+ All Categories
Home > Documents > The Dynamics of Adjustable-Rate Subprime...

The Dynamics of Adjustable-Rate Subprime...

Date post: 25-Mar-2018
Category:
Upload: duongnga
View: 218 times
Download: 2 times
Share this document with a friend
44
The Dynamics of Adjustable-Rate Subprime Mortgage Default: A Structural Estimation * Hanming Fang You Suk Kim Wenli Li § May 27, 2015 Abstract One important characteristic of the recent mortgage crisis is the prevalence of subprime mortgages with adjustable interest rates and their high default rates. In this paper, we build and estimate a dynamic structural model of adjustable-rate mortgage defaults using unique mortgage loan level data. The data contain detailed information not only on borrowers’ mortgage payment history and lender responses but also on their broad balance sheet. Our structural estimation suggests that the factors that drive the borrower delinquency and fore- closure differ substantially by the year of loans’ origination. For loans that originated in 2004 and 2005, which precedes the severe downturn of the housing and labor market conditions, the interest rate resets associated with ARMs, as well as the housing and labor market condi- tions do not seem to be important factors for borrowers’ delinquency behavior, though they are important factors that determine whether the borrowers would pay off their loans (i.e., sell their houses or refinance). However, for loans that originated in 2006, interest rate reset, housing price declines and worsening labor market conditions all contributed importantly to their high delinquency rates. Countefactual policy simulations also suggest that mone- tary policies in the most optimistic scenario might have limited effectiveness in reducing the delinquency rates of 2004 and 2005 loans, but could be much more effective for 2006 loans. Interestingly, we found that automatic modification loans in which the monthly payment and principal balance of the loans are automatically reduced when housing prices decline can reduce delinquency and foreclosure rates, and significantly so for 2006 loans, without having much a negative impact on lenders’ expected income. * Preliminary and Incomplete. All comments are welcome. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect those of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia, or the Federal Reserve System. Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania, 3718 Locust Walk, Philadelphia, PA 19104 and the NBER. Email: [email protected] Division of Research and Statistics, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Email: [email protected]. § Department of Research, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. Email: [email protected].
Transcript

The Dynamics of Adjustable-Rate Subprime Mortgage Default:

A Structural Estimation∗

Hanming Fang† You Suk Kim‡ Wenli Li§

May 27, 2015

Abstract

One important characteristic of the recent mortgage crisis is the prevalence of subprime

mortgages with adjustable interest rates and their high default rates. In this paper, we build

and estimate a dynamic structural model of adjustable-rate mortgage defaults using unique

mortgage loan level data. The data contain detailed information not only on borrowers’

mortgage payment history and lender responses but also on their broad balance sheet. Our

structural estimation suggests that the factors that drive the borrower delinquency and fore-

closure differ substantially by the year of loans’ origination. For loans that originated in 2004

and 2005, which precedes the severe downturn of the housing and labor market conditions,

the interest rate resets associated with ARMs, as well as the housing and labor market condi-

tions do not seem to be important factors for borrowers’ delinquency behavior, though they

are important factors that determine whether the borrowers would pay off their loans (i.e.,

sell their houses or refinance). However, for loans that originated in 2006, interest rate reset,

housing price declines and worsening labor market conditions all contributed importantly

to their high delinquency rates. Countefactual policy simulations also suggest that mone-

tary policies in the most optimistic scenario might have limited effectiveness in reducing the

delinquency rates of 2004 and 2005 loans, but could be much more effective for 2006 loans.

Interestingly, we found that automatic modification loans in which the monthly payment

and principal balance of the loans are automatically reduced when housing prices decline can

reduce delinquency and foreclosure rates, and significantly so for 2006 loans, without having

much a negative impact on lenders’ expected income.

∗Preliminary and Incomplete. All comments are welcome. The views expressed are those of the authors anddo not necessarily reflect those of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, the Federal Reserve Bank ofPhiladelphia, or the Federal Reserve System.†Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania, 3718 Locust Walk, Philadelphia, PA 19104 and the

NBER. Email: [email protected]‡Division of Research and Statistics, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Email:

[email protected].§Department of Research, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia. Email: [email protected].

Keywords:Adjustable-Rate Mortgage, Default

JEL Classification Codes: C1, C4, G2

1 Introduction

The collapse of the subprime residential mortgage market played a crucial role in the recent

housing crisis and the subsequent Great Recession.1 At the end of 2007, subprime mortgages

accounted for about 13 percent of total first-lien residential mortgages outstanding but over half

of total house foreclosures. The majority of the subprime mortgages, by number as well as by

value, had adjustable rates and the fraction of the adjustable-rate subprime mortgages in foreclo-

sure at 17 percent was much higher than the fraction of the fixed-rate subprime mortgages at 5

percent (Frame, Lehnert, and Prescott 2008, Table 1). In response to these developments, many

government policies have been designed and carried out that aimed at changing the incentives

of these borrowers to default.2 Few structural models, however, exist that can guide us in these

efforts especially since most of them have had limited success.3

In this paper, we first develop a dynamic structural model to study the various incentives

adjustable-rate subprime borrowers have to default and how these incentives change under differ-

ent policies. Our study focuses on the period between the time when either a mortgage is granted

and the time when the mortgage is repaid (including refinance), or the house is foreclosed, or

the end of the sample period. More specifically, at each period, a borrower decides whether to

repay the loan (and be current) or not repay the loan (and stay in various delinquent status),

taking as given lender’s possible responses which include various loss-mitigation practices such

1There is no standard definition of subprime mortgage loans. Typically, they refer to loans made to borrowerswith poor credit history (e.g., a FICO score below 620) and/or with a high leverage as measured by either thedebt-to-income ratio or the loan-to-value ratio. For the data used in this paper, subprime mortgages are definedas those in private-label mortgage-backed securities marketed as subprime, as in Mayer, Pence, and Sherlund(2009).

2To name a few of such programs, the FHASecure program approved by Congress in September 2007; the HopeNow Alliance program (HOPENOW) created by then-Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson in October 2007; Hopefor Homeowners refinancing program passed by Congress in the spring 2008; Making Home Affordable (MHA)initiative in conjunction with the Home Affordable Modification Program (HAMP) and the Home AffordableRefinance Program (HARP) launched by the Obama administration in March 2009 (HAMP). See Gerardi and Li(2010) for more details.

3Over the first two and a half years, HARP refinancing activity remained subdued relative to model-basedextrapolations from historical experience. From its inception to the end of 2011, 1.1 million mortgages refi-nanced through HARP, compared to the initial announced goal of three to four million mortgages. In De-cember, HARP 2.0 was introduced and HARP refinance volume picked up, reaching 3.2 million by June 2014.http://www.fhfa.gov/AboutUS/Reports/Pages/Refinance-Report-February-2014.aspx. Similarly, HAMP was de-signed to help as many as 4 million borrowers avoid foreclosure by the end of 2012. By February 2010, oneyear into the program, only 168,708 trial plans had been converted into permanent revisions. Through January2012, a population of 621,000 loans had received HAMP modifications. See http://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/economic-policy/Documents/HAMPPrincipalReductionResearchLong070912FINAL.pdf

1

as mortgage modification, liquidation, and waiting (i.e., doing nothing). Relative to the existing

structural models on mortgage defaults which we review below, our theoretical framework has

the two key distinguishing features: first, in our model default is not the terminal event, and

second, besides liquidation we also consider lenders’ various loss mitigation practices such as

loan modification.

We then empirically implement our model using unique mortgage loan level data. Our data

not only contains detailed information on borrowers’ mortgage payment history and lenders’

responses, but also detailed credit bureau information (from TransUnion) about borrowers’

broader balance sheet and income. We are thus one of the first to utilize borrowers’ credit

bureau information to understand their mortgage payment decisions.4 To track movements in

home prices and local employment situation, we further merge our data with zip code level home

price indices and county level unemployment rates.

Three main forces drive adjustable-rate mortgage (ARM) borrowers’ mortgage payment de-

cisions: changes in home equity, changes in income, and changes in monthly mortgage payment.

Borrowers with negative home equity have little financial gains from continuing with their mort-

gage payments especially when they do not expect house prices to recover and when costs

associated with defaults and foreclosures are low. Changes in incomes and expenses including

monthly mortgage payments affect borrowers’ liquidity position. In principal, borrowers can

refinance their mortgages to lower interest rates or sell their houses to improve their liquidity

positions, but these options may not be available in the presence of declining house prices, in-

creasing unemployment rates, rising interest rates, and/or tightened lending standards. As a

result, these constrained borrowers have no choice but to default on their mortgages. To arrive

at the relative importance of these different drivers of default, we analyze our structurally es-

timated model under various counterfactual scenarios. Our structural estimation suggests that

the factors that drive the borrower delinquency and foreclosure differ substantially by the year

of loans’ origination. For loans that originated in 2004 and 2005, which precedes the severe

downturn of the housing and labor market conditions, the interest rate resets associated with

ARMs, as well as the housing and labor market conditions do not seem to be important factors

for borrowers’ delinquency behavior, though they are important factors that determine whether

the borrowers would pay off their loans (i.e., sell their houses or refinance). However, for loans

that originated in 2006, interest rate reset, housing price declines and worsening labor market

conditions all contributed importantly to their high delinquency rates.

Our counterfactual policy simulations suggest that monetary policies in the most optimistic

scenario might have limited effectiveness in reducing the delinquency rates of 2004 and 2005

4Elul, Souleles, Chomsisengphet, Glennon, and Hunt (2010) also use credit bureau information to study mort-gage default decisions in their empirical analysis.

2

loans, but could be much more effective for 2006 loans. Interestingly, we found that automatic

modification loans in which the monthly payment and principal balance of the loans are au-

tomatically reduced when housing prices decline can reduce delinquency and foreclosure rates,

and significantly so for 200 loans, without having much a negative impact on lenders’ expected

income.

There are several structural models on mortgage defaults and foreclosures. None of them,

however, captures lenders’ decisions beyond setting interest rates and liquidation despite the

use of other loss-mitigation tools such as mortgage modification in practice. Furthermore, they

all treat default as a terminal event that leads to liquidation with certainty. We briefly review

several closely related papers. Bajari, Chu, Nekipelov, and Park (2013) is the closest in spirit

and methodology to our paper. Both papers provide and estimate using micro data dynamic

structural models to understand borrowers’ behavior and to conduct policy analyses. There are,

however, key differences in addition to the two mentioned previously. First, we estimate bor-

rowers decisions structurally, i.e., our approach resolves borrowers’ optimal behavior whenever

policy changes. By contrast, Bajari, et al. (2013) can only accommodate policy interventions

that result in state-variable realizations that are actually observed for a subset of borrowers in

the data and does not change the state transition process. In other words, the new optimal

behavior is correctly captured by the estimation decision rules of some of the borrowers in the

data. We view this as a serious limitation of their model. Additionally, they focus on fixed-rate

subprime mortgages which are much less prevalent than the adjustable-rate subprime mortgages.

Our model, by contrast, nest both cases. Finally, we bring in income and credit score from credit

bureau files which afford us additional information not available in the mortgage data.

Campbell and Cocco (2014) study a dynamic model of households’ mortgage decisions in-

corporating labor income, house price, inflation, and interest rate risk to quantify the effects of

adjustable versus fixed mortgage rates, mortgage loan-to-value ratio, and mortgage affordability

measures on mortgage premia and default. Corbae and Quintin (2013) solve an equilibrium

model to evaluate the extent to which low down payments and Interest-Only mortgages were re-

sponsible for the increase in foreclosures in the late 2000s. Garriga and Schlagenhauf (2009) study

the effects of leverage on default using long term mortgage contract. Hatchondo, Martinez, and

Sanchez (2011) investigate the effect of a broader recourse on default rates and welfare. Mitman

(2012) considers the interaction of recourse and bankruptcy on mortgage defaults. Chatterjee

and Eyigungor (2015) analyze default of long-duration collateralized debt. None of these works

make use of mortgage loan level data as in our paper and that of Bajari et al. (2013).

There are several recent empirical papers that adopt regression techniques to study lenders’

loss mitigation practices and the impact of government intervention policies on these prac-

tices. For example, Haughwout, Okah, and Tracy (2010) estimate a competing risk model using

3

modifications of subprime loans originated between December 2004 and March 2009 excluding

capitalization modifications. They find a substantial impact of payment reduction on mortgage

re-default rates. Agarwal, Amromin, Ben-David, Chomsisengphet, and Evanoff (2010) analyze

lenders’ loss mitigation practices including liquidation, repayment plans, loan modification, and

refinance of mortgages originated between October 2007 and May 2009 from OCC-OTS Mort-

gage Metrics data and find a much modest effect of mortgage modification on defaults. In a

subsequent paper, Agarwal, Amromin, Ben-David, Chomsisengphet, Piskorski, and Seru (2012)

study the impact of the 2009 Home Modification Program on lenders’ incentives to renegotiate

mortgages. We innovation over these papers lies in our structural modeling of borrowers’ incen-

tives to default to lenders’ loss-mitigation practices and to policies that affect these practices.

Finally, the paper also adds to the increasing literature on the recent subprime mortgage

crisis, including, among many others, Foote, Gerardi, and Willen (2008), Demyanyk and van

Hemert (2011), Keys, Benjamin, Tanmoy Mukherjee, Amit Seru, and Vikrant Vig (2010), and

Gerardi, Kristopher, Andreas Lehnert, Shane Sherlund, and Paul Willen (2008).

The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we describe the data sets we

use in our empirical analysis and present some summary and descriptive statistics. In Section

3 we present our model of borrowers’ behavior and their interactions with the lenders in a

stochastic environment with shocks to housing prices, unemployment rates, Libor interest rates,

and incomes. In Section 4 we briefly discuss how we solve and estimate our model. In Section

5 we present our estimation results. In Section 6 we describe the goodness-of-fit between the

implications of our model under the estimated parameters and their data analogs. In Section 7

we present results from several counterfactual experiments. In Section 8 we conclude and discuss

avenues for future research.

2 Data

2.1 Data Source

Our data come from three differences sources, the CoreLogic Private Label Securities data –

ABS, the CoreLogic Loan Modification data, and the TransUnion-CoreLogic Credit Match Data.

The CoreLogic ABS data consist of loans originated as subprime and Alt-A loans and represents

about 90 percent of the market. The data include loan level attributes generally required of

issuers of these securities when they originate the loans as well as historical performance, which

are updated monthly. The attributes include borrower characteristics (credit scores, owner

occupancy, documentation type, and loan purpose); collateral characteristics (mortgage loan-to-

value ratio, property type, zip code); and loan characteristics (product type, loan balance, and

loan status).

4

The CoreLogic Loan Modification data contain information on modifications on loans in the

CoreLogic ABS data. The data include detailed information about modification terms including

whether the new loan is of fixed interest rate, the new interest rate, whether some principals

are forgiven, whether the mortgage terms are changed, etc. The merge of the two data sets are

straightforward as each loan is uniquely identified by the same loan id in both data sets.

The TransUnion-CoreLogic Credit Match Data provide consumer credit information from

TransUnion for matched mortgage loans in CoreLogic’s private label securities databases. Tran-

sUnion employs a proprietary match algorithm to link loans from the CoreLogic databases to

borrowers from TransUnion credit repository databases, allowing us to access many borrower

level consumer risk indicator variables, including borrowers’ credit scores, number of credit ac-

counts, credit balances, and delinquency history.

We then merge our data with CoreLogic monthly zip code level house price index based on

repeated sales and county level unemployment rates from the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Thus

our constructed data have several advantages over most of those used in the literature. First,

the match with the mortgage modification data allow us to identify lenders’ actions more closely

and therefore separate delinquent mortgages that are self-cured from delinquent mortgages that

become current after lender modification. Second, the TransUnion data enable us to capture

borrowers’ other liabilities as well as the payment history of these liabilities. This information

is important for borrowers’ mortgage payment decision.

2.2 Data Description

We focus on subprime adjustable-rate mortgage loans originated in the four crisis states,

Arizona, California, Florida, and Nevada, between 2004 and 2007.5 In particular, we take a 1.75

percent random sample of adjustable-rate mortgages with an initial interest rate fixed period

of two or three years and a mortgage maturity of 30 years that are for borrowers’ primary

residence, first lien, and not guaranteed by government agencies such as Fannie Mae, Freddie

Mac, the Federal Housing Administration, and Veterans Administration. We follow these loans

until February 2009 before the first coordinated large-scale government effort to modify mortgage

loans – the“Making Home Affordable”program was unveiled. In total, we have 16,347 mortgages

and 337,811 observations. Of the 16,347 mortgages, 11 percent were originated in Arizona, 55

percent in California, 28 percent in Florida, and 6 percent in Nevada. Not surprisingly, the

largest fraction of the loans were originated in 2005 (43 percent), followed by 2004 (37 percent),

2006 (17 percent), and then 2007 (2 percent).

Table 1 provides summary statistics of the mortgage loans at origination and of the whole

dynamic sample period. The average age of the loan is 16 months in the sample and the median

5The subprime mortgqage market dried up after the mortgage crisis broke out in 2007.

5

Table 1: Summary Statistics.

At Origination Whole Sample Period

Variable Mean Median Std. Dev. Mean Median Std. Dev.

Age of the loan (months) 0 0 0 16 14 11

Share of 2-yr fixed period (%) 81 1 39 76 1 41

Prepayment penalty (%) 0.90 1 0.30 0.92 1 0.27

Interest-only mortgages (%) 40 0 49 44 0 50

Full document at orig. (%) 52 1 50 52 1 50

Purchase loan (%) 43 0 50 48 0 50

Risk score 445 445 155 424 432 178

Inverse-LTV ratio at orig. (%) 79 80 11 81 78 21

Annual income ($1000) 72 67 26 77 76 28

Principal balance ($1000) 259 228 141 260 228 141

Current interest rate (%) 7.13 6.99 1.15 7.35 7.13 1.39

Remaining mortgage terms (months) 360 360 0 345 347 11

Monthly payment ($1000) 1.616 1.429 0.859 1.679 1.475 0.902

30 days delinquent(%) 0 0 0 6.86 0.0 25.37

60 days delinquent(%) 0 0 0 3.10 0.0 17.33

90 days delinquent(%) 0 0 0 1.62 0.0 12.63

120 days delinquent(%) 0 0 0 1.40 0.0 11.73

150 days delinquent(%) 0 0 0 1.25 0.0 11.11

180 days delinquent(%) 0 0 0 1.14 0.0 10.63

180 days more delinquent(%) 0 0 0 3.86 0.0 19.27

House liquidation (%) 0 0 0 0.64 0.0 8.08

Loan modification (%) 0 0 0 0.26 0.0 5.06

Deviation local unemployment rates (%) -1.51 -1.81 1.40

Local house price growth rates (%) -0.32 -0.27 2.15

Number of observations 16,347 337,811

6

is 14 months. At origination, 81 percent of the sample are loans with two-year fixed-rates.

Through the sample period, however, 76 percent of the sample are loans originated with two-

year initial fixed-rate period indicating that more of those loans have terminated. over 90 percent

of the loans have prepayment penalty. About 40 percent of the mortgages at origination are

interest-only mortgages and the fraction becomes slightly higher for the whole sample. About

half of the mortgages have full documentation both at the origination and through the sample

period. While about 43 percent of the mortgages are purchase loans at the origination, the

ratio increases to about 48 percent indicating that purchase loans are less likely to default than

refinance loans. The risk scores are estimated by TransUnion. They range between 150 and

950 with a high score indicating low risk. Consistent with being subprime, mortgage borrowers

in the sample all have relatively low risk scores, averaging about 445 at origination, and the

scores deteriorate somewhat as the loans age suggesting that the relatively less riskier borrowers

may have refinanced their loans and therefore left our sample. Additionally, both the average

and the mean mortgage loan-to-value ratios exceed 100 at origination and they do not change

much as the loans aged.6 The annual household income estimated by TransUnion average about

$72,000 at origination and $77,000 dynamically. The fact that both mean and median income

are higher in the dynamic sample than at origination suggests that mortgage loans from low

income households are terminated earlier in our sample. Loan balances average $259,000 at

origination with a median of $228,000. These numbers are not very different from their dynamic

counterparts suggesting that borrowers do not make much loan payments during our sample

period. The mortgage interest rates average about 7.13 percent at origination with a median of

6.99 percent. Interestingly, dynamically both the mean and median mortgage interest rates are

higher by 20 and 15 basis points, respectively, as many of these adjustable-rate mortgages reset

to higher rates after the initial fixed-rate period expires. Unemployment rates tend to be lower

than their local averages. Local house prices, on the other hand, all depreciate.

The two most striking observations emerge from Table 1. First, some mortgages stayed in

delinquency status for a long time without being liquidated. Particularly, in our sample, close to

7 percent of loans are 30-day delinquent, 3 percent are 60-day delinquent, 2 percent are 90-day

delinquent, etc. What is most surprising is that close to 4 percent of the loans are actually over

half a year delinquent. The house liquidation rate, by contrast, is only 0.64 percent. Second,

about 0.26 percent of all mortgage loans are modified by their lenders. This ratio is obviously

much higher if we consider loans that are delinquent. We elaborate the second observation

regarding lenders’ decisions in more details in the next subsection.

6We report inverse mortgage-loan-to-value ratio in Table 1. The reason is because in our estimation we assumethat house prices follow an AR(1) process with a normal distribution. The mortgage loan-to-value ratio, which isthe inverse of a normal random variable, does not have a mean. See the model section for more details.

7

Loan Status (beginning of the month) At Liquidation (%) At Modification (%)

Current 0.00 17.09

1 months 0.05 18.71

2 months 0.05 10.74

3 months 0.87 8.55

4 months 2.39 6.12

5 months 2.71 7.39

6 months 10.98 4.62

7 months 26.32 4.50

8 months 15.48 5.31

9 months 9.00 4.04

10 months 7.35 2.54

11 months 5.19 1.96

12 months 3.81 1.50

13 months 4.04 0.92

14 months 3.12 1.73

15 months 2.02 1.15

16 months 2.07 0.81

More than 17 months 4.46 2.31

Number of observations 2,177 857

Table 2: Loan Status at the Beginning of the Month when Liquidation or Modification Occurs.

2.3 Lenders’ Choices: Descriptive Statistics

From Table 1 we know that lenders do not always respond to borrowers’ mortgage delin-

quency immediately by liquidating them. We study lenders’ decisions in more details in this

subsection.

We start by presenting the months of delinquency at liquidation and mortgage modification

in Table 2. As can be seen, mortgage liquidation typically occurs when the borrower is between

6 month and 9 month delinquent. While houses with loans less than 3 months delinquent rarely

gets liquidated, many houses are liquidated when the mortgage is over one year delinquent. As a

matter of fact, about 4.46 percent of the loans liquidated is over 17 months delinquent. As a side

note, the average loan age is 27 months at liquidation. About half of the liquidation occurred

in 2008, 30 percent in 2007, and 8 percent in 2006. About 6 percent of the liquidation occurred

in the first two months of 2009.

Turning to loan modifications, they are offered generally to loans already in distress. Nearly

60 percent of the loans are three months or more behind payments at the time of modification.

Close to 9 percent are one year or more behind payments. What is interesting, however, is that

about 17 percent of the loans are modified when they are listed as current at the beginning of

the period. The majority of these loans (55 percent) are originated in 2005 and the rest mostly

in 2006 (37 percent). Furthermore, the majority of the modifications occur within three months

8

Variable Reduction No Change∗ Increase

Monthly payment (percentage) 83.41 7.95 8.64

Average change in monthly payment ($)-542

(443)

1

(19)

287

(1,141)

Balance (percentage) 5.41 30.18 64.40

Average change in balance ($)-34,030

(39,603)

-73

(143)

12,248

(11,993)

Interest rate (percentage) 83.11 16.89 0.00

Average change in interest rate (%)-2.980

(1.415)

0.00

(0.00)n/a

Table 3: Terms of Modification.Notes: No change refers to monthly payment change less than 50andtotalloanbalancechangelessthan500. Stan-dard deviations are in parenthesis.

of interest rate reset. These suggest that servicers are aware that these borrowers will default

imminently without mortgage modification.7

Table 3 presents modification terms. The majority of the modification results in more af-

fordable mortgages as 83 percent of them have a reduction in monthly payments of about $542.

However, about 9 percent of the modifications produce higher payments of about $287 on av-

erage. Capitalization of modification is very common with arrearage added to total principal

balance. Indeed over 64 percent of the modified loans have an increase of principal balance of

$12,248 on average. Only 5 percent of the loans have a principal reduction averaging $34,030.

Nonetheless, more than 83 percent of the modified loans have an annualized interest rate reduc-

tion averaging 2.98 percent, leading to reduced monthly payment. No modified loans experience

any interest rate increase. All of the loans are brought into the current status after modification.

3 The Model

The model describes a borrower’s behavior from the time his mortgage is originated until

period T which we specify later. We do not model lenders’ decision but estimate it parameter-

ically, which borrowers take as given. Time is discrete and finite with each period representing

one month. Let xt denote the state vector in period t, which includes time-invariant borrower

and mortgage characteristics such as information collected at mortgage origination and house

location as well as time-varying characteristics such as a mortgage’s delinquency status, interest

rates, local housing market conditions, local unemployment rates, etc.

7Haughwout (2010) documented similar observations but their sample are different from ours as they includefixed rate mortgages, adjustable-rate mortgages that have more than 3 years of fixed period, and mortgages withmaturity not equal to 30 years (Table 3).

9

3.1 Choice set

In each period t, after information xt is realized, a borrower chooses an action j. He has

three choices: make the monthly mortgage payment, skip the payment, or pay off the mortgage.

The option to pay off the mortgage, however, is only available to borrowers who are current

on mortgage payment.8,9 Moreover, the borrower has different options of making mortgage

payments, depending on the number of late monthly payments denoted by d ≥ 0 he has. If the

borrower is current on his mortgage payment, then he decides whether to make one monthly

payment Pt. If the borrower is one month behind on the payment, then he makes the following

decisions: pay just Pt and stay one-month-delinquent, pay 2Pt to be current again, or do not

pay anything. To generalize, if the borrower has d unpaid monthly payments at the beginning of

time t, he can make the following decisions: pay Pt, 2Pt, · · · , (d+ 1)Pt, or nothing. To simplify

the problem, for d ≥ 2, we assume that if the borrower decides to pay he only has the options

to pay (d − 1)Pt, dPt, or (d + 1)Pt to become two-month delinquent, one-month delinquent, or

current, respectively.10

Formally, a borrower’s choice set with d unpaid payments is denoted by J(d):

J(d) =

{0, 1,paying off}, if d = 0;

{0, 1, 2}, if d = 1;

{0, d− 1, d, d+ 1}, if d ≥ 2,

where the number zero refers to the action of not making any payment. For the remaining

paper, we will sometimes denote the choice set by J(xt) instead of J(d) because xt includes the

loan delinquency status d. We denote the borrower’s chosen number of payments in period t as

nt ∈ J (dt) .

3.2 State Transition

The evolution of the state variables is captured by the transition probability F (xt+1|xt, j),where, as discussed previously, xt represents the state vector, and j represents the borrower’s

action at time t. We now discuss each of the state variables.

8In the data, some borrowers pay off their mortgages even when they are delinquent. Based on our conversationwith CoreLogic, we believe this is mostly because of reporting lag as borrowers typically stop making paymentson their current mortgage during mortgage refinance or house sale.

9In reality, a borrower can pay off the mortgage by refinancing or by selling the house. Our data, unfortunately,do not allow us to make such a distinction.

10It is rare in the data for borrowers to make payments after they are more than 2 months late that would stillleave them 60 days or more delinquent. Additionally, recall that a borrower in our model can still choose not topay and hence be more than 3 months late on his mortgages.

10

Interest Rate, Monthly Payment, Mortgage Balance, and Liquidation A mortgage

contract with adjustable rates specifies the initial interest rate, the length of the period during

which the initial rate is fixed, mortgage maturity, the rate to which the mortgage rate is indexed,

the margin rate, the frequency at which the interest rate is reset, and the cap on interest rate

change in each period, and the mortgage lifetime interest rate cap and floor. Given the data,

we focus on loans that have a two or three years of initial fixed period and 30 years maturity.

Almost all of the loans have a six-month adjustment frequency after the initial fixed period.

In terms of notation, let i0 denote the initial interest rate and let ir denote the new mortgage

interest rate at the r-th reset. For example, i1 denotes the interest rate at the first reset right

after the fixed-rate period. The term margin represents the margin rate. Since most ARM

in our data are indexed to the six-month Libor rate, we use libort to denote the index rate.

The lifetime interest rate floor and cap are represented by lflo and lcap, respectively. The cap

on interest rate change in each period is represented by pcap. For most mortgages, the cap on

interest rate change for the first reset at the end of the initial fixed-rate is different from the

subsequent caps. We, therefore, denote the cap for interest rate change at the first reset by

fcap.11

Combining all the elements, the new interest rate at the r-th reset in period t is calculated

as follows:

ir =

max{ir−1 − fcap, lflo,min{margin+ libort−1, ir−1 + fcap, lcap}}, if r = 1;

max{ir−1 − pcap, lflo,min{margin+ libort−1, ir−1 + pcap, lcap}}, if r > 1.(1)

The first term in Equation (1) is the lowest interest rate the mortgage can have assuming the

periodic interest change takes its maximum allowed value, the second term is the lowest life long

interest rate the mortgage can have, and the third term is the lowest of three rates, Libor rate

plus margin, last period interest rate plus the maximum allowed periodic interest adjustment, life

time mortgage interest rate cap. Note that libort evolves stochastically. The borrower, therefore,

needs to form expectations about future values for Libor in order to predict the interest rate he

will have to pay. The values for the other mortgage parameters {margin, lflo, lcap, fcap, pcap} are

fixed throughout the life of the mortgage.

It follows from Equation (1) that ir ∈ [max{ir−1 − fcap, lflo},min{ir−1 + fcap, lcap}] if r = 1

and that ir ∈ [max{ir−1−pcap, lflo},min{ir−1+pcap, lcap}] if r > 1. In other words, {lflo, lcap, fcap, pcap}put bounds on the volatility of the adjustable mortgage interest rate. Even when libor is very

volatile, the mortgage interest rate may not change significantly if fcap, pcap and lcap − lflo are

low.

11Usually, fcap is larger than pcap. That is, the interest rate change is typically larger at the initial reset thanat subsequent resets.

11

Given the rule that determines the interest rate reset, we now specify the transition of an

ARM interest rate from period t to period t + 1. With a slight abuse of notation, let r(t)

denote the number of resets that occurred up to period t.12 Note that either r(t+ 1) = r(t) or

r(t+ 1) = r(t) + 1. The former is true when both period t and t+ 1 are in between two resets,

and ir(t+1) = ir(t). The latter is true when an interest rate is just reset in period t + 1, and

ir(t+1) = ir(t)+1, where ir(t)+1 is calculated using the formula in (1).

Once the new interest rate is determined, the new monthly payment can be calculated based

on the interest rate and the beginning of the period mortgage balance. Consider a borrower in

period t with remaining mortgage balance balt−1 and interest rate ir(t). The borrower’s mortgage

monthly payment Pt is calculated so that if the borrower makes a fixed payment of Pt until the

360th period, he will pay off the entire mortgage; specifically,

Pt =balt−1

ir(t)12

1− 1(1+

ir(t)12

)360−t+1

, (2)

and the new balance entering period t+ 1 is updated to:

balt = balt−1

1− 1(1 +

ir(t)12

)360−t

. (3)

Remark: Note that the lenders’ decisions affect the transition of borrowers’ state variables, i.e.,

F (xt+1|xt, j) incorporates the lenders’ responses. If the lender chooses to modify the loan,

it will lead to possible changes of the borrower’s loan status, interest rate, monthly payment

and mortgage balance; if the lender chooses to liquidate the house, then the borrower will

be forced to the state of liquidation.

Other State Variables Other state variables include the number of late monthly payments

dt, the Libor rate libort, house price ht, changes in local unemployment rate ∆UNRt, borrower

credit score CSt, and borrower income yt. The evolution of these state variables are as follows:

• Number of late monthly payments: dt+1 = dt − nt + 1, where nt ∈ J (dt) is the

number of monthly payments a borrower makes at time t.

• Libor: We assume that the borrower’s belief regarding the evolution of Libor rates is that

12For example, if the initial fixed-rate is at least as long as t periods, r(t) = 0. If an interest rate is reset forthe second time in period t, r(t) = 2.

12

it follows an AR(1) process in logs

ln(libort+1) = λ0 + λ1 ln(libort) + εlibor,t,

where εlibor,t ∼ N(0, σ2libor) is assumed to be serially independent.

• House price (h): We assume that the borrower’s belief regarding the evolution of housing

prices in each zip code is that it follows an AR(1) process:

ht+1 = λ2 + λ3ht + εh,t,

where εh,t ∼ N(0, σ2h) is assumed to be serially independent.

• Local unemployment rate: We focus on the deviation of the current unemployment

rate in a county from the average of monthly unemployment rates from 2000 to 2009 in the

same county, which we denote by ∆UNR. We assume that the borrower’s belief regarding

the evolution of ∆UNR is that it follows an AR(1) process:

∆UNRt+1 = λ4 + λ5∆UNRt + εunr,t,

where εunr,t ∼ N(0, σ2∆UNR) is assumed to be serially independent.

• Credit score (CS): We assume that the borrower’s belief regarding the evolution of the

log of his credit score is that it follows the following process:

ln (CSt+1) = λ6 + λ7 ln (CSt) + λ81[d = 1] + λ91[d = 2] + λ101[d = 3] + λ111[d ≥ 4] + εcs,t,

where εcs,t ∼ N(0, σ2CS) is assumed to be serially independent.

• Income (Yt): We assume that the borrower’s belief regarding the evolution of his income

is that it follows an AR(1) process:

Yt+1 = λ12 + λ13Yt + εy,t,

where εy,t ∼ N(0, σ2Y ) is assumed to be serially independent.

3.3 Loan Modification and Foreclosure

A lender makes the following decisions each period: foreclose the house, modify the loan, or

wait (i.e., do nothing). As we mentioned in the introduction, in this paper we do not endogenize

these decisions. Rather, we assume that lenders follow decision rules that depend on borrowers’

13

various characteristics and are invariant to policy changes.13 Borrowers take these decision rules

as given. We provide details in the estimation section.

3.4 Payoff Function

We specify a borrower’s current-period payoff from taking action j in period t as

uj(xt) + εjt,

where uj(xt) is a deterministic function of xt and εjt is a choice-specific preference shock. The

vector εt ≡(ε1t, · · · εJ(xt)t

)is drawn from the Type I Extreme Value distribution that is inde-

pendently and identically distributed over time.

When a borrower with d late payments makes n monthly payments, but does not pay off the

mortgage, we assume that the deterministic part of his period-t payoff is:

un(xt) =

{Ptβ1 + (n− 1)Ptβ2 + CStβ3 + Ytβ4 + ∆UNRtβ5 + X0β6 + ξd + ζn if n ≥ 1

ξd if n = 0,

(4)

where Pt denotes the borrower’s monthly payment in period t. The first term Ptβ1 represents

the disutility from one month’s payment. The second term (n − 1)Ptβ2 is the disutility of

n − 1 months’ payment.14 The next term determines the borrower’s ability or willingness to

make a payment. Specifically, CSt is the borrower’s updated current credit score provided

by TransUnion. It captures not only the borrower’s past payment history but also his ability

to obtain future credit. The term Yt represents the borrower’s current income imputed by

TransUnion. We define ∆UNRt = UNRt − UNR, where UNRt and UNR denote the current

and the average unemployment rates in the borrower’s county of residence, respectively.15 While

UNRt captures current local macroeconomic conditions, its average captures unobserved time-

invariant differences in macroeconomic conditions across counties. The term X0 is a collection

of the borrower’s initial characteristics at origination which contains original monthly payment

amount (P0),inverse loan-to-value ratio at origination (ILTV0), the year of loan origination, and

whether the borrower’s income is fully documented. ξd is a dummy variable for the borrower’s

payment status d at the beginning of the period. We assume that ξd = ξd′ for d, d′ ≥ 3. Finally,

ζn is a constant for taking action n. We normalize ζ0 = 0 because only relative utility is identified

13This characterization of lender behavior seems to be consistent with the data. In a companion paper, weendogenize lenders’ decisions and investigate why they did not change much after the government introducedvarious policies to reduce foreclosures and encourage loan modifications.

14We use Ptβ1 + (n− 1)Ptβ2, instead of a single term nPtβ1 to allow for the possibility that paying more thana single monthly payment amount could have a different utility cost than making only one payment.

15The average is taken over the periods of 2000 to 2009.

14

in a discrete choice model.

When a borrower, who is current on the mortgage (d = 0), chooses to pays off the mortgage

(j = payoff), the deterministic part of the flow payoff

upaying off (xt) =T∑

t′=t+1

δt′β7 +PPNtβ8 +CStβ9 +Ytβ10 + ILTVtβ11 + ILTV0β12 + ζpaying off,t,

(5)

Where δ is the discount factor (which we set to be 0.99 in our estimation), PPNt is whether

the borrower has to pay a prepayment penalty if prepaying in period t, ILTVt is the ratio of the

borrower’s current house price to the remaining balance, i.e., the inverse of mortgage loan-to-

value ratio, and ILTV0 is the inverse mortgage loan-to-value ratio at origination.16 We assume

that the model is terminated when the borrower pays off the mortgage.17

If the house is liquidated, then Vt(liquidated) = 0. If the borrower does not pay off the

mortgage by period T , and if the borrower’s house is not liquidated by period T , the borrower

reaches the final period T .18 The model is then terminated, and the borrower receives the

terminal payoff

VT (xT ) =

β13 + β14CST + β15ILTVT , if current at T

0, otherwise.(6)

Remark: In our framework, we assume that the lender can affect a borrower’s flow utility only

if the lender forecloses (or liquidates) the house. If the lender chooses to modify the loan

terms, or wait, we assume that the borrower’s flow utility is affected only to the extent

that the modified loan term affects the borrower’s monthly payment. Of course, dynami-

cally, the lender’s choices affect the borrowers’ ability to stay current in the mortgage and

subsequently the probability of being foreclosed.

3.5 Value Function

The borrower sequentially maximizes the sum of expected discounted flow payoffs in each

period t = 1, ..., T . Let us define σ to be a borrower’s decision rule such that σj(xt, εt) = 1 if

a borrower chooses action j given (xt, εt). Recall F (xt+1|xt, j) denotes a transition probability

16We assume that the house price follows an AR(1) process with the shock drawn from a normal distribution.The inverse of a normal random variable, however, does not have mean. In the analysis, we therefore use theinverse loan-to-value ratio ILTV instead of the mortgage loan-to-value ratio.

17We make this assumption because the mortgage loan exits our data base once the borrower pays off or refinancethe mortgage.

18To simplify the problem, we do not follow mortgages to their actual terminal period, that is, 360 months. Asshown in the data section, most borrowers either pay off their mortgages or become seriously delinquent withinthe first six years after mortgage origination.

15

function of state variables which depends on the current state xt and an endogenous choice j.

We can then express the borrower’s problem recursively as follows:

V (xt;σ) = Eεt

∑j∈J(xt)

σj(xt, εt)

{uj(xt) + εjt + δ

∫xt+1∈Xt

V (xt+1;σ)dF (xt+1|xt, j)

} . (7)

The borrower’s optimal decision rule σ∗ is such that V (xt;σ∗b) ≥ V (xt;σ) for any possible decision

rule σ in all xt (t = 1, · · · , T ).

4 Estimation

We define the choice-specific value function for action j in period t, vj(xt) as

vj(xt) = uj(xt) + δ

∫xt+1∈Xt

V (xt+1;σ∗)dF (xt+1|xt, j). (8)

The value function can then be written as:

V (xt;σ∗) = Eεt

∑j∈J(xt)

σ∗j (xt, εt) {vj(xt) + εjt}

. (9)

In order to solve for the optimal decision rule σ∗, we use backward induction following the

standard methods on dynamic discrete choice model with a finite number of period (see, for

example, Rust (1987, 1994a, 1994b) and Keane and Wolpin, 1993). We start from period T − 1.

The choice-specific value function in period T − 1 is given by:

vj(xT−1) = uj(xT−1) + δ

∫xT∈XT

V (xT )dF (xT |xT−1, j). (10)

Note that the value function for period T , V (xT ), does not depend on σ∗; the optimal decision

rule in period T − 1 is then that:

σ∗j (xT−1, εT−1) = 1 iff vj(xT−1) + εj,T−1 ≥ maxj′∈J

{vj′(xT−1) + εj′,T−1

}. (11)

Given the functional form assumption for εT−1, we can show, following Rust (1987), that

V (xT−1;σ∗) = ln

∑j′∈J

exp(vj′(xT−1))

+ γ (12)

where γ is the Euler constant.

16

Now let us consider the borrower’s optimal decision rule in period T−2. In order to calculate

vj(xT−2), we need to know∫xT−1∈Xt

V (xT−1;σ∗)dF (xT−1|xT−2, j), which can be calculated using

equation (12). We then derive σ∗j (xT−2, εT−2) and V (xT−2;σ∗) similarly as we did in period

T − 1. We repeat this process until we reach the initial period. In general, the borrower’s

optimal decision rule in period t is:

σ∗j (xt, εt) = 1 if vj(xt) + εjt ≥ maxj′∈J

{vj′(xt) + εj′t

}, (13)

and

V (xt;σ∗) = log

∑j′∈J

exp(vj′(xt))

+ γ. (14)

Moreover, a borrower’s conditional choice probability for alternative j ∈ J (xt) is given by:

pj(xt;σ∗) ≡ Eεt [σ∗j (xt, εt)] =

exp(vj(xt))∑j′∈J exp(vj′(xt))

. (15)

We estimate the model using maximum likelihood. In the data, we observe a path of states

and choices for each individual i: (xi,ai) ≡ {(xit,ait)}Tt=1, where ait ≡ {aijt}j∈J(xit), and aijt is

defined to be a dummy variable equals to one when individual i chose action j in period t. The

likelihood of observing (xi,ai) given initial state xi1 and parameter θ for individual i is:

L(xi,ai|xi1; θ) =

T∏t=1

l(ait, xi,t+1|xit; θ), (16)

where l(ait, xi,t+1|xit; θ) is the likelihood of observing (ait, xi,t+1) given state xit and parameter

θ:

l(ait, xi,t+1|xit; θ) =∏

j∈J(xit)

[pj(xt; θ)f(xi,t+1|xit, j)]aijt . (17)

Parameter estimate θ∗ maximizes the log-likelihood for the whole sample, i.e,

θ∗ = arg max lnL(θ) =

I∑i=1

ln (L(xi,ai|xi1; θ))

=I∑i=1

T∑t=1

∑j∈J(xit)

aijt [ln (pj(xt; θ)) + ln f(xi,t+1|xt, j)] .

17

5 Estimation Results

5.1 Lenders’ Decisions

As previously discussed, we estimate lenders’ policy functions parametrically using Logit or

multinomial logit regressions. In any period t, we assume that the timing of interaction between

the borrower and the lender is as follows. The borrower enters period t with a delinquent status

dt, makes the payment decision at, after which the lender makes the decisions regarding whether

to modify, liquidate, or do nothing about the loan based on the delinquent status of the loan at

the end of the period t. However, in the data we only observe the loan status at the beginning

of the period. Thus when we observe that a loan was current in period t and was also modified

in period t, we assume that the loan would have been one month late at the end of period t had

the modification not taken place.

Specifically, we estimate the lenders’ decisions separately for four categories of loans:

Category 1: (dt = 0, at = 0) . Borrowers who are current in the beginning of the period, but

do not make a payment in the period;

Category 2: (dt = 1, at = 0) . Borrowers who are one month delinquent in the beginning of the

period, but do not make a payment in the period;

Category 3: (dt = 2, at = 0) . Borrowers who are two month delinquent in the beginning of the

period, but do not make a payment in the period;

Category 4: (dt ≥ 3, at = 0) . Borrowers who are three-or-more-month delinquent at the be-

ginning of a period, but do not make a payment in the period.

It is important to note that lenders only modify or liquidate a loan if the borrower does not

make any payment in the period. Therefore, if a borrower who enters the period with loan status

dt ≥ 1, and if he makes at ≥ 1 payment, the lender’s only choice is waiting even though the

status of the loan at the end of the period is still one or more month delinquent (i.e. at < dt+1).

In our specification of the lenders’ decisions, we note that lenders never liquidate a house

whose mortgage is less than three months delinquent. Thus we assume that for loans in cate-

gories 1 to 3, the lenders choose only between modification and waiting ; and the probability of

modification is specified as a logit function of the state variables that includes borrower char-

acteristics and loan status. For loans in category 4, we assume that lenders decides among

three options: modification, liquidation, and waiting. We specify a multinomial logit function to

represent the lenders’ probabilities of choosing the three alternatives. The estimation results for

lenders’ decisions are reported in Appendix Tables A1 and A2. For all regressions, the default

18

state of the loan is Nevada and the default year of the loan is 2006. In all regressions, the default

lender decision is waiting.

Category 1 Loans. For category 1 loans, lenders are more likely to modify if the borrower

has a high credit score, high loan-to-value ratio, high monthly payment but low initial monthly

payment, and full documentation. The loan is also more likely to be modified if it is still

within the initial fixed period though the probability of modification decreases with the number

of months left in the fixed-rate period. An older loan is slightly less likely to be modified.

Compared to loans made in 2006, loans originated in 2004 or 2005 are much less likely to be

modified perhaps reflecting the quality of those loans as they were made during the peak of the

housing boom and borrowers were of less quality. However, loans originated in 2004 and 2005

are more likely to be modified as they age than those originated in 2006. Higher than historical

local average unemployment rates reduce lenders’ incentive to modify.

Category 2 Loans. For category 2 loans, the factors that explain modification probability

are similar to those that are current at the beginning of the period with a few exceptions. Older

loans now are more likely to be modified. There are no longer cohort effects, but geographic

pattern appears. Loans in California and Florida are more likely modified than loans in Nevada.

Category 3 Loans. For category 3 loans, a borrower is more likely to receive modification

if he has high a credit score, low income, low initial loan-to-value ratio, still in the initial fixed

period, and with full documentation. Loans originated in 2005 are less likely to be modified

though are more likely to be modified as they age.

Category 4 Loans. For category 4 loans, we include many more explanatory variables to our

multinomial logit regressions. A loan is more likely modified if income is low, initial loan-to-value

ratio is high, local unemployment rate goes up, the borrower has more missed payments, and

the loan is relatively seasoned with full documentation. As in the previous cases, loans made in

2004 and 2005 are less likely modified. Loans in California and Florida are more likely modified.

Furthermore, most loans are modified when they are 9 or 10 months delinquent.

In terms of liquidation, interestingly, a high credit score and high income make borrow-

ers marginally more likely to be liquidated. Lower current mortgage loan-to-value ratio but

higher initial loan-to-value ratio increase the liquidation probability. Loans that are still in the

interest-only period and loans made in 2004 are also more likely liquidated. Full documentation

marginally reduces liquidation probability. Arizona is more likely to liquidate than Nevada but

Florida less likely. The more missed payments, especially when mortgage loan-to-value is high,

19

the more likely the loan will be liquidated. However, the effect is weaker when local unemploy-

ment rates also go up. Finally, the most liquidation occurs when the loan misses 8 or 9 months

of payment.

Remark. Note that in the data section we documented that the most popular modification is

recapitalization coupled with interest rate reset. After modification, borrowers’ payment

status is brought to current. For simplification, we assume in our analysis that the new

reset interest rate is the initial teaser interest rate during the fixed-interest period of ARM.

We also assume that the modified loan is a fixed rate mortgage with the maturity equal to

the remainder of the initial loan. This simplification allows us to avoid having to estimate

a separate lender decision rule on the new reset interest rate upon modification.19

5.2 Estimates of the Stochastic Processes

In Section 3.2, we also described that borrowers and lenders have beliefs about some stochas-

tic processes such as the evolution of Libor rates, the local housing prices, local unemployment

rates, income and credit scores. We assume that the borrowers have rational expectations about

these processes and estimate them using the ex post realizations of these processes. The es-

timates for these stochastic processes are reported in Table 4. Note that the processes of log

credit score is endogenous for the borrower because its evolution depend on the payment status

on mortgage loans, whose evolution depends on the borrower’s payment decisions.

Table 4 shows that all the variables depend strongly on their lagged values, i.e., they ex-

hibit strong persistence. For credit scores, missing mortgage payments also impact significantly

negatively on their values.

5.3 Borrowers’ Payoff Function Parameters

Table 5 presents the coefficient estimates in the three payoff functions associated with the

three payment decisions. From Panel A, we see that a borrower derives negative utilities from

high mortgage payments, and more so if he makes more than one payment in a given month.

Additionally, he is more likely to make payments when his credit score is high but less likely to

make payments when the local unemployment rate is high as his payment ability is positively

correlated with his credit score but negatively correlated with the local unemployment rate.

Interestingly, the higher the current income, the less likely the borrower will make the mortgage

payment. This counter intuitive result may stem from the imprecise nature of the income

estimate by TransUnion. In terms of conditions at origination, a borrower’s payment ability

19In the data, the mean differnce between the new interest rate upon modification and the initial teaser rate is16 basis points and the median is 37 basis points. Therefore this assumption is a rough approximation.

20

Coefficient Estimate Standard Errors

Panel A: Libor ln (libort+1) = λ0+λ1 ln (libort) + εlibor,tλ0 -0.013 0.010

λ1 0.996*** 0.009

σlibor 0.09656*** 0.00106

Panel B: House Price ht+1= λ2+λ3ht+εh,tλ2 0.671*** 0.010

λ3 0.997*** 0.000

σh 2.5419*** 0.00979

Panel C: Local Unemp. Rates ∆UNRt+1= λ4+λ5∆UNRt+εunr,tλ4 0.049*** 0.007

λ5 0.959*** 0.003

σunr 0.90066*** 0.00979

Panel D: Income Yt+1= λ12+λ13Yt+εy,tλ12 0.045*** 0.000

λ13 0.945*** 0.001

σY 0.09421*** 2.24e-05

Panel E: Credit Score:ln (CSt+1) = λ6+λ7 ln (CSt) + λ81[d = 1]

+λ91[d = 2] + λ101[d = 3] + λ111[d ≥ 4] + εcs,tλ6 0.149*** 0.001

λ7 0.897*** 0.001

λ8 -0.072*** 0.001

λ9 -0.164*** 0.002

λ10 -0.130*** 0.002

λ11 -0.007*** 0.000

σCS 0.17719*** 7.93e-05

Table 4: Coefficient Estimates for Stochastic Processes

21

Coefficient Estimate Std. Err.

Panel A: Coefficients in un(xt) as specified in (4)

Pt : (β1) -0.1660*** (0.0055)

(n− 1)Pt : (β2) -0.0079** (0.0032)

CSt : (β3) 0.0734*** (0.0068)

Yt : (β4) -0.0735*** (0.0087)

∆UNRt : (β5) -0.0117*** (0.0011)

P0 : (β6,1) -0.1643*** (0.0069)

ILTV0 : (β6,2) 0.0313*** (0.0058)

Full Doc: (β6,3) 0.0039*** (0.0015)

Orig 2004: (β6,4) -0.0000 (0.0025)

Orig 2005: (β6,5) 0.0057** (0.0024)

Constant: (ξ0) -0.8999*** (0.0350)

Constant: (ξ1) -1.6613*** (0.0344)

Constant: (ξ2) -1.7183*** (0.0375)

Constant: (ξ3) 4.9652*** (0.2631)

Constant: (ξ4+) -0.0648*** (0.0093)

Constant: (ζ1) 0.5480*** (0.0382)

Constant: (ζ2) -1.4588*** (0.0688)

Constant: (ζ3) -1.7841*** (0.1051)

Constant: (ζ4+) -8.1837*** (0.2547)

Panel B: Coefficients in upaying off (xt) as specified in (5)∑Tt′=t+1 δ

t′ : (β7) 0.0065 (0.0043)

PPN t: (β8) -0.6362*** (0.0782)

CSt: (β9) 0.5488*** (0.0138)

Yt: (β10) -1.1399*** (0.1064)

ILTV t: (β11) 8.6215*** (0.1689)

ILTV 0: (β12) -5.8382*** (0.2902)

ζpaying off -1.0310*** (0.4299)

Panel C: Coefficients in VT (xT ) as specified in (6)

Constant (β13) -16.3973 (18.009)

CSt (β14) 0.9895 (1.0759)

ILTV T (β15) 10.4758 (8.8002)

Table 5: Coefficient Estimates for Borrowers’ Payoff Functions

22

0.2

.4.6

.81

0 5 10Number of Late Monthly Payments

Data Model

Probability of Missing Payments

Figure 1: By Beginning-of-Period Delinquency Status

is greatly reduced by the amount of the payment. High house value relative to mortgages (or

low mortgage loan-to-value ratio) and full document increase the propensity to make payments.

There is no strong cohort effect. Finally, turning to the constants associated with each payment

status at the beginning of the period captured by ξ0 to ξ4+, the model requires a very high value

associated with 3 months delinquent in order to explain the payment rate for such borrowers.

For constants associated with payment decisions, the high disutility the borrower suffers from

making large number of payments indicates their reluctance or inability to do so.

From Panel B, we see that the borrower’s repayment decisions are positively correlated with

the tenure left with the mortgage contract, but negatively correlated with prepayment penalty.

A borrower with higher current credit score, high current house value relative to mortgage, but

low house value relative to mortgage at origination is more likely to payoff his mortgage. As

before, the estimated income generates a counter-intuitive sign.

Finally, from Panel C, we see that at the terminal period T , as expected a borrower’s con-

tinuing payoff is positively correlated with the updated credit score and the current house value-

to-mortgage ratio.

6 Model Fit

In order to gauge the fit of our model, we present figures that compare the model’s predictions

for the distributions of endogenous variables with empirical analogs in the data.

Figure 1 compares the probability of missing payment conditional the delinquency status at

the beginning of the period in the data and that predicted by our estimated model. Note that a

borrower cannot prepay the mortgage or sell the house when he is behind in mortgage payment.

The model does an excellent job in capturing the patterns in the data. The more payments a

borrower misses, the more likely that he will miss payments again. More important, once the

23

0.1

.2.3

.4.5

0 10 20 30 40 50Loan Age (Months)

Data Model

Probability of Missing Payments

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8

0 10 20 30 40 50Loan Age (Months)

Data Model

Probability of Prepayment

Figure 2: By Loan Age

.1.2

.3.4

.5.6

1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5Ratio of Current Payment to Initial Payment

Data Model

Probability of Missing Payments

.02

.04

.06

.08

.1

1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5Ratio of Current Payment to Initial Payment

Data Model

Probability of Prepayment

Figure 3: By Relative Monthly Payment

borrower is three months or more behind his payment schedule, he will stay delinquent with

almost certainty.

Figure 2 compares the probability of missing payments and the probability of prepayment

by loan age in the data and those predicted by our model. Note that while we capture the

probably of default by loan age well, the match with the probability of prepayment is less so

partly because the data is more volatile. Both curves are hump shaped with the probability of

default or staying default peaking at age 36 months, roughly one-year after the majority of the

loans have existed their fixed-teaser-rate period. The peak of prepayment, by contrast, occurs

at 24 months, the time when the majority of the loans’ fixed-rate period expires.

Figure 3 charts the probability of default and prepayment by the ratio of current monthly

mortgage payment to initial monthly payment. The fits are reasonably good for both charts.

Interestingly, there is a large jump of about 50 percentage points in default probability when the

current payment exceeds the initial payment, consistently with the observations we documented

24

.1.2

.3.4

.5.6

40 60 80 100 120Loan to Value Ratio

Data Model

Probability of Missing Payments

0.0

2.0

4.0

6.0

8

40 60 80 100 120Loan to Value Ratio

Data Model

Probability of Prepayment

Figure 4: By Mortgage Loan-to-Value Ratio

0.2

.4.6

2 4 6 8Updated Credit Score (from TransUnion)

Data Model

Probability of Missing Payments

.03

5.0

4.0

45

.05

2 4 6 8Updated Credit Score (from TransUnion)

Data Model

Probability of Prepayment

Figure 5: By Credit Score

earlier that a borrower has a higher probability of default shortly after his mortgage payment

resets to a higher value. After that, the probability of default declines somewhat and then hovers

at around 50 percent. The prepayment probability, on the other hand, increases consistently

with the increase in the current mortgage payment relative to the initial mortgage payment.

Figure 4 depicts the default probability and the prepayment probability by the current

mortgage loan-to-value ratio. The model does a good job at capturing both series. As expected,

the large the mortgage loan-to-value ratio is, the more likely the borrower will default and less

likely he will prepay or make a payment at all.

Finally, Figure 5 charts the default probability and the prepayment probability by credit

scores. The model captures the default probability better than it captures the prepayment

probability. Note that credit scores capture the borrower’s past payment history as well as future

payment ability. Not surprisingly, the higher the credit score is, the less likely the borrower will

default or prepay. In other words, a borrower with a high credit score will make his mortgage

25

payments on time.

7 Counterfactual Simulations

In this section, we report counterfactual simulation results that are aimed to address two

sets of questions. The first set of simulations are aimed at a quantitative understanding of the

roles of different factors that contributed to the subprime borrowers’ default and prepayment

behavior during the housing crisis. The second set of simulations are aimed at the policies,

particularly monetary policy, that may help reduce defaults.

It is useful to start out with some basic facts about the changes in monthly payments, housing

prices and unemployment rates that the ARM borrowers in our dataset face as their loans age.

In Figure 6, we show the average monthly payment amounts as loans age, for 2/28 (2 years

fixed rate, 28 years adjustable rate) and 3/27 (3 years fixed rate, 27 years adjustable rate) ARM

mortgages. It shows that upon the end of the initial lower teaser rate period, borrowers’ monthly

payment would typically increase substantially for loans that originated in 2004 and 2005, in

contrast, it will decrease substantially for loans that originated in 2006.

In Figure 7, we plot the percentage changes of local housing prices and local unemployment

rates at the loans age for loans originated in 2004, 2005 and 2006 respectively. It shows that

for loans that originated in 2004, the local housing prices experienced on average more than

30% gains before it declined at around these loans reached about 24 months of loan age; for

loans that originated in 2005, there was also a modest (about 10%) and short-lived hosing price

gains up to loan age of 12 months before the housing market crash. In contrast, the loans that

originated in 2006 seemed to immediately experience housing price declines as deep as close to

45%. Similarly, the experience of the loans in terms of labor market conditions as measured by

local unemployment rates also differs substantially by loan origination years. The differences by

loan origination year on these dimensions explain why the effects of a variety of counterfactual

changes differ by loan origination years we discuss below.

7.1 Understanding the Factors for Defaults and Prepayments

Adjustable-Rate Mortgages. An amount of the mortgage payment in an ARM is fixed for

a few years initially and then resets every six month. The initial fixed rate is typically lower

than typical mortgage payments after an interest rate starts to reset. Because of an increase

in mortgage payments upon the reset, many commentators believed that the massive amount

of default by subprime mortgage borrowers in the recent financial crisis was attributable to the

reset of ARM interest rates. To quantify how much the initial reset of ARMs contributed to

the subprime borrower’s default and prepayment rates observed in the data, we simulate the

26

Figure 6: Current Monthly Payment Transition by Loan Age and ARM Type

27

Figure 7: Housing Price and Unemployment Rate Trends, by Year of Origination of Loans

28

model under the situation that an interest rate is fixed at the initial fixed rate. In other words,

a mortgage becomes equivalent to a fixed-rate mortgage with an interest rate fixed at the initial

teaser rate.

In Table 6 we report the model’s predictions regarding the fraction of loans in different

status (current, delinquent, foreclosure, or paid off) at different loan ages, for loans originated in

2004, 2005 and 2006 respectively. The panel labeled “Baseline” is the model’s prediction of the

loan status under the actual loan, and the panel labeled “Fixed Rate Mortgage” is the model’s

prediction of the loan status if all of the ARMs were replaced by FRMs with interest rate fixed

at the initial teaser rate of the ARM.

Comparing the two panels, we see that the effect of switching the ARMs to FRMs on loan

status depend on the year in which the loans were originated. For those loans that originated in

2004, it seems that the interest rate resets of the ARMs had very little impact on the fractions of

loans that end up in delinquency or foreclosure status. However, interest rate resets significantly

increased the fraction of loans that would be paid off, and reduced the fraction of loans that

would stay current: 48 months after originating in 2004, the fraction of loans that would stay

current in the baseline is 1.8% in the baseline, in contrast to 8.2% under the fixed rate mortgage

counterfactual, while those paid off would be 88% in the baseline, in contrast to 81.6% in the

counterfactual.

For those loans that originated in 2005, the ARM interest rate resets seem to be a much

more important factor for delinquency and foreclosure. At 48-month age, a total 29.2% (20.3%,

respectively) of loans originated in 2005 would be in delinquency (in foreclosure respectively)

under the baseline, while under the fixed rate mortgage counterfactual, 27% (respectively 17.2%)

of the loans would be in delinquency (respectively, in foreclosure). As for loans originated in 2004,

the fraction of current loans would also be significantly higher under the fixed rate mortgage

than under the baseline, and the fraction of loans that are paid off would be smaller under the

FRM than under the baseline.

For those loans that originated in 2006, the interest rate reset seems to have little effect on

the fraction of loans that would be paid off; instead, it has significant effects on the fraction of

loans that are either current or in delinquency (including those in foreclosure). At 48 months,

the fraction of loans in delinquency (respectively, in foreclosure) would be 63% (respectively,

39.7%) under the baseline, much higher than 54.4% and 34.4% respectively predicted under the

FRM. The fraction of loans that stay current at 48 months is 14.6% under FRM, in contrast to

4.6% under the ARM baseline.

The difference in the effect of FRM by the year of the loan origination suggests that the

interaction between the housing market condition at the time loans were originated and whether

the loans are ARM or FRM may be important. We examine these interactions below.

29

Table

6:F

ixed

-rat

eM

ortg

ages

and

Lif

etim

efloor

rate

s

Base

lin

eF

ixed

Rate

Mort

gages

Lif

etim

efl

oor

Loan

Age

Yea

rO

rig

%C

urr

ent

%D

elin

q%

Forc

l%

Paid

off

%C

urr

ent

%D

elin

q%

Forc

l%

Paid

off

%C

urr

ent

%D

elin

q%

Forc

l%

Paid

off

18

2004

0.4

46

0.0

76

0.0

31

0.5

08

0.4

98

0.0

70

0.0

31

0.4

64

0.5

01

0.0

69

0.0

31

0.4

57

24

2004

0.3

02

0.0

78

0.0

45

0.6

75

0.3

54

0.0

76

0.0

45

0.5

90

0.3

62

0.0

76

0.0

45

0.5

83

30

2004

0.1

16

0.0

97

0.0

60

0.8

03

0.2

55

0.0

89

0.0

57

0.6

71

0.2

41

0.0

89

0.0

57

0.6

87

36

2004

0.0

64

0.1

01

0.0

74

0.8

45

0.1

78

0.0

99

0.0

69

0.7

36

0.1

60

0.1

02

0.0

67

0.7

47

42

2004

0.0

32

0.1

04

0.0

84

0.8

68

0.1

20

0.1

06

0.0

79

0.7

82

0.1

06

0.1

08

0.0

77

0.7

95

48

2004

0.0

18

0.1

04

0.0

89

0.8

80

0.0

82

0.1

07

0.0

88

0.8

16

0.0

72

0.1

06

0.0

84

0.8

28

18

2005

0.5

05

0.1

13

0.0

37

0.4

08

0.5

82

0.1

00

0.0

31

0.3

37

0.5

84

0.0

96

0.0

31

0.3

39

24

2005

0.3

59

0.1

55

0.0

65

0.5

24

0.4

61

0.1

39

0.0

56

0.4

16

0.4

71

0.1

29

0.0

52

0.4

18

30

2005

0.1

73

0.2

31

0.1

04

0.6

11

0.3

48

0.1

84

0.0

89

0.4

80

0.3

25

0.1

87

0.0

83

0.5

02

36

2005

0.1

10

0.2

63

0.1

50

0.6

40

0.2

61

0.2

24

0.1

21

0.5

27

0.2

29

0.2

30

0.1

22

0.5

55

42

2005

0.0

67

0.2

82

0.1

81

0.6

59

0.1

98

0.2

50

0.1

49

0.5

62

0.1

64

0.2

55

0.1

55

0.5

93

48

2005

0.0

38

0.2

92

0.2

03

0.6

75

0.1

46

0.2

70

0.1

72

0.5

96

0.1

15

0.2

73

0.1

81

0.6

17

18

2006

0.5

25

0.2

47

0.0

57

0.2

43

0.5

83

0.2

10

0.0

51

0.2

21

0.5

67

0.2

09

0.0

55

0.2

38

24

2006

0.3

77

0.3

62

0.1

20

0.2

91

0.4

56

0.3

09

0.0

99

0.2

48

0.4

51

0.2

96

0.1

04

0.2

68

30

2006

0.2

34

0.4

68

0.1

92

0.3

15

0.3

36

0.3

98

0.1

62

0.2

76

0.3

40

0.3

81

0.1

58

0.2

96

36

2006

0.1

48

0.5

43

0.2

69

0.3

22

0.2

58

0.4

61

0.2

26

0.2

96

0.2

58

0.4

43

0.2

12

0.3

11

42

2006

0.0

79

0.6

04

0.3

39

0.3

30

0.1

91

0.5

09

0.2

91

0.3

11

0.2

03

0.4

83

0.2

71

0.3

26

48

2006

0.0

46

0.6

30

0.3

97

0.3

33

0.1

46

0.5

44

0.3

44

0.3

22

0.1

61

0.5

09

0.3

17

0.3

40

30

Housing Price Declines. Many researchers investigated importance of a negative house eq-

uity in a borrower’s default decision and found that a negative equity is one of the most impor-

tance forces leading to default (references?) In Table 7, we report counterfactual simulation

results to understand the role of substantial housing price declines that first triggered, and then

deepened by, the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression.

We conduct two counterfactuals. In the first counterfactual experiment, we ask what would

have happened to the delinquency and foreclosure rates, had the housing prices stayed unchanged

from the origination of the mortgage? In the second counterfactual experiment, we set the

housing price to be at 70% of the housing price at loan origination.

In Panel A where the housing price is set at 70% of the level at loan origination, we see that

the delinquency and foreclosure rates are an order of magnitude higher at all loan ages than

the baseline for loans that were originated in 2004 and 2005. For the mortgages that originated

in 2006, however, the model’s prediction of delinquency rates is not so much different from the

baseline, but the fraction of current loans is much higher and the fraction of paid off loans much

lower under the counterfactual than the baseline. As we showed in Figure 7, loans originated in

2006 eventually did experience a housing price decline of 40% or more, however, the housing price

declines were realized at a slower pace than the 30% decline we introduced in this counterfactual.

As a result, we see more loans that were paid off in the baseline than in the counterfactual when

the loans were still relatively young (when there were a larger discrepancy between the realized

housing price decline and the 30% abrupt price decline in the counterfactual). In fact, most of

the differences in the fraction of paid off loans and current loans between the baseline and the

counterfactual are a result of the differences when the loans were still relatively young.

In Panel B, we report the simulation results under the hypothetical situation that a bor-

rower’s house price stayed constant at its level at the mortgage origination. As should be

expected from Figure 7, setting housing price unchanged at its level of mortgage origination

would have deprived the substantial housing price gains for loans that originated in 2004, and

to some extent for the loans that originated in 2005. Indeed, our counterfactual experiments

show that our model predicted much higher (respectively, slightly higher) delinquency rates and

foreclosure rats for 2004 loans (respectively, for 2005 loans) than in the baseline. Analogously,

from Figure 7 we know that the 2006 loans experienced housing price declines immediately in

the data; thus setting the housing prices unchanged at their origination levels would lead to

much lower delinquency and foreclosure rates. Indeed, our counterfactual results for the 2006

loans confirm these. These counterfactual results, taken together, suggest that the effects of the

dynamics of housing prices differ substantially on the loans that originated in different years.

31

Tab

le7:

The

Rol

eof

Hou

sin

gP

rice

s

Base

lin

eH

PI0

FR

Man

dH

PI0

Loan

Age

Yea

rO

rig

%C

urr

ent

%D

elin

q%

Forc

l%

Paid

off

%C

urr

ent

%D

elin

q%

Forc

l%

Paid

off

%C

urr

ent

%D

elin

q%

Forc

l%

Paid

off

Pan

elA

:HPI t

=.7∗HPI 0

18

2004

0.4

46

0.0

76

0.0

31

0.5

08

0.7

33

0.2

50

0.0

96

0.0

31

0.7

32

0.2

52

0.0

97

0.0

33

24

2004

0.3

02

0.0

78

0.0

45

0.6

75

0.6

33

0.3

40

0.1

67

0.0

42

0.6

36

0.3

38

0.1

72

0.0

41

30

2004

0.1

16

0.0

97

0.0

60

0.8

03

0.4

86

0.4

71

0.2

51

0.0

60

0.5

41

0.4

24

0.2

47

0.0

49

36

2004

0.0

64

0.1

01

0.0

74

0.8

45

0.3

41

0.6

04

0.3

49

0.0

73

0.4

40

0.5

17

0.3

25

0.0

56

42

2004

0.0

32

0.1

04

0.0

84

0.8

68

0.2

16

0.7

18

0.4

43

0.0

84

0.3

45

0.6

04

0.3

96

0.0

65

48

2004

0.0

18

0.1

04

0.0

89

0.8

80

0.1

41

0.7

84

0.5

30

0.0

91

0.2

62

0.6

75

0.4

62

0.0

74

18

2005

0.5

05

0.1

13

0.0

37

0.4

08

0.7

48

0.2

36

0.0

75

0.0

27

0.7

51

0.2

38

0.0

73

0.0

23

24

2005

0.3

59

0.1

55

0.0

65

0.5

24

0.6

63

0.3

15

0.1

40

0.0

35

0.6

54

0.3

29

0.1

41

0.0

31

30

2005

0.1

73

0.2

31

0.1

04

0.6

11

0.4

55

0.5

09

0.2

12

0.0

49

0.5

49

0.4

23

0.2

09

0.0

40

36

2005

0.1

10

0.2

63

0.1

50

0.6

40

0.2

98

0.6

66

0.3

12

0.0

59

0.4

26

0.5

36

0.2

80

0.0

52

42

2005

0.0

67

0.2

82

0.1

81

0.6

59

0.2

02

0.7

46

0.4

21

0.0

70

0.3

35

0.6

15

0.3

57

0.0

61

48

2005

0.0

38

0.2

92

0.2

03

0.6

75

0.1

49

0.7

85

0.4

97

0.0

78

0.2

61

0.6

78

0.4

23

0.0

74

18

2006

0.5

25

0.2

47

0.0

57

0.2

43

0.6

84

0.3

02

0.0

81

0.0

28

0.7

02

0.2

87

0.0

79

0.0

23

24

2006

0.3

77

0.3

62

0.1

20

0.2

91

0.5

75

0.4

01

0.1

51

0.0

39

0.5

80

0.3

99

0.1

44

0.0

31

30

2006

0.2

34

0.4

68

0.1

92

0.3

15

0.4

00

0.5

56

0.2

21

0.0

61

0.4

56

0.5

16

0.2

17

0.0

44

36

2006

0.1

48

0.5

43

0.2

69

0.3

22

0.2

99

0.6

44

0.3

16

0.0

74

0.3

68

0.5

84

0.2

90

0.0

60

42

2006

0.0

79

0.6

04

0.3

39

0.3

30

0.2

51

0.6

78

0.3

98

0.0

86

0.2

95

0.6

48

0.3

59

0.0

74

48

2006

0.0

46

0.6

30

0.3

97

0.3

33

0.2

09

0.7

05

0.4

62

0.0

98

0.2

28

0.6

97

0.4

27

0.0

85

Pan

elB

:HPI t

=HPI 0

18

2004

0.4

46

0.0

76

0.0

31

0.5

08

0.6

00

0.1

21

0.0

47

0.2

94

0.5

92

0.1

35

0.0

48

0.2

90

24

2004

0.3

02

0.0

78

0.0

45

0.6

75

0.4

89

0.1

59

0.0

79

0.3

70

0.4

82

0.1

72

0.0

84

0.3

66

30

2004

0.1

16

0.0

97

0.0

60

0.8

03

0.3

33

0.2

17

0.1

16

0.4

68

0.3

79

0.2

05

0.1

22

0.4

32

36

2004

0.0

64

0.1

01

0.0

74

0.8

45

0.2

04

0.2

69

0.1

62

0.5

48

0.2

87

0.2

46

0.1

56

0.4

80

42

2004

0.0

32

0.1

04

0.0

84

0.8

68

0.1

14

0.3

02

0.1

99

0.5

98

0.2

11

0.2

75

0.1

88

0.5

27

48

2004

0.0

18

0.1

04

0.0

89

0.8

80

0.0

75

0.3

05

0.2

30

0.6

30

0.1

55

0.2

87

0.2

12

0.5

69

18

2005

0.5

05

0.1

13

0.0

37

0.4

08

0.6

47

0.1

27

0.0

44

0.2

46

0.6

48

0.1

34

0.0

42

0.2

37

24

2005

0.3

59

0.1

55

0.0

65

0.5

24

0.5

41

0.1

59

0.0

71

0.3

17

0.5

34

0.1

74

0.0

72

0.3

04

30

2005

0.1

73

0.2

31

0.1

04

0.6

11

0.3

43

0.2

52

0.1

06

0.4

24

0.4

20

0.2

24

0.1

08

0.3

70

36

2005

0.1

10

0.2

63

0.1

50

0.6

40

0.2

11

0.3

14

0.1

56

0.4

95

0.3

20

0.2

65

0.1

46

0.4

30

42

2005

0.0

67

0.2

82

0.1

81

0.6

59

0.1

37

0.3

25

0.1

96

0.5

51

0.2

39

0.2

90

0.1

79

0.4

85

48

2005

0.0

38

0.2

92

0.2

03

0.6

75

0.0

95

0.3

20

0.2

21

0.5

93

0.1

77

0.2

95

0.2

04

0.5

38

18

2006

0.5

25

0.2

47

0.0

57

0.2

43

0.5

85

0.1

60

0.0

46

0.2

75

0.5

96

0.1

68

0.0

42

0.2

55

24

2006

0.3

77

0.3

62

0.1

20

0.2

91

0.4

47

0.2

12

0.0

79

0.3

59

0.4

64

0.2

24

0.0

76

0.3

32

30

2006

0.2

34

0.4

68

0.1

92

0.3

15

0.2

90

0.2

74

0.1

15

0.4

62

0.3

37

0.2

71

0.1

14

0.4

10

36

2006

0.1

48

0.5

43

0.2

69

0.3

22

0.2

05

0.2

80

0.1

48

0.5

31

0.2

49

0.2

88

0.1

47

0.4

79

42

2006

0.0

79

0.6

04

0.3

39

0.3

30

0.1

52

0.2

82

0.1

78

0.5

74

0.1

76

0.3

00

0.1

82

0.5

37

48

2006

0.0

46

0.6

30

0.3

97

0.3

33

0.1

15

0.2

83

0.1

96

0.6

12

0.1

26

0.3

03

0.2

05

0.5

81

32

Fixed Rate Mortgage and House Price. One may also expect that the effect of fixed rate

mortgages on the borrowers’ payment behavior to depend on the housing market conditions. In

Table 7, we also report counterfactual results where we let all the loans to be FRMs, and consider

the same two housing price dynamics as described in the previous section. These counterfactual

results are to be compared with both those in Table 6 and those in Table 7. It suggests that

making the mortgage fixed rate rather than adjustable rates reduces the delinquency rates for

loans of all origination years, at the counterfactual housing price dynamics, but the effects are

not very large.

Labor Market Conditions. In Table 8, we simulate the role of local unemployment rate on

the observed borrowers’ delinquency and foreclosure. We suppose that the local unemployment

rate stayed the same as that at loan origination. The results show that for loans that originated

in 2004, the local unemployment conditions did not change the borrowers’ delinquency and

foreclosure rates much, and slightly increased in the delinquency and foreclosure rates for loans

that originated in 2005. However, for 2006 loans, the worsening labor market condition as

depicted in Figure 7, seems to be a significant contributor to the delinquency and foreclosure

observed in the data. It is worth emphasizing that, in the counterfactual results reported in

Table 8, we are changing the dynamic process for the local unemployment rates while holding

the borrowers’ own income process as estimated.

7.2 Potential Policy Responses to Reduce Defaults?

In this subsection, we evaluate the effectiveness of several potential policy responses to reduce

default and foreclosure rates. We first consider the role of monetary policy, and then consider

the role of alternative mortgage contract designs.

7.2.1 Monetary Policy

There are recent works that looked at how ARM borrowers responded to a decrease in their

mortgage interest rates due to a low short-term interest rate (LIBOR). General findings in

the works are that monetary policy can have positive effects on ARM borrowers because their

interest rates are tied to a short-term interest rate. They found that ARM borrowers are less

likely to default (Fuster and Willen, 2014) and that they are more likely to increase consumption

due to a larger disposable income (Keys, Piskorski, Seru and Yao, 2014; Di Maggio, Kermani

and Ramcharan, 2014).

In Table 6, we report the counterfactual results from an experiment where Libor rate is

set to zero, and as a result, the ARM borrowers’ monthly payment amount will be determined

by the lifetime floor interest rate once the teaser rate period of the ARM expires. This could

33

Table

8:T

he

Rol

eof

Loca

lU

nem

plo

ym

ent

Rat

e

Base

lin

e∆UNR

t=

∆UNR

0

Loan

Age

Yea

rO

rig

%C

urr

ent

%D

elin

q%

Forc

l%

Paid

off

%C

urr

ent

%D

elin

q%

Forc

l%

Paid

off

18

2004

0.4

46

0.0

76

0.0

31

0.5

08

0.4

93

0.0

63

0.0

28

0.4

75

24

2004

0.3

02

0.0

78

0.0

45

0.6

75

0.3

55

0.0

65

0.0

38

0.6

00

30

2004

0.1

16

0.0

97

0.0

60

0.8

03

0.2

02

0.0

84

0.0

50

0.7

33

36

2004

0.0

64

0.1

01

0.0

74

0.8

45

0.1

13

0.1

00

0.0

65

0.8

00

42

2004

0.0

32

0.1

04

0.0

84

0.8

68

0.0

61

0.1

07

0.0

79

0.8

38

48

2004

0.0

18

0.1

04

0.0

89

0.8

80

0.0

36

0.1

07

0.0

88

0.8

62

18

2005

0.5

05

0.1

13

0.0

37

0.4

08

0.5

90

0.0

92

0.0

30

0.3

37

24

2005

0.3

59

0.1

55

0.0

65

0.5

24

0.4

80

0.1

22

0.0

52

0.4

11

30

2005

0.1

73

0.2

31

0.1

04

0.6

11

0.3

13

0.1

92

0.0

78

0.5

13

36

2005

0.1

10

0.2

63

0.1

50

0.6

40

0.1

93

0.2

50

0.1

17

0.5

70

42

2005

0.0

67

0.2

82

0.1

81

0.6

59

0.1

29

0.2

74

0.1

53

0.6

06

48

2005

0.0

38

0.2

92

0.2

03

0.6

75

0.0

95

0.2

84

0.1

80

0.6

28

18

2006

0.5

25

0.2

47

0.0

57

0.2

43

0.5

76

0.1

82

0.0

43

0.2

56

24

2006

0.3

77

0.3

62

0.1

20

0.2

91

0.4

56

0.2

66

0.0

84

0.2

88

30

2006

0.2

34

0.4

68

0.1

92

0.3

15

0.3

34

0.3

65

0.1

40

0.3

15

36

2006

0.1

48

0.5

43

0.2

69

0.3

22

0.2

44

0.4

31

0.2

02

0.3

37

42

2006

0.0

79

0.6

04

0.3

39

0.3

30

0.1

82

0.4

75

0.2

64

0.3

51

48

2006

0.0

46

0.6

30

0.3

97

0.3

33

0.1

46

0.5

00

0.3

18

0.3

62

34

provide the best case scenario (or upper bound) on how much monetary policy may reduce the

delinquency and foreclosure rates.

Note, however, setting Libor rate to zero does not necessarily imply that the borrowers’

monthly payment will be lower than their payment in the teaser period. The reason is that for

a vast majority of borrowers, margin rates and life time floor rates are still higher than initial

teaser rates; in fact, borrowers will on average still have their monthly payment increasing by

about 10% even if Libor rate is zero upon the reset of the interest rate. The results in Table 6

suggests that setting Libor rate at zero does not seem to affect the delinquency and foreclosure

rates for 2004 and 2005 loans, though the fraction of paid loans is reduced. However, for 2006

loans, setting Libor rate at zero significantly reduced the delinquency and foreclosure rates, and

significantly reduces the fraction of current loans, though the fraction of paid off loans do not

change much.

7.2.2 Automatic Loan Modification Contingent on Housing Price Index

If a housing price downturn leads to massive default rates, then a way to mitigate this

problem is to tie a mortgage payment to the current house price index. Shiller (?), Mian and

Sufi (??) and Kung (2013) have suggested that such “continuous workout mortgages” might have

reduced the mortgage default and foreclosure. We consider two slightly different automatic loan

modification schemes in this subsection.

Modification of Monthly Payments Only. We first consider the case in which only the

monthly payment amount is automatically modified as housing prices change. Specifically, de-

note P̃t as the modified monthly payment at period t, and Pt as the monthly payment amount

in the absent of modification according to the original loan. Let Ht and H0 denote the housing

price index at period t and at origination respectively. The first counterfactual we consider

assumes that the monthly payment will be automatically modified from Pt to P̃t as follows:

P̃t = Pt ×min {1, Ht/H0} , (18)

while the principal balance is not adjusted.

Modification of Principal Balance (and Monthly Payments Too) In the second coun-

terfactual, we assume that

B̃ALt = BALt ×min {1, Ht/H0} . (19)

35

Table

9:

Au

tom

atic

Mod

ifica

tion

sof

Mon

thly

Pay

men

tsan

dP

rinci

pal

Bal

ance

Base

lin

eP̃t

=Pt×

min{ HP

It

HPI0,1}

B̃ALt

=BALt×

min{ HP

It

HPI0,1}

Loan

Age

Yea

rO

rig

%C

urr

ent

%D

elin

q%

Forc

l%

Paid

off

%C

urr

ent

%D

elin

q%

Forc

l%

Paid

off

%C

urr

ent

%D

elin

q%

Forc

l%

Paid

off

18

2004

0.4

46

0.0

76

0.0

31

0.5

08

0.4

74

0.0

65

0.0

29

0.4

95

0.4

52

0.0

62

0.0

30

0.5

16

24

2004

0.3

02

0.0

78

0.0

45

0.6

75

0.3

01

0.0

79

0.0

42

0.6

42

0.2

93

0.0

68

0.0

40

0.6

60

30

2004

0.1

16

0.0

97

0.0

60

0.8

03

0.1

84

0.0

91

0.0

57

0.7

42

0.1

75

0.0

81

0.0

51

0.7

60

36

2004

0.0

64

0.1

01

0.0

74

0.8

45

0.1

01

0.1

01

0.0

70

0.8

09

0.0

96

0.0

92

0.0

63

0.8

19

42

2004

0.0

32

0.1

04

0.0

84

0.8

68

0.0

56

0.1

07

0.0

81

0.8

43

0.0

50

0.0

99

0.0

74

0.8

55

48

2004

0.0

18

0.1

04

0.0

89

0.8

80

0.0

32

0.1

10

0.0

89

0.8

60

0.0

30

0.0

99

0.0

82

0.8

75

Rev

enu

ep

er’0

4b

orr

ow

er216.7

4K

216.6

4K

216.9

5K

18

2005

0.5

05

0.1

13

0.0

37

0.4

08

0.5

24

0.1

00

0.0

32

0.4

00

0.5

29

0.0

92

0.0

34

0.4

06

24

2005

0.3

59

0.1

55

0.0

65

0.5

24

0.3

87

0.1

38

0.0

59

0.4

94

0.3

79

0.1

25

0.0

58

0.5

19

30

2005

0.1

73

0.2

31

0.1

04

0.6

11

0.2

65

0.1

88

0.0

87

0.5

63

0.2

51

0.1

58

0.0

88

0.6

06

36

2005

0.1

10

0.2

63

0.1

50

0.6

40

0.1

85

0.2

25

0.1

21

0.6

03

0.1

77

0.1

74

0.1

17

0.6

60

42

2005

0.0

67

0.2

82

0.1

81

0.6

59

0.1

39

0.2

43

0.1

54

0.6

28

0.1

32

0.1

80

0.1

36

0.6

96

48

2005

0.0

38

0.2

92

0.2

03

0.6

75

0.1

10

0.2

49

0.1

73

0.6

46

0.1

00

0.1

82

0.1

50

0.7

23

Rev

enu

ep

er’0

5b

orr

ow

er223.7

4K

224.0

7K

226.0

4K

18

2006

0.5

25

0.2

47

0.0

57

0.2

43

0.6

08

0.1

76

0.0

42

0.2

22

0.5

94

0.1

37

0.0

54

0.2

86

24

2006

0.3

77

0.3

62

0.1

20

0.2

91

0.5

21

0.2

40

0.0

84

0.2

49

0.5

07

0.1

63

0.0

90

0.3

41

30

2006

0.2

34

0.4

68

0.1

92

0.3

15

0.4

50

0.2

90

0.1

25

0.2

69

0.4

45

0.1

78

0.1

22

0.3

88

36

2006

0.1

48

0.5

43

0.2

69

0.3

22

0.4

01

0.3

20

0.1

64

0.2

85

0.3

92

0.1

89

0.1

42

0.4

28

42

2006

0.0

79

0.6

04

0.3

39

0.3

30

0.3

57

0.3

49

0.1

97

0.3

00

0.3

51

0.1

95

0.1

58

0.4

64

48

2006

0.0

46

0.6

30

0.3

97

0.3

33

0.3

24

0.3

69

0.2

27

0.3

12

0.3

11

0.2

03

0.1

72

0.4

93

Rev

enu

ep

er’0

6b

orr

ow

er203.0

8K

198.1

9K

202.4

7K

36

Because monthly payment is proportional to principal balance, as we showed in (2), the auto-

matic modification of principal balance will also automatically adjust the monthly payment.

In Table 9 we present the results from these counterfactual simulations. We find that these

automatic modification mortgages do not seem to impact the delinquency and foreclosure rates

for loans that originated in 2004; however, the delinquency and foreclosure rates are significantly

reduced for 2005 and particularly for 2006 loans. Interestingly, we also find that lenders’ rev-

enues do not seem to be lower, and in fact for 2004 and 2005 loans they are higher, than the

baseline. These counterfactual results suggest that automatic modification mortgages, particu-

larly automatic modifications of principal balance contingent on housing price index, could be

a promising alternative mortgage design that can prove to be win-win for both borrowers and

lenders.

8 Conclusion

One important characteristic of the recent mortgage crisis is the prevalence of subprime

mortgages with adjustable interest rates and their high default rates. In this paper, we build and

estimate a dynamic structural model of adjustable-rate mortgage defaults using unique mortgage

loan level data. The data contain detailed information not only on borrowers’ mortgage payment

history and lender responses but also on their broad balance sheet. Our structural estimation

suggests that the factors that drive the borrower delinquency and foreclosure differ substantially

by the year of loans’ origination. For loans that originated in 2004 and 2005, which precedes the

severe downturn of the housing and labor market conditions, the interest rate resets associated

with ARMs, as well as the housing and labor market conditions do not seem to be important

factors for borrowers’ delinquency behavior, though they are important factors that determine

whether the borrowers would pay off their loans (i.e., sell their houses or refinance). However,

for loans that originated in 2006, interest rate reset, housing price declines and worsening labor

market conditions all contributed importantly to their high delinquency rates. Countefactual

policy simulations also suggest that monetary policies in the most optimistic scenario might

have limited effectiveness in reducing the delinquency rates of 2004 and 2005 loans, but could be

much more effective for 2006 loans. Interestingly, we found that automatic modification loans in

which the monthly payment and principal balance of the loans are automatically reduced when

housing prices decline can reduce delinquency and foreclosure rates, and significantly so for 2006

loans, without having much a negative impact on lenders’ expected income.

An important limitation of this paper is that we take lenders’ behavior as given. For the

questions we address, this assumption may be realistic, because lenders’ policy regarding modi-

fication and foreclosure do not seem to be too responsive to a variety of government policies that

37

were specifically introduced to increase modification. However, it is important to model lender

behavior explicitly so we can have a better understanding of why lenders’ are not responsive to

government policy. This is a topic we will explore in our companion paper.

References

[1] Agarwal, Sumit, Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet, and Dou-

glas Evanoff, 2011, ”Market-Based Loss Mitigation Practices for Troubled Mortgages Fol-

lowing the Financial Crisis,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper 2011-03.

[2] Agarwal, Sumit, Gene Amromin, Itzhak Ben-David, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Tomasz

Piskorski, and Amit Seru, 2012, ”Policy Intervention in Debt Renegotiation: Evidence from

the Home Affordable Modification Program,” University of Chicago Kreisman Working

Paper on Housing Law and Policy No. 7.

[3] Bajari, Patrick, Sean Chu, Denis Nekipelov, and Minjung Park, ”A Dynamic Model of

Subprime Mortgage Default: Estimation and Policy Implications,” 2013, NBER Working

Paper 18850.

[4] Campbell, John Y., and Joao F. Cocco, ”A Model of Mortgage Default,”Journal of Finance,

forthcoming.

[5] Chatterjee, Satyajit, and Burcu Eyigungor, 2015, ”A Quantitative Analysis of the U.S.

Housing and Mortgage Markets and the Foreclosure Crisis,” Federal Reserve Bank of

Philadelphia Working Paper 15-13, Philadelphia, PA.

[6] Corbae, Dean, and Erwan Quintin, 1984, ”Leverage and the Foreclosure Crisis,” Journal of

Political Economy, forthcoming.

[7] Demyanyk, Yuliya, and Otto van Hemert, 2011, ”Understanding the Subprime Mortgage

Crisis,” Review of Financial Studies 24(6), 1848-1880.

[8] Deng, Youngheng, John M. Quigley, and Robert van Order, 2000, ”Mortgage Terminations,

Heterogeneity and the Exercise of Mortgage Options,” Econometrica 68(2), 275-307.

[9] Elul, Ronel, Nicholas S. Souleles, Souphala Chomsisengphet, Dennis Glennon, and Robert

Hunt, 2010, ”What ’Triggers’ Mortgage Default?” American Economic Review 100(2), 490-

494.

[10] Foote, Christopher, Kristopher Gerardi, and Paul Willen, 2008, ”Negative Equity and Fore-

closure: Theory and Evidence,” Journal of Urban Economics 64(2), 234-245.

38

[11] Foster, Chester, and Robert van Order, 1984, ”An Option-Based Model of Mortgage De-

fault” Housing Finance Review 3(4), 351-372.

[12] Frame, Scott, Andreas Lehnert, and Ned Prescott, 2008, ”A Snapshot of Mortgage Condi-

tions: Emphasis on Subprime Mortgage Performance,” manuscript.

[13] Garriga, Carlos, and Don Schlagenhauf, 2009, ”Home Equity, Foreclosures, and Bailouts,”

manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

[14] Gerardi, Kristopher, Andreas Lehnert, Shane Sherlund, and Paul Willen, 2008, ”Making

Sense of the Subprime Crisis,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 69-145.

[15] Gerardi, Kristopher, and Wenli Li, 2010, ”Mortgage Foreclosure Prevention Efforts,”Federal

Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review 2, 1-13.

[16] Hatchondo, Juan Carlos, Leonardo Martinez, and Juan M. Sanchez, 2011, ”Mortgage De-

faults,” Federal Reserve Bank of Saint-Louis Fed Working Paper no. 2011-019A.

[17] Haughwout, Andrew, Ebiere Okah, and Joseph Tracy, 2010, ”Second Chances: Subprime

Mortgage Modification and Re-Default” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report

No. 417.

[18] Keane, Michael, and Kenneth Wolpin, 1993, ”Career Choices of Young Men,” Journal of

Political Economy, 105 (3), 473-522.

[19] Keys, Benjamin, Tanmoy Mukherjee, Amit Seru, and Vikrant Vig, 2010, ”Did Securitization

Lead to Lax Screening? Evidence From Subprime Loans,” Quarterly Journal of Economics

125(1), 307-362.

[20] Mayer, Christopher, Karen Pence, and Shane M. Sherlund, 2009, ”The Rise in Mortgage

Defaults,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 23(1), 27-50.

[21] Mitman, Kurt, 2012, ”Macroeconomic Effects of Bankruptcy and Foreclosure Policies,”

manuscript, Department of Economics, University of Pennsylvania.

[22] Rust, John (1987). “Optimal Replacement of GMC Bus Engines. An Empirical Model of

Harold Zurcher.” Econometrica, 55(5), 999-1033.

[23] Rust, John (1994a). “Estimation of Dynamic Structural Models, Problems and Prospects:

Discrete Decision Processes,” in Christopher Sims and J.J. Laffont, eds., Proceedings of the

6th World Congress of the Econometric Society. Cambridge University Press.

39

[24] Rust, John (1994b). “Structural Estimation of Markov Decision Processes,” in Robert En-

gle and Daniel McFadden eds., Handbook of Econometrics, Vol. IV. Amsterdam: North-

Holland.

[25] Tracy, Joseph, and Joshua Wright, 2015, ”Payment Changes and Default Risk: The Impact

of Refinancing on Expected Credit Losses,” manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of New York.

40

Category 1 Loans

(dt= 0, at= 0)Category 2 Loans

(dt= 1, at= 0)Category 3 Loans

(dt= 2, at= 0)Variable coeff. s.d. coeff. s.d. coeff. s.d.

Current Credit Score 0.32*** 0.04 0.17*** 0.05 0.23*** 0.07

Income ($1000) -0.14 0.42 -0.77 0.49 -2.57*** 0.60

Inverse loan-to-value (%) -1.63*** 0.59 -1.61*** 0.68 -0.96 0.71

Inverse loan-to-value at orig. (%) 0.99 0.62 -0.46 0.82 1.44** 0.68

Changes in local unemp. rates (%) -0.16** 0.07 -0.02 0.08 0.01 0.08

Current monthly payment ($1000) 0.74*** 0.29 0.93*** 0.31 0.56 0.43

Initial monthly payment ($1000) -0.90** 0.37 -0.98*** 0.40 -0.35 0.52

Dummy for initial fixed period (%) 0.77*** 0.29 0.59* 0.34 0.87* 0.47

Dummy for interest-only period -0.94 0.66 -0.26 0.68 -0.63 0.91

Loan age (month) -0.43* 0.24 0.56** 0.25 0.17 0.29

Loan age squared 0.01 0.00 -0.01** 0.00 -0.00 0.01

Months before first reset -0.71*** 0.12 -0.21*** 0.09 -0.13 0.15

Months before first reset squared 0.01*** 0.00 0.01* 0.00 -0.00 0.01

Months before interest-only 0.05* 0.03 0.01 0.03 0.01 0.04

Months before interest-only squared -0.00* 0.00 -0.00 0.00 -0.00 0.00

Dummy for full documentation 0.50*** 0.17 0.54*** 0.19 0.42* 0.23

Dummy for loan orig. in 2004 -41.58*** 17.91 -12.18 11.13 -32.32 23.98

Dummy for loan orig. in 2005 -12.92*** 4.23 -6.06 4.91 -20.36*** 7.59

Dummy for loan orig. in 2004 x age 1.89*** 0.82 0.32 0.56 1.31 1.07

Dummy for loan orig. in 2004 x age2 -0.02** 0.01 0.00 0.01 -0.01 0.01

Dummy for loan orig. in 2005 x age 0.76*** 0.29 0.24 0.39 1.05** 0.47

Dummy for loan orig. in 2005 x age2 -0.01** 0.01 -0.00 0.01 -0.01* 0.01

Dummy for Arizona -0.11 0.39 0.64 0.59 0.04 0.47

Dummy for California 0.12 0.33 1.05** 0.53 -0.05 0.42

Dummy for Florida -0.22 0.36 1.05* 0.54 -0.23 0l.43

Constant 3.04 3.53 -9.77*** 3.42 -6.96* 3.93

Number of observations 13,716 7,676 5,740

Pseudo R2 0.26 0.19 0.1966

Table A1: Lenders’ Decisions for Loans in Categories 1-3.Notes: Results are from logit Regressions where the dependent variable is a dummy for loan modification. ***indicates significance at 1 percent confidence level; ** at 5 percent; and * at 1 percent.

41

Modification Liquidation

Variable coeff. s.d. coeff. s.d.

Current Credit Score -0.05 0.05 0.04* 0.02

Income ($1000) -0.56** 0.24 0.21* 0.12

Inverse loan-to-value (%) -0.20 0.99 3.57*** 0.55

Inverse loan-to-value at orig. (%) -0.66* 0.38 -0.89*** 0.53

Changes in local unemp. rates (%) 0.25** 0.12 0.20* 0.11

Current monthly payment ($1000) -0.06 0.19 -0.01 0.09

Initial monthly payment ($1000) 0.04 0.22 -0.15 0.11

Dummy for initial fixed period (%) -0.09 0.22 -0.14 0.11

Dummy for interest-only period -0.70 0.40 0.36*** 0.14

Loan age (month) 0.29*** 0.09 -0.01 0.04

Loan age squared -0.00*** 0.00 -0.00 0.00

Months before first reset 0.07 0.05 0.01 0.02

Months before first reset squared -0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

Months before interest-only 0.02 0.02 -0.01 0.01

Months before interest-only squared -0.00 0.00 0.00* 0.00

Dummy for full documentation 0.20** 0.10 -0.09* 0.05

Dummy for loan orig. in 2004 -11.67** 5.66 1.90*** 0.71

Dummy for loan orig. in 2005 -3.12* 1.72 0.94 0.57

Dummy for loan orig. in 2004 x age 0.49* 0.28 0.02 0.05

Dummy for loan orig. in 2004 x age2 -0.00 0.00 -0.00 0.00

Dummy for loan orig. in 2005 x age 0.11 0.12 0.02 0.04

Dummy for loan orig. in 2005 x age2 -0.00 0.00 -0.00 0.01

Dummy for Arizona -0.79 1.60 1.99*** 0.65

Dummy for California 2.38* 1.20 -0.51 0.57

Dummy for Florida 2.20* 1.22 -4.68*** 0.64

Number of late payments 0.70* 0.38 0.72*** 0.18

Number of late payments squared -0.03** 0.02 -0.02*** 0.0.01

Inverse ltv x number of late payments 0.04 0.18 -0.52*** 0.10

Inverse ltv x number of late payments squared 0.00 0.11 0.02*** 0.00

Change in unemp rates x number of late payments -0.02 0.02 -0.05*** 0.02

Change in unemp rates x number of late payments2 0.00 0.00 0.00** 0.00

Table A2: Lenders’ Decisions on Category 4 Loans (to be continued in Table A3).Notes: Results are from multinomial logit Regressions where the alternatives are modification, liquidation andwaiting (omitted). *** indicates significance at 1 percent confidence level; ** at 5 percent; and * at 1 percent.

42

Modification Liquidation

Variable coeff. s.d. coeff. s.d.

Dummy for 4 months deliq. 1.45 0.97 -3.74*** 0.69

Dummy for 5 months deliq. 0.96 0.84 -2.47*** 0.48

Dummy for 6 months deliq. 1.01 0.71 -2.19*** 0.40

Dummy for 7 months deliq. 0.47 0.60 -0.59* 0.32

Dummy for 8 months deliq. 0.54 0.50 0.67*** 0.25

Dummy for 9 months deliq. 0.75* 0.41 0.42** 0.20

Dummy for 10 months deliq. 0.60* 0.35 0.10 0.16

Dummy for 11 months deliq. 0.23 0.32 0.13 0.13

Arizona x months of deliq. 0.00 0.37 -0.20** 0.10

Arizona x months of deliq. squared -0.01 0.02 0.00 0.00

California x months of deliq. -0.46* 0.25 0.13 0.09

California x months of deliq. squared 0.02 0.01 -0.01** 0.00

Florida x months of deliq. -0.50** 0.25 0.48*** 0.10

Florida x months of deliq. squared 0.02 0.01 -0.01*** 0.00

Originated in 2004 x months of deliq. -0.21 0.16 -0.29*** 0.10

Originated in 2004 x months of deliq. squared 0.01 0.01 0.01*** 0.00

Originated in 2005 x months of deliq. -0.07 0.10 -0.19*** 0.07

Originated in 2005 x months of deliq. squared 0.00 0.01 0.01*** 0.00

Constant -10.98*** 2.66 -5.44*** 1.29

Number of observations 33,449

Pseudo R2 0.15

Table A3: Lenders’ Decisions on Category 4 Loans (continued from A2).Notes: Results are from multinomial logit Regressions where the alternatives are modification, liquidation andwaiting (omitted). *** indicates significance at 1 percent confidence level; ** at 5 percent; and * at 1 percent.

43


Recommended