+ All Categories
Home > Documents > SSRN-id714761

SSRN-id714761

Date post: 06-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: pratyush-tripathi
View: 225 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend

of 49

Transcript
  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    1/49

    1

    AMITAV CHAKRAVARTI and JINHONG XIE*

    Standards Competition and Effectiveness of Advertising Formats in New

    Product Introduction

    * Amitav Chakravarti is Assistant Professor of Marketing, New York University, 44 West FourthStreet, Suite 9-83, New York, NY 10012-1126 (Phone: 212 998 0517; Fax: 212 995 4006; email:[email protected]). Jinhong Xie is Associate Professor of Marketing, University ofFlorida, P.O. Box 117155, Gainesville, FL 32611-7155 (Phone: 352 392 0161 Ext. 1233; Fax:352 846 0457; email: [email protected]). The authors thank Bart Weitz, Joe Alba, RichLutz, and Alan Sawyer for their detailed comments and many helpful suggestions.

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    2/49

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    3/49

    3

    INTRODUCTION

    With the rapid development of information technology and the digital revolution,

    technological standards have an increasingly important effect on the success of many new

    products, including computers, electronic video games, wireless communication, home

    networking, video/audio electronics, banking services, and the Internet (Katz and Shapiro 1994).

    As noted by The Economist, New standards can be the source of enormous wealth, or the death

    of corporate empires. With so much at stake, standards arouse violent passions (The Economist

    1993).

    A common feature of the markets in which technological standards have become so

    important is that the consumption utility of a product or service increases with the number of

    people using it. Economists call this demand interdependence network externalities (Farrell and

    Saloner 1986, Katz and Shapiro 1985) or network effects (Chou and Shy, 1992). Standards

    competition is common in the presence of network effects because the product feature that

    creates the network usually requires a technical protocol to do so. These technical protocols are

    often patent protected. In the early stages of market development, competitors may

    simultaneously introduce products based on incompatible patented technologies. Standards

    competition may also occur either because an incumbent refuses to license its technology to a

    new entrant or because the cost of achieving compatibility is so high that the entrant prefers to

    introduce its own technology. Standards competition may also arise because an entrant may

    refuse to take a license, hoping to establish its own standard and reap major profits in future.

    Over the last two decades, we have observed many fierce standards battles between

    incompatible technologies (Shapiro and Varian 1998). Some well-known examples are those for

    the VCR between Matsushitas VHS and Sonys Betamax formats, for streaming audio and

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    4/49

    4

    video software between Microsoft and RealNetworks, for 56k modems between 3Com and

    Rockwell/Lucent, and for Internet browsers between Microsoft and Netscape. In addition, there

    are many ongoing standards battles in various new product markets, such as home networking

    (Wong 2000), wireless communication (Wexler 2000), expansion devices for portable

    electronics (Miles 2000), digital music devices (Chun 1999), personal digital assistants, and on-

    line music sharing software (Richtel 2001).

    Because of their importance, standards battles and network effects have generated a

    considerable amount of research. For example, economists have examined the social welfare

    implications of standards competition and have analyzed associated issues of regulatory policy

    (e.g., Farrell and Saloner 1986, Katz and Shapiro 1985). Recent research has also explored issues

    of firm strategy and new product pricing (Dhebar and Oren 1985, Xie and Sirbu 1995), new

    product diffusion acceleration (Van den Bulte 2000), product upgrades (Padmanabhan, Rajiv,

    and Srinivasan 1997), technology licensing and standards competition (Sun, Xie, and Cao 2002),

    product compatibility (Xie and Sirbu 1995), complementary products diffusion (Gupta, Jain, and

    Sawhney 1999), asymmetric network effects (Shankar and Bayus 1999), knowledge management

    in service firms (Ofek and Sarvary 2001), cross-market network effects (Chen and Xie 2003),

    effect of network effects on pioneer survival (Srinivasan, Lilien, and Rangaswamy 2004), and

    empirical analysis of indirect network effects (Nair, Chintagunta, and Dub 2004).

    While recent research has examined standard battles from both societal and firm

    perspectives, the consumers perspective has received little attention. Most theoretical work on

    standard wars is based on the simple assumption that consumers willingness to pay for a

    standard increases with its installed base. Aside from several recent empirical studies that use

    aggregate, market-level data such as prices and sales to test the existence of such a relationship

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    5/49

    5

    in some industries (e.g., Brynjolfsson and Kemerer 1996, Gandal 1995), recent research has

    provided little theory or evidence on how consumers may behave in markets with standards

    battles. Compared to other markets, those with standard battles exhibit certain fundamental

    characteristics that make the consumer decision to adopt a new product more risky and complex.

    First, the expected utility of adopting a product in these markets is largely determined by the

    standards future installed base, which is highly uncertain in the early stages of the standards

    introduction. Second, the adoption decision is also more complicated because consumers often

    must choose not only among brands but also among competing technological standards (e.g.,

    Nintendo vs. Sega systems for video game players, GSM vs. TDMA for digital wireless

    telephones, DVD vs. Divx systems for digital video disk players, and Microsoft Word vs.

    WordPerfect for word processing software). Finally, adopting a "losing" standard can be very

    costly to consumers (e.g., to owners of the Betamax VCR and Divx digital video players). For

    these reasons, consumers may behave very differently in markets with standards battles than in

    those without them: they may search for different types of information, use different criteria in

    evaluating and comparing alternatives, engage in different decision-making processes, and

    respond differently to advertising.

    Another limitation of research on standards competition and network effects is the dearth

    of research on firm communication strategies. Given the high uncertainty and extreme

    complexity of consumers adoption decisions in markets with standards battles, it is crucial for

    firms to communicate effectively with consumers about the value of their products and to take

    steps to build consumer confidence in the products future market growth.

    In this paper, we ask and answer four specific research questions. First, does standards

    competition affect the likelihood of consumer new product adoption? Second, does standards

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    6/49

    6

    competition affect the importance that consumers place on different types of performance-related

    product information? Third, since advertising is often used to convey performance-related

    information, how does standards competition affect consumer response to various advertising

    formats, and which advertising format is most effective in winning a standards battle? Fourth,

    will the effectiveness of various advertising formats in markets with standards competition be

    moderated by consumer familiarity with the advertised and comparison brands?

    To address these questions, we designed three studies. The first study was motivated by

    the fact that it is fairly commonplace to express consumption utility in both absolute and relative

    terms. Thus, in the first study we examine the effect of standards competition on consumers

    adoption decisions and the relative importance in such decisions of two types of performance-

    related information: absolute and relative product performance. Building on results from the first

    study, the second study investigates the interaction between standards competition and the

    effectiveness of three different advertising formats--direct comparative, indirect comparative,

    and non comparative. The third study investigates the moderating effect of consumer brand

    familiarity on the effectiveness of advertising formats in markets with competing standards.

    The three studies are presented in the next three sections. After presenting the results of

    our three experiments, we conclude by summarizing our findings, interpreting their implications,

    and discussing avenues for future research.

    STUDY 1

    Study 1 addresses two of the four questions raised earlier. First, we investigate how a

    standards battle affects a consumer's new product adoption decision. Specifically, does an

    ongoing standards battle significantly reduce the consumers likelihood of adopting a new

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    7/49

    7

    product? The literature on network effects suggests that an unresolved standards competition

    reduces the probability of adoption early in the diffusion process (Van den Bulte 2000). Such a

    standards war increases consumer uncertainty because the value of a product is determined not

    by its quality alone but also by the outcome of the standards war (Klopfenstein 1989). For

    example, after VHS won the standards battle in the VCR market in the 1980s, the Sony Betamax

    player was considerably devalued because it could not play VHS tapes, and Betamax tapes were

    no longer being made. Although the outcome of standards battles has a very significant impact

    on them, consumers have no means of predicting that outcome accurately. This leads to a great

    deal of uncertainty for the consumer early in the life cycle of the product (Van den Bulte 2000).

    Consequently, consumers may defer making a choice and may even forego adopting a product

    altogether (e.g., see Tversky and Shafir 1992, Dhar 1997, Burnham, Frels, and Mahajan 2003).

    As a face validity check, we hypothesize that:

    H1: Consumers are less likely to adopt a new product in the presence of standards

    competition than in the absence of such competition.

    The second and more important question addressed by Study 1 concerns the effect of

    standards competition on the importance that consumers place on different types of performance-

    related product information. Consumers often actively seek information about the performance

    of products they intend to buy in order to predict the consumption utility of those products.

    Consumption utility can be expressed in both absolute and relative terms, as economics and

    decision-making research have clearly shown. Absoluteutility, which is sometimes described as

    choiceless utility (Loomes and Sugden 1982), is the utility associated with the consumption of a

    particular good independent of other available alternatives. Relative utility is the differential

    consumption utility of a good relative to available alternatives.

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    8/49

    8

    Utility theory (e.g., see Mas-Colell, Whinston, and Green 1995) suggests that, when

    facing two alternative product offerings X and Y, a consumer will choose product X if two

    conditions hold: (1) a positive absolute utility of X (i.e., U(X) > 0), and (2) a positive relative

    utility of X over Y (i.e., U(X) - U(Y) > 0). Clearly, information about product performance can

    help consumers evaluate the two utility conditions, and this information also can be expressed in

    absolute or relative terms. In general, consumers value information on both absolute and relative

    performance of a product since it is predictive of its underlying absolute and relative utility.

    We propose, however, that consumers give significantly greater weight to information

    about the relative performance of a product in the presence of standards competition than in the

    absence of such competition. Findings from several streams of literature suggest that, in the face

    of uncertainty, decision makers become significantly more sensitive to information that

    compares choice alternatives. For example, the reason-based choice paradigm suggests that, in

    the face of uncertainty, decision makers tend to evaluate the consequences both of choosing one

    alternative and of foregoing the other (Shafir and Tversky 1992, Inman, Dyer and Jia 1997).

    Regret theory makes similar claims (e.g., Loomes and Sugden 1982, Sage and White 1983). The

    literature on decision making under conditions of uncertainty (e.g., Lipshitz and Strauss 1997)

    suggests that when faced with undifferentiated alternatives, decision makers often cope by

    carefully weighing the pros and cons of adopting one alternative over another. In the face of

    standards competition, consumers often feel very uncertain about which of the competing

    products will eventually win the standards battle. It is likely that consumers will resolve this

    uncertainty by carefully weighing the pros and cons of adopting one standard over another. Thus,

    information on relative performance of a product should have a greater impact on consumer

    adoption decisions when a standards war is present than when absent.

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    9/49

    9

    Additionally, we propose that standards competition may decrease the value of

    information regarding the absolute performance of a product. Our proposition is based on the

    fact that "winner-takes-all" scenarios are common in markets with standards competition

    (although not all incompatibilities lead to winner-takes-all outcomes). In a standards market, a

    product often needs to win the standards battle in order to provide any benefit at all to the

    consumer. As a result, in the presence of standards wars, the value of information depends

    greatly on whether it can help consumers predict the winner. Product information that helps

    consumers predict the winner is highly valued, whereas product information that is a poor

    predictor of the winning standard is devalued. In markets with standards competition,

    information on absolute product performance is an unreliable predictor of the winning standard

    (Klopfenstein 1989). Consequently, consumers are likely to give less weight to information

    regarding absolute product performance in markets with standards competition than in those

    without. Note that this proposition does not automatically follow from the previous proposition

    because absolute performance and relative performance of a product are two distinct aspects of

    product performance (e.g., see discussion by Markman and Moreau 2001), and more

    importantly, the absolute performance and relative performance of a product can vary

    independent of each other.

    Formally, we hypothesize that:

    H2a: The impact of information regarding the relative performance of a product on

    consumers' adoption decisions is significantly stronger in markets with standards

    competition than in those without standards competition.

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    10/49

    10

    H2b: The impact of information regarding the absolute performance of a product on

    consumers' adoption decisions is significantly weaker in markets with standards

    competition than in those without standards competition.

    Procedure and Stimuli

    A computer-based experiment was conducted with a 2 (presence/absence of standards

    wars) x 2 (high/low absolute ratings) x 2 (high/low relative ratings), between-subjects design. A

    total of 181 undergraduate subjects participated in the study for extra credit. Videophones were

    chosen as the experimental product for two reasons: (1) Subjects did not have strong existing

    opinions about the product, and (2) subjects would not automatically assume the existence of a

    standards battle. The latter could be of concern especially with products such as computers and

    digital video disc players because of the widely publicized battles between Windows and

    Macintosh, and between DVD and Divx. The experimental procedure consisted of the following

    steps:

    Step1. Subjects were briefed about the experimental session. This briefing included

    instructions about the computer terminals and about the study. The computer terminals randomly

    assigned the subjects to any one of the eight experimental conditions.

    Step2. Subjects then read a description of a new product market (videophones).

    Depending on the condition assigned, subjects read either the No Standards War description or

    the Standards War description (see Figure 1, top panel). The first two paragraphs were

    identical for both descriptions and introduced the subjects to the new product, the key attributes

    of this product, and the two competing firms (Conmec and Dwyer) that produced it. The

    presence or absence of a standards war was manipulated by the third and fourth paragraphs in the

    description. Subjects assigned to the standards war conditions were told that the two competing

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    11/49

    11

    brands were incompatible with each other, that analysts expected a standards battle between the

    two brands, and that there was considerable uncertainty regarding the outcome of this battle.

    Subjects assigned to the no standards war conditions were told that the two competing brands

    were compatible with each other, that analysts expected a battle between the two brands, and that

    there was considerable uncertainty regarding the outcome of this battle. Thus, the key difference

    between the two descriptions was the presence or absence of compatibility between the two

    competing brands.

    Step3. After the subjects understood the previous section to their satisfaction, they were

    given a choice task. Subjects saw one of the four possible choice scenarios (see Figure 1, middle

    panel). Subjects were told that they would be given "overall" ratings from Consumer Reports for

    the two products. The brands were shown on an 11-point scale and the ratings were described in

    a sentence (e.g., see Figure 1, bottom panel). The key manipulations involved varying the

    absolute and relative ratings of Conmec. The absolute rating of Conmec was determined by the

    star rating directly associated with Conmec, while the relative rating of Conmec was determined

    by the difference in the star ratings of Conmec and Dwyer. For example, consider the condition

    where Conmec was rated 8 stars while the other brand, Dwyer, was rated 7 stars (see Figure 1,

    middle panel). Here the absolute rating of Conmec was 8 stars, while the relative rating (i.e., the

    difference in ratings between the two brands) of Conmec was 1 star. The absolute rating of

    Conmec was varied at two levels, i.e., 8 stars or 10 stars. The relative rating of Conmec was also

    varied at two levels, i.e., a difference of 1 star or a difference of 3 stars. The design ensured that

    the absolute (relative) rating of Conmec was held constant when its relative (absolute) rating was

    varied.

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    12/49

    12

    The focal brand, Conmec, was the higher-rated and more expensive brand (Conmec =

    $120, Dwyer = $80) in all four choice scenarios. In each case, subjects were given the option to

    defer their decision for a later occasion, choose the focal brand (Conmec), or choose the other

    brand (Dwyer). In addition to the choice task, they were asked to provide reasons for their

    choice. They were also asked to answer a manipulation check question that is discussed later.

    Results

    Adoption Rates (H1). Hypothesis H1 suggests a negative effect of standards competition

    on new product adoption. Table 1 presents the choice count and share (in parenthesis) for each

    choice option given different relative (low/high) and absolute (low/high) ratings. Table 1 also

    presents the category adoption rate (AR) with and without a standards war (ARwithout std. wars =

    80%, ARwith std. wars = 51% ). We formally tested the hypothesized negative effect of standards

    competition on new product adoption using a logistic regression model:

    CHOICEConmec = 0 + 1*SWAR

    where CHOICEConmec is the choice share of the focal brand Conmec, and SWAR is a dummy

    variable indicating the existence of standards war (i.e., SWAR = 0 in the absence of a standards

    war, SWAR = 1 in the presence of standards war). As predicted, standards competition had a

    negative effect on the focal brands choice share (1= -1.36, standard error [S.E.] = 0.33, Wald-

    2 (1, N = 181) = 16.41, p < 0.01, also p = 0.00 by Fishers Exact Test1). This suggests that

    significantly more subjects chose to defer choice in the presence of standards war than in its

    absence.

    Information on Relative Performance (H2a). Our hypothesis (H2a) suggests that the

    presence of standards competition will strengthen the impact of information regarding relative

    1 For all studies, we provide Fishers Exact Test for small samples along with the Wald-2 statistic. Note though,FET can be conducted only on ab contingency tables, and not on higher order (e.g., abc) contingency tables.

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    13/49

    13

    performance. Following Barron and Kenny (1986), we tested the hypothesized interaction effect

    using the following logistic regression model:

    CHOICEConmec = 0 + 1*RELATIVE + 2*SWAR + 3*RELATIVE*SWAR

    where RELATIVE is the relative rating (low/high). The interaction term was marginally

    significant (3 = 1.07, S.E. = 0.64, Wald-2

    (1, N = 181) = 2.74, p < 0.10), providing support for

    H2a. This result implies that information on the relative performance of a product had a greater

    impact on choice shares in the market with a standards war than in the market without a

    standards war.

    This positive moderating effect of standards competition on the importance of relative

    performance can also be found by examining the simple main effects. The upper part of Table 2

    shows Conmecs marginal choice share under low and high relative performance ratings. As

    shown in Table 2, in the presence of a standards war, Conmecs choice share is 20% given a low

    relative performance rating, but 59% given a high relative performance rating.2 This difference is

    significant (parameter estimate [B] = -1.73, S.E. = 0.47, Wald-2 (1, N = 91) = 13.21,p < 0.01,

    also p = 0.00 by Fishers Exact Test). However, in the absence of a standards war, Conmecs

    choice share is 53% given a low relative performance rating and 69% given a high relative

    performance rating. This difference is not significant (B = -0.66, S.E. = 0.43, Wald-2 (1, N =

    90) = 2.26, p > 0.10, also p = 0.20 by Fishers Exact Test). We also graphically illustrate this

    interaction effect in Table 2. The graph shows that an increase in Conmecs relative performance

    increases Conmecs choice share to a greater degree in the presence of a standards war (39%

    increase) than in the absence of a standards war (16% increase).

    2 The choice shares in Table 2 are margin totals calculated from Table 1 (see the example presented at the bottom ofTable 2).

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    14/49

    14

    Information on Absolute Performance (H2b). Hypothesis H2b suggests that the presence of

    standards competition will weaken the impact of information regarding absolute performance.

    We tested the hypothesized interaction effect using the following logistic-regression model:

    CHOICEConmec = 0 + 1*ABSOLUTE + 2*SWAR + 3*ABSOLUTE*SWAR

    where ABSOLUTE is the absolute rating (high/low). This interaction term was not

    significant (3 = -0.63, S.E. = 0.61, Wald-2 (1, N = 181) = 1.05, p > 0.10). However, the simple

    main effects do provide some evidence that the impact of absolute ratings differ with the

    presence/absence of a standards war. As shown in the lower part of Table 2, in the presence of a

    standards war, Conmecs choice share is 38% given a low absolute performance rating and 41%

    given a high absolute performance rating. This difference is not significant (B = -0.14, S.E. =

    0.42, Wald-2 (1, N = 91) = 0.11, p > 0.10, alsop = 0.83 by Fishers Exact Test). However, in

    the absence of a standards war, Conmecs choice share is 52.2% given a low absolute

    performance rating, but 70.5% given a high absolute performance rating. This difference is

    significant (B = -0.78, S.E. = 0.44, Wald-2 (1, N = 90) = 3.11, p < 0.10, also p = 0.08 by

    Fishers Exact Test). As shown in the corresponding graph, an increase in absolute rating

    increases Conmecs choice share to a lesser extent in the presence of a standards war (3%

    increase) than in the absence of a standards war (18.3% increase). These results provide evidence

    supportingH2b.

    Discussion

    The evidence from Study 1 suggests that standards competition moderates the effect of

    both absolute and relative ratings on the choice shares of the focal brand. A higher relative rating

    leads to a significant increase in choice share in the presence of a standards war, but to a non

    significant increase in choice share in the absence of a standards war. This implies that standards

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    15/49

    15

    competition strengthens the impact of information regarding relative product performance. On

    the other hand, a higher absolute rating of the focal brand leads to a significant increase in its

    choice share in the absence of standards competition but does not significantly affect its choice

    share in the presence of such competition. This implies that standards competition weakens the

    impact of information regarding absolute performance.

    These results indicate that subjects were differentially sensitive to information regarding

    absolute and relative product performance in the presence of standards wars. Analysis of the

    manipulation check is consistent with this explanation. As a manipulation check, subjects were

    asked to indicate the extent to which they paid more attention to the relative ratings of the brands

    than to corresponding absolute ratings in making their decision. Subjects reported greater use of

    relative judgments in the presence of a standards war (mean [M] = 5.70) than in the absence of a

    standards war (M = 5.0,F(1, 179) = 5.43, p < 0.05).

    STUDY 2

    The first study demonstrated the importance of information on relative performance of

    products in standards markets. However, the implications of this finding for ways in which

    companies should design their marketing communications are less clear. The previous study

    suggests that consumers value marketing communication that conveys information on relative

    performance of a target brand. One way of conveying information about the relative performance

    of a product is to use ad formats that are comparative in nature. Would the increased value of

    information on relative performance lead to a greater preference for comparative over non

    comparative ad formats? More specifically, in the presence of standards competition, are

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    16/49

    16

    comparative formats more effective than non comparative formats in inducing consumers to

    adopt the advertised brand? We addressed this specific research question in the current study.

    Results from Study 1 and past research on comparative advertising suggest that the

    presence of a standards war might moderate the impact of comparative and non comparative ad

    formats on product adoption. First, results from Study 1 indicate that comparative ad formats

    may positively impact product adoption. Recall that Study 1 showed that the presence of a

    standards war resulted in greater impact of information on relative performance of products,

    which in turn led to higher choice shares (see also manipulation check). These results indirectly

    suggest that, in the presence of a standards war, information on relative product performance

    creates greater confidence in the target brand. Since comparative ad formats tend to provide

    information about relative performance of the advertised product, whereas non comparative ad

    formats typically do not provide such information, it is likely that there will be greater

    confidence in the advertised brand when the format is comparative than when it is non

    comparative. Thus, comparative ad formats could be more effective than their non comparative

    counterparts because of the ability of the former to reduce uncertainty regarding the advertised

    brand. This suggests that, in markets with standards competition, comparative formats are likely

    to be more effective than non comparative formats in inducing consumers to adopt the target

    brand.

    However, past research on comparative advertising shows that, under certain conditions,

    comparative formats can be less effective than non comparative formats. Two main explanations

    have been advanced for the relative superiority of non comparative formats in such cases. One is

    related to the generation of negative affect (e.g., see Pechmann & Ratneshwar 1991).

    Comparative ads tend to generate negative affect, and consumers find such ads offensive and

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    17/49

    17

    irritating. Negative affect or ad-evoked feelings, in turn, often lead to source derogation,

    discounting of ad message, and negative attitude toward the ad and advertised brand (Brown,

    Homer and Inman 1998). As a result, consumers may view the advertised brand unfavorably

    (Batra and Ray 1986). In contrast, non comparative ads do not generate negative affect because

    they avoid comparison between brands (Grewal et al. 1997). In the presence of a standards war,

    certain characteristics of the environment may accentuate this negative affect toward

    comparative ads. Given the possibility of a "winner-takes-all" outcome in a standards war

    environment, firms have a greater incentive to claim superiority over competing standards.

    Consumers are likely to be sensitive to this fact and may more actively engage in source

    derogation and discounting of the ad message when they view such ads (Friestad and Wright

    1994).

    The second explanation for why non comparative formats may be superior under some

    conditions is based on association heuristics (Chaiken 1987). According to this theory, the very

    act of comparing two (or more) brands reinforces the consumer's belief in the similarity of these

    brands, often leading to sponsor misidentifications (e.g., see Pechmann and Stewart 1990).

    Consequently, consumers end up invoking a heuristic that leads them to believe that if two

    brands are being compared, then they must be similar. By avoiding any comparison, non

    comparative ads do not invoke this heuristic. Several studies, such as those conducted by

    Pechmann and Ratneshwar (1991), Gorn and Weinberg (1984), Sujan and Dekleva (1987), and

    Grewal et al. (1997), document this unintended associational effect of comparative advertising.

    In the context of a standards war, certain characteristics of the market may further encourage

    such heuristic processing. Association heuristics are more likely to occur when the advertised

    and comparison brands have the same relative market size (Pechmann and Stewart 1991, Grewal

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    18/49

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    19/49

    19

    three types of ad formats were direct comparative, indirect comparative and non comparative.

    There were four broad steps in the experimental procedure:

    Step1. This step was identical to that of Study 1 and primarily involved randomly

    assigning the subjects to any one of the six experimental conditions.

    Step2. The second step was also identical to that of Study 1 and primarily manipulated

    the presence or absence of a standards war.

    Step3. In this step, subjects saw an ad for the Conmec brand on the computer screen.

    Each subject saw an ad that was direct comparative, indirect comparative, or non comparative.

    Each brand was described by three product-based and three non product-based attributes. The

    product-based attributes were clarity of picture, quality of video, and power consumption. The

    non product-based attributes were industry support, availability at retail outlets, and sales. Figure

    2 presents the direct comparative ad along with the ad copy of the other two formats. After

    reviewing the ads, the subjects continued to the third set of screens containing the dependent

    measures.

    Step4. The main dependent measure of interest was the adoption rate (choice tasks).

    However, to track the process explanations underlying the competing predictions outlined in the

    previous section, we also took specific measures of an ad format's potential to (a) reduce

    uncertainty (confidence ratings), (b) generate negative affect (attitude toward ad), and (c) invoke

    association heuristics (similarity ratings). We also recorded subjects' perceptions about the

    performance of the advertised product (performance ratings).

    In this step, subjects were first asked to provide similarity ratings. Specifically, they were

    asked to indicate how similar they thought the advertised brand, Conmec, was to its competitor,

    Dwyer (a) on an overall basis, and (b) with respect to each of the six attributes discussed in the

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    20/49

    20

    ad. Each response was recorded on a 9-point similarity scale with "most different" and "exact

    same" as the endpoint anchors. Subjects were then asked to rate the advertised brands

    performance against the competition on an overall basis as well as on each of the six target

    attributes. These responses were collected on 9-point semantic scales.

    Each subject was then given two choice tasks. For the first choice task, subjects were

    presented with two offers: (a) the advertised brand (Conmec) at a price of $490, and (b) the non

    advertised brand (Dwyer) at a price of $380. Subjects were asked to: (a) choose the advertised

    brand, or (b) choose the non advertised brand, or (c) defer their decision. The second choice task

    was similar to the first task but without the option to defer. For both choice tasks, subjects were

    asked to provide reasons for their choice. We then measured each subjects attitude toward the ad

    and confidence in the advertised brand. The items used for these two measures and their

    psychometric properties are discussed in Appendix 1. Finally we asked subjects to rate the

    importance of each of the six videophone attributes.

    Results

    For the sake of brevity, we discuss only key findings in this section. Our discussion of the

    results will focus on the five measures mentioned earlier: choice shares with the option to defer,

    confidence ratings, attitude towards ad ratings, similarity ratings, and performance ratings. We

    also limit our discussion of the planned contrasts to differences between the (a) direct

    comparative and non comparative formats, and (b) indirect comparative and non comparative

    formats. Comparisons between the direct and indirect comparative conditions can be inferred

    from the results presented in Table 3. For all other detailed statistical results, the reader may

    contact the authors directly.

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    21/49

    21

    Interactions. The standards war manipulation had a significant interaction with the ad

    format manipulation for choice shares (B = 1.77, S.E. = 0.55, Wald-2 (1, N = 95) = 10.09,p 0.10).

    For the performance ratings, there was also a significant interaction between the ad

    format and familiarity manipulations (F(2, 89) = 7.08, p < 0.01). In the condition where the

    advertised brand was relatively unfamiliar (Conmec), the ad format had a significant effect on

    the average performance rating (F(2, 45) = 3.84, p < 0.05). Post-hoc analysis showed that the

    average performance rating for the direct comparative format was significantly higher than that

    of the non comparative format (MDC = 6.25, MNC = 5.20, F(1, 45) = 8.47, p < 0.01). When the

    advertised brand was relatively familiar (Philips), the format had a significant effect (F(2, 44) =

    3.37, p < 0.05). Post-hoc analysis showed that the average performance rating for the direct

    comparative format was significantly lower than those of the non comparative formats (MDC =

    6.06, MNC = 7.06, F(1, 44) = 6.20, p < 0.01). This pattern of results too, did not differ for the

    overall performance measure, nor did it differ by the type of attribute.

    Discussion

    The results of Study 3 support our prediction. Across different measures, the efficacy of

    comparative ad formats was moderated by the relative familiarity of the advertised brand. The

    comparative ad format led to higher adoption rates, more confident adoption decisions, increased

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    31/49

    31

    differentiation, and better performance ratings for the advertised brand when the advertised

    brand was relatively unfamiliar.

    These results are consistent with the explanation that the relative superiority of the

    comparative formats observed in Study 2 is attributable to their uncertainty-reducing role. When

    we used the relatively unfamiliar brand (Conmec) as the advertised brand, there was a high

    degree of uncertainty regarding the advertised brands performance in the standards war. As

    reflected in the confidence measures, this uncertainty was best addressed by the direct

    comparative format. In contrast, when we used the relatively familiar brand (Philips) as the

    advertised brand, the uncertainty regarding the advertised brand was considerably lower.

    Consequently, the relative efficacy of the comparative ad format was significantly diminished.

    Results of an ANCOVA further confirm this uncertainty-reducing role. The ANCOVA shows

    that when confidence ratings are controlled for, ad format is a non significant predictor of

    perceived performance in both (a) Study 2: Performance = a + 1 (Ad Format) + 2 (Confidence);

    1 = 0.03 (p = 0.88), 2 = 0.22 (p = 0.01), and (b) Study 3: Performance = a + 1 (Ad Format) +

    2 (Confidence); 1 = 0.16 (p = 0.58), 2 = 0.27 (p = 0.01).

    GENERAL DISCUSSION

    In this research, we have examined choice situations with a standards war from a

    consumers perspective, giving special attention to the impact of standards competition on a new

    products adoption rate, the value of performance-related product information to consumers, and

    the effectiveness of advertising formats. Building upon past research, we proposed that standards

    competition impacts consumer behavior by affecting a consumers likelihood of adopting a new

    product, varying the value that consumers place on different types of performance-related

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    32/49

    32

    product information, and affecting consumers responses to different advertising formats. Our

    results support these hypotheses. Additionally, our findings may also be generalizable to other

    winner-takes-all scenarios besides standard wars, such as political elections and sports betting.

    However, our findings do not apply to scenarios where consumers can easily acquire both

    competing technologies.

    Summary of Findings and Implications

    Impact of Standards Battles on New Product Adoption. Our results reveal that an ongoing

    standards competition has a negative effect on new product adoption (Study 1). The lower

    adoption rate in the presence of a standards war suggests that new product success in the early

    stages of the product life-cycle, is less likely if competing products are based on different

    technology standards than if they are compatible. Even though compatibility may be desirable, as

    pointed by Gilbert (1992), incompatibility cannot be avoided when: (a) legal barriers such as

    patent protection prevent firms from using proprietary technology; (b) the use of compatible

    technology actually leads to significant increases in the costs of the new product; and (c)

    compatibility does not allow a firm to fully exploit the advantages of its new technology. This

    further underscores the importance of understanding the impact of standards competition on

    consumer behavior and developing marketing communication strategies that are more effective

    in the presence of such competition. This research takes a step toward a better understanding of

    these important but under explored issues and provides managerial insights for firms launching

    new products in markets with competing technological standards. However, two qualifiers about

    our findings deserve mention: (a) these results are particularly relevant for the early stages of a

    products life cycle, and (b) not all standards incompatibilities lead to winner-takes-all

    outcomes.

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    33/49

    33

    Relative vs. Absolute Performance-Related Information. Results from the three studies

    also shed light on the important issue of how consumers respond to information on absolute and

    relative utility of a product. Results of Study 1 show that standards competition varies the impact

    of different types of performance-related information. Specifically, standards competition

    motivates consumers to heed information on relative performance and to ignore information on

    absolute performance. As a result, information regarding the relative (absolute) performance of a

    product has a stronger (weaker) impact on a products share in markets with standards

    competition. This is not an isolated finding; we also find similar evidence in Studies 2 and 3.

    Although absolute and relative performance information was not directly varied in Studies 2 and

    3, the ad format manipulation can be considered an indirect manipulation of information on

    absolute and relative product performance. The relative superiority of the comparative ad over its

    non comparative counterpart underscores the fact that consumers tend to heed information on

    relative performance and to ignore information on absolute performance in the presence of a

    standards war.

    Relative performance is especially crucial in markets with standards competition because

    of the sensitivity of such markets to sudden tipping in which a winner takes all. Our findings in

    Studies 1, 2, and 3 empirically demonstrate that consumers are much more sensitive to relative

    performance in markets with standards competition than in those without, suggesting that firms

    competing in markets with incompatible technologies should emphasize relative product

    performance over absolute product performance in new product design and in go/no-go

    decisions. It is also equally important that firms communicate this relative advantage to

    consumers (Baker and Lutz 1987).

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    34/49

    34

    Effectiveness of Advertising Formats: Comparative vs. Non Comparative. Our

    examination of the effectiveness of advertising formats (Study 2) reveals several important

    findings on how standards competition affects consumer response to different advertising

    formats. First, our results show that standards competition moderates the effectiveness of

    different ad formats: it strengthens the effect of comparative ads but weakens the effect of non

    comparative ads. We attribute this moderating effect to the fact that, in markets with standards

    competition, on viewing comparative ads, consumers: (a) develop greater confidence in the

    advertised brand, (b) are less likely to engage in associative heuristic processing, and (c) tend not

    to have a negative attitude toward the ad. Second, our results demonstrate that the benefit (cost)

    of using a comparative (non comparative) ad format in the presence of standards competition can

    be significant. For example, in Study 2, when non comparative ad formats were used, there was

    no significant difference in choice share between the two brands. However, when a direct

    comparative ad formats was used, the advertised brand had a significant advantage in choice

    share (Table 3). These results show that the use of certain ad formats can stimulate adoption rates

    even in the presence of standards competition (Study 2).

    Third, we find that ad format may affect consumer price sensitivity. Note that the

    advertised brand in Study 2 was priced higher than the comparison brand. The direct

    comparative ad format led to a greater choice share for the higher-priced brand in markets with

    standards competition than in markets without. The results also show that the non comparative

    ad format led to a lower choice share for the higher priced brand in markets with standards

    competition than in markets without (Table 3). These results imply that in the presence of

    standards competition, while the direct comparative format reduces consumer price sensitivity,

    the non comparative format increases consumer price sensitivity. The ad formats affected

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    35/49

    35

    consumer price sensitivity primarily by influencing consumer confidence. This is borne out by

    the data from Study 2, where, when direct comparative (non comparative) ads were used,

    consumers felt more (less) confident about the winner, and were thus less (more) sensitive about

    prices (Urbany et al. 1997).

    Effect of Brand Familiarity on the Effectiveness of Advertising Formats. In markets with

    standards competition, firms sponsoring different standards may differ on the extent to which

    consumers are familiar with the brand name of their products. Our results (Study 3) support the

    hypothesized moderating effect of brand familiarity on the effectiveness of different ad formats

    in the presence of standards competition. We show that comparative ad formats are more

    effective when the advertised brand has a disadvantage than when it has an advantage in terms of

    brand familiarity. In other words, we should see more comparative ads for smaller firms than for

    their larger rivals. This is borne out by some observations in the trade press. An apt example is

    Apples ads for its G4 chip (e.g., Time, January 1999). These ads directly compare the G4 to the

    Pentium chips and claim to be 100% to 200% faster. On the other hand, the ads for the

    Pentium III chip were non comparative in nature (e.g., PC Magazine, 05/25/99). This was also

    the case in many other industries (e.g., Microsoft Windows 2000 vs. Linux Red Hat). Note,

    however, that other factors might encourage larger firms to refrain from comparative advertising

    (e.g., fear of inadvertent awareness building for the comparison brand).

    Directions for Future Research

    Although we have looked at some key factors influencing consumer behavior in the

    presence of standards competition, several important issues remain unexamined. First, while our

    results in the absence of standards competition were consistent with past research, in the

    presence of standards competition, there were no differences in attitude toward the ad across

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    36/49

    36

    different ad formats. To account for this unexpected result, we surmised that the "informational"

    value of comparative ad formats might have shifted the consumers attention away from its

    "executional" aspects. Although past research suggests that this explanation is plausible, future

    research should investigate this effect in a systematic manner. Another important research issue

    concerns the time to adopt or the delay in adopting a standard or a new product. In other words,

    what factors influence the time when a standard or a product category is adopted? This research

    question is best addressed by a longitudinal study. It is also important to investigate other

    scenarios of uncertainty where our findings our extendable (e.g., political elections, sports

    betting). Finally, we need a clearer understanding of consumer risk perceptions and the factors

    that influence consumer expectations about the installed base. For example, besides a standards

    perceived probability of success, do consumers also take into account the potential payoff? Do

    potential payoffs and success probabilities equally influence consumer expectations about the

    installed base? Do negative externalities have an influence similar to that of positive

    externalities? Do perceptions of risk in a standards market vary by consumer expertise? Research

    directed toward these issues will further our understanding of consumer behavior in standards

    markets.

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    37/49

    37

    TABLE 1

    STUDY 1: SHARES BY CHOICE OPTIONS AND CATEGORY ADOPTION RATE

    Without Standards War With Standards War

    Absolute Rating Absolute RatingCount (%) for each

    Choice OptionLow High Low High

    Low

    N = 23Conmec: 9 (39%)

    Dwyer: 3 (13%)

    Defer: 11 (48%)

    N = 22Conmec: 15 (68%)

    Dwyer: 5 (23%)

    Defer: 2 (9%)

    N = 22Conmec: 4 (18%)

    Dwyer: 1 (5%)

    Defer: 17 (77%)

    N = 23Conmec: 5 (22%)

    Dwyer: 1 (4%)

    Defer: 17 (74%)

    Relative

    Rating

    High

    N = 23

    Conmec: 15 (65%)

    Dwyer: 5 (22%)

    Defer: 3 (13%)

    N = 22

    Conmec: 16 (73%)

    Dwyer: 4 (18%)

    Defer: 2 (9%)

    N = 23

    Conmec: 13 (57%)

    Dwyer: 4 (17%)

    Defer: 6 (26%)

    N = 23

    Conmec: 14 (61%)

    Dwyer: 4 (17%)

    Defer: 5 (22%)

    Total

    N = 90Conmec: 55 (61%)

    Dwyer: 17 (19%)

    Defer: 18 (20%)

    N = 91Conmec: 36 (40%)

    Dwyer: 10 (11%)

    Defer: 45 (49%)

    Category Adoption

    Rate (AR)ARwithout std. wars = (55+17)/90 = 80% ARwith std. wars = (36+10)/91 = 51%

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    38/49

    38

    TABLE 2

    STUDY 1: IMPACT OF RELATIVE AND ABSOLUTE PRODUCT PERFORMANCE

    H2a: Impact of Relative Performance On Conmecs Choice Share*

    Without Standards War

    (N = 90)With Standards War

    (N = 91)

    Low Relative Rating High Relative Rating Low Relative Rating High Relative Rating

    N = 45(9+15)/45 = 53%

    N = 45(15+16)/45 = 69%

    N = 45(4+5)/45 = 20%

    N = 46(13+14)/46 = 59%

    H2b: Impact of Absolute Performance On Conmecs Choice Share*

    Without Standards War

    (N = 90)With Standards War

    (N = 91)

    Low Absolute Rating High Absolute Rating Low Absolute Rating High Absolute Rating

    N = 46(9+15)/46 = 52.2%

    N = 44(15+16)/44 = 70.5%

    N = 45(4+13)/45 = 38%

    N = 46(5+14)/46 = 41%

    * Note: The choice shares presented in Table 2 are margin totals calculated directly from data given in Table 1. Forexample, in the presence of a standards war and given a low relative rating, Conmecs share of 20% is calculated bypooling data from the two cells under With Standards War in Table 1: the Low Relative-Low Absolute and LowRelative-High Absolute cells. Specifically, Conmecs choice share given a Low Relative rating is (4+5)/(22+23) =20%. Similarly, other marginal choice shares presented in Table 2 can be calculated directly from Table 1.

    Absolute Ratings

    52

    70

    38

    41

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

    70

    80

    Low High

    %C

    hoosingConmec

    No SW

    SW

    Relative Ratings

    69

    5953

    20

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    60

    70

    80

    Low High

    %C

    hoosingCo

    nmec

    No SW

    SW

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    39/49

    39

    TABLE 3

    STUDY 2 RESULTS: MEANS

    With Standard Wars Without Standard WarsAd Formats Direct

    ComparativeIndirect

    ComparativeNon-

    comparativeDirect

    ComparativeIndirect

    ComparativeNon-

    comparative(N = 16) (N = 16) (N = 16) (N = 16) (N = 15) (N = 16)

    Choice SharesDefer Choice 31% 50% 62% a* 56% 53% 25% a*Advertised Brand 69% 44% 19% a 31% 40% 63% a*

    Confidence Measures 5.33 4.59 3.41 a, b 4.52 4.53 4.70

    Attitude towards Ad 5.98 6.12 6.15 4.78 5.94

    a

    6.86

    a, b

    Similarity Ratings 4.68 5.57 a* 6.85 a, b 5.95 4.38 a* 4.79 a

    Performance Ratings 6.80 6.00 a 4.65 a, b 4.94 6.00 a 6.69 a, b

    a Cell means significantly different from Direct Comparative means at p < 0.05 significanceb Cell means significantly different from Indirect Comparative means at p < 0.05 significancea* Cell means significantly different from Direct Comparative means at p < 0.10 significanceb* Cell means significantly different from Indirect Comparative means at p < 0.10 significance

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    40/49

    40

    TABLE 4

    RESULTS OF STUDY 3: MEANS

    High Prior Uncertainty(Ad Brand = Conmec)

    Low Prior Uncertainty(Ad Brand = Philips)

    Ad Formats DirectComparative

    (N = 16)

    IndirectComparative

    (N = 16)

    Non-Comparative

    (N = 16)

    DirectComparative

    (N = 16)

    IndirectComparative

    (N = 16)

    Non-Comparative

    (N = 15)

    Choice SharesDefer Choice 50% 44% 38% 56% 56% 60%Advertised Brand 44% 31% 6% a, b* 31% 31% 33%

    Confidence Measures 5.83 4.86 a 4.00 a, b* 5.67 5.77 5.95

    Attitude towards Ad 6.07 5.96 5.42 6.42 6.09 5.66

    Similarity Ratings 4.00 5.05 a 5.85 a, b* 5.00 5.05 5.17

    Performance Ratings 6.25 5.79 5.20 a 6.06 6.70 7.06 a

    a Cell means significantly different from Direct Comparative means at p < 0.05 significanceb Cell means significantly different from Indirect Comparative means at p < 0.05 significancea* Cell means significantly different from Direct Comparative means at p < 0.10 significanceb* Cell means significantly different from Indirect Comparative means at p < 0.10 significance

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    41/49

    41

    FIGURE 1

    STUDY 1 MANIPULATION, CHOICE SCENARIOS, AND CHOICE SCENARIO EXAMPLE

    Manipulation:NO STANDARDS WAR CONDITIONS STANDARDS WAR CONDITIONS

    The New Videophone Industry

    Due to recent technological breakthroughs in sending voice and videoover a POTS (plain old telephone system) line, a consumer market forvideo telephones has now emerged. Seeing the people you call maysoon become an everyday reality.

    Currently, in the video telephone industry, there are two main players:Conmec Systems and Dwyer Technologies.

    The Conmec and Dwyer videophones are totally compatible with eachother. Users of the Conmec brand of videophone will be able tocommunicate with the users of Dwyer brand of videophones, and viceversa. Software functions such as message recording and image editingfor Conmec systems will work with messages and images from Dwyersystems.

    Analysts predict a market share battle. As of now there is a lot ofuncertainty about which brand will eventually have a higher marketshare.

    The New Videophone Industry

    Due to a very recent technological breakthrough in sending voice andvideo over a POTS (plain old telephone system) line, a consumermarket for video telephones is now emerging. Seeing the people youcall may soon become an everyday reality.

    Currently, in the video telephone industry, there are two main players:Conmec Systems and Dwyer Technologies.

    The Conmec and Dwyer videophones are totally incompatible witheach other. Users of the Conmec brand of videophone will not be ableto communicate with the users of the Dwyer videophone, and viceversa. Software functions such as message recording and image editingfor Conmec systems will not work with messages and images fromDwyer systems.

    Analysts predict a winner-take-all, VCR-like standards battle. As ofnow there is a lot of uncertainty about which brand will eventuallyemerge as the winner.

    Choice Scenarios:

    Choice Scenario Example:

    Instruction: We would now like you to make a product choice. Below we will provide you information on two videophone brands. To help youwith your decision, we will also provide you with some information from Consumer Reports regarding these two brands.

    Q: Provided below is the Overall Rating of two videophones, reproduced from the Consumer Reports table published in a recent issue of JEC(Journal of Electronics & Communication). The Overall Rating considers all possible aspects related to the product experience, ranging fromactual physical performance of the machine to more indirect, market related factors. Based on the 11-point star-scale the brands were rated asfollows:

    1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11| | | | | | | | | | |

    Dwyer Conmec($80) ($120)

    Thus, Conmec ($120) got an 8-star rating , while Dwyer ($80) got a 7-star rating.

    Now based on this information and all that you have read about the videophone industry till now, which of the following choice options givenbelow, would you prefer? Please click on the appropriate button.

    1. Choose Conmec, OR2. Choose Dwyer, OR3. Defer Choice for a later occasion.

    Standards War Absent Standards War PresentLow Absolute Rating High Absolute Rating Low Absolute Rating High Absolute Rating

    Low Relative Rating Dwyer = 7, Conmec = 8 Dwyer = 9, Conmec = 10 Dwyer = 7, Conmec = 8 Dwyer = 9, Conmec = 10

    High Relative Rating Dwyer = 5, Conmec = 8 Dwyer = 7, Conmec = 10 Dwyer = 5, Conmec = 8 Dwyer = 7, Conmec = 10

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    42/49

    42

    FIGURE 2

    STUDY 2 AD STIMULUS: DIRECT, INDIRECT, AND NON COMPARATIVE FORMATS

    Ad Copy* for the Indirect Comparative Format Ad Copy* for the Non Comparative FormatCrystal Clear

    With 500 lines of horizontal resolution (HR), Conmec offers youpictures that are twice as clear as any other videophone.

    Real Time Video

    A communication speed of 56 kilobytes per second (Kbps), or40-45 frames per second (fps), that is far superior to all other

    brands, gives you a smooth, no-jerk, video signal. Just like onTV.

    Electricity Bills

    And all this, without any monster electricity bills. Conmecconsumes half as much power as any other brand does.

    Great Support More videophone manufacturers, software developers, &

    technicians to look after your every need, than any othercompetitor.

    Available Everywhere

    YourConmec Videophone is now available at more stores andshops than any other videophone.

    Preferred

    Already we have sold a 100,000 units, much more than any othercompetitor.

    Crystal Clear

    With 500 lines of horizontal resolution (HR), Conmec offers youpictures that are crystal clear.

    Real Time Video

    A communication speed of 56 kilobytes per second (Kbps), or40-45 frames per second (fps), gives you a smooth, no-jerk,video signal. Just like on TV.

    Electricity Bills

    And all this, without any monster electricity bills. Conmecconsumes very little power.

    Great Support Videophone manufacturers, software developers, & technicians

    to look after your every need.

    Available Everywhere

    YourConmec Videophone is now available at a lot of stores andshops.

    Preferred

    Already we have sold a 100,000 units.

    * NB: Barring the copy differences, the ad (picture/layout) was identical to the direct comparative ad shown above.

    The new CONMEC Videophone !

    Heres whats really different

    about the Conmec Videophone:

    Crystal Clear

    With 500 lines of horizontal

    resolution (HR), Conmec offers you

    pictures that are twice as clear as

    the Dwyer videophone.

    Real Time Video

    A communication speed of 56 kilo

    bytes per second (Kbps), or 40-45

    frames per second (fps), that is far

    superior to Dwyer, gives you a

    smooth, no-jerk, video signal. Just

    like on TV.

    Electricity Bills

    And all this, without any monster

    electricity bills. Conmec consumes

    half as much power as Dwyer does.

    Great Support

    More videophone manufacturers,

    software developers, & technicians

    to look after your every need, than

    competitors like Dwyer.

    Available Everywhere

    Your Conmec Videophone is now

    available at more stores and shops

    than the Dwyer videophone.

    Preferred

    Already we have sold a 100,000

    units, much more than competitors

    like Dwyer.

    ChooseCONMEC: TheBestWayToKeepinTouch !

    Direct Com arative Format

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    43/49

    43

    APPENDIX 1

    ITEMS USED FOR ATTITUDE TOWARDS AD AND CONFIDENCE MEASURES IN

    STUDIES 2 & 3

    Attitude Towards Ad:

    Instruction: We are now interested in knowing how youfeltabout the ad which you saw earlier.Please mark your response by circling at an appropriate place on the scale provided below. Didyou find the ad:

    Not Convincing 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 ConvincingOffensive 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Not Offensive

    Bad 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Good Not Interesting 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Interesting

    Irritating 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Non Irritating Not Informative 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Informative

    Cronbach Alpha = 0.83 (Study 2); 0.80 (Study 3)

    Confidence Measures:

    Q: To what extent do you agree ordisagree with the following statements:

    The ad made me feel that there is something special about Conmec that is different from otherbrands.

    Totally Disagree 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Totally Agree

    I would have more confidence in using Conmec now, than before I saw this advertisement.

    Totally Disagree 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Totally Agree

    Given the uncertainty in the videophone market, this ad helps me in making up my mind aboutwhich brand to go with.

    Totally Disagree 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Totally Agree

    Given the uncertainty in the videophone market, this ad makes me feel confident that Conmec islikely to emerge as the winner.

    Totally Disagree 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 Totally Agree

    Cronbach Alpha = 0.89 (Study 2); 0.89 (Study 3)

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    44/49

    44

    REFERENCES

    Baker, William E. and Richard J. Lutz (1987), "The Relevance-Accessibility Model of

    Advertising Effectiveness," inNonverbal Communication in Advertising, S. Hecker and

    D. W. Stewart, eds. Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, 59-84.

    Barron, Reuben M. and David A. Kenny (1986), The Moderator-Mediator Variable Distinction

    in Social Psychological Research: Conceptual, Strategic, and Statistical Considerations,

    Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 51(6), December, 1173-1182.

    Batra, Rajeev and Michael L. Ray (1986), "Affective Responses Mediating Acceptance of

    Advertising,"Journal of Consumer Research, 13 (September), 234-249.

    _____ and Morris B. Holbrook (1987), "Assessing the Role of Emotions as Mediators of

    Consumer Responses to Advertising,"Journal of Consumer Research, 14 (December),

    404-420.

    Brown, Steven P., Pamela M. Homer, and J. Jeffrey Inman (1998), "A Meta-Analysis of

    Relationships Between Ad-Evoked Feelings and Advertising Responses,"Journal of

    Marketing Research, 35 (February), 114-126.

    Brynjolfsson, Erik and Chris K. Kemerer (1996), "Network Externalities in Microcomputer

    Software: An Econometric Analysis of the Spreadsheet Market," Management Science,

    42 (December), 1627-1647.

    Burnham, Thomas A., Judy K. Frels, and Vijay Mahajan (2003), Consumer Switching Costs: A

    Typology, Antecedents, and Consequences,Journal of the Academy of Marketing

    Science, 31 (Spring), 109-126.

    Chaiken, Shelly (1987), The Heuristic Model of Persuasion, in Social Influence: The Ontario

    Symposium, vol.5, ed. M.P. Zanna et al., Hillsdale, NJ: Erlbaum, 3-39.

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    45/49

    45

    Chen, Yuxin and Jinhong Xie (2003), Cross-market Network Effect with Asymmetric Customer

    Loyalty: Implications on Competitive Advantage, Working Paper, University of Florida.

    Chou, Chien-fu and Oz Shy (1992), "Network Effects, Software Provision, and Standardization,"

    The Journal of Industrial Economics, 40 (March), 85-103.

    Chun, Miran (1999), Analysis: Lessons for MP3 from the Death of Divx,

    http://www.zdnet.co.uk, June 22.

    Dhar, Ravi (1997), "Consumer Preference for a No-Choice Option,"Journal of Consumer

    Research, 24 (September), 215-231.

    Dhebar, Anirudh and Shumel Oren (1985), "Optimal Dynamic Pricing for Expanding Networks,"

    Marketing Science, 4 (Fall), 326-351.

    Eagly, Alice and Shelley Chaiken (1993), The Psychology of Attitudes, Harcourt Brace

    Jovanovich, 327-333.

    Farrell, Joseph and Garth Saloner (1986), "Installed Base and Compatibility: Innovation, Product

    Preannouncements, and Predation,"American Economic Review, 76 (December), 940-55.

    Friestad, Marian and Peter Wright (1994), "The Persuasion Knowledge Model: How People

    Cope With Persuasion Attempts,"Journal of Consumer Research, 21 (June), 1-31.

    Gandal, Neil (1995), "Competing Compatibility Standards and Network Externalities in the PC

    Software Market," The Review of Economics and Statistics, 77 (November), 599-6008.

    Gilbert, Richard J. (1992), "Symposium on Compatibility: Incentives and Market Structure,"

    Journal of Industrial Economics, 40 (March), 1-8.

    Goldberg, Marvin E., and Gerald J. Gorn (1987), "Happy and Sad TV Programs: How They

    Affect Reactions to Commercials,"Journal of Consumer Research,14(December),387-

    03.

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    46/49

    46

    Gorn, Gerald J. and Charles B. Weinberg (1984), The Impact of Comparative Advertising,

    Journal of Consumer Research, 11 (September), 719-727.

    Grewal, Dhruv, Sukumar Kavanoor, Edward F. Fern, Carolyn Costley, and James Barnes (1997),

    Comparative Versus Non-comparative Advertising: A Meta Analysis,Journal of

    Marketing, 61 (October), 1-15.

    Gupta, Sachin, Deepak Jain and Mohanbir S. Sawhney (1999), "Modeling the Evolution of

    Markets with Indirect Network Externalities: An Application to Digital Television,"

    Marketing Science, 18 (Summer), 396-416.

    Inman, J. Jeffrey, James S. Dyer and Jianmin Jia (1997), "A Generalized Utility Model of

    Disappointment and Regret Effects on Post-Choice Valuation," Marketing Science, 16

    (2), 97-111.

    Janiszewski, Christopher and Stijn Van Osselaer (2000), "A Connectionist Model of Brand-

    Quality Associations,"Journal of Marketing Research, 37 (August), 331-350.

    Katz, Michael and Carl Shapiro (1985), " Network Externalities, Competition, and

    Compatibility,American Economic Review, 75 (June), 424-440.

    _____ and _____ (1994), "Systems Competition and Network Effects,"Journal of Economic

    Perspectives, 8 (Spring), 93-115.

    Klopfenstein, Bruce (1989), "Forecasting Consumer Adoption of Information Technology and

    Services: Lessons from Home Video Forecasting," in The VCR Age: Home Video and

    Mass Communication, Ed. Mark R. Levy, Sage Publications.

    Lipshitz, Raanan and Orna Strauss (1997), Coping With Uncertainty: A Naturalistic Decision-

    Making Analysis, Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 69

    (February), 149-163.

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    47/49

    47

    Loomes, Graham and Robert Sugden (1982), Regret Theory: An Alternative Theory of Rational

    Choice Under Uncertainty, The Economic Journal, 92 (December), 805-24.

    MacKenzie, Scott B., and Richard J. Lutz (1989), An Empirical Examination of the Structural

    Antecedents of Attitude Toward the Ad in an Advertising Pretesting Context,Journal of

    Marketing, 53 (April), 48-65.

    Markman, A. B., and C. P. Moreau (2001), "Analogy and Analogical Comparison in Choice," in

    The Analogical Mind: Perspectives from Cognitive Science, Dedre Gentner, Keith J.

    Holyoak, and Boicho N. Kokinov Eds., The MIT Press, 363-399.

    Mas-Colell, Andreu, Michael D. Whinston and Jerry R. Green (1995), Microeconomic Theory,

    Oxford University Press: New York, 46-49.

    Miles, S. (2000), Standards battle brewing over expansion devices, CNET News.com, July 5.

    Nair, Harikesh, Pradeep Chintagunta and Jean-Pierre Dub (2004), Empirical Analysis of

    Indirect Network Effects in the Market for Personal Digital Assistants, Quantitative

    Marketing and Economics, forthcoming.

    Ofek, Elie, and Miklos Sarvary (2001), "Leveraging the Customer Base: Creating Competitive

    Advantage Through Knowledge Management," Management Science, 47 (November),

    1441-1456.

    Padmanabhan, V., Surendra Rajiv and Kannan Srinivasan (1997), " New Products, Upgrades,

    and New Releases: A Rationale for Sequential Product Introduction,"Journal of

    Marketing Research, 34 (November), 456-472.

    Pechmann, Cornelia and David W. Stewart (1990), "The Effect of Comparative Advertising on

    Attention, Memory and Purchase Intentions,"Journal of Consumer Research, 17

    (September), 180-191.

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    48/49

    48

    _____ and _____ (1991), "How Direct Comparative Ads and Market Share Affect Brand

    Choice,"Journal of Advertising Research, 31 (December), 47-55.

    _____ and S. Ratneshwar (1991), The Use of Comparative Advertising for Brand Positioning:

    Association versus Differentiation,Journal of Consumer Research, 18 (September),

    145-60.

    Petty, Richard E., and John T. Cacioppo (1981),Attitudes and Persuasion: Classic and

    Contemporary Approaches. Dubuque, IA: A. C. Brown.

    Richtel, Matt (2001), With Napster Down, Its Audience Fans Out., New York Times, July 20.

    Sage, Andrew P., and Elbert B. White (1983), Decision and Information Structures in Regret

    Models of Judgement and Choice,IEEE Transactions on Systems, Man, and

    Cybernetics, SMC-13 (March), 136-45.

    Shafir, Eldar, and Amos Tversky (1992), Thinking Through Uncertainty: Non Consequential

    Reasoning and Choice, Cognitive Psychology, 24 (October), 449-74.

    Shankar, Venkatesh, and Barry L. Bayus (1999), "Network Effects and Competition," Working

    Paper, University of North Carolina.

    Shapiro, Carl and Hal R. Varian (1998), The Art of Standard Wars, California Management

    Review, 4 (Winter), 8-32.

    Srinivasan, Raji, Gary L. Lilien, and Arvind Rangaswamy, (2004), First in, First out? The

    Effects of Network Externalities on Pioneer Survival,Journal of Marketing, 68

    (January), 41-58.

    Stewart, David W. and David H. Furse (2000), "Analysis of the Impact of Executional Factors on

    Advertising Performance,"Journal of Advertising Research, 40 (November), 85-88.

  • 8/3/2019 SSRN-id714761

    49/49

    49

    Sun, Baohong, Jinhong Xie, and Henry. Cao (2004), Product Strategy for Innovators in Markets

    with Network Effects, Marketing Science, Vol. 20 (Summer).

    Sujan, Mita and Christine Dekleva (1987), Product Categorization and Inference Making: Some

    Implications for Comparative Advertising,Journal of Consumer Research, 14

    (December), 372-378.

    The Economist(1993), Special Survey, The Computer Industry, Vol. 326. No. 7800. Feb. 27.

    Tversky, Amos and Eldar Shafir (1992), "Choice Under Conflict: The Dynamics of Deferred

    Decision,"Psychological Science, 3 (November), 358-361.

    Urbany, Joel E., William O. Bearden, Ajit Kaicker and Melinda Smith-de Borrero (1997),

    "Transaction Utility Effects When Quality is Uncertain,Journal of the Academy of

    Marketing Science, 25 (Winter), 45-55.

    Van den Bulte, Christophe (2000), New Product Diffusion Acceleration: Measurement and

    Analysis, Marketing Science, 19 (Fall), 366-380.

    Wexler, Joanie (2000), LAN standards do battle, Network World Wireless in the Enterprise

    Newsletter, Sep. 13, www.nufusioin.com.

    Wong, Wylie (2000) Competing efforts may threaten home-networking standard, CNET

    News.com, April 14.

    Xie, Jinhong and Marvin Sirbu (1995), "Price Competition and Compatibility in the Presence of

    Positive Demand Externalities," Management Science, 41 (May), 909-926.


Recommended