+ All Categories
Home > Documents > The bottom-up beta of momentum - CFA ARX | Asia … bottom-up beta of momentum Pedro Barrosoy First...

The bottom-up beta of momentum - CFA ARX | Asia … bottom-up beta of momentum Pedro Barrosoy First...

Date post: 07-Jun-2018
Category:
Upload: buihanh
View: 214 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
21
The bottom-up beta of momentum Pedro Barroso y First version: September 2012 This version: November 2014 Abstract A direct measure of the cyclicality of momentum at a given point in time, its bottom-up beta with respect to the market, forecasts both the returns and the risk of the strategy. Challenging a potential risk-based explanation, a highly cyclical momentum portfolio forecasts both higher risk and lower returns for the strategy. The results show robustness out-of-sample (OOS) and controlling for other variables. One predictive regression of monthly momentum returns on its bottom-up beta produces an OOS R-square of 2.41%. This contrasts with the usual negative OOS R-squares of similar predictive regressions for the market excess return. I thank Alan Gregory, Miguel Ferreira, Pedro Santa-Clara, and Ronald Masulis for their suggestions. y University of New South Wales, School of Banking and Finance. E-mail: [email protected] 1
Transcript

The bottom-up beta of momentum∗

Pedro Barroso†

First version: September 2012

This version: November 2014

Abstract

A direct measure of the cyclicality of momentum at a given point in time, its

bottom-up beta with respect to the market, forecasts both the returns and the risk

of the strategy. Challenging a potential risk-based explanation, a highly cyclical

momentum portfolio forecasts both higher risk and lower returns for the strategy.

The results show robustness out-of-sample (OOS) and controlling for other variables.

One predictive regression of monthly momentum returns on its bottom-up beta

produces an OOS R-square of 2.41%. This contrasts with the usual negative OOS

R-squares of similar predictive regressions for the market excess return.

∗I thank Alan Gregory, Miguel Ferreira, Pedro Santa-Clara, and Ronald Masulis for their suggestions.†University of New South Wales, School of Banking and Finance. E-mail: [email protected]

1

1 Introduction

Unconditionally, the Fama-French factors do not explain the risk or the returns of mo-

mentum (Fama and French (1996)). But Grundy and Martin (2001) show this is because

momentum portfolios have time-varying systematic risk and this is not captured in un-

conditional regressions.

The beta of the winners-minus-losers portfolio should depend by construction on the

previous returns of the market. For instance, in late 1999, and after good returns in the

stock market, the winners were mostly high beta stocks while the laggards were low beta

stocks. Hence the momentum portfolio, short on previous losers and long on previous

winners, should have a high beta by design. By contrast, at the end of 2008, in an

extreme bear market, previous losers should be typically stocks with high betas such as

financial firms at the time, while the group of winner stocks would have low betas. Thus

the momentum portfolio would have a negative beta by construction.

I compute the bottom-up beta of momentum using monthly returns from January

1950 to December 2012 for all stocks in the Center of Research for Security Prices

(CRSP). The bottom-up betas change quite substantially over time, ranging from a

minimum of -1.71 to a maximum of 2.09 and are positively related to previous returns

in the market.

Bottom-up betas are much better at explaining the risk of momentum than one

unconditional regression. The bottom-up betas with respect to the Fama-French factors

explain 39.59 percent of the out-of-sample variation in momentum returns, nearly 17

times more than one unconditional regression. They also compare favorably to other

methods of estimation of the conditional beta.

On the other hand, it is known that it is not persistence in returns of the Fama-

French factors that explains momentum profits (Grundy and Martin (2001), Blitz, Huij,

and Martens (2011), Chaves (2012)). As such, large loadings of momentum on some

other factors should constitute a warning against the attractiveness of investing in the

strategy.

The expected return of momentum diminishes significantly with the absolute loading

of the strategy on the market. An increase of one standard deviation in the absolute

value of the market beta leads to a 1.18 percentage points decrease in momentum’s

2

monthly expected return. One regression of momentum returns using this predictive

variable holds an out-of-sample (OOS) R-square of 2.41%, a very high value for a monthly

frequency. This contrasts with the predictability of the market, where similar regressions

typically have negative R-squares (Goyal and Welch (2008)). In fact, the predictive

models that show more robustness for the market achieve OOS R-squares of about 1%

for the same frequency, so the predictability of momentum returns is more than double

that of the market.

The absolute loading of momentum on the market also forecasts its risk. One pre-

dictive regression of the realized variance of momentum on the absolute value of its beta

holds an OOS R-square of 8.25 percentage points.

The results of predictive regressions for risk and returns are robust controlling for

other variables found relevant in the literature. In particular, the absolute loading on

the market is not subsumed by the market being in a bear state (Cooper, Gutierrez, and

Hameed (2004)) and the recent volatility of the market (Wang and Xu (2011); and Tang

and Xu (2012)).

One possible use of time-varying betas is to hedge the systematic risk of momentum

(Grundy and Martin (2001); Daniel and Moskowitz (2011); and Martens and Oord

(2014)). I examine the usefulness of bottom-up betas to hedge the risk of momentum in

real time and find that it does not avoid its large drawdowns. The hedged strategy still

has a high excess kurtosis and a pronounced left-skew, so the crash risk is not removed by

hedging. Daniel and Moskowitz (2011) estimate the beta of momentum with a regression

of daily returns and they also find momentum investors could not use time-varying betas

to avoid the crashes in real time. This contrasts with the benefits of using the time-

varying volatility of momentum to manage its risk (Barroso and Santa-Clara (2014)).

2 The time-varying beta of momentum

The momentum portfolio changes its composition as new stocks join the group of pre-

vious losers or the group of previous winners. This changing composition induces time

variation in the beta of the portfolio with respect to the market. I compare three meth-

ods of estimation of these time-varying betas: i) a bottom-up approach; ii) estimating

beta as a linear function of factor returns in the formation period; iii) a high-frequency

3

beta estimated from daily returns.

The bottom-up beta of the momentum portfolio is the weighted average of individual

betas in the portfolio:

βBU,t =

Nt∑i=1

wi,tβ̂i,t (1)

where Nt is the number of stocks in the portfolio at time t, wi,t is the weight of stock

i in the WML portfolio and β̂i,t is the beta of the individual stock estimated from past

monthly returns. This beta relies only on past information, known before time t, so its

forecasts are out-of-sample (OOS) by construction.1

Figure 1 shows the bottom-up beta of the momentum strategy and compares it with

the unconditional beta, obtained from running a regression of the WML on the market

with the full sample.

The unconditional beta is -0.27. So on average the losers portfolio has a higher beta

than the winners portfolio. But this unconditional beta masks substantial time-variation

in the composition of the WML portfolio. The bottom-up beta ranges from -1.71 to 2.09.

Therefore, the momentum strategy is at times highly exposed to the overall stock market,

while at other times it is actually negatively related with the market.

Grundy and Martin (2001) show that the time-varying systematic risk of momentum

is due to the return of the overall market during the formation period. After bear mar-

kets, winners tend to be low-beta stocks while losers are high-beta stocks. By shorting

losers to go long winners, the WML portfolio will have by construction a negative beta.

The opposite happens after bull markets. Figure 2 illustrates this point, confirming the

results of Grundy and Martin (2001) and Korajczyk and Sadka (2004).

The bottom-up beta, obtained from the individual stock level, is approximately a

linear function of market returns during the formation period. Following Grundy and

Martin (2001), I estimate this beta running an OLS regression:

rwml,t = α+ β0rmrft + β1rmrftrmrft−2,t−12 (2)

where rmrft−2,t−12 is the cumulative excess return of the market during the formation

period of the momentum portfolio. Then the time-varying linear beta is:

1 I describe with more detail the method of estimation of the bottom-up betas in the annex.

4

βL,t = β0 + β1rmrft−2,t−12 (3)

Another method to estimate the time-varying beta of momentum is to use the daily

returns of the WML portfolio and those of the market. Following Daniel and Moskowitz

(2011) we regress at the end of each month the daily returns of momentum on the

market in the previous 126 sessions (≈ 6 months).2 As the bottom-up beta, the one-

month lagged high-frequency beta (βHF,t−1) produces an OOS forecast of momentum’s

exposure to the market.

Table 1 presents descriptive statistics for different estimates of beta. The uncondi-

tional beta is the estimate from on OLS regression, which is constant. The first two

rows show the in-sample results for βunc and βL using returns from 1964:02 to 2010:12.3

The third and fourth rows present the OOS results for the same variables. Here I use

the period from 1950:01 to 1964:01 to obtain initial estimates of the betas, producing

an OOS forecast for the following month. Then I re-iterate the procedure every month

till the end of the sample using an expanding window of monthly observations. The

resulting OOS period is from 1964:02 to 2010:12.

The in-sample (out-of-sample) linear beta varies between a minimum of -1.74 (-

1.60) and a maximum of 1.61 (1.46). The high-frequency beta varies even more from

a minimum of -1.94 to a maximum of 2.16. So all estimates show there is substantial

time-variation in the market exposure of the momentum strategy.

A relevant test is whether time-varying betas explain the risk and returns of momen-

tum. For each estimation method I obtain the hedged momentum return as:

zt = rwml,t − β̂trmrft (4)

where β̂t is the conditional beta at time t.

Table 2 shows that time-varying risk does not explain the excess returns of the

momentum strategy. The mean excess return of the market-hedged momentum strategy

ranges from 1.19 percent per month to 1.47 percent per month. All the t-statistics

2They estimate the beta using 10 lags of daily returns to correct for stale quotes. This correctiondoes not improve results in my sample period, so I only repport results from regressions with no lags.

3To facilitate the comparison, the same sample period is examined for all methods. The daily returnsof the Fama-French factors is only available starting in 1963:07. This restricts the comparable sampleperiod to start in 1964:02.

5

exceed four, so they are highly significant. This confirms the results of Grundy and

Martin (2001) and Blitz, Huij, and Martens (2011). Grundy and Martin (2001) show

that time-varying risk does not explain the alpha of momentum. Conversely, Blitz,

Huij, and Martens (2011) and Chaves (2012) show that momentum profits come from

persistence in returns at the individual stock level, rather than in the factors themselves.

As a result, hedging market risk has little effect on the alpha of momentum.

Momentum has more beta risk in ‘good times’(in bull markets) than in ‘bad times’

(in bear markets). The opposite pattern should hold for time-varying beta to explain

momentum average excess returns.

But taking time-varying betas into consideration enhances substantially the under-

standing of momentum’s risk. The R-squared (1 − var(zt)var(rwml,t)

) improves OOS from just

1.93 percent for the unconditional model to values ranging from 15.78 percent to 24.81

percent using the conditional models.4 This is 8 to nearly 13 times more than the uncon-

ditional model. The bottom-up beta performs particularly well OOS, with the highest

R-square among those considered.

3 Exposure to the Fama-French factors

One unconditional OLS regression of monthly momentum returns on the Fama-French

factors from 1964:02 to 2010:12 holds (t-statistics in parenthesis):

rWML,t = 1.71 − 0.34 rRMRF,t − 0.04 rSMB,t − 0.47 rHML,t

(5.70) (−4.91) (−0.42) (−4.51)

The regression has an adjusted R-square of just 5.63 percent and a significant positive

alpha of 1.71 percent, confirming the result in Fama and French (1996) that their factors

do not explain the risk and returns of momentum. Still, this improves substantially the

fit of the CAPM, which has an adjusted R-square of just 2.54 percent for the same period.

This is mainly because momentum is significantly and negatively related to value. Yet,

as for the exposure to the market, these estimates mask substantial time-variation in

risk.4Note that the OOS r-squared can assume negative values. Goyal and Welch (2008) show this is often

the case with predictive regressions.

6

Figure 3 shows the exposure of momentum to the market (RMRF), value (HML),

and size (SMB) factors. Just as for the market, exposure to value and size varies a lot.5

Table 3 shows the descriptive statistics of the bottom-up betas. The exposure of

the momentum portfolio to size and value varies even more than the exposure to the

market. For the HML factor, the beta ranges from -3.06 to 2.61, while for the market it

ranges only from -1.62 to 1.58. The standard deviation of the betas with respect to size

and value are, respectively, 0.82 and 0.83. This is more than the standard deviation of

βrmrf .

Table 4 shows the average excess returns of the hedged portfolio with respect to the

Fama-French factors, its t-statistics and R-square.

As for the CAPM, the conditional models do not explain the mean excess returns

of momentum which have always a positive mean with significant t-statistics ranging

between 3.57 (for the bottom-up beta) and 6.48 (for the beta linear with past returns).

However, the conditional models improve considerably the understanding of the sys-

tematic risk of momentum. In sample, the R-square of the unconditional model is 6.13

percent, which is reduced to only 2.37 percent in the out-of-sample (OOS) test. The

high-frequency beta, used in Daniel and Moskowitz (2011), produces an OOS R-square

of 29 percent. In spite of this large improvement, the high frequency approach underper-

forms other measures of systematic risk. The linear model has an OOS R-square of 37.72

percent. Even more so, bottom-up betas explain 39.59 percent of the systematic risk of

momentum OOS. This is nearly 17 times more than the unconditional model. As for

the CAPM, the bottom-up beta is the best conditional model to explain the systematic

risk of momentum.

4 Predicting the risk and return of momentum

At times, the momentum portfolio is well characterized by a directional exposure on

the persistence of returns for some factor. The bottom-up betas constitute a direct and

real-time measure of this. But the source of momentum returns is more likely to be

persistence in returns at the stock level, not in factor returns. As such, a larger beta (in

absolute value) should forecast a lower return for the momentum portfolio.

5 In unreported results, I find that the betas w.r.t. to each factor are positively related. Yet most oftheir variation is idiosyncratic (more than 90 percent). They do not move in tandem with each other.

7

Table 6 shows the results of variations of a predictive regression for momentum

returns from 1964:02 to 2010:12:

rWML,t = α+ β1|β̂RMRF,t−1|+ β2|β̂SMB,t−1|+ β3|β̂HML,t−1|+ β4Beart−1

+β5RVrmrf,t−1where the first three regressors are the absolute values of the (lagged) bottom-up

betas of momentum w.r.t. the Fama-French factors. The fourth regressor is an indicator

variable that assumes the value of 1 if the cumulative return on the stock market has

been negative in the previous three years, and zero otherwise. The fifth regressor is the

(lagged) realized volatility of the stock market, which is computed from the daily returns

of the market in the previous month.

The first three models in table 6 show, one by one, the significance of each bottom-up

beta. The bottom-up betas of the size and value factors are not significant, but the beta

with respect to the market, with a t-statistic of -3.97, is significant by any conventional

level. This shows that an extreme positive, or negative, loading on the market factor

predicts a lower momentum return. One standard deviation increase in the absolute

value of the market-beta of momentum is associated with a reduction in the month-

ahead expected return of 1.18 percentage points. So this is an economically significant

result.

The last column shows the out-of-sample (OOS) R-square of the regressions. A posi-

tive value indicates that the regression outperformed the historical mean when forecast-

ing the momentum premium. For the size and value betas, the negative OOS R-square

show that the regressions performed worse out-of-sample than the historical mean, what

should be expected since the regressors lack significance even in-sample. But the re-

gression using the beta of momentum w.r.t. the market shows a high and positive

OOS R-square of 2.41 percentage points. This contrasts with the usual negative OOS

R-squares of regressions predicting the equity premium, even when using in-sample sig-

nificant variables (Goyal and Welch (2008)).

In model four, I test the three betas simultaneously. The beta w.r.t. the market

forecasts returns, but not the other betas.

The last two regressors are controls for other variables that have been found to

predict the return of momentum. Cooper, Gutierrez, and Hameed (2004) show that

momentum performs badly after bear markets. Both Wang and Xu (2011) and Tang and

8

Xu (2012) show that momentum has lower returns in volatile markets. Testing all these

simultaneously shows that the market-beta of momentum is significant controlling for the

other variables. This regression is not robust OOS as using too many regressors increases

the chances for in-sample overfitting, even if some predictors are indeed significant.

Daniel and Moskowtiz (2011) find that momentum crashes are due to the option-like

payoffs of the losers portfolios in extreme bear markets. As the bottom-up market beta

of momentum tends to be very negative in those situations, it is pertinent to examine if

my results are not driven by negative betas and momentum crashes alone. To test for

this, the following OLS regression distinguishes between positive and negative bottom-up

betas. It holds (t-statistics in parenthesis):

rWML,t = 2.56 −3.46 β̂+

RMRF,t−1 +4.70 β̂−RMRF,t−1

(6.05) (−2.71) (3.75)

where β̂+

RMRF,t−1 is the value of the beta of momentum w.r.t. the market if positive

and β̂−RMRF,t−1 the same if negative.

The results are stronger for the left tail of the bottom-up beta. A marginal increase

in the negative beta reduces the expected return of momentum more than in a positive

beta. But the predictability is quite significant in the right tail as well. A high positive

beta predicts lower returns for momentum, with a t-statistic of -2.71, the variable is

significant at the 1% level. So the result is not driven by the negative betas, momentum

crashes and option-like payoffs alone.6

As there is a large momentum crash in the sample, I also test for non-linearities in

this relation running a step-wise regression:

rWML,t = 2.64 −5.18 |β̂m−,t−1| −3.17 |β̂m+,t−1|

(6.19) (−4.00) (−2.55)where |β̂m−,t−1| is the absolute value of the bottom-up beta w.r.t. the market if this

value is below the median and |β̂m+,t−1| the same if it is above the median. I find the

results are not totally driven by observations with particularly high absolute values of

beta w.r.t the market. In fact, there is a slightly stronger association for smaller absolute

values of the predictor variable.

Another important issue is whether the bottom-up betas of momentum help predict

its risk. Table 7 presents variations of the predictive regression:

6 In fact, in unreported results, I find there is no supportive evidence that the market-beta of momen-tum forecasts market reversals, which have been interpreted as the cause of momentum crashes.

9

rWML,t = α+ β1|β̂RMRF,t−1|+ β2|β̂SMB,t−1|+ β3|β̂HML,t−1|+ β4Beart−1

+β5RVrmrf,t−1 + β6RVwml,t−1where the dependent variable is the realized variance of momentum, at a monthly

frequency. The regressors are the same as above for predicting returns, except for the

last one which is the lagged value of momentum’s realized variance. Barroso and Santa-

Clara (2014) show the risk of momentum is highly predictable using its own lagged value

as a predictor. As such it is important to control for this variable.

The first three regressions show that the betas w.r.t. the market and value factors

are significant, but the beta of the size factor is not. The regressions that use the value

and market betas are robust, with an OOS R-square as high as 8.25 percentage points for

the market. The fourth regression includes all three variables and confirms this result.

The fifth regression includes the two control variables (the lagged risk of the market

and the state of the market). The bottom-up betas of the market and value factors

remain significant. The last model includes the lagged realized variance of momentum.

This variable with a t-statistic of 21.88 is highly significant and it increases the OOS

R-square from 22.77 percentage points to 53.84 percentage points. The significance of

the bottom-up beta of momentum w.r.t. the market remains significant but the beta

w.r.t. the value factor does not.

In general, the predictability of momentum’s risk is much higher than the predictabil-

ity of its returns. The most relevant predictor is the lagged value of momentum’s risk.

Still, the bottom-up beta of momentum w.r.t the market is significant in every regres-

sion considered and robust OOS. So a highly cyclical (or counter-cyclical) momentum

portfolio predicts a higher risk going forward.

5 Systematic risk and momentum crashes

Grundy and Martin (2001) find that hedging the time-varying risk exposures of mo-

mentum produces stable returns. Daniel and Moskowitz (2011) show that this relies on

using ex post information and that hedging in real time with time-varying betas does

not avoid the momentum crashes. However, their method of estimating the time varying

risk is with top-down regressions of daily data —the high-frequency beta. I find this is

a less satisfactory approach to capture the time-varying systematic risk of momentum

10

(although it still clearly outperforms an unconditional model).

Bottom-up betas provide a superior method to estimate the time-varying exposure

of momentum to other factors. This leads to the question of whether hedging this time-

varying risk with a more suitable method could avoid the large drawdowns of momentum.

Table 5 shows the performance of hedged portfolios using bottom-up betas. Hedging

market risk or the Fama-French factor exposures reduces the excess kurtosis and left-

skewness of returns, without a clear effect on the Sharpe ratio (it improves using the

CAPM but decreases using the Fama-French factors). The reduction in crash risk is

modest though. The hedged strategies have an excess kurtosis exceeding 5 and a left-

skew almost as pronounced as the WML strategy.

Figure 4 shows the cumulative return of the WML and its hedged versions during the

last two years of our sample. This period includes the major momentum crash since the

great depression —March-April 2009. The WML factor accumulated a return of -74.87

percent in the period. The hedged portfolios performed slightly better. The CAPM-

hedged portfolio accumulated a negative return of -66.21 percent and the Fama-French

portfolio -63.66 percent. So hedging with time-varying betas would have a relatively

minor impact during the momentum crash. The crash is still there after hedging. This

confirms the result of Daniel and Moskowitz (2011) that hedging the time-varying betas

does not avoid the crashes in real time.

Other practical considerations should also limit the potential usefulness of the idea

of hedging the risk of momentum. While there are future contracts that could be easily

used to hedge the market-risk of momentum, there are no such obvious analogues for the

size and value factors. Besides, the hedge ratios exhibit substantial time variation and

very high values at particular times. Anderson, Bianchi, and Goldberg (2012) show that

time-varying leverage can seriously dampen the results of a strategy after transaction

costs. So this should be another source of concern for a hedged momentum portfolio.

But to all of these considerations, one can add a very simple fact: the performance of

hedged momentum, even before transaction costs and other practical implementation

issues are taken into account, is not impressive.

11

6 Conclusion

When the previous returns of a factor are high, the momentum portfolio rotates from

low-beta stocks to high-beta stocks on that factor. This changes the betas of momentum

over time.

Conditional betas capture the systematic risk of momentum much better than an

unconditional model. Using the Fama-French factors, the out-of-sample R-square in-

creases from just 2.37 percent for the unconditional model to as much as 39.59 percent

using conditional betas.

The bottom-up betas perform particularly well in capturing time variation in system-

atic risk. They achieve the best results comparing to the linear and the high-frequency

beta, both with the CAPM and the Fama-French factors. Using this method to hedge

the time-varying betas of momentum does not avoid its crashes though or translate into

any significant improvement.

Conventional momentum is a less appealing strategy whenever it relies excessively on

a (positive or negative) loading in the market factor. This forecasts both lower returns

and higher risk for the strategy.

This happens because the stocks in both legs of the portfolio are most likely selected

on the basis of their high exposure to the market in the formation window. The market

may have performed very well, or very badly, in that period but that says very little

about its performance going forward. On the other hand, it does convey important

information about the future performance of momentum.

12

Annex

To estimate the bottom-up betas, I use data from CRSP (Center for Research in Security

Prices) with monthly returns for all stocks listed in the NYSE, AMEX or NASDAQ

from January 1950 to December 2010. Following the standard practice, the momentum

portfolios are sorted according to accumulated returns in the formation period which is

from month t-12 to month t − 2. The stocks are classified into deciles using as cutoff

points the universe of all firms listed on the NYSE. This way there is an equal number

of firms listed in the NYSE in each decile. This is to prevent the possibility of very small

firms dominating either the long or short leg of the portfolio.

In order to be considered in the portfolio a firm’s stock must have a valid return in

month t−2, a valid price in month t−13, and information on the market capitalization of

the firm in the previous month. We take into consideration the delisting return of a stock

whenever it is available. Individual stocks are value-weighted within each decile. The

return of the winner-minus-losers (WML) is simply the return of the top decile portfolio,

sorted on previous momentum, minus the return of the bottom decile portfolio.

I estimate the beta of each individual stock running an OLS regression of its monthly

excess return on the excess return of the market from t − 61 to t − 2, the end of the

formation period. I require at least 24 valid returns in that period to estimate the beta.

The market return is the value-weighted return of all stocks in the CRSP universe, as

obtained from Kenneth French’s online data library.

13

References

[1] Anderson, R., S. Bianchi, and L. Goldberg (2012). “Will My Risk Parity Strategy

Outperform?”, Financial Analysts Journal, 68(6), pp. 75-93.

[2] Barroso, P. and P. Santa-Clara (2014). “Momentum has its moments”, forthcoming

in the Journal of Financial Economics.

[3] Blitz, D., J. Huij, and M. Martens (2011). “Residual momentum”, Journal of Em-

pirical Finance, Vol 18, 3. pp. 506-521.

[4] Chaves, D. (2012). “Eureka! A momentum strategy that also works in Japan”,

working paper.

[5] Cooper, M., R. Gutierrez Jr., and A. Hameed (2004). “Market states and momen-

tum”, The Journal of Finance, 59 (3), pp. 1345-1366.

[6] Daniel, K., and T. Moskowitz (2011).“Momentum crashes”, Working paper.

[7] Fama, E. and K. French (1992). “The cross-section of expected stock returns”, The

Journal of Finance, vol. 47, no. 2, pp. 427-465.

[8] Fama, E. and K. French (1996). “Multifactor explanations of asset pricing anom-

alies”, The Journal of Finance, vol. 51, no. 1, pp. 55-84.

[9] Goyal, A., and I. Welch (2008). “A comprehensive look at the empirical performance

of equity premium prediction”, Review of Financial Studies 21, pp. 1455-1508.

[10] Grundy, B., and J. S. Martin (2001). “Understanding the nature of the risks and

the source of the rewards to momentum investing”, Review of Financial Studies,

14, pp. 29-78.

[11] Jegadeesh, N., and S. Titman (1993). “Returns to buying winners and selling losers:

Implications for stock market effi ciency”, The Journal of Finance, vol. 48, no. 1, pp.

65-91.

[12] Martens, M., and A. Oord (2014). “Hedging the time-varying risk exposures of

momentum returns”, Journal of Empirical Finance, vol. 28, pp. 78-89.

[13] Tang, F., and J. Mu (2012). “Market Volatility and Momentum”, working paper.

14

[14] Wang, K., and W. Xu (2011). “Market Volatility and Momentum”, working paper.

15

Tables and Figures

60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 00 05 10

­1.5

­1

­0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

Market beta of WML portfolioBe

ta o

f WM

L po

rtfol

io

Time

βbu

βunc

Figure 1. Bottom-up and unconditional beta of the WML portfolio. The bottom-upbeta of the WML portfolio is obtained from the previous 5 years of monthly returns ofindividual stocks. Returns from 1955:03 to 2010:12.

16

0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8­2

­1.5

­1

­0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5Market beta of WML and return in the formation period

Beta

 of W

ML 

portf

olio

Gross return on market portfolio from t­12 to t­2

β t

β t = ­2.76 + 2.55 rmrft­2,t­12

Figure 2. The bottom-up beta of the WML portfolio w.r.t. the market and the previousone-year return on the market portfolio. All returns from 1955:03 to 2010:12.

Beta Mean Max Min STD(B)βunc (IS) -0.26 - - -βL (IS) -0.12 1.61 -1.74 0.52βunc -0.08 0.07 -0.24 0.07βL -0.06 1.46 -1.60 0.38βBU -0.05 2.09 -1.71 0.57βHF 0.15 2.16 -1.94 0.62

Table 1. Descriptive statistics of different betas of momentum. The first is the betafrom one unconditional regression of the returns of the WML portfolio on the market.The second is a conditional regression where the beta depends linearly on the previousone-year return of the market. The third and fourth rows present the results for thesesame regressions but out-of-sample. The fifth row shows the results for the bottom-upbeta of momentum w.r.t. the market. The final row shows the results for the high-frequency beta estimated from daily returns of momentum in the previous 6 months.The bottom-up and high-frequency betas are out-of-sample. All betas are from 1964:02to 2010:12. The final column shows the standard deviation of the beta estimate.

17

Beta zt zt/σzt R2

βunc (IS) 1.47 4.95 2.71βL (IS) 1.43 5.36 22.14βunc 1.40 4.70 1.93βL 1.37 5.11 20.39βBU 1.34 5.15 24.81βHF 1.19 4.32 15.78

Table 2. Performance of time-varying betas in explaining the excess returns and riskof the momentum strategy. The first column shows the average return of a hedgedmomentum strategy using the estimated betas as hedge ratios. The second columnshows the t-statistic of the mean return of the hedged momentum strategy. The finalcolumn shows the r-squared of the model for the risk of momentum. The first two rowspresent results for in-sample betas and the others for out-of-sample betas. All hedgedreturns and betas are from 1964:02 to 2010:12.

1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

­1

0

1

Bet

a

Load on Rm­Rf

1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

­1

0

1

2

Bet

a

Load on SMB

1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010

­2

0

2

Bet

a

Load on HML

Figure 3. The loading of the WML on the FF factors using bottom-up betas. Thebottom-up betas are estimated from the betas of individual stocks in the momentumportfolio. The sample period is from 1955:02 to 2010:02.

18

Beta Mean Max Min STD(B)Rm-Rf -0.03 1.58 -1.62 0.40SMB -0.03 2.25 -1.91 0.82HML 0.07 2.61 -3.06 0.83

Table 3. Descriptive statistics of the conditional betas of the WML portfolio (estimatedfrom the bottom-up) for the Fama-French factors. The bottom-up betas are estimatedfrom the betas of individual stocks in the momentum portfolio. All betas are from1955:03 to 2010:12.

Beta zt zt/σzt R2

βunc (IS) 1.71 5.85 6.13βL (IS) 1.48 6.48 42.73βunc 1.65 5.56 2.37βL 1.39 5.85 37.72βBU 0.84 3.57 39.59βHF 1.29 5.1 29.00

Table 4. Performance of time-varying betas with respect to the Fama-French factorsin explaining excess returns and risk of the momentum strategy. The first column showsthe mean return of a hedged momentum strategy, using the given model to estimate thebeta of momentum each moment in time. The second column shows the t-statistic ofthe mean and the third the r-square of the model. The first two rows present results forin-sample betas and the others for out-of-sample betas. All hedged returns and betasare from 1964:02 to 2010:12.

Max Min Mean STD KURT SKEW SharpeWML 25.54 -45.53 16.14 24.65 7.89 -1.52 0.65

Market hedged 23.41 -38.05 15.98 21.33 5.77 -1.22 0.75FF hedged 24.07 -37.12 9.87 19.09 6.81 -1.17 0.52

Table 5. Performance of the hedged portfolios. The hedged portfolios consist in thelong-short momentum portfolio complemented with a loading on the risk factor chosen tooffset the time-varying beta of momentum each point in time. In each case the betas areestimated bottom-up. The results are thus OOS. ’Kurt’stands for excess kurtosis. Themean return, the standard deviation and the Sharpe ratio are all annualized. Returnsfrom 1964:02 to 2010:12.

19

0 5 10 15 20 250.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

1.1

1.2

cum

ulat

ive 

retu

rn

WMLCAPM­hedgedFF­hedged

Figure 4. Momentum crash. The cumulative returns of the WML portfolio (blue), themomentum portfolio hedged for market risk (green) and for the Fama-French factors(red). Returns from 2008:12 to 2010:12.

20

Model Const RMRF SMB HML Bear RVrmrf adj-R2 OOS R2

1 2.55 -4.10 - - - - 2.56 2.41[6.03] [-3.97] - - - - - -

2 1.80 - -0.65 - - - 0.00 -0.15[3.33] - [-0.99] - - - - -

3 1.23 - - 0.20 - - -0.16 -1.02[2.59] - - [0.36] - - - -

4 2.68 -4.26 -0.61 0.50 - - 2.54 1.30[3.73] [-4.07] [-0.94] [0.89] - - - -

5 2.76 -3.79 -0.66 0.59 -0.24 -82.84 2.43 -0.01[3.81] [-3.28] [-1.01] [1.04] [-0.32] [-1.13] - -

Table 6. Predictive regressions of the return of the WML portfolio on the absolutevalue of the bottom up-betas of momentum with respect to the Fama-French factors.In model 5, we include the bear market indicator function and the lagged one-monthrealized variance of the market. The bear market indicator assumes the value of 1 ifthe cumulative return of the market for the previous 3 years is negative. The returnsare from 1964:02 to 2010:12. The coeffi cients are multiplied by 100 for readability. Itst-statistics are in squares brackets. The R-squares are in percentage points. The lastcolumn shows the out-of-sample r-squared, this is computed using an expanding windowof observations after an initial in-sample period of 240 months.

Model Const RMRF SMB HML Bear RVrmrf RVwml adj-R2 OOS R2

1 0.04 1.19 - - - - - 10.32 8.25[0.67] [8.10] - - - - - - -

2 0.50 - -0.16 - - - - 0.31 0.32[6.20] - [-1.66] - - - - - -

3 0.08 - - 0.46 - - - 5.49 5.23[1.16] - - [5.80] - - - - -

4 -0.10 1.08 -0.10 0.36 - - - 13.80 11.44[-0.95] [7.41] [-1.15] [4.66] - - - - -

5 -0.14 0.80 -0.09 0.31 -0.16 88.31 - 25.40 22.77[-1.47] [5.33] [-1.00] [4.17] [-1.62] [9.29] - - -

6 0.06 0.27 -0.05 0.01 -0.08 4.78 73.76 59.85 53.84[0.84] [2.44] [-0.82] [0.22] [-1.08] [0.60] [21.88] - -

Table 7. Predictive regressions of the monthly realized variance of the WML portfolio onthe absolute value of the bottom-up betas of momentum with respect to the Fama-Frenchfactors. In model 5, we include the bear market indicator function, the lagged one-monthrealized variance of the market and the lagged one-month realized variance of momentumitself. The bear market indicator assumes the value of 1 if the cumulative return of themarket for the previous 3 years is negative. The forecasted realized variances are from1964:02 to 2010:12. The coeffi cients are multiplied by 100 for readability, its t-statisticsare in squares brackets. The R-squares are in percentage points. The returns are from1964:02 to 2010:12. The coeffi cients are multiplied by 100 for readability. Its t-statisticsare in squares brackets. The R-squares are in percentage points. The last column showsthe out-of-sample r-squared, this is computed using an expanding window of observationsafter an initial in-sample period of 240 months.

21


Recommended