+ All Categories
Home > Documents > Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

Date post: 14-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: andrei-kamarouski
View: 222 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
24
Annu. Rev. Sociol. 2003. 29:283-306 doi: 10.1146/annurev.soc.29.010202.100105 Copyright © 2003 by Annual Reviews. All rights reserved First published online as a Review in Advance on June 4,2003 THE CHANGING PICTURE OF MAX WEBER S SOCIOLOGY Richard Swedberg Department of Soc iol ogy, Corn ell Un iversity, I thaca, New York 14853-7601; email:   [email protected]  Key Words rational choice, interests, economic sociology, sociological theory Abstract Over the years the secondary literature on Max Webers sociology has grown enormously, and it is time to raise the following question: Is the picture of his sociology the same today as it was yesterday? In this review I argue that the traditional picture of Webers sociology has begun to change and that one important factor in this change has to do with the perception of the role that the theme of the economy plays in Webers life and work. Special attention has recently been paid to Webers relationship to economics, his economic sociology, and the fact that Weber came from a background of wealthy merchants that he strongly identified with. Several new topics in Webers sociology are explored that are related to the changing picture of his work. Special attention is also paid to interpretations of Weber that draw on rational choice sociology and an interest-based type of analysis. INTRODUCTION For several decades the general picture of Max Weber in sociology, and especially in American sociology, has roughly been as follows: Webers main contribution to the social sciences is to be found in his sociology, which is comparative in nature and based on an immense richness of historical material. Two of his most important concepts are domination and legitimation, and he especially made contributions to sociology through his studies of religion and politics. From a theoretical viewpoint, Weber assigned special importance to the way that the actor understands his or her actions ( verstehen ), and these actions can be grouped into his four types of social action (instrumentally rational, value- rational, affectual, and traditional). Weber had a good eye for  Real polit ik and can be described as a liberal in despair. The world, as he saw it, was increasingly being rationalized and bureaucratized; it was turning into an iron cage. This picture of Weber and his work is heavily influenced by literature such as the following: Parsonss The Structure of Social Action  (1937), Gerth & Millss Fro m Max Weber (1946), and Be ndixs  Max Webe r: An Inte llec tual Portr ait (1960). That it is  pos sible to giv e a mor e ref ined and deta iled ver sio n of the rec epti on of Web er in American sociology is clear from the existing literature and can be exemplified, 0360-0572/03/0811-0283$14.00 28 3 This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM All use subject t o JSTOR Terms and Conditions 
Transcript
Page 1: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 1/24

Annu. Rev. Sociol. 2003. 29:283-306 doi:

10.1146/annurev.soc.29.010202.100105 Copyright © 2003 by Annual

Reviews. All rights reserved First published online as a Review in

Advance on June 4,2003

THE CHANGING PICTURE OF MAX WEBER ‟S SOCIOLOGY 

Richard SwedbergDepartment of Sociol ogy, Cornell Un iversity, I thaca, New York 14853-7601; 

email:  [email protected]  

Key Words rational choice, interests, economic sociology, sociological theory

■ Abstract Over the years the secondary literature on Max Weber‟s sociology has grown

enormously, and it is time to raise the following question: Is the picture of his sociology

the same today as it was yesterday? In this review I argue that the traditional picture of 

Weber‟s sociology has begun to change and that one important factor in this change has to

do with the perception of the role that the theme of the economy plays in Weber‟s life and

work. Special attention has recently been paid to Weber‟s rela tionship to economics, his

economic sociology, and the fact that Weber came from a background of wealthy

merchants that he strongly identified with. Several new topics in Weber‟s sociology are

explored that are related to the changing picture of his work. Special attention is also paid

to interpretations of Weber that draw on rational choice sociology and an interest-based

type of analysis.

INTRODUCTION

For several decades the general picture of Max Weber in sociology, and especially in

American sociology, has roughly been as follows: Weber‟s main contribution to the social

sciences is to be found in his sociology, which is comparative in nature and based on an

immense richness of historical material. Two of his most important concepts are

domination and legitimation, and he especially made contributions to sociology through

his studies of religion and politics. From a theoretical viewpoint, Weber assigned special

importance to the way that the actor understands his or her actions (verstehen), and these

actions can be grouped into his four types of social action (instrumentally rational, value-

rational, affectual, and traditional). Weber had a good eye for  Realpolitik and can be

described as a liberal in despair. The world, as he saw it, was increasingly being

rationalized and bureaucratized; it was turning into an iron cage.

This picture of Weber and his work is heavily influenced by literature such as the

following: Parsons‟s The Structure of Social Action (1937), Gerth & Mills‟s From Max

Weber  (1946), and Bendix‟s  Max Weber: An Intellectual Portrait  (1960). That it is

 possible to give a more refined and detailed version of the reception of Weber in

American sociology is clear from the existing literature and can be exemplified,

0360-0572/03/0811-0283$14.00 283 

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 2: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 2/24

284 SWEDBERG

first of all, by the important work by Roth (1977a,b; Roth 1996; Oakes 1997) but also by

other scholars (e.g., Cohen et al. 1975; Eliaeson 1982,2002; Hinkle 1986; Baehr& Wells2002).

In what amounts to Roth‟s (1977a,b) most detailed attempt in this regard, he argues

that it is possible to distinguish between three different stages in the reception of Weber in

the United States. During the first of these periods (1930 to the late 1950s) Parsons‟s

interpretation and translation of The Protestant Ethic were dominant (Weber [1904/1905]

1930). Bendix‟s (1960) important study of Weber‟s comparative historical sociology was

added to the secondary literature during the next period (the late 1950s to the mid-1960s).

During the third period (the mid- 1960s to the early 1970s) a stream of new works

appeared —“so large that the individual reader no longer can keep track of it” (Roth

1977a, p. xx). Nonetheless, important studies of Weber‟s work on bureaucracy and

methodology, as well as on his political opinions, were produced during these years.

Many of the individual contributions to what may be called the traditional picture of Max Weber are still valid. Weber, for example, did produce an outstanding comparative

historical sociology in which such concepts as domination and legitimation play a key

role. The verstehen approach and the typology of social action are central to Weber‟s

theoretical sociology, and so on. The overall Gestalt of the picture of Weber‟s contribution

to sociology has, however, begun to change, and the reason for this is that a number of 

new facts and interpretations have been presented during the past ten or so years. A

special mention must also be made of the more than dozen volumes of Weber‟s collected

works that have started to become available since the mid-1980s, through the giant efforts

of Mommsen, Schluchter, Ay, and many other excellent scholars (see, e.g., Poggi 1986,

Roth 1996).

From all of this new material we have learned, for example, that Weber participated in

an important fashion in the debate about the stock exchange in the 1890s in Germany. Hisvarious writings and interventions in this debate have recently been published in two

volumes of more than 1100 pages (Weber 1999a; for comments, see Borchardt 2002,

Borchardt & Meyer-Stoll 1999, Hennis 2000, Roth 2002; for recent translations of 

Weber‟s pamphlets on the stock exchange, see Weber [1894] 

2000,  [1896] 2000; for comments on these translations, see Lestition 2000). During the

1890s Weber was also an advocate of a broad concept of economics — what he called

Sozialbkonomik  — which included not only conventional economics but also economic

history and economic sociology (Swedberg 1998; but see Nau 1997). It has been noted

that when Weber presented himself officially, throughout his life, it was as an economist

and not as a sociologist (e.g., Dahrendorf 1987, p. 574). The accuracy of Marianne

Weber‟s portrayal of her husband as a fervent nationalist has been challenged, and her 

general description of Weber‟s family background has been complemented and revised onseveral points (e.g., Roth 2001, Palonen 2001; but see Marianne Weber [1926] 1975). It

has also been suggested that instead of constantly em phasizing Weber‟s views on

rationality and the iron cage, it would be interesting to look at his analysis of different

types of capitalism and his defense of capitalism against its various critics.

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 3: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 3/24

THE CHANGING PICTURE OF WEBER‟S SOCIOLOGY 285 

The most radical challenge to the traditional picture of Weber, however, has come

from the advocates of rational choice sociology (e.g., Kiser & Hechter 1998; E. Kiser,unpublished paper; Elster 2000; Norkus 2000, 2001, 2002; but see S. Turner, unpublished

manuscript). These advocates argue that Weber‟s work has more in common with the

analytical camp of neoclassical economics than with the nontheoretical camp of 

mainstream sociology and that his ideas on rationality, methodological individualism, and

the importance of models in historical research have all been misunderstood or neglected.

Weber can be seen as an advocate of rational choice sociology or as one of its

 predecessors. In any case, Weber‟s work is of much interest to rational choice sociology. 

Where does this leave us today? The answer to this question is not immediately clear.

On the one hand the challenge to the traditional picture of Weber is real enough: There

are a number of facts about Weber, as well as texts by his hand and interpretations of his

work, that simply do not fit the picture of Parsons (1937), Bendix (1960), and others. The

old vision, it would seem, cannot hold. On the other hand it is not clear what the new picture of Weber is. There are bits and pieces that point to something new, but exactly

what the new picture will look like is by no means obvious.

In the following pages I try to bring some clarity to this situation, and I proceed as

follows. First of all, I present some of the most important texts, facts, and interpretations

that diverge from the traditional picture of Weber. The two themes I have chosen to focus

on are (a) new information about Weber‟s life and (b) the role that analytical models from

economics play in Weber‟s sociology. Others could have been selected— what Weber has

to say on gender, emotions, and evolution, for example —  but these latter show more of a

continuity with the traditional picture (e.g., Bologh 1990, Barbalet 2000, Runciman

2001). I then try to add to the changing picture of Weber‟s sociology through a discussion

of some new aspects of Weber‟s work in theoretical sociology and economic sociology.

NEW INFORMATION ON WEBER‟S LIFE 

A student of Weber‟s work in the mid-1970s may well have thought that the information

that was available at that point in time on Weber‟s life was quite sufficient. There was,

first of all, the detailed portrait of Weber in his wife‟s biography (Marianne Weber [1926]

1975; for a recent evaluation of this work, see Roth 1988). There was also a fine little

volume with letters that Weber had written as a young man, and various portraits and

reminiscences by contemporaries (Weber 1936; e.g., Jaspers [1920-1962] 1989,

Honigsheim [1946-1963] 2000, Baumgarten 1964). For Weber‟s political opinions, the

reader could consult Mommsen‟s huge study as well as the debate it inspired (Mommsen

[1959] 1984, Stammer 1971). Many other items existed as well (for a bibliography of 

items in German, see Seyfarth & Schmidt 1977, and for ones in English, see Kivisto &

Swatos 1988, Sica 2003).

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 4: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 4/24

Page 5: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 5/24

THE CHANGING PICTURE OF WEBER‟S SOCIOLOGY 287 

Roth notes that the Weber family was not only well connected in economic circles

 but also in political circles. How the economic and political links mixed with one another in the Weber network can be illustrated with the following quote from Roth‟s work:  

Max jun. [that is, Max Weber] realized early that his Heidelberg grandmother, Frau

Geheime Finanzrat (Privy Councilor) Emilie Souchay Fallenstein was the daughter 

of the Anglo-German business founder Carl Cornelius Souchay; the sister of the

Frankfurt senator and mayor Eduard Souchay and of the two English „patrician

merchants‟ ( Handelsherren) Charles and John Souchay in Manchester; the sister-in-

law of Friedrich Wilhelm Benecke, head of Benecke, Souchay & Co. in London; and

the mother-in-law of the Baden prime minister Julius Jolly, the political writer and

historian Adolph Hausrath, the Alsatian geologist Ernst Wilhelm Benecke, the

leading Antwerp businessman Karl Gustav Bunge, as well as of his own father, the

Berlin city councilor in charge of public construction and member of the Reichstag

and Prussian diet. (Roth 2002, p. 511)

Roth argues that Weber‟s family background influenced his career as well as his

thinking in various ways. In his youth, for example, Weber tried for several years to go

into business “to learn the practise of the import/export trade” (Weber 1936, p. 326, as

cited in Roth 2002, p. 511). In his academic studies Weber decided to specialize in

commercial law, which he also taught for some time in Berlin. When he left this position

it was to accept a chair in economics at the University of Freiburg. Weber then continued

to teach economics until his nervous breakdown at the end of the 1890s. Roth also

emphasizes that the portrait of Weber as a fervent nationalist and imperialist needs to be

revised in the light of Weber‟s cosmopolitan leanings. During World War I, for example,

Weber argued strongly against the anticapitalist propaganda of the right-wing nationalists,

and he was always an advocate of free trade in the international arena.

Weber emerges as strongly procapitalist in Roth‟s account. From early on in his

academic career Weber criticized the economic policy of the agrarian interests and backed

the alternative vision of Germany as a modem industrial nation, on a sound capitalist

foundation. He fought hard against the Junkers‟ attempt to stop the German stock 

exchanges from trading in grain and thereby protecting their economic interests.

Germany‟s problem, he noted, was not that it had too much capitalism, as the right wing

and the intellectuals charged, but that there wasn‟t enough. “Let us stop the railing against

capital and bourgeoisie! We don‟t have too much but too little capital and too few big

entrepreneurs!” (Weber 1984, p. 668, as cited in Roth 2002, p. 517). Weber was

especially irritated at the German intellectuals, whose critique of capitalism he felt was

immature and childish (“the stupid outcries of the literati against capitalism”) (Weber 

1984, p. 212). During World War I Weber warned against nationalizations after the war 

and against creating a strong welfare state. These type of measures, he argued, would sap

the strength of capitalism.

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 6: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 6/24

288 SWEDBERG

THE ROLE OF MODELS FROM ECONOMICS

IN WEBER‟S SOCIOLOGY 

There is one argument especially that distinguishes the current discussion of Weber‟s

sociology from the one that was dominant before the mid-1970s. This is the argument that

an important strength in Weber‟s sociology comes from the fact that he borrowed several

key ingredients from the economists‟ model of analysis. Most sociologists know of this

argument only in the form of rational choice sociology, which they tend to be critical of 

(see, e.g., Kalberg 1994 and Schluchter 2000 for critiques of the attempt to interpret

Weber‟s sociology in terms of rational choice). As I try to show, however, the discussion

of the role of economic models in Weber‟s sociology encompasses at least two different

conceptions of what these models are like in the first place. There also exists different

opinions among rational choice sociologists about the usefulness of various parts of 

Weber‟s work. Some find the core of Weber‟s sociology helpful, whereas others only find bits and pieces of interest (for the former, see, e.g., Kiser & Hechter 1998; for the latter,

see, e.g., Coleman 1990, Goldthorpe 1998).

The first sociologist to argue that Weber‟s sociology had gained considerably in

sharpness and originality by borrowing models from economics is Bourdieu. The hostility

of Bourdieu to neoclassical economics is well known, so it hardly needs to be mentioned

that the models that Weber had borrowed from economics, according to Bourdieu, were

not neoclassical (homo economicus, rational choice, and so on). Bourdieu based his

argument on this point primarily on a reading of Weber‟s sociology of  religion (Bourdieu

[1971] 1987). The two notions in Weber‟s work that Bourdieu highlights are interests and

competition — in this specific case, religious interests, and competition for religious

legitimacy and for lay followers. In a later work Bourdieu sums up his argument about

Weber‟s use of economic models in the following way: Economics is one of the major reference points for sociology. First and foremost

economics is already a part of sociology, largely due to the work of Max Weber,

who transferred numerous models of thought [schèmes de pensée]  borrowed from

economics into the area of religion among others. (Bourdieu [1987] 1990, p. 46; see

also 1987, p. 61)

The approach to Weber that can be found among the advocates of rational choice

sociology differs from that of Bourdieu, even if it is more in degree than in kind, as I try to

show in this review. Two of the earliest attempts to approach Weber‟s work from a  

rational choice perspective can be found in the writings of Coleman and Elster. Coleman

was sympathetic to Weber‟s version of methodological individualism and used the key

argument in The Protestant Ethic to illustrate his famous micro-to-macro model, which

was to become something of a symbol for rational choice sociology (see also the debate

about Coleman‟s interpretation of  The Protestant Ethic in Hemes 1989a,b, Coleman

1989). A few other aspects of Weber‟s work are also discussed in Foundations of Social 

Theory (e.g., Coleman 1990, pp. 422-25,612-13).

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 7: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 7/24

THE CHANGING PICTURE OF WEBER‟S SOCIOLOGY 289 

Elster , in contrast, argues that although Weber‟s work on rational action deserves an

honorable place in the history of rational choice, it falls short in comparison with theconcept of rational action that has been developed in game theory. Although Weber 

correctly understood that the social actor makes a rational choice among existing

alternatives (“ parametric rationality” in Elster‟s terminology), he did not realize that the

choice of the actor also depends on what other actors do [“strategic rationality” (see, e.g.,

Elster 1979, p. 68)]. More recently, Elster has argued that Weber‟s attempt to introduce

emotions into his analysis of action and rationality is “stunning” (Elster 2000, p. 39; for 

the traditional interpretation of Weber‟s concept of rationality, see the literature cited in

Schroeder 1992, pp. 34-42, Scaff 2000, pp. 49-51).

Today there also exist many other attempts to draw on Weber for rational choice

sociology and see how well Weber fits the paradigm of rational choice sociology. For 

example, several attempts have been made to develop a broad concept of rationality by

explicitly drawing on or referring to Weber. In a programmatic text by Nee, we read, for example, that “he [Weber] pioneered the context-bound rationality approach in

sociology” (Nee 1998, p. 6, see also Hechter & Kanazawa 1997, p. 194). Another 

example is Boudon (1996,1997,2001), who draws strongly on Weber in his attempt to

develop a “cognitivist model” in sociology. Boudon‟s argument is that Weber‟s concept

of value rationality can help us to better understand how beliefs can be integrated into a

rational choice type of analysis. More precisely, Weber‟s concept of  Wertrationalitat  

(translated by Boudon as “axiolog- ical rationality”) can be of assistance in showing how

one can analyze situations where the actor does not base his or her decision on some kind

of cost- benefit calculation but on an argument of the following type: “I do this because it

is good, fair, legitimate, and so on.” Finally, a scholar who has carefully gone through the

whole debate about Weber and rational choice concludes that Weber‟s work can best be

described as “an anticipation of RCA [that is, Rational Choice Analysis]” (Norkus 2000, p. 268; see also Norkus 2001, 2002; Voss 2000).

Two new expressions that sometimes appear in discussions of Weber and rational

choice are “analytical Weberianism” and “neoclassical sociology.” The former was

launched in a heated debate about the use of rational choice models in comparative

historical sociology in The American Journal of Sociology in 1998 (for the various texts,

see Gould 2002). According to Kiser & Hechter, who initiated this debate, it is important

to develop an analytical Weberianism, just as there already exists an “analytical

Marxism.” The rationale for this is that “the core of Weber‟s approach to historical

analysis corresponds to emerging developments in sociological versions of rational choice

theory” (Kiser & Hechter 1998, p. 798). 

A concrete example of what analytical Weberianism may look like can be found in a

few recent articles by Kiser on bureaucracy. In a creative manner, Kiser recasts Weber‟sanalysis of bureaucracy and legitimation in terms of agency theory (e.g., Kiser &

Schneider 1994, Kiser 1999, Kiser & Baer 2001). The principal, Kiser and his coauthor 

argue, wants the agent to carry out some task, and the extent to which the agent conceives

of this task as legitimate is of great importance. The authors conclude that “future work 

[in analytical Weberianism] should address other key

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 8: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 8/24

290 SWEDBERG

substantive themes in Weber‟s work, such as types of legitimacy, forms of religion, and

the relationship between religion and politics or economics” (Kiser & Baer  2001,  pp. 27-28).

Also the expression neoclassical sociology is embroiled in discussion and refers to

Weber‟s work on an important point. In a recent issue of  The American Journal o

Sociology Burawoy (2001, p. 1100) accuses several well-known analysts of Eastern

Europe of sacrificing their earlier critical stance for a watered down and sociological

version of neoclassical economics. “The use of „neoclassical‟ to describe the new research

 program [of these authors],” Burawoy charges, “suggests parallels with neoclassical

economics, and indeed parallels there are.” Szel6nyi, Stark and some other  sociologists

are then severely criticized along these lines.

Burawoy, however, seems to have been tricked by the similarity between the terms

neoclassical economics and neoclassical sociology because these two approaches have

next to nothing in common. According to Szel6nyi, who often uses the term neoclassicalsociology, this expression basically means that a reinterpretation of the classics has

 become possible after the fall of Communism. Weber‟s idea that capitalism should not be

seen in unitary terms is of special importance in the following reinterpretation:

The neo-classical turn in sociology does not imply at all a neo-classical convergence

of economics and sociology. The opposite is the case: the neo-classical turn in

sociology helps sociology to engage economics at the very core of its project (as it

was the case in the “classical” epoch). The key difference is that economics operate

with a single concept of capitalism (or market), while sociology sees it as a

multiplicity of forms. (Szelenyi 2001, see also Nee 2002)

ADDING TO THE PICTURE OF WEBER 

As earlier mentioned, it would not be correct to say that a new picture of Weber‟s

sociology has emerged and that the old one has vanished. A more accurate charac-

terization of the current situation is that traits from the old and the new picture mix and

 blend with one another. It should also be noted that even if a few parts of the new picture

can be discerned with some clarity, its overall gestalt is not clear. This is also true for the

new parts that I have chosen to focus on so far in this review, which all have to do with the

economy: how Weber analyzed the economy, how he used models from economics in his

sociology, and so on. Here as elsewhere, the dots can be connected in different ways.

Instead of spending more time in this review on recent secondary literature, however,

I now proceed to suggest two areas where I think it is possible to push ahead and advance

our understanding of Weber‟s work so that we can make better use of it. The ones I have

chosen are key concepts in Weber‟s theoretical sociology and his economic sociology.Both of these topics, I argue, are currently underdeveloped and can be improved by being

analyzed from a perspective that sets Weber‟s view of the economy and how to analyze

the economy at the center. Once this has been done, I suggest a way to connect the dots.

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 9: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 9/24

THE CHANGING PICTURE OF WEBER‟S SOCIOLOGY  291

Topic # 1: Weber‟s Theoretical Sociology 

Over the years considerable work has been carried out on Weber‟s theoretical sociology,

which is mainly to be found in Chapter 1 of  Economy and Society and in the essay Some

Categories of Interpretive Sociology (Weber [1922] 1978, pp. 3-62, [1913] 1981). Topics

that have been analyzed include the following: ideal type, the notion of  verstehen, the

concept of rationality, the four types of social action, and Weber‟s theory of causality. A

number of important topics nevertheless remain to be researched, and the ones that I

discuss here are Weber‟s concepts of interest, institution, and orientation to others.  

The concept of interest, I argue, constitutes one of the most important concepts in

Weber‟s sociology, even if little attention has been devoted to it. Not only is it a key

concept in its own right, but many other concepts in Weber‟s sociology— social action,

institution, and so on — can only be fully understood if they are related to it. The concept

of interest is also strongly related to the economy, to the concept of rational action, and to

the whole problematic of rational choice — in brief, to many of the issues that are at the

heart of  the changing picture of Weber‟s sociology. To better understand the role that

interest plays in Weber‟s thought therefore becomes an imperative task. 

At first it may seem surprising that Weber assigns such a central role in his work to the

concept of interest. Given the crucial role that the concept of interest has played in

Western social, political, and economic thought, however; and given the role that they

 played in Weber‟s own time, it would actually be more peculiar if it did not appear in a

 prominent place in Weber‟s work. Although there is no definitive study of the role of 

interest in Western thought, the general importance of this concept has been well

established by Hirschman, Holmes, and other scholars (see especially Orth & Koselleck 

1982, Hirschman 1986, Holmes 1990, Heilbron 2001). All of these show that from the

1500s onward practically every major social thinker assigned a central place to the

concept of interest in his or her analysis. A plethora of different interests have beendiscussed: political interests, economic interests, self-interest, class interests, the public

interest, and so on. The concept of interest in particular plays a key role in the works of 

Hume, Smith, Tocqueville, Mill, and Marx.

Although Hirschman and the other historians of the concept of interest discuss in great

detail the role that interest has played in the works of philosophers, political thinkers, and

economists, they have nothing to say about the use that sociologists have made of this

concept. It is at this point that Weber comes into the picture because he tried to introduce

a sociological concept of interest (Swedberg 2003). By sociological in this context it is

meant, on the one hand, that the concept of interest is used as part of a sociological

analysis, and on the other hand, that interest is not seen as something given or biological,

 but as something that comes into being as part of society.

By assigning such a central role to the notion of interest, it can be added, Weber wasnot alone among sociologists of his generation. Simmel and several others did the same

(e.g., Simmel [1908] 1971, see also Ratzenhofer 1898, Small 1905,

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 10: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 10/24

292 SWEDBERG

Bentley [1908] 1949). Among contemporary sociologists, especially Coleman and

Bourdieu have used the concept of interest prominently in their works. The maintheoretical concept in Coleman‟s rational choice sociology is precisely interest, defined as

control over resources that actors want (Coleman 1990, pp. 27-44). For Bourdieu, interest

is one of a handful of key concepts that the sociologist needs to use, next to habitus, field,

and different types of capital (e.g., Bourdieu & Wacquant 1992, pp. 115-40). According to

Bourdieu (1998), a disinterested act is not possible, and acts that appear to be disinterested

typically mask some interest. Furthermore, interests are always shaped by society, and just

about anything can be turned into an interest by the force of society (Bourdieu &

Wacquant 1992, p. 117).

In order to get a better sense of the way that Weber viewed the concept of interest, and

the role that it plays in his analysis more generally, one may begin with the following

famous quote:

 Not ideas, but material and ideal interests, directly govern men‟s conduct. Yet very

frequently the “world images” that have been created by “ideas” have, like

switchmen, determined the tracks along which action has been pushed by the

dynamic of interest. (Weber [1915] 1946, p. 280)

Although often cited, little sustained attention has been devoted to this passage (see,

however, Kalberg 1985; see also Blau 1996). What first of all should be noted about this

 passage is that Weber breaks with the tendency in mainstream economics to equate

interest exclusively with one type of interest (self-interest), and he does this by speaking

about different types of interests. By doing so, he is much closer to people such as Smith,

Tocqueville, and Mill than to contemporary economists. What should also be pointed out

is that although the interests are portrayed by Weber as the driving forces, it is the social

element (in the form of world images or religious world views) that channels and steersthe actions. The stronger these driving forces are, we may conclude, the more energy

 people will invest in their actions, the stronger the clashes are likely to be between actors,

and so on. Although Weber does not mention from where the interests come, and

although we would naturally tend to identify the world images with what is social, a

moment of reflection tells us that the interests themselves must be socially shaped (from

Weber‟s perspective)— if nothing else simply to qualify as either ideal or material

interests.

Even if one grants a certain centrality to the famous passage about ideal and material

interests, which can be found in a prominent place in Weber‟s Collected Essays in the

Sociology of Religion (Weber [1920/1921] 1988), it is legitimate to ask what role interests

 play elsewhere in Weber‟s work, especially in his theoretical sociology. No answer to this

question can be found in the secondary literature, even if one student has pointed out thatthe concept of interest can be found in nearly 800 sentences in  Economy and Society and

on roughly every third page (Peillon 1990, p. 55; see also Sprondel 1973). To this can be

added that Weber uses a large number of different types of interests in  Economy and 

Society, including sexual

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 11: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 11/24

THE CHANGING PICTURE OF WEBER‟S SOCIOLOGY  293

interests, speculative interests, class interests and emotional and affective interests (Weber 

[1922] 1978, pp. 41, 345, 928; for a complete listing of all the places in Weber‟s work where he uses the term Interesse, see the index in Weber 1999b). Weber also speaks of 

interest struggles and the well-known phrase material and ideal interests turns up in

 Economy and Society as well (Weber [1922] 1978, p. 202; [1922] 1976, p. 209).

To give a sense of the centrality of the concept of interest in Weber‟s work, I use his

sociology of law as a brief example. In one of the well-known passages of  Economy and 

Society, Weber outlines the general relationships that exist between law and the economy

(Weber [1922] 1978, pp. 333-37). There are six such relationships, and interest plays a

key role in three of these. We are told, for example, that law does not only protect

economic interests, but also “the most diverse interests ranging from the most elementary

one of protection of personal security to such purely ideal goods as personal honor or the

honor of the divine powers” (Weber [1922] 1978, p. 333). When economic interests stand

against “interests promoting conformance to the rules of law,” Weber continues,everything hinges on “the relative proportion of strength” (Weber [1922] 1978, p. 335).

He also states that even if the law in many cases does not appear to have been shaped by

economic interests, this is nonetheless often the case. In explaining why this is so, Weber 

states that legal power usually depends on support from the major social groups, and “the

formation of [major] social groups depends, to a large extent, upon constellations of 

material interests” (Weber [1922] 1978, p. 334). 

Weber‟s concept of institution has also been neglected in the secondary literature, even

if there exist some exceptions. An institution has its beginning, Weber says, in the

interaction of a few actors, which after some time acquires a certain independence in their 

eyes. This order (Ordnung ) is seen as “obligatory or exemplary” to the actors (Weber 

[1922] 1978, p. 31). An institution is typically supported by habit as well as by

legitimation. What completes the needed requirements for there to be a full-scaleinstitution are as follows: Significant interests must be involved, and (in modem society)

coercion will be applied by a staff when there are threats to the institution (Weber [1922]

1978, pp. 34,48-56).

To Weber, the number of institutions in society are relatively few. There is what he

terms the legal order, the economic order, the household, and so on. What is especially

important in Weber‟s notion of institution is that these are conceived as constellations of 

interests that have been locked into specific configurations through social relations

(including world images and the capitalist spirit). What this means is that institutions are

hard to change; they are deeply rooted in interests, something that gives them

considerable strength and survival capacity. That the basic institutions of society may

nevertheless change under certain conditions is clear from The Protestant Ethic and other 

studies by Weber. However, the force that challenges an institution has to be strong andfirmly grounded in competing interests.

One reason for emphasizing the role of interests and enforcement in Weber‟s view of 

institutions is that there is little discussion of these in what constitutes

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 12: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 12/24

294 SWEDBERG

the most popular account of Weber‟s ideas on this specific topic, namely The Social 

Construction of Reality by Berger & Luckmann (1967; see also Powell & DiMaggio1991 for the use of these ideas in the area of organizations). This work, which draws

heavily on Alfred Schutz‟s phenomenological interpretation of Weber, is an important

source in contemporary sociology for the widespread notion that everything is socially

constructed. Although this may be true on a high level of abstraction, this proposition can

also easily lead wrong if the role of interests and the enforcement of challenges to these

interests are not explicitly taken into account — which they rarely are in the work by

Berger & Luckmann (but see Berger & Luckmann 1967, pp. 22,45,48,51-67). If people

try to socially construct something that goes against the existing institutions of society,

they run the risk of being hit by a force similar to that of a train rushing ahead (to use

Weber‟s railroad metaphor). 

The last theoretical concept I discuss is orientation to others, which has been generally

ignored in the secondary literature on Weber. Why this is the case is not clear, but it maywell have to do with the fact that it is closely linked to Weber‟s concept of methodological

individualism. Weber was a strong defender of methodological individualism in

sociology — a topic that for rather obvious reasons has not attracted much attention in the

conventional picture of Weber with its advocacy of social systems and other forms of 

holism (for Weber‟s ideas on methodological individualism, see, e.g., Udehn 2001, pp.

95-103).

The concept of orientation to others appears in a prominent place in Weber‟s

sociology, namely in the first paragraph of  Economy and Society, where the task of 

sociology is outlined (Weber [1922] 1978, p. 4; see also [1913] 1981, p. 152). Sociology,

Weber states, is the science that deals with social action. You have action when there is

 behavior to which the actor attaches a subjective meaning, and this action becomes social

if it “takes account of the behavior of others and is thereby oriented [orientiert] in itscourse.” 

Elsewhere in Chapter 1 of  Economy and Society Weber states that an action can be

oriented to the past, the present, or the future — that it can be oriented to an order, and that

it can be oriented to several orders simultaneously. To this it should be added that the only

actor who can carry out and orient an action is the individual, and this is consequently

where methodological individualism comes into the picture. The orientation of an actor is

in principle driven by his or her interests, and the course that the action will take will be

shaped by existing world images (or their equivalents).

Topic # 2: Weber's Economic Sociology

Economic sociology is a topic that is close to the current Zeitgeist , and it would therefore

seem suitable to further explore Weber‟s work in this respect. Some advances in this fieldhave already been made (e.g., Collins 1986, pp. 19-142; Holton & Turner 1989b; Bruhns

1996; Engerman 2000). It has, for example, been increasingly realized that Economy and 

Society is not so much a work in general

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 13: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 13/24

THE CHANGING PICTURE OF WEBER‟S SOCIOLOGY 295 

sociology, with independent sections on law, religion, and so on, as was earlier believed.

 Economy and Society should rather be understood as a study that explores the relationship between, on the one hand, the economy, and on the other hand, politics, law, and religion

(e.g., Stinchcombe 1960; for the coming into being and structure of   Economy and 

Society, see especially Mommsen 2000, Orihara 1999, 2002). 

Weber‟s Wirtschaftssoziologie has also attracted some direct attention during the past

few years, as opposed to the earlier literature. Its general structure and main areas have,

for example, been outlined (Swedberg 1998). A text with Weber‟s key texts in economic

sociology has also been published (Weber 1999c; see also the recent translations of 

Weber‟s study of the stock exchange and of his dissertation on the lexmercatoria in

Weber [1889] 2003, [1894] 2000, [1896] 2000). Added to this should be single studies of 

Weber‟s analysis of the firm, the market, the business community, patrimonialism,

entrepreneurial opportunities, and the relationship of sociology to marginal utility theory

(Segre 1998; Makler 2000; Engelen 2001; Zafirovski 2001a,b; Jagd 2003, Kaelber 2003b). There is also what we have recently learned about Weber‟s relationship to the

work of single economists, from Smith to the Austrians (see Hennis 1987; Mitzman 1987;

Osterhammel 1987; Schon 1987; Holton & Turner 1989a; Sica 1992, pp. 225-48;

Zafirovski 2000).

Even if a few first steps have been taken along the path of a better understanding of 

Weber‟s economic sociology, many topics still remain to be analyzed or have not been

sufficiently explored. Little is known, for example, about the giant handbook on

economics that Weber edited and of which Economy and Society is a part, Grundriss der 

Sozialdkonomik. We also need to better understand the following topics: Weber‟s view of 

economic theory, the general structure of his theoretical economic sociology (in Chapter 2

in Economy and Society), his view of the firm, and his view of capitalism. Although all of 

these topics represent worthwhile enterprises in their own right, I focus on the latter two because these best illustrate that we are indeed witnessing a change in the general picture

of Weber‟s sociology. 

Weber‟s analysis of the capitalist firm was little discussed during the early period of 

Weberian studies. What instead fascinated and even spellbound American sociologists

was Weber‟s analysis of bureaucracy. The text on bureaucracy that was cited over and

over again originally appeared in Gerth & Mills‟s best-selling anthology  From Max

Weber  (1946, pp. 196-204; for this work, see Oakes 1999, Oakes & Vidich 1999). A

vivid debate soon broke out over whether Weber‟s theory of bureaucracy was correct.

Several of the most creative sociologists in the postWorld War II generation, such as

Merton and Gouldner, took part in this debate, usually suggesting that Weber was wrong

on some point, but that this could be amended with the help of the author‟s own revisions

(for reviews of the relevant literature, see, e.g., Albrow 1970, Scott 1998, pp. 42-49).Two aspects of Weber‟s work on bureaucracy were, however, not explored during the

earlier period: Weber‟s general theory of organization, of which his ideas on bureaucracy

are an integral part, and his view of the modem firm. In Chapter 

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 14: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 14/24

296 SWEDBERG

1 of  Economy and Society Weber carefully develops the concept of organization, starting

out (as always) with the social action of the individual (Weber [1922] 1978, pp. 48-52).Two actors who interact with one another create a social relationship, and these

relationships can be either open or closed. An organization is defined by Weber as a

closed social relationship, with a person or staff in charge of enforcing its rules.

Weber discusses three broad classes of organizations in his theoretical sociology:

 political, economic, and religious organizations (Weber [1922] 1978, pp. 52-56, 74-75).

These are distinguished from each other on several accounts, such as the way that

authority is maintained and what type of interests are involved. Economic organizations,

for example, can be exclusively devoted to economic tasks (such as the modem firm);

they can be partly devoted to economic tasks (such as the modem state); they can have as

their task the regulation of economic activities (such as a trade union); and they can

 protect the economic order from interference (such as the laissez-faire state) (Weber 

[1922] 1978, pp. 74-75).Three types of actors can be found in the modem firm, according to Weber:

entrepreneurs, bureaucrats, and workers. The bureaucrats run the corporation on an

everyday basis, by virtue of their knowledge and dedication. The workers execute the

orders given to them by the bureaucrats, in a disciplined manner. The entrepreneur 

represents the capitalist spirit, and is the only one who is able to successfully challenge the

 bureaucrats. What the entrepreneur lacks in detailed knowledge, compared to the

 bureaucrats, he or she makes up for through independence and economic power. In each

firm, as in capitalism as a whole, there is a constant struggle between the aggressive profit

seeking of the entrepreneur, on the one hand, and the correct behavior and the defense of 

the status quo of the bureaucrats, on the other. The bureaucrats value competence, skill,

and honor more than profit making. They actually “abhor” profit making, according to

Weber, who says that “every bureaucracy” tends to “stifle the private economic initiative”(Weber [1922] 1978, pp. 1108-9; 1988, p. 277).

Another aspect of Weber‟s work on the modem firm that has been ignored in the

traditional view of his work has to do with the history and the development of the firm. In

 Economy and Society as well as in several other works, we find an interesting attempt to

sketch the history of the firm, starting with the commenda and the family firm in

Antiquity (see, e.g., Weber [1889] 2003, [1923] 1981; but see Kaelber 2003a). Weber 

also highlights the emergence of limited liability in the firm and the notion of the firm as a

legal personality, two key innovations that occurred in the Middle Ages. Weber notes

further the emergence of the shareholding corporation, and he devotes considerable

energy to describing the kind of giant corporations that emerged around 1900, and which

not only Weber but also Chandler has held up as the apex of efficiency (e.g., Chandler 

1977).

Weber‟s analysis of the modem firm is not only part of his general theory of 

organization but also of his general analysis of capitalism —the second topic in Weber‟s

economic sociology that I have selected to discuss in this review as part

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 15: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 15/24

Page 16: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 16/24

298 SWEDBERG

Figure 1 The different types of capitalism in social action terms, according to Weber in

 Economy and Society ([1922] 1978, pp. 164-66).

of a “mode for capitalistic orientation of profit-making” (Weber [1922] 1978, p. 164; see

also [1904-1905] 1930, p. 17). What is at the heart of Weber‟s view of capitalism is, in

other words, the individual, driven by his or her economic interest and trying to make a

 profit while simultaneously orienting his or her actions to various institutions. According

to the key passage on capitalism in Economy and Society, there are six of these modes of 

capitalistic orientation of profit making. Two of these can only be found in the modem

Western world, whereas the other four have been around for several thousand years in

many parts of the world (see Figure 1).

(1)  Continuous buying and selling in free markets, and continuous production of 

goods in capitalist enterprises.

(2)  Speculation in standardized commodities or securities; continuous financial

operations of political organizations; promotional financing of new enterprises by

selling securities; speculative financing of new enterprises and other economic

organizations to gain power or a profitable regulation of the market

(3)  Predatory profit can come, e.g., from the financing of wars, revolutions, and party

leaders.

(4)  Continuous business activity thanks to force or domination, e.g., tax and office

farming, colonial profits (plantations, monopolistic, and compulsory trade)

(5)  No more information on this type of political capitalism can be found in section

31 in chapter 2 of  Economy and Society. 

(6)  Trade and speculations in currencies, professional and credit extension, creation of 

means of payment, the taking over of payment functions.

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 17: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 17/24

THE CHANGING PICTURE OF WEBER‟S SOCIOLOGY  299

Weber broke with Marx‟s idea that there only exists one type of capitalism, which

emerged in the West in the modem period. He also tried to recast capitalism in socialaction terms in order to avoid the notion of capitalism as a system independent of the

individual. According to the main theoretical passage on capitalism in  Economy and 

Society, Weber distinguishes between six different types of “principal modes of 

capitalistic orientation of profit- making.” Only two of these main modes of 

capitalistic orientation of profit making are typical of modem times and the West; the

other four can be found far back in history all over the world. The former two Weber 

terms are rational capitalism, and the remaining four are political capitalism and

traditional-commercial capitalism.

CONCLUSION

During the course of this review I have made references to three different interpretations

of Weber that can be described in ideal-typical terms (see Table 1). There is first of all

what I have referred to as the traditional viewpoint, which represents the early

interpretation of Weber in American sociology. The work of such scholars as Parsons and

Bendix are central here, but this interpretation is still strong and can be found in a number 

of contemporary works as well. The individual actor is primarily seen as driven by norms

and values, and authority is crucial to the structuring of society. Weber‟s comparative

work on religion and domination is at the center of this interpretation.

TABLE 1 What drives the actor, according to Weber? Three ideal-typical answers

Traditional iewpoint 

Rational Choice viewpoint 

Interest iewpoint 

Cause of action  Values, norms  Rational choice  Interests 

View of verstehen   Incorporated  Downplayed  Incorporated 

View of methodological

individualism 

Downplayed  Context-bound  Social 

Paradigmatic text by Weber  Sociology of authority and

religion 

Chapter 1 of Economy and 

Society  

Sociology of 

religion 

Ideal-typical representative  Parsons  Kiser-Hechter  Bourdieu 

Source: Parsons 1937; Kiser & Hechter 1998, pp. 785-816; Bourdieu 1987, pp. 119-36.

ote; It is possible to distinguish between three different views in the secondary literature on Weber on what drives the actor: the

raditional view, where values and norms are central; the rational choice view, where the actor makes a rational decision; and the interest-

ased view, where the actor attempts to realize his or her interests. These three views can also be distinguished on several other accounts,

as indicated in the table.

It can be added that the view of history differs as well between these three views. The conventional view sees history as a progression

in terms of rationality; the rational choice view is focused on historical comparisons; and the interest view is mainly concerned with

different types of capitalism.

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 18: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 18/24

300 SWEDBERG

More recently this view has been challenged by interpretations that argue the

individual actor in Weber‟s sociology is driven by other forces than norms and values,such as interests and rational choice. Bourdieu exemplifies the interest view, and Hechter 

and Kiser the rational choice view. These three interpretations also differ on several other 

accounts, as Table 1 indicates. They have different views on how to understand Weber‟s

notion of verstehen and his view of methodological individualism.

Is it possible to arbitrate between these different interpretations and assert that one is

 preferable to the others, in the sense of leading to better sociology? It is difficult to give an

affirmative answer to this question. Nonetheless, it is also clear that the reader who wants

to know something about Weber‟s view of various economic topics, including Weber‟s

use of the models of the economists, will find little material in the secondary literature

 before the mid-1970s. Similarly, the great majority of the issues that have concerned

Parsons, Bendix, and other advocates of what has here been called the traditional

interpretation of Weber have not been much discussed by the representatives of the other two approaches, which have a long way to go before they are fully developed. As things

stand today, the various views of Weber‟s work complement each other, and the serious

student of Weber may want to consult them all.

Earlier in this review I mentioned that several new pieces of information about

Weber‟s life and work have recently become available that in one way or another deal

with the economy and that there may also be a way of understanding their general

significance or gestalt — to connect the dots, so to speak. Before giving my own answer to

how this may be done, it should be noted that both the rational choice interpretation and

the interest interpretation of Weber‟s sociology, as I see it, pick up on something that is

absolutely central in Weber‟s work and which has been neglected. 

What they pick up on is Weber‟s use, in his sociology, of models of thought from

economics (as Bourdieu puts it). The rational choice approach, however, suggests aradical recasting of Weber‟s work from a viewpoint that, to a large extent, has been

created after Weber‟s death, namely modem rational choice analysis. Game theory, for 

example, did not exist in Weber‟s days. One can also use Posner‟s (1995) critique of 

Weber to illustrate the distance that exists between modem rational choice theory and

Weberian sociology as a whole. According to Posner, Weber is interested in describing

 broad themes in human history, not in developing mathematical models for predicting the

 behavior of rational actors. Modem rational choice theory also differs on several accounts

from the type of analytical economics with which Weber was familiar, and which he also

was influenced by, namely the type of analysis that can be found in the works of 

economists such as Menger and Mill (e.g., Weber [1898] 1900; see also Udehn 2001, pp.

95-103).

Interest analysis, in contrast, picks up on several elements that are already present in

Weber‟s work. Weber speaks, for example, to a large extent in interest terms, as I have

tried to show, and when he does not do so explicitly, he many times does so implicitly.

The interest model, as opposed to the modem rational choice

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 19: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 19/24

THE CHANGING PICTURE OF WEBER‟S SOCIOLOGY  301

model, is also better at capturing the fact that although Weber borrowed much from

economics, he did not borrow everything. There are parts of theoretical economics, Weber argues in Economy and Society and elsewhere, that are simply not useful in sociology.

Weber‟s relationship to the models he found in economics can be summed up in the

following way: Weber borrowed quite a bit from economics, as he did from the other 

social sciences, but he did not simply reproduce what he had borrowed in his sociology.

Instead he turned it into something new and exciting — and profoundly sociological.

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

For comments and/or information I thank Raymond Boudon, Sven Eliaeson, Michael

Hechter, Stephen Kalberg, Edgar Kiser, Harry Makler, Heino Nau, Zenonans Norkus,

Guenther Roth, Dick Scott, Ralph Schroeder, Alan Sica, Ivan Szelenyi, and Stephen

Turner. This review was written while I was at the Center for Advanced Study in the

Behavioral Sciences, and I am grateful for financial support from Center General Funds

and the William and Flora Hewlitt Foundation Grant #2000-5633.

The Annual Review of Sociology is online at http://soc.annualreviews.org 

LITERATURE CITED

Albrow M. 1970. On Bureaucracy. London:

Macmillan

Baehr P, Wells G. 2002. Editors‟ introduction. In

The Protestant Ethic and the „Spirit‟ of 

Capitalism and Other Writi ngs , ed. M Weber pp.

ix-lxiii. New York: Penguin Books Barbalet JM.

2000.Beruf rationality and emotion in Max

Weber‟s sociology.Arch. Eur . Sociol. 41(2):329-51

Baumgarten E, ed. 1964. Max Weber. Werk und 

Person. Dokumente. Tübingen: Mohr Bendix R.

1960.Max Weber: An Intellectual Portrait. 

Garden City, NY: Doubleday Bentley A. [1908]

1949.The Process of Government: A Study of 

Social Processes. Bloomington, IN: Principia

Berger P, Luckmann T. 1967 . The Social Con - 

struction of Reality. Garden City, NY: Doubleday

-► Blau J. 1996. The toggle switch of institutions:

religion and art in the United States since the

nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Soc.

Forces 74:1159-77

Bologh RW. 1990. Love or Greatness: M ax Weber 

and Masculine Thinki ng  — A Feminist I nquiry. 

London: Unwin Hyman Borchardt K, Meyer-Stoll C. 1999. Einleitung. In Börsenwesen.

Schr if ten und Reden 18931898. Max Weber 

Gesamtausgabe 1/5 , pp. 1111. Tübingen: Mohr.

2 Vols. 

Borchardt K. 2002. Max Weber‟s writings on the

Bourse: puzzling out a forgotten corpus. Max 

Weber Stud. 2(2): 139-62 Boudon R. 1996. The

„cognitivist model‟: a generalized rational-choice

model.Ration . Soc. 8(2): 123-50 Boudon R. 1997.

The present relevance of Max Weber‟s

Wertr ational ität (value rationality). In

Methodology of the Social Sciences, Ethi cs, and 

Economics in the Newer Hi storical School , ed. P

Koslowski, pp. 4-29. New York: Springer Boudon R.

2001.The Origi n of Values: Sociology and 

Phil osophy of Beliefs.New Brunswick, NJ:

Transaction Bourdieu P. [1971] 1987. Legitimation

and

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 20: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 20/24

302 SWEDBERG

structured interests in Weber‟s sociology of 

religion. In Max Weber, Rationality and Modernity , ed. S Lash, S Whimster, pp. 119 — 36.

London: Allen & Unwin Bourdieu R 1987.

Choses Dites. Paris: Ed. Minuit

Bourdieu P. [1987] 1990. I n Other Words. Stanford:

Stanford Univ. Press Bourdieu P. 1998. Is a

disinterested act possible? In Practi cal Reason: 

On the Theory of Action , pp. 75-91. Stanford:

Stanford Univ. Press

Bourdieu P, Wacquant L. 1992. An I nvitation to 

Reflexive Sociology. Chicago: Univ. Chicago

Press

Bruhns H. 1996. Max Weber, l‟economie et

l‟histoire.Ann . Hi st. Sci. Soc. 51:125987-► Burawoy M. 2001. Neoclassical sociology: from the end

of communism to the end o W classes. Am. J . Soc. 

106:1099-20 Chandler A. 1977. The Visible Hand: The 

Manageri al Revolution in America.Cambridge, MA:

Belknap -► Cohen J, Hazelrigg L, Pope W. 1975. De-

arsonizing Weber: A critique of Parsons‟ interpretation

of Weber‟s sociology. Am. Soc. Rev.40:229-41 Coleman J.

1989. Weber and the protestant ethic: a comment on

Hemes.Ration. Soc. l(2):291-94 Coleman J. 1990.

Foundations of Social Theory.Cambridge, MA: Harvard

Univ. Press Collins R. 1986. Weberi an Sociologi cal 

Theory. 

Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univ. Press

Dahrendorf R. 1987. Max Weber and modem social

science. See Mommsen & Osterhammel 1987, pp.

574-80 Eliaeson S. 1982. Bil den av Max Weber: En 

Studie i Samhdll svetenskapens Seku lar iser- ing 

(The Picture of Max Weber: A Study in th e 

Secular ization of Social Science). Stockholm:

Nordstedt Eliaeson S. 2002. Max Weber' s 

Methodologies: I nterpretation and Cri tique. 

Cambridge, UK: Polity

Elster J. 1979. Some unresolved problems in the

theory of rational behavior. In Sociological  

Economics , ed. L Levy-Garboa, pp. 65-85.

London: Sage Elster J. 2000. Rationality,economy, and society. See Turner 2000, pp. 21-41

Engelen E. 2001. „Breaking in‟ and „breaking

out‟: A Weberian approach to entrepreneurial

opportunities,/.Ethn. M igr. Stud. 27(2):203- 23

Engerman SL. 2000. Max Weber as economist and

economic historian. See Turner 2000, pp. 256-71

Eyal G, SzelSnyi I, Townsley E. 1998.Making 

Capitalism without Capitalists: Class Formation 

and El ite Struggle in Post-Communist Central 

Europe.London: Verso Gerth H, Mills CW, eds.

1946. Introduction: The man and his work. In From 

Max Weber: Essays in Sociol ogy , pp. 1-74. New

York: Oxford Univ. Press Goldthorpe J. 1998.Rational action theory for sociology. Br. J . Sociol. 

49:167-92 Gould R, ed. 2002. The Rational Choice 

Controversy in Hi storical Sociology.Chicago:

Univ. Chicago Press Hall P, Soskice D, eds. 2001.

Varieties of Capitalism: The I nstitutional 

Foundations of Comparati ve Advantage. New

York: Oxford Univ. Press

Hechter M, Kanazawa S. 1997. Sociological rational

choice theory.Annu. Rev. Sociol. 23:191-214

Heilbron J. 2001. Interest: history of a concept. In

I nternational Encyclopaedia of the Social and 

Behavioral Sciences , ed. N Smelser, P Baltes,

11:7708-12. Amsterdam: Elsevier Hennis W. 1987.

A science of man: Max Weber and the political

economy of the German historical school. See

Mommsen & Osterhammel 1987, pp. 25-58 Hennis

W. 2000. Fur Wissenschaftler sind Kursgewinne

edeutunglos (Review of Max Weber,Borsenwesen.

Schri ften und Reden 1893-1898). Frankf. A ll g. Z

Oct. 17:L52 Hemes G. 1989a. The logic of the

Protestant ethic.Ration . Soc. 1(1): 123-62 Hemes G.

1989b. Response to Coleman. Ration . Soc. 1(2):295-

99 Hinkle G. 1986. The americanization of Max

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 21: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 21/24

THE CHANGING PICTURE OF WEBER‟S SOCIOLOGY 303 

Weber. Cur r. Perspect. Soc. Theory 7:87 

104Hirschman AO. 1986. The concept of interest: From

euphemism to tautology. InRival Views of M arket 

Society and Other Recent Essays , pp. 35-55. New

York: Viking Hollingsworth R, Schmitter P,

Streeck W, eds. 1994. Governi ng Capitali st 

Economies. New York: Oxford Univ. Press Holmes

S. 1990. The secret history of self -► interest. In

Beyond Self-I nterest , ed. J Mans- bridge, pp. 267-

86. Chicago: Univ. Chicago Press

 

 —► 

Holton R, Turner BS. 1989a. Max Weber, Austrian

economics, and liberalism. See Holton & Turner1989b, pp. 30-67 Holton R, Turner BS. 1989b.Max 

Weher on Economy and Society , pp. 30-67. New

York  —► Routledge

Honigsheim P. [1946-1963] 2000. The Unknown 

Max Weber , ed. A Sica. New Brunswick, NJ:

Transaction Jagd S. 2003. Max Weber‟s last

theory of the modem business enterprise. Max 

Weber Stud. 2(2): In press Jaspers K. [1920-

1962] 1989. On Max Weber. 

New York: Paragon House Kaelber L. 2003a.

Introduction: Max Weber‟s dissertation in the

context of his early life and career. In The 

History of Commercial Partnerships in the M iddle Ages , pp. 1 — 47. New York: Rowman &

Littlefield

Kaelber L. 2003b. Max Weber‟s dissertation. 

H ist. Hum. Sei. In press

Kalberg S. 1985. The role of ideal interests in Max

Weber‟s comparative historical sociology. In The 

Marx-WeberDebate, ed. R Antonio, R Glassman,

pp. 46-67. Lawrence: Univ. Kans. Press Kälber S.

1994.  Max Weber‟s Comparative- Historical 

Sociology. Chicago: Univ. Chicago Press

Käsler D. 1989. Der retuschierte Klassiker. Zum

gegenwärtigen Forschungsstand der Biographie

Max Webers. InMax Weber Heute , ed. J Weiss, pp.

29-54. Frankfurt Main: Suhrkamp

-+ Kiser E. 1999. Comparing varieties of agency

theory in economics, political science and

sociology: an illustration from state policyimplementation.Sociol . Theory 17(2): 146 — 70

Kiser E, Baer J. 2001. The bureaucratization of 

states: toward an analytical Weberianism.

Pepared for the Conf. “The Making and Un-

making of Modernity”, March 30-April 1,

Northwestern Univ.

Kiser E, Hechter M. 1998. The debate on historical

sociology: rational choice theory and its critics. Am.

J. Soc. 104(1998):785 — 816 Kiser E, Schneider E.

1994. Bureaucracy and efficiency: an analysis of 

taxation in early Prussia.Am. Soc. Rev.59:187-204

Kivisto P, Swatos W. 1988. Max Weber: A Bio- 

Bibliography. Westport, CT: Greenwood LestitionS. 2000. Historical preface to Max Weber, „stock and

commodity exchanges‟. Theory Soc. 29:289-304

Makler H. 2000. Bank transformation and pri-

vatization in Brazil: financial federalism and some

lessons about bank privatization, Q. Rev. Econ.

Finance 40:45-69 Mitzman A. 1987. Personal

conflicts and ideological options in Sombart and

Weber. See Mommsen & Osterhammel 1987, pp. 99

105

Mommsen W. [1959] 1984. Max Weber and 

German Poli tics, 1890-1920. Chicago: Univ.

Chicago Press Mommsen W. 2000. Max Weber‟s

„grand sociology‟: The origins and composition of 

Wirtschaft und Gesell schaft. Soziologie. Hi st.

Theory 39:364-83 Mommsen W, Aldenhoff R. 1993.

Einleitung. In Landarbeieterfrage, Nationalstaat 

und Volkswirtschaftspolitik . Schr iften und Reden 

1892-1899. Max Weber Gesamtausgabe 1/4 , 1:1-

68. Tübingen: Mohr Mommsen W, Osterhammel J,

eds. 1987. Max Weber and H is Contemporar ies. 

London: Unwin

Nau H. 2003. Max Weber Economist. In press Nau

H. 1997. Eine „Wissenschaft von Men- 

sc h en M a x Weber und dir Begründung der 

Sozialökonomi k i n der deutschsprachi gen 

Ökonomie. Berlin: Duncker & Humblot 

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AMAll use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 22: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 22/24

304 SWEDBERG

Nee V. 1998. Sources of the new institutionalism. In

The New Institutional ism in Sociology , ed. MBrinton, V Nee, pp. 1-16. New York: Russell Sage

Found.

Nee V. 2002. Discussion with Richard Swed- berg

about the term neo-classical sciology - Ithaca, NY,

Oct. 6 Norkus Z. 2000. Max Weber‟s interpretive

sociology and rational choice approach.Ration. Soc. 

12(3):259-82 Norkus Z. 2001. Max Weber und 

Rational Choice. Marburg: Metropolis-Verlag

Norkus Z. 2002. Max Weber and Rational Choi ce. 

Vilnius: Inst. Soc. Res.

Oakes G. 1997. Guenther Roth and Weberian

studies in America. I nt. J. Polit. Cult. Soc. 11(1):

175-79 Oakes G. 1999. Gerth, Mills, and Shils: theorigins of From Max Weber. I nt. J. Polit. Cult. Soc. 

12(3):399-433 Oakes G, Vidich A. 1999.

Collaboration, Reputation , and Ethics in 

American Academic L if e: Hans H. Gerth and C.

Wright Mill s. Urbana: Urbana 111. Press Orihara

H. 1999. Max Webers Beitrag zum „Grundriss der

Sozialökonomik‟. Das Vorkriegsmanuskript als

eines integriertes Ganzes. KölnerZ . Soz .

Sozialpsychol. 51(4): 724-34

Orihara H. 2002. From „a torso with a wrong head 9  

to \f ive disjointed pieces of carcass 9 ?: Problems 

of the editori al policies for the Mm - Weber 

Gesamtausgabe 1/22 (Old M anuscri pt Known as „Part IV of the Economy and Society). Work.

Pap. Seri., Sugiyama Jogakuen Univ., Aichi-ken,

Jpn. 

Orth EW, Koselleck R. 1982. Interesse. In

Geschichtli che Grundbegri ff e , ed. O Brunner,

W Conze, R Koselleck, pp. 305-64. Stuttgart:

Klott-Ketta Osterhammel J. 1987. Varieties of 

social economics: Joseph A. Schumpeter and Max

Weber. See Mommsen & Osterhammel 1987, pp.

106-20

Palonen K. 2001. Was Max Weber a „nationalist‟? A

study in rhetoric of conceptual change. Max 

Weber Stud. 1(2): 196214

Parsons T. 1937. The Structur e of Social Action.

New York: McGraw-Hill Peillon M. 1990.The Concept of I nterest in Social Theory. Lewiston,

NY: The Edwin Mellen

Poggi G. 1986. Max Weber: A monumental edition

in the making. Br . J. Soc. 37(2):297- 303

Posner R. 1995. The sociology of the sociology of 

law.Eur . J. Law Soc. 2:265-84

Powell W, DiMaggio P, eds. 1991. The New 

Institutionali sm in Organizational Analysis.

Chicago: Univ. Chicago Press

Ratzenhofer G. 1898. Die Soziol ogische Erken- 

ntnis. Leipzig: Brockhaus

Roth G. 1977a. Introduction to the New Edition. In

Max Weber: An I ntellectual Portrai t , pp. [xiii]-xxxvi. Berkeley: Univ. Calif. Press Roth G. 1977b.

Max Weber: a bibliographic essay. Z.Soziol. 

6(1):91 — 102 Roth G. 1988. Introduction to the new

edition. InMax Weber: A B iography , pp. xv-lx.

Brunswick, NJ: Transaction

Roth G. 1993a. Between cosmopolitanism and

ethnocentrism: Max Weber in the nineties. Telos  

96:148-62

Roth G. 1993b. Weber the would-be Englishman:

Anglophilia and family history. In Weber's 

Protestant E thic , ed. H Lehmann, G Roth, pp. 83-

121. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univ. Press

Roth G. 1996. The complete edition of Weber‟swork: an update. Contemp. Sociol . 25(4):464-67

Roth G. 1997. The young Max Weber: Anglo-

American religious influences and Protestant social

reform in Germany. I nt. J. Polit. Cult. Soc.10:659-

71

RothG. 1999. Max Weber at home and in Japan:

On the troubled genesis and successful reception of 

his work. I nt. J. Polit. Cult. Soc. 12:515-25

Roth G. 2000. Global capitalism and multiethnicity:

Max Weber then and now. See Turner 2000, pp.

117-39

Roth G. 2001. Max Webers deutsch-englische 

Familiengeschichte 1800-1950. Tübingen:

Mohr

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 23: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 23/24

THE CHANGING PICTURE OF WEBER‟S SOCIOLOGY 305 

Roth G. 2002. Max Weber: Family history, eco -

nomic policy, exchange reform. Int. J. Polit.Cul t. Soc. 15:509-20

Runciman WG. 2001. Was Max Weber a se-

lectionist despite himself? J. Cl ass. Soc. 1(1): 13-

32

Scaff L. 1998. The „cool objectivity of soci- ation‟:

Max Weber and Marianne Weber in America.

Hi st. Hum. Sei. 11(2):61 — 82

Scaff L. 2000. Rationalization and culture. See

Turner 2000, pp. 42-58

Schluchter W. 2000. Handlungs- und Struk-

turtheorie nach Max Weber. Berl. J. Soziol.

10:125-36

Schon M. 1987. Gustav Schmoller and Max Weber.See Mommsen & Osterhammel 1987, pp. 59-70

Schroeder R. 1992.Max Weber and the Sociology 

of Culture. London: Sage

Scott WR. 1998. Organizations: Rational, Natural ,

and Open Systems. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice

Hall. 4th ed.

Segre S. 1998. Business communities and their

milieux: reappraisal of Toennies, Weber, and

Simmel. I nt. J. Pol. Cult. Sociol. 11:411-37

Seyfarth C, Schmidt G. 1977. Max-Weber Bi b- 

liographie. Stuttgart: Enke

Sica A. 1992.Weber, Ir rationali ty and Social 

Order. Berkeley: Univ. Calif. Press

Sica A. 2003.Max Weber: A Comprehensive 

Bibliography. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction

Press

Simmel G. [1908] 1971. The problem of sociology. In

On Individualism and Social Forms , ed. D

Levine, pp. 23-35. Chicago: Univ. Chicago Press

Small A. 1905. General Sociology: An Expo- 

siti on of the Main Development of Sociological 

Theory f rom Spencer to Ratzenhofer. Chicago:

Univ. Chicago Press

Sprondel W. 1973. Sozialer Wandel, Ideen und

Interessen: Systematisierungen zu Max Webers

Protestantischer Ethik. In Seminar: Religion 

und gesellschaftliche Entwicklung , ed. C

Seyfarth, W Sprondel, pp. 206-24. Frankfurt

Main: Suhrkamp

Stammer O, ed. 1971. Max Weber and Sociology 

Today. New York: Harper Torchback 

Stark D. 1996. Recombinant property in East

European capitalism. Am. J. Sociol  101:993-1027

Stinchcombe A. 1960. Review of Max Weber.

Economy and Society. Am. J. Sociol . 75:28286

Swedberg R. 1998 . Max Weber and the Idea of 

Economi c Sociol ogy. Princeton: Princeton Univ.

Press

Swedberg R. 2003. Principles of E conomic So- 

ciology.Princeton: Princeton Univ. Press

Szelenyi I. 2001. Email message to R Swedberg,

June 7 Tribe K. 1995. Strategies of Economic 

Order: German Economic Discourse, 1750- 

1950. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univ.

Turner S, ed. 2000. Cambridge Companion to Weber. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge Univ. Press

Udehn L. 2001. Methodological Individualism: 

Background, History and Meaning. London:

Routledge 

Voss T. 2000. Rational choice theory in sociology: a

survey. In The International Handbook of 

Sociology, ed. SR Quah, A Sales, pp. 50-83.

London: Sage Weber M. [1889] 2003. The 

History of Commercial Partnerships in the 

M iddle Ages. New York: Rowman & Littlefield

Weber M. [1894] 2000. Stock and commodity

exchanges [D ie Börse  (1894)]. Theory Soc.

29:305-38

Weber M. [1896] 2000. Commerce on the stock and

commodity exchanges [D ie Börsenverkehr] .

Theory Soc. 29:339-71 Weber M. [1898] 1900.

Grundr iss zu den Vorl esungen über Al lgemeine 

(“theoretische”) Nationalöknomie (1898). 

Tübingen: Mohr Weber M. [1904/1905] 1930.The 

Protestant Ethi c and the Spiri t of Capitalism. 

London: Allen & Unwin Weber M. [1913] 1981.

Some categories of interpretive sociology.Soc. Q. 

22(Spring):151-80 Weber M. [1915] 1946. The social

psychology of the world religions. See Gerth & Mills

1946, pp. 267-301 Weber M. [1920/1921] 1988.

Gesammelte  

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 

Page 24: Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

7/27/2019 Swedberg (2003) The Changing Picture of Max Weber Sociology.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/swedberg-2003-the-changing-picture-of-max-weber-sociologydocx 24/24

306 S WEDBERG

Auf sätze zur Religions-soziologie, /-///.

Tübingen: MohrWeber M. [1922] 1976. Wirtschaft und 

Gesellschaft . Grundr iss der verstehenden 

Soziologie.Tübingen: Mohr. 5th ed. 

Weber M. [1922] 1978. Economy and Society: An 

Outli ne of I nterpretive Sociology , ed. G Roth, C

Wittich. Berkeley: Univ. Calif. Press

Weber M. [1923] 1981. General Economic Hi story. 

New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction

Weber M. [1926] 1975. Max Weber: A Biography. 

New York: Wiley Weber M. 1936. Jugendbriefe. 

Tübingen: Mohr Weber M. 1984. Zur Politik im 

Weltkr ieg. Schri ften und Reden 1914-1918. Max 

Weber Gesamtausgabe 1/15. Tübingen: MohrWeber M. 1988. Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Sozial - 

und Wir tschaftsgeschichte. Tübingen: Mohr 

Weber M. 1990. Br iefe 1906-1908. Max Weber 

Gesamtausgabe I I /5. Tübingen: Mohr

Weber M. 1994. Br iefe 1909-1910. Max Weber 

Gesamtausgabe I I /6. Tübingen: Mohr

Weber M. 1998. Br iefe 1911-1912. Max Weber 

Gesamtausgabe 11/7. Tübingen: Mohr

Weber M. 1999a. Börsenwesen. Schri ften und 

Reden 1893-1898. Max Weber Gesamtausgabe 

1/5. Tübingen: Mohr. 2 Vols. Weber M. 1999b. Max Weber im Kontext.

Gesammelte Schri ft en, Auf sätze und Vorträge. 

Berlin: Karsten Worm, InsoSoft- Ware 

Weber M. 1999c. Wri tings in Economic Sociology, 

ed. R Swedberg. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ.

Press Weber M. 2002. Excerpts from Die Börse.

Max Weber Stud. 2(2):239-41

Whimster S, ed. 1999. Max Weber and the Cultur e 

of Anarchy. New York: St. Martin‟s Press 

Zafirovski M. 2000. Latent theoretical convergence

upon a pluralist conception of action: Adam

Smith and Max Weber. Const. Polit. Econ. 

11:119-45Zafirovski M. 2001a. Exchange, Action and Social 

Structure: Elements of Economic Sociology. 

Westport, CT: Greenwood

Zafirovski M. 2001b. Max Weber‟s analysis of 

marginal utility theory and psychology revisited:

Latent positions in economic sociology and the

sociology of economics. H ist. Polit. Econ. 33:437-

58

This content downloaded on Tue, 22 Jan 2013 05:29:27 AM

All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions 


Recommended