set up the Chinese Soviet Republic (

中华苏维埃共和国) of Jiangxi-Fuijian in 1931. By 1946, the CCP had control of over twenty

Chinese Soviets (or base areas), covering approximately one-fourth the area of China.146

Mao had been, perhaps above all else, pragmatic and experimental. His experiments

eventually proved quite successful. From these experiences, Mao arrived at his preferred

strategies. These included forging reciprocal relationships with local peoples, relying on mass

initiative and participation, and a pragmatic approach to arms.147 Mao had produced a way

forward for the CCP, when the party had little other options. The ‘correctness’ (or successful

results) of Mao’s strategies earned him a prominent place within the party.148 Starting in the

early 1930s, Mao’s ‘line’ charted the distinctive nature of the CCP’s path to victory. This line

perhaps best summed up in his concept and strategy of People’s War. People’s War is a doctrine

for how to pursue revolution when the establishment power is equipped with a large and

technologically-superior army. Mao advocated for revolutionary movements to foster and make

use of their crucial advantage: their broad based popular support. The doctrine of People’s War

was later adopted and used by revolutionary movements in places such as Vietnam, Nepal, Cuba,

and Nicaragua.149

The crucial significance of Mao’s formulation can only be understood when placed

within the context of how society is organized under Western capitalism. In capitalism, the

powerful minority—capitalists—have a monopoly over the means of production, including the

means of making war.150 The power of the capitalist elite can only be maintained if the majority

are subordinated to technology and machinery. Capitalism produces this subordination by

separating mental from physical labour, and through a process of de-skilling.151 Those who

146 Guoming Liu, 中华民国国民政府军政职官人物志 [Republic of China Military and Governance Records] (Chunqiu Press [春秋出版社], 1989). 147 Selden, China in Revolution, 1995; Howard, Breaking the Iron Rice Bowl, 1988. 148 Barbara Barnouin and Changgen Yu, Zhou Enlai: A Political Life (Hong Kong: Chinese University Press, 2006), 62; Schwartz, Chinese Communism and the Rise of Mao, 90–117. 149 Vo Nguyen Giap, People’s War, People’s Army (University Press of the Pacific, 2001). 150 Christon I. Archer, World History of Warfare (U of Nebraska Press, 2002); Randall Forsberg, The Arms Production Dilemma: Contraction and Restraint in the World Combat Aircraft Industry (MIT Press, 1994). 151 Michel Freyssenet, La division capitaliste du travail (Savelli, 1977); Karl Marx, Capital: A Critique of Political Economy, trans. David Fernbach, vol. 1 (Penguin Classics, 1992).

Page 106: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

100

understand the theory behind machines (e.g. engineers) are deemed ‘too educated’ to work with

them. Knowledge about the logic and design of machines judged as unnecessary for (or withheld

from) those who work with them. Mao’s strategy of the people’s war combines the knowledge

and mastery of the capitalist’s tools—machinery, arms—with the crucial advantage of the

masses: their numbers.

When the CCP re-approached China’s railway system in 1945, the party had been shaped

by the Maoist line. The CCP’s renewed operations in China’s railway system emphasized

reciprocity between the party and local workers. The party fostered and relied on mass initiative

and a sense of workers’ ownership. Mass participation and investment made it possible for the

CCP and its allies to repair and make use of China’s railway system during the Civil War. This

gave the CCP a crucial advantage. Emphasis on workers’ ownership continued into the post-war

recovery years. The MOR had prioritized the democratic reorganization of railway workplaces;

the railway system in the PRC was importantly conceptualized as the People’s Railway.

The implementation of the PRC’s First Five Year Plan (FFYP) brought some

complications to evolving practices of workers’ ownership. As earlier discussed, Soviet-type

planned economies achieve their efficiency and productivity through the centralization of

responsibility and division of labour. In theory, this system is not incompatible with (the actual

felt experience of) mass ownership. In practice, authority often defaulted into the hands of

specialists and managers. After the FFYP, the PRC would begin a series of experiments aimed at

reconciling mass ownership with specialized knowledge and roles. These experiments—

including the Great Leap Forward and Cultural Revolution—were not necessarily the disasters

that critics of state socialism would insist on.152 They produced some important results. It is

outside of the scope of this thesis to dwell on the PRC’s post-FFYP experiments, but suffice it to

say, their results—and the way that these results are understood—would be very different had

the PRC existed in a different world economy. It would also be inaccurate to conflate the FFYP

with efficiency and rationality, and post-FFYP experiments with inefficiency and waste. CCP

operations in China’s railway system during the Civil War had been resourceful and efficient

precisely because the party had relied on mass initiative and ownership. In the post-war years,

152 For instance, Naughton’s discussion: Naughton, The Chinese Economy, 2007, 5–20.

Page 107: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

101

the PRC government would continue to rely on mass participation and investment to reduce

waste and achieve efficient development, even during the FFYP.

4. Conclusion In this chapter, I discussed the different systems of infrastructure, knowledge, and practices that

came together to form the early PRC railway system. The operations of history had bestowed

their legacies. PRC state administrators inherited issues faced by the earlier Republican

government, and earlier forms of solutions. The CCP first approached China’s railway system

through organizing workers in the 1920s. During the Chinese Civil War, the PLA’s Northeast

Field Army developed a close symbiotic relationship with railway lines and workers in China’s

Northeast. As the Civil War proceeded, China’s railways gained increasing prominence in CCP

military strategies. Histories of activism and resistance left important imprints on China’s post-

1949 railway system. Finally, the CER or Zhongchang railways had been under Russian state

control since 1897. This set of railways came under joint Sino-Soviet management for a period

before it was handed back to the PRC in 1952. The Zhongchang Railway became a ‘model

railway’ in the early PRC system, passing on aspects of its operations and management to other

railway enterprises.

In the last section of this chapter, I turned to how the different parties referenced above

had interacted with each other. When Nationalist violence exiled CCP members to the

countryside, the party broke away from its Comintern-directed roots. Mao and his ‘line’ gained a

prominent role within the CCP. This line emphasized mass mobilization, mass ownership, and a

pragmatic approach to arms. Mao’s approach brought the CCP to its 1949 victory, and continued

to shape industrial—and particularly railway—developments in the early PRC. The currently

concluding chapter provided a set of historical and railway-specific contexts for the early PRC.

These contexts anticipate and anchor the discussion in the next chapter, which discusses the

mechanisms of early PRC state planning and their implementation in the state railway sector.

Chapter 4 picks up the thread of earlier discussions about ‘irrational’ socialism. The next chapter

also carries forward a set of ideas that began to be discussed in this current chapter. These

concern the relationship between Chinese socialism and the nation’s people. One question that

Page 108: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

102

emerges in Chapter 4 is how the state socialist pursuit—and achievement—of efficiency shaped

the PRC’s national subjects.

Page 109: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

103

Chapter IV. The Red passion for economizing, part two: State plans and railway sector accounting in the early PRC

1. Introduction In this chapter, I return to my questioning of ‘irrational’ socialism discourses. In Chapter 1, I

noted that these discourses include three sets of ideas: that (1) planners had been idiosyncratic

and produced irrational plans; that (2) resource allocation had been inefficient due to the absence

of economic mechanisms; and that (3) economic planning produces the waste of resources,

materials, and labour. While discussing the first set of ideas in Chapter 2, I argued that the entire

discourse of ‘irrational’ socialism has little to do with actual events and processes in historically-

existing socialist states. This discourse rather revolves around the reproduction of what it

rhetorically excludes—the operations of Western imperialism.

Having first contextualized and understood common Western discussions of early PRC

developments, I then turned to look at events in China itself. In Chapter 3, I discussed the

formation of the early PRC railway sector. The early system brought together elements from

Republican China, the CCP’s history of activism and war-time experiences, and management

practices from the Soviet Union. The complex interactions between these parties made space for

Mao and his innovations. The Mao-shaped concept of the People’s Railways (人民铁道) came to

characterize Chinese railway operations during the Civil War. This understanding remained in

place in the decades after.

In this chapter, I pick up temporally from where Chapter 3 left off. I discuss mechanisms

of early PRC state planning—a process that began after 1950—and their implementation in the

state railway sector. I begin with an account of the planning process in the early PRC. I then use

evidence from this process to challenge the second and third sets of ideas about ‘irrational’

socialism, which revolve around its alleged lack of economic mechanisms, inefficiency of

resource allocation, and corresponding waste. In the last part of this chapter, I turn to the

operations of state plans in the PRC railway sector. I trace the ‘landing’ of plans through the

Page 110: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

104

implementation—in the railway sector—of a particular mechanism of state planning. This

mechanism is the economic accounting system.

Tracking processes of state plan implementation makes visible a critical condition of the

early PRC: its ‘backwardness’. This ‘backwardness’ is produced by imperialism, and manifests

in the shortage of capital, technology, and particular kinds of human subjects. The condition of

‘backwardness’ had important implications for how economic efficiency was understood and

acted upon in the early PRC. This condition had also meant that the pursuit—and achievement—

of economic efficiency in the early PRC was tied crucially to the moulding of its population.

2. Early PRC state planning in process As previously discussed, state economic planning in the early PRC benefitted immensely from

the existing Soviet template. In my following account of early PRC state planning, I draw from

accounts—of either the planning or enterprise production process in the PRC—from Andors,

Donnithorne, Fan, Hsiao, Kwang, Meisner, Ren, Wang, Yang, and Zhu.1 For areas less covered

by these authors (e.g. the role of prices in the planned economy), I turned to works on Soviet-

style economic planning by Bornstein and Montias.2 Reading both sets of accounts gave me a

better sense of the overall logic of the process and how specific pieces fit in the PRC context. I

also use information gained from archives and railway-specific sources (e.g. Annals of railway

management bureaus) to fill in some ‘missing pieces’, especially when it comes to how central

processes were linked to local events (e.g. planning and production schedules, transmission of

1 Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution, 1977; Audrey Donnithorne, “China’s Economic Planning and Industry,” The China Quarterly, no. 17 (1964): 111–24; Fan, 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988], 1995, 505–627; Kwang, The Economic Accounting System of State Enterprises in Mainland China, 1966; Mitch Meisner, “The Shenyang Transformer Factory--A Profile,” The China Quarterly, no. 52 (1972): 717–37; Jianxin Ren, “加强经济合同工作促进国民经济计划的顺利执行 [Strengthening economic contracts to create a smooth process for our economic planning],” 法学研究 [Legal Research], no. 01 (1957): 31–34; Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 777–1000; Yang, “第一个五年计划的资金积累问题 [The question of capital accumulation in the First Five Year Plan]”; Zhu, 铁路材料技术供应计划 [Plans for Supplying Railway Materials and Technology]. 2 Morris Bornstein, “The Soviet Price System,” The American Economic Review 52, no. 1 (1962): 64–103; J. M. Montias, “Planning with Material Balances in Soviet-Type Economies,” The American Economic Review 49, no. 5 (1959): 963–85.

Page 111: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

105

information). In the below account, I try as much as possible to link items of information to their

specific sources. However, some of my understanding of early PRC state planning come from an

extended process of amalgamating information and checking sources against each other.3 I do

not always document this process. I imagine readers would largely find it distracting.

Two key state bodies involved in early PRC economic planning were the State Planning

Commission (SPC; 国家计划委员会 or 国家计委) and the State Economic Commission (SEC;

国家经济委员会 or 国家经委). The SPC was established in 1952, and is responsible for long-

term (e.g. five year) planning. The SEC was established in 1956, and functions in the drafting

and implementation of annual plans. Until the SEC was formed—in the fourth year of the

FFYP—its functions had been distributed between the SPC, the various ministries, and the

Finance and Economic Committee under the State Administrative Council (政务院财政经济委

员会 or 中财委).4

The following discussion of state economic planning in the PRC presents an ‘ideal

version’ of the process, or what was supposed to happen, given requisite structures and capacity.

Certain mechanisms of the ‘ideal’ process had not been present in the PRC until after 1955, and

some much later than that.5 I describe the ideal process in order to make visible the logic and

goals of the centrally planned economy. To first present the ideal process also makes it possible

to discuss how and why certain operations did not proceed according to plan. Since James Scott,

it has been almost customary to understand projects of large-scale planning through their

unplanned-for effects.6 Scott separates the intentions of plans from their actual implementations.

3 For instance, something like: Source A says Bodies 1 and 2 are involved. Source B suggests that Body 1 functions in x way, which is similar to what Source C had documented of Body 3 in the Soviet context. Therefore the relationship between Bodies 1 and 2, and their role in the PRC planning process, should be y. 4 BMA 004-014-00008, “中财委批准并印发的 1951 年各月份全国铁路运输计划、会议记录,” January 1, 1951; BMA 004-016-00472, “市财委转发中财委关于各地铁路供应商店若干业务问题的指示及有关铁路系统的供应问题,” January 1, 1954. 5 Fan, 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988], 1995, 510–30. 6 James C. Scott, Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed (Yale University Press, 1998); Susan Greenhalgh, Just One Child: Science and Policy in Deng’s China (University of California Press, 2008); Tania M. Li, The Will to Improve: Governmentality, Development, and the Practice of Politics (Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 2007); Shannon May, “Ecological Urbanization: Calculating Value in an Age of Global Climate Change,” in Worlding Cities, ed. Ananya Roy and Aihwa Ong (Wiley-Blackwell, 2011), 98–126; David Mosse, Cultivating Development : An Ethnography of Aid Policy and Practice (Anthropology,

Page 112: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

106

The later is what shapes the lives of (local) people, producing the ‘reality’ of plans.7 But the

mismatch between plans—or concepts—and their realization happens in very different ways.

Scott argues that modernist state projects had failed through their exclusion of local

knowledge.8 I argued previously that a gap, also premised on exclusion, exists between Mises’s

concept of capitalism and how capitalism actually operates. The Misesean concept excludes the

operations of power. The relationships of ‘free’ and ‘equal’ exchange that Mises conceives do

not (can not) happen in practice. In the case of Misesean capitalism, what is excluded from the

concept renders its implementation impossible. The very point of the concept—capitalism as

‘free’ and ‘equal’ exchange—is not to produce its implementation, but rather to obscure and

prevent the possibilities of such practices. This was not the relationship between plans and

practices in the early PRC. Rather, the gap that existed between plans and their implementation

in the early PRC had largely been the space of ‘not yet’.

The text of the First Five Year Plan (FFYP), for instance, referred to the PRC ‘not yet’

having sufficient amounts of technical personnel or equipment, as well as planners ‘not yet’

having sufficient experience or access to statistical data.9 Most, if not all, Western accounts of

early PRC planning contain discussions of how certain aspects of state plans fell short in

practice. For accounts containing actual information—where the focus is not on the ‘distortions’

produced through plans—the issues described can also be seen as ones of ‘not yet’. Donnithorne

discusses how, during the FFYP, some local bodies had begun construction without consulting

higher-levels, therefore diverting materials from planned objectives.10 Hsiao describes how—

also during the FFYP—some supplying bodies did not deliver contracted goods in time,

delivered defective goods, and/or disputed with purchasing bodies about prices. State leaders and

Culture and Society Series) (Pluto Press, 2005); Emily T. Yeh, “Greening Western China: A Critical View,” Geoforum 40, no. 5 (2009): 884–94. 7 Scott, Seeing Like a State, 309-41. 8 Ibid. 9 PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957., 1956, 18–19. 10 Donnithorne, “China’s Economic Planning and Industry,” 113.

Page 113: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

107

planners in the early PRC were presumably aware of these issues. Donnithorne and Hsiao both

draw their knowledge from discussions in early PRC research journals.11

An awareness of China’s pre-PRC history would make it difficult to attribute the above

issues to the centrally-planned aspect of the early PRC economy. Firstly, all enterprises were

operating with a limited amount of capital and resources. In the context of scarcity—and low

technology levels—it is unsurprising that some goods would be produced behind schedule and

with lower-than-expected quality. Secondly, China had been—and still was, during the early

PRC—a largely agricultural society. In Britain, formal education did not become widespread

until the Industrial Revolution was well underway.12 The knowledge and skills for industrial

work had to be taught. Over 70% of workers in the Harbin Railway Management Bureau in 1952

had either an elementary-level of education or less.13 A certain level of reading, writing, and

arithmetic skills are required for successful contract negotiation, and being able to carry out—or

report modifications to—a plan.

A detailed elaboration of the early PRC’s ‘not yet’ state might suggest that the FFYP had

been non-operational. It is important to then contextualize the above details in what had been

discussed in Chapter 3—that the PRC’s FFYP had been quite successful. And finally, one last

item in the discussion of ‘not yet’: it is very much valid to question the direction in which PRC

leaders and planners had urged the nation and its population. Is it better to be more educated,

rather than less? Is it better to improve at self-governance—in order to fulfill plans and

contracts—rather than not? But these are not the questions asked by critics of socialist state

planning. Or at least, not asked with any degree of genuineness. These questions are much more

applicable to the operations of non-state planned economies.

11 Ibid.; Hsiao, “The Role of Economic Contracts in Communist China,” October 31, 1965, 1048–51. 12 Michael Sanderson, Education, Economic Change and Society in England 1780-1870 (Cambridge University Press, 1995), 1–24; Joyce Burnette, Gender, Work and Wages in Industrial Revolution Britain (Cambridge University Press, 2008), 114–16. 13 Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1996, 1205–8. Also see events described in: Baohua Song, “铁路系统的考工升级工作 [The task of testing and promoting workers in the railway system],” 劳动 [Labour], no. 08 (1956): 17–19.

Page 114: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

108

Back to the process of state economic planning, then. The first step of the process begins

months prior to the beginning of the production year.14 The State Economic Commission (SEC)

determines a list of ‘control items’. In the early PRC, these included the output and balance of

major industrial products (e.g. steel, iron, coal, machines, etc.); the output and balance of major

agricultural products (e.g. grain, cotton, vegetable oil, etc.); the total volume of freight

transported on railways; the total wages and workers in each industry; and profits in each

industry.15 The SEC then makes a survey of the existing national situation, including existing

stockpiles in warehouses, latest production figures, forecasts of productive capacity, and

estimated demands for products.16 The SEC largely relies on information provided by the various

ministries (e.g. the First and Second Ministry of Machine-Building; Ministry of Agriculture,

Ministry of Railways).17 From its national survey, the SEC drafts output targets for the ‘control

items’—these are often referred to as ‘control figures’ in English-language literature on state

economic planning.

After drafting tentative output targets, the SEC transmits these targets to the production

ministries. The tentative targets that ministries (e.g. MOR) receive includes targets for

production output; labour productivity; number of employees; and estimates of receipts,

expenditures, and profits.18 Using tentative targets from the SEC as guidelines, each ministry—

taking into account its own capacity, needs, and the latest up-to-date information—calculates

their actual expected output targets, as well as the material inputs that they would require to meet

output targets.19 Based on these two sets of information, each ministry drafts its own production

and procurement plans. These plans are then submitted by the ministries to the SEC. The SEC

proceeds to ‘balance’ plans from the individual ministries.20 For state-owned enterprises

14 Montias, “Planning with Material Balances in Soviet-Type Economies,” 963–64. 15 Donnithorne, “China’s Economic Planning and Industry,” 115. 16 Hsiao, “The Role of Economic Contracts in Communist China,” October 31, 1965, 1045–46; Montias, “Planning with Material Balances in Soviet-Type Economies,” 964–66; Donnithorne, “China’s Economic Planning and Industry,” 114–15. 17 Meisner, “The Shenyang Transformer Factory--A Profile,” 1972, 720. 18 Bornstein, “The Soviet Price System,” 964–70; Fan, 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988], 1995, 515–25. 19 Hsiao, “The Role of Economic Contracts in Communist China,” October 31, 1965, 1046. Also see: Montias, “Planning with Material Balances in Soviet-Type Economies,” 965. 20 Montias, “Planning with Material Balances in Soviet-Type Economies,” 965.

Page 115: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

109

involved in the use and production of ‘control items’ (e.g. steel, cotton), it is this process of

balancing that substitutes—in the national economy—the operations of the free market. Hence

why Soviet-type economies are sometimes known to operate through ‘material balance

planning’. For each control item, the process of its balancing ends when the SEC—working from

the plans submitted by each ministry—has matched the total expected output (supply) of the item

to total plans for its input (demand).21

When the SEC finishes all processes of balancing, it formulates the national production

and procurement plan. The national plan contains production and procurement quotas for each

ministry. This information is transmitted by the SEC to each ministry, before the beginning of

each planned production year.22 Each ministry then distributes its production and procurement

quotas among its subordinate enterprises (e.g. locomotive depots, railway management bureaus).

Using these quotas as strict guidelines, each enterprise formulates its own production and

procurement plans. These plans consist of how the individual enterprise will meet its production

targets (quota), and what inputs are required—including the variety, quantity, and other specific

characteristics of the materials needed.23 Enterprise plans are submitted to the ministry in charge

for approval. Once plans are approved, enterprises are under legal obligation to meet (or

overfulfill) the targets set out by its plan.24 However, modifications to the enterprise plan are

possible and do happen.25 Prior to the approval of its plan by the ministry, the enterprise is

expected to carry out production according to its draft plan. Final enterprise plans can look

significant different from the initial production and procurement quotas issued to each enterprise.

These initial quotas become modified in the course of realistic plan-making by each enterprise,

and through the ministry’s reconciling of plans from different enterprises.

21 Ibid. 22 Hsiao, “The Role of Economic Contracts in Communist China,” October 31, 1965, 1045–46. 23 Ibid.; Zhu, 铁路材料技术供应计划 [Plans for Supplying Railway Materials and Technology], 2–7. 24 Hsiao, “The Role of Economic Contracts in Communist China,” October 31, 1965, 1043–47; Kwang, The Economic Accounting System of State Enterprises in Mainland China, 1966, 69. 25 Kwang, The Economic Accounting System of State Enterprises in Mainland China, 1966, 69; Fan, 成都铁路局志1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988], 1995, 510–25.

Page 116: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

110

Starting during the FFYP, enterprises were considered distinct legal entities with their

own set of rights and responsibilities.26 Enterprises entered into contracts with other enterprises

for supplying and procuring products, and were expected to fulfill the terms of these contracts or

bear penalty terms.27 Each enterprise was an independent account unit, and was expected to

cover its expenses from its own revenues. As early as 1942 Mao had said of enterprises in CCP-

governed areas: “All factories should shrink or grow according to their economic prosperity. All

salaries should be paid from the factories' own profit and not from tax grant, government

clothing and government grants.”28 In the early PRC, enterprise operations were directed toward

the fulfillment (and overfulfillment) of its enterprise plan. Enterprise plans included plans for

items such as production output, lowering cost, ensuring quality, and maximizing profit.29

During this time, failing to meet planned objectives had been met with public criticisms, the

garnishing of top managers’ wages, and assistance in getting back on track.30

3. Critical projections: The distorted reflection of American corporations The above presents, in somewhat broad strokes, an overview of how state economic planning

worked in the early PRC. Even a broad overview provides grounds for questioning ideas about

‘irrational’ socialism, such as those revolving around its absence of economic mechanisms,

inefficient resource allocation, and the corresponding production of waste. I start with a

discussion of economic mechanisms. I use this term to refer to those items that Nolan and Ash

26 Ren, “加强经济合同工作促进国民经济计划的顺利执行 [Strengthening economic contracts to create a smooth process for our economic planning]”; “铁道部决定自七月一日起全国各铁路管理局实行经济核算制度 [MOR Issues Nation-Wide Directive for Railway Bureaus to Implement the Economic Accounting System, Starting on July 1],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], June 24, 1951, sec 2. 27 Hsiao, “The Role of Economic Contracts in Communist China,” October 31, 1965, 1043–47. 28 Zedong. Mao, Economic and Financial Problems during the Anti-Japanese War, and Other Articles. (Beijing, China: Foreign Languages Press, 1955), 43. 29 Kwang, The Economic Accounting System of State Enterprises in Mainland China, 1966, 65–68; Meisner, “The Shenyang Transformer Factory--A Profile,” 1972, 720–22. 30 Meisner, “The Shenyang Transformer Factory--A Profile,” 1972; People’s Daily Editorial, “吸取铁路运输工作中的教训 [Absorbing the Lesson from Railway Transport Work],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], February 25, 1953, sec 1; Fan, 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988], 1995, 710–25.

Page 117: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

111

had found lacking from the early PRC economy, the—in the authors’ words—“fundamental

economic concepts [of] price, cost, and profit”.31

First is profit. As discussed above, both state and enterprise plans contained targets for

profit. These were usually expressed as a percentage of the production ministry’s or enterprise’s

operating costs.32 The fulfillment (or overfulfillment) of the enterprise profit plan was generally

considered one of the three key measures of enterprise success in the early PRC. The other two

were the fulfillment of the production plan, and the quality plan.33 The emphasis on profit in

state socialism may seem surprising to readers of Marx—or those of Mises. Marx had equated

profit to surplus value, or the value that capitalists take from workers.34 In Marx’s socialism,

workers would presumably receive back (in wages, goods, etc.) the value produced by their

labour.35 There would be no profit to speak of. But for actually-existing projects of state

socialism, a key task was to accrue capital, which facilitates the nation’s development of its own

means of production. It was consequently of crucial importance for socialist states to maximize

the aggregate value derived from labour, calculated in aggregate profit.

In order to calculate profit—as well as cost, income, and a whole set of other value

measurements—state planned economies needed a system of prices. Prices made it possible to

commensurate different input items (e.g. raw materials, labour, capital goods) and different

output items, which additionally varied from enterprise to enterprise.36 This process of

commensuration served a key goal: both state planners and enterprises could then calculate how

to maximize output given a set amount of input, and vice versa. Mises had initially argued that

socialism was irrational—impossible—due to the absence of prices, and consequently other

measurements of economic value. Mises was proven wrong by the operations of the Soviet

31 Nolan and Ash, “China’s Economy on the Eve of Reform,” 1996, 18. 32 Kwang, The Economic Accounting System of State Enterprises in Mainland China, 1966, 92–96; Meisner, “The Shenyang Transformer Factory--A Profile,” 1972, 719–21. 33 Meisner, “The Shenyang Transformer Factory--A Profile,” 1972, 719–21; Mao, Economic and Financial Problems during the Anti-Japanese War, and Other Articles. 34 Karl Marx, Value, Price and Profit: Speech to the First International Working Men’s Association, June 1865 (Socialist Labor Party, 1919). 35 Ibid. 36 Bornstein, “The Soviet Price System,” 65.

Page 118: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

112

economy. But his original misconception lives on, as evident from how Nolan and Ash

understand early PRC resource allocations to have happened in the absence of mechanisms such

as cost, profit, and prices.

For critics of ‘irrational’ socialism, the alleged lack of economic measurements in state

planned economies is linked to their inefficient resource allocation. But planned allocation—and

central to it, the process of balancing outputs and inputs—is geared precisely towards the

efficient use of resources. Everything that is produced becomes used. A similar system of

planning and matching exists in North America for scarce and valuable resources. These include

the matching system that bring together North American hospitals with graduating medical

doctors, and the system of quotas that match dairy production with demand.

Moreover, planning and coordination—including of resource use—are key operating

components of large Western corporations. In fact, American corporations (e.g. General Motors)

and Soviet-type economies have very similar operating structures. They share the three key

characteristics of centralized planning, de-centralized responsibility, and coordination between

different functional bodies.37 Accordingly to Kaplan, it is widely known that the evolution of

these organizational structures had produced the success of the DuPont Power Company in the

early 1900s. These structures were brought over to (and further developed in) General Motors,

when executives and shareholders of Dupont migrated to GM in the 1920s. The accounting and

managerial structures of GM set the template for large American corporations in the decades to

come. Kaplan, writing in 1988, remarks that since 1925, there has been little change or

innovation in the accounting and management practices of American corporations.38

The confluence of organizational structures in Soviet-type planned economies and

American corporations might seem quite surprising. What is perhaps even more surprising is the

reason behind this confluence. In the 1920s, Soviet leaders puzzled over the design of an

economic system for the newly socialist state. Bear in mind that a key objective for Soviet

socialism—also shared by subsequent projects of state socialism—had been rapid surplus

37 Robert S. Kaplan, “The Evolution of Management Accounting,” The Accounting Review 59, no. 3 (1984): 398–99. 38 Ibid., 410.

Page 119: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

113

accumulation and industrial development. In designing for both rapid and collectivist

accumulation, Lenin and his colleagues turned to an unlikely source: the work of Frederick

Winslow Taylor. In the words of Lenin: “The Taylor system, […] like all capitalist progress, is a

combination of the refined brutality of bourgeois exploitation and a number of the greatest

scientific achievements in the field of analysing mechanical motions during work, the

elimination of superfluous and awkward motions, the elaboration of correct methods of work, the

introduction of the best system of accounting and control, etc. The Soviet Republic must at all

costs adopt all that is valuable in the achievements of science and technology in this field.”39

And Soviet planners did proceed to adopt the best of American accounting and

managerial technologies. In the 1920s, managerial and technological exchanges proliferated

between the Soviet state and American corporations.40 The events of this decades have since—

especially since the Cold War—been buried by both sides. But before these memories were

erased, perhaps Stalin said it best. When discussing the USSR’s FFYP, Stalin attributed its

success to the work style of Leninism, which, according to Stalin, combined “Russian

revolutionary sweep” and “American efficiency”. Stalin continued: “American efficiency is that

indomitable force […] which with its business-like perseverance brushes aside all obstacles;

which continues at a task once started until it is finished […]. But American efficiency has every

chance of degenerating into narrow and unprincipled practicalism if it is not combined with

Russian revolutionary sweep.”41

In advocating for the adoption of American management and accounting structures for

the Soviet economy, Lenin presumably thought that it was possible to separate “bourgeois

exploitation” from American scientific achievements. The possibility of this separation is very

much questionable, especially when the branch of science in question concerns labour

management and discipline. But as the quote from Stalin reminds us, American corporate

structure had been incorporated into Soviet socialism as a tool—to be contextualized by the

39 Lenin, “The Immediate Tasks of the Soviet Government,” 259. 40 Mark R. Beissinger, Scientific Management, Socialist Discipline and Soviet Power (I.B.Tauris, 1988), 19–58; Charles E. Sorensen, My Forty Years with Ford (Wayne State University Press, 1956), 190–215. 41 Joseph Stalin, Problems of Leninism (Beijing, China: Foreign Languages Press, 1976), 115.

Page 120: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

114

revolutionary frame.42 Two key aspects separate the overall operations of Soviet-type economies

and American corporations. The first concerns the objectives of profit accumulation, and uses for

profit. In capitalism, profit-use falls within the private domain of the capitalist. Profit is

moreover most often used to maintain and reproduce class distinction—including the historical

and ongoing distinction of the Global North from the Global South.43 In state socialism, profit is

reinvested into the project of (peripheral) state industrialization.

The second key aspect separating Soviet-type economies from American corporations is

the role that people play in the process. Both the USSR and the PRC were, in theory, led by and

for the purposes of the people.44 The planning process in the early PRC involved a degree of

worker input. After the enterprise receives its production and procurement quotas from the

ministry in charge, the enterprise planning process begins. Enterprise management (e.g. railway

management bureau chief) draws up a set of preliminary plans, assisted by top-level specialists

(e.g. chief engineer, department heads). These plans are passed to subordinate and other bodies

(e.g. locomotive section, work teams within the section, workers’ assembly) for discussions and

revisions. Through ‘lower’-level discussions, sections and work teams draw up their monthly and

quarterly work plans.45 The revised plan is then passed back to enterprise management, and

circulated again as needed. The process of plan circulation incorporates workers and makes use

of their experiences and expertise. This step has important implications for the matching of plans

to capacity and resources.46

Successful—and efficient—state planning and production relies on local initiative and

practices. In the next section, I turn to local developments brought about by state planning in the

early PRC railway sector. I trace the development of the economic accounting system, known as

the ‘link’ between different operations in the railway sector, as well as what ‘links’ the railway to

42 Of course what is brought to mind is Audre Lorde’s idea of ‘master’s tools, master’s house’. 43 Vernengo, “Technology, Finance, and Dependency: Latin American Radical Political Economy in Retrospect”; Williams, Capitalism & Slavery, 1944. 44 Yiching Wu Wu, The Cultural Revolution at the Margins (Harvard University Press, 2014), 39–42. 45 Meisner, “The Shenyang Transformer Factory--A Profile,” 1972, 720–26; Fan, 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988], 1995, 510–15; Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 813, 815–16. 46 Meisner, “The Shenyang Transformer Factory--A Profile,” 1972, 723–25.

Page 121: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

115

national production plans. The development of the economic accounting system in PRC railways

shed further light on how efficiency and resource conservation had been two key components of

the early PRC’s planned economy.

4. The ‘central link’ of the plan: Economic accounting in the PRC railway sector The last section in this chapter brings together state socialist planning and railway sector

developments in the early PRC. The system of state planning reshaped forms of economic and

social organization in China’s railway sector. In this section, I focus on how the railway sector

was changed through the adoption of one particular—and central—mechanism of state planning:

the system of economic accounting. I delve into details about this system and its relevance to the

early PRC in the below section. I want to first draw out the significance of what has already been

covered, in terms of linking railway sector developments to early PRC state plans.

I have spent some time discussing the history and origins of the PRC railway system. The

earlier discussion provides context for understanding the sector-wide implementation of the

economic accounting system after 1952. Early PRC plans, including those for its railways, were

formed in response to certain pre-existing states in Chinese industries. These pre-existing

conditions in turn shaped and constrained processes of implementing state plans and their

mechanisms, including the system of economic accounting. The enduring nature of China’s

railways makes it possible to track—through evolving railway structures and operations—the

interplay between history, state industrialization plans, and their results. Tracking state plans

through railway sector development also makes visible relationships between early PRC plans

and the project of nation-building. Plans and the processes of their implementation unfolded

differently in different parts of the PRC. This is not indicative of the ‘failure’ of state plans per

se, but rather shows that one objective of early PRC planning was to bring together—or

commensurate—the Chinese nation-state.47

47 The segmented nature of pre-1949 China can be attributed to at least two factors. These include the largely non-modern forms of governance exercised in pre-1949 China, and the nation’s partitioning by imperialist powers.

Page 122: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

116

Finally, before proceeding to the economic accounting system, I will provide a brief

overview of the railway’s role in the early PRC. China’s railways were a key component of early

PRC industrialization plans. In the PRC’s First Five Year Plan (FFYP), railways received 69% of

the total funding allocated to transport and telecommunications development.48 The Ministry of

Railways (铁道部; MOR) was founded ten months prior to the Ministry of Transportation (交通

部; MOT). The MOR existed alongside the MOT until 2013, when the former was dissembled

and partly incorporated into the later. Transportation itself had a key role in early PRC plans.

Early PRC leaders had—following Marx—considered the transportation sector to be one of four

spheres of material production (基本物资生产部门).49 The other three so-considered spheres

were agriculture, industry, and mining. Transportation enables production in the other spheres

and connects them, by moving materials to where they can be further laboured upon.50

Railways had been the primary method of transporting materials for two important

reasons. Firstly, much of what needed to be transported was bulky and heavy, such as the fuel

and machines needed for heavy industry, and crops moving from the countryside into cities.51

Secondly, a key objective of early PRC state plans was to achieve balanced development of the

entire nation.52 Industrial centers were planned in places such as Central China and the

Northwest, away from existing production centers in China’s coast and the Northeast.53 A

reliable method was therefore needed for the long-distance transport of materials and machinery

into hitherto underdeveloped areas. According to the FFYP, a study had shown that at the time,

48 PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957., 1956, 139–42. 49 Peng, 第一个五年计划中的铁路建设 [Railway Construction in the First Five Year Plan], 1–4. See also: Karl Marx, Theories of Surplus Value (Prometheus Books, 2000). 50 Peng, 第一个五年计划中的铁路建设 [Railway Construction in the First Five Year Plan], 1–2. 51 PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957., 1956, 142; MOR Planning Division [铁道部计划司], 全国铁路历史统计资料汇编 1949-1991 (Beijing, China: 中华人民共和国铁道部 [PRC MOR], 1992). 52 See discussions in: Peng, 第一个五年计划中的铁路建设 [Railway Construction in the First Five Year Plan], 2–3; Nicholas R. Lardy, Economic Growth and Distribution in China (Cambridge University Press, 1978); Lippit, “Development of Transportation in Communist China.” 53 Peng, 第一个五年计划中的铁路建设 [Railway Construction in the First Five Year Plan], 2–3.

Page 123: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

117

the railway carried over 80% of freight travelling by modern transport methods.54 In 1949, the

Minister of Railways, Teng Daiyuan, stated that the railway’s crucial contribution to national

development was to increase the ratio and speed of cargo turnover in relation to cost.

Consequently, the main goal for the PRC railway system was to raise efficiency and lower

cost.55 The stage was therefore set for the introduction of the economic accounting system.

In the Chinese context, the concept of economic accounting systems was first referenced

by Mao in 1942, while addressing a conference of cadres in Yan’an. Mao’s speech concerned the

economic development of CCP base areas. Mao stated the need to “[e]stablish the system of

economic accounting (经济核算制), [in order to] overcome the muddled situation within the

enterprises”. Mao went on to list several steps needed to establish this system, concluding that

“[o]nce we have a strict accounting system, we can examine fully whether an enterprise is

profitably operated or not.”56 Kwang surmises that in the early PRC, the economic accounting

system operated to ensure the “attainment of maximum economic results from a minimum

expenditure of labor and capital”—subject of course to the directives of state plans and

planners.57

The system of economic accounting was therefore key to the PRC’s plans for rapid and

frugal industrialization. This system is also the very tool that makes possible state planning and

local production according to plan. State plans are produced through lower levels making

calculations of maximum output (of production, profit, labour productivity, etc.) from minimum

input; higher levels can also ‘double-check’ these calculations. Once calculated and approved,

these figures provide the guiding framework for enterprises in their daily operations. For these

54 PRC, First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic of China in 1953-1957., 1956, 142. 55 “要办好人民铁道 须解决六个问题 [For Well-Functioning Chinese Railways, Resolve Six Problems].” 56 Mao, Economic and Financial Problems during the Anti-Japanese War, and Other Articles., 161. 57 Kwang, The Economic Accounting System of State Enterprises in Mainland China, 1966, 80.

Page 124: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

118

reasons, the system of economic accounting was often referred to as the ‘basic mechanism’ (基

本方法) or ‘central link’ (主要环节) of the early PRC’s planned economy.58

In the early PRC, there were some discussions about the relationship of economic

accounting systems to socialism, the particular system of social and economic organization. For

instance, was the economic accounting system merely a method of economic calculation? Or did

the system enable a set of relationships—between enterprises and the state, between workers and

their workplaces—that were unique to socialism?59 Early PRC authors usually traced the

economic accounting system to the Soviet Union.60 It is very likely that the particular

combinations of calculations contained within the system—and especially its role in the state

planned economy—had been unique Soviet innovations. However, there are certainly similarities

in form and function between the economic accounting system and management and accounting

systems used by American enterprises after the 1900s. The numerical commensuration and cost-

saving aspects of the economic accounting system particularly resembles Return on Investment

(ROI) measurements pioneered by the DuPont Company and later adopted as standard American

corporate practice.61 In the Chinese context, more philosophical questions were soon replaced by

practical discussions of how to implement the system, including how to mitigate existing and

anticipated challenges.62

In the PRC, the first directive for implementing the economic accounting system came in

April 1951 from the Finance and Economic Committee of the Central People’s Government (中

央政府政务院财政经济委员会). This directive specified five methods for establishing the

system in state industrial enterprises. These were: (1) planned management involving targets for

58 Kwang, The Economic Accounting System of State Enterprises in Mainland China, 1966; Xue, “关于在国家银行推行经济核算制的意见 [Comments on the National Bank's implementing of the economic accounting system],” 中国金融 [China Finance], no. 12 (1951): 1–2. 59 Kwang, The Economic Accounting System of State Enterprises in Mainland China, 1966; Xue, “关于在国家银行推行经济核算制的意见 [Comments on the National Bank's implementing of the economic accounting system].” 60 Jiang, “经济核算 [Economic accounting],” 中国金融 [China Finance], no. 12 (1951): 3–4+13; Xue, “关于在国家银行推行经济核算制的意见”; Zhang, “论新民主主义经济核算制度 [Discussing the economic accounting system of the new democracy],” 厦门大学学报 [Xiamen University Newspaper], no. 01 (1952): 59–64. 61 Kaplan, “The Evolution of Management Accounting,” 387–98. 62 Kwang, The Economic Accounting System of State Enterprises in Mainland China, 1966, 62.

Page 125: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

119

production, labour productivity, and cost reduction; (2) determination of required amount of

working and fixed capital for each enterprise; (3) establishment of independent accounting

systems and the assuming of responsibility by enterprise managers for performance; (4) granting

enterprises the right to enter into contracts for purchases and sales; and (5) institution of factory

bonus fund for overfulfillment of profit plans.63 The content of this early directive closely

matches what Taylor had identified as necessary components of scientific management systems.

In Taylor’s account, these were: formalized planning, standardized accounting and production

processes, functional foremen with specialized expertise, and incentive wage schemes.64

One crucial aspect present in the early PRC directive but missing from Taylor’s

prescriptions is the need to determine and establish sufficient funds. Mao had listed this step first

when discussing the implementation of economic accounting systems in CCP base areas.

Sufficient funds were needed so that, according to Mao, “production is not frequently hindered

through capital problems.”65 The absence of this step from Taylor’s discussion suggests that

operational inefficiency linked to capital shortage had not been a concern for American

corporations. One other requirement of economic accounting systems appears in neither Taylor’s

account nor the 1951 directive from the Finance and Economic Committee. This is the shaping

of workers into plan- and goal-oriented subjects; those who would be properly incentivized by

incentive wage structures. Mao had initially spoken on this topic in 1942. For Mao,

implementing the economic accounting system involved “improv[ing] the work of the workers’

congress (职工会)”. Mao elaborated:

“Work done by the workers' congress which is not suitable for raising labour discipline and activism must be changed. Within a factory, the work of the administration, Party branch and workers’ congress must be united towards common ends. These common ends are to save as much as possible on costs (raw materials, tools and other expenses), to make as many and as good products as possible, and to sell them as quickly and as profitably as possible. […] Finally the factory should reward the workers and employees with the greatest achievements, and criticize or punish workers and employees who

63 Ibid., 78. 64 Daniel. Nelson, Frederick W. Taylor and the Rise of Scientific Management (Madison, Wis.: University of Wisconsin Press, 1980), 102. 65 Mao, Economic and Financial Problems during the Anti-Japanese War, and Other Articles., 43.

Page 126: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

120

commit errors. Without a suitable system of rewards and punishments, we cannot ensure the improvement of labour discipline and labour enthusiasm.”66

Mao’s candor here—about the need to shape workers—was rarely seen again from PRC state

leaders in the two decades after 1949. In the early PRC, official (and popular) discourses

advocating forms of change or improvement were usually aimed at leaders, party members, and

managers (or cadres), rather than workers.67

Here it is useful to pause and revisit some elements of ‘irrational’ socialism discourses.

For Mises and his intellectual progeny, practices of state socialism are deemed ‘irrational’

because they contravene natural processes. Part of the ‘nature’ that is in question for Mises is

human nature. For Mises, socialism imposes upon and contravenes man’s ‘natural’ tendency to

maximize his own individual pursuit of value. Socialism consequently—will—fail because

man’s essential nature cannot be converted to one that seeks shared value. Misesean predictions

about socialist failure are already untenable due to their assumptions about capitalism. Western

capitalism, characterized by its industries and corporations, is not a system where each individual

pursues the maximization of his own value. What is additionally untenable is of course the

Misesean understanding of state socialism.

State socialism arose out of the experience of capitalist exploitation and the attempt at

self-defense. When looking closely at the specific mechanisms and operations of early PRC state

plans, it becomes clear that state socialism was not aimed at the conversion of capitalist human

nature to one more suited to socialism. Early PRC state plans aimed to, first of all, create the

kind of self-conscious and calculating subject that began emerging in the West more than a

hundred and fifty years ago—at the dawn of the Industrial Revolution.68 This subject (or the

‘ought’ nature of its existence) could already be taken for granted by Taylor, writing in the U.S.

between 1890 and 1920. In the early PRC, the ‘new’ subject in formation was expected to

66 Ibid. 67 These dynamics are particularly visible in events around the Cultural Revolution (CR). See discussions of the CR in: Lowell Dittmer, Liu Shaoqi and the Chinese Cultural Revolution (M.E. Sharpe, 1998); Wu, The Cultural Revolution at the Margins, 2014. 68 See discussions in: Michel Foucault, The Government of Self and Others: Lectures at the College de France, 1982-1983 (Macmillan, 2011); Nikolas Rose, “Government, Authority and Expertise in Advanced Liberalism,” Economy and Society 22, no. 3 (1993): 283–99.

Page 127: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

121

simultaneously learn the skills for and value productivity, while re-inhabiting—or creating

anew—the forms of collectivity that more easily accompanied pre-industrial societies, with their

lesser degree of functional differentiation.69 And all of this from a starting condition of scarcity.

To compare the two sets of programs—Taylor’s and those of early PRC leaders—for

establishing enterprise management systems makes it clear that one objective of state socialist

planning had been to get to the level of, or ‘catch up’ with, Western capitalism.70 The enterprises

that early PRC plans sought to act upon lacked two important pre-existing conditions of

American corporations in the early 1900s. These were: a sufficient amount of capital, and the

taken-for-granted presence of individuated and plan-following workers. The ‘backwards’

conditions of early PRC state enterprises gave rise to two key aspects related to the efficiency of

socialist planned economies. I have earlier referenced or suggested these aspects of state socialist

economic operations elsewhere. It is however worthwhile to reiterate the two before discussing

the implementation of the economic accounting system in the early PRC railway sector. But first,

a few words on the idea of ‘backwardness’.

In much of contemporary Western academic literature, the PRC’s initial

‘backwardness’—if mentioned—is usually viewed as an intrinsic characteristic of the nation-

state.71 Thus internalized, China’s ‘backwardness’ can co-exist with the ‘irrational’ socialism of

the early PRC state. Both can be attributed to poor decision-making on the part of the Chinese.

On the other hand, if ‘backwardness’ is instead understood to be a condition imposed onto

China, then it becomes possible to see early PRC state actions as actively responding to, if

constrained by, these conditions. It is this second understanding of early PRC ‘backwardness’

that has two important implications for how to think about the efficiency of state socialist

economies. Firstly, conditions of ‘backwardness’ (or scarcity) and the need to ‘catch up’ meant

that the conservation and efficient use of resources had been the paramount concern for early

PRC leaders, planners, and managers. Secondly, what appear to Western eyes to be incidences of

69 Emile Durkheim, The Division of Labor in Society (New York: Simon and Schuster, 2014). 70 After all, an important slogan during the Great Leap Forward had been Mao’s statement that in terms of steel production, China would surpass Britain and catch up with the USA in fifteen years. 71 Lin, Cai, and Li, The China Miracle, 2003, 30–35; Zhenhua Chen and Kingsley E. Haynes, Chinese Railways in the Era of High-Speed (Emerald Group Publishing Limited, 2015), 3–5.

Page 128: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

122

inefficient resource use and waste can often be traced to the early PRC’s ‘backwardness’, or a

condition of lacking capital, technology, and the calculating and individuated subjects called

forth by capitalism. These two aspects of the early PRC’s planned economy both call into

question ideas about ‘irrational’ socialism. These ideas tie the ‘failure’ of state socialism to its

alleged lack of economic mechanisms, inefficient resource allocation, and corresponding

production of waste. Both implications of the PRC’s ‘backwardness’—the state’s concern with

conservation and the ‘in formation’ nature of its systems—can be seen from events surrounding

the implementation of the economic accounting system in the early PRC railway sector.

The PRC railway sector began its own set of discussions about implementing the

economic accounting system in 1951. The earliest publicized call for the sector-wide

implementation of the system came from Minister Teng Daiyuan in June 1951, in the form of an

editorial published in the People’s Daily (人民日报).72 Teng wrote that the issue of economic

accounting systems had been raised at the February meeting of railway bureau chiefs (管理局长

会议). The attendees had agreed that the system of economic accounting would be implemented

in all railway management bureaus across the country, starting on July 1, 1951. The

implementation process was to be completed within the next two years.73 Teng’s editorial also

discussed why, at that time, the economic accounting system had become necessary to the state

railway sector. Teng’s article was accompanied by a set of others about how to implement the

economic accounting system and its importance to the PRC railways.74 I will return to these

discussions later. I first take a look at events that prefigured Teng’s announcement.

72 Daiyuan Teng, “经济核算制是经营管理人民铁路的基本方法 [The Economic Accounting System Is the Basic Method of Operations Management for the People’s Railways],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], June 21, 1951, sec 1. 73 Ibid.; Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 30–31. 74 “铁道部决定自七月一日起全国各铁路管理局实行经济核算制度 [MOR Issues Nation-Wide Directive for Railway Bureaus to Implement the Economic Accounting System, Starting on July 1]”; Ruilin Cao, “天津铁路管理局丰台机务段 忽视了对职工进行思想教育 经济核算准备工作走了弯路 [The Fengtai Locomotive Section of the Tianjin Railway Bureau Neglected the Task of Educating Workers, Implementing the Economic Accounting System Has Gone Awry],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], June 10, 1951, sec 2; Xinhua News Agency, “铁道部召开全国铁路管理局长会议 决定贯彻经济核算制的办法 批判了供给制思想和本位主义思想 [MOR Hosted a National Meeting of Railway Bureau Chiefs, Decided to Implement Economic Accounting System. Criticized the Supply System Way of Thinking and Narrow Pragmatism],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], July 19, 1951, sec 2; “铁路部门实

Page 129: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

123

A July 1951 article in the People’s Daily casted railway sector activities in the previous

three years as preparatory work (准备工作) for the implementation of the economic accounting

system.75 According to the article, this preparatory work consisted of three sets of activities. The

first had been the democratic reform of railway workplaces. I referred to this set of reforms

earlier, when discussing CCP influences on the formation of the early PRC railway sector. I

provide more details here. A key part of railway workplace reform was to find and struggle

against counter-revolutionary elements. These elements were not restricted to the corporal bodies

of the enemy; they can also be present in the thoughts and habits of otherwise good people.76

Consequently, democratic reforms involved the reading of revolutionary documents (e.g. the

writings of Marx; Mao), and self- and group-study sessions.77 Through structural reform of

workplaces and thought-reform of management and workers, the early PRC state aimed to

eliminate previous forms of worker exploitation. These included the contract work (包工)

system, where contracts and wages for a group of workers were given to the gang boss in

charge.78

As a part of workplace reforms, workers were also mobilized to discuss working

conditions, structures, and wages. These discussions both informed and provided consent for the

implementation of new forms of work organization and wage structures.79 Workplaces were also

行经济核算制前作了一系列必需的准备工作 [A Series of Preparatory Work Is Required before Implementing the Economic Accounting System in the Railway Sector].” 75 “铁路部门实行经济核算制前作了一系列必需的准备工作 [A Series of Preparatory Work Is Required before Implementing the Economic Accounting System in the Railway Sector].” 76 See for instance the discussion in: Liu Shaoqi, How to be a Good Communist (Beijing: Foreign Language Press, 1949). 77 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 31–33; Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1996, 1343–60. 78 Tongwei Liu, ed., 铁路修建史料第三集 1949-1962 [The Third Series of Historical Materials on Railway Construction, 1949-1962], vol. 第四册 [Volume four] (Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1964); Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 31–33; Ji Chen, “专靠包商是做不好工程建设的---记西北铁路干线工程局盲目依靠包商的恶果 [Construction Projects That Rely on Contract Labour Will Not Go Well--the Northwest Railway Bureau Reflects on Bad Results],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], August 7, 1951, sec 2. 79 Takahara, The Politics of Wage Policy in Post-Revolutionary China, 1992, 11–18; Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 791–800.

Page 130: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

124

encouraged to establish democratic forms of management, such as governance through elected

management committees (管理委员会) and workers’ representative assemblies (职工代表会).80

Many workers who had been active in reform discussions and representative assemblies were

promoted to manager (干部) positions.81 Democratic reforms—and certainly those in the West—

are not (solely) concerned with fair governance. These reforms shape subjects, by producing and

modeling self-conscious and deliberative behaviours.82 The subject-shaping function of the

above-discussed education and struggle sessions is perhaps even more obvious. The shaping of

certain kinds of worker-subjects was therefore one form of preparatory work for implementing

the economic accounting system in the early PRC railway sector.

Another set of preparatory activities was the reforming of railway financial systems.83

The state planned economy required the railway system to operate with centralized procedures

and de-centralized responsibility. In order to implement the economic accounting system in the

PRC railway sector, each railway enterprise needed to be able to calculate its own profits and

losses, while sharing uniform methods of calculation with all other railway enterprises. In the

railway system of Republican China, each line had its own methods of determining profits and

losses. Some railway calculations at this time were still being conducted by foreign accounting

offices.84 Different railway lines also calculated these items at different time intervals.85 In

addition, while individual railway lines had been the main economic entities in the Republican

system, this spot went to railway bureaus in the early PRC’s planned economy.

80 Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution, 1977, 43–52; Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 791–800. 81 Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 960–69; Fan, 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988], 1995, 600–616; Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1996, 1205–7. 82 Jürgen Habermas, The Structural Transformation of the Public Sphere: An Inquiry into a Category of Bourgeois Society (MIT press, 1991); Rose, “Government, Authority and Expertise in Advanced Liberalism.” 83 “铁路部门实行经济核算制前作了一系列必需的准备工作 [A Series of Preparatory Work Is Required before Implementing the Economic Accounting System in the Railway Sector].” 84 Chang, China’s Struggle for Railroad Development, 1943, 153–72. 85 Jui-te Chang, “Technology Transfer in Modern China: The Case of Railway Enterprise (1876-1937),” Modern Asian Studies 27, no. 2 (1993): 283–88.

Page 131: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

125

The railway bureaus were standardized in their form and function, each containing the

same numbers and types of departments (e.g. transportation order, locomotive, infrastructure,

accounting, etc.). The bureaus consequently formed central hubs for supervising and directing

diverse kinds of railway work. However, in the initial transition from the Republican system,

each railway management bureau had no way of independently calculating its own profits and

losses: these were calculated in aggregate by each railway line.86 To establish independent—yet

commensurate—accounting systems for each railway enterprise was therefore another way of

preparing for the implementation of the economic accounting system. Railway sector financial

reforms proceeded via the issuing and implementation of a set of policies in January 1950, and

again in January 1951.87 In a sense, the production of independent yet commensurate enterprises

for the purposes of early PRC planning mirrored the production of independent yet

commensurate human subjects for the same purpose.

The third set of preparatory activities—as discussed in the July 1951 People’s Daily

article—involved finding, collecting, and making inventory of assets. This process was required

in order to establish the amount of working and liquid capital (in funds and assets) available to

each enterprise. The process of finding and collecting railway assets had began prior to the end

of the Civil War. After the MOR was founded in January 1949, the Ministry had faced an acute

shortage of materials.88 In September 1949, the MOR promulgated a policy of ‘collecting assets

and protecting the railways’ (搜集铁路器材及保护铁路). In order to ensure uninterrupted

military transport and railway-driven economic development, all people were asked to help

railway bureaus to collect and protect any railway materials and equipment, including those left

behind and scattered in the open, existing in public or private collections, or being sold in

markets. The MOR policy had pertained to (1) railway track materials, (2) communications

86 “铁路部门实行经济核算制前作了一系列必需的准备工作 [A Series of Preparatory Work Is Required before Implementing the Economic Accounting System in the Railway Sector]”; MOR Materials Bureau Communications Group, “清理资材,核定资金,反对浪费![Sort Materials, Determine Available Capital, Fight Waste!].” 87 “铁路部门实行经济核算制前作了一系列必需的准备工作 [A Series of Preparatory Work Is Required before Implementing the Economic Accounting System in the Railway Sector]”; Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 777–97. 88 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 22–25; Junzheng Jiang, “节约金属是国民经济的重要任务,” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], February 27, 1949, sec 3.

Page 132: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

126

materials, (3) vehicle materials, (4) signal and lighting materials, and (5) water supply

materials.89

The practice of mobilizing the population for finding and collecting railway assets

continued into the post-war recovery period. Alongside practices of mass salvaging in the early

PRC, there was also an emphasis placed on saving and re-using railway materials. A People’s

Daily article published in May 1950 contained exhaustive instructions on how to classify waste

materials, as well as how to repair and make use of items in various states of damage. Items

addressed in the article included iron scrapings, springs, hooks, wheels, various tools, and many

others.90 Between April 1950 and July 1951, the MOR led a nation-wide process of finding and

inventorying assets in the PRC railway sector.91 In this fifteen-month period, railway workplaces

processed in total 20,000 tons of unused goods, 3,300 tons of goods existing outside of settled

accounts, and 143,700 tons of waste materials.92 In July 1951, the total value of inventoried,

donated, and collected assets in the railway sector reached over 452 billion RMB (or 45 million

in post-1955 RMB values).93 This sum—deriving from mass practices of salvaging and saving—

would provide the fixed and circulating assets needed to implement economic accounting

systems in the early PRC railway sector.

While the above forms of preparatory activities were underway, two other sets of events

in the PRC railway sector foreshadowed the coming call for sector-wide implementation of the

economic accounting system. The first is the MOR’s movement towards a more formalized

89 People’s Railway News Group, “军委铁道部制定办法 搜集保护铁路交通器材 全国军民应一致协助各路局收集 [MOR Formulates Measures to Gather and Protect Railway Transport Equipment, All Mobilized Masses Asked to Help Railway Bureaus with Collection].” 90 Wenxiang Wang, “怎样利用铁路废料 [How to Make Use of Railway Waste],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], May 26, 1950, sec 5. 91 MOR Technology Research Communications Group, “铁道部铁道技术研究所介绍 [Introducing MOR Technology Institute]”; “天津铁路局进行工作大检查 杜绝浪费厉行节约 [Tianjin Railway Bureau Carried out a Large Inspecton, to Oppose Waste and Practice Strict Economy],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], March 21, 1950, sec 1; Xinhua News Agency, “郑州铁路管理局大力收集遗散器材 [Zhengzhou Railway Bureau Makes a Great Effort to Collect Scattered and Left-behind Equipment],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], March 24, 1950, sec 1. 92 “铁路部门实行经济核算制前作了一系列必需的准备工作 [A Series of Preparatory Work Is Required before Implementing the Economic Accounting System in the Railway Sector].” 93 In 1955, the PRC issued the new RMB series, which has been in use since. 1 RMB (Yuan) = 10,000 old Yuan. See: Lin, Cai, and Li, The China Miracle, 2003, 42.

Page 133: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

127

planning process for the railway sector. By late 1950, the MOR had already established and

implemented nationally-unified systems for items such as transportation order, schedule, rates,

car-loading procedures, etc. The MOR had also promulgated national policies for accounting and

financial procedures, including how to calculate cost and profit. 94 The stage was set for the

making of a detailed national plan, with inputs from and output targets for railway enterprises. In

fall 1950, when the MOR had been in the process of drafting its 1951 plan, an article appeared in

the People’s Daily about the need to implement more specific planning and accounting

procedures in the state railway sector.95

Also in fall 1950, the Qiqihar Railway Management Bureau began to implement the

system of economic accounting in its operations.96 Qiqihar, located in China’s Northeast, was a

key city traversed by the China Eastern Railway (later known as the Zhongchang Railway). The

Qiqihar Bureau had been created by the CCP during its Civil War-era dalliance with railways in

China’s Northeast.97 The bureau’s implementation of the economic accounting system had been

publicized by the political department of Northeast Railways (东北铁路政治部). This decision

was attributed to the drawbacks of the previously-existing budgetary system, referred to as the

supply system (供给制).

According to published accounts, the issue with the supply system is as follows. When a

functional body within the railway enterprise needed to complete a task (e.g. the infrastructure

section needs to fix tracks), its members would request funding from the authorizing party (e.g.

94 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 30–45; 1956 年全国铁路先进生产者代表会议选编:财务会计先进经验 [Selection from the 1956 National Conference of Advanced Railway Production Representatives: Best Practices of Financial Accounting] (Beijing, China: 人民铁道出版社 [The People’s Railway Press], 1956). 95 Yin Lin, “全国铁路工作中存在严重偏向 单纯追求数字浪费国家财富 铁道部指示各局立即加以纠正 [National Railway Work Has a Severe Problem with Only Chasing Numbers, Wasting the Nation’s Resources. MOR Instructs Each Railway Bureau to Immediately Correct Problem],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], September 7, 1950, sec 2. 96 Northeast Railway Political Department, “齐齐哈尔铁路局 检查纠正供给思想坚决实行经济核算 [The Qiqihar Railway Bureau Inspected and Corrected Supply-System Thinking, Determined to Implement Economic Accounting System],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], October 22, 1950, sec 2; Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1996, 1160–93. 97 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 22–24.

Page 134: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

128

Bureau Chief, Chief Accountant, etc.). The largest concern of the requesting party was usually

having enough money to complete the task, so they would ask for more than what was needed.

The authorizing party in turn does not check or calculate the details of the request, and instead

“blindly” (盲目的) trusts the requester. The ‘supply system’ kind of thinking (供给制思想) is

criticized for solely focusing on the task at hand, not making calculations, and not seeing the

larger picture (of the national economy).98 In the Qiqihar Bureau, this type of action had wasted

money by spending more than what was needed. Consequently, for the second half of 1950, the

Bureau had incurred 300 million RMB (30,000 RMB in post-1955 values) more in expenses than

budgeted.99 To remedy the situation, the Qiqihar Bureau had adopted the system of economic

accounting. Starting in late 1950, a number of articles appearing in PRC publications made

similar points to the Qiqihar account—about the drawbacks of the supply system.100

With preparatory measures—the making of responsible subjects, independent accounting

systems, and finding sufficient assets—well underway, the early PRC railway sector was ready

to begin the formal process of planning. The supply system of budgeting had proved itself

incompatible with early PRC state goals for plan-abiding and efficient production. The railway

sector was ready for a new system. In advocating for the economic accounting system, Teng—in

his editorial—also highlighted the drawbacks of the existing supply system. Teng began his

narrative with the February meeting of Bureau Chiefs, where participants agreed to the sector-

wide implementation of the economic accounting system. Teng proceeded to state:

98 Northeast Railway Political Department, “齐齐哈尔铁路局 检查纠正供给思想坚决实行经济核算 [The Qiqihar Railway Bureau Inspected and Corrected Supply-System Thinking, Determined to Implement Economic Accounting System]”; Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 30–34. 99 Northeast Railway Political Department, “齐齐哈尔铁路局 检查纠正供给思想坚决实行经济核算 [The Qiqihar Railway Bureau Inspected and Corrected Supply-System Thinking, Determined to Implement Economic Accounting System].” 100 Xinhua News Agency, “铁道部召开全国铁路管理局长会议 决定贯彻经济核算制的办法 批判了供给制思想和本位主义思想 [MOR Hosted a National Meeting of Railway Bureau Chiefs, Decided to Implement Economic Accounting System. Criticized the Supply System Way of Thinking and Narrow Pragmatism]”; Teng, “经济核算制是经营管理人民铁路的基本方法 [The Economic Accounting System Is the Basic Method of Operations Management for the People’s Railways]”; “中央人民政府铁道部 关于一九五零年工作总结与一九五一年计划的报告 [MOR Report on the Work Completed in 1950 and Plans for 1951],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], March 29, 1951, sec 2; Shanxi Daily, “彻底批判供给制思想,树立经济核算制观点 [Thoroughly criticize supply-system thinking, establish the economic accounting system perspective],” 山西日报, no. 05 (1953): 50–51.

Page 135: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

129

“We all agreed that railway work over the last year had many achievements, but there were also many shortcomings. Only the economic accounting system can help us overcome these shortcomings. We can see this by looking at the situations of Dongbei Railway and Zhongchang Railway. Dongbei Railway in the past years have produced a great many results; the enthusiasm of the masses (群众热情) is very high. But for some leading cadres, this produced a state of complacent satisfaction. […] Their passive approach to work has become clear in the past year, with tasks going uncompleted in the past winter and this spring. On the other hand, the Sino-Soviet jointly managed Zhongchang Railway has operated with an economic accounting system from the beginning. In the past year, all aspects of work on the Zhongchang Railway has shown significant development. This example shows us that in the process of constructing our People’s Railway, the implementation of economic accounting system is not only necessary, but also possible.”101

The implementation of the economic accounting system in all railway bureaus was slated

to begin on July 1, 1951.102 To enable the operations of this new system, railway bureaus were

granted a new set of rights and responsibilities—becoming a new kind of subject in relation to

the state. After July 1, 1951, the PRC’s railway bureaus (1) had the responsibility of fulfilling the

MOR-approved transport plan (运输计划) as their most important task; (2) had independent

economic rights in implementing production and financial plans; (3) had an independent

accounting system and legal status; had the right to use fixed capital and allocate liquid capital;

had the right to borrow from banks and enter into contracts with other enterprises; (4) were

required to make all efforts to fulfill or overfulfill production plan, reduce waste, decrease cost,

increase profit, and increase fund accumulation.103

Thus began a more intensive process of shaping railway enterprises into components of

the state economic plan. Beginning in 1949, PRC railway enterprises had been organized into a

three-level structure. The body with the most authority (highest level) is the railway bureau (铁

路局). Directly subordinate to the railway bureau—in the second level—are different functional

departments (处) (e.g. departments for transport organization, rolling stock, railway

101 Teng, “经济核算制是经营管理人民铁路的基本方法 [The Economic Accounting System Is the Basic Method of Operations Management for the People’s Railways].” 102 Ibid.; Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 22–26. 103 “铁道部决定自七月一日起全国各铁路管理局实行经济核算制度 [MOR Issues Nation-Wide Directive for Railway Bureaus to Implement the Economic Accounting System, Starting on July 1].”

Page 136: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

130

infrastructure, material acquisitions, accounting, finance, etc.). The railway sub-bureaus (铁路分

局) also exist on the second level. They are considered the functional department in charge of

transportation order. Each functional department then has authority over grassroots (基层) level

organizations, which include stations (subordinate to railway sub-bureaus) and work sections (段

).104 A similar structure consisting of three or two levels had also existed in the railway system of

Republican China.105

The introduction of the economic accounting system—and subsequent enrollment of

railway enterprises into state planning processes—produced a new set of relationships between

different railway entities. Functional differentiations in the PRC railway sector became much

more prominent in the initial years after implementing the economic accounting system. During

the post-war recovery period, railway enterprises had largely operated through collective

management.106 For railway bureaus, the management committee would usually consist of the

Bureau Chief and a small number of each of the following: technical specialists, party members,

and workers. Some railway enterprises, such as the Tianjin Railway Bureau, had established

governance through decision-making by the workers’ representative assembly.107 During this

period, workers had a relatively large degree of control over items such as workload, working

conditions, timeline, etc. Workers—in work sections—could also speak and bargain with the

department in charge.108

With the implementation of the economic accounting system, and especially during the

first years of its operations (or the period of the First Five Year Plan), workplace functions and

104 Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 793, 949; Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1996, 239, 243, 279. 105 Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 793. 106 Gong and Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994], 1996, 1070–75; Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 791–800, 1200–1215; Akio Takahara, The Politics of Wage Policy in Post-Revolutionary China (Springer, 1992), 11–23. 107 Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 791–815. 108 Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution, 1977, 45–52.

Page 137: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

131

responsibilities in the PRC became more rigid and fixed.109 The priority placed on accurate

calculations and plan fulfillment gave key roles to the financial, accounting, and other technical

departments of railway enterprises.110 Grassroots sections became more subordinated to the

decisions and directives of these departments. Workers’ representative congresses and other

bodies fostering worker participation in management ceased to meet during the FFYP.111 Some

railway enterprises implemented the one-leader system (一长制). In this system, the leader of

each railway entity (e.g. department, section, bureau) assumes all rights and responsibilities for

that particular entity. Rights and responsibilities are also distributed hierarchically—for instance,

the Bureau Chief assumes all rights and responsibilities over all departments, including their

department heads.112 This system produced an additional degree of specialization and separation.

PRC state leaders called for an end to the one-leader system in state enterprises in 1956.113 Other

developments after the FFYP (e.g. the Great Leap Forward) were devised to address what

became seen as an overly large degree of specialization and differentiation.

The implementation of the economic accounting system and related elements—such as

the one-leader system—proceeded differently in different locations and for different enterprises.

As previous mentioned, some railway enterprises, such as the Beijing Railway Bureau and the

Kunming Railway Bureau, chose not to adopt the one-leader system.114 The implementation of

the economic accounting system in railway bureaus was scheduled to happen within two years of

July 1, 1951. But each railway bureau was granted the freedom and flexibility of implementing

109 Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 791–805; Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution, 1977, 50–75; Meisner, “The Shenyang Transformer Factory--A Profile,” 1972, 728–29. 110 Cao, “天津铁路管理局丰台机务段 忽视了对职工进行思想教育 经济核算准备工作走了弯路 [The Fengtai Locomotive Section of the Tianjin Railway Bureau Neglected the Task of Educating Workers, Implementing the Economic Accounting System Has Gone Awry]”; Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution, 1977, 50–75. 111 Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 1200–1215; Shuqing Gong and Shutian Li, 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway Bureau 1896-1994] (Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1996), 1343–80. 112 Schurmann, Ideology and Organization in Communist China, 235, 260–82. 113 Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution, 1977, 38–60; Takahara, The Politics of Wage Policy in Post-Revolutionary China, 1992, 38–44. 114 Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 791; Kejing Fan, ed., 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988] (Chengdu, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1995), 93.; Kunming ju

Page 138: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

132

the system however it saw fit, and on its own timeline.115 External events also interfered with

MOR plans, such as the Korean War and the role that Chinese railway workers came to play in

it.116 Consequently, some railway bureaus were still in the course of implementing the economic

accounting system after 1955.117

I proceed now to present a brief snapshot of the implementation process. I provide some

details about local processes; I also address sector-wide progress. The Beijing Railway Bureau

began to test out the system of economic accounting at the bureau and sub-bureau levels in July

1951. Between 1953 and 1957, the Beijing Railway Bureau established specialized departments

for planning and statistics. These departments were tasked with producing items such as

transport plans, operations plans, construction plans, operations statistics, salary statistics,

business statistics, etc. Also starting in 1953, the Beijing Bureau began implementing economic

accounting systems at all three levels of the enterprise.118 The Kunming Railway Bureau began

implementing the economic accounting system in 1953, as a part of its plan to ‘learn from

Zhongchang Railway’. The Kunming Bureau started at its grassroots level—the economic

accounting system was first implemented in its twenty-three grassroots work units.119

For both the Kunming Railway Bureau and the Chengdu Railway Bureau, their

implementation of the economic accounting system came after their incorporation into state

planning processes. In 1954, while ‘learning from Zhongchang Railway’, the Chengdu Bureau

had strengthened planned management and began to develop plans in areas such as production,

transportation, operations, worker salary, etc.120 The Chengdu Bureau first tested the economic

accounting system in 1955 at a particular locomotive work section (九龙坡机务段). By October

1956, 91% of all possible work units within the bureau had implemented economic accounting

115 Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 795. 116 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 22–27. 117 Fan, 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988], 1995, 707–25; Xie and Yu, 兰州铁路局志 1956-1995 [Annals of the Lanzhou Railway Bureau, 1956-1995], 635–700. 118 Wang, 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway Administration, 1881-1987], 795, 842. 119 Fan, 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-1988], 1995, 533. 120 Ibid., 510.

Page 139: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

133

systems.121 By the end of 1956, the economic accounting system had been implemented in all

railway bureaus and sub-bureaus across the entire nation. The system had also been implemented

in all railway-sector locomotive and rolling stock departments, and in the large majority of other

railway-sector functional departments.122

A myriad of issues emerged in the course of implementing economic accounting systems

in the early PRC railway sector. In some enterprises, these systems had been implemented

without involving or providing explanations to workers. Workers consequently found it strange

and disruptive for managers to observe and record their actions; cadres in turn lacked a practical

understanding of the task that they observed and could not assess it well.123 In late 1952, the

State Council published a report about a serious issue. Some factory leaders, under slogans such

as “complete the production plan” and “carry out the economic accounting system”, had ordered

large workloads, extended working hours, and failed to heed worker health and safety. This had

caused worker welfare issues, as well as accidents and very serious safety concerns.124 In 1953,

the entire PRC railway sector came under criticism for the practice of “blindly” soliciting

transport business in order to increase profits, without considering how such transport

contributes to national development—and thus disrupting national plans.125 It would of course be

difficult to attribute these issues to the system of state socialism (especially when juxtaposed to

capitalism). They could perhaps be linked to the early PRC’s ‘backwardness’, or inexperience in

carrying out production plans. But the above incidents would not seem out of place in ‘advanced’

capitalist states.

121 Ibid., 535. 122 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 45–46. 123 Cao, “天津铁路管理局丰台机务段 忽视了对职工进行思想教育 经济核算准备工作走了弯路 [The Fengtai Locomotive Section of the Tianjin Railway Bureau Neglected the Task of Educating Workers, Implementing the Economic Accounting System Has Gone Awry].” 124 “中央人民政府政务院人民监察委员会 关于处理某些国营、地方国营厂矿企业忽视安全生产致发生重大伤亡事故的通报 [Report from the State Council Inspection and Supervision Committee, on the Subject of How to Handle State- and Local-Run Factories and Mines That Have Neglected Safety, Causing Major Accidents],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], September 17, 1952, sec 1. 125 “铁路系统在一九五二年中盲目运输打乱国家计划 [The Blindly Transporting Activities of the Railway Sector Have Disrupted State Plans for 1952],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], February 25, 1953, sec 1; Yifan Geng, “对盲目招揽货源的检讨 [A Self-Criticism on Blindly Soliciting Business],” 人民日报 [People’s Daily], March 24, 1953, sec 2.

Page 140: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

134

Use of the economic accounting system did help the PRC railway sector to be much more

efficient in its operations. Again, the efficient use of resources had been a key tenet driving early

PRC plans. The economic accounting system had contributed to a large reduction in railway

production costs. In 1956, the operating expenses required to produce 1,000 ton-km of freight

travel was 7.65 RMB. This was a 10.7% decrease from operating expenses in 1952.126 The total

value of railway industry output was 980 million RMB in 1956. This amount almost doubled the

total value of 520 million RMB produced in 1952.127 Total profit for the railway sector was 1.46

billion RMB in 1956. This is a 5.8-fold increase from the 250 million RMB earned in railway-

sector profit in 1952.128 Finally, labour productivity—measured by the ratio of ton-km

production to number of employees—had increased by 160% between 1952 and 1956.129

5. Conclusion State socialism in the early PRC was tied crucially to the shaping of its population. This process

did not resemble the one imaged by Mises, where socialist planners attempted with futility to

convert the essentially capitalist nature of man. Rather, early PRC state socialism had

encouraged the formation of capitalist subjects—humans who were calculating, deliberative, and

oriented to task and plan completion. These budding capitalist subjects were additionally asked

to take into account and consider others (the ‘big picture’).

Chinese state socialism had not particularly failed in its shaping of human nature. The

early PRC largely pursued the Soviet route to economic efficiency—through state planning,

prioritizing calculations, and functional differentiation. The national quest for efficiency was

therefore inseparable from the creation of new kinds of subjects. All manners of statistics and

reports from both inside and outside of China suggests that the early PRC had succeeded in

producing economic efficiency. It follows that the state must have also met with success in

126 Xu and MOR Record Compiling Department, 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50 Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999], 45–46. 127 MOR Planning Division [铁道部计划司], 全国铁路历史统计资料汇编 1949-1991, 182. 128 Ibid., 262. 129 Ibid., 241.

Page 141: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

135

producing the required human subjects. It is perhaps important to note that the ideal subject for

early PRC state plans had shared many similarities with those sculpted by Taylorist programs of

scientific management. To fully draw out the implications of that statement might require

another entire thesis—so I will just leave that idea for now.

In this chapter, I discussed mechanisms of early PRC state planning and their

implementation in the state railway sector. I began with an account of the planning process in the

early PRC. I then used evidence from this process to challenge the second and third sets of ideas

about ‘irrational’ socialism, which revolve around its alleged lack of economic mechanisms,

inefficiency of resource allocation, and corresponding waste. In the last part of this chapter, I

turned to the operations of state plans in the PRC railway sector. I traced the implementation of a

particular mechanism of state planning: the economic accounting system. Processes of

implementing state plans and their mechanisms in the early PRC provide further proof against

ideas about ‘irrational’ socialism.

I think that given the evidence presented by this chapter and the previous two, it is

possible to state conclusively, in the case of state socialism in the PRC at least, that (1) planners

had been rational and produced reasonable plans; (2) resource allocation had been efficient

through the use of economic mechanisms—such as those shared with American corporations;

and (3) economic planning saves resources, materials, and labour.

Page 142: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

136

Chapter V. Conclusion New things always have to experience difficulties and setbacks as they grow. It is sheer fantasy to imagine that the cause of socialism is all plain sailing and easy success, without difficulties and setbacks or the exertion of tremendous efforts.

--Mao Zedong, February 19571

1. Rewind: Summary and arguments This thesis began with my interest in three related topics. These are: socialist industrialization in

the early PRC, Western discourses about ‘irrational’ socialism, and the structures and operations

of the Chinese railway system. I first noted that Western discourses about state socialist

inefficiency and failure revolve around three themes: (1) that planners had been idiosyncratic and

produced irrational plans; (2) that resource allocation had been inefficient due to the absence of

economic mechanisms; and (3) that economic planning produces the waste of resources,

materials, and labour. My discussion of early PRC industrialization then unfolded as a kind of

double-account: I juxtaposed the above narratives with the actual plans, events, and processes of

early PRC development. I used the state railway system as a lens into plans and processes of

industrialization in the early PRC.

In the thesis, Chapter 2 addressed the first set of ideas about irrational socialism. I argued

that ideas about irrational socialist plans are produced through and reproduce the erasure of

Western imperialism. Contemporary Western accounts of the PRC often exclude the nation’s

colonized history. But imperialism had mattered, both materially and politically. In the early

1920s, Sun Yat-sen had calculated China’s annual loss to foreign powers to be around 1.2 billion

Hong Kong dollars, or the equivalent of 600 million U.S. dollars at the time. To put these

numbers into some context: the Nationalist government of the Nanjing Decade (1928-1937)

operated with an annual budget that averaged 806 million Chinese dollars, or the equivalent of

274 million U.S. dollars at the time. Sun and others, including Western historians, thought that

1 Zedong Mao, On the Correct Handling of Contradictions Among the People (Foreign Languages Press, 1957), 43.

Page 143: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

137

the impact of imperialism on China had only been growing. What Marxism, or Marxist-

Leninism, had offered Chinese reformers was precisely a way to analyze and strategize in the

imperialist global context.

Chapters 3 and 4 moved away from discourses and towards events on the ground.

Chapter 3 traced the formation of the early PRC railway sector. The early system incorporated

infrastructures inherited from the Nationalist (GMD) government of late-Republican China,

approaches shaped by the CCP’s history of labour activism and war-time experiences, and the

results of learning from Soviet railway operations. Interactions between the USSR, GMD, and

CCP also compelled the Chinese Communists to innovate new approaches to socialism and. This

new approach is encapsulated in Mao’s idea of the People’s War (人民战争), which combines

knowledge and mastery of the capitalist’s tools with mass participation. The CCP during the

Civil War had prioritized thrift and reciprocity with local populations in its railway-related

activities. The railway system in the early PRC became known as the People’s Railways (人民铁

道). The grounds covered in Chapter 3 provided the context and background for the events and

processes later discussed in Chapter 4.

Chapter 4 focused on the mechanisms of early PRC state planning and their

implementation in the state railway sector. I began by describing the state planning process in the

early PRC. I used evidence from this process to challenge the second and third sets of ideas

about ‘irrational’ socialism, which revolve around its alleged lack of economic mechanisms,

inefficiency of resource allocation, and corresponding waste. In the later part of Chapter 4, I

turned to the local realizations of central plans. I focused in particular on how the economic

accounting system was implemented in the state railway sector. This system was known to be the

mechanism that connected state plans to local production, thereby enabling centrally-planned

production. Processes of state plan implementation in the early PRC make visible a set of

realities that are quite far removed from assumptions made by ‘irrational’ socialism discourses.

Against the backdrop of events discussed in Chapters 3 and 4, I also ask a set of questions about

what was ‘produced’ through the early PRC’s budding state socialist economy. These refer in

particular to the kinds of human subjects that become shaped through the PRC’s new economic

system. These questions are only possible, I think—and not engulfed or distorted—when the

operations of imperialist discourses have been identified and pinned in their place.

Page 144: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

138

The main arguments coming from the above discussions can be summarized in three

interrelated points. One: Contemporary Western critiques of state socialist economies share in a

set of self-referential discourses. These discourses make little sense when questioned because

they exclude (make absent) what is at their logical center—the reproduction of imperialism.

Two: The system of central planning had been adopted by socialist states (e.g. the PRC) for the

very purpose of achieving efficient (and rapid) surplus accumulation. Accumulation enabled

industrialization, a process that is both made necessary and denied to ‘Third World’ states

through imperialism. Three: The operations of the early PRC’s socialist planned economy had

encountered a number of issues and setbacks. These were largely tied to China’s ‘backwardness’,

a concept that encapsulates two aspects of the early PRC. These are: its (1) conditions of

scarcity, and (2) aspirations to ‘catch-up’, or to, in some ways, become like the West. Both

aspects are inextricable from the larger global context. This last point is key for approaching

different narrations of state socialist failure.

In my discussion of the early PRC economy in this thesis, I mostly draw evidence from

events that transpired between 1949-1957. This period saw the set-up and normalization of the

PRC’s planned economy. Common Western discourses on Chinese socialist irrationality and

failure might emphasize the events of the Great Leap Forward (GLF, 1958-1960) and Cultural

Revolution (CC, 1966-1976). For the narratives that I engage the most closely in this thesis, it is

not the ‘excesses’ of the socialist planned economy that were problematic, but rather its very

basic and routine functioning. I think one would often find that, beneath mentions of the ‘crazy’

GLF and CC, lies the notion that the very structure of Chinese socialism is unworkable. It would

be rare, I think, to find someone in the English-speaking world who views the events of the early

PRC as quite reasonable aside from the GLF and CC—who then is also attached to the ideas of

state socialist irrationality and failure.

While the GLF and the CC do not feature prominently in my thesis, they are neither

consciously excluded (e.g. as radically different and therefore negating the idea of early PRC

rationality), nor are they conflated with earlier periods. Some events that I discuss began before

1957, and continued in its aftermath. These include processes of state economic planning, and

the implementation of economic accounting systems in grass-roots work units across the entire

state railway sector. I also make references to certain dynamics that were more prominent during

the post-war recovery period (1949-1952) than during the FFYP, and that resurfaced during the

Page 145: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

139

GLF. These include the idea of the ‘People’s Railway’, and democratic assemblies in

workplaces. My thesis presents Chinese socialism in the early PRC as a confluence of diverse

elements, many of which were experimental and contextual. Very few were, however, irrational

or doomed to failure. It was not the point of this thesis to construct and present one form of early

PRC rationality that challenges Western narratives about socialist ‘irrationality’. But it was the

point of this thesis to make a set of arguments. The overarching one is perhaps that the early

PRC’s trajectory cannot be understood independently from plans and processes of production—

which were in turn shaped by histories and ongoing contexts of imperialism.

2. Stakes, part one: On knowledge I draw here from Said to clarify the approaches and stakes of my project. Said argued that

Orientalism, the system of knowledge, “is more particularly valuable as a sign of European-

Atlantic power over the Orient than it is as a veridic discourse about the Orient (which is what, in

its academic or scholarly form, it claims to be).” Said therefore dissected Orientalist discourses

in order to articulate the forms and operations of a particular system of power. It was not my

original intention to trace in detail the operations of imperialist power. I arrived at the need to

untangle Western discourses on state socialism after realizing what Said had assumed from the

very start, which is the distance of these discourses from what they purport to describe. I am not

particularly interested in drawn out discussions or debates about imperialism. It happened. Its

destructive effects are well-documented. It is not particularly interesting or intellectually

productive to dismiss or trivialize its effects. But the absenting of this history has produced a set

of misleading and vacuous discourses that stand in for substantial English-language research and

analysis of the early PRC economy.

If my main goals in this research lie to the side of rehashing what are already well-

substantiated and well-explained arguments about Western power, I am also not particularly

driven by the need to ‘speak truth to power’. As Said cautioned, “One ought never to assume that

the structure of Orientalism is nothing more than a structure of lies or of myths which, were the

truth about them to be told, would simply blow away.” Instead, I was primarily looking to learn

about the logic and processes of industrialization in the early PRC. I was also interested in the

Page 146: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

140

implications that these events might have for understanding (1) the possibilities and trajectories

for state socialist projects, and (2) later developments in the PRC. But my very basic quest to

learn took a substantial detour once it became obvious that a large gap existed between

narrations of early PRC development that I encountered ‘in the field’, and those existing in

contemporary English-language accounts. My time in Beijing also reminded me that Western

knowledge about China continues to be produced through—and reproduce—a field of unequal

power. But this is not an argument about the impossibility of learning or producing non-

imperialist knowledge. It is worthwhile, I think, to at least attempt to produce knowledge that

disrupts a set of self-referencing discourses about the ‘other’, especially if the other possibility is

to perpetuate this set.

3. Stakes, part two: Between capitalism, socialism, and efficiency I had originally thought that this thesis was already long enough—to write, but also for keeping

the attention of any readers—but I guess it would be disingenuous to pretend that there is not

more at stake than my own learning. At the end of my thesis, I remain somewhat curious about

one question. Perhaps readers join me in this. This question is: What is a more economically

efficient system—capitalism or state socialism? But the point of my thesis is not to ask this

question. It is rather to make this question askable at all. The reason why this question is not

askable, at least in the West, is because the answer has been stated, repeated, and is now

assumed. Capitalism has won. My thesis then arises not out of some abstract belief in the

economic superiority of socialism, but rather from the implications of the ‘capitalist victory’

narrative.

3.1 The aftermath of ‘capitalist victory’

The first implication of ‘capitalist victory’ is that it shuts down, in the West, space and

willingness to engage seriously with other forms of social and economic organizing. This is

especially true for people who do not have the time or resources to critically analyse and find

Page 147: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

141

‘the outside’ of pervasive discourses about capitalist victory. As a result, contemporary anti-

capitalist organizing (by that I mean discussions) in the West has become the exclusive domain

of people who have time to sit around and read Marx, Laclau, and Hardt and Negri. Critiques of

capitalism are becoming increasingly estranged from experiences of work, or even experiences

with those who do work.

The increasing difficulty of critical approaches to capitalism also makes it difficult—for

people who do engage in these critiques, or in organizing—to have space for much else. The

‘else’ here refers to activities such as listening to other people, self-reflection, assessing how one

is situated in and relates to the world, and learning from the history of existing anti-capitalist

projects. These things are difficult. Mao, in the quote that opened this chapter, may have said that

mistakes and setbacks do not equate to failure. But I am not sure how much of that particular

structure of feelings exists in the West. Consequently, anti-capitalist organizing in the

contemporary West exists mostly as a hobby and way to reproduce a particularly privileged—but

also ‘radical’—position. This is a problem. Anyone who has read this far I think would agree that

there are serious problems with the capitalist system, or at least in how it currently exists in the

West (and has been imposed onto the world). If state socialist, or Third World socialist projects,

have not posed adequate solutions, then they need to be examined seriously, rather than

summarily dismissed.

Many critical Western writers would agree that the above is a problem. To make askable

questions about socialist efficiency can hold space for anti-capitalist thought in the Global North,

but it is not the only way. The summary dismissal of state socialism has perhaps a larger second

set of implications: these are for the Global South. The ‘capitalist victory’ narrative shuts down

willingness to take seriously Global South liberation projects. It also shuts down space for

Global South projects to experiment with non-capitalist, or non-Western abiding, plans for

aggregate improvement. For people living in the Global South, the ‘capitalist victory’ narrative

plays out in two ways. Firstly, if capitalism is unarguably the more efficient form of social

organization, then it makes sense to organize local, national, etc. policies around capitalist logic.

The need for economic efficiency, though taken perhaps not so seriously by Marxists or other

Western progressives, remains crucial for many places in the Global South. To organize Global

South policies and programs around capitalist logic can also make available flows of Western

funding.

Page 148: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

142

Conversely, when Global South leaders attempt to organize local and national programs

around non-capitalist logic—and experience perhaps some degree of success—they are met with

embargos and sanctions. The U.S. (and other NATO states) currently has sanctions against Cuba,

DPR Korea, Syria, Iran, and Venezuela. It is quite easy to argue that there are states with worse

‘human right abuses’. The U.S. itself has the highest prison population rate in the world; its

prison population makes up 25% of all imprisoned people in the world.2 But states that are not

governed by socialist parties seem much less susceptible to Western sanctions. The ‘capitalist

victory’ narrative produces Global South realities partly by shaping Global North perspectives

and actions. If capitalism is unarguably more efficient—and morally superior, as Fukuyama and

Friedman would say—to socialism, then people in the Global South must be irrational to have

experimented with socialism. And more irrational to perhaps still be experimenting. Irrational

people in power is of course dangerous, or despotic and authoritarian. Global South experiments

have been, and continue to be, watched closely by the West. It is the mistakes and missteps that

become overwhelmingly reported. What is produced thereafter are Western calls for sanctions

and interventions, and their implementation. This process is currently playing out for Venezuela.

3.2 A step back: The unconcluded debate The ‘capitalist victory’ narrative shuts down crucial spaces in both the Global North and Global

South. The presence of these spaces is then what is at stake, in being able to ask questions about

relationships between capitalism, state socialism, and economic efficiency. To make this

question askable, I have, in a way, set up a debate. On one side are Mises and his intellectual

progeny, who have recently written about the early PRC economy. On the other side are early

PRC planners and researchers. A number of Soviet planners and researchers would presumably

also belong on this side, but have been cut by limits imposed by language ability and research

scope. The English-language debate has already been declared over; the victors however

excluded an important context—the historical and ongoing operations of imperialism. Again, the

2 Michelle Ye Hee Lee, “Yes, U.S. Locks People up at a Higher Rate than Any Other Country,” Washington Post, July 7, 2015, sec. Fact Checker, https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/fact-checker/wp/2015/07/07/yes-u-s-locks-people-up-at-a-higher-rate-than-any-other-country/.

Page 149: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

143

point of my thesis is not to ‘win’ the debate. It is rather to argue that this debate (and others like

it) is important to have in the first place. But why this particular match-up? What about other

pro- and anti-capitalist scholars and bodies of literatures? To explain this particular set-up, I trace

a fascination set of twists and turns in post-1800 global political and intellectual histories.

Side one: Mises and the economists

I begin with Mises’s side. What about other critiques of socialism? Why is Mises particularly

important here? From a cursory search into the history of contemporary Western economic

thought, it seems like mainstream distaste for socialism became fixed only after the end of the

Cold War. Samuelson is known for his widely-used textbook, Economics. This textbook was first

published in 1948; nineteen editions have been published up to 2009. In the thirteenth edition of

Economics, published in 1989, the author had written: “the Soviet economy is proof that,

contrary to what many skeptics had earlier believed, a socialist command economy can function

and even thrive.”3 Certain events transpired to change Samuelson’s mind, between the thirteenth

and fourteenth edition, published in 1992. On the same subject, the later edition states: “the

Soviet data are questioned by many experts”.4 One edition later, Samuelson came to characterize

the Soviet economy as “the failed model” in 1995.5

It seems quite possible that until the end of the Cold War, economists had been split on

the question of whether capitalism was in fact more efficient than socialism. In what became

known as the Socialist Calculation Debate of the 1930-1940s, Mises and Hayek positioned

themselves in favour of capitalism. Their most clearly defined opponents were Lange and

Lerner. Drawing on Lerner’s work, Lange proposed a model of a planned economy where a

central planning board allocates investment and capital goods, while the market allocates labour

and consumer goods. The planning board would direct all production; the market would ensure a

functioning price mechanism. With both in place, the planning board would be able to set prices

3 Paul Anthony Samuelson and William D Nordhaus, Economics, 13th ed. (McGraw-Hill, 1989), 837. 4 Paul Anthony Samuelson and William D. Nordhaus, Economics, 14th ed. (McGraw-Hill, 1992), 389. Also see: Mark Skousen, “The Perseverance of Paul Samuelson’s Economics,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 11, no. 2 (June 1997): 148. 5 Paul A. Samuelson, William D. Nordhaus, and Michael J. Mandel, Economics, 15th ed. (Mcgraw-Hill, 1995), 714–18; Skousen, “The Perseverance of Paul Samuelson’s Economics,” 148.

Page 150: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

144

equal to marginal cost, thereby ensuring Pareto efficiency in the economy.6 Samuelson reports

that many found the Lange-Lerner model convincing, including even Schumpeter, another well-

known member of the Austrian school.7

In some ways, it is Lange, Lerner, and others on their side of the Socialist Calculation

Debate—such as Fred Taylor and Joan Robinson—that stand the closest to early PRC and Soviet

planners and researchers, in their shared disagreement with Mises et al. However, it is important

to note that the Lange-Lerner model had been hypothetical, or an abstraction of how a timeless

and placeless planned economy would work. Some aspects of what Lange proposed were close

to how Soviet-style economies did operate (e.g. planning board). But Lange did not base his

model on actually-existing socialist planned economies, with their specific contexts and

objectives (i.e. imperialism, drive to accumulate and industrialize). Dynamics simulated by

Lange therefore had little to do with actual events and processes in socialist states. When

‘realities’ surfaced in 1989, they were far from the contents of Lange’s models. This was likely

when the debate was called conclusively in favour of Mises et al. Samuelson, writing in 2009,

finds in favour of Mises’s side—though he retroactively attributes the win to Hayek’s

preliminary discussion of information economics in the 1940s.8

Samuelson came to agree with Mises’s side. But interestingly enough, Samuelson’s

verdict of socialist failure—first issued in 1995—had little to do with problems of economic

inefficiency. ‘Failure’ was instead accounted for in the following passage: “In the 1980s and

1990s, country after country threw off the shackles of communism and stifling central

planning—not because the textbooks convinced them to do so but because they used their own

eyes and saw how the market-oriented countries of the West prospered while the command

economies of the East collapsed.”9 Another clue about the content of mainstream economic

opinions on state socialism, or at least those articulated post-1990, comes from Samuelson’s

6 Paul Auerbach and Dimitris P. Sotiropoulos, “Revisiting the Socialist Calculation Debate: The Role of Markets and Finance in Hayek’s Response to Lange’s Challenge,” in Economic Crisis and Political Economy, Palgrave Studies in the History of Economic Thought Series (Palgrave Macmillan, London, 2014), 212–30. 7 Paul A. Samuelson, “A Few Remembrances of Friedrich von Hayek (1899–1992),” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 69, no. 1 (2009): 2. 8 Ibid. 9 Samuelson, Nordhaus, and Mandel, Economics, 737.

Page 151: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

145

remarks on Keynes. When writing in memory of Hayek, Samuelson compares his character

favorably to that of Keynes. But Keynes is redeemed in Samuelson’s account through his

hostility to Soviet socialism, which came from his “recogniz[ing] barbaric evils in Lenin’s

utopia”.10

From these accounts, I propose three tentative conclusions about the contemporary field

of economics and its orientation to socialist projects. The first is that firm attachments to ideas

about state socialist inefficiency came after the dissolution of the Soviet Union. Inefficiency was

retrospectively read into the operations of the planned economy, given the ‘fact’ of capitalist

victory. The second tentative conclusion is that mainstream economic critiques of state socialism

revolve more around its alleged despotism, rather questions of inefficiency.11 The third tentative

conclusion is that Mises’s ideas remain quite influential in discussions about, at the very least,

the inefficiency of state socialist economies.12 Mises had accomplished a feat: his prediction that

capitalism would triumph over irrational socialism came true. He and his pupil and champion,

Hayek, persisted in their ideas about inefficient (irrational) socialism, even when such ideas were

less popular. Consequently, their analysis was ready and available to be applied at the moment of

capitalist ‘victory’.

If specific approaches and points seem outdated in Mises’s work, I would argue that the

bones of his argument have remained very influential. Mises had been one of the first to link

state socialist structures with notions of failure.13 This frame emerges in even Samuelson’s 1995

characterization of the Soviet economy. Mises’s set of frames and logics also reappear in

contemporary accounts of the early PRC economy. Mises emerges as the progenitor for a

particular set of critiques against socialism—this set insists on the economic irrationality of state

10 Samuelson, “A Few Remembrances of Friedrich von Hayek (1899–1992),” 3. 11 Notions about state socialist inefficiency and despotism are of course in some ways intertwined, as I showed when discussing Mises’s work in Chapter 2. 12 More substantial discussions on this subject draw from certain accounts by former Soviet economists. The work of János Kornai is crucial here. Kornai had first published in 1980 about issues of shortage in the Soviet economy (János Kornai, Economics of Shortage (North-Holland Publishing Company, 1980)). However, to my understanding, Kornai—at least in his early work—does not connect problems in state socialism with its inevitable and ahistorical defeat by capitalism. Narratives about the rational triumph of capitalism seem very much rooted in the work of Mises. 13 Mises, Socialism, 1951, 128–45.

Page 152: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

146

socialist projects, which is keyed to their inevitable failure. Mises and his contemporary

progeny—those who write on the early PRC economy—therefore occupy one side of the debate

in question, which revolve around relationships between capitalism, state socialism, and

economic efficiency.

Side two: Early PRC planners and shared projects

What about on the other side? Who else agrees with early PRC planners and researchers (and

possibly their Soviet counterparts)? Are other sets of people (e.g. progressive Western scholars,

postcolonial scholars) not interested in defending state socialist projects against charges by Mises

et al.? The answer is complicated. Some aspects have to do with what authors like Trouillot and

Wallerstein have called attention to, which is the post-Enlightenment reproduction of specific

and bounded knowledge fields in the West.14 In earlier sections, I discussed how Western

discourses on the early PRC are constructed through the systematic exclusion and erasure of

other forms of knowledge. This is a central theme in my thesis. But Western constructions do not

only shape the body of literature that I focus on, those contemporary accounts of early PRC

economic inefficiency and ‘failure’. Related discourses also estrange potential Western allies

from the kinds of practical and intellectual projects that were pursued in the early PRC.

As a student working on this thesis, I have been encouraged to both bound and to make

further connections in its framing. These are both important pieces of guidance and advice. This

section—and really, the entire thesis—is perhaps a slightly unwieldy attempt to do both. It is

unwieldy because there seems to be little pressure on other academic works to do both, and thus

a kind of absence of a well-trodden path. But I have already made the case that the absence of

specific and detailed studies of Chinese socialism—ones that understands the project within its

historical context and significance—is a major theoretical problem, if not also a political one.

And so I persist in this section.

14 Trouillot, Global Transformations, 7–46; Immanuel Maurice Wallerstein, Unthinking Social Science: The Limits of Nineteenth-Century Paradigms (Temple University Press, 1991).

Page 153: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

147

Redux on a theme: Orientalism and its reach

In terms of the big picture (on the ‘making connections’ side), the intellectual forefather of this

work is of course Said. But this thesis likely looks very different from most other works that

claim this lineage, and would perhaps be judged as lacking if standards derived from those

conventions were applied. The stakes and content of this thesis can perhaps be the most legibly

described as an attempt to take Said’s work seriously, while studying early PRC

industrialization. This should not be such an ambitious undertaking. How can Western

researchers approach studying ‘elsewhere’ without taking into account Said’s seminal analysis?

This is akin to approaching molecular biology without understanding DNA. Or studying civil

engineering without applying Newton’s laws of motion. But Said’s insights have not achieved

their necessary impact on English-language studies of China. This thesis may appear as

ambitious or unwieldy—though perhaps the later is only in my perception—but it arises out of a

very simple objective.

It is Said’s words that provide the most useful entry into thinking about the

presence/absence of allied scholarship on questions of state socialist efficiency. I quote them

here: “[S]o authoritative a position did Orientalism have that I believe no one writing, thinking.

or acting on the Orient could do so without taking account of the limitations on thought and

action imposed by Orientalism. […] This is not to say that Orientalism unilaterally determines

what can be said about the Orient, but that it is the whole network of interests inevitably brought

to bear on (and therefore always involved in) any occasion when that peculiar entity “the Orient”

is in question.”15

In the search for allied scholarship, one might begin with the assumption that Marxists

would be invested in defending state socialist projects. But a set of researchers who work in

and/or are from the Global South—such as Lu—have written on the distance existing between

Western Marxist thought and the realities of Third World socialism.16 Marx’s writing centres the

15 Said, Orientalism, 3. 16 Lu, Remaking Chinese Urban Form, 2006, 7. See also: Walter Rodney, Marx in the Liberation of Africa (Working People’s Alliance, 1981).

Page 154: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

148

European working class (the proletariat).17 Marxists have often continued to position white

workers as the proper revolutionary subjects.18 Many Western Marxists had taken an interest in

the project of Chinese socialism, or at least initially. This interest was often expressed as

solidarity, a kind of relationship that presumes common (and similar) circumstances and goals.19

White workers could unite with Chinese workers, if the two were basically the same.20 Or if the

later was on his way of becoming like the former (just more ‘backwards’).

The projection of sameness from Western ‘allies’ renders invisible much of the Chinese

socialist project, including its key goals for economic and technological development. These

were not concerns for contemporaneous Western Marxist projects. Herein lies, I think, a key part

of the reason why most sympathetic English-language accounts of the early PRC have focused

away from its economy or questions of production. This is not a critique of those works. There

are other important subjects to study. I am however trying to explain how my project finds itself

in a particular theoretical lacuna. There are of course important exceptions to the above. Some

sympathetic Western works on the PRC economy have studied aspects of production. Two from

the pre-‘end of history’ period include Mitchell Meisner’s article on the operations of the

17 The Communist Manifesto, for instance, states: “Of all the classes that stand face to face with the bourgeoisie to-day, the proletariat alone is a really revolutionary class. The other classes decay and finally disappear in the face of modern industry; the proletariat is its special and essential product.” (Karl Marx and Friedrich Engels, The Communist Manifesto: A Modern Edition (Verso, 1998), 44.) 18 Marxism and the privileging of white workers is discussed in works such as: Roderick Bush, The End of White World Supremacy: Black Internationalism and the Problem of the Color Line (Temple University Press, 2009), 91–92; Charles Mills, From Class to Race: Essays in White Marxism and Black Radicalism (Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, 2003), 163–70; Cary D. Wintz, African American Political Thought, 1890-1930: Washington, Du Bois, Garvey and Randolph (Routledge, 2015), 146–55. 19 Western Marxist projections of sameness onto their Chinese ‘comrades’ can be seen from the following account, which I return to at the end of this chapter: Harold Isaacs, The Tragedy of the Chinese Revolution (Haymarket Books, 2010), x. My critique of Western ideas and practices of solidarity is developed through pulling together pieces from Rutherford’s work on colonial projection and identification, and Povinelli’s work on liberalism and commensuration. See: Danilyn Rutherford, “Sympathy, State Building, and the Experience of Empire,” Cultural Anthropology 24, no. 1 (February 1, 2009): 1–32; Elizabeth A. Povinelli, Economies of Abandonment: Social Belonging and Endurance in Late Liberalism (Duke University Press, 2011); Elizabeth A. Povinelli, “Radical Worlds: The Anthropology of Incommensurability and Inconceivability,” Annual Review of Anthropology 30, no. 1 (2001): 319–34. 20 A caveat here is that of the Western Marxists who had expressed solidarity with the Chinese socialist project—especially for those who had visited China—it is unclear how many would have even self-identified as ‘workers’.

Page 155: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

149

Shenyang Transformer Factory during the Cultural Revolution, and Andors’s book on industrial

planning and management practices from 1949 to the 1970s.21

Certain contemporary works on the early PRC have also studied aspects related to

production, without dismissing how the Chinese state and its leaders understood their own plans

and projects. Authors such as Boland, Ghosh, Lu, and Schmalzer have accomplished the above

by attending closely to technical and technological logics.22 It is then possible, though perhaps

uncommon, to engage in a detailed study of the early PRC, while not partaking too much in the

discourses that Said had identified. And without engaging in an extended discussion of

discourses or political stakes. There is, I think, a certain way in which studies that begin with the

technical can avoid the kinds of assumptions that are more present in other works about the

Global South. The other works are those located closer to issues more readily identified as

political or economic. The above-listed authors, each in their own way, make visible certain

logics and strategies present in early PRC development projects. But it seems unfair to drag them

into this particular debate, since their central arguments lie quite far from questions about state

socialism, capitalism, and their relative efficiencies.

I return to discussing relationships between Marxist scholarship and questions of state

socialist efficiency. Hayek pointed out, when writing in 1935, that socialist reformers to date had

taken little interest in economic efficiency.23 This form of disinterest persisted, even for Western

Marxists who came into contact with existing state socialist projects—which were organized

around the very quest for efficiency. Some exceptions existed. One Marxist researcher who

seems to have investigated state socialist economies in some detail is Charles Bettelheim, whose

21 Mitch Meisner, “The Shenyang Transformer Factory--A Profile,” The China Quarterly, no. 52 (1972): 717–37; Andors, China’s Industrial Revolution, 1977. 22 Alana Boland, “From Factory to Field: Waste-Water Irrigation in China’s Early Socialist Cities,” Global Environment 9, no. 1 (April 1, 2016): 219–39; Arunabh Ghosh, “Making It Count: Statistics and State-Society Relations in the Early People’s Republic of China, 1949-1959” (PhD thesis, Columbia University, 2014); Lu, Remaking Chinese Urban Form, 2006; Sigrid Schmalzer, Red Revolution, Green Revolution: Scientific Farming in Socialist China (University of Chicago Press, 2016). 23 Frederich Hayek, “The Nature and History of the Problem,” in Collectivist Economic Planning: Critical Studies on the Possibilities of Socialism, ed. Frederich Hayek (Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1967), 1–3, 17–18.

Page 156: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

150

work I have only very recently come across.24 Bettelheim is not often mentioned, especially in

post-Cold War era scholarship. His work also remains largely untranslated from the original

French. Shaffer is another scholar who studied the Soviet economy in-depth. Shaffer did not

identify as Marxist; he did aim for a fair (or balanced) account of the system’s actual

operations.25 Generally speaking, Western Marxists devoted little attention to the actual

operations of state socialist economies before the end of the Cold War. Most seem even less

interested in challenging the kinds of discourses that have resurfaced since 1989, about state

socialist inefficiency.

What about the set of Marxist and affiliated scholars who explicitly write about and

structure their works around themes of imperialism? These include Barrat-Brown, Kemp, the

dependency theorists (Baran, Sweezy, and Frank), and world-systems theorists (Wallerstein).

They should understand the emphasis that Third World (or Second World) socialist projects had

placed on production. These authors and their works are of course very important to my project.

But dependency and world-system theorists appear to have shown little interest in the actual

operations of state socialist economies. Most seem to operate from the understanding that

Samuelson came to after 1989, that state socialism had been essentially oppressive.

Baran, for instance, drew from the Soviet experience the following conclusion:

“socialism in backward and underdeveloped countries has a powerful tendency to become a

backward and underdeveloped socialism.”26 Baran went on to say: “Socialism in the West, once

firmly established, would destroy for all time the bases and the need for any reappearance of the

political and social repression that marked the early stages of socialism in the East.”27 It does

boggle my mind that in his book on the very subject of imperialism, Baran would insist that

existing state socialist projects—those “in the East”—did it wrong. There is little sense that the

events of state socialism had emerged from innovative, if flawed, attempts to navigate ongoing

24 Works that seem relevant include: Charles Bettelheim, La Planification soviétique (Rivière, 1945); Charles Bettelheim, Problèmes théoriques et pratiques de la planification (Maspero, 1970); Charles Bettelheim, Calcul Économique et Formes de Propriété (Maspero, 1971). 25 Shaffer produced works such as: Harry G. Shaffer, The Soviet Economy (Appleton-Century-Crofts, 1963); Shaffer, The Soviet Economy, 1969. 26 Paul A. Baran, Political Economy of Growth (NYU Press, 1968), 14. 27 Ibid., 15.

Page 157: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

151

pressures exerted by the capitalist world system. For Baran, state socialist projects had rather

taken their shape due to “backwardness” and tendencies towards repression in their home

countries.

The hold that imperialist ideological (and material) structures have on the very possibility

of thinking is quite impressive. The historian Maurice Meisner is known for his extensive

research on China and early support of the Chinese socialist project. Meisner published a book

on Li Dazhao, one of the co-founders of the CCP, in 1967. In this work, Meisner discussed how

Li had understood China to be a “proletariat nation”.28 Thirty-some years later, in the third and

final edition of Meisner’s Mao’s China, the author writes of the Chinese Communist Revolution

that it “almost entirely lack[ed] any internationalist dimensions either in objective historical

reality or in the mentality of its leaders.”29 Meisner makes this statement in support of the

chapter’s theme, which is that Chinese socialism had failed (and grown monstrous) due to its

deviations from the ‘true’ course of Marxism. For Meisner, the largest deviation came from the

presence of bureaucracy (i.e. production-directing apparatus) in the early PRC.30

Meisner is not known for his affiliation with dependency or world-systems theory. My

point is only that the entire set of Marxist and affiliated scholars seem, especially in the wake of

the Cold War, stubbornly resistant to what they themselves know (or once knew) about the

world. Of the set, perhaps Wallerstein comes the closest to a nuanced perspective on state

socialist projects. But Wallerstein did not write on the specifics of socialist planned economies.

But not all dependency theorists were Marxists. They can perhaps be broadly divided into

two schools: the American Marxist school, for which Baran was a representative figure, and

what is known as the Latin American Structuralist school, which included scholars such as Celso

Furtado and Aníbal Pinto Santa Cruz. The later set are perhaps less likely to characterize

historically-existing state socialist projects as backwards and repressive. The South American

dependency theorists had been the main advocates for import-substitution industrialization (ISI),

which had been quite close to the actual practices of the early PRC. Though the South American-

28 Meisner, Li Dazhao and the Origins of Chinese Marxism, 1967, 144. 29 Meisner, Mao’s China and After, 247. 30 Ibid., 243–53.

Page 158: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

152

based dependency theorists might have been sympathetic to the Chinese socialist project, they

were largely preoccupied with theories and experiments in forms of capitalism.31 South

American dependency theorists likely were, and perhaps still are, open to debates about the

comparative efficiencies of capitalism and state socialism. But their existing work has, from

what I can gather, little to do with the operations of state planned economies.

I should caution before proceeding that while I am relatively familiar with bodies of

works on political economy, my grasp on mainstream economic literatures and their intellectual

histories is more tentative. With that said, I provide a summary of above discussions. The list of

scholars— coming from an economics or political economy-influenced perspective—whose

works challenge how Mises positions relationships between capitalism, state socialism, and

efficiency include Lange, Lerner, associate authors, Bettelheim, and Shaffer.

Lange and Lerner approached the subject through modelling; they researched questions

of socialist efficiency in the abstract. It was only Bettelheim and Shaffer, and perhaps some

others like them, who studied the actual operations of Soviet and Soviet-type planned economies

with questions of efficiency in mind. My approach in this project comes, in one sense, closest to

theirs. We mutually track knowledge held by state socialist planners and researchers; knowledge

suggesting that questions about socialist inefficiency are far from settled. It is perhaps

worthwhile to mention here that Mises’s Socialism (first published in 1922) has over 1400

citations on Google Scholar, 90% of which come from the period 1990-2017. Of the works that

cite Mises, the two shown as most cited are pieces by Fukuyama. Bettelheim’s monograph,

L'économie soviétique (1945), has 31 citations; 6 are from 1990-2017. Shaffer’s book titled The

Soviet Economy (1963) has 18 citations; 3 are from the period 1990-2017.

PRC planners between Orientalism and responses

Finally, the knowledge of early PRC planners and researchers extends into a vast area largely

dismissed by economics, and even political economy, literatures. This area concerns the

operations and impacts of Western imperialism. In drafting and implementing plans, early PRC

planners acted with knowledge about imperialism—its histories, legacies, and ongoing

31 Vernengo, “Technology, Finance, and Dependency: Latin American Radical Political Economy in Retrospect.”

Page 159: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

153

processes. Early PRC planners also applied this knowledge to their assessment of plans and their

outcomes. Who else might have had held similar forms of knowledge? Perhaps postcolonial

scholars, and others who share postcolonial approaches and sensibilities.

Several scholars active in anti-colonial and emancipatory projects, including Kosambi,

Rodney, and Du Bois, have written and spoken in nuanced ways about using Marxist

frameworks for emancipatory projects.32 Mintz and Williams, among others, have studied the

operations of colonialism and imperialism through a historical materialist lens.33 This

approach—bringing together postcolonial and historical materialist insights—is also present in

works about imperialism and its economic impacts on China. Authors who have written on this

include Chesneaux, Esherick, and Sun, whose works I featured in Chapter 2. The above set of

writers share important histories, approaches, and investments with early PRC planners and

researchers. Early PRC actors came to be in a somewhat unique position, of applying these

elements to the construction, operation, and assessment of a socialist planned economy. Not

many other Third World nations had, or have, economies based around principles of socialist

planning. It is also likely that records of historically-existing forms of economic experimentation

in Third World states have not been translated and disseminated; this is true of much of early

PRC discussions and records.

Early PRC knowledge about state socialist efficiency does not fit easily into the

postcolonial canon for another important reason. Many well-known works within this tradition

express a degree of hostility towards Marxism and socialism. This kind of hostility is certainly

justifiable; it likely also contributes to the palatability of these works for English-language

audiences. Said, for instance, wrote extensively about Orientalist discourses in the works of

Marx.34 I have already shown how Marxists tend to systematically dismiss realities and theories

from the Third World. Many Third World states, including the PRC, were also cautious about the

Soviet Union. In Chapter 3 of this thesis (covering origins of and influences on the early PRC

32 Damodar Dharmanand Kosambi, An Introduction to the Study of Indian History (Popular Prakashan, 1975); Rodney, Marx in the Liberation of Africa; Wintz, African American Political Thought, 1890-1930. 33 Sidney W. Mintz, “Was the Plantation Slave a Proletarian?,” Review (Fernand Braudel Center) 2, no. 1 (1978): 81–98; Williams, Capitalism & Slavery, 1944. 34 Said, Orientalism, e.g. 13–16, 153–60, 323.

Page 160: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

154

railway system), I discussed how Lenin and the Bolsheviks had considered Asian revolutionary

projects to be ‘backwards’ and behind their European counterparts. Russia was an imperialist

power; Third World states were concerned about historical continuities in Soviet approaches.35

Most works in the postcolonial tradition, at least those that are readily accessible, are not

particularly interested in the economic operations of state socialist projects.

My attempt in this project, to track what early PRC planners had observed and

understood about state socialist efficiency, shares important and overlapping parts with many

other investigations. With dependency theorists, world-systems theorists, and scholars who

combine historical materialist and postcolonial approaches, I share questions about imperialism

and its production of spaces and places in the world. With Du Bois, Kosambi, Rodney, and

others, I share questions about materialist frameworks for emancipatory projects. With Lange,

Lerner, Bettelheim, Shaffer and others, I share questions about relationships between ownership

configurations and the efficient mobilization of resources, particular in terms of how they played

out in actually-existing socialist planned economies. With other researchers of the early PRC, I

share questions about the empirical details of early PRC economic and technological

development processes. And so on.

The early PRC industrialization project also shared key aspects—contexts, approaches,

investments, etc.—with other historical and contemporary social undertakings. What was

produced from this project was, however, somewhat distinctive. Early PRC knowledge about

relationships between socialist planning and economic efficiency occupy perhaps a unique

position: they challenge discourses constructed and perpetuated by Mises and his students. The

bones of Mises’s argument seem, at least in the present moment, far from marginal. These

discourses do not only shape contemporary accounts of the early PRC economy. They also

permeate non-specialist and widely-circulated works, such as those by Fukuyama and Friedman.

One could even wonder if perhaps the post-Cold War rediscovery of Mises and his framing was

motivated, at least in part, by what early PRC planners and researchers came to know—about the

very kinds of connections between socialist planning and economic efficiency.

35 See, for instance, Jersild’s discussion: Austin Jersild, The Sino-Soviet Alliance: An International History (UNC Press Books, 2014).

Page 161: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

155

But I stop at my earlier point. I contend that the kind of debate that this thesis sets up,

between Mises et al. and early PRC planners, has not already been won. This victory should not

be assumed, especially for people in the Global North who produce knowledge about the Global

South. Global structures of power had shaped the very terrain for early PRC development plans

and processes. These structures have persisted: they produce the contemporary Western inability

to take seriously early PRC plan and processes. This project may not fit comfortably into one

existing body of literature. It veers to the side and threads across several, in order to ask

questions that are considered to already have been answered. But this does not mean, I do not

think, that questions about relationships between capitalism, state socialism, and efficiency are

unimportant. Perhaps even the opposite.

4. Towards unpaused histories In this thesis, I am interested in the early PRC’s attempt to construct alternative modernities. I

am simultaneously interested in why these attempts are largely narrated as having failed in the

West. I have thoroughly covered how Western discourses narrate the economic aspects of state

socialist ‘failure’. But projects of state socialism are also viewed as having failed in another

crucial way. I have already alluded to this second form of failure, especially when accounting for

how Western Marxists have recently narrated the events of state socialist projects. To further

draw out the contours of these narrations, I use a quote from Arnold Isaacs, the son of Harold

Isaacs. The older Isaacs—seemingly a lifelong Marxist—has since passed away. In the 1930s, he

was an early and fervent supporter of the Chinese Communist project. Isaacs became

disillusioned sometime after 1949. In the 1980s, he traveled back to China for the first time since

before 1949. Isaacs would write a book about this experience, published under the title Re-

encounters in China. In 2010, one of Isaacs’s earlier works was reissued, with an introduction

from his son. The following passage comes from Arnold Isaacs’s introduction, which quotes a

passage that his father had written in Re-encounters.

But the air was far from free enough for the men and women Isaacs met in those re-encounters to go very far beyond the approved Communist Party formulas in discussing their experiences. For the most part my father was left to guess what they really felt and what meaning they had really found in their lives and their country's life under the regime they had sacrificed to create. And eventually he heard the answer in his own voice, not

Page 162: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

156

theirs, when he burst out to one of them: “This has not been your experience alone. Our whole generation everywhere went through it in different ways, dreaming the great socialist dream, then having it crushed, by Stalin and his murderous regime in Russia and now again here in China. We were left to find some better way to human betterment, something better than prisons and labor camps and killings and oppression worse than before, and we haven't been very successful.”36

Isaacs may not have thought of himself as agreeing with Friedman on many things. But they

shared a rather close understanding of historically-existing projects of state socialism, especially

about the essentially oppressive nature of these projects. The below passage is from Friedman.

“[The end of the Cold War] tipped the balance of power across the world toward those advocating democratic, consensual, free-market-oriented governance, and away from those advocating authoritarian rule with centrally planned economies. The Cold War had been a struggle between two economic systems-capitalism and communism-and with the fall of the wall, there was only one system left and everyone had to orient himself or herself to it one way or another. Henceforth, more and more economies would be governed from the ground up, by the interests, demands, and aspirations of the people, rather than from the top down, by the interests of some narrow ruling clique.”37

Those in the West who are (or have been) invested in progressive—and even radical—

projects seem no less susceptible to ‘end of history’ discourses. Isaacs’s understanding of the

afterlife of state socialism comes, I think, from a similar place as authors whose narratives that I

focused on in this thesis. Isaacs did not understand that the men and women that he re-

encountered in China were, and had always been, different than him. Not essentially or

biologically different, but shaped by and fighting within a very different context. Imperialism

had shaped the very terrain of the Chinese socialist project. Isaacs and CCP members did not in

any way share in the same struggle or the same “socialist dream”. What does it mean then, for

Isaacs to conceptualize the Chinese socialist project as having failed? What does it mean for

Isaacs to partake in a shared conception with Friedman, and with Mises? What kind of

possibilities—for knowledge, and for political practice—might be opened up, if narratives of

failure could be dislodged from common understandings of state socialist projects?

36 Isaacs, The Tragedy of the Chinese Revolution, x. The quote from H. Isaacs can be found in: Harold Isaacs, Re-Encounters in China: Notes of a Journey in a Time Capsule (Routledge, 1985). 37 Friedman, The World Is Flat 3.0, 2007, 49.

Page 163: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

157

Bibliography Ahmad, Diana L. The Opium Debate and Chinese Exclusion Laws in the Nineteenth-Century

American West. University of Nevada Press, 2007. American Petroleum, and Institute. “Economic Impacts of the Oil and Natural Gas Industry on

the US Economy in 2011,” July 2013. Andors, Stephen. China’s Industrial Revolution: Politics, Planning, and Management, 1949 to

the Present. New York: Pantheon Books, 1977. Andreas, Joel. Rise of the Red Engineers: The Cultural Revolution and the Origins of China’s

New Class. Stanford University Press, 2009. Anell, Lars, and Birgitta Nygren. The Developing Countries and the World Economic Order.

Bloomsbury Publishing, 2013. Archer, Christon I. World History of Warfare. University of Nebraska Press, 2002. Auerbach, Paul, and Dimitris P. Sotiropoulos. “Revisiting the Socialist Calculation Debate: The

Role of Markets and Finance in Hayek’s Response to Lange’s Challenge.” In Economic Crisis and Political Economy, 212–30. Palgrave Studies in the History of Economic Thought Series. Palgrave Macmillan, 2014.

Bagwell, Philip Sidney. The Transport Revolution. Routledge, 1988. Bai, Chong-En, and Yingyi Qian. “Infrastructure Development in China: The Cases of

Electricity, Highways, and Railways.” Journal of Comparative Economics 38, no. 1 (2010): 34–51.

Bai, Fuyin, ed. 铁道部第十四工程局志 1948-1995 [Annals of the Ministry of Railways

Engineering Corps Fourteenth Division, 1948-1995]. Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1998.

Baran, Paul A. Political Economy of Growth. NYU Press, 1968. Barlow, Tani E. “Colonialism’s Career in Postwar China Studies.” Positions 1, no. 1 (March 20,

1993): 224–67. Barnouin, Barbara, and Changgen Yu. Zhou Enlai: A Political Life. Hong Kong: Chinese

University Press, 2006. Barratt Brown, Michael. The Economics of Imperialism. First Edition. Harmondsworth: Penguin

Books, 1975.

Beijing Railway School. 铁路经济活动分析 [An Analysis of Railway Economic Operations].

Beijing, China: 北京铁道学院 [Beijing Railway School], 1956.

Beissinger, Mark R. Scientific Management, Socialist Discipline and Soviet Power. I.B. Tauris, 1988.

Bernstein, Thomas P., and Hua-Yu Li. China Learns from the Soviet Union, 1949-Present. Rowman & Littlefield, 2010.

Page 164: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

158

Bettelheim, Charles. Calcul Économique et Formes de Propriété. Maspero, 1971. ———. La Planification soviétique. Rivière, 1945. ———. Problèmes théoriques et pratiques de la planification. Maspero, 1970. Blum, William. Killing Hope: US Military and CIA Interventions since World War II. Zed

Books, 2003.

BMA 004-014-00008. “中财委批准并印发的 1951 年各月份全国铁路运输计划、会议记录,” January 1, 1951.

BMA 004-016-00472. “市财委转发中财委关于各地铁路供应商店若干业务问题的指示及有

关铁路系统的供应问题,” January 1, 1954.

Boland, Alana. “From Factory to Field: Waste-Water Irrigation in China’s Early Socialist Cities.” Global Environment 9, no. 1 (April 1, 2016): 219–39.

Bornstein, Morris. “The Soviet Price System.” The American Economic Review 52, no. 1 (1962): 64–103.

Bourdieu, Pierre. “Participant Objectivation.” The Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute 9, no. 2 (2003): 281–94.

Bowie, Robert R., and John K. Fairbank. Communist China 1955-1959: Policy Documents with Analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1962.

Brady, Dylan. “Forging the Nation through Rails: Transportation Infrastructure and the Emergence of Chinese Nationalism.” MA Thesis, University of Oregon, 2013.

Burnette, Joyce. Gender, Work and Wages in Industrial Revolution Britain. Cambridge University Press, 2008.

Bush, Roderick. The End of White World Supremacy: Black Internationalism and the Problem of the Color Line. Temple University Press, 2009.

Cao, Ruilin. “天津铁路管理局丰台机务段 忽视了对职工进行思想教育 经济核算准备工作

走了弯路 [The Fengtai Locomotive Section of the Tianjin Railway Bureau Neglected the Task of Educating Workers, Implementing the Economic Accounting System Has Gone Awry].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. June 10, 1951, sec 2.

Carley, Michael Jabara. “Allied Intervention and the Russian Civil War, 1917-1922.” Edited by Michael Kettle, Richard Luckett, Iurii Vladimirovich Got’e, Terence Emmons, and Donald J. Raleigh. The International History Review 11, no. 4 (1989): 689–700.

CCP. “Constitution of the Communist Party of China: Revised and Adopted at the 18th National Congress of the Communist Party of China on November 14, 2012.” ChinaToday.com: A China Information Base, November 14, 2012. http://www.chinatoday.com/org/cpc/china_communist_party_constitution.htm.

Chan, Kam Wing, and Xeuqiang Xu. “Urban Population Growth and Urbanization in China since 1949: Reconstructing a Baseline.” The China Quarterly, no. 104 (1985): 583–613.

Page 165: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

159

Chan, Sylvia. “The Image of a ‘Capitalist Roader’--Some Dissident Short Stories in the Hundred Flowers Period.” The Australian Journal of Chinese Affairs, no. 2 (1979): 77–102.

Chang, Jui-te. “Technology Transfer in Modern China: The Case of Railway Enterprise (1876-1937).” Modern Asian Studies 27, no. 2 (1993): 281–96.

———. 中國近代鐵路事業管理的研究--政治層面的分析 1876-1937 [Railroads in Modern China: Political Aspects of Railroad Administration (1876-1937)]. Institute of Modern History, Academia Sinica, 1991.

Chang, Kia-ngau. China’s Struggle for Railroad Development. The John Day Company, 1943. Chao, Kuo-chün. Economic Planning and Organization in Mainland China: A Documentary

Study, 1949-1957. Cambridge, MA: East Asian Research Center, 1963. Chao, Yung-hsin. Railways in Communist China. Kowloon, H.K.: Union Research Institute,

1956.

Chen, Ji. “专靠包商是做不好工程建设的---记西北铁路干线工程局盲目依靠包商的恶果 [Construction Projects That Rely on Contract Labour Will Not Go Well--the Northwest Railway Bureau Reflects on Bad Results].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. August 7, 1951, sec 2.

Chen, Xueming. “A Sustainability Analysis on the Wuhan-Guangzhou High-Speed Railway in China.” International Journal of Sustainable Transportation 9, no. 5 (July 4, 2015): 348–63.

Chen, Zhenhua, and Kingsley E. Haynes. Chinese Railways in the Era of High-Speed. Emerald Group Publishing Limited, 2015.

Cheremukhin, Anton, Mikhail Golosov, Sergei Guriev, and Aleh Tsyvinski. “The Economy of People’s Republic of China from 1953.” National Bureau of Economic Research, 2015.

Chesneaux, Jean. The Chinese Labor Movement, 1919-1927. Translated by H. M. Wright. Stanford University Press, 1968.

Chuang, Michael Y., and William H. A. Johnson. “‘Hop on Board’: The Importation and Future Development of High-Speed Rail (HSR) in China.” Journal of Technology Management in China 6, no. 3 (2011): 232–41.

CIA. “United States of America: Industries.” In The World Factbook. Masterlab, 2015. CIA Office of Research and Reports. “Comparison of the First Five Year Plans of Communist

China and the USSR.” Economic Intelligence Report. Central Intelligence Agency, June 1959.

Collier, Stephen J. Post-Soviet Social: Neoliberalism, Social Modernity, Biopolitics. Princeton University Press, 2011.

CRCC. “中国人民解放军铁道兵 [PLA Railway Corps].” 中国铁建股份有限公司 [China Railway Construction Corporation Ltd], June 7, 2017. http://www.crcc.cn/g754/s1859/t26177.aspx.

Page 166: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

160

CRSHMC. “历史沿革 [Historical Background].” 中铁上海工程局集团市政工程有限公司 [Shanghai Construction Bureau of China Railway Engineering Corporation Ltd]. Accessed July 9, 2017. http://www.crshmc.com/index.php?catid=13.

Crush, Jonathan. Power of Development. Psychology Press, 1995. Davis, Clarence B., Kenneth E. Wilburn, and Ronald. Robinson, eds. Railway Imperialism. New

York: Greenwood Press, 1991. Davis, Clarence Baldwin. “Railway Imperialism in China, 1895-1939.” In Railway Imperialism,

edited by Clarence Baldwin Davis, Kenneth E. Wilburn, and Ronald Edward Robinson, 155–74. Greenwood Press, 1991.

Deng, Kent. “China’s Population Expansion and Its Causes during the Qing Period, 1644–1911,” 2015.

Derrida, Jacques. Of Grammatology. Translated by Gayatri Chakravorty Spivak. JHU Press, 1998.

Desfosses, Helen, and Jacques Lévesque. Socialism in the Third World. Praeger, 1975. Dittmer, Lowell. “‘Line Struggle’ in Theory and Practice: The Origins of the Cultural Revolution

Reconsidered.” The China Quarterly, no. 72 (1977): 675–712. ———. Liu Shaoqi and the Chinese Cultural Revolution. M.E. Sharpe, 1998. Donnithorne, Audrey. “China’s Economic Planning and Industry.” The China Quarterly, no. 17

(1964): 111–24. ———. China’s Economic System. Praeger, 1967. Durkheim, Emile. The Division of Labor in Society. New York: Simon and Schuster, 2014. Edmonds, Richard Louis. “The Legacy of Sun Yat-Sen’s Railway Plans.” The China Quarterly

111 (September 1987): 421–443. Elleman, Bruce, and Stephen Kotkin. Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China: An

International History. M. E. Sharpe, 2015. Epstein, Israel. “Main Directions in Chinese Labor.” Science & Society 13, no. 4 (1949): 313–

26. Esherick, Joseph. “Deconstructing the Construction of the Party-State: Gulin County in the

Shaan-Gan-Ning Border Region.” The China Quarterly, no. 140 (1994): 1052–79. ———. “Harvard on China: The Apologetics of Imperialism.” Bulletin of Concerned Asian

Scholars 4, no. 19 (1972): 9–16. ———. “On The ‘Restoration of Capitalism.’” Modern China 5, no. 1 (1979): 41–77. Evans, Alfred B. Soviet Marxism-Leninism: The Decline of an Ideology. ABC-CLIO, 1993. Fairbank, John K. “The Early Treaty System in the Chinese World Order.” In The Chinese

World Order: Traditional China’s Foreign Relations, 257–75. Harvard University Press, 1968.

———. Trade and Diplomacy on the China Coast: The Opening of Treaty Ports, 1842-1854, 1964.

Page 167: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

161

Fan, Kejing, ed. 成都铁路局志 1909-1988 [Annals of the Chengdu Railway Bureau, 1909-

1988]. Chengdu, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1995.

Feng, Xingyuan, Christer Ljungwall, and Guangwen He. The Ecology of Chinese Private Enterprises. World Scientific, 2015.

Ferguson, Charles. Inside Job. Documentary. Sony, 2010. Ferguson, James. The Anti-Politics Machine: ’Development’, Depoliticization and Bureaucratic

Power in Lesotho. Cambridge University Press, 1990. Feuerwerker, Albert. The Chinese Economy, 1870-1949. Center for Chinese Studies, University

of Michigan, 1995. ———. The Chinese Economy, Ca. 1870-1911. Center for Chinese Studies, University of

Michigan, 1969. Flick, Uwe. Managing Quality in Qualitative Research. SAGE, 2008. Forsberg, Randall. The Arms Production Dilemma: Contraction and Restraint in the World

Combat Aircraft Industry. MIT Press, 1994. Foucault, Michel. The Government of Self and Others: Lectures at the College de France, 1982-

1983. Macmillan, 2011. ———. “The Order of Discourse.” In Untying the Text: A Post-Structuralist Reader, edited by

Robert Young, 48–78. Routledge, 1981. Frazier, Mark W. The Making of the Chinese Industrial Workplace: State, Revolution, and Labor

Management. Cambridge University Press, 2002. Freyssenet, Michel. La division capitaliste du travail. Savelli, 1977. Friedman, Thomas L. The World Is Flat 3.0: A Brief History of the Twenty-First Century.

Macmillan, 2007. Friedmann, John. China’s Urban Transition. University of Minnesota Press, 2005.

Fu, Ying. “为什么苏联工业发展如此迅速? [Why has industry in the Soviet Union developed

so quickly?].” 世界知识 [World Affairs], no. 47 (1952): 9–11.

Fukuyama, Francis. The End of History and the Last Man. Penguin Books Limited, 1993. Gao, Mobo C. F. The Battle for China’s Past: Mao and the Cultural Revolution. Pluto Press,

2008.

Geng, Yifan. “对盲目招揽货源的检讨 [A Self-Criticism on Blindly Soliciting Business].” 人民

日报 [People’s Daily]. March 24, 1953, sec 2.

Ghosh, Amitav. Opium financed British rule in India, June 23, 2008. Ghosh, Arunabh. “Making It Count: Statistics and State-Society Relations in the Early People’s

Republic of China, 1949-1959.” PhD thesis, Columbia University, 2014. Giap, Vo Nguyen. People’s War, People’s Army. University Press of the Pacific, 2001.

Page 168: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

162

Gibson, Catherine, and Julie Graham. The End of Capitalism (as We Knew It). Oxford: Blackwell, 1996.

Glatfelter, R. Edward. “Russia, the Soviet Union, and the Chinese Eastern Railway.” In Railway Imperialism, edited by Clarence Baldwin Davis, Kenneth E. Wilburn, and Ronald Edward Robinson, 121–36. Greenwood Press, 1991.

Goldman, René. “The Rectification Campaign at Peking University: May--June 1957.” The China Quarterly, no. 12 (1962): 138–53.

Gong, Shuqing, and Shutian Li. 哈尔滨铁路局志 1896-1994 [Annals of the Harbin Railway

Bureau 1896-1994]. Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1996.

Greenhalgh, Susan. Just One Child: Science and Policy in Deng’s China. University of California Press, 2008.

Habermas, Jürgen. The Structural Transformation of the Public Sphere: An Inquiry into a Category of Bourgeois Society. MIT press, 1991.

Haggard, Stephan. “The Politics of Industrialization in the Republic of Korea and Taiwan.” In Achieving Industrialization in East Asia, edited by H. Hughes, 274–75. Cambridge University Press, 1988.

Hammond, F. D. Report by Brigadier-General F. D. Hammond on the National Railways of the Republic of China., 1937.

Harding, Harry. China: The Problem of Bureaucracy, 1949-1976. Stanford University Press, 1981.

Hayek, Frederich. “The Nature and History of the Problem.” In Collectivist Economic Planning: Critical Studies on the Possibilities of Socialism, edited by Frederich Hayek, 1–40. Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1967.

High, Steven. Industrial Sunset: The Making of North America’s Rust Belt, 1969-1984. University of Toronto Press, 2003.

Hill, Kim, Debra Menk, Joshua Cregger, and Michael Schultz. “Contribution of the Automotive Industry to the Economies of All Fifty State and the United States.” Center for Automotive Research, January 2015.

“Hong Kong Overtaken by Singapore as Third Leading Global Financial Centre.” South China Morning Post, April 7, 2016. http://www.scmp.com/news/hong-kong/economy/article/1934559/hong-kong-overtaken-singapore-third-leading-global-financial.

hooks, bell. “Marginality as Site of Resistance.” In Out There: Marginalization and Contemporary Cultures, edited by Russell Ferguson, Martha Gever, Trinh T. Minh-ha, and Cornel West, 341–43. MIT Press, 1990.

Hou, Chi-ming. Foreign Investment and Economic Development in China, 1840-1937. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 1965.

Howard, Pat. Breaking the Iron Rice Bowl: Prospects for Socialism in China’s Countryside. M.E. Sharpe, 1988.

Page 169: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

163

Howe, Christopher. Wage Patterns and Wage Policy in Modern China 1919-1972. Cambridge University Press, 1973.

Hsiao, Gene. “The Role of Economic Contracts in Communist China.” California Law Review 53, no. 4 (October 31, 1965): 1029.

Hsiao, Liang-lin. China’s Foreign Trade Statistics, 1864-1949. Harvard East Asian Research Center, 1974.

Hsu, Mongton Chih. Railway Problems in China. AMS Press, 1968. Huenemann, Ralph William. The Dragon and the Iron Horse: The Economics of Railroads in

China, 1876-1937. Council on East Asian Studies, Harvard University, 1984. IHS Economics. “Aerospace and Defense Economic Impact Analysis: A Report for the

Aerospace Industries Association,” April 2016. “Imperial Peking-Kalgan Railway.” The Far-Eastern Review VI, no. 6 (November 1909): 320–

30. Isaacs, Harold. Re-Encounters in China: Notes of a Journey in a Time Capsule. Routledge, 1985. ———. The Tragedy of the Chinese Revolution. Haymarket Books, 2010. Jackman, W. T. The Development of Transportation in Modern England. Cambridge University

Press, 2014. Jackson, Michael. “Whose Human Rights? Suffering and Reconstruction in Post-War Sierra

Leone.” Sites: A Journal of Social Anthropology and Cultural Studies 2, no. 2 (2005): 141–59.

Jersild, Austin. The Sino-Soviet Alliance: An International History. UNC Press Books, 2014.

Jiang, Junzheng. “节约金属是国民经济的重要任务.” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. February 27, 1949, sec 3.

Jiang, Xuedong. “经济核算 [Economic accounting].” 中国金融 [China Finance], no. 12 (1951): 3–4+13.

Jiao, Jingjuan, Jiaoe Wang, and Michael Dunford. “Impacts on Accessibility of China’s Present and Future HSR Network.” Journal of Transport Geography, January 1, 2014.

Jin, Fengjun. “Transportation Development Transition in China.” Chinese Geographical Science 22, no. 3 (June 1, 2012): 319–33.

Jin Shixuan. 铁路史话 [A brief history of Chinese railways]. 中华书局, 1965.

Junghans, Lida. “Industrial Involution: Recruitment and Development within the Railway System.” In How China Works: Perspectives on the Twentieth-Century Industrial Workplace, edited by Jacob Eyferth, 74–90. London: Routledge, 2006.

Kaplan, Robert S. “The Evolution of Management Accounting.” The Accounting Review 59, no. 3 (1984): 390–418.

Kataoka, Tetsuya. Resistance and Revolution in China: The Communists and the Second United Front. University of California Press, 1974.

Page 170: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

164

Kemble, Whitney. “Research Guides: Finding Primary Sources: Primary & Secondary Sources Explained.” Accessed September 27, 2017. http://guides.library.utoronto.ca/c.php?g=250552&p=1671086.

Kemp, Tom. Theories of Imperialism. Dobson, 1967. Kent, Percy Horace Braund. Railway Enterprise in China: An Account of Its Origin and

Development. E. Arnold, 1907. Khrushchev, Nikita Sergeevich, and Sergei Guriev. Memoirs of Nikita Khrushchev. Vol. 3. Penn

State Press, 2007. Kinder, C W. “Railways and Colleries of North China.” Minutes of the Proceedings of the

Institution of Civil Engineers 103, no. 1891 (January 1, 1891): 278–306. Kiviat, Barbara. “Why Are Economists So Bad at Forecasting?” Time, July 17, 2009.

http://content.time.com/time/business/article/0,8599,1911011,00.html. Köll, Elisabeth. “Chinese Railroads, Local Society, and Foreign Presence: The Tianjin-Pukou

Line in Pre-1949 Shandong.” In Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China: An International History: An International History, edited by Bruce Elleman and Stephen Kotkin, 123–48. M. E. Sharpe, 2015.

Kopicki, Ron, and Louis Thompson. “Best Methods of Railway Restructuring and Privatization.” The World Bank, August 31, 1995. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/1995/08/697143/best-methods-railway-restructuring-privatization.

Kornai, János. Economics of Shortage. North-Holland Publishing Company, 1980. Kosambi, Damodar Dharmanand. An Introduction to the Study of Indian History. Popular

Prakashan, 1975. Kotkin, Stephen. “Preface.” In Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China: An International

History, edited by Bruce Elleman and Stephen Kotkin, xii–xvi. M. E. Sharpe, 2015. Kraus, Richard Curt. The Cultural Revolution: A Very Short Introduction. Oxford University

Press, 2012. Kwang, Ching Wen. The Economic Accounting System of State Enterprises in Mainland China.

Committee on the Economy of China, Social Science Research Council, 1966. Lam, Tong. A Passion for Facts: Social Surveys and the Construction of the Chinese Nation-

State, 1900–1949. University of California Press, 2011. Lardy, Nicholas R. Economic Growth and Distribution in China. Cambridge University Press,

1978. ———. “Economic Recovery and the 1st Five-Year Plan.” In The Cambridge History of China,

edited by Roderick MacFarquhar and John K. Fairbank, 144–83. Cambridge University Press, 1987.

Latour, Bruno, and Steve Woolgar. Laboratory Life: The Construction of Scientific Facts. Princeton University Press, 1979.

Page 171: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

165

Lau, Virginia. “Record Breaker: China’s Incredible North-South High-Speed Train Line Plan.” CNN Travel, January 8, 2015. http://www.cnn.com/travel/article/china-high-speed-north-south-rail/index.html.

Lee, En-han. China’s Quest for Railway Autonomy, 1904-1911: A Study of the Chinese Railway-Rights Recovery Movement. Singapore University Press, 1977.

Lee, Hong Yung. From Revolutionary Cadres to Party Technocrats in Socialist China. University of California Press, 1991.

Lee, Michelle Ye Hee. “Yes, U.S. Locks People up at a Higher Rate than Any Other Country.” Washington Post, July 7, 2015, sec. Fact Checker. https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/fact-checker/wp/2015/07/07/yes-u-s-locks-people-up-at-a-higher-rate-than-any-other-country/.

Lenin, Vladimir Ilych. Imperialism: The Highest Stage of Capitalism. International Publishers, 1937.

———. What Is to Be Done? International Publishers, 1969. ———. “The Immediate Tasks of the Soviet Government.” In Collected Works, 27:237–78.

Progress Publishers, 1972. Leung, Chi-Keung. China, Railway Patterns and National Goals. Chicago: University of Chicago

Press, 1980. Levine, Steven I. Anvil of Victory: The Communist Revolution in Manchuria, 1945-1948.

Columbia University Press, 1987.

Li, Dazhao. “Bolshevism 的胜利 [The Victory of Bolshevism].” In 李大钊选集 [Selected Works of Li Dazhao], 117–18. Beijing: Beijing Renmin Press, 1962.

Li, Hongjuan. “Population Remains Top Priority for China.” JOICFP News, no. 286 (April 1998): 1–2.

Li, Hua-Yu. Mao and the Economic Stalinization of China, 1948–1953. Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, 2006.

Li, Tania M. The Will to Improve: Governmentality, Development, and the Practice of Politics. Duke University Press, 2007.

Lieberthal, Kenneth. Revolution and Tradition in Tientsin, 1949-1952. Stanford University Press, 1980.

———. “The Great Leap Forward and the Split in the Yenan Leadership.” In The Cambridge History of China, edited by Roderick MacFarquhar and John K. Fairbank, 291–359. Cambridge University Press, 1987.

Lin, Cheng. The Chinese Railways: A Historical Survey. China United Press, 1935. Lin, Justin Yifu, Fang Cai, and Zhou Li. The China Miracle: Development Strategy and

Economic Reform. Chinese University Press, 2003.

Lin, Yin. “全国铁路工作中存在严重偏向 单纯追求数字浪费国家财富 铁道部指示各局立即

加以纠正 [National Railway Work Has a Severe Problem with Only Chasing Numbers,

Page 172: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

166

Wasting the Nation’s Resources. MOR Instructs Each Railway Bureau to Immediately Correct Problem].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. September 7, 1950, sec 2.

Lippit, Victor D. “Development of Transportation in Communist China.” The China Quarterly, no. 27 (1966): 101–19.

Liu, Guoming. 中华民国国民政府军政职官人物志 [Republic of China Military and Governance Records]. Chunqiu Press [春秋出版社], 1989.

Liu, Rongfang. “The Role of State: High Speed Rail Development in China.” Advances in Management 8, no. 3 (March 2015): 1–16.

Liu Shaoqi. How to be a Good Communist. Beijing: Foreign Language Press, 1949.

Liu, Tongwei, ed. 铁路修建史料第三集 1949-1962 [The Third Series of Historical Materials on

Railway Construction, 1949-1962]. Vol. 第一册 [Volume one]. Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1964.

———, ed. 铁路修建史料第三集 1949-1962 [The Third Series of Historical Materials on

Railway Construction, 1949-1962]. Vol. 第三册 [Volume three]. Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1964.

———, ed. 铁路修建史料第三集 1949-1962 [The Third Series of Historical Materials on

Railway Construction, 1949-1962]. Vol. 第四册 [Volume four]. Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1964.

———, ed. 铁路修建史料第四集 1963-1980 [The Fourth Series of Historical Materials on

Railway Construction, 1963-1980]. Vol. 第一册 [Volume one]. Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1991.

Lu, Aiguo. China and the Global Economy Since 1840. Palgrave Macmillan UK, 2000.

Lu, Chongpu. “怎样认识与学习苏联电焊技术 [How to Recognize and Learn Soviet Electric Welding Technique].” 机械制造 [Machinery], no. 8 (1953).

Lu, Duanfang. Remaking Chinese Urban Form: Modernity, Scarcity and Space, 1949-2005. Taylor & Francis, 2006.

Lu, Shiwei. “Impacts of High-Speed Rails on the Accessibility Inequality of Railway Network in China.” 2014 22nd International Conference on Geoinformatics, June 1, 2014, 1–5.

Luger, Katrin. Chinese Railways: Reform and Efficiency Improvement Opportunities. Springer Science & Business Media, 2008.

Lüthi, Lorenz M. The Sino-Soviet Split: Cold War in the Communist World. Princeton University Press, 2008.

Ma, Ye, and Herman de Jong. “Unfolding the Turbulent Century: A Reconstruction of China’s Historical National Accounts, 1840–1912.” Review of Income and Wealth, 2017.

Page 173: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

167

MacFarquhar, Roderick, and Michael Schoenhals. Mao’s Last Revolution. Harvard University Press, 2006.

Mao, Zedong. A Talk to the Editorial Staff of the Shansi-Suiyuan Daily (April 2, 1948). Beijing: Foreign Languages Press, 1968.

———. Economic and Financial Problems during the Anti-Japanese War, and Other Articles. Beijing: Foreign Languages Press, 1955.

———. On New Democracy. 2d ed. Beijing: Foreign Languages Press, 1960. ———. On the Correct Handling of Contradictions Among the People. Beijing: Foreign

Languages Press, 1957. March, G. Patrick. Eastern Destiny: Russia in Asia and the North Pacific. Greenwood Publishing

Group, 1996. Marx, Karl. A Contribution to the Critique of Political Economy. C.H. Kerr, 1904. ———. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy. Translated by David Fernbach. Vol. 1.

Penguin Classics, 1992. ———. Theories of Surplus Value. Prometheus Books, 2000. ———. Value, Price and Profit: Speech to the First International Working Men’s Association,

June 1865. Socialist Labor Party, 1919. Marx, Karl, and Friedrich Engels. The Communist Manifesto: A Modern Edition. Verso, 1998. May, Shannon. “Ecological Urbanization: Calculating Value in an Age of Global Climate

Change.” In Worlding Cities, edited by Ananya Roy and Aihwa Ong, 98–126. Wiley-Blackwell, 2011.

Maycroft, Neil. “Consumption, Planned Obsolescence and Waste.” University of Lincoln, no. Working paper (2009).

McGee, Terry, George C. S. Lin, Mark Wang, Andrew Marton, and Jiaping Wu. “‘Seeing like a State’: The Urbanization Project in Post-1978 China.” In China’s Urban Space: Development Under Market Socialism, 29–52. Routledge, 2007.

Meisner, Maurice. Li Dazhao and the Origins of Chinese Marxism. Harvard University Press, 1967.

———. Mao’s China: A History of the People’s Republic. Free Press, 1977. ———. Mao’s China and After: A History of the People’s Republic, Third Edition. Simon and

Schuster, 1999. Meisner, Mitch. “The Shenyang Transformer Factory--A Profile.” The China Quarterly, no. 52

(1972): 717–37. Melman, Seymour. The War Economy of the United States: Readings on Military Industry and

Economy. St. Martin’s Press, 1971. Meyskens, Covell. “Third Front Railroads and Industrial Modernity in Late Maoist China.”

Twentieth-Century China 40, no. 3 (2015): 238–60.. Mills, Charles. From Class to Race: Essays in White Marxism and Black Radicalism. Rowman

& Littlefield Publishers, 2003.

Page 174: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

168

Miners, Norman. “Building The Kowloon-Canton-Hankow Railway.” Journal of the Royal Asiatic Society Hong Kong Branch 46 (2006): 5–24.

Ministry of Railways, ed. 鐵道年鑑 [Railway Yearbook]. Nanjing: 鐵道部秘書處 [Ministry of Railways Recording Office], 1936.

Mintz, Sidney W. “Was the Plantation Slave a Proletarian?” Review (Fernand Braudel Center) 2, no. 1 (1978): 81–98.

Mises, Ludwig von. “Economic Calculation in the Socialist Commonwealth.” In Collectivist Economic Planning: Critical Studies on the Possibilities of Socialism, edited by Frederich Hayek, 87–130. Ludwig von Mises Institute, 1967.

———. Socialism. Indianapolis, IN: Liberty Classics, 1981. ———. Socialism: An Economic and Sociological Analysis. Yale University Press, 1951. Monson, Jamie. Africa’s Freedom Railway: How a Chinese Development Project Changed Lives

and Livelihoods in Tanzania. Indiana University Press, 2009. Montias, John Michael. “Planning with Material Balances in Soviet-Type Economies.” The

American Economic Review 49, no. 5 (1959): 963–85. Moore, Michael. “The Rich Are Staging a Coup This Morning. A Message From Michael

Moore.” Common Dreams, September 9, 2008. https://www.commondreams.org/views/2008/09/29/rich-are-staging-coup-morning-message-michael-moore.

MOR Materials Bureau Communications Group. “清理资材,核定资金,反对浪费![Sort

Materials, Determine Available Capital, Fight Waste!].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. August 13, 1951, sec 2.

MOR Planning Division [铁道部计划司]. 全国铁路历史统计资料汇编 1949-1991. Beijing,

China: 中华人民共和国铁道部 [PRC MOR], 1992.

MOR Technology Research Communications Group. “铁道部铁道技术研究所介绍

[Introducing MOR Technology Institute].” 科学通报 [Chinese Science Bulletin], May 1950.

Mosse, David. Cultivating Development: An Ethnography of Aid Policy and Practice (Anthropology, Culture and Society Series). Pluto Press, 2005.

Mukerji, Chandra. Impossible Engineering: Technology and Territoriality on the Canal Du Midi. Princeton University Press, 2009.

Murphey, Rhoads. The Treaty Ports and China’s Modernization: What Went Wrong? University of Michigan, Center for Chinese Studies, 1970.

Nader, Laura. “Up the Anthropologist: Perspectives Gained from Studying Up.,” 1972. Nathan, Andrew J. “Imperialism’s Effects on China.” Bulletin of Concerned Asian Scholars 4,

no. 19 (1972): 3–8. Naughton, Barry. The Chinese Economy: Transitions and Growth. MIT Press, 2007.

Page 175: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

169

———. “The Third Front: Defence Industrialization in the Chinese Interior.” The China Quarterly, no. 115 (1988): 351–86.

Nelson, Daniel. Frederick W. Taylor and the Rise of Scientific Management. University of Wisconsin Press, 1980.

Ning, Jiafeng. “社会主义企业中流动资金的组织和计划工作 [The organization of liquid funds and planning work in socialist enterprises].” 中国金融 [China Finance], no. 12 (1953): 1–4.

Nolan, Peter, and Robert F. Ash. “China’s Economy on the Eve of Reform.” In China’s Transitional Economy, edited by Andrew George Walder, 18–36. Oxford University Press, 1996.

Northeast Railway Political Department. “齐齐哈尔铁路局 检查纠正供给思想坚决实行经济核算 [The Qiqihar Railway Bureau Inspected and Corrected Supply-System Thinking, Determined to Implement Economic Accounting System].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. October 22, 1950, sec 2.

Nove, Alec, and Domenico Mario Nuti. Socialist Economics: Selected Readings. Penguin, 1972. OECD. “Railway Reform in China Promoting Competition: Summary and Recommendations of

an OECD/DRC Seminar on Rail Reform in Beijing 28-29 January 2002,” January 2002. http://www.oecd.org/regreform/sectors/34566769.pdf.

O’Hanlon, Michael E. “U.S. Defense Strategy and the Defense Budget.” Brookings, November 18, 2015. https://www.brookings.edu/research/u-s-defense-strategy-and-the-defense-budget/.

Packard, Vance. The Waste Makers. D. Mckay, 1960. Parsons, William Barclay. An American Engineer in China. McClure, Phillips & Company,

1900. Peck, James. “The Roots of Rhetoric: The Professional Ideology of America’s China Watchers.”

Bulletin of Concerned Asian Scholars 2, no. 1 (1969): 59–69.

Peng, Yun ’e. 第一个五年计划中的铁路建设 [Railway Construction in the First Five Year

Plan]. Beijing, China: 中华全国科学技术普及协会出版 [Nation-wide society for the popularization of science and technology], 1956.

People’s Daily Editorial. “吸取铁路运输工作中的教训 [Absorbing the Lesson from Railway

Transport Work].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. February 25, 1953, sec 1.

People's Daily Editorial. “发扬勤俭办企业的革命精神 实行严格的经济核算制度 [Develop the Revolutionary Spirit of Dligience and Thrift in Enterprise Operations, Rigorously Carry out the Economic Accounting System].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. July 7, 1963, sec 1.

Page 176: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

170

People’s Railway News Group. “军委铁道部制定办法 搜集保护铁路交通器材 全国军民应

一致协助各路局收集 [MOR Formulates Measures to Gather and Protect Railway Transport Equipment, All Mobilized Masses Asked to Help Railway Bureaus with Collection].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. August 18, 1949, sec 1.

Perkins, Dwight. China’s Modern Economy in Historical Perspective. Stanford University Press, 1975.

Perry, Elizabeth J. Patrolling the Revolution: Worker Militias, Citizenship, and the Modern Chinese State. Rowman & Littlefield, 2007.

———. Shanghai on Strike: The Politics of Chinese Labor. Stanford University Press, 1993. Pittman, Russell. “Chinese Railway Reform and Competition: Lessons from the Experience in

Other Countries.” Journal of Transport Economics and Policy 38, no. 2 (2004): 309–32. Pomeranz, Kenneth. The Great Divergence: Europe, China, and the Making of the Modern

World Economy. Princeton University Press, 2000. Povinelli, Elizabeth A. Economies of Abandonment: Social Belonging and Endurance in Late

Liberalism. Duke University Press, 2011. ———. “Radical Worlds: The Anthropology of Incommensurability and Inconceivability.”

Annual Review of Anthropology 30, no. 1 (2001): 319–34. PRC. First Five-Year Plan for Development of the National Economy of the People’s Republic

of China in 1953-1957. Beijing: Foreign Languages Press, 1956. PRC State Statistics Bureau. Ten Great Year: Statistics of the Economic and Cultural

Achievements of the People’s Republic of China. Beijing: Foreign Languages Press, 1960.

“Premier Zhou En-Lai’s Report on the Work of the Government to the First Session of the Third National People’s Congress of the People’s Republic of China", December 1964.” In Main Documents of the First Session of the Third National People’s Congress of the People’s Republic of China. Beijing: Foreign Languages Press, 1965.

Rabinowitch, Alexander. The Bolsheviks Come to Power: The Revolution of 1917 in Petrograd. Pluto Press, 2004.

Rawski, Thomas G. “Chinese Industrial Reform: Accomplishments, Prospects, and Implications.” The American Economic Review 84, no. 2 (1994): 271–75.

Rea, George Bronson. “Railway Loan Agreements and Their Relation to the Open Door.” The Far-Eastern Review VI, no. 6 (November 1909): 215–27.

Reardon, Lawrence C. The Reluctant Dragon: Crisis Cycles in Chinese Foreign Economic Policy. University of Washington Press, 2015.

Ren, Jianxin. “加强经济合同工作促进国民经济计划的顺利执行 [Strengthening economic contracts to create a smooth process for our economic planning].” 法学研究 [Legal Research], no. 01 (1957): 31–34.

Page 177: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

171

Retsu, Kojima. “The Bearers of Science and Technology Have Changed.” Modern China 5, no. 2 (1979): 187–230.

Richman, Barry M. Industrial Society in Communist China: A Firsthand Study of Chinese Economic Development and Management. Random House, 1969.

Rigby, Edward Hulme, and William Orr Leitch. “Railway Construction in North China.” Minutes of the Proceedings of the Institution of Civil Engineers 160, no. 1905 (1905): 271–314.

Riskin, Carl. China’s Political Economy: The Quest for Development since 1949. Oxford University Press, 1987.

Robbins, Michael. The Railway Age. Manchester University Press, 1998. Rodney, Walter. Marx in the Liberation of Africa. Working People’s Alliance, 1981. Rogers, Heather. Gone Tomorrow: The Hidden Life of Garbage. New Press, 2006. Rose, Nikolas. “Governing by Numbers: Figuring out Democracy.” Accounting, Organizations

and Society 16, no. 7 (January 1, 1991): 673–92. ———. “Government, Authority and Expertise in Advanced Liberalism.” Economy and Society

22, no. 3 (1993): 283–99. Rosenbaum, Arthur. “Railway Enterprise and Economic Development: The Case of the Imperial

Railways of North China, 1900-1911.” Modern China 2, no. 2 (1976): 227–72. Rosovsky, Henry. Capital Formation in Japan, 1868-1940. Free Press of Glencoe, 1961. Rostow, Walt Whitman. The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-Communist Manifesto.

University Press, 1960. Rousseau, Jean-François. “An Imperial Railway Failure: The Indochina—Yunnan Railway,

1898–1941.” The Journal of Transport History 35, no. 1 (June 1, 2014): 1–17. Rutherford, Danilyn. “Sympathy, State Building, and the Experience of Empire.” Cultural

Anthropology 24, no. 1 (February 1, 2009): 1–32. Ryan, Tom. China Rising: A Study in Revolution. Melbourne: History Teachers Association of

Victoria, Limited, 2009. Said, Edward W. Orientalism. Vintage Books, 1979. Samuelson, Paul A. “A Few Remembrances of Friedrich von Hayek (1899–1992).” Journal of

Economic Behavior and Organization 69, no. 1 (2009): 1–4. Samuelson, Paul A., William D. Nordhaus, and Michael J. Mandel. Economics. 15th ed.

Mcgraw-Hill, 1995. Samuelson, Paul Anthony, and William D Nordhaus. Economics. 13th ed. McGraw-Hill, 1989. Samuelson, Paul Anthony, and William D. Nordhaus. Economics. 14th ed. McGraw-Hill, 1992. Sanderson, Michael. Education, Economic Change and Society in England 1780-1870.

Cambridge University Press, 1995. Schmalzer, Sigrid. Red Revolution, Green Revolution: Scientific Farming in Socialist China.

University of Chicago Press, 2016.

Page 178: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

172

Schurmann, Franz. Ideology and Organization in Communist China. University of California Press, 1971.

Schwartz, Benjamin Isadore. Chinese Communism and the Rise of Mao. Harvard University Press, 1951.

Scott, David. China and the International System, 1840-1949: Power, Presence, and Perceptions in a Century of Humiliation. SUNY Press, 2008.

Scott, James C. Seeing Like a State: How Certain Schemes to Improve the Human Condition Have Failed. Yale University Press, 1998.

Selden, Mark. China in Revolution: The Yenan Way Revisited. M.E. Sharpe, 1995. Shaffer, Harry G. The Soviet Economy. Appleton-Century-Crofts, 1963. ———. The Soviet Economy: A Collection of Western and Soviet Views. Appleton-Century-

Crofts, 1969. Shambaugh. “Building the Party-State in China, 1949–1965: Bringing the Soldier.” In New

Perspectives on State Socialism in China, edited by Timothy Cheek and Tony Saich. Routledge, 2016.

Shanxi Daily. “彻底批判供给制思想,树立经济核算制观点 [Thoroughly criticize supply-

system thinking, establish the economic accounting system perspective].” 山西日报, no. 05 (1953): 50–51.

Shaw, Adam. “Why Economic Forecasting Has Always Been a Flawed Science,” September 2, 2017, sec. Money. http://www.theguardian.com/money/2017/sep/02/economic-forecasting-flawed-science-data.

Shi, Zhihong. Central Government Silver Treasury: Revenue, Expenditure and Inventory Statistics, Ca. 1667-1899. BRILL, 2016.

Shrestha, Nanda R. In the Name of Development: A Reflection on Nepal. University Press of America, 1997.

Silver, Nate. The Signal and the Noise: Why So Many Predictions Fail-but Some Don’t. Penguin, 2012.

“Singapore.” U. S. Energy Information Administration. Accessed August 1, 2017. https://www.eia.gov/beta/international/analysis.cfm?iso=SGP.

Skousen, Mark. “The Perseverance of Paul Samuelson’s Economics.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 11, no. 2 (June 1997): 137–52.

Smith, Adrian J. Privatized Infrastructure: The Role of Government. Thomas Telford, 1999. Smith, Linda Tuhiwai. Decolonizing Methodologies: Research and Indigenous Peoples. Zed

Books, 1999.

Song, Baohua. “铁路系统的考工升级工作 [The task of testing and promoting workers in the

railway system].” 劳动 [Labour], no. 08 (1956): 17–19.

Page 179: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

173

Song Yongfu, ed. 中国铁路建设史 [The construction history of Chinese railways]. 中国铁道出

版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 2003.

Sorensen, Charles E. My Forty Years with Ford. Wayne State University Press, 1956. “South Korea.” U. S. Energy Information Administration. Accessed August 1, 2017.

https://www.eia.gov/beta/international/country.cfm?iso=KOR. Spence, Jonathan D. The Search for Modern China: A Documentary Collection. Norton, 1999. Stalin, Joseph. Problems of Leninism. Beijing, China: Foreign Languages Press, 1976. Stranahan, Patricia. Underground: The Shanghai Communist Party and the Politics of Survival,

1927-1937. Rowman & Littlefield, 1998. Stringer, Harold. “Railway Economics for China.” The Far-Eastern Review XXV, no. 7 (July

1929): 300–301. ———. The Chinese Railway System. Shanghai, 1922. Sun, E-tu Zen. “The Pattern of Railway Development in China.” The Far Eastern Quarterly (Pre-

1986); Ann Arbor 14, no. 2 (February 1955): 179. Sun, Yat-sen. San Min Chu I: The Three Principles of the People. Edited by L. T. Chen.

Translated by Frank W. Price. Shanghai: Commercial Press, 1929. ———. The International Development of China. New York: Putnam, 1929. Swyngedouw, Erik. Liquid Power: Contested Hydro-Modernities in Twentieth-Century Spain.

MIT Press, 2015. “Taiwan.” U. S. Energy Information Administration. Accessed August 1, 2017.

https://www.eia.gov/beta/international/country.cfm?iso=TWN. Takahara, Akio. The Politics of Wage Policy in Post-Revolutionary China. Springer, 1992. Tanner, Harold. “Railways in Communist Strategy and Operations in Manchuria, 1945-48.” In

Manchurian Railways and the Opening of China: An International History, edited by Bruce Elleman and Stephen Kotkin, 149–70. M. E. Sharpe, 2015.

Teng, Daiyuan. “经济核算制是经营管理人民铁路的基本方法 [The Economic Accounting System Is the Basic Method of Operations Management for the People’s Railways].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. June 21, 1951, sec 1.

Teng, Ssu-yu. Taiping Rebellion and the Western Powers: A Comprehensive Survey. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1971.

Teubal, Morris. “Heavy and Light Industry in Economic Development.” The American Economic Review 63, no. 4 (1973): 588–96.

The Common Program and Other Documents of the First Plenary Session of the Chinese People’s Political Consultative Conference. Beijing: Foreign Languages Press, 1950.

Tow, William T. Assessing US Bilateral Security Alliances in the Asia Pacific’s “Southern Rim”: Why the San Francisco System Endures. Institute for International Studies, Stanford University, 1999.

Page 180: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

174

Trouillot, Michel-Rolph. Global Transformations: Anthropology and the Modern World. Palgrave Macmillan, 2003.

Ven, Hans J. van de. From Friend to Comrade: The Founding of the Chinese Communist Party, 1920-1927. University of California Press, 1992.

Verdery, Katherine. What Was Socialism, and What Comes Next? Princeton University Press, 1996.

Vernengo, Matias. “Technology, Finance, and Dependency: Latin American Radical Political Economy in Retrospect.” Review of Radical Political Economics 38, no. 4 (2006): 551–68.

Visweswaran, Kamala. Fictions of Feminist Ethnography. University of Minnesota Press, 1994. Vukovich, Daniel. China and Orientalism: Western Knowledge Production and the PRC.

Routledge, 2013. Wakeman, Frederic. Strangers at the Gate: Social Disorder in South China, 1839-1861.

University of California Press, 1997. Walder, Andrew G. The Waning of the Communist State: Economic Origins of Political Decline

in China and Hungary. Berkeley: University of California Press, 1995. Wallerstein, Immanuel. “The Rise and Future Demise of the World Capitalist System: Concepts

for Comparative Analysis.” Comparative Studies in Society and History 16, no. 04 (September 1974): 387–415.

———. Unthinking Social Science: The Limits of Nineteenth-Century Paradigms. Temple University Press, 1991.

Wang, Chunshan, ed. 北京铁路局志 1881-1987 [Records of the Beijing Railway

Administration, 1881-1987]. Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1995.

Wang, Dong. China’s Unequal Treaties: Narrating National History. Lexington Books, 2005. Wang, James Jixian, Jiang Xu, and Jianfeng He. “Spatial Impacts of High-Speed Railways in

China: A Total-Travel-Time Approach.” Environment and Planning A 45, no. 9 (September 1, 2013): 2261–80.

Wang, Jiaoe, Fengjun Jin, Huihui Mo, and Fahui Wang. “Spatiotemporal Evolution of China’s Railway Network in the 20th Century: An Accessibility Approach.” Transportation Research Part A 43, no. 8 (2009): 765–78.

Wang, Lin. “天津铁路局财务工作显著进步 [The Tianjin Railway Bureau Has Made

Significant Progress in Its Financial Work].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. November 19, 1949, sec 2.

Wang, Wenxiang. “怎样利用铁路废料 [How to Make Use of Railway Waste].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. May 26, 1950, sec 5.

Warrian, Peter. A Profile of the Steel Industry: Global Reinvention for a New Economy. Business Expert Press, 2012.

Page 181: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

175

Weeks, Stanley B., and Charles A. Meconis. The Armed Forces of the USA in the Asia-Pacific Region. Allen & Unwin, 1999.

Wen, Pujin, and Zhizhong Wang, eds. 铁道部第十三工程局志 1948-1995 [Annals of the Ministry of Railways Engineering Corps Thirteenth Division, 1948-1995]. Beijing, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 2000.

Williams, Eric Eustace. Capitalism & Slavery. University of North Carolina Press, 1944. Williams, Mike, and D. A. Farnie. Cotton Mills in Greater Manchester. Carnegie, 1992. Wintz, Cary D. African American Political Thought, 1890-1930: Washington, Du Bois, Garvey

and Randolph. Routledge, 2015. Wójcik, Dariusz. “The Dark Side of NY–LON: Financial Centres and the Global Financial

Crisis.” Urban Studies 50, no. 13 (October 1, 2013): 2736–52. Wolff, Richard D. Capitalism Hits the Fan. Interlink Publishing, 2012. Wong, Christine. “Rebuilding Government for the 21st Century: Can China Incrementally

Reform the Public Sector?” The China Quarterly, no. 200 (2009): 929–52. World Bank. “Tracks from the Past, Transport for the Future: China’s Railway Industry 1990-

2008 and Its Future Plans and Possibilities.” The World Bank, May 1, 2009. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/2009/05/12721204/tracks-past-transport-future-chinas-railway-industry-1990-2008-future-plans-possibilities.

———. World Development Report 1983. The World Bank, 1983. Wou, Odoric Y. K. “The Chinese Communist Party and the Labor Movement: The May 30th

Movement in Henan.” Chinese Studies in History 23, no. 1 (October 1, 1989): 70–104.

Wu, Bingyuan, Pei Li, Jianfen Zhang, Jianfan Zhang, Shucheng Mu, and Xiaohua Li, eds. 毛泽

东哲学思想与中国铁路建设 [Mao Zedong’s Philosophical Thought and China’s Railway Construction]. Beijing, China: 文津出版社 [Wenjin Press], 1993.

Wu, Yiching. The Cultural Revolution at the Margins. Harvard University Press, 2014.

Xie, Yongjie, and Wenping Yu, eds. 兰州铁路局志 1956-1995 [Annals of the Lanzhou Railway

Bureau, 1956-1995]. Lanzhou, China: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 2001.

Xinhua News Agency. “郑州铁路管理局大力收集遗散器材 [Zhengzhou Railway Bureau

Makes a Great Effort to Collect Scattered and Left-behind Equipment].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. March 24, 1950, sec 1.

———. “铁道部召开全国铁路管理局长会议 决定贯彻经济核算制的办法 批判了供给制思

想和本位主义思想 [MOR Hosted a National Meeting of Railway Bureau Chiefs, Decided to Implement Economic Accounting System. Criticized the Supply System Way of Thinking and Narrow Pragmatism].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. July 19, 1951, sec 2.

Page 182: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

176

Xining Railway Bureau. 土方工程机械化半机械化施工经验 [The Experience of Mechanizing

and Half-Mechanizing Earthwork Construction]. Beijing, China: 人民铁道出版社 [The People’s Railway Press], 1960.

Xu, Zenglin, and MOR Record Compiling Department, eds. 新中国铁路五十年 1949-1999 [50

Years of New China’s Railways 1949-1999]. Beijing: 中国铁道出版社 [Chinese Railway Press], 1999.

Xue, Jichun. “关于在国家银行推行经济核算制的意见 [Comments on the National Bank's implementation of the economic accounting system].” 中国金融 [China Finance], no. 12 (1951): 1–2.

Yang, Peixin. “第一个五年计划的资金积累问题 [The question of capital accumulation in the

First Five Year Plan].” 经济研究 [Economics Research], no. 04 (1955): 12–35.

Yang, Yonggang. 中国近代铁路史 [History of Chinese Railways in the Modern Period].

Shanghai: 新华书店上海发行所, 1997.

Yeh, Emily T. “Greening Western China: A Critical View.” Geoforum 40, no. 5 (2009): 884–94. Yin-nor, Linda Tjia. Explaining Railway Reform in China: A Train of Property Rights Re-

Arrangements. Routledge, 2015. Young, Arthur Nichols. China’s Nation-Building Effort, 1927-1937. Hoover Institution Press,

1971. Young, Crawford. “Ideas of Progress in the Third World.” In Progress and Its Discontents, edited

by Gabriel Abraham Almond and Marvin Chodorow. University of California Press, 1985.

Yu, Fisher Y. C. “The Chinese Eastern Railway.” The Far-Eastern Review XXII, no. 2 (February 1926): 55–61.

Yu, Hong. “Railway Sector Reform in China: Controversy and Problems” 24, no. 96 (November 2, 2015): 1070–91.

Zhu, Jiamu and Liu Shukai. 陈云年谱 [The Life and Times of Chen Yun]. Vol. 1. Beijing: Central Literary Publishers [中央文献出版社], 2000.

Zhang, Laiyi. “论新民主主义经济核算制度 [Discussing the economic accounting system of the

new democracy].” 厦门大学学报 [Xiamen University Newspaper], no. 01 (1952): 59–64.

Zhang, Qikun. “浅谈中国铁路发展 [An Overview of Chinese Railway Development].” Beijing Jiaotong University, 2016.

Zhou, Hong, Jun Zhang, and Min Zhang. Foreign Aid in China. Springer, 2014.

Page 183: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

177

Zhu Congbin. 铁路与社会经济: 广西铁路研究 (1885-1965) [Railways and the economics of

society: Research on Guangxi Railways]. 合肥工业大学出版社 [Hefei University of Technology Press], 2012.

Zhu, Daijie. 铁路材料技术供应计划 [Plans for Supplying Railway Materials and Technology].

Beijing, China: 人民铁道出版社 [The People’s Railway Press], 1957.

Zhu, Xiaodong. “Understanding China’s Growth: Past, Present, and Future.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 26, no. 4 (2012): 103–124.

1956 年全国铁路先进生产者代表会议选编:财务会计先进经验 [Selection from the 1956 National Conference of Advanced Railway Production Representatives: Best Practices of Financial Accounting]. Beijing, China: 人民铁道出版社 [The People’s Railway Press], 1956.

马克思恩格斯列宁斯大林论交通运输业 [Marx, Engels, Lenin and Stalin on the Transportation Industry]. 人民铁道出版社 [The People’s Railway Press], 1965.

全党全民办铁路 [The party and all people make the railway run]. 人民铁道出版社 [The People’s Railway Press], 1959.

“全国铁道职工临代会上 滕部长报告任务及方针 [At the Nation-Wide Workers’

Representative Meeting, Minister Teng Reports on Tasks and Directions].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. July 4, 1949, sec 1.

“认真实行铁路军运条例 [Conscientiously Carry out the Regulations for Military Transport].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. April 23, 1949, sec 1.

“天津铁路局进行工作大检查 杜绝浪费厉行节约 [Tianjin Railway Bureau Carried out a Large

Inspecton, to Oppose Waste and Practice Strict Economy].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. March 21, 1950, sec 1.

“铁路系统在一九五二年中盲目运输打乱国家计划 [The Blindly Transporting Activities of the

Railway Sector Have Disrupted State Plans for 1952].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. February 25, 1953, sec 1.

“铁路部门实行经济核算制前作了一系列必需的准备工作 [A Series of Preparatory Work Is Required before Implementing the Economic Accounting System in the Railway Sector].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. July 19, 1951, sec 2.

“铁道部决定自七月一日起全国各铁路管理局实行经济核算制度 [MOR Issues Nation-Wide Directive for Railway Bureaus to Implement the Economic Accounting System, Starting on July 1].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. June 24, 1951, sec 2.

Page 184: Socialist Industrialization and Railway Sector Development ... · Zyler Zexi Wang . Master of Arts . Department of Geography and Planning University of Toronto . 2017 . Abstract .

178

“要办好人民铁道 须解决六个问题 [For Well-Functioning Chinese Railways, Resolve Six Problems].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. July 4, 1949, sec 1.

中国人民解放军铁道兵司令部 [PLA Railway Corp Headquarters], ed. 铁路职工专业教材:混凝土及钢筋工 [Specialized Education Material for Railway Work: Concrete and Steel-Reinforcing Work]. Beijing, China: 人民铁道出版社 [The People’s Railway Press], 1959.

“中央人民政府政务院人民监察委员会 关于处理某些国营、地方国营厂矿企业忽视安全生产致发生重大伤亡事故的通报 [Report from the State Council Inspection and Supervision Committee, on the Subject of How to Handle State- and Local-Run Factories and Mines That Have Neglected Safety, Causing Major Accidents].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. September 17, 1952, sec 1.

“中央人民政府铁道部 关于一九五零年工作总结与一九五一年计划的报告 [MOR Report on the Work Completed in 1950 and Plans for 1951].” 人民日报 [People’s Daily]. March 29, 1951, sec 2.

中长铁路经验介绍 [Introducing Experiences on the Zhongchang Railway]. Beijing, China: 人民铁道出版社 [The People’s Railway Press], 1953.


Recommended