+ All Categories
Home > Documents > SSRN-id158050

SSRN-id158050

Date post: 15-Apr-2016
Category:
Upload: puput-waryanto
View: 213 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
SSRN-id158050
23
THE MARKET VALUATION OF FIRM REPUTATION ERVIN L. BLACK* THOMAS A. CARNES* VERNON J. RICHARDSON** April 1999 *Assistant Professors, Department of Accounting, University of Arkansas, Fayetteville, AR 72701 **Assistant Professor, Division of Accounting and Information Systems, University of Kansas, Lawrence, KS 66045 Please direct all correspondence to Thomas A. Carnes at the above address, (501) 575-4117, [email protected]. The authors would like to thank Mark Hirschey, Jim Guthrie and Kelly Welch at the University of Kansas and participants at the Central States Accounting Workshop for their helpful comments on an earlier version of this paper.
Transcript
Page 1: SSRN-id158050

THE MARKET VALUATION OF FIRM REPUTATION

ERVIN L. BLACK*THOMAS A. CARNES*

VERNON J. RICHARDSON**

April 1999

*Assistant Professors, Department of Accounting, University of Arkansas,Fayetteville, AR 72701**Assistant Professor, Division of Accounting and Information Systems,University of Kansas, Lawrence, KS 66045

Please direct all correspondence to Thomas A. Carnes at the above address,(501) 575-4117, [email protected].

The authors would like to thank Mark Hirschey, Jim Guthrie and Kelly Welch atthe University of Kansas and participants at the Central States AccountingWorkshop for their helpful comments on an earlier version of this paper.

Page 2: SSRN-id158050

1

THE MARKET VALUATION OF FIRM REPUTATION

Abstract

We show that the intangible asset firm reputation has value relevance, as

measured by its ability to explain part of the difference between book value and market

value of equity. Firm reputation is measured using the Fortune survey of ÒAmericaÕs

most admired companies.Ó We allow the Fortune rankings to serve as a proxy for

nonfinancial information, such as customer service and intellectual capital. We

demonstrate this summary measure of nonfinancial information adds to market value,

even after controlling for the financial performance halo effects on the Fortune ratings.

Page 3: SSRN-id158050

2

THE MARKET VALUATION OF FIRM REPUTATION

Measurements of firm reputation appear nowhere in the financial

statements, yet it is apparent to the most casual of observers that corporations

expend vast amounts of time and money to burnish their reputations. Such

expenditures, of course, are undertaken with the expectation of resultant benefits

to the corporation. The benefits may not always be financial in a direct sense

(e.g., corporate sponsorship of a community event may be a Ògood neighborÓ

gesture that does not translate into increased sales). But it has been shown that

favorable reputations have firm-specific financial benefits to corporations by

reducing the mobility of industry rivals (Caves and Porter, 1977; Wilson, 1985);

by allowing firms to charge premium prices (Klein and Leffler, 1981; Milgrom and

Roberts, 1986); or by enhancing firm access to capital markets (Beatty and

Ritter, 1986). Firms appear to be Òinvolved in a competitive market for

reputational status in which, because of information asymmetries, firms signal

their key characteristics to constituentsÓ (Fombrun and Shanley, 1990). Firm

reputation therefore meets the customary accounting definition of an intangible

asset, though it is not one that is specifically identifiable (in contrast to a patent or

trademark). Instead, it is a qualitative asset, and the determination and timing of

its future benefits to the firm are extremely difficult to quantify, thereby posing

serious valuation problems. Edvinsson and Malone (1997) refer to such assets

as Òinvisible assets.Ó

Despite the difficulty in quantifying the worth of a favorable firm reputation,

it should have value to the investor since it results in financial benefits to the

Page 4: SSRN-id158050

3

corporation. As Edvinsson and Malone (1997) write, ÒSomehow, if only by

hunches and intuitions, the market is putting a value on invisible assets. And

some of these qualitative assets seem to hover in the ether almost indefinitely,

converting to line items on the balance sheet years after the market has

accounted for them.Ó There is anecdotal evidence regarding the value-relevance

of firm reputation: Fortune reports that a 1988 investment in its ten most admired

companies would have grown to nearly three times as much by 1998 as would

have a comparable investment in the Standard and PoorÕs 500.

We provide an empirical analysis of the value-relevance of one widely

known measure of firm reputation, the annual Fortune survey of AmericaÕs most

admired companies. We examine the value of firm reputation through use of the

Ohlson model (1995), which allows us to determine if firm reputation is a

significant explanatory component of market value of equity (MV). We take into

account the Brown and Perry (1994) finding that there is a financial performance

halo that heavily influences the list of FortuneÕs most admired companies and

employ a modified form of their methodology, thereby segregating financial

measures (MV, risk and growth) in the Fortune rankings before employing the

Ohlson model. This allows the Fortune rankings to serve as a proxy for an

aggregation of nonfinancial information, such as customer service, product

quality, and intellectual capital.

We find evidence of value-relevant information provided by the Fortune

survey that cannot be explained by financial information available from financial

reporting sources. This non-financial reputation component is evidence of an

Page 5: SSRN-id158050

4

invisible intangible asset that is value-relevant in explaining the market value of

the firm and appears to demonstrate the validity of corporate decisions to make

reputation-enhancing expenditures.

The remainder of this paper is organized as follows. First, we review

pertinent research on firm reputation. We then discuss research methodology,

provide results of the study, and present concluding remarks.

LITERATURE REVIEW

Tangible assets, as well as some classes of intangible assets (e.g.,

patents and trademarks), can be easily transferred, thereby allowing valuation

through an armsÕ length transaction. Firm reputation, an intangible asset that is

developed internally for the most part and that is not easily transferable to other

parties, does not lend itself to such easily determinable valuation.

Reputation-building, though, appears to be valuable to firms. Reputations

represent publicsÕ cumulative judgments of firms over time, according to

Fombrun and Shanley (1990), who conclude that these judgments Òstratify

industries, with potentially significant competitive advantages accruing to firm

with higher perceived reputational status.Ó They theorize that conditions of

incomplete and ambiguous information and heterogeneous publics make

reputations relevant, and they find that firms compete for reputation in such a

market. They study the 292 firms included in the 1985 Fortune survey and find

that assessments of reputation appear to be positively related to prior accounting

profitability, advertising intensity, and size, and negatively related to prior

performance-adjusted risk.

Page 6: SSRN-id158050

5

The importance of financial information, such as accounting profitability

and risk, to the Fortune rankings means that there exists a financial performance

halo in the magazineÕs index of firm reputation. Since individual raters appear to

be so heavily influenced by previous financial performance, previous attempts to

determine the relationship between specific attributes of firm reputation and firm

value may be victimized by a circularity Ð firm value improves reputation which

improves firm value ad infinitum. Brown and Perry (1994) develop a statistical

method to remove a significant portion of that halo in order to alleviate the

perceptual distortion it adds to the data. After forming a halo index based upon

various measures of recent financial performance, they determine firm-specific

residuals that represent the portion of the Fortune ratings not explained by

financial performance. They apply this method to the firms in the 1992 Fortune

survey and validate their results by comparing the halo-removed rating on four

specific attributes (e.g., product quality or innovation) to independent evaluations

of corporate performance on similar attributes. They conclude their method is

especially valuable for researchers using FortuneÕs ratings to test Òthe impact of

(nonfinancial) attributes on corporate financial performance or stock market

returns.Ó

Empirical investigations of limited aspects of firm reputation have been

undertaken by Ittner and Larcker (1998), Beatty and Ritter (1986), McGuire,

Sundgren and Schneeweis (1988), and McGuire, Schneeweis and Branch

(1990). Ittner and Larcker examine the value relevance of customer satisfaction

in order to determine whether measures of it are leading indicators of accounting

Page 7: SSRN-id158050

6

performance and whether the release of such measures provides new or

incremental information to the stock market. Their study includes customer

service measures at three levels: (1) a study of 2,491 customers buying a

specific telecommunications service from a single firm; (2) a business-unit

analysis of customer satisfaction from 73 retail branch banks of a major U.S.

financial services provider; and (3) firm-level data from the American Customer

Satisfaction Index. They find the relationships between customer satisfaction

and future accounting performance generally are positive, but some are non-

linear, showing evidence of diminishing benefits at high levels of satisfaction.

They also find that public release of these measures is statistically associated

with excess stock market returns.

Beatty and Ritter (1986) examine the underpricing of initial public offerings

and find that it is related to the reputational capital of investment bankers. They

conclude that investment bankers have non-salvageable reputational capital at

stake, and this enforces the underpricing equilibrium, as they show the market

penalizes underwriters who cheat on this equilibrium by underpricing too much or

too little.

McGuire, Sundgren and Schneeweis (1988), using FortuneÕs ratings as a

proxy for corporate social responsibility, find that perceptions of social

responsibility are more closely associated with prior financial performance than

with subsequent financial performance. These results may reflect the Òhalo

effectÓ referred to by Brown and Perry (1994), as the authors fail to control for the

influence financial variables have upon the Fortune rankings. McGuire,

Page 8: SSRN-id158050

7

Schneeweis and Branch (1990) extend these results to all eight dimensions of

perceived firm performance contained in the Fortune rankings and find that high

returns (both return on assets and market returns) are highly correlated with

subsequently high firm image Ð the Òhalo effectÓ of Brown and Perry (1994).

However, they find that the Fortune rankings Òhave little value as a forecaster of

future firm financial performance.Ó

Our research extends the existing literature by undertaking an explicit

search for market effects of nonfinancial factors affecting firm reputation. We

employ the Fortune ÒAmericaÕs most admired corporationsÓ rankings, thereby

investigating a broader definition of reputation than the specific aspect studied by

Ittner and Larcker (1998). By applying a variation of the model developed by

Brown and Perry (1994), we remove the Òhalo effectÓ of financial performance

and isolate the other influences upon the Fortune rankings in order to extend the

research of McGuire, Sundgren and Schneeweis (1988), and McGuire,

Schneeweis and Branch (1990).

METHODOLOGY

The market value of equity (MV) is the expectation of the expected future

cash flows (CF) accruing to stockholders discounted at the appropriate risk-

adjusted rate r:

(1)

×

=+= =

0][)1( 0

tCFErtMV tt

t

Page 9: SSRN-id158050

8

MV can be disaggregated into the market value of assets and liabilities. A

commonly used proxy for the market value of assets and liabilities is the book

value of assets and liabilities. However, due to conservatism, historical costs,

and the exclusion of most intangible assets, accounting book values are unlikely

to capture completely the implications of their market value counterparts.

Therefore, equation 1 becomes:

MVt = Assetst - Liabilitiest + Intangible Assetst (2)

where intangible assets represent, for example, the discounted cash flows

accruing to shareholders due to a competitive advantage, an anticipated growth

opportunity, or positive net present value projects.

Fortune annually rates AmericaÕs largest corporations in its ÒAmericaÕs

most admired corporationsÓ issue. Brown and Perry (1994) find that this rating,

which is a measure of the firmÕs competitive advantage, is heavily influenced by

the firmÕs previous financial results, thus creating a Òhalo effect.Ó This effect must

be removed or controlled for before these qualitative reputational measures can

be used appropriately in this study to measure the value relevance of the

intangible asset unexplained by financial reporting data. Brown and Perry find

several financial factors that affect the Fortune rating score (SCORE): return on

assets (ROA), market-to-book value (MKTBV), size, growth, and risk. Adding in

dummy variables for each year to control for other economic effects yields

equation 3.

Page 10: SSRN-id158050

9

(3)

where:

SCOREt = Firm Reputation Score in year t taken from Fortune magazine

annual reputation survey.

ROAt = (Income Before Extraordinary Items Deflated by Total Assets) *100

in year t.

MKTBVt = Market Value of Common Equity Deflated By Book Value of

Common Equity at the end of year t.

SIZEt = the natural log of the Market Value of Common Equity in year t

BETAt = Market Model Beta computed as 5-year (60-month) time period,

ending at the end of year t (as computed by Compustat).

GROWTHt = (Sales t-5 Ð Salest)/ Salest .

The residuals and estimated coefficients from this model are used to test

the value-relevance of the nonfinancial factors (the invisible assets). The

estimated coefficients are used to calculate a predicted reputation score which

measures the portion of the Fortune rating score that financial statement users

can obtain from financial performance data. The residuals from estimating

equation 3 represent the intangible assets related to reputation effects that a firm

has which cannot be obtained through the analysis of the financial statements

and market data.

tttttty

yt GROWTHaBETAaSIZEaMKTBVaROAaDMYaSCORE ε+++++++==

54321

96

820

Page 11: SSRN-id158050

10

Ohlson (1995) develops the following market valuation model, assuming

clean surplus accounting:

(4)

where,

MVt = the market value of equity at time t.

BVt = the book value of equity at time t.

NIt = net income at time t.

Modifying this equation to control for annual effects and to allow for the

measure of intangible assets including the nonfinancial factors estimated from

equation 3 yields:

(5)

where,

MVt = Market Value of Common Equity at year t

DMYy = Annual year dummy variables set equal for 1 if t = y; 0

otherwise.

BVt = Book Value of Common Equity at year t

NIt = Net Income Before Extraordinary Items at year t

NonFREPt-1 = Nonfinancial Component of Firm Reputation Ð derived by

taking the residual value from the estimation of firm

reputation in equation 3.

ttt NIBVMV +=

tttty

yt vNonFREPbNIbBVbDMYbMV +++++= −=

1321

96

820

Page 12: SSRN-id158050

11

The value-relevance of the nonfinancial component of firm reputation,

NonFREP, is estimated in equation 5. We use market value of equity at the end

of the year t as the dependent variable. It is expected that the market will have

impounded all current and past information into this value. The Fortune survey

results are published early in year t, but apply to the survey taken during t-1.

Thus, if the survey results are value-relevant, NonFREP should be significant.

Sample Selection

The sample consists of all of the firms rated by Fortune magazine in the

1982 through 1996 ÒAmericaÕs most admired corporationsÓ rating published early

each of the following years. For each year included in the sample, Fortune

sought ratings of corporate excellence from several thousand top executives,

outside directors, and securities analysts. These experts were asked to rate

firms in their own industry or economic sector, comparing them to competitors

with respect to eight key attributes of reputation: innovativeness, quality of

management, employee talent, quality of products/services, long-term investment

value, financial soundness, social responsibility, and use of corporate assets.

Fortune typically gets a response rate of about 50 percent to its survey, and it

publishes the results every March. In addition to the Fortune rating, we obtained

other financial data from Compustat PCPlus. These sample selection criteria

result in a sample size of 2,905 firm-year observations for equation 3 and 2,881

firm-year observations for estimation of equation 5.

Page 13: SSRN-id158050

12

RESULTS

We first estimate equation 3 in order to control for the Òhalo effectÓ

described by Brown and Perry (1994). Each of the variables in equation 3 is

statistically significant, with signs the same as found by Brown and Perry .

Descriptive statistics for the variables used in estimating equation 3 are found in

Table 1.

Insert Table 1 about here

The residuals from equation 3, which represent the nonfinancial reputation

component, are saved for use in equation 5. Coefficients for the estimation of

equation 2 are found in Table 2. The mean of these residuals, as expected, is

equal to 0.1

Insert Table 2 about here

We then estimate equation 5 in order to determine whether the

nonfinancial reputation component of the Fortune survey is incrementally value-

relevant once we control for the financial information. Descriptive statistics for

variables used to estimate equation 5 are found in Table 3.

Insert Table 3 about here

Page 14: SSRN-id158050

13

In column 3, Table 4, results of the estimation of equation 5 are reported.

Nonfinancial components of the Fortune reputation score are incrementally

value-relevant at p=.001, as are BV and income. The significant positive

coefficient on the nonfinancial components (NonFREP) provides evidence that

information provided by the Fortune survey that cannot be explained by financial

information available from financial reporting sources is value-relevant. This

nonfinancial reputation component is evidence of an invisible intangible asset

that is value-relevant in explaining the market value of the firm.

Insert Table 4 about here

As a form of sensitivity analysis, we test equation 5 using various

combinations of the independent variables. These results also are reported in

Table 4. The first column contains the results of the Ohlson model (equation 4),

omitting any variables related to reputation. As expected, both book value and

income have significant positive coefficients.

When the rating score from Fortune is added to the Ohlson model, its

coefficient is significant and positive (see column 2 of Table 4), indicating that the

score is incrementally value-relevant beyond income and book value. We also

find that the nonfinancial component of reputation, NONFREP, continues to be

positive and significant (see column 4 of Table 4) even when the financial

component of reputation is included.2

We also note the increase in the adjusted R2 from 74.2% to 75.41% when

the reputation score, SCOREt-1, is disaggregated between the nonfinancial and

Page 15: SSRN-id158050

14

financial components (see columns 2 and 4 of Table 4). It also interesting to

note the different coefficients and valuations given to a one-point change in score

($2.063 billion in column 2) versus a one-point change in the nonfinancial

component and financial components ($1.081 billion and $4.171 billion in column

4 respectively).

CONCLUSIONS

An important asset of the firm is its internally generated goodwill. Such

goodwill is the result of past reputation-enhancing activities and must be

constantly maintained. We provide evidence of the marketÕs ability to value this

invisible intangible asset, using the annual Fortune survey of ÒAmericaÕs most

admired companies,Ó even after controlling for the portion of the Fortune ranking

explained by financial reporting information. Our findings add support to existing

research that internally generated intangibles not currently recognized as assets

contribute to firm value and thus are viewed as assets by investors.

These findings have implications for external reporting, as many critics of

generally accepted accounting principles, such as Edvinsson and Malone (1997),

decry the failure of financial statements to value many intangible assets that are

critically important to modern corporations. Our demonstration that one widely-

publicized summary measure of such intangible assets is highly correlated with

market value Ð even after controlling for financial performance Ð provides further

evidence of the relevance of non-GAAP measures of firm-specific information.

This provides support for IASC Statement No. 38, ÒIntangible AssetsÓ and for the

Page 16: SSRN-id158050

15

position of the American Accounting Associations Financial Accounting

Standards Committee (1998).

A valid question for the inclusion of firm reputation as an intangible asset

in the financial statement continues to be the recognition criteria. While we

provide some evidence on the relative worth of an incremental increase in firm

reputation we do not provide a method for evaluating an individual firmÕs

reputation. Avenues for future research include isolation and valuation of specific

factors affecting firm reputation in order to determine which nonfinancial

information is more value-relevant to the markets and investigation of the market

effects of shifts in reputation.

Page 17: SSRN-id158050

16

REFERENCES

Beatty, R.P., and J.R. Ritter. 1986. Investment banking, reputation, andunderpricing of initial public offerings. Journal of Financial Economics, 15: 213-232.

Brown, B., and S. Perry 1994. Removing the financial performance halofrom FortuneÕs ÒMost Admired Companies.Ó Academy of Management Journal,37: 1347-1359.

Caves, R.E., and M.E. Porter. 1977. From entry barriers to mobilitybarriers. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 91: 421-434.

Edvinsson, L., and M.S. Malone. 1997. Intellectual capital: Realizing yourcompanyÕs true value by finding its hidden brainpower. New York:HarperBusiness.

Fombrun, C., and M. Shanley. 1990. WhatÕs in a name? Reputationbuilding and corporate strategy. Academy of Management Journal, 33: 233-258.

Ittner, C.D., and D.F. Larcker. 1998. Are nonfinancial measures leadingindicators of financial performance? An analysis of customer satisfaction.Journal of Accounting Research, Supplement: 1-35.

Lindsmeier, T., J. Boatsman, R. Herz, R. Jennings, G. Jonas, M. Lang, K.Petroni, D. Shores, and J. Wahlen. 1998. American Accounting AssociationÕsFinancial Accounting Standards Committee Response to IASC Exposure DraftE60, ÒIntangible Assets.Ó Accounting Horizons, 12: 312-316.

McGuire, J., T. Schneeweis, and B. Branch. 1990. Perceptions of firmquality: A cause or result of firm performance? Journal of Management, 16: 167-180.

McGuire, J., A. Sundgren, and T. Schneeweis. 1988. Corporate socialresponsibility and firm financial performance. Academy of Management Journal,31: 854-872.

Milgrom, P., and J. Roberts. 1986. Relying on the information ofinterested parties. Rand Journal of Economics, 17: 18-32.

Ohlson, J.A. 1995. Earnings, Book Values and Dividends in SecurityValuation. Contemporary Accounting Research, 11: 661-687.

Page 18: SSRN-id158050

17

Stewart, T.A. 1998. AmericaÕs Most Admired Companies. Fortune,137(4): 70-82.

Wilson, R. 1985. Reputations in games and markets. In Game-theoreticmodels of bargaining, edited by A. E. Roth, New York: Cambridge UniversityPress.

Page 19: SSRN-id158050

18

Table 1

Descriptive Statistics for firms used in Equation 3

Variable Mean Median Std. Deviation

SCOREt 6.445 6.480 0.881

ROAt 4.824 4.840 5.776

MKTBVt 2.597 1.999 3.777

SIZEt 8.072 8.086 1.395

BETAt 0.905 0.881 0.401

GROWTHt 65.224 42.029 194.007

N= 2,905 Firm-year observations

Definition of Variables:

SCOREt = Firm Reputation Score in year t taken from Fortune MagazineAnnual Reputation Survey.

ROAt = (Income Before Extraordinary Items Deflated by Total Assets) *100inyear t.

MKTBVt = Market Value of Common Equity Deflated By Book Value ofCommon Equity in year t.

SIZEt = the natural log of the Market Value of Common Equity in year tBETAt = Market Model Beta computed as 5-year (60-month) time period,

ending at the end of year t (as computed by Compustat).GROWTHt = (Sales t-5 Ð Salest)/ Salest .

Page 20: SSRN-id158050

19

Table 2

Estimation of Fortune Reputation Score

Score0 = α0 + α1ROAt + α2 MKTBVt + α3SIZEt + α4 BETAt

+ α5GROWTHt+ εt (3)

Variable Coefficient T-statistic

Constant 4.106 6.480

ROAt 0.058 23.471

MKTBVt 0.012 3.390

SIZEt 0.245 24.367

BETAt -0.086 2.663

GROWTHt 0.024 3.665

Adjusted R2: 39.82% F=107.732

Note: Statistically significant annual dummy variables are estimated (notreported) over pooled cross-section samples of firm data.

Definition of Regression Variables:

SCOREt = Firm Reputation Score in year t taken from Fortune MagazineAnnual Reputation Survey.

ROAt = (Income Before Extraordinary Items Deflated by Total Assets) *100inyear t.

MKTBVt = Market Value of Common Equity Deflated By Book Value ofCommon Equity in year t.

SIZEt = the natural log of the Market Value of Common Equity in year tBETAt = Market Model Beta computed as 5-year (60-month) time period,

ending at the end of year t (as computed by Compustat).GROWTHt = (Sales t-5 Ð Salest)/ Salest .

Page 21: SSRN-id158050

20

Table 3

Descriptive Statistics for Variables Used in Market Value Model

Variable Mean Median Std. Deviation

MVt 6702.344 2974.555 10983.647

BVt 3261.155 1623.376 4978.992

INCOMEt 458.549 206.443 894.561

SCOREt-1 6.445 6.480 0.881

NonFREPt-1 0.000 0.041 0.684

FREPt-1 6.446 6.470 0.561

N= 2,881 Firm-year Observations

Definition of Variables:MVt = Market Value of Common Equity at year t.BVt = Book Value of Common Equity at year t.NIt = Net Income Before Extraordinary Items at year t.NonFREPt-1 = Nonfinancial Component of Firm Reputation Ð derived by

taking the residual value from the estimation of firmreputation in equation 3.

FREPt-1 = Financial Component of Firm Reputation Ð derived bytaking the residual value from the estimation of firmreputation in equation 3.

SCOREt-1 = Firm Reputation Score in year t taken from FortuneMagazine Annual Reputation Survey.

Page 22: SSRN-id158050

21

Table 4

Market Valuation of Nonfinancial Components of Firm Reputation

(5)

Coefficient(t-statistic)

Coefficient(t-statistic)

Equation 5

Coefficient(t-statistic)

Coefficient(t-statistic)

Constant 1261.419(3.67)

-11566.977(-13.87)

1283.959(3.68)

-24687.711(-18.39)

BVt 1.068(32.49)

1.048(33.29)

1.073(32.30)

1.030(32.97)

NIt 4.961(26.927)

4.398(24.53)

4.924(26.49)

3.898(21.45)

NonFREPt-1 1023.691(6.41)

1081.10(7.22)

FREPt-1 4170.684(19.95)

SCOREt-1 2062.755(16.74)

Adj. R2 71.77% 74.20% 72.02% 75.41%

Definition of Regression Variables:MVt = Market Value of Common Equity at year t.BVt = Book Value of Common Equity at year t.NIt = Net Income Before Extraordinary Items at year t.NonFREPt-1 = Nonfinancial Component of Firm Reputation Ð derived by

taking the residual value from the estimation of firmreputation in equation 3.

FREPt-1 = Financial Component of Firm Reputation Ð derived bytaking the residual value from the estimation of firmreputation in equation 3.

SCOREt-1 = Firm Reputation Score in year t taken from FortuneMagazine Annual Reputation Survey.

Variables for which no coefficient was reported were not considered in thatversion of equation 5.

tttty

yt NonFREPbNIbBVbDMYbMV ν+++++= −=

1321

96

820

Page 23: SSRN-id158050

22

ENDNOTES

1 We also ranked the residuals and used the ranking rather than the residual, with no qualitativeeffect upon the results.2 It is possible that firm reputation varies by industry. As a test of robustness, we include industrydummy variables in the estimation of models 3 and 5 and find similar results. As another test ofrobustness, we control for the possible endogeneity between market value and the estimation ofthe Fortune reputation score by estimating the incremental market valuation of the financial(FREPt-1) and non-financial components of reputation (NonFREPt-1) beyond the lagged marketvalue of common equity, MVt-1 and find NonFREPt-1 to still be positive and significant.


Recommended