+ All Categories
Home > Documents > The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X...

The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X...

Date post: 22-Jan-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 2 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
137
Tropical Ecology Support Program (TÖB) The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity
Transcript
Page 1: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Tropical Ecology SupportProgram (TÖB)

The Economic Valuationof Biological Diversity

Page 2: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Tropical Ecology SupportProgram (TÖB)

The Economic Valuationof Biological Diversity

Dr. Thomas Plän

Eschborn, 1999

Page 3: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

TÖB Publication No.: TÖB P-3e

Published by: Deutsche Gesellschaft fürTechnische Zusammenarbeit (GTZ) GmbHPostfach 5180D-65726 Eschborn

Responsible: Tropenökologisches Begleitprogramm (TÖB)Dr. Claus Bätke

Author: Dr. Thomas Plän, inf – Informationsmanagement,Biotechnologie / Biodiversitätsnutzung,Lessingstr. 3a, D-93049 Regensburg, GermanyTel.: +49-941-299054, Fax: +49-941-25627,email: [email protected]

Edited by: Michaela Hammer

Nominal fee: DM 5,-

ISBN:

Produced by: TZ-Verlagsgesellschaft mbH, D-64380 Roßdorf

© 1999 All rights reserved

Page 4: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Foreword

For the majority of the world's population, tropical ecosystems are a vital life-sustaining force. However, the progressive destruction and depletion of naturalresources in developing countries are jeopardising efforts aimed at achievingsustainable development and effective poverty reduction.

The Flanking Program for Tropical Ecology is a supraregional service projectbeing run by the Deutsche Gesellschaft für Technische Zusammenarbeit (GTZ)GmbH on behalf of the Federal German Ministry for Economic Cooperationand Development (BMZ), its mandate being to help collect and processexperience in this sector, thus improving the information status.

On request, the program flanks specific projects with studies focusing onissues relevant to tropical ecology. By so doing, it is aiming to further developconcepts and approaches geared to protecting, conserving and ensuring thesustainable use of tropical ecosystems. At the same time, this research workprovides the basis for designing innovative instruments that will facilitate moreecologically-sound development cooperation in future.

By applying scientific results at grass-roots extension level, the program assistsother projects in the implementation of international agreements, in particularAgenda 21 and the Biodiversity Convention, to which the BMZ attaches greatimportance.

A key element of the program concept centres on a joint approach whichprovides German and local scientists with a forum for discussion. TheFlanking Program for Tropical Ecology is thus making a valuable contributionto the practice-oriented upgrading of counterpart experts and the consolidationof tropical-ecology expertise in partner countries.

This series of publications has been produced in a generally comprehensibleform with the specific aim of presenting its results and recommendations to allorganisations and institutions active in development cooperation, and also to allthose members of the general public who are interested in environmental anddevelopment-policy issues.

Dr. H. P. SchipulleHead of the Environmental Policy,Protection of Natural Resources and

Forestry Division

Dr. C. van TuyllHead of the Rural Development Division

Federal German Ministry for EconomicCooperation and Development (BMZ)

Deutsche Gesellschaft für TechnischeZusammenarbeit (GTZ) mbH

Page 5: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Contents

I

Table of Contents

TABLE OF CONTENTS .....................................................................I

LIST OF FIGURES..........................................................................IV

LIST OF TABLES...........................................................................IV

GLOSSARY ...................................................................................V

SUMMARY...................................................................................IX

1 INTRODUCTION ......................................................................1

1.1 Description of the development cooperation project and

purpose of the project ................................................................. 1

1.2 Analysis of problems .................................................................. 2

1.3 Objectives................................................................................... 3

2 RESULTS AND ANALYSIS........................................................7

2.1 Decrease in biodiversity as a consequence of the lack of

markets and of market failure ..................................................... 7

2.2 Classification of the types of values of biological diversity ...... 11

2.3 Examples of evaluating biological diversity ............................. 22

2.3.1 Use value of genes and biochemicals ............................ 22

2.3.2 Use value of species...................................................... 28

2.3.3 Use value of ecosystems and landscapes....................... 30

3 RECOMMENDATIONS............................................................35

3.1 Valuation methods and techniques............................................ 35

3.1.1 Determining direct and passive use values on

simulated markets ......................................................... 38

3.1.2 Indirectly determining direct use values........................ 43

3.1.3 Determining indirect use values.................................... 45

Page 6: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

II

3.2 The cost aspect of the conservation and destruction of

biological diversity and the cost-benefit analysis procedure ..... 48

3.2.1 Opportunity costs: restoration costs, sustainability

costs, lost use values..................................................... 48

3.2.2 Cost-benefit analysis..................................................... 52

3.3 Organisation of markets with appropriate prices....................... 53

3.3.1 Monetisation and cost-benefit analyses......................... 54

3.3.2 Dismantling failed interventions ................................... 55

3.3.3 Creation of private property rights and integrated

biodiversity management.............................................. 56

3.3.4 Creation of market-based regulatory instruments.......... 58

3.3.5 Creation of global markets............................................ 61

3.4 Recommendations for development cooperation ...................... 65

3.4.1 Project-oriented cost-benefit analyses using the

available valuation instruments..................................... 66

3.4.2 Training and capacity-building to inventor and

monitor biodiversity ..................................................... 66

3.4.3 Creation and/or strengthening of institutional

prerequisites for the development and

implementation of national biodiversity strategies ........ 67

3.4.4 Training and capacity-building to conduct cost-

benefit analyses and valuation techniques..................... 67

3.4.5 Supporting research capacities in developing

countries at the frontier between ecology and

economics 68

3.4.6 Identification of interventions failures .......................... 70

3.4.7 Creation of incentive instruments ................................. 71

3.4.8 Participation of local communities in biodiversity

yields ............................................................................ 71

Page 7: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Contents

III

3.4.9 Assistance in the creation of property rights ................. 72

3.4.10 Cooperation in establishing global environmental

markets through bilateral and multilateral

agreements.................................................................... 73

4 BIBLIOGRAPHY ....................................................................75

4.1 Cited references........................................................................ 75

4.2 Other references ....................................................................... 83

Page 8: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

IV

List of figures

Fig. 1: Total economic value of a biological asset 13

Fig. 2: Classification of resources 17

Fig. 3: Classification of economic values and attributable valuation

methods (methods in angled brackets are less suitable ones) 37

Fig. 4: Comparison of the resulting costs and use of protected areas 52

List of tables

Table 1: Use values of genes and biochemicals 28

Table 2: Use values of species 30

Table 3: Use values of ecosystems 33

Page 9: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Glossary

V

Glossary

Allocation

mechanism

Mechanism for the allocation of productive factors or

resources to certain goals

Assimilation Admission and processing of a substrate

Bequest value Value of keeping a resource intact for future

generations

Biodiversity or

biological diversity

General term for the number, variety and diversity of

living organisms in a certain environment or unit of

space, divisible into the order and integration levels

genes, species and ecosystems

Biological resource General term for genetic resources, organisms or

parts of organisms, populations or any other

biological component of ecosystems of actual or

potential use or value for mankind

Bioprospecting Exploration of biodiversity in search of commercially

exploitable genetic and biochemical resources

Biotic Of or relating to organisms or life processes

Cost-benefit analysis

(CBA)

Collection and evaluation of relevant actions or

measures and their alternatives in monetary terms

Direct use value Value of biological resources or resource systems by

consumption or production or by their direct

interaction with market subjects

Discounting Preference of a currently available private use, which

Page 10: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

VI

involves social destruction, over a private use in the

future, which also involves social preservation

Ecosystem Fundamental functional ecological unit which

includes organisms and environment, divisible into

energy flows, food chains, diversity samples,

biogeochemical food cycles, development and

evolution, cybernetics

Emission rights Pollution licence entitling the holder to a certain level

of emissions

Existence value Intrinsic value of a resource

Global environmental

markets (GEMs)

Global markets which have either been enforced by

international sets of rules or have resulted from

voluntary agreements

Gross national

product (GNP)

Total value of the goods and services produced by

firms owned by a country

Gross primary

production

Entire photosynthesis, including organic material

used during respiration

Habitat Place in which an organism lives

Indirect use value Value of biological resources or achievement for

directly used resources or ecosystems

Market analysis Analysis of the procurements and sales prospects of

an enterprise or an industry and the market influences

affecting it at a certain time

Page 11: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Glossary

VII

Natural capital The natural wealth of biological resources

Net primary

production

Quantity of organic material stored in green plants

minus that used in respiration

Opportunity costs Costs of alternatives that are not used

Option value Use reserved for a later time

Passive use value Measurement of the significance of resources or

similar factors for us, our descendants or other

species

Population Total individuals belonging to a certain species in a

certain area

Preference Ranking of demand for certain goods by individuals

Productivity Accumulation of one organic substance per unit of

time

Quasi-option value Value of delaying an irreversible decision to wait for

additional information to help in the decision-making

process

Surrogate market

concept

Evaluation of markets for private goods and services

related to the relevant resources and products

Screening Purposeful search for certain substances or effects

Travel cost approach Market approach based on the expenditure required

for a particular journey corresponding to or

characteristic of products or resources, etc.

Page 12: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

VIII

Total economic value

(TEV)

Sum or aggregation of direct value, indirect value,

option/quasi-option value and passive use value of a

resource or a resource system

Transferable

development rights

(TDRs)

International trade development rights to enable

adequate protection of global biodiversity values, in

particular in tropical countries

Willingness to pay Survey to obtain a value, e.g. for biological diversity

Page 13: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Summary

IX

Summary

Biological diversity is decreasing at all levels of integration at an alarming

rate. The market prices of biological resources do not reflect their true

values because of a lack of internalisation of external costs and benefits.

This omission is an indication of market failure, based in particular on the

difference between private and social/ecological benefits, on the lack of

markets and on failed interventions.

This paper is based on the hypothesis that the failure to allocate economic

values to the respective components of biological diversity is one of the

causes of this decrease in diversity. Conversely, the allocation of the

appropriate economic values to these components should be able to halt

this trend and to reverse it.

After an introductory chapter, the chapter on "Results and Analysis"

highlights the loss of biodiversity under the aspect of the lack of markets

and of market failure. It is postulated that a market-oriented strategy to

valuate the components of biological diversity would help to stop this

decline. Types of values of biological diversity are therefore subdivided

into different use-dependent and use-independent categories. The

social/ecological value of biological resources or services is made up of

four categories of use values: the direct use value, indirect use value,

option/quasi-option use value and passive use value. These are added

together to give the so-called total economic value (TEV). However, there

is a certain amount of overlap between these types of values, which means

that there is a danger of values attributes being counted more than once in

different value categories. The more aspects of use value that can be

determined and compiled to form the TEV, the closer the TEV will come to

the "real" value of a biological asset. However, if this TEV fails to be

Page 14: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

X

reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the

benefits of biological diversity and the lack of information available about

these benefits as a result of market failure, there is an urgent need for

economic valuation studies to be carried out.

The results of several studies carried out to assess genes and biochemicals,

species, ecosystems and landscapes in terms of the use values of the

respective components of biological diversity are highlighted.

The third chapter discusses application relevance and recommendations for

action and presents the relevant assessment methods. These methods

primarily suggest how markets would need to be reformed in order to

correct the present imbalance between prices and values and/or, where this

is not possible, provide decision-making aids indicating the political

measures that need to be taken to correct market signals.

The contingent valuation method (CVM) and related methods of analysis

are of particular importance in this context, because they allow combined

valuations of the direct use value, the option/quasi-option use value and the

passive use value of the components of biological diversity. Moreover,

these methods are the only useful ones to determine passive or non-use

values. Alternative indirect techniques by which to determine direct use

values are also presented.

Methods to determine preferences such as the CVM are not suitable to

determine the indirect use values (e.g. ecological regulatory functions) of

nature as a production factor, since these values support economic activities

or even enable such activities to be carried out regardless of preferences. In

order to determine indirect use values, methods such as productivity

change, maintenance or optimisation work effort, the restoration cost

approach and the production-function approach are currently being applied.

Page 15: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Summary

XI

The latter approach is designed to determine the physical effects that

changes of ecological functions have on economic activities.

In order to be able to be compared with use values and benefits, the costs

associated with the conservation, sustainable use and restoration of

biological diversity need to be determined. On the basis of the results of

this analysis, the alternative that is not chosen generates opportunity costs.

Finally, cost-benefit analyses (CBAs) allow relevant activities and their

alternatives to be identified and valuated in monetary terms. The relevant

cost and benefit variables have to established to allow an accurate direct

comparison of the possible alternatives to be made.

By applying valuation methods, it was able to be shown that the economic

benefits of conserving biological diversity are limited at a local level, are

somewhat higher at a regional and national level and become substantial at

a global level. In contrast, the costs frequently show the opposite trend:

They are significant at a local level and low at a regional and national level.

In order to allow effective conservation of biodiversity, the imbalance on

each of these levels needs to be corrected.

In this context, four measures are discussed which should lead to an

effective translation of the evaluation approaches into the creation of

markets. They concern the following:

The removal of damaging distortions of market mechanisms (deregulation)

by dismantling failed interventions. In order to establish prices that reflect

social costs, it is important to abolish all supportive measures that

artificially reduce the private costs of activities detrimental to biodiversity.

The creation of markets by privatisation and integrated biodiversity

management based on the efficiency criterion, i.e. those who control assets

Page 16: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

XII

should also be those who profit from the benefits of these assets. This could

be attained by establishing property rights to those biological resources to

which vested titles do not yet exist and/or by transferring vested titles from

the State to landowners (including those not yet entitled to land tenure due

to pending reforms).

The introduction of control instruments, in particular market-induced

instruments, in addition to regulatory ones. While the latter imply direct

control (reduction/limitation) of unwanted actions in conjunction with

legislative or politically agreed standards, market economy-based

intervention instruments (MEIs) create economic incentives. Strictly

speaking, MEIs include all political measures explicitly related to private

benefits and costs by which the comparative social benefits and costs can

be incorporated into market prices. These instruments can be subdivided

into five categories: duties/taxes/fees, subsidies, pledge systems, tradable

rights and compensatory incentives.

The creation of global environmental markets (GEMs). These markets can

be enforced by international law or can be created on the basis of voluntary

agreements. A common feature of both approaches are bilateral or

multilateral transfer payments. The particular practical relevance of

approaches used to valuate conservation, sustainable use and restoration

costs for transfer payments (e.g. transferable development rights, TDRs)

lies in the fact that these payments can be related to the amount of money

required in national and international budgets to be spent inter alia on

conservation. In this respect, it is not sufficient to provide donor countries

with financial compensation. The transfer payments must also reach those

individuals and communities immediately involved in using and preserving

the components of biological diversity in question.

Page 17: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Summary

XIII

After describing application-relevant methods and mechanisms, ten

specific recommendations are made for development cooperation (DC):

• the establishment of project-oriented cost-benefit analyses applying the

available valuation methodology for the DC projects themselves,

• training and capacity-building to inventory and monitor biodiversity in

the partner countries,

• the creation and enforcement of institutional frameworks for the

development and implementation of national biodiversity strategies,

• training and capacity-building within the partner countries to carry out

cost-benefit analyses and valuation techniques,

• the support of research capacities in developing countries at the frontier

between ecology and economics,

• the identification of failed interventions and consultation concerning

their dismantling,

• consultation on the establishment of economic incentives, especially

market-based ones,

• the development of strategies for the participation of local communities

in biodiversity yields,

• assistance in the creation of vested titles/property rights and

• cooperation in creating GEMs on the basis of bilateral and multilateral

agreements.

Page 18: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Introduction

1

1 Introduction

1.1 Description of the development cooperation project

and purpose of the project

In December 1994, with the financial support of the German Forum on

Environment and Development, the present author submitted a carefully

considered preliminary study on "Economic concepts in the valuation of

biological diversity". This study contained a short presentation and

evaluation of economic valuation concepts of biological diversity.

After discussions had been held with those involved in the Deutsche

Gesellschaft für technische Zusammenarbeit (GTZ) GmbH's Tropical

Ecology Support Programme (TÖB), this preliminary study was developed

into a final study to be translated into English and laid out in accordance

with the guidelines for TÖB research projects. Above all, it was to be

revised to enable it to be used for practical purposes: How are valuation

studies on biological diversity carried out and what methods are available

to obtain adequate payment for the determined values?

First of all, the German version of the study was therefore revised to meet

comprehensibility criteria. In order to enable it to be put to practical use, it

was also supplemented by a description of the methods used to valuate

biological diversity, procedures used for cost-benefit analyses (CBAs),

recommendations regarding the organisation of markets with appropriate

prices and supplementary recommendations for development cooperation

(DC). Finally, the revised text was translated into English.

Page 19: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

2

1.2 Analysis of problems

Biological diversity or biodiversity is the umbrella term for the number,

variety and diversity of living organisms in a certain environment and unit

of space. It is subdivided into the following order and integration levels:

• genes (and their derivatives),

• species and

• ecosystems.

On all three of these levels of integration and on a global scale, biological

diversity is decreasing at an alarming rate. This paper is based on the

hypothesis that the failure to allocate economic values to the respective

components of biological diversity is one of the causes of this decrease in

diversity. Conversely, the allocation of the appropriate economic values to

the components in question should be able to halt and even reverse this

trend.

If market prices reflected the actual value of biological resources (including

resource systems) and of their services (especially ecological ones), i.e. if

external costs were internalised and the costs of the respective resources

thus corresponded to all the values attributable to them, and if not only

their private value but also their social (and ecological) value became

apparent on the market to a sufficient degree, this notion should support

conservation and the sustainable use of biological diversity. In addition, the

socio-economic benefits of biological resources need to be determined as

comprehensively as possible and translated into marks or dollars. Even if

complete monetisation of the components of biological diversity cannot be

achieved (e.g. because access to certain goods and resources is impossible

Page 20: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Introduction

3

to monitor and control), it might nevertheless be possible to arrive at an

approximate value for these components.

1.3 Objectives

This study is concerned with existing valuations of the components of

biological diversity, i.e. those to which market prices have been assigned,

either as raw materials or as refined products. In addition, the various

methods of direct and indirect valuation that are used to try to capture the

"real" value of biological resources over and above their actual market

prices are listed and classified.

Which methods are available to determine the direct and indirect use values

of biological resources? To what extent do biological resources contribute

directly or indirectly to the economic prosperity and the socio-economic

development of political economies? Or, put differently, what is the "real"

value that authors attach to commercially used and usable biological

resources? And how do they estimate the indirect value of biological

resources, most obvious in functions such as flood protection,

photosynthesis, climate stabilisation and soil protection?

Many different approaches exist. One common procedure is the calculation

of those costs that are incurred by restoration ecology. Another procedure

is based on the market prices of biological resources using the theoretical

concept of maximum sustainable harvests. A further approach addresses

ecological and economic productivity. In this study, an attempt is made to

categorise the various approaches and to evaluate their respective deficits,

without overlooking the pitfalls of an exclusively economically oriented

valuation approach.

Page 21: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

4

On the basis of the deficits that are identified, hypotheses of quality goals,

values and costs of biological diversity are derived. Scientific, political and

economic aspects are considered in order to establish which economic

and/or monetary preconditions need to be fulfilled in order to enable

biodiversity to be conserved and restored.

Using cost-benefit analyses, the social conservation, sustainable use and

restoration of biological diversity in monetary terms and their related costs

and benefits can be compared with the private and social values of

competitive benefits and costs. The following three steps are presented:

• the consequences of these competitive scenarios are identified,

• these scenarios are quantified in terms of their respective economic

benefits and costs and

• cost-benefit analyses are summarised and compared.

However, even if this comparison favours the conservation alternative, this

does not yet result in a conservation effect. This can only happen if the

actual use value and its cost advantages become visible on the market in

market prices. This can be accomplished as follows:

• by creating markets for the components of biological diversity,

• by using free market instruments to correct the existing price

imbalances,

by using regulatory interventions to impose balancing effects that even a

functioning market could not achieve.

This also raises the question of financing instruments that could generate

the crucial incentive for the conservation, sustainable use or restoration of

Page 22: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Introduction

5

biological diversity at a national and international level. The concluding

discussion concerns how financial instruments that already exist or that are

in preparation should be considered and how they should be developed or

modified.

This paper is organised as follows:

Following this introductory chapter, the second chapter on "Results and

Analysis" highlights the loss of biodiversity under the aspect of the lack of

markets and of market failure. It is postulated that a market-oriented

valuation of the components of biological diversity would help to counter

this loss. To this end, types of values of the components of biological

diversity are then subdivided into different use-dependent and use-

independent categories. Finally, actual and target values of genes, species

and ecosystems are presented and illustrated using examples.

In the third chapter on "Recommendations", methods are presented to

valuate biological diversity for the different use values. The second section

of this chapter deals with the cost aspect of conservation and presents the

instrument of cost-benefit analysis. In the third section, measures are

discussed which should lead to an effective translation of the evaluation

approaches into the creation of markets. These measures are developed into

recommendations for DC.

Page 23: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Results and Analysis

7

2 Results and Analysis

2.1 Decrease in biodiversity as a consequence of the lack

of markets and of market failure

The notion that economic well-being may not be impaired and that it may

even be enhanced if the profits obtained by depleting natural capital are

reinvested in reproducible capital is not particularly new in the literature on

theoretical economics. It has been suggested that reinvestment of the profits

derived from the intertemporal efficient use of exhaustible natural

resources in reproducible and hence non-exhaustible capital will ensure a

constant stream of consumption over time (e.g. Hartwick 1977; Solow

1974, 1986).

In the context of ecological crisis, however, the increasing rate of loss of

biological resources has led to a fundamental reappraisal of the role of the

living environment in the economy in recent years. Biodiversity is now

increasingly regarded as a form of natural capital that supports economic

activities. In Art. 2 of the Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD),

biological diversity is therefore defined as "variability among living

organisms from all sources including, inter alia, terrestrial, marine and

other aquatic ecosystems and the ecological complexes of which they are

part". This definition "includes variety within species, between species and

of ecosystems". In the same passage, biological resources are characterised

as including "genetic resources, organisms or parts thereof, populations or

any other biotic component of ecosystems with actual or potential use or

value for humanity".

In order for biological diversity and resources to be able to contribute to

general prosperity, their economic yields have to become comparable to

Page 24: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

8

and higher than competitive sources. In other words, if the yields from

investments that reduce the natural capital are higher than those that sustain

it, the consumption of natural capital is economically justified (Barbier et

al. 1994, pp. 53f.).

This economic justification, however, is currently disappearing. Market

prices of biological resources do not reflect the true value of these

resources because they do not include external costs and benefits. The

failure to include such external effects in the price is an indication of

market failure.

This market failure can have different causes:

• Difference between private and social benefits: Where components of

biological diversity are traded on markets, their market prices usually

reflect only the private benefits and not the social (and ecological)

benefits that are attributable to them in different degrees from the local

to the global level. The assignment of market prices to marketed

components of biological diversity thus does not mean that these prices

reflect their actual economic values. Partially reliable methods to

establish the social value of the components of biological diversity are

lacking. Above all, there are no mechanisms that permit the integration

of such valuation results into market prices.

• Lack of property rights to components of biological diversity or the

discounting problem, i.e. preference of a currently available private use,

which involves social destruction, over a private use in the future, which

also involves social preservation, makes it more difficult to find a

solution to this problem.

Page 25: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Results and Analysis

9

• Lack of markets: The problem is not only that only certain attributes of

the biological components that are traded on markets are included in

market prices, but that most biological resources and ecological services

are not traded on markets at all, while there are markets for alternative

uses. The market does not take into account anthropogenic influences on

biological diversity or the effects of biological diversity on humans.

Local and/or global markets for the relevant components of biological

diversity in which the market subjects could convert their value

conceptions of biological/ecological goods and services into purchases

and sales by aid of the price mechanism are lacking.

• Interventions failures: Additional market failures as a consequence of

politic failure, e.g. by disincentives (e.g. subsidies, direct income

transfers, tax exemptions), making existing markets inefficient and

favouring the depreciation or destruction of biological resources (clear-

cutting, cultivation of certain species, nutrient supplies detrimental to

the ecosystem).

Despite these limitations, the ability of the market to bring private and

social benefits closer together and to contribute to a reduction of the threat

to biological diversity should not be underestimated. "Finally, the quality of

an allocation mechanism (= mechanism for the allocation of productive

factors or resources to certain goals) may not exclusively be judged on the

basis of a comparison of its results with ideal results, which are ultimately

not attainable by any allocation mechanism (the so-called Nirvana

approach). (...) Since in reality only incompletely functioning allocation

mechanisms are available, it is worth asking what the market may

contribute in pragmatic terms to taking care of natural resources" (Endres

and Querner 1993, p. 139). By setting prices that reflect the real economic

Page 26: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

10

value, the social interest in the conservation of biological resources

becomes translatable into an individual interest.

Overcoming this market failure therefore implies the following:

• the inclusion of the social values and costs of biological diversity in

market prices,

• the creation of markets for the value-oriented mobilisation of demand

for and supply of biological resources and

• the abolition of price-distorting political and economic interventions.

The benefit that a certain component of biological diversity gives its

consumers governs the purchase decision (e.g. pharmacologically

exploitable resource, resource that can be exploited in tourism) and thus

also the price. This benefit corresponds to the value that a potential

consumer attaches to the respective component. One of the most important

tasks of the monetisation of biological diversity is therefore to reflect this

benefit and/or value in the market price. The appropriate methodology will

be dealt with in a later section.

According to Hampicke (1991, pp. 104f.), regarding biological diversity in

economic and monetary terms obviously does not mean dealing with the

monetary value of a species or nature on its own ("this kind of monetisation

approach would not be allowed"). The question is actually how much it

would cost to stop destruction of these resources and/or to re-establish their

maximum possible functional capacity. "It cannot be agreed that this goes

beyond the borders of what is admissible in monetary analyses. The

criticism not infrequently expressed by the public that this kind of

monetisation can only be based on misunderstandings could be avoided if

people listened more carefully to what most economists really said." "If a

Page 27: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Results and Analysis

11

level of nature conservation is postulated that makes nature almost

inviolable, then in economic terms this means that it is not possible to fall

below this minimum level of species conservation even against paying

demand - in purely mathematical terms, the price of this is infinitely high.

It would only be at our disposal if the costs of nature conservation were

unreasonably high, which might be interpreted as meaning that they are so

high they cannot be expressed in monetary terms – e.g. if human lives have

to be sacrificed. Then a decision must be made between two non-

monetisable alternatives, a decision nobody would be envied for having to

make."

2.2 Classification of the types of values of biological

diversity

The demand for biological goods results from the different value

preferences of market subjects. Use values are relative and linked to market

subjects and their preferences, i.e. all decisions on political allocation result

in opportunity costs (i.e. the costs of alternatives that are not used). In cost-

benefit analyses (see Sect. 3.2.2), the alternatives can then be weighed up

against each other. The social value of biological resources or services is

thus composed of four categories of use value:

Use-dependent values

1. The direct value of biological resources or resource systems is derived

from their direct use (by consumption or production) or from their direct

interaction with market subjects. Some biological resources are traded on

markets, and their direct use values (e.g. agriculturally useful plants and

animals, wood, medicinal plants, wildlife watching) are included in their

market prices. Expenditure on the use of ecosystems for tourism, hunting

Page 28: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

12

or fishing also reflects their direct market values. As already mentioned,

these market prices are incomplete, because they do not take account of

certain social value attributes.

2. The indirect value of biological resources or services results from the

value that these have for directly used resources or ecosystems. Many

biological resources derive their value from their indirect economic

importance for directly used resources. Indirect values result from (a)

their benefit for other directly used species and/or their genes (indirect

biocoenotic value), (b) their importance for ecological services, e.g.

protection from erosion, assimilation of biological waste materials,

microclimatic stabilisation, water retention, carbon storage (indirect

ecosystem value), and (c) their importance for future evolution (indirect

evolutionary value).

3. The option use value describes a use reserved for a later time. The option

to use biological resources at a later date is kept open by value

assignment. The quasi-option value refers to the delay of an irreversible

decision to wait for additional information to help in the decision-

making process. Because future information connected with the resource

in question may be valuable, this resource remains untouched for the

time being. Due to gaps in our knowledge, it can be difficult to assess

risks and uncertainties when carrying out an evaluation; together with

the partially irreversible consequences of the alternative use of the

components of biological diversity, this means that the concept of the

quasi-option value is becoming increasingly important.

Use-independent values

4. The passive use value of biological diversity results from the importance

attributed to it for us, our descendants or other species. It can be

Page 29: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Results and Analysis

13

subdivided into its bequest value (the value of keeping a resource intact

for future generations) and its existence value (the value conferred by

ensuring the survival of a resource). The non-use or passive use value of

biological resources is nearly completely determined by ethical

considerations and is of importance where individuals who do not intend

to use components of biological diversity would nevertheless feel a loss

if these disappeared (Brown 1990; Randall 1991).

The direct value, indirect value, option/quasi-option value and passive use

value of resources or resource systems add up to give their total economic

value (TEV, Fig. 1).

TEV = F (DUV, IUV, OV, QOV, BV, EV)

TEV = UV + NUV = (DUV + IUV + OV + QOV) + (BV + EV)

TEV: Total economic value

UV: Use value

NUV: Non-use value

DUV: Direct use value

IUV: Indirect use value

OP: Option value

QOV: Quasi-option value

BV: Bequest value

EV: Existence value

There is some overlap between the different types of values, which means

that there is a risk of the same value attributes being counted more than

Fig. 1: Total economic value of a biological asset

Page 30: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

14

once in different value categories. This is particularly true of option,

bequest and existence values. However, there are different concepts in

economics of how the valuations of environmental changes should be

aggregated in order to arrive at an overall economic evaluation.

ad 1.Many biological resources are traded directly on local or international

markets. This suggests that some direct use values of biological

resources will be reflected in the prices of marketed goods and

services. However, because subjects (individuals, public and private

institutions, companies) can more readily perceive the economic value

of marketed products and services of biological resources than the

value of non-commercial and direct subsistence uses, the result may

be a bias towards the development of the commercial use and an

exploitation of biological resources. This may mean not only that

commercial fishery, forestry and agricultural operations, for example,

may be preferred to subsistence operations or to a philosophy of

nature conservation involving doing nothing, but also that many

natural ecosystems and habitats may also be converted to other

monetisable direct uses (Perrings 1995, p. 866).

The user value, for instance, is a typical non-monetised direct use

value, corresponding to the individual personal benefit of biological

diversity, e.g. by observing or photographing nature or being

stimulated to carry out artistic activities. Where this direct use value is

commercialised (e.g. by charging fees for wildlife watching), it

becomes a serious alternative to other price-related direct uses (e.g.

hunting).

However, the explicit view of the direct use value shows that a value-

related consideration of non-monetised direct alternative uses is

Page 31: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Results and Analysis

15

necessary in order to give them a fair chance on the market. (On the

creation of markets by monetisation, see Sect. 3.3).

ad 2.The indirect use value of a particular component of biological

diversity is not usually taken into account by market prices. Its

expression in monetary terms becomes more realistic the more

indirect the particular use is. While an indirect biocoenotic use of soil

micro-organisms (e.g. Leguminosae are associated with nitrogen-

fixing bacteria) for the direct use of legumes is relatively easy to

derive, the central ecological role that elephants play in the

diversification of African savannas and forests, the spreading of seeds,

the prevention of scrubland, the expansion of grassland and the

reduction in numbers of the tsetse fly is considerably more difficult to

quantify, and indirect ecological use values, in particular, do not

readily lend themselves to direct economic assessment. Determining

these use values by value preferences becomes increasingly difficult

and ultimately impossible due to the complexity of the object and of

system properties that are emerging in the light of present ecological

knowledge.

ad 3.Difficult theoretical calculations in decision-making suggest that

decisions with irreversible results should be examined particularly

carefully in terms of possible consequences; moreover, in situations in

which there is both an irreversible and a reversible alternative, the

reversible one should be chosen. While the basic idea of the option

value is to maintain access options on components of biological

diversity that are not used at present, the idea of the quasi-option value

is to use expenditure on biodiversity conservation to diminish

uncertainty and/or to avoid irreversible decisions (Hampicke 1991,

pp. 87f.). The difficult methodical question here is how much society

Page 32: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

16

should pay for the conservation of components of biological diversity

that might one day become useful.

ad 4.The bequest value is often included in the existence value, and the

user value is sometimes added to these two values, reflecting the

personal benefits of biological diversity. Since there is some overlap

between these value types, these value components should be

determined as a holistic non-use or passive use value.

The more aspects of use value that can be determined and integrated into

the TEV, the closer it comes to representing the "real" value of biological

goods or services. In particular, due to the aspects of passive use and option

value, the TEV is subject to group- and culture-dependent differences.

Above all, however, the TEV remains a theoretical variable unless it is

reflected by market prices.

In addition to the relativity of values and prices on the user level, further

limitations result from the usability of the respective resources. The use

value includes the following:

a) the extent to which biological resources can be used for different

purposes (transformability),

b) the extent to which they are replaceable by other resources

(substitutability) and

c) whether the use of biological resources by a market subject impairs the

use of these or other resources by other market subjects (rival usability,

sustainability criterion).

Page 33: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Results and Analysis

17

However, market prices are not only based on demand and the value

preferences of market subjects it indicates. The market prices of biological

resources are also determined by

d) supply and by exclusivity of their usability, i.e. by (actual and

intellectual) property rights and their effectiveness. Purely public goods

(e.g. air, water) or a jointly usable resources pool (e.g. the welfare effects

of the forest) can in fact be attributed with values, but because they are

not scarce, they remain outside the market.

Figure 2 shows the relation between the sustainability criterion (c) and the

supply aspect (d).

Others cannot be excluded

from the use of resources

Others can be excluded

from the use of resources

Use of resources by A does not

influence consumption by

others

Purely public goods

Resources under

Jointly usable resource pool

(e.g. national) sovereignty

Use of resources by A does

influence consumption by

others

Private goods

ad a-c)The values of competitively usable resources have to be determined

in separate valuation steps and be evaluated comparatively in cost-

benefit analyses (see Sect. 3.2.2). Their results differ particularly due

to the conflict between interests of private and social use. It is the

dominance of private use interests in the market that frequently

Fig. 2: Classification of resources

Page 34: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

18

constitutes a threat to biological diversity. Markets and market prices

exist for purely privately used goods, but not for purely public goods.

ad d) When the Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD) came into

force, exclusive national rights of use and property were created for

the large majority of biological resources.

Use rights to biological resources that are privately owned are purely

exclusive. However, there is still some controversy over a whole range

of biological resources and their services as to whether the use rights

should be exclusively private or national. Vogel (1994) correctly

acknowledges that it is only through consistent privatisation of

biological resources that an interest in sustainability can become

generally accepted against alternative uses.

Before the CBD came into effect, those of the earth's biological

resources that are now subject to national sovereignty were treated as

the common heritage of mankind and thus as non-exclusively usable,

freely accessible resources. Now that the CBD has come into force,

the number of non-exclusive biological resources has decreased

considerably. Resources that are still non-exclusively usable include

marine biology resources outside national sovereignty zones.

Ecological services of biological diversity are usually also non-

exclusively usable (e.g. the production of oxygen by green plants).

A gradual transition is taking place between exclusively privately

usable biological resources and (the few) completely non-exclusively

usable resources freely accessible to the public. The items "resources

under national sovereignty" and "jointly usable resource pool" in

Fig. 2 are the quasi-exclusive and/or quasi-non-exclusive links

between these extremes. In determining use values, it is important to

Page 35: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Results and Analysis

19

make value preferences much more visible in markets by means of

property interests.

Regardless of whether a local, national or global perspective is taken,

normative valuation approaches have to be integrated into the TEV of

biological resources in order to take proper account of rights of access and

property, unless the goods concerned are public ones.

At the beginning of this paper, the hierarchical division of biological

resources into the levels of genes, species and ecosystems was presented.

TEVs can be determined on each of these three levels (and on further

intermediate levels). However, the TEV of a gene or a biochemical will

obviously not be suitable to show the TEV of its host species, and the TEV

of a species (or a biocoenosis) is not sufficient to illustrate the value of the

respective ecosystem. To use an analogy, the total value of a screw cannot

be used deduce the value of an engine, the value of an engine cannot be

used to determine the value of an aeroplane and the value of an aeroplane

does not indicate the value of an airport. The significance of economic

valuation depends on the integration level on which it was carried out.

In this respect, it is not surprising that particular attention is paid to the

application of economic valuation approaches at the level of the ecosystem

(Barbier et al. 1994). If cost-benefit analyses (see Sect. 3.2.2) of an

ecosystem's TEV result in the conservation option, this also includes a

number of components of biological diversity on the lower integration

levels for which individual TEVs do not need to be determined (and which

would presumably not be technically feasible). If cost-benefit analyses of

an ecosystem result in the options sustainable use, restoration or alternative

use, then supplementing the TEV on lower hierarchical levels may become

Page 36: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

20

necessary in order to arrive at evaluations or specific management

recommendations for specific populations or genetic resources.

Economic valuations of biological resources of the lower levels can of

course lead to effects that make a TEV on a higher integration level

superfluous. In addition, depending on the economic question concerned,

dealing with objects on a lower level of the hierarchy can lead to

synergistic results that are relevant for higher levels as well. For instance,

screening all the higher plants of an ecosystem for pharmacological

ingredients may have a direct ecosystem-sustaining effect, while interest in

one specific gene will only generate marginal conservation effects, if any.

Furthermore, the notion of a so-called primary value has also been

introduced; this is added to the TEV (i.e. the secondary value) to give the

total environmental value (TV). It represents properties of an ecosystem or

biosphere that are highly relevant in economic terms, but that cannot be

captured by value preferences. Whether it will be possible to express it in

economic terms at all is contentious (see Perrings 1995, pp. 842f.). There is

no clear-cut distinction between this and the indirect use value, and it is

therefore not discussed separately here. The properties of its system should

be integrated in the indirect use value.

The central importance of these values for monetisation approaches,

however, is undisputed. Immler (1993) states that "the productive natural

capital is the key category in a holistic ecological/economic valuation". In

answer to the objection that economics does not offer the tools for

operationalising pricing, he rightly points out that "any approximation to

this admittedly difficult unit is better and more reasonable than an

operational term which is certainly wrong" and that "the lack of industrial

understanding of the category 'natural capital' is not the consequence of a

Page 37: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Results and Analysis

21

nature that cannot be understood, but of an economics that does not want to

know anything about it".

One method of approximation is the production-function approach. The

transformation of ecological value units into economic ones could be

successful on the basis of productivity, both an ecological and an economic

concept. Ecological productivity (net and gross primary production) has a

theoretically assignable (potential) maximum, which could be defined as

the productivity of the primary ecosystems ("world-wide wilderness

productivity") and/or by the theoretical productivity of ecosystems after the

sudden end of human influences ("potential natural productivity").

Cultivated ecological systems may obviously show the same net

productivity (agricultural areas including external fertiliser supply) but a

smaller gross productivity than autochthonous ecosystems. (Due to the

ecological degradation phenomena such as nutrient washing and soil

erosion that accompany the creation of cultivated ecological systems,

however, their net primary production also diminishes over time; 20% of

cultivable soil has been lost over the past 30 years world-wide). Even back

in 1986, humans consumed 40% of the global terrestrial net primary

production (Vitousek et al. 1986).

However, even if ecosystems were ranked by determining their TEVs, this

would not correspond to ecologically specified rankings (e.g. on the basis

of productivity criteria). This is partially because of the inclusion of non-

use values (whereby a mountainous region that is not particularly

productive, but attractive might gain a higher monetary value than a highly

productive grassland, for example). However, it is primarily due to the fact

that there are at present still no methods or scientific information to

approximate the actual indirect use value. For instance, we need to

understand the role of species in mediating the key structuring processes in

Page 38: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

22

ecosystems over a range of environmental conditions. This requires

ecological and economic production functions to be specified (Perrings

1995, p. 889).

It also requires not just snapshots of the value of ecosystem function, but

also time series that show how the value of such functions is changing. Not

only the ecological aspect, but also the evolutionary component is not taken

into consideration sufficiently in economic valuation approaches of

biological diversity, although awareness of the value of the genetic

resources of plants and their relatives in the wild has risen in economic

terms as well, implicitly acknowledging its importance (see e.g. Mooney

and Fowler 1991). However, it is only by regarding natural ecosystems in

economic terms as durable in situ production, experimentation and storage

sites of biodiversity evolution that conservationists' expectations linked to

bioprospecting strategies can have a chance of being realised.

2.3 Examples of evaluating biological diversity

This section deals with estimates of the value of genes, species and

ecosystems arrived at using the valuation methods described previously and

methodologically illustrated in Sect. 3.1 (see Perrings 1995, pp. 844 ff.).

2.3.1 Use value of genes and biochemicals

Whereas the utilisation of genes (animal and plant breeding) or natural

products used to be linked to the cultivation of the respective species, new

biotechnologies now permit genes and biochemicals to be utilised

independently of their parent species, e.g. in cell cultures or transgenic

organisms. This makes the examples discussed in this section different

from product examples such as ivory or timber, whose use remains bound

to the species producing them. However, the borders between the two types

Page 39: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Results and Analysis

23

are transient, and it may be more profitable not to make use of these

biotechnological options and to obtain certain natural products from

complete (cultivated or wild living) individuals of the species of origin.

The direct use value of genetic diversity results from delivering the raw

material with desirable properties for the pharmaceutical, agricultural and

food production industry. Modern biotechnology and genetic engineering

(with the potential for intra- and inter-species gene transfer they offer)

allow the use potential of genetic resources to be extended and therefore

lead economically to an increase and/or a supplementary effect to the direct

use value of genetic resources and their derivatives (natural products).

The size of the market for biotechnologically manufactured products

world-wide is now more than US $250 billion per year, and private

biotechnological research and development (R&D) investments in the

countries of the Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development

(OECD) amount to approximately US $9 billion per year. The annual

growth rates vary between 8% (biotechnological processes) and 20%-35%

(gene technology processes). For example, the United States' proceeds of

sale in 1992 amounted to approximately US $5 billion, i.e. a 35% increase

compared to the previous year (Burrill and Lee 1992; cited in Downes

1993). For the year 2000, a tenfold increase is expected (Industrial

Biotechnology Association 1992; cited in Downes 1993).

Like the existing and potential market prices specified in the following

examples, these are usually distorted by transfer components, and

corrections therefore have to be made for economic cost calculations (cf.

Hampicke 1991, pp. 180f.). Above all, however, the obtained or attainable

price for the respective biological resources is not determined ecologically,

but solely on the basis of market criteria.

Page 40: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

24

Nevertheless, conservation effects on biological resources can arise from

the presence or development of a market (although the opposite can also

occur). Thus bioprospecting projects are associated with the idea that the

identification (via bioassays) and development of useful biochemicals and

genes might result in a market that exerts conservation effects on concrete

resources in situ with optional conservation effects on other resources in

the same habitat that are not yet commercially exploited. According to

Sánchez and Juma (1994), the exchange of genetic resources and

technologies between the North and the South should increase to about

10% of the respective world trade volume.

Some authors have published papers about the commercial value of genetic

resources. However, some of these data are questionable, because indirect

or passive use values were hardly integrated into these valuations and

TEVs are also lacking. As far as direct use options are concerned,

pharmacological or agricultural uses of genes and biochemicals have been

dealt with more intensely, whereas enzyme use or the genetic resources of

ornamental plants, for example, have been largely neglected.

A study by Sedjo et al. (1994) addresses prospecting strategies for genetic

resources by comparing them with a lottery. Neither the prize nor the

possible number of main winners among whom the prize is finally divided

is known, and it is not clear whether numbers are drawn for which no

tickets have been submitted. This comparison highlights the unknown

spatial distribution of organisms and the uncertainty about whether the

relevant gene or biomolecule might also be found in other organisms. Due

to genetic engineering, the market for genetic resources is developing into

new segments, and it is not known how scarce most biological resources

actually are; the willingness of industry to pay high prices for biomolecules

is thus relatively small. The study by Sedjo and colleagues concludes that,

Page 41: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Results and Analysis

25

under optimal conditions, a maximum economic yield of US $10,000 per

species might result. With respect to endangered habitats in which the

relevant species exist, a maximum of $20 per hectare might be paid.

On the basis of respective contracts, prospecting companies have so far

been willing to pay approximately $50-200 per unprocessed in situ sample

(Laird 1993). However, it would be too simplistic to infer the market value

of the genetic material from these amounts, because it is primarily the

labour-intensive collection that is paid for and not the material itself.

Pharmacologically useful biomolecules

According to a study by the OECD (1987), about 25% of all medicaments

in the OECD countries are of plant origin; if we include those countries that

are not industrially developed, the overall world-wide proportion increases

to 75%. In the OECD member countries, plant-based medicaments

amounting to more than DM 100 billion were sold in 1985. Two fifths of

all modern U.S. pharmaceutical products contain one or more ingredients

of natural origin (Oldfield 1984).

The commercial value of medicines derived from species living in the wild

is estimated at more than US $40 billion p.a. world-wide, and the figure for

the United States in 1980 was US $8112 billion. The present share of the

genetic material used for pharmaceutical products originating from the

South amounts to about US $4.7 billion. The present hectare yields of

medicinal plants from the tropical rain forest are estimated to range from

$262 to $1000 (Pearce and Moran 1994).

Assuming a rate of extinction of 10%, an estimated 2067 plant species will

have become extinct by the year 2000, 16 of them of special

Page 42: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

26

pharmaceutical interest; Farnsworth and Soejarto (1985) have estimated

this to entail an economic loss of US $3.25 billion ($16×203 million).

By means of bioprospecting, i.e. screening biological diversity in search of

commercially exploitable genetic and biochemical resources, the value of

the germ plasm for medicinal purposes from the South, which currently

amounts to approximately US $4.7 billion, might rise over the next

10 years to US $47 billion. For Costa Rica, Aylward (1993) estimated the

value of "pharmaceutical prospecting" at $4.81 million per successfully

prospected product. However, these figures have to be related to capital

outlays of over US $200 million for the development of a single successful

pharmaceutical ready for the market (Krattiger and Lesser 1994).

Mendelsohn and Balick (1995) are sceptical regarding the future economic

importance of bioprospecting. They estimate the entire social value of non-

discovered tropical pharmaceuticals at only approximately US $150 billion

or US $48 per hectare, and the market value for private enterprises at US

$3 billion or US $1 per hectare.

A rough estimation of the pharmaceutical value of extinct plant species on

behalf of UNEP came to the conclusion that the average "pharmaceutical"

loss for each of these species amounts to approximately $80,000 (UNEP

1993). This figure is problematic, however, because some "best-sellers"

that have earned the companies that sell them millions (e.g. aspirin, taxol)

are included in this estimate.

Genetic resources of plants

The complexity of modern and traditional breeding practices means that

only a very general approximation of the actual monetary value is possible,

and even then only for the most common grain varieties. This uncertainty

Page 43: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Results and Analysis

27

in putting a number on the existing market value is reflected in estimations

concerning the contribution of the genetic resources of the South to the

valuation of food production in the North. For wheat and corn, the figures

are estimated at US $75 million p.a. for Australia, US $500 million p.a. for

the United States and US $2.7 billion p.a. for all the OECD countries

together (Mooney and Fowler 1991). According to Woodruff and Gall

(1992), about half of the increase in agricultural productivity in this century

can be directly attributed to artificial selection, recombination and intra-

species gene transfer.

Calculations by the U.S. seed industry show that a genetic trait of a plant in

the Third World that can be used for breeding purposes may contribute

over $2 billion annually to the yields of U.S. wheat, rice and corn

producers. The U.S. Department of Agriculture estimates that genetic plant

material has led to an average increase in productivity of about 1% a year,

with an initial monetary value far exceeding US $1.billion.

Bioprospecting as a source of new cultivated plants and of raw materials to

breed improved plant varieties and as a supplier of natural pesticides and

renewable resources such as fibres and botanical chemicals has great

potential (Plotkin 1992).

At the beginning of the next millennium, the world-wide biotechnology

food sector will increase to US $20 billion (a sixfold increase).

Page 44: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

28

Components used Evaluation methodapplied

Estimatedvalue (US $)

Source

Plants Market analysis:estimations of

proceeds of sale

2,580,000 Farnsworth andSoejarto 1985

Plants Market analysis 474,000 Principe 1989Trees Market analysis 7,500 McAllister 1991Plants Evaluation of the

number of lives saved23,700,000 Principe 1989

Species from Cameroon Costs of renewingpatents

15-150 Ruitenbeek1989

Species from Costa Rica Market analysis,estimated licence fees

253 HarvardBusiness School

Plants of the rain forest Market analysis andevaluation of human

lives saved

585-1,050,000 Pearce andPuroshothaman

1992Pharmaceutical bioprospecting for acommercially successful plantproduct

Market analysis: netreturns on

bioprospecting

4.81 million Aylward 1993

Living organisms Market analysis:returns on purchase +

licence fees

52-46,000 Reid et al. 1993

2.3.2 Use value of species

In contrast to Sect. 2.3.1., the components of biological diversity dealt with

in this section are used as total organisms.

Use of plants

Of the approximately 250,000 higher plant species that have been described

world-wide, about one third probably has edible components, i.e. around

80,000 species. About 15,000 species (including spice plants, herbs, etc.)

Table 1: Use values of genes and biochemicals

Page 45: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Results and Analysis

29

are actually used for human nutrition (Heywood 1994, personal

communication). Supraregionally or world-wide, about 150 species are

cultivated for human nutrition. However, only five varieties of grain

(wheat, corn, rice, barley and millet) account for 50% of vegetable nutrition

in humans, and 20 species supply 90% of the world-wide demand (Myers

1989).

The quantity of renewable resources currently used and processed world-

wide amounts to approximately 2 billion tons of timber, 2 billion tons of

grain (including the food supply) and 2 billion tons of other products such

as sugar-cane, carrots, oil and leguminous plants. The global timber trade is

worth approximately $80 billion annually.

According to Peters et al. (1989), the present net value of sustainably used

biological raw materials (rubber, fruits, wood) from the rain forest in Peru

amounts to $6330 per hectare, i.e. more than sixfold the value of utilisable

wood ($490/ha). In the German chemical industry, about 2 million tons of

renewable resources are utilised at present (i.e. 10% of the entire

consumption of raw materials).

Use of game animals

Prescott-Allen and Prescott-Allen (1986) estimate the monetary

contributions of wild and semi-wild animals and plants as accounting for

approximately 4% of the gross national product (GNP) in the United States

and Canada. Barnes and Pearce (1991) have shown that the direct use value

of certain forms of wildlife management is financially more productive

than the transformation of game reserves into pasture areas (cf. Table 2).

Page 46: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

30

Components of biodiversityused

Evaluationmethod applied

Estimatedvalue (US $)

Source

Wildlife watching value of elephants,Kenya

CVM; travel costmethod

25million/year

Brown and Henry 1989

Ivory exports before the export ban,Africa

35-35million/year

Barbier et al. 1990

Use of wild buffaloes, Zimbabwe 3.5-4.5/ha Child 1990Export of non-coniferous woodproducts, entire tropics

11 billion/year Barbier et al. 1994

Harvest of wood fruits and latex,Peru

6330/ha Peters et al. 1989

Fish and firewood from wetlands,Nigeria

38-59/ha Barbier et al. 1991

Improvement of the survivalprobability of the Northern spottedowl

CRM 21/person andyear

Brown et al. 1994

CVM, contingent valuation method; CRM, contingent ranking method.

2.3.3 Use value of ecosystems and landscapes

Ecological resources and services that can be derived from the production,

carrier and information functions of ecosystems produce economic yields

in the form of direct use values. Direct use values include timber and non-

wood products, medicinal plants, plant genes, hunting and fishery,

recreation and tourism, education and human living areas, since all these

products and services are the result of a direct use of forests. Direct use

presupposes access to forest resources, among other things.

In contrast, indirect use does not require access to forest resources. The

most important indirect use values of biological diversity include the

regulatory functions of ecosystems. Each ecosystem is composed of a

Table 2: Use values of species

Page 47: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Results and Analysis

31

whole range of physical, biological and chemical components. Interaction

between these components results in specific types of ecosystem functions

or characteristics such as the nutrient cycle, biological productivity, water

regime and sedimentation. These regulatory ecological functions are

fundamental to numerous secondary ecological functions and services,

which again are of fundamental importance in human life and societies

(e.g. erosion protection, water retention, detoxification, assimilation of

biological waste, climatic stabilisation, carbon storage).

As far as the role of individual species in the mediation of such regulatory

functions is understood, it is principally possible to establish the indirect

use value of such species. Indeed, the relationship between individual

organisms and ecosystem functioning is of central importance in the

concept of indirect use valuation.

Immler (1989) assumes that roughly a third of GNP (based on the German

GNP) would be necessary to re-establish the disturbed non-human natural

services and processes.

Most studies assessing the economic value of forests only take account of

partial values and not the TEV (for a relevant review, see Perrings 1995,

pp. 886f.). Indirect and non-use values are usually completely neglected,

and direct use values are also frequently only incompletely considered.

The first attempt to estimate the TEV of tropical forest habitats was

undertaken by Castro (1994). Castro calculated an average net actual value

of $1278-$2871 per hectare for Costa Rica's game wilderness. Multiplied

by the total area of 1.3 million hectares, this gave a present total value of

$1.7-$3.7 billion, of which, according to this study, 34% benefits Costa

Rica and 66% the world community.

Page 48: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

32

Kaosard et al. (1994) evaluated not the total, but almost the total economic

value of the Khao Yai Park in Thailand (not including non-use values for

people who do not live in Thailand and estimations of carbon storage). The

comparative evaluation with agriculturally managed areas arrived at a

figure of $250 per hectare (see Table 3).

Barbier et al. (1991) showed that the direct use of the Hadejia Jama'are

floodplain in Nigeria for fishery, the production of firewood and migration

agriculture results in economic yields that are higher than alternative

irrigation projects upstream.

Page 49: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Results and Analysis

33

Components used Evaluation methodapplied

Estimated value(US $)

Source

Nature tourism, Cameroon: 19/ha Ruitenbeek 1989Sustaining soil fertility byforests and inundationcontrol, Cameroon

Productivity change 8/ha and 23/ha Ruitenbeek 1989

Khao Yai Park, Thailand CVM, travel costmethod

80 million/year,400/ha/year

Kaosard et al.1994

Ecotourism, Costa Rica Travel cost method 1250/ha Tobias andMendelsohn 1991

Importance of wetlands forcrab production, ArabianSea

Production-functionapproach

Ellis and Fisher1987

Valuation of reserves,Madagascar

Production-functionapproach, CVM, travel

cost method

566,070-2,160,000 Munasinghe 1993;Kramer et al. 1993

Carbon storage by forests,Brazil

1300/ha/year Pearce 1990

Importance of mangrovesfor agriculture, fishery,Indonesia

536 million Ruitenbeek 1992

Water retention by forests,USA

232-388/acre Bowes andKrutilla 1989

Forest in Peru, Rio Nanay Productivity method(comparisons of

income)

6300/ha for non-timber products

vs. 1000 for clear-cutting

Peters et al. 1989

Primeval forest, Costa Rica TEV 102-214/ha/year,1278-2871/ha,

133-278million/year, 1.7-

3.7 billion

Castro 1994

Table 3: Use values of ecosystems

Page 50: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

35

3 Recommendations

3.1 Valuation methods and techniques

Because of the benefits of biological diversity and the lack of information

about these benefits due to market failure, there is an urgent need for

economic valuation studies to be carried out. In the following, relevant

valuation methods are thus presented. Arguments in favour of their

application include the following:

• they give valuable information on how markets need to be reformed in

order to correct the present bias and/or, where this is not possible,

• they provide decision-making aids indicating political measures that

should be taken to correct market signals.

When applying these valuation methods, however, it is important to

remember what is actually being measured by the valuation technique, e.g.

direct use benefits, net benefits including use and non-use benefits, etc.,

and the reliability of the different data and methodologies in assessing these

different benefits yields (Perrings 1995, p. 878).

As Fig. 3 shows, the use value categories "direct use values", "indirect use

values", "option/quasi-option values" and "non-use values", which together

give the TEV, allow the application of various valuation methods. In the

following, these methods are presented and the range of effects to be

valued is considered.

Not all of these methods are able to completely determine biodiversity-

related costs and benefits. Each of them, however, is useful in the correct

Page 51: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

36

context. Roughly speaking, we can differentiate between monetisation

methods as follows (see OECD 1996, p. 74):

• on the basis of actual market prices (market analyses),

• on the basis of simulated market prices (contingent valuation and

ranking; individual choice model),

• on the basis of surrogate market prices (e.g. the travel cost approach and

hedonic price approach) and

• on the basis of the production-function approach (e.g. value of changes

of productivity, avoided damage costs).

Since, in the context of this study, we are interested in the external use

values of biological diversity that are not reflected by actual market prices,

the subsequent discussion is limited to valuation approaches for simulated

markets (Sect. 3.1), surrogate markets (Sect. 3.2) and the production-

function approach (Sect. 3.3). The common instrument of market analysis

is therefore not discussed here.

The presently available set of valuation methods show very large

differences not only in valuation methodology, but also in their

conceptional treatment of the problem. For instance, there is still no

consensus on how to determine the existence value (Perrings 1995, p. 891).

These methods presuppose acceptance by those with political

responsibility. They have to guarantee that the monetisation requirements

that are identified become economically effective by income transmissions,

taxes, etc.

Page 52: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

37

<Replacement costapproach etc.>

'Public' prices

Hedonic prices

Contingent valuationmethod

Travel costmethod

Market analysis

METHODS:

Direct use values

<Replacement costapproach>

<Transplantationcosts>

Value of productivitychanges

Prophylacticexpenses

Avoideddamage costs

METHODS:

Indirect use values(functional values)

Contingent valuationmethod

Restrictedinformation value

'Individual choice'model

METHODS:

Option valuesQuasi-option values

Use values

Contingent valuationmethod

METHODS:

Existence valuesBequest values

Non-use values

Figure 3 highlights the particular importance of the contingent valuation

method (CVM); this method allows statements to be made about all use

value categories with the exception of the indirect use value. Indeed, it is

the only useful method to identify non-use values. This is because passive

or non-use values of the components of biological diversity are not related

to any activity or even the purchase of market goods and thus cannot be

determined using indirect valuation methods (Stephan and Ahlheim 1996,

p. 153).

Fig. 3: Classification of economic values and attributable valuation

methods (methods in angled brackets are less suitable ones)

Page 53: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

38

3.1.1 Determining direct and passive use values on simulated markets

Sociological interviewing methods are the most practicable approaches to

determine the economic value of the components of biological diversity. In

principle, these methods can be differentiated according to two interview

objectives:

• to attribute a value to the components of biological diversity concerned

(contingent valuation method, CVM) on the basis of analyses of

willingness to pay (WTP) and willingness to accept (WTA) or

• to rank values (contingent ranking method, CRM).

The best way to apply the direct valuation method is to determine the

WTP/WTA of one environment-related use for the person being

interviewed or the one that corresponds to his or her personal opinion and

knowledge, e.g. recreation options. WTP analyses on the basis of losses of

environmental/biological diversity are more problematic. Moreover, we

still have some way to go before the psychological and cognitive processes

that influence the formulation of answers can be definitively assessed.

Even if the direct valuation method is not exact enough for carrying out

cost-benefit analyses or for legislative purposes, provided that specific

questions are asked, its results may nevertheless be used as a

supplementary public opinion poll to establish earmarking priorities

concerning the use and conservation of biodiversity, particularly because it

is the only method that is able to translate non-use values into market prices

(Blamey and Common 1993).

The main problem of this method is undoubtedly related to the possible

disparity between the data obtained from interviewees concerning their

WTP and the amounts that they are actually willing to pay if the need arises

(Ruck 1990, p. 330). In Australia, for instance, CVMs and related methods

Page 54: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

39

are not generally recognised as accepted methods, since the values that are

determined are seen as improbably high (Blamey 1996).

Contingent valuation method (CVM)

In a direct analysis of WTP or willingness to renounce, value preferences

are determined on the basis of interviews. This method is referred to as the

CVM, not least because of the hypothetical nature of the situation

("simulated market situation"). It is applied to determine direct use, non-use

or passive use (existence and bequest values) and option/quasi-option use

values, but not indirect use values. Thus CVM (and the analogous CRM)

differ from all other important economic valuation methods, which can

only be used to determine one type of use value.

According to Pearce and Moran (1994), the CVM is the most important

method for the economic valuation of biodiversity, largely because it is the

only one that directly reflects the non-use-orientated (bequest and

existence) values of biodiversity. In addition to information retrieval and

information exchange during the interview process, verbatim minutes and

tape recordings allow the interviewer to analyse the biodiversity-related

knowledge and understanding of the interviewee ("think-aloud analysis").

Interest in this method has greatly increased over the last 10 years:

• because it is the only procedure that can be used to evaluate non-use-

values,

• because well-conceived and correctly conducted interviews might be as

valid as valuations of direct use values obtained by other methods and

• because the conception, analysis and interpretation of stated preferences

have also improved, e.g. the "scientific sampling" and "benefit

Page 55: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

40

estimation" theories have improved the computerised data

administration and analysis of public opinion polls and their validity.

The first stage of a CVM involves providing interviewees with background

information about the relevant biological resources. They are given further

information about the quality, quantity and the time-scale of changes.

In the second stage, a payment instrument is selected. This involves asking

interviewees whether they would be willing to pay into a hypothetical fund

or whether they would prefer a tax or a price increase. At this stage, it is

very important for the interviewer to propose a reliable payment instrument

and to be able to depict a plausible and acceptable scenario for the

interviewee.

In the third stage, a method has to be selected that allows the WTP or

willingness to renounce to be determined as accurately as possible. In an

open-ended approach, interviewees have to state the maximum amount that

they would be ready to pay or renounce. If a "dichotomous choice"

approach is used, the interviewee is confronted with a concrete amount that

is varied within a group of interviewees to come as close as possible to the

"real" value (see Perrings 1995, pp. 845f.; Hampicke 1991, pp. 118ff.;

Pearce and Moran 1994, pp. 58ff.).

Valuation of the direct value assigned to a product or service on the basis

of the interview requires verification of the reliability and validity, and

answers need to be examined to identify any possible falsifications.

In order to obtain exact and reliable answers regarding the WTP,

standardised guidelines can be used, such as those developed by the U.S.

National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration Committee (NOAA;

Arrow 1993):

Page 56: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

41

1. Sample type and size - probability sampling is essential. The choice of sample

specific designs and size is a difficult technical question that requires the guidance

of a professional sampling statistician.

2. Minimize non-responses - high non-response rates would make CV (contingent

valuation) survey results unreliable.

3. Personal interview - it is improbable that reliable value estimates can be elicited

with mail surveys. Face-to-face interviews are usually preferable, although

telephone interviews have some advantages in terms of costs and centralized

supervision.

4. Pretesting for interviewer effects - an important respect in which CV surveys differ

from actual referendum is the presence of an interviewer (except in the case of mail

survey). It is possible that interviewers contribute to 'social desirability' bias, since

preserving the environment is widely viewed as something positive. In order to test

this possibility, major CV studies should incorporate experiments that assess

interviewer effects.

5. Reporting - every report of a CV study should make clear the definition of the

population sampled, the sampling frame used, the sample size, the overall sample

non-response rate and its components (e.g., refusals), and item non-responses on all

important questions. The report should also reproduce the exact wording and

sequence of the questionnaire and of other communications to respondents (e.g.,

advance letters). All data from the study should be archived and made available to

interested parties.

6. Careful pretesting of a CV questionnaire - respondents in a CV survey are

ordinarily presented with a good deal of new and often technical information, well

beyond what is typical in most surveys. This requires very careful pilot work and

pre-testing, plus evidence from the final survey that respondents understood and

accepted the description of the good or service offered and the questioning

reasonably well.

7. Conservative design - when aspects of the survey design and the analysis of the

responses are ambiguous, the option that tends to underestimate the willingness-to-

pay is generally preferred. A conservative design increases the reliability of the

Page 57: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

42

estimate by eliminating extreme responses that can enlarge estimated values wildly

and implausibly.

8. Elicitation format - the willingness-to-pay format should be used instead of

compensation required because the former is the conservative choice.

9. Referendum format - the valuation question should be posed as a vote on a

referendum.

10. Accurate description of the program or policy - adequate information must be

provided to respondents about the environmental program that is offered.

11. Pretesting of photographs - the effects of photographs on subjects must be carefully

explored.

12. Reminder of substitute commodities - respondents must be reminded of substitute

commodities. This reminder should be introduced forcefully and directly prior to the

main valuation to assure that the respondents have the alternatives clearly in mind.

13. Temporal averaging - time-dependent measurement noise should be reduced by

averaging across independently drawn samples taken at different points in time. A

clear and substantial time trend in the responses would cast doubt on the reliability

of the value information obtained from a CV survey.

14. 'No-answer' option - a 'no-answer' option should be explicitly allowed in the

addition to the 'yes' or 'no' options on the main valuation (referendum) question.

Respondents who choose the 'no-answer' option should be asked to explain their

choice.

15. Yes/no follow-ups - yes and no responses should be followed-up by the open-ended

question: 'Why did you vote yes/no?'

16. Cross-tabulations - the survey should include a variety of other questions that help

interpret the responses to the primary valuation question. The final report should

include summaries of willingness-to-pay broken down by these categories (e.g.,

income, education, attitudes towards biodiversity).

17. Checks on understanding and acceptance - the survey instrument should not be so

complex that it poses tasks that are beyond the ability or interest level of many

participants.

Page 58: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

43

Contingent ranking method (CRM)

The CRM is the stepsister of the CVM. The different feature in this

interview situation is that respondents are confronted with a set of options

that they are asked to rank according to their valuation scale. For each of

the options, the interviewer designates a set of characteristics and describes

how the options differ. The resulting costs should be delineated for each

option.

Asking questions about relative valuations and specifically costed

alternatives facilitates the choice for the interviewee; conversely, however,

it becomes more difficult to determine the actual monetary limit.

Further methodological progress

The "stated preference" method (SPM; Adamowicz 1994; Louviere 1994)

promises further improvements in the direct valuation process. Application

of the SPM (which was originally developed for the marketing and

transportation business) allows consumer responses to be made to a larger

range of subject characteristics than is normally possible using direct

valuation analysis.

3.1.2 Indirectly determining direct use values

The indirect or surrogate market valuation methods are all based on the fact

that the commodities "nature" or "biological resources" are consumed

together with complementary private goods with well-known or easily

determinable prices. These indirect approaches are techniques that derive

preferences from actual market-based observations. Preferences for a

biodiversity commodity can be assumed if an individual buys a product that

is somehow related to the biodiversity commodity in question. The relevant

techniques are as follows:

Page 59: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

44

• the travel cost method,

• the "hedonic price" approach,

• the avertive behaviour approach and

• the dose-response method.

Surrogate market techniques focus on markets for private commodities and

services that are related to biological (or environmental) resources or

products. The products or services sold on these surrogate markets

correspond to the products/resources in question, because individuals

reveal their preferences for a biodiversity commodity by purchasing a

related object or service. "Strongly simplified: If a bird watcher spends DM

1000 on a telescope, then he is obviously willing to pay at least DM 1000

to watch birds" (Hampicke 1991, p. 115).

However, the potential of surrogate market approaches is limited for

several reasons:

• No hypothetical conclusions can be drawn. If the natural commodity is

no longer available, there will be no expenditure on the surrogate object

(in the case described above, the telescope) either.

• The method only measures the intensity of a personal interest ("user

value"), and not the interest in conserving biological diversity

("existence value").

• The relationship between private expenditure and the conservation goal

is frequently weak (e.g. telescopes may also serve other purposes).

• Experiencing nature is often non-specific; many people experience

biological diversity even in an ecologically worthless spruce forest.

Page 60: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

45

Analogous limitations need to be addressed in the travel cost method. The

relationship between travel expenses and the valuation of the components

of biodiversity at the journey's destination is questionable if this journey is

undertaken for other reasons as well. Nevertheless, this method can lead to

valuable explanations about the WTP for experiencing nature, especially if

expensive and very specific destinations (e.g. a national park) have been

chosen. Past applications refer to large game parks in Africa (Brown and

Henry 1989) and tropical forest reserves in Costa Rica (Tobias and

Mendelsohn 1991), for example. In the latter study, it was shown that the

WTP of native and foreign visitors (primarily from the United States)

corresponding to a hectare of tropical forest exceeds the purchase price by

two powers of ten. In economic terms, the only possible conclusion is that

the area of the reserve should be increased. With respect to the travel cost

method, Ruck (1990, p. 261) states that, in the case of Kenya and Tanzania,

the abolition of national parks as tourist attractions would also lead to

substantial losses in seaside tourism, whereas in countries such as Sri

Lanka, India or the Ivory Coast, where tourism is largely beach or congress

tourism and national parks do not play a central role, there would be less or

no effects on the cost-benefit analyses of the tourism industry.

The dose-response approach is designed to determine relationships between

damage and its causes (e.g. pollution load); a certain load level is related to

the output change, which in turn leads to value changes on the market. This

approach, however, is only applicable to environmental changes and is

therefore not suitable for the economics of use-independent values.

3.1.3 Determining indirect use values

The methods presented in Sects. 3.1.1 and 3.1.2 to determine preferences

are not suitable to determine the direct or indirect use values (ecological

Page 61: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

46

regulatory functions) of nature as production factors, since they support

economic activities regardless of preferences. In order to determine indirect

use values, other methods therefore have to be applied. However, such

methods currently still suffer from our lack of knowledge about the

functional importance of biological diversity and the ecological services

linked to them.

Indirect productivity measurements

The productivity change method can be used to determine the direct and

indirect use values of ecosystems within market prices. For instance, the

value of the ecological function of a forest in the catchment area of a

hydroelectric power plant can be measured by the net value of the

difference in water power production because of sedimentation in the

presence or absence (clearing) of forest or with a smaller (reduction) forest

stand.

A related productivity method measures the expenditure of work by a

market subject (individual, enterprise) to maintain or optimise ecological

effects (e.g. a farmer building terraces to prevent soil erosion). The

observed protective or preventive expenditure provides a measure of the

subject's valuation of the relevant ecological services (Perrings 1995,

p. 856).

The replacement cost approach focuses on the costs of replacing (e.g.

reintroduction) or restoring (e.g. reforestation) components of biological

diversity.

Avoidance and repair costs are difficult to determine, since neither

sophisticated techniques nor reliable cost levels are available for the

avoidance or repair of environmental damage. We cannot use the costs of

Page 62: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

47

reducing the percentage of sulphur dioxide and nitrogen oxide in the air to

approximately zero to conclude that the value of clean air corresponds to

the level of avoidance costs. An estimation of forest degradation by acid

rain or the loss of fishery resources by water pollution on the basis of

avoidance costs, for example, will be misleading unless those concerned

are willing to bear these costs. The final report by the German Ministry of

the Environment's research programme on the "Costs of Environmental

Pollution/Benefit of Environmental Protection" puts the relevant avoidance

costs at DM 130 million p.a. (Wicke 1986).

Production-function approach

The production-function approach determines the physical effects of

changes of ecological functions on economic activities. The consequences

of these changes become visible in the change in economic yield of these

economic activities. Thus a relation between economic and ecological

productivity is produced.

In order to translate ecological into economic productivity, it is clearly

necessary to understand how regulatory ecological functions support

economic activities, and this is still the limiting factor. This becomes even

more difficult where the causes (e.g. the functional role of individual

species) of ecological functions have to be understood in greater detail. It is

highly desirable both from an economic and an ecological point of view to

promote this understanding.

Our lack of understanding of the ecological causes of economic

productivity should not prevent production-function valuations from being

carried out using existing knowledge. On the basis of different assumptions

about causal links between ecological and economic factors, Ruitenbeek

Page 63: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

48

(1992), for instance, has carried out valuations in different scenarios. The

results of these valuation approaches are given in Sect. 2.3.

The marketable yield Q is formally represented as being dependent on a set

of factors: Q = F(Xi ... Xk, S). [In the study by Ellis and Fisher (1987) on

the effect of wetlands on the crab harvest, QS is the area of the wetlands in

question.]

3.2 The cost aspect of the conservation and destruction of

biological diversity and the cost-benefit analysis

procedure

The preceding sections have dealt with the type and range of economic use

values of biological resources and the methods used to determine them.

This section discusses the costs associated with the conservation,

sustainable use and restoration of biological diversity in order to balance

these costs with their social and economic benefits. If biological resources

for conservation, sustainable use or restoration can be treated as scarce

resources and valued accordingly, they can be balanced against alternative

uses. The forgone opportunities are referred to as opportunity costs. On the

basis of cost-benefit analyses (see below), the relevant activities and their

alternatives can ultimately be determined and evaluated in monetary terms.

3.2.1 Opportunity costs: restoration costs, sustainability costs, lost use

values

How much does it cost not to destroy nature? Since the pioneering work by

Krutilla and Fisher (1975), this question has been addressed by a number of

studies. Approaches such as that used by Bishop (1980) to estimate

conservation costs for individual species are still rare; other studies deal

Page 64: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

49

with the opportunity costs of area requirements for nature conservation.

The starting point of this kind of research was the work carried out by

Goldstein (1971), who compared two alternative uses of areas in the

Midwest of the United States. Retaining the area as an adventure range for

WTP bird hunters instead of intensifying its agricultural uses proved to be

economically more favourable.

Some studies, such as the ones by Turner et al. (1983) and Krutilla and

Fisher (1975), have established that maintaining a natural condition does

not cause economic costs, because large investment planning has proved to

be unprofitable. A study by Willis et al. (1988) elucidates the difference

between land use costs if distorted prices support a use that destroys nature

while lower opportunity costs are arrived at by correct calculations.

The TEV approach should be used as the basis on which to calculate

opportunity costs. Use-dependent and use-independent values have to be

taken into account, and market price-based and market price-independent

methods should be examined to valuate them. In 1989, the U.S. Court of

Appeals ruled that the procedural guidelines of the U.S. Ministry of the

Interior for the monetary valuation of environmental damage should be

revised (Marggraf and Streb 1997, p. 17). However, this court decision has

not yet been implemented, although a second ruling that environmental

damage should be valuated on the basis of the sum of restoration costs and

forgone use options has now been put into practice.

At this point, it would seem appropriate to step aside for a moment and

consider the actual and potential market values of the (minimum) goals and

costs of biodiversity. What are the ecological and biodiversity standards

that should be aimed at from a scientific point of view? And how can they

Page 65: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

50

be translated into global and national economic units to make their

economic superiority visible?

"The progressive destruction of nature in many developing countries calls

for an answer to the question of the number, size and geographical location

of national parks that might be regarded as economically optimal within a

given time frame for a country or for human civilisation" (Ruck 1990,

p. 365), where "national park" is used as a synonym for protected,

sustainably used or restored ecosystems/biodiversity. Ruck (pp. 365ff.)

presents ways to arrive at economic responses to this question.

"Market prices for products and factors partly reflect material scarcity and

thus opportunity costs, but they are usually distorted by transfer

components, and corrections therefore need to be made for calculations of

economic costs. A distinction should always be made between dynamic and

static sets of costs, and each has to be incorporated in the other" (Hampicke

1991, p. 180). Funds for the conservation of biological diversity should

always be spent according to defined priorities and as efficiently as

possible: certain goals can either be attained at minimum costs, or the

degree to which a given goal is realised should be maximised at a given

cost. The practical cost categories for the conservation of biological

diversity can be divided into investment, work and land use costs, and each

poses specific problems. A number of studies that have been undertaken

world-wide concerning conflicts of various sizes show that opportunity

costs for the conservation of biological diversity are often far lower than

expected. In those federal states that belonged to West Germany before

German reunification, for example, DM 1 billion would be sufficient to

implement a thorough nature protection programme.

Page 66: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

51

Wells (1992) compared the costs and benefits of protected areas at the

local, regional and global level, qualitatively estimating the distribution of

costs and benefits on these different levels. His estimation of the benefit of

protected areas was based on the work of Dixon and Sherman (1990; cited

in Wells 1992). It was shown that the economic benefits of protected areas

are limited at a local level, are somewhat higher at regional and national

levels and become substantial at a global level. The related costs follow the

opposite trend: They are significant at a local level, moderate at a regional

and national level and small at a global level (e.g. contributions to

multilateral financing mechanisms, cf. Fig. 4).

Wells (1992) concluded that to ensure that biodiversity is effectively

protected, this imbalance needs to be corrected by:

• North-South money transfers and

• an increase in profits at both a local and a regional and national level,

e.g. by the expansion of sustainable use strategies.

In order for local communities to actually profit from sustainable uses,

however, further socio-economic and legal conditions have to be fulfilled

on a national and regional level. These concern aspects such as land tenure

rights, property rights to biological diversity and the promotion of rural

development.

Page 67: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

52

Potentially significant benefits Potentially significant costsLOCAL LEVEL

Consumption benefit Indirect costs (e.g. damage by grazing)Recreation/tourism Opportunity costs (e.g. by restriction of

use)Future values

REGIONAL/NATIONAL LEVEL

Recreation/tourism Direct costs (establishment of protectedareas)

Water drainage areas Opportunity costsFuture values

GLOBAL LEVEL

Biological diversity (Minimum costs)Non-consumption useEcological processesEnvironmental education and researchFuture values

3.2.2 Cost-benefit analysis

Cost-benefit analyses (CBAs) allow biodiversity-relevant activities and

their alternatives to be evaluated and expressed in monetary terms. In order

to be able to compare the costs and benefits of alternative uses, the

following procedure should be followed:

1. All the consequences of a relevant action should be identified (e.g. use,

alternative use, change in the status quo of biodiversity).

2. The present private benefits PV[B(DEV)] and costs PV[C(DEV)]

associated with the individual action taken should be determined and the

difference between them calculated: PV[B(DEV)] - PV[C(DEV)].

3. Depending on the relevant integration level, the present local, national,

global or total (TEVtot = TEVg + TEVn + TEVl) social benefit

Fig. 4: Comparison of the resulting costs and use of protected areas

Page 68: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

53

PV[TEV(SUB)] of the alternative use (e.g. conservation, sustainable

use) should be calculated; its social costs PV[C(SUB)] are then

subtracted.

4. If the difference PV[TEV(SUB) - C(SUB)] is larger than the difference

PV[B(DEV) - C(DEV)], then the social use alternative is the

economically relevant one. It will also be politically relevant whether

the private user is able to participate in the social global, national and/or

local yields.

If the costs and benefits of an action are to be calculated without

considering an alternative scenario, step 2 should be omitted. The action

concerned will then be economically reasonable if the valued benefit

exceeds the respective costs. Since the cost-benefit analysis requires

national and international costs and benefits to be identified and quantified

as comprehensively as possible, it also includes individual cost and benefit

aspects (e.g. external effects), even if these are not economically apparent.

3.3 Organisation of markets with appropriate prices

In the preceding sections, the causes of market failure were explained in

terms of the valuation or rather the lack of valuation of biological diversity.

In addition, techniques were described with which the actual value of the

components of biological diversity can be determined (TEVs at a local,

national and global level, etc.). The critical question is now how these

theoretical insights and methods can have a practical impact on markets

and prices and how the external costs and benefits of biological resources

can become visible on the markets and in market prices.

Page 69: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

54

3.3.1 Monetisation and cost-benefit analyses

In order for market prices to approximate the "real" value of the

components of biological diversity and/or for efficient market price-

relevant decisions to be made, it is first necessary to gather all the available

information about the value of biodiversity commodities. The first step

from theory to practice therefore has to be to apply the valuation techniques

described in Sect. 3.1 and the cost-benefit analyses presented in Sect. 3.2.

Barbier et al. (1994) draw some important conclusions from the

investigation of Mantadia National Park for the practical relevance of cost-

benefit analyses (Munasinghe 1993):

• Firstly, valuation techniques have to be adapted to the local situation; in

the specific case concerned, the currency "rice" was used to value the

economic advantages of forests.

• Secondly, by carefully selecting and applying valuation techniques in

relevant situations, useful indications can be obtained of the values that

would be impaired by the selected land use alternative. It is important to

realise what is actually measured by the particular valuation method

used, e.g. direct use effects, net proceeds from direct and indirect use

effects, etc., and to have a clear idea of the reliability of data and

methods for the evaluation of the respective advantages.

• Thirdly, it also needs to be clarified what was not measured by the study

in question, on which level of the hierarchy the study was conducted

and whether the TEV or only elements thereof were determined.

Only with such specifically adapted instruments and the initial knowledge

they provide about the "real" economic value of the biological resources

and their use can the following central issue be addressed: What are the

Page 70: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

55

mechanisms that transform the socio-economic values that have been

determined into monetary reality on the market?

Four such mechanisms will be discussed below:

1. the removal of damaging distortions of market mechanisms

(deregulation) by dismantling failed interventions (Sect. 3.3.2),

2. the creation of markets by privatisation and integrated biodiversity

management (Sect. 3.3.3),

3. market-induced control systems (Sect. 3.3.4.) and

4. the creation of global biodiversity markets (Sect. 3.3.5).

3.3.2 Dismantling failed interventions

Governments generally tend to intervene in markets. This may be done

with the best intentions. However, even though some interventions may use

price corrections to adjust external effects that are damaging to

biodiversity, many interventions run counter to the goals of protection

biodiversity, even if they serve other important purposes. Well-known

examples of such intervention prices are deforestation subsidies, water

prices that are too low, subsidisation of agriculture, etc. Such measures are

referred to as perverse incentives, i.e. incentives that lead to a decrease in

biological diversity, and are the result of policy failure. The most perverse

incentives are those that have been created to promote goals that destroy

biodiversity (OECD 1996, p. 70).

An important step towards achieving prices that reflect social costs is

therefore to abolish any supportive measures that artificially reduce the

private costs of actions that are detrimental to biodiversity. The OECD

(1998) has very recently undertaken a study of this problem, which will be

Page 71: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

56

referred to later. One way of correcting the price distortions caused by price

controls or national monopolies is to take internationally valid competitive

market prices as "shadow" prices (Ruck 1990, p. 220).

3.3.3 Creation of private property rights and integrated biodiversity

management

In an ideal free market, the market develops on its own such that private

use interests work to support social interests and correcting measures are

kept to a minimum. In order to at least come close to this ideal, private

users have be able to profit from the national or global yields of the

conservation and/or sustainable use of biodiversity. This could be achieved

by creating vested titles to those biological resources to which vested titles

do not yet exist and/or by transferring property rights from the State to

landowners (including those who should be entitled to such rights due to

pending land reforms).

This approach would be the logical consequence of the "national

sovereignty regime" over genetic resources that was created by the CBD to

replace the former "free access regime" to shift it at the local level. It would

meet the efficiency criterion that those who control net assets should also

be those who profit from the utilisable effects of these net assets. If a local

community cannot draw net use from its investment (the sustainable use of

ecosystems/components of biodiversity), it will not have an interest in

maintaining its investment (Pearce and Moran 1994, p. 144).

Persson (1994) was able to show that the transferral of vested titles to

squatters causes them to stop clearing, in particular if discounting is lower

than the future value of the forest. These property rights could further be

licensed, e.g. as bioprospecting ratios, visitor ratios, harvest ratios,

emission rights, development rights, etc.

Page 72: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

57

With respect to genes, species and ecosystems as levels in the biodiversity

hierarchy, property rights will probably refer to the ecosystem level. It

would be advisable for transferred vested titles not to be restricted to single

uses, but to be open for the whole range of use options, e.g. tourism,

bioprospecting, hunting, renewable resources, etc. For a comprehensive

bioprospecting strategy could ensure conservation effects for the specific

resource in situ; moreover, it may also generate conservation effects for

other resources in the same habitat that are not yet being sought or

commercially exploited.

This presupposes that a bioprospecting strategy will be open in terms of the

species, genes and biomolecules it is looking for. A broader screening

policy for commercially useful resources means that the quasi-option value

of the resources that are not yet being screened for can create preservation

effects for the whole ecosystem more effectively. If prospecting is more

specific (species xy, effect ab), a holistic protective effect becomes less

likely, particularly if shortages or losses may result from subsequent

exploitation of the resources being sought. The status of the components of

biodiversity concerned should therefore be monitored by means of pre- and

post-prospecting programmes.

Bioprospecting opens up new sources of income for developing countries.

Instead of having to ask for new technologies and transfer payments from

the North, these countries may be able to offer "genetic technology" in the

form of raw materials, plant-based medicines, etc. (Krattiger and Lesser

1994). For a more lasting success in bioprospecting strategies, it would also

be helpful to transfer an increasing amount of relevant biotechnological

know-how ("capacity-building") to the area from which bioresources

originate to enable further processed resources to be marketed not only

globally, but also regionally.

Page 73: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

58

The same is true of ecotourism; multiple attractions can increase the

duration of usability, but here, too, monitoring programmes should be

implemented to register any side-effects, and benefits were to be shared

with the local communities concerned.

3.3.4 Creation of market-based regulatory instruments

Many regulatory instruments are available to bridge the gap between TEVs

and current market prices on the national market. The main distinction is

between regulatory and market-based instruments. While regulatory

instruments imply the direct control (reduction/limitation) of unwanted

actions in conjunction with legislative or politically agreed standards,

market-based instruments create economic incentives. "It is no accident

that 'command and control' concepts have dominated environmental policy

so far world-wide. The reasons for this are the sectoral organisation and

splintering of national competences, the minor political importance of

national environmental institutions and, last but not least, the insufficient

integration of environmental policy into public discussion in many

countries" (Paulus 1995).

Economic incentive systems can be subdivided into four categories:

1. Positive incentives: any monetary (direct payment, cost-sharing, tax

advantages) or non-monetary inducement (such as awards in recognition

of outstanding performance) that motivates individuals or groups

(governments, international organisations, local communities) to

conserve biological diversity.

2. Disincentives: any mechanism that internalises the costs of use and/or

damage of biological resources in order to discourage activities that

deplete biological diversity.

Page 74: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

59

3. Indirect incentives: any mechanism that creates or improves upon

markets and price signals for biological resources, encouraging the

conservation and sustainable use of biological diversity.

4. Perverse incentives: an incentive that induces behaviour leading to a

reduction in biological diversity. Perverse incentives are the result of

failed government intervention. Most perverse incentives are designed to

achieve other policy objectives and their "perversity" is thus an external

factor or an unanticipated side-effect of the policy (OECD 1996, p. 70).

If the results of economic valuations of biological resources do not lead to

reformed or newly created markets, the economic value of biological

resources can only be asserted by intervention. The notion that the market

is basically flexible enough, with only occasional State subsidies required,

is only a qualitative one. "By no means can it be concluded that economic

adjustment processes and government incentives are implemented in time

and to a sufficient extent to avoid the catastrophic consequences of

resource shortages" (Endres and Querner 1993; on market failure, see

pp. 124ff.).

However, despite the shortcomings of the market mechanism outlined

above in reflecting the TEV of the relevant components of biological

diversity, the capacity of the market to contribute to solving the problem of

the destruction of biodiversity should not be underestimated. As only

incomplete allocation mechanisms currently exist, it is not certain how the

market can contribute to the conservation of natural resources in pragmatic

terms (Endres and Querner 1993, p. 139).

In order to optimise the quality of an allocation mechanism, free market

economy intervention instruments (MEIs) should be used. Examples of

such mechanisms include environment-related fees, a price strategy with

Page 75: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

60

resources and inputs, duties and taxes, subsidies, environmental funds,

tradable rights and licences, flexible levies, pledge systems, etc. (Paulus

1995).

Strictly speaking, MEIs include all political measures explicitly related to

private costs and benefits by which the comparative social costs and

benefits can be incorporated into market prices. These MEIs can be

subdivided into five categories:

1. charges, taxes, fees or additional prices to be paid for the social costs

arising from damage,

2. subsidies to assist individuals in altering activities or conforming to

environmental standards,

3. deposit/refund or fee/rebate systems in which a surcharge is levied on the

price of products leading to resource depletion which is then refunded if

the product is recycled or if the depleted resource is restored,

4. tradable permits by which rights to exploit resources can be exchanged

and

5. compensatory incentives to create markets or financial inducements for

certain individuals or groups who bear a disproportionate share of the

risks or costs of the conservation of biological resources (Barbier et al.

1994, p. 180).

MEIs, however, entail a considerable amount of administrative and/or

monitoring expenditure. It is therefore important to examine carefully, as

Paulus (1995) does, the institutional conditions and to integrate measures

into existing structures wherever possible. The following criteria need to be

taken into account when selecting measures: ecological effectiveness,

Page 76: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

61

economic efficiency, administrative management, public costs and yields,

distribution effects and interspersing ability.

No single MEI instrument will be sufficient to counter specific threats to

biological diversity, and a range of MEIs will be necessary to address the

complex problems of the social costs of conservation, sustainable use and

restoration of biological diversity.

In principle, the groups that damage biological resources should bear the

damage prevention costs and/or the social costs connected with the

damage. Otherwise, those who use biological resources would have to bear

the entire costs of using resources, including the costs of control and

prevention. Conversely, the incremental costs connected with the

mobilisation of non-marketed uses should be offset by the utilisation of

positive incentive systems. The latter could be implemented using market-

based control instruments, as clearly shown by Lippke (1996, p. 253).

3.3.5 Creation of global markets

As mentioned several times in the preceding sections, many conservation

and/or sustainable use approaches produce global benefits. The

conservation of biological diversity in a tropical rain forest may benefit

individuals and groups in other countries, e.g. because they profit from its

renewable resources, because its biogeochemical cycles have global

benefits or because they want it to exist for its own sake.

However, if the country that owns the resources cannot derive monetary

benefit from these global external use values due to a lack of appropriate

markets, it will have no or little incentive to conserve the biological

resources in question.

Page 77: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

62

It is therefore necessary to create global markets (GEMs). These markets

can be enforced by international law or may result from voluntary

agreements. Examples of the latter include debt-for-nature swaps or

benefit-sharing agreements, as concluded by Merck & Co., Shaman

Pharmaceuticals, Biotics Ltd. and others with the owners of bioresources.

Regulation-induced markets have gained attention in the context of the

Climate Convention, e.g. the intergovernmental agreement on CO2

reduction between Norway, Poland and Mexico concluded via the Global

Environmental Facility (GEF) or the afforestation agreements entered into

by various U.S. energy companies.

Both approaches - regulation-induced and voluntary agreements - have a

common feature: bilateral or multilateral transfer payments. Indeed, in the

foreseeable future, well-organised and specific financial transfer services

will be indispensable. The particular practical relevance of monetisation

approaches for the conservation, sustainable use and restoration costs of

biological diversity lies in the fact that these approaches will form the basis

of assessment for the budgets of national and international measures for the

protection of biological diversity. This is especially relevant for the

implementation of the CBD with regard to international financing

instruments such as the GEF and biodiversity portfolios of the World Bank,

the Development Bank of the United Nations and continental development

banks. The concept of "incremental costs" in the realisation of the CBD and

the conservation of biological diversity may be helpful in this respect.

Exactly what is covered by the term "full incremental costs" in accordance

with Art. 20 of the CBD is still the subject of detailed discussion. A

definition of the scope of this term, however, is urgently needed, since it

determines which elements of biodiversity-relevant projects may be

Page 78: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

63

covered as "incremental costs" by the financial mechanisms of the

CBD/GEF.

For a definition of incremental costs, the (then still interim) secretariat of

the CBD listed several items to justify transfer payments in the light of the

CBD; however, these also suggest that a complicated bureaucracy will need

to be established (UNEP/CBD/IC/2/17 of 25 April 1994). It might be more

appropriate to restrict net incremental costs to the CBD aims of

conservation and sustainable use (global externalities of biodiversity loss),

because to achieve the third aim, the sharing of benefits and not

incremental costs would have to be refunded, but yields would have to be

divided. According to Glowka et al. (1994), incremental costs could be

defined in a simplified form as those costs that are necessary to conserve,

use sustainably or restore the components of biodiversity defined by quality

goals (if necessary, minus the immediate yields from the direct sustainable

use of biodiversity and benefit-sharing), whereby the extent of the specific

financial expenditure should be based on non-use-related monetary values.

The International Conservation Financing Project of the World Resources

Institute has attempted to calculate the annual funds necessary for the

conservation of biological resources and estimates a total of $20-50 million

per year (Reid and Miller 1989). The conservation for 20 years of 2000

animal species with 500 individuals each costs approximately $25 billion

alone, as much as the first landing by man on the moon. The traditional

conservation of tropical rain forests is estimated to cost $170 million per

year for at least 5 years.

In order to develop a ranking order for transfer payments, a cost-efficiency

index for biodiversity projects has been developed (see the Second Global

Biodiversity Forum, Nassau 1994):

Page 79: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

64

• a suitable indicator of the benefits of biodiversity or of biological

significance: data at a national level on species diversity and endemism

(per km2) may be used to represent the benefits gained by the

conservation activity concerned;

• cost of intervention: represented by the amount of investment (per km2)

in conservation measures at a national level;

• probability of success (willingness to conserve): the percentage of land

area defined as protected area is used to assess the probability of

success;

• degree of threat: deforestation rates and population growth are used to

approximate the level of threat.

It should be remembered that it is not sufficient to guarantee the return of

profit shares to the countries owning the resources. Instead, financial

compensation for the use or exploitation of biological diversity must

benefit those groups (e.g. local communities, conservation organisations,

national park administrations) that directly protect and sustainably use

biodiversity. However, this presupposes a whole range of institutional,

organisational and legal conditions, including procedures to ensure the

predictability and reliability of the distribution of transfer funds as

equivalents for economic values.

A number of financing instruments (e.g. an international rain forest fund,

resource franchise agreements) are being discussed to ascertain strategic

international payments. Because of their free market nature, transferable

development rights (TDRs) appear to be particularly promising to allow

adequate conservation of global biodiversity values in tropical countries.

Page 80: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

65

The first step towards establishing TDRs for the conservation of biological

diversity would be to differentiate between conservation and development

areas. Individuals owning land in the conservation areas would also receive

TDRs, but would not be allowed to implement these rights within the

conservation areas. Instead, they could sell these vested titles in

development areas in which there is assumed to be a high demand for

limited development rights. Full compensation should thus result for the

owners of the conservation areas by the sales of development rights.

Such a market for TDRs could develop internationally. Tropical countries

could exclude areas of authentic ecosystems from alternative use and offer

TDRs locally and internationally at prices that cover their opportunity costs

(current net value of the forgone development alternative; for further

discussion, see Panayotou 1994). To a certain extent, a TDR system

already exists in the form of the debt-for-nature swaps. The essential

element of these agreements is the transfer of development rights for

conservation areas to international non-governmental organisations

(NGOs) in exchange for assuming part of the national debts of the

countries concerned. However, the extent of these rights is usually not

correlated with the opportunity costs.

3.4 Recommendations for development cooperation

The example of valuation techniques highlights the fundamental dilemma

of environmental economics, i.e. the need to proceed from generalisations

to formulate operational recommendations for action. The economic

analyses in many case studies are fairly convincing, but their scientific

theory is often still not translated into practice. Development co-operation

is required in order to develop operational concepts and to implement them

in pilot projects. The key concepts in this context are the acquisition of

Page 81: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

66

knowledge about specific costs and benefits, training and capacity-

building.

3.4.1 Project-oriented cost-benefit analyses using the available

valuation instruments

The most obvious measure might be to introduce biodiversity valuation

techniques and comprehensive cost-benefit analyses in project planning

and to create project-oriented cost-benefit analyses (as a continuation of

project environmental-impact assessments, EIAs) as a basis on which to

determine project-related TEVs. This would require the development of

appropriate training programmes and guidelines for those responsible for

the projects in Germany and in the partner country, which should initially

be conducted in a pilot phase for selected projects. When developing such

programmes and guidelines, care should be taken to ensure that the

necessary standardisation still allows sufficient scope for the individual

project conditions and the practical adaptation of the relevant procedures

(e.g. CVM).

3.4.2 Training and capacity-building to inventor and monitor

biodiversity

In order to carry out economic valuations of the components of biological

diversity under reasonable conditions, the component to be valuated must

be adequately characterised, i.e. inventories of the components of

biological diversity concerned should be made on the relevant hierarchy

and integration levels (e.g. genes, species, ecosystems); in the follow-up,

these inventories also need to be reviewed using monitoring and

assessment programmes. There is now an extensive body of literature (e.g.

Stork and Samways 1995; Guarino et al. 1995) on the implementation of

Page 82: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

67

such programmes, and this issue will not be addressed in detail here.

Particular attention should be paid to rapid biodiversity assessment

techniques (discussed in the literature) and to close cooperation between

experts and parataxonomists, as has been documented particularly clearly

for the Instituto de la Biodiversidad (INBio) in Costa Rica. DC is required

to support and to participate in biodiversity inventories in the partner

countries by means of suitable training courses and infrastructure measures.

3.4.3 Creation and/or strengthening of institutional prerequisites for

the development and implementation of national biodiversity

strategies

In this context, it is necessary to support the national and regional

authorities responsible for the conservation and sustainable use of

biological diversity in diverse areas, to help integrate biodiversity

conservation strategies in the planning of land use and to support

cooperation among the organisations involved (government authorities,

local authorities, environmental and development organisations, social

movements, development cooperation institutions). DC can contribute to

this process, e.g. by providing consultancy services. A possible form of

support is to ensure that yields from the use of genetic resources are

proportionately supplied to protected areas. At the same time, legislation

must be examined and amended to ensure its compatibility with

conservation and development goals.

3.4.4 Training and capacity-building to conduct cost-benefit analyses

and valuation techniques

Not only should project planning be carried out in donor countries (cf.

Sect. 3.4.1), but the know-how for the application of valuation techniques

Page 83: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

68

and the implementation of cost-benefit analyses should also be transferred

to the recipient countries by means of DC in association with the capacities

to be built and developed in order to catalogue biodiversity. DC should

organise project-related (advanced) training courses and consult the

relevant institutions of the partner country. At the same time, legislation

should be examined and amended in the light of the relevant methods and

techniques, as done for the relevant American DOI guidelines, for example.

3.4.5 Supporting research capacities in developing countries at the

frontier between ecology and economics

Due to the rising demand for genetic resources, resulting in increased

bioprospecting activity in tropical forests, for example, national inventory

programmes on biological diversity and ecosystem research need to be

supported in order to set up sustainable utilisation strategies. An

international fund should provide support in capacity-building to inventory

biological diversity, to document and analyse samples and to exchange

information. Free access to information and the participation of local

communities need to be ensured. Experience at institutions such as the

Costa Rican Instituto de la Biodiversidad (INBio) suggest that we should

be thinking about models for other countries above and beyond this Costa

Rican approach.

The research and technology capacity of developing countries can be

supported by private initiatives; however, due to the size of these tasks, this

alone will not be sufficient and supplementary efforts will be necessary. In

close cooperation with partner institutions in the tropical countries, foreign

research institutions should contribute to the complex field of basic

research in the rain forests. In this context, it should be ensured that

research results are accessible to all those involved, that emphasis is placed

Page 84: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

69

on building national research capacities and that research results are put

into practice by means of environmental education.

One extremely important area in which DC is required is undoubtedly the

establishment and promotion of modern biodiversity research in partner

countries, in particular the creation of a sound modern taxonomy, as this

forms the basis of all other fields of biodiversity research. "Taxonomy is

fundamental in providing the units and the pattern to humankind's notion of

species diversity" (Bisby 1995). As Hubert Markl puts it, "It has to be

clearly stated: Without the active contribution of lively and productive

biotaxonomic research - above all organism inventories of the tropics and

subtropics and the seas of all latitudes - it will be impossible to gain the

ecological insights that are necessary for the global management of the

biosphere (a profitable form of management to our benefit, e.g. self-

restraint in relation to natural communities) in such a way that mankind and

nature will be able to live together on a long-term basis, something our

future depends on. (...) As an infrastructure-related task of biodiversity

research, however, this reflects only part of the particular scientific value of

biotaxonomic research. Is it not the sophisticated differentiation of life

forms that forms the indispensable prerequisite for our astonishment and

enthusiasm for all kinds of organisms more than anything else: their

marvellous ability to adapt to their environment, their skilful methods of

conquering ecological niches, their inexhaustible wealth of original

solutions for all of life's problems from the procurement of food in

competition with their own and other species, the avoidance of enemies, the

fight against parasites and, finally, the development of supra-organismal

social systems whose abilities to learn and adapt seem to know no limits

even in animals, let alone in humans? We would not be able to carry out

research on any of this without the clear distinctions identified by

Page 85: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

70

taxonomic research that provide the basis for our comparative analyses"

(Markl 1995).

Important tasks for the future include developing a modern taxonomy as an

integral science combining both classical and molecular methods (see

Bisby 1995) and training methodically (classical/molecular) holistic

taxonomists who also have a particular expertise in data processing using

information technology. It should be added that taxonomy will also become

increasingly significant as an infrastructure for biotechnology. In the

context of bioprospecting, biodiversity conservationists have pinned their

hopes on strategies of participative use for biotechnologically exploitable

natural substances for the in situ preservation of biological diversity. DC

should therefore also take account of research into chemical ecology and

natural products, including the industrial, sociological and economic

aspects of biodiversity. Where possible, appropriate DC projects should be

integrated into international scientific biodiversity initiatives such as

DIVERSITAS, BioNET International or Species 2000.

A further key area of biodiversity research for DC is the area of

biodiversity economics. In recent years, not least as a result of discussions

on the CBD, this subdiscipline of environmental economics has undergone

rapid development, and there have been a number of publications focusing

on valuation studies of biological resources. Interdisciplinary coordinated

research efforts are still largely lacking, however.

3.4.6 Identification of interventions failures

In order to come closer to the goal of having prices that reflect social costs,

it is necessary both to eliminate subsidies that artificially lower private

costs and to implement suitable economic instruments or other regulatory

measures to ensure that harmful external effects are taken into account in

Page 86: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

71

price setting. As part of DC, consultancy services are required in this

context to support the dismantling of misdirected economic instruments on

the basis of TEVs and cost-benefit analyses; in addition, approval for

biodiversity project funding needs to be linked to the removal of any

disincentives counterproductive to the aim of the project.

3.4.7 Creation of incentive instruments

Consumption and non-consumption values of biological diversity are only

partially reflected in market prices. An overall economic calculation should

also consider ecological follow-up costs. Subsidising non-sustainable uses

sends the wrong politico-economic signals and frequently causes the

exploitation of natural resources. Within the framework of project

cooperation, DC should therefore recommend that more attention be paid to

economic incentives for the conservation of biological diversity together

with the abolition of subsidies for ecologically harmful land uses.

By means of consultancy services, national governments and authorities

should be encouraged to use and test economic instruments able to generate

market prices that approximate previously determined TEVs.

3.4.8 Participation of local communities in biodiversity yields

Successful work on a project requires the appropriate participation of local

communities in decision-making processes and the identification of

problems in project planning, implementation, and monitoring and

evaluation. Decision-making processes concerning the organisation of the

project should be made as transparent as possible and should include

objection options for the local communities concerned.

Page 87: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

72

The effectiveness of economic incentives for local communities has not

been sufficiently considered so far. Bioprospecting and the gathering of

biological resources by national organisations offer the opportunity for fair

and equitable participation by local communities, and benefit-sharing

arrangements should be made at the beginning of a project. Private

initiatives that take account of such participation should be supported by

government authorities.

3.4.9 Assistance in the creation of property rights

The property rights of local communities need to be strengthened and

secured. This includes examining land tenure structures and strengthening

the rights of indigenous peoples and traditional communities to their

cultural identity and the collective intellectual property of their traditional

knowledge.

While industrial innovations and newly developed products enjoy the

protection of legally enforced intellectual property rights at an international

level, e.g. patent rights (recently internationally strengthened by the GATT

agreement), the collective intellectual property of traditional local

communities and indigenous peoples is not internationally recognised. If

the wealth of experience and valuable knowledge of this part of humanity

is to be used in a fair and equitable way for the management and

sustainable use of biological resources, these rights need to be

strengthened.

Action particularly needs to be taken in the following areas:

• in the evaluation of land tenure systems to support sustainable

management practices and the transfer of vested titles to biological

diversity (keyword: privatisation),

Page 88: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Recommendations

73

• in the establishment of legal instruments to protect the collective

intellectual property of indigenous peoples and traditional local

communities and

• in the examination of the influence that international rules such as the

GATT and TRIPS agreements (strengthening of patent rights) might

have on the availability of environmentally acceptable technologies in

developing countries and the socio-economic and ecological effects that

they may have on the lives of small farmers and indigenous peoples.

3.4.10 Cooperation in establishing global environmental markets

through bilateral and multilateral agreements

As in the implementation of the Climate Convention (with the goal of a

reduction in the emission of CO2), where both bilateral and multilateral

conventions and agreements under public and private law have been made,

similar agreements should be made with the specific goal of biodiversity

conservation. As example that might be mentioned here is the U.S. Forest

for the Future Initiative. The participation and motivation of the private

sector should also be sought in such bilateral or multilateral agreements on

biodiversity.

Page 89: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

75

4 Bibliography

4.1 Cited references

ADAMOWICZ, W. 1994 Stated preference methods for environmentalvaluation. Paper presented at the Agricultural Economics SocietyAnnual Conference, University of Exeter.

ARROW, K.J. 1993 Report of the NOAA panel on contingent valuation.US Federal Register 58(10):4602-4614.

AYLWARD, B.A. 1993 The economic value of pharmaceuticalprospecting and its role in biodiversity conservation. LEECDiscussion Paper 93-05. International Institute for Environment andDevelopment, London.

BARBIER, E., ADAMS, W., KIMMAGE, K. 1991 Economic valuation ofwetland benefits: The Hadejiia-Jama'are floodplain, Nigeria. LondonEnvironmental Economics Centre, Paper 91-02, London.

BARBIER, E.B., BURGESS, J.C., FOLKE, C. 1994 Paradise lost? Theecological economics of biodiversity. Earthscan, London.

BARBIER, E.B., BURGESS, J.C., SWANSON, T., PEARCE, D.W. 1990Elephants, economics and ivory. Earthscan, London.

BARNES, J. & PEARCE, D.W. 1991 The mixed use of habitat. Centre forSocial and Economic Research on the Global Environment, London.

BISBY, F.A. 1995 Characterization of biodiversity. In: Heywood, V. &Watson, R. (eds.): Global biodiversity assessment, 21-106,Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

BISHOP, R.C. 1980 Endangered species: an economic perspective.Transactions of the 45th North American Wildlife and NaturalResources Conference, Wildlife Management Institute, WashingtonD.C., 208-218.

Page 90: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

76

BLAMEY, R.K. 1996 Citizens, consumers and contingent valuation:Clarification and the expression of citizen values and issue-opinions.In: Adamowicz, W.L., Boxall, P.C., Luckert, M.K., Phillips, W.E.,White, W.A. (eds.): Forestry, economics and the environment. CABInternational, Guildford.

BLAMEY, R. & COMMON, M. 1993 Stepping back from contingentvaluation. Centre for Resource and Environmental Studies,Australian National University, Canberra.

BOWES, M.D. & KRUTILLA, J.V. 1989 Multiple-use management: The

economics of public forestlands. Resources for the Future, Washington,

D.C.

BROWN, G.M. 1990 Valuation of genetic resources. In: Orians, G.H.,Brown, G.M., Kunin, W.E., Swierbinski, J.E. (eds.): Thepreservation and valuation of biological resources, 203-228.University of Washington Press, Seattle.

BROWN, G.M., LAYTON, D., LAZO, J. 1994 Valuing habitat andendangered species. Discussion Paper 94-1 (January). Institute forEconomic Research, University of Washington.

BROWN, G. & HENRY, W. 1989 The economic value of elephants.LEEC Discussion Paper 89-12, London Environmental EconomicsCentre.

BURRILL, G.S. & LEE, K.B. 1992 Biotech 93: Acceleratingcommercialization: An industry annual report 1.

CASTRO, R. 1994 The economic opportunity cost of wildlandsconservation areas (EOCWCAs): the case of Costa Rica. HarvardUniversity, Mass.

CHILD, B. 1990 Economic analysis of buffalo range ranch. In: Kiss, A.(ed.): Living with wildlife resource management with localparticipation in Africa. World Bank, Washington D.C., 155-176.

Page 91: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

77

DIXON, J.A. & SHERMAN, P.B. 1990 Economics of protected areas, anew look at the benefits and costs. Earthscan, London.

DOWNES, D.R. 1993 New diplomacy for the biodiversity trade:

Biodiversity, biotechnology and intellectual property in the Convention

on Biological Diversity. Draft. Washington D.C.

ELLIS, G.M. & FISHER, A.C. 1987 Valuing the environment as input.Journal of Environmental Management 25:149-156.

ENDRES, A. & QUERNER, I. 1993 Die Ökonomie natürlicherRessourcen. Wissenschaftliche Buchgesellschaft, Darmstadt.

FARNSWORTH, N.R. & SOEJARTO, D.D. 1985 Potential consequencesof plant extinction in the United States on the current and futureavailability of prescription drugs. Economic Botany 39 (3):231-240.

GLOWKA, L., BURHENNE-GUILMIN, F., SYNGE, H., MCNEELY,J.A., GÜNDLING, L. 1994 A guide to the Convention on BiologicalDiversity. Environmental Policy and Law Paper no. 30, IUCN,Cambridge.

GOLDSTEIN, J.H. 1971 Competition for wetlands in the midwest: Aneconomic analysis. Johns Hopkins University Press for Resources forthe Future, Baltimore - London.

GUARINO, L., RAMATHA RAO, V., REID, R. 1995 Collecting plantgenetic diversity. CAB International, Wallingford and UniversityPress, Cambridge

HAMPICKE, U. 1991 Naturschutz-Ökonomie. Ulmer Verlag, Stuttgart.

HARTWICK, J.M. 1977 Intergenerational equity and the investing of rentsfrom exhaustible resources. American Economic Review 66:972-974.

IMMLER, H. 1993 Welche Wirtschaft braucht die Natur? Frankfurt a.M.

Page 92: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

78

IMMLER, H. 1989 Vom Wert der Natur. Zur ökologischen Reform vonWirtschaft und Gesellschaft. Natur in der ökonomischen Theorie,Teil 3. Westdeutscher Verlag, Opladen.

KAOSARD, M. et al. 1994 Green Finance: A case study of Khao Yai.Final report for the Natural Resources and Environment Program,Thailand Develeopment Research Institute and Harvard Institute forInternational Development.

KRAMER, R. et al. 1993 Valuing a protected tropical forest: A case studyof Madagascar. Paper prepared for the IVth World Congress ofNational Parks and Protected Areas, Caracas.

KRATTIGER, A. & LESSER, W. 1994 The "Facilitator": A newmechanism to strengthen the equitable and sustainable use ofbiodiversity. In: SEI: A clearing-house mechanism to promote andfacilitate technical and scientific cooperation, Stockholm, 13-22.

KRUTILLA, J.V. & FISHER, A.C. 1975 The economics of naturalenvironments. Studies in the valuation of commodity and amenityresources. Johns Hopkins University Press for Resources for theFuture, Baltimore - London - Washington D.C.

LAIRD, S. 1993 Contracts for biodiversity prospecting, In: Reid, W. (ed.):Biodiversity prospecting: Using genetic resources for sustainabledevelopment. World Resources Institute, Washington D.C.

LIPPKE, B. 1996 Incentives for managing landscapes to meet non-timbergoals: Lessons from the Washington Landscape ManagementProject. In: Adamowicz, W.L., Boxall, P.C., Luckert, M.K., Phillips,W.E., White, W.A. (eds.): Forestry, economics and the environment.CAB International, Guildford.

LOUVIERE, J.J. 1994 Relating stated preference measures and models tochoices in real markets. Paper prepared for the US Department ofEnergy and Environmental Protection Agency workshop "Usingcontingent valuation to measure non-market values", Herndon, VA.

Page 93: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

79

MARGGRAF, R. & STREB, S. 1997 Ökonomische Bewertung dernatürlichen Umwelt. Spektrum Akademischer Verlag, Heidelberg,Berlin.

MARKL, H. 1995 Wohin geht die Biologie? Biologen in unserer Zeit3:33-39.

MENDELSOHN, R. & BALICK, M. 1995 The value of undiscoveredpharmaceuticals in tropical forests. Economic Botany 49(2):223-228.

MOONEY, P. & FOWLER, C. 1991 Die Saat des Hungers. Rowohlt,

Hamburg.

MUNASINGHE, M. 1993 Environmental economics and sustainabledevelopment. World Bank Environment Paper 3. Washington D.C.

MYERS, N. 1989 Loss of biological diversity and its potential impact onagriculture and food production. In: Pimentel, D. & Hall, C.W.(eds.): Food and natural resources. Academic Press, San Diego, 49-68.

OECD 1998 Improving the environment through reducing subsidies, PartI. Summary and policy conclusions. OECD, Paris.

OECD 1996 Saving biological diversity - Economic incentives. OECD,Paris.

OECD 1987 The economic value of biological diversity amaong medicinal

plants. Environment Directorate ENV/ECO/87.8. Prepared by Principe,

P. OECD, Paris.

OLDFIELD, M.L. 1984 The value of conserving genetic resources. U.S.Dept. of the Interior, National Park Service, Washington D.C.

PANAYOUTOU, T. 1994 Conservation of biodiversity and economicdevelopment: The concept of transferable development rights. In:Perrings, C. et al. (eds.): Biodiversity conservation: Policy issues andoptions. Kluwer Academic Press, Amsterdam.

Page 94: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

80

PAULUS, S. 1995 Marktwirtschaftliche Instrumente der Umweltpolitik inEntwicklungsländern. GTZ, Eschborn.

PEARCE, D.W. 1990 An economic approach to saving the tropical forests.LEEC Paper 90-06, London.

PEARCE, D.M. & MORAN, D. 1994 The economic value of biodiversity.Earthscan, London.

PERRINGS, C. 1995 The economic valuation of biodiversity. In:Heywood, V.H. (ed.) Global Biodiversity Assessment, UNEP,Cambridge University Press, pp. 823-914.

PERSSON, A. 1994 Macroeconomic policies behind deforestation inCosta Rica. In: Perrings, C., Mäler, K.-G., Folke, C., Holling, C.S.,Jansson, B.-O. (eds.): Biodiversity conservation: Policy issues andoptions. Kluwer Academic Press, Dordrecht.

PETERS, C.M., GENTRY, A.H., MENDELSOHN, R.O. 1989 Valuationof an Amazonian rain forest. Nature 229 (26 June 1989):655-56.

PLOTKIN, M.J. 1992 Tropische Länder als Quelle neuer Produkte vonIndustrie und Landwirtschaft - ein Ausblick. In: Wilson, E.O. (ed.):Ende der biologischen Vielfalt. Springer Verlag, Heidelberg, 128-138.

PRESCOTT-ALLEN, C. & PRESCOTT-ALLEN, R. 1986 The firstresource. Wild species in the North American economy. YaleUniversity Press, New Haven - London.

PRINCIPE, P. 1989 The economic significance of plants and theirconstituents as drugs. In: Wagner, H., Hikino, H., Farnsworth, N.(eds.): Economic and medicinal plant research. Academic Press,London, 3:1-17.

RANDALL, A. 1991 The value of biodiversity. Ambio 20:64-68.

REID, W.V. et al. 1993 A new lease of life. In: Reid, W. (ed.):Biodiversity prospecting. World Resources Institute, WashingtonD.C.

Page 95: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

81

REID, W.V. & MILLER, K.R. 1989 Keeping options alive: The scientificbasis for conserving biodiversity. World Resources Institute,Washington D.C.

RUCK, C. 1990 Die ökonomischen Effekte von Nationalparks inEntwicklungsländern. Verlag Pinus Druck, Augsburg.

RUITENBEEK, H.J. 1992 The rainforest supply price: A tool forevaluating rainforest conservation expenditures. EcologicalEconomics 6(1):57-78.

RUITENBEEK, H.J. 1989 Social cost benefit analysis of the Korupproject, Cameroon. WWF report prepared for the World Wide Fundfor Nature and the Republic of Cameroon, London.

SÁNCHEZ, V. & JUMA, C. 1994 Challenges and opportunities for south-south-cooperation in implementing the Convention on BiologicalDiversity. In: Krattiger, A.F., McNeely, J.A., Lesser, W.H., Miller,K.R., St. Hill, Y., Senanayake, R. (eds.): Widening perspectives onbiodiversity, IUCN. Gland and International Academy of theEnvironment, Geneva, 305-307.

SEDJO, R.A., SIMPSON, R.D., REID, W. 1994 Contracting for GeneticResources, OECD, Group on Economic and Environment PolicyIntegration, Expert Group on Economic Aspects of Biodiversity,Paris.

SOLOW, R.M. 1974 Intergenerational equity and exhaustible resources.Review of Economic Studies, Symposium on the economics ofexhaustible resources, 29-46.

SOLOW, R.M. 1986 On the intertemporal allocation of natural resources.Scandinavian Journal of Economics 88(1):141-149.

STEPHAN, G. & AHLHEIM, M. 1996 Ökonomische Ökologie. SpringerVerlag, Berlin, Heidelberg, New York.

STORK, N.E. & SAMWAYS, M.J. 1995 Inventorying and monitoring ofbiodiversity. In: Heywood, V. & Watson, R. (eds.): Global

Page 96: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

82

biodiversity assessment, 453-544. Cambridge University Press,Cambridge.

SWANSON, T.M. 1994 Biodiversity and intellectual property rights. In:Perrings, C., Mäler, K.-G., Folke, C., Holling, C.S., Jansson, B.-O.(eds.): Biodiversity loss: Ecological and economic issues. CambridgeUniversity Press, Cambridge.

TOBIAS, D. & MENDELSOHN, R. 1991 Valuing ecotourism in a tropicalrain-forest reserve. Ambio 20:91-93.

TURNER, R.K., DENT, D., HEY, R.D. 1983 Valuation of theenvironmental impact of wetland flood protection and drainageschemes. Environment and Planning A 15:871-888.

UNEP 1993 Guidelines for country studies on biodiversity. UNEP,Nairobi.

VITOUSEK, P. et al. 1986 Human appropriation of products ofphotosynthesis. BioScience 36(6):368-373.

VOGEL, J.H. 1994 Genes for sale - Privatization as a conservation policy.Oxford University Press, Oxford, New York.

WELLS, M. 1992 Fiduciary funds to preserve biodiversity: Green funds.Ecologia.

WICKE, L. 1986 Die ökologischen Milliarden. Kösel, Munich.

WILLIS, K.G., BENSON, J.F., SAUNDERS, C.M. 1988 The impact ofagricultural policy on the costs of nature conservation. LandEconomics 64:147-157.

WOODRUFF, D.S. & GALL, G.A.E. 1992 Genetics and conservation.Agriculture, Ecosystems and Environment 42:53-73.

Page 97: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

83

4.2 Other references

Abramowitz, J. 1991 Investing in biodiversity: US research andconservation efforts in developing countries. World ResourcesInstitute, Washington D.C.

Adamowicz, W.L., Boxall, P.C., Luckert, M.K., Phillips, W.E., White,W.A. (eds.) 1996 Forestry, economics and the environment. CABInternational, Guildford.

Adamowicz, W., Louviere, J., Williams, M. 1994 Combining stated andrevealed preference methods for valuing environmental amenities.Journal of Environmental Management 26.

Adamowicz, W., Asafu-Adalaye, J., Boxall, P.C., Philips, W. 1991Components of the economic value of wildlife: An Alberta study.The Canadian Field Naturalist. 105(3):423-429.

Adamowicz, W., Phillips, W., Pattison, W. 1986 The distribution ofeconomic benefits from Alberta duck production. Wildlife SocietyBulletin 14(4).

Adger, W.N., Brown, K. Cervigni, R., Moran, D. 1995 Total economicvalue of forests in Mexico. Ambio 24:286-296.

Altschul, S. v. Reis 1973 Drugs and foods from little-known plants.Harvard University Press, Cambridge, Mass. - London.

Amacher, R.C., Tollison, R.D., Willett, T.D. 1972 The economics of fatalmistakes: Fiscal mechanisms for preserving endangered predators.Public Policy 20:411-441.

Anderson, D. & Williams, R.H. 1994 The cost effectiveness of GEFprojects. GEF Working Paper no. 6, Washington D.C

Antonovic, J. 1990 Genetically based measures of uniqueness. In: Orians,G.H., Brown, G.M., Kunin, W.E., Swierzinbisnki, J.E. (eds.): Thepreservation and valuation of genetic resources. University ofWashington Press, Seattle, 94-118.

Page 98: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

84

Appasamy, P. 1993 Role of non-timber forest products in a subsistenceeconomy: the case of a joint forestry project in India. EconomicBotany 47.

Arndt, U., Nobel, W., Schweizer, B. 1987 Bioindikatoren. Möglichkeiten,Grenzen und neue Erkenntnisse. Ulmer Verlag, Stuttgart.

Arrow, K.J. & Fisher, A.C. 1974 Environmental preservation, uncertaintyand irreversibility. Quarterly Journal of Economics 88:312-319.

Asafu-Adjaye, J., Phillips, W., Adamowicz, W. 1989 Towards themeasurement of total economic value: The case of wildlife resourcesin Alberta. Staff paper no. 89-16, Department of Rural Economy,University of Alberta, Edmonton, Alberta.

Attfield, R. 1983 The ethics of environmental concern. Blackwell, Oxford.

Association of Environmental and Resource Economists Workshop 1992Benefit transfer: procedures, problems, and research needs. Casestudy synopsis.

Aylward, B. & Barbier, E. 1992 Valuing environmental functions indeveloping countries. Biodiversity and Conservation 1:34-50.

Bachmura, F.T. 1971 The economics of vanishing species. NaturalResources Journal 11:674-692.

Balandrin, M.F., Klocke, J.A., Wurtele, E.S., Bollinger, W.H. 1985Natural plant chemicals: sources of industrial and medicinalmaterials. Science 228:1154-1160.

Balick, M. & Mendelsohn, R. 1992 Assessing the economic value oftraditional medicines from tropical rainforests. Conservation Biology6(1).

Barbier, E. 1992 Rehabilitating gum arabic systems in Sudan: economicand environmental implications. Environmental and ResourceEconomics 2:341-358.

Page 99: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

85

Barbier, E. 1994 Valuing environmental functions: tropical wetlands. LandEconomics 70(2):155-173.

Barbier, E.B., Burgess, J.C., Markandya, A. 1991 The economics oftropical deforestation. Ambio 20:55-58.

Barbier, E.B. 1989 The economic value of ecosystems: 1. Tropicalwetlands. LEEC, Gatekeeper series no. 89-02.

Barbier, E.B. 1989 Economics, natural resources scarcity anddevelopment. Conventional and alternative views. Earthscan,London.

Barrett, S. 1991 Economic instruments for climate change policy. In:OECD (ed.): Environmental policy: How to apply economicinstruments. OECD, Paris, 53-110.

Barrett, S. 1991 Economic analysis of international environmentalagreements: Lessons for a global warming treaty. In: OECD (ed.):Environmental policy: How to apply economic instruments. OECD,Paris, 111-149.

Barstow, R. 1986 Non-consumptive utilization of whales. Ambio 15:155-163.

Bateman, I. et al. 1992 A contingent valuation study of the NorfolkBroads. Report to the National Rivers Authority.

Batie, S.S., Mabbs-Zeno, C.C. 1985 Opportunity costs of preservingcoastal wetlands: a case study of a recreational housing development.Land Economics 61:1-9.

Beck, G. 1990 Naturschutz - aus ökonomischer Sicht. Dissertation atBerlin Technical University.

Benkert, W. 1987 Die Bedeutung des Gemeinlastprinzips in derUmweltpolitik. Zeitschrift für Umweltpolitik und Umweltrecht9:213-229.

Page 100: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

86

Bennett, E. & Reynolds, C. 1993 The value of a mangrove area inSarawak. Biodiversity and Conservation 2:359-375.

Bennett, E. 1978 Threats to crop plant genetic resources. In: Hawkes, J.G.(ed.): Conservation and agriculture. Duckworth, London, 113-122.

Bennett, J. 1984 Using direct questioning to value the existence benefits ofpreserved natural areas. Australian Journal of AgriculturalEconomics 28(2/3):136-152.

Benson, J.F. & Willis, K.J. 1990 The aggregate value of non-pricedrecreation benefits of the Forestry Commission Estate. Report to theForestry Commission, University of Newcastle Upon Tyne.

Bergstrom, J.C., Stoll, J.R., Titre, J.P., Wright, V.L. 1990 Economic valueof wetlands-based recreation. Ecological Economics 2:129-147.

Binswanger, H. 1989 Brazilian policies that encourage deforestation in theAmazon. World Bank, Environment Department, Working Paper 16,Washington D.C.

Bishop, R.C. 1982 Option value: An exposition and extension. LandEconomics 58:1-15.

Bishop, R.C. 1978 Endangered species and uncertainty: The economics ofa safe minimum standard. American Journal of AgruculturalEconomics 61:10-18.

Blab, J., Forst, C., Klär, C., Niclas, G., Wey, H., Woithe, G. 1991Förderprogramme zur Errichtung und Sicherung schutzwürdigerTeile von Natur und Landschaft mit gesamtstaatlich repräsentativerBedeutung. Natur und Landschaft 66:3-9.

Blum, E. 1993 Incentive policies and forest use in the Phillipines. In:Repetto, R. & Gillis, M. (eds.): Public policies and the misuse offorest resources. World Resources Institute, Washington D.C.

Blum, E. 1993 Making biodiversity conservation profitable: a case studyof the Merck/INBio agreement. Environment 35:16-20, 38-45.

Page 101: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

87

Boado, E. 1989 Incentive policies and forest use in the Philippines. In:Repetto, R. & Gillis, M. (eds.): Public policies and the misuse offorest resources. World Resources Institute, Washington D.C.

Boadu, F.O. 1992 Contingent valuation for household water in ruralGhana. Journal of Agricultural Economics 43(3).

Bohn, A. & Byerlee, D. 1993 The wheat breeding industry in developingcountries: An analysis of investments and impacts. CentroInternacional de CIMMYT, Singapore.

Bonus, H. 1986 Eine Lanze für den "Wasserpfennig". Wider dieVulgärform des Verursacherprinzips. Wirtschaftsdienst1986/IX:451-455.

Bonus, H. 1981 Instrumente einer ökologieverträglichenWirtschaftspolitik. In: Binswanger, H.C., Bonus, H., Timmermann,M. (eds.): Wirtschaft und Umwelt, Kohlkammer Verlag, Stuttgart,84-163.

Bonus, H. 1980 Öffentliche Güter und der Öffentlichkeitsgrad von Gütern.Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft 136:50-81.

Bowers, J. 1988 Farm incomes and the benefit of environmentalprotection. In: Collard, D., Pearce, D., Ulph, D. (eds.): Economics,growth and sustainable environments. Essays in memory of RichardLecomber. Macmillan, Basingstoke - London, 161-171.

Bowers, J. 1988 Cost-benefit analysis in theory and practice: Agriculturalland drainage projects. In: Turner, E.K. (ed.): Sustainableenvironmental management. Belhaven Press - Westview Press,London - Boulder, 265-269.

Bowles, I.A. & Prickett, G.T. 1994 Reframing the green window: Ananalysis of the GEF pilot phase approach to biodiversity and globalwarming and recommendations for the operational phase.Conservation International, Natural Resources Defense Council,Washington D.C.

Page 102: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

88

Boyd, R. & Hyde, W. 1989 Forestry sector intervention: the impacts ofpublic regulation on social welfare. Iowa State University Press.

Boyle, K.J. & Bergstrom, J.C. 1992 Benefit transfer studies: myths,pragmatism, and idealism. Water Resources Research 28(3):657-663.

Braatz, S., Davis, G., Rees, C. 1992 Conserving biological diversity: Astrategy for protected areas in the Asia-Pacific region. World BankTechnical Paper 193. Washington D.C.

Bradley, P.N. & McNamara, K. (eds.) 1993 Living with trees: Policies forforest management in Zimbabwe. World Bank Technical Paper 210,Washington D.C.

Bromley, D. & Cernea, M. 1989 The management of common propertyresources: Some conceptual and operational fallacies. World BankDiscussion Paper no. 57.

Brookshire, D.S. & Neill, H.R. 1992 Benefit transfers: Conceptual andempirical issues. Water Resources Research 28(3):651-655.

Brookshire, D.S., Eubanks, L.S., Randall, A. 1983 Estimating optionprices and existence values for wildlife resources. Land Economics59:1-15.

Brookshire, D.S., David, S., Ives, B., Schulze, W. 1976 The valuation ofaesthetic preferences. Journal of Environmental Economics andManagement 3(3):325-346.

Browder, J.O. 1988 The social costs of rainforest destruction. Interciencia13(2).

Browder, J.O. 1988 Public policy and deforestation in the BrazilianAmazon. In: Repetto, R. & Gillis, M. (eds.): Public policies and themisuse of forest resources. World Resources Institute, WashingtonD.C.,

Brown, G. & Goldstein, J.H. 1984 A model for valuing endangeredspecies. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management11:303-309.

Page 103: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

89

Brown, K. 1992 Carbon sequestration and storage in tropical forests.Centre for Social and Economic Research on the GlobalEnvironment, Discussion Paper 92, University of East Anglia andUniversity College London, Norwich and London.

Brown, K. & Goldin, I. 1992 The future of agriculture: Developingcountry implications. Development Centre Studies, OECD, Paris.

Brown, K., Pearce, D.W., Perrings, C., Swanson, T. 1993 Economics andthe conservation of biological diversity. GEF Working Paper 2.Washington D.C.

Callicott, J.B. 1986 On the intrinsic value of nonhuman species. In:Norton, B.G. (ed.): The preservation of species. University Press,Princeton, 138-172.

Cameron, T.A. & Quiggin, J. 1994 Estimation using contingent valuationdata from a 'dichotomous choice with follow-up' questionnaire.Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 27:218-234.

Carson, R. et al. 1992 A contingent valuation study of lost passive valuesresulting from the Exxon Valdez oil spill. Report to the AttorneyGeneral of the State of Alaska.

Carter, M. 1987 Economic and socio-economic impacts of the ThornsStarfish on the Great Barriert Reef. Report to the Great Barrier ReefMarine Park Authority, Institute of Applied Environmental Research,Griffith University, Brisbane.

Cernea, M. 1993 The sociologist's approach to sustainable development.Finance and Development 30(4):11-13.

Cervigni, R. 1993 Biodiversity, incentives to deforest and tradeabledevelopment rights. GEC working paper 93-07, Centre for Socialand Economic Research on the Global Environment, University ofEast Anglia, University College London.

Cervigni, R. 1993 Estimating the benefits of plant genetic resources forfood and agriculture: Suggested approaches. Centre for Social and

Page 104: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

90

Economic Research on the Global Environment, University College,London and University of East Anglia.

Cesario, F.J. 1976 Value of time in recreation benefit studies. LandEconomics 52:32-41.

Child, B. 1990 Assessment of wildlife utilization as a land use option inthe semi-arid rangelands of Southern Africa. In: Kiss, A. (ed.):Living with wildlife. Wildlife resource management with localparticipation in Africa. World Bank, Washington D.C., Annex 3:193-204.

Chopra, K. 1993 The value of non-timber forest products: an estimatefrom India. Economic Botany 47(3):251-257.

Cicchetti, C.J., Fisher, A., Smith, V.K. 1971 An econometric evaluation ofa generalized consumer surplus measure: The mineral kingcontroversy. Econometrica 39:813-827.

Cicchetti, C.J. & Freeman, A.M. 1971 Option demand and consumersurplus: Further comment. Quarterly Journal of Economics 85:528-539.

Ciriacy-Wantrup, S.V. 1952 Resource conservation economics andpolitics. University of California, Division of Agricultural Sciences,Berkeley and Los Angeles.

Clark, C.W. 1976 Mathematical bioeconomics: The optimal managementof renewable resources. John Wiley, New York.

Cleaver, K., Munasinghe, M., Dyson, M., Egli, N., Peuker, A., Wencelius,F. (eds.) 1992 Conservation of West and Central African rainforests.World Bank Environment Paper 1. Washington D.C.

Cline, W. 1992 The economics of global warming. International Institutefor International Economics, Washington D.C.

Collard, D., Pearce, D., Ulph, D. (eds.) 1988 Economics, growth andsustainable environments. Essays in memory of Richard Lecomber,Macmillan, Basingstoke - London.

Page 105: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

91

Common, M. & Perrings, C. 1992 Towards an ecological economics ofsustainability. Ecological Economics 6:7-34.

Cooper, D., Vellvé, R., Hobbelink, H. (eds.) 1992 Growing diversity:Genetic resources and local food security. Intermediate TechnologyPublications, London.

Cornes, R. & Sandler, T. 1986 The theory of externalities, public goodsand club goods. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, U.K, NewYork, Port Chester, Melbourne, Sydney.

Cornia, G.A., Jolly, R., Stewart, F. (eds.) 1989 Adjustment with a humanface. Oxford University Press, New York.

Costanza, R. & Daly, H.E. 1987 Toward an ecological economics.Ecological Modelling 38:1-7.

Costanza, R., Farber, S., Maxwell, J. 1989 Valuation and management ofwetland ecosystems. Ecological Economics 1(4):335-362.

Cummings, R.G., Brookshire, D.S., Schulze, W.D. 1986 Valuing publicgoods. An assessment of the contingent valuation method. Rowman& Allanheld, Totowa, N.J.

Danielson, L.E., Leitch, J.A. 1986 Private versus public economics ofprairie wetland allocation. Journal of Environmental Economics andManagement 13(1).

Dasgupta, A.K. & Pearce, D.W. 1978 Cost-benefit analysis, theory andpractice. Macmillan, London - Basingstoke.

Davis, S.G. (ed.) 1993 Indigenous views of land and the environment.World Bank Discussion Paper 188. Washington S.C.

Davis, S., Castilleja, G., Poole, P.J., Geisler, C. (eds.) 1993 The socialchallenge of biodiversity conservation. GEF Working Paper 1,Washington D.C.

Page 106: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

92

Deacon, R. & Murphy, P. 1992 The structure of an environmentaltransaction: the debt-for-nature swap. Department of Economics,University of California at Santa Barbara.

Decker, D.J. & Goff, G.R. (eds.) 1987 Valuing wildlife. Economic andsocial perspectives. Westview Press, Boulder - London.

deGroot, R. 1992 Functions and values of protected areas: Acomprehensive framework for assessing the benefits of protectedareas to human society. Climate Change Research Centre,Agricultural University, Wageningen.

deLacy, T. & Lockwood, M. 19zz Estimating the non-market values ofnature conservation resources Australia. Charles Sturt University,Albury, Australia.

Desvousges, W.H., Gable, A.R., Dunford, R.W., Hudson, S. 1993Contingent valuation: the wrong tool to measure passive-use losses.Choices II:9-11

Dewees, P.A. 1993 Trees, land, and labor. World Bank Environment Paper4. Washington D.C.

Diamond, A.W. & Filion, F.L. (eds.) 1987 The value of birds. ICBPTechnical Publication no. 6, IUCN, Cambridge.

Dinerstein, E. & Wikramanayake, E. 1993 Beyond hotspots: how toprioritise investments to conserve biodiversity in the Indo-Pacificregion. Conserv. Biol. 7(1):53-65.

Dixon, J.A., Scura, L.F., van't Hof, T. 1993 Meeting ecological andeconomic goals: Marine parks in the Caribbean. Ambio 22(2-3):117-125.

Dixon, J.A. & Sherman, P.B. 1991 Economics of protected areas. Ambio20:68-74.

Dogse, P. & von Droste, B. 1990 Debt for nature exchanges and biospherereserves. UNESCO, Paris.

Page 107: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

93

D'Silva, E. & Appanah, S. 1993 Forestry management for sustainabledevelopment. EDI Policy Seminar Report 32. World Bank,Washington D.C.

Duke, J.A. 1976 Economic appraisal of endangered plant species.Phytologica 34:21-27.

Durning, A.B. 1989 Poverty and the environment: Reversing thedownward spiral. Worldwatch Paper 92, Worldwatch Institute,Washington D.C.

Ebenroth, C.T. & Bühler, S. 1990 Verschuldungskrise und Umweltschutz -Debt-for-Nature-Swaps, eine Lösung für zwei Probleme? Natur undRecht 6:260-266.

Ehrlich, P.R. & Ehrlich, A.H. 1992 The value of biodiversity. Ambio21(3).

Eltringham, S.K. 1984 Wildlife resources and economic development.John Wiley, Chichester.

Endres, A. 1985 Umwelt- und Ressourcenökonomie. Erträge derForschung 229, Wissenschaftliche Buchgesellschaft, Darmstadt.

English, J., Tiffen, M., Mortimer, M. 1993 Land resource management inMachakos district, Kenya 1930-1990. World Bank EnvironmentPaper 5, Washington D.C.

Evenson, R.E. 1991 Genetic resources: assessing economic value. In:Vincent, J., Crawford, E., Hoehn, J. (eds.): Valuing environmentalbenefits in developing economies. Proceedings of a seminar seriesheld in February-May 1990 at Michigan State University, SpecialReport no. 29.

Faeth, P., Cort, C., Livernash, R. 1994 Evaluating the carbon sequestrationbenefits of forestry projects in less developed countries. WorldRessources Institute, Washington D.C.

Fankhauser, S. 1992 A point estimate of the economic damage from globalwarming. Centre for Social and Economic Research on the Global

Page 108: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

94

Environment. CSERGE Discussion Paper 92, University of EastAnglia and University College London, Norwich and London.

Fankhauser, S. 1994 The social costs of greenhouse gas emissions: anexpected value approach. Energy Journal 15(2).

Farber, S. & Costanza, R. 1987 The value of coastal wetlands forprotection of property against hurricane wind damage. Journal ofEnvironmental Economics and Management:14:143-151.

Farnsworth, N.R. 1988 Screening plants for new medicines. In: Wilson,E.O. (ed.): Biodiversity. National Academy Press, Washington D.C.,83-97.

Favre, D.S. 1989 International trade in endanered species. A guide toCITES. Martinus Nijhoff, Dordrecht

Fearnside, P.M. 1990 The rate and extent of deforestation in BrazilianAmazonia. Environmental Conservation 17:213-226.

Festl, J. 1980 Kosten-Nutzen-Analyse von Meliorationen undKultivierung. Dissertation, Hohenheim.

Findeisen, C. 1991 Natural products research and the potential role of thepharmaceutical industry in tropical forest conservation. RainforestAlliance, New York.

Fisher, A.C. & Krutilla, J.V. 1974 Valuing long run ecologicalconsequences and irreversibilities. Journal of EnvironmentalEconomies and Management 1:96-108.

Fisher, A.C. & Hanemann, W.M. 1985 Endangered species: Theeconomies of irreversible damage. In: Hall, D.O., Myers, N.,Margaris, N.S. (eds.): Economies of ecosystem management. JunkPublications, Dordrecht, 129-138.

Fitzgerald, S.G. 1986 World Bank pledges to protect wildlands.BioScience 36:712-715.

Page 109: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

95

Freeman, A.M. III 1984 The quasi-option value of irreversibledevelopment. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management11:292-295.

Freeman, A.M. III 1979 The benefits of environmental improvement:Theory and practice. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.

French, H. 1994 Umgestaltung der Weltbank. In: Brown, L.R. (ed.): ZurLage der Welt 1994. Fischer, Frankfurt, 211-244

Frey, R.L. & Blöchinger, H. 1991 Schützen oder Nutzen.Ausgleichszahlungen im Natur- und Landschaftsschutz. Rüegger,Chur - Zürich.

Furtado, J. 1990 Biological diversity: Global conservation needs and costs.Environment Programme Report, Centre for IntegratedDevelopment, London.

Gámez, R. et al. 1993 Costa Rica's conservation program and NationalBiodiversity Institute (INBio). In: Reid, W. et al. (eds.): Biodiversityprospecting: Using genetic resources for sustainable development.World Resources Institute, Washington D.C.

Gans, O. & Margraf, R. 1997 Kosten-Nutzen-Analyse und ökonomischePolitikbewertung, Vol. I: Wohlfahrtsmessung.Betriebswirtschaftliche Investitionskriterien. Springer, Berlin, NewYork, Heidelberg.

Germann, D. 1989 Erlauben die defizitären Wirtschaftsergebnisse eineunveränderte Beibehaltung der forstpolitischen Zielsetzung? EinDiskussionsbeitrag - am Beispiel der HessischenLandesforstverwaltung. Forstarchiv 60:219-222.

Gillis, M. 1988 Indonesia: Public policies, resource management and thetropical forest. In: Repetto, R. & Gillis, M. (eds.): Public policies andthe misuse of forest resources. World Resources Institute,Washington D.C.

Page 110: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

96

Gillis, M. 1988 Malaysia: Public policies and the tropical forest. In:Repetto, R. & Gillis, M. (eds.): Public policies and the misuse offorest resources. World Resources Institute, Washington D.C.

Gillis, M. 1988 West Africa: Resource management policies and thetropical forest. In: Repetto, R. & Gillis, M. (eds.): Public policies andthe misuse of forest resources, World Resources Institute,Washington D.C.

Global Environmental Facility 1992 Memorandum of understanding onNorwegian funding of pilot demonstration projects for jointimplementation arrangements under the climate convention GEF.World Bank, Washington D.C.

Godoy, R. & Bawa, K. 1993 The economic value and sustainable harvestof plants and animals from the tropical rainforest: Assumptions,hypotheses, and methods. Economic Botany 47(3):215-219.

Godoy, R., Lubowski, R., Markandya, A. 1993 A method for the economicvaluation of non-timber tropical forest products. Economic Botany47(3):220-233.

Gödde, M. 1990 Unternehmen als Sponsoren. Umwelt (VDI) 20:632-634.

Goodland, R.J.A. 1988 A major new opportunity to finance thepreservation of biodiversity. In: Wilson, E.O. (ed.): Biodiversity.National Academy Press, Washington D.C.

Goodland, R.J.A. & Webb, M. 1987 The management of cultural propertyin World Bank assisted projects. World Bank Technical Paper 62.

Gradwohl, J. & Greenberg, R. 1988 Saving the tropical forests. Earthscan,London.

Green, R.M. 1977 Intergenerational distributive justice and environmentalresponsibility. BioScience 27:260-265.

Grimes, A. et al. 1993 Valuing the rainforest: The economic value of non-timber forest products in Ecuador. Yale School of Forestry andEnvironmental Studies, New Haven.

Page 111: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

97

GTZ 1997 Bodenrecht und Bodenordnung. GTZ, Eschborn.

GTZ 1993 Die Rolle von Abreizen bei der Anwendung von RMSH alsVorgehensweise. GTZ, Eschborn.

Gutierrez, B. & Pearce, D.W. 1992 Estimating the environmental benefitsof the Amazon forest: an intertemporal valuation exercise. GECworking paper 92-44, Centre for Social and Economic Research onthe Global Environment, University College London and Universityof East Anglia, London and Norwich.

Hall, P. & Bawa, K. 1993 Methods to assess the impact of extraction ofnon-timber tropical forest products on plant populations. EconomicBotany 47(3):234-247.

Hampicke, U. 1991 Neoklassik und Zeitpräferenz - derDiskontierungsnebel. In: Beckenbach, F. (ed.): Die ökologischeHerausforderung für die ökonomische Theorie. Metropolis, Marburg,127-149.

Hampicke, U. 1990 Naturschutzfinanzierung. In: GanzheitlicheNaturschutzpolitik statt Reservatsdenken. Dokumentation einerAnhörung der Grünen im Bundestag, Bonn, 42-64.

Hampicke, U. 1990 Ökologische und ökonomische Probleme derGrünlandextensivierung. Naturschutz in Nordhessen 11:31-46.

Hampicke, U. 1990 Naturschutz als eine regionalwirtschaftliche Option.In: deHaen, H. & Isermeyer, F. (eds.): Ländlicher Raum im Abseits?Vauk, Kiel, 178-193.

Hampicke, U. 1989 Was darf und was kann monetarisiert werden? In:Möglichkeiten und Grenzen der Monetarisierung von Natur undUmwelt. Schriftenreihe des IÖW 88-20, Institut für ÖkologischeWirtschaftsforschung, Berlin, 19-41.

Hampicke, U. 1989 Volks- und betriebswirtschaftliche Kosten desNaturschutzes in der Landwirtschaft und Möglichkeiten derFinanzierung. Laufener Seminarbeiträge 87-3:60-84.

Page 112: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

98

Hampicke, U. 1988 Extensivierung der Landwirtschaft für denNaturschutz - Ziele, Rahmenbedingungen und Maßnahmen.Schriftenreihe Bayer. Landesamt für Umweltschutz 84:9-35.

Hampicke, U. 1987 Naturschutz als ökonomisches Problem. Zeitschrift fürUmweltpolitik und Umweltrecht 10:157-195.

Hampicke, U. 1987 Ökologische Vorgaben für die Agrarökonomie.Umrisse einer Landwirtschaft ohne Ausrottung von Arten.Internationales Institut für Umwelt und Gesellschaft, Berlin.

Hampicke, U. 1985 Die volkswirtschaftlichen Kosten des Naturschutzes inBerlin. Ökonomische Begleitstudie zu den "Grundlagen für dasArtenschutzprogramm Berlin". Technische Universität, Berlin.

Hampicke, U. 1985 Die voraussichtlichen Kosten einernaturschutzgerechten Landwirtschaft. Kali-Briefe17:701-714.

Hampicke, U. 1983 Die voraussichtlichen Kosten einer umweltgerechtenLandwirtschaft. Landschaft+Stadt 15:171-183.

Hampicke, U., Horlitz,T., Kiemstedt, H., Tampe, K., Timp, D., Walters, M.1991 Kosten und Wertschätzung des Arten- und Biotopschutzes.Erich Schmidt Verlag, Berlin.

Hanemann, W.M. 1991 Willingness to pay and willingness to accept: Howmuch can they differ? American Economic Review 81(3):663-647.

Hanemann, W.M. 1989 Welfare evaluations in contingent valuation:Experiments with discrete responses. American Journal ofAgricultural Economics 66(3):32-34.

Hanemann, W.M 1988 Economics and the preservation of biodiversity. In:Wilson, E.O. (ed.): Biodiversity. National Academy Press,Washington D.C., 193-199.

Hanley, N.D. 1990 Valuation of environmental effects: final report - stageone. Industry Department of Scotland and the Scottish DevelopmentAgency.

Page 113: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

99

Hanley, N.D. & Craig, S. 1991 Wilderness development decisions and theKrutilla-Fisher model: the case of Scotland's flow country.Ecological Economics 4(2):145-162.

Hanley, N.D. & Spash, C. 1993 Preferences, information and biodiversitypreservation. Discussion papers in Economics 93-12, Department ofEconomics, University of Stirling.

Hanusch, H. 1987 Nutzen-Kosten-Analyse. Vahlen, Munich.

Hartje, V.J. 1986 Zur Erhaltung genetischer Ressourcen. Zeitschrift fürWirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften 106:229-252.

Hausman, J.A., Leonard, G.K., McFadden, D. 1992 Assessing use valuelosses due to natural resource injury. Cambridge Economics Inc.,Cambridge, Mass.

Heath, R. 1992 Wildlife based tourism in a developing country: Theeconomic implications. University of Zimbabwe.

Heath, R. 1992 The growth in wildlife based tourism in Zimbabwe.University of Zimbabwe.

Heberlein, T.A. 1986 Measuring resource values: the reliabilitiy andvalidity of dichtomous contingent valuation measures. Paperpresented at the American Sociological Association Meeting, NewYork.

Hecht, S., Norgaard, R., Possio, G. 1988 The economics of cattle ranchingin Eastern Amazonia. Interciencia 13(5):233-239.

Henry, C. 1974 Investment decisions under uncertainty: The"irreversibility effect". American Economic Review 64:1006-1012.

Hof, J. & King, D. 1991 Recreational demand by tourists for saltwaterbeach days: Comment. Journal of Environmental Economics andManagement 22:281-291.

Page 114: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

100

Hoffmann, H. & Wohlgschaft, M. 1990 Ökonomische Betrachtungen zumBayerischen Kulturlandschaftsprogramm. Berichte überLandwirtschaft 68:196-215.

Hohl, A. & Tisdell, C. 1993 How useful are environmental safetystandards in economics? - The example of safe minimum standardsfor protection of species. Biodiversity and Conservation 2:168-181.

Huber, R. 1992 Case studies showing cost/benefit of tourism and protectedareas development. Paper presented at the IVth World Congress onNational Parks and Protected Areas, Caracas.

Hundloe, T.J. 1990 Measuring the value of the Great Barrier Reef.Australian Parks and Recreation 26(3):11-15.

Hundsdorfer, M. 1989 Kostendatei für Maßnahmen des Naturschutzes undder Landschaftspflege. Materialien 55, BayerischesStaatsministerium für Landesentwicklung und Umweltfragen,Munich.

Imber, D., Stevenson, G., Wilks, L. 1991 A contingent valuation survey ofthe Kakadu conservation zone. Resource Assessment Commission,Research Paper no. 3, Canberra.

IUCN, The Nature Conservancy, WWF 1994 First global forum onenvironmental funds. Cambridge, U.K.

Jansen, D.J. 1990 Sustainable wildlife utilization in the Zambezi valley ofZimbabwe: Economic, ecological and political tradeoffs. Projectpaper no. 10, WWF Multispecies Project, Harare.

Jarass, L., Niesslein, E., Obermair, G.M. 1989 Von derSozialkostentheorie zum umweltpolitischen Steuerungsinstrument.Nomos, Baden-Baden.

Johansson, P.-O., Kristrom, B., Maler, K. 1989 Welfare evaluations incontingent valuation: Experiments with discrete response data:Comment. American Journal of Agricultural Economics.

Page 115: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

101

Johansson, P.-O. & Löfgren, K.G. 1985 The economics of forestry andnatural resources. Basil Blackwell, Oxford.

Kahnemann, D., Knetsch, J.L. 1992 Valuing public goods: The purchaseof moral satisfaction. Journal of Environmental Economics andManagement 22(1):57-70.

Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J.L., Thaler, R.H. 1990 Experimental tests of theendowment effect and the coarse theorem. Journal of PoliticalEconomy 98(6).

Karl, H. & Klemmer, P. 1988 Ökonomische und ökologischeAgrarmarktreform und Ansatzpunkte für die Vergabe vonBewirtschaftungsbeiträgen. Zeitschrift für Umweltpolitik undUmweltrecht 11:339-359.

Katzman, M. & Cale, W. 1990 Tropical forest preservation usingeconomic incentives: A proposal of conservation easements.BioScience 40(11):827-832.

King, K. 1993 The incremental costs of global environmental benefits.GEF Working Paper 5. Washington D.C.

King, K. 1993 Issues to be addressed by the GEF program for measuringincremental costs for the environment. GEF Working Paper 8.Washington D.C.

Kling, C.L. 1988 Comparing welfare estimates of environmental qualitychanges from recreational demand models. Journal of EnvironmentalEconomics and Management 15(3):331-340.

Kling, C.L. 1987 A simulation approach to comparing multiple-siterecreation-demand models using Chesapeake Bay survey data.Marine Resource Economics 4(2):95-109.

Klockow, S. & Matthes, U. 1991 Umweltbedingte Folgekosten im BereichFreizeit und Erholung. Forschungsvorhaben 101 03 110/06 desUmweltbundesamtes. Umweltbundesamt Berlin, Texte 4/91.

Page 116: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

102

Knebel, B. & Krause, M. 1989 Gesamtwirtschaftliche Analyse derFlurbereinigung. Dissertation, Kassel.

Knetsch, J.L. & Sinden, J. 1984 Willingness to pay and compensationdemanded: Experimental evidence of an unexpected disparity inmeasures of value. Quarterly Journal of Economics XCIX(3):507-521.

Köhne, M. 1987 Auflagen zum Natur- und Wasserschutz: Rechtliche undökonomische Aspekte der Entschädigung. In: Landwirtschaft undUmwelt, Schriften der Gesellschaft für Wirtschafts- undSozialwissenschaften 23:347-360.

Kosmo, M. 1989 Commercial energy subsidies in developing countries.Energy Policy 17:244-253.

Kuhlmann, F. & Müller, H. 1986 Zur ökonomischen Bewertung vonNaturschutzauflagen für den Landwirtschaftsbetrieb.Landwirtschaftsverlag Hessen, Friedrichsdorf im Taunus.

Kuliopulos, H. 1990 Amazon biodiversity. Science 248:1305.

Ledec, G. & Goodland, R. 1992 Harmonizing sustainable developmentwith conservation of wildlands. In: Kapoor-Vijay, P. & White, J.(eds.): Conservation biology: a training manual for biologicaldiversity and genetic resources. Commonwealth Science Council,London.

Leibundgut, H. 1983 Führen naturnahe Waldbauverfahren zurbetriebswirtschaftlichen Erfolgsverbesserung? Forstarchiv 54:47-51.

Leslie, A.J. 1987 A second look at the economics of natural managementsystems in tropical mixed forests. Unasylva 39(155):46-58.

Lever, H. & Huhne, C. 1987 Debt and danger. The world financial crisis.Penguin Books, Middle Essex.

Loehmann, E.T. & De, V.H. 1992 Application of stochastic choicemodelling to policy analysis of public goods: A case study of air

Page 117: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

103

quality improvements. Review of Economics and Statistics 64:474-480.

Loomis, J.B. 1990 Comparative reliability of the dichotomous choice andopen ended valuation techniques. Journal of EnvironmentalEconomics and Management 18(1):78-85.

Loomis, J.B. 1989 Test-retest reliability of the contingent valuationmethod: A comparison of general population and visitor response.American Journal of Agricultural Economics 71:76-84.

Loomis, J.B. 1988 Contingent valuation using dichotomous choice models.Journal of Leisure Research 20(1):46-56.

Lynne, G.D., Conroy, P., Prochaska, F.J. 1981 Economic valuation ofmarsh areas for marine production processes. Journal ofEnvironmental Economics and Management 8:175-186.

Mährlein, A. 1990 Einzelwirtschaftliche Auswirkungen vonNaturschutzauflagen. Vauk, Kiel.

Mäler, K.G. 1977 A note on the use of property values in estimatingmarginal willingness to pay for environmental quality. Journal ofEnvironmental Economics and Management 4(4):355-369.

Magrath, W. & Arens, P. 1989 The cost of soil erosion in Java: A naturalresource accounting approach. Environment Department, WorkingPaper no. 18, World Bank, Washington D.C.

Mahar, D. 1989 Government policies and deforestation in Brazil's Amazonregion. World Bank, Washington D.C.

Maille, P. & Mendelsohn, R. 1993 Valuing ecotourism in Madagascar.Journal of Environmental Management 38:213-218.

Marcondes, M. 1981 Adaptation de una metodologia de evaluacioneconomica, aplicada al Parque Nacional Cahuita, Costa Rica. CentroAgronomico Tropical de Investigacion y Ensenanza (CATIE), SerieTecnica no. 9.

Page 118: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

104

Margulis, L. & Lovelock, J.E. 1974 Biological modulation of the earth'satmosphere. Icarus 21:471-489.

Markandya, A. & Pearce, D.W. 1988 Environmental considerations andthe choice of the discount rate in developing countries. World Bank,Environmental Department Working Paper no. 3.

Martinez-Alier, J. 1987 Ecological economics. Basil Blackwell, Oxford.

Mateo, C.A.Q. (ed.) 1993 Debt-for-nature swaps to promote naturalresource conservation. FAO, Rome

Mauksch, W. 1987 Der Naturschutzwert von einigen normalen agrarischenFlurbereinigungsmaßnahmen. Landschaft+Stadt 19:136-143.

McConnell, K.E. & Strand, I.E. 1981 Measuring the cost of time inrecreation demand analysis. American Journal of AgriculturalEconomics 63:153-156.

McNeely, J.A. 1989 How to pay for conserving biological diversity.Ambio 18:303-313.

McNeely, J.A. 1988 Economics and biological diversity. Developing andusing economic incentives to conserve biological resources. IUCN,Gland.

McNeely, J.A. & Norgaard, R. 1991 Developed country policies andbiological diversity in developing countries. Agriculture, Ecosystemsand Environments 42:194-204.

McNeely, J.A. & Tobias, R.J. 1991 Economic incentives for conservingbiological diversity in Thailand. Ambio 20(2):86-90.

Mendelsohn, R.O., Hof, J., Petersen, G., Reed, J. 1992 Measuringrecreation values with multiple destination trips. American Journal ofAgricultural Economics 74(4):926-933.

Mendelsohn, R.O. & Tobias, R.J. 1991 Valuing ecotourism in a tropicalrainforest reserve. Ambio 20(2):91-93.

Page 119: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

105

Mercer, E., Kramer, R., Sharma, N. 1993 Estimating the nature tourismbenefits of establishing the Mantadia National Park in Madagascar.Centre for Resource and Environmental Policy Research, DukeUniversity, NC.

Miller, J.R. & Menz, F.C. 1979 Some economic considerations in wildlifepreservation. Southern Economic Journal 45:718-729.

Milner-Gulland, E.J. & Leader-Williams, N. 1992 A model of incentivesfor illegal exploitation of rhinos and elephants: Poaching pays inLuangwa Valley, Zambia. Journal of Applied Ecology 29.

Ministry of Natural Resources, Energy and Mines, Costa Rica 1991National study of biodiversity: Costs, benefits and needs forfinancing and conservation of biological diversity in Costa Rica.

Mintzer, I.M. 1993 Implementing the framework convention on climatechange: Incremental costs and the role of the GEF. GEF WorkingPaper no. 4. Washington D.C.

Mishan, E.J. 1981 Introduction to normative economics. OxfordUniversity Press, New York - Oxford.

Mishan, E.J. 1976 Cost-benefit analysis. Praeger, New York.

Mitchel, C. 1989 Economics and the environment: A case of small islandstates. Prepared for the Caribbean Conservation AssociationConference on Economics of the Environment, Barbados.

Mitchell, R.C. & Carson, R.T. 1989 Using surveys to value public goods:The contingent valuation method. Resources for the future,Washington D.C.

Mittermeier, R.A., Bowles, I.A., Cavalcanti, R.B., Olivieri, S., da Fonseca,G.A.B. 1994 A participatory approach to biodiversity conservation:The regional priority setting workshop. Conservation International,Washington D.C.

Page 120: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

106

Montgomery, C., Brown, G.M., Adams, D. 1994 The marginal cost ofspecies preservation: The Northern Spotted Owl. Journal ofEnvironmental Economics and Management. 26(2):111-128.

Moran, D. 1994 Contingent valuation and biodiversity conservation inKenyan protected areas. Biodiversity and Conservation, 3.

Morey, E.R., Shaw, W.D., Rowe, R.D. 1991 A discrete-choice model ofrecreational participation, site choice, and the activity valuation whencomplete trip data are not available. Journal of EnvironmentalEconomics and Management 20:181-201.

Munasinghe, M. 1992 Economic and policy issues in natural habitat andprotected areas. World Bank, Washington D.C.

Munasinghe, M., Cruz, W., Warford, J. 1993 Are economy-wide policiesgood for the environment? Finance and Development 30(3):40-43.

Myers, N. 1993 Questions of mass extinction. Biodiversity andConservation 2:2-17.

Myers, N. 1991 Biological diversity and global security. In: Bormann,F.H. & Kellert, S.R. (eds.): Ecology, economics, ethics: The brokencircle. Yale University Press.

Myers, N. 1991 Tropical forests: present status and future outlook.Climatic Change 19:3-32.

Myers, N. 1991 Tropical forests and climate. Climatic Change 19:1-2.

Myers, N. 1983 A wealth of wild species, storehouse for human welfare.Westview Press, Boulder.

Newcombe, K. & de Lucia, R. 1993 Mobilising private capital againstglobal warming: a business concept and policy issues. GlobalEnvironmental Facility, Washington D.C.

NOAA (National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration) 1994 Oilpollution act of 1990: Proposed regulations for natural resourcedamage assessments, US Department of Commerce.

Page 121: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

107

Nordhaus, W. 1991 To slow or not to slow: The economics of thegreenhouse effect. American Economic Review 81(2):920-937.

Nordhaus, W. 1991 A sketch of economics of the greenhouse effect.American Economic Review 81(2):146-150.

Norgaard, R.B. 1987 The economics of biological diversity: Apologeticsor theory? In: Southgate, D.D. & Disinger, J.F. (eds.): Sustainableresource development in the Third World. Westview Press, Boulder -London.

Norse, E.A. (ed.) 1993 Global marine biological diversity: A strategy forbuilding conservation into decision making. Island Press,Washington D.C.

Norton, B.G. 1986 On the inherent danger of undervaluing species. In:Norton, B.G. (ed.): The preservation of species. University Press,Princeton.

Norton, B.G. 1984 Environmental ethics and weak anthropocentrism.Environmental Ethics 6:131-148.

Norton, B.G. 1982 Environmental ethics and nonhuman rights.Environmental Ethics 4:17-36.

Norton, B.G. & Ulanowocz, R.E. 1992 Scale and biodiversity policy: Ahierarchical approach. Ambio 21(3):244-249.

Noss, R.F., Cline, S., Csuti, B., Scott, M. 1992 Monitoring and assessingbiodiversity. In: Lykke, E. (ed.): Achieving environmental goals: Theconcept and practice of environmental performance review.Belhaven Press, London.

Nutzinger, H.G. & Zahrnt, A. (eds.) 1989 Ökosteuern. Umweltsteuern und-abgaben in der Diskussion. C.F. Müller, Karlsruhe.

Oberndörfer, D. 1989 Schutz der tropischen Regenwälder durchEntschuldung. Schriftenreihe des Bundeskanzleramts, Vol. 5, Beck,Munich.

Page 122: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

108

O'Connor, S. & Langrand, O. 1992 Can wildlife pay its way inMadagascar? World Wildlife Fund for Nature, Madagascar.

OECD 1991 Environmental policy: How to apply economic instruments.OECD, Paris.

OECD 1991 Responding to climate change: Selected economic issues.OECD, Paris.

OECD 1989 Environmental policy benefits: Monentary evaluation.Prepared by Pearce, D.W. & Markandya, A. OECD, Paris.

O'Hara, S. 1984 Externe Effekte der Stickstoffdüngung. Probleme ihrerBewertung und Ansätze zu ihrer Verminderung aus ökonomischerSicht. Vauk, Kiel.

Padoch, C. & de Jong, W. 1989 Production and profit in agroforestry: anexample from the Peruvian Amazon. In: Browder, J.G. (ed.): Fragilelands of Latin America: Strategies for sustainable development.Westview Press, Boulder.

Pearce, D.W. 1994 Capturing global environmental values. Centre forSocial and Economic Research on the Global Environment.University College London and University of East Anglia, Norwichand London.

Pearce, D.W. 1992 Discounting. In: Pearce, D.W., Whittington, J.,Georgiou, S. (eds.): Manual of environmental projects and policyappraisal. OECD, Paris.

Pearce, D.W. 1992 Assessing the social rate of return in temperate zoneforestry. Centre for Social and Economic Research on the GlobalEnvironment, University College London and University of EastAnglia, Norwich and London.

Pearce, D.W. 1991 Economic valuation and the natural world. Earthscan,London.

Pearce, D.W. (ed.) 1991 Blueprint 2: Greening the world economy.Earthscan, London.

Page 123: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

109

Pearce, D.W. 1991 Economic valuation and the natural world. Centre forSocial and Economic Research on the Global Environment,University College London and University of East Anglia, Norwich.

Pearce, D.W. 1991 Deforesting the Amazon: Toward an economicsolution. Ecodecision 1:40-49.

Pearce, D.W. 1987 Foundations of an ecological economics. EcologicalModelling 38:9-18.

Pearce, D.W. 1986 Cost-benefit analysis. Macmillan, Basingstoke.

Pearce, D.W. et al. 1993 Mexico forestry and conservation sector review:substudy of economic valuation of forests. Report to Latin AmericanTechnical Department, World Bank, Washington D.C.

Pearce, D.W., Bann, C., Georgiou, S. 1992 The social costs of fuel cycles.Centre for Social and Economic Research on the GlobalEnvironment, University College London.

Pearce, D.W. & Barbier, E.B. 1987 Forest policy in Indonesia. WorldBank, Washington D.C.

Pearce, D.W., Barbier, E.B., Markandya, A. 1990 Sustainabledevelopment. Oxford University Press, Oxford - New York.

Pearce, D.W., Markandya, A., Barbier, E.B. 1989 Blueprint for a greeneconomy. Earthscan, London.

Pearce, D.W. & Nash, C.A. 1981 The social appraisal of projects.Macmillan, London - Basingstoke.

Pearce, D.W. & Turner, R.K. 1990 Economics of natural resources and theenvironment. Harvester Wheatsheaf, New York

Pearce, D.W. & Warford, J. 1992 World without end: Economics,environment and sustainable development. Oxford University Press,Oxford - New York.

Pearsall, S.H. III 1984 In absentia benefits of nature preserves: A review.Environmental Conservation 11:3-10.

Page 124: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

110

Perrings, C. 1995 The economic value of biodiversity. In: Heywood, V.,Watson, R. (eds.): Global biodiversity assessment, 823-914.Cambridge University Press.

Perrings, C. & Pearce, D.W. 1994 Threshold effects and incentives for theconservation of biodiversity. Environmental and ResourceEconomics 4:13-28.

Peterson, G.L. & Randall, A. (eds.) 1984 Valuation of wildland resourcebenefits. Westview Press, Boulder - London.

Phillips, W.E., Adamowicz, W.L., Asafu-Adjaye, J., Boxall, P.C. 1989 Aneconomic assessment of the wildlife resource in Alberta. ProjectReport no. 89-04, Alberta Recreation, Parks and WildlifeFoundation.

Pinedo-Vasquez, M., Zarin, D., Jipp, P. 1992 Economic returns from forestconversion in the Reuvian Amazon. Ecological Economics 6:163-173.

Pister, W.P. 1979 Endangered species: Costs and benefits. EnvironmentalEthics 1:341-352.

Porter, R.C. 1982 The new approach to wilderness preservation throughbenefit-cost analysis. Journal of Environmental Economics andManagement 9:59-80.

Posner, B. et al. 1981 Economic impact analysis for the Virgin IslandResources Foundation. St. Thomas, US Virgin Islands.

Principe, P. 1991 Monetizing the pharmacological benefits of plants. USEnvironmental Protection Agency, Washington D.C.

Randall, A. 1988: What mainstream economists have to say about the valueof biodiversity. In: Wilson, E.O. (ed.): Biodiversity. NationalAcademy Press, Washington D.C.

Randall, A. 1987 Resource economics. John Wiley, New York

Page 125: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

111

Randall, A. 1986 Human preferences, economics and the preservation ofspecies. In: Norton, B.G. (ed.): The preservation of species.Princeton University Press.

Randall, A. & Stoll, J. 1983 Existence values in a total valuationframework. In: Row, R.D. & Chestnut, L.G. (eds.): Managing airquality and scenic resources at national parks and wilderness areas.Westview Press, Boulder.

Raven, P. 1988 Our diminishing tropical forests. In: Wilson, E.O. (ed.):Biodiversity. National Academy Press, Washington D.C.

Reed, D. 1991 The global environmental facility. Sharing responses for thebiosphere. Multilateral Development Bank Program, WWFInternational, Washington D.C.

Rees, C. 1993 The ecologist's approach to sustainable development.Finance and Development 30(4):14-15.

Reid, W.V. (ed.) 1993 Biodiversity prospecting: Using genetic resourcesfor sustainable development. World Resources Institute, WashingtonD.C.

Reid, W.V. et al. 1992 Developing indicators of biodiversity conservation.World Resources Institute, Draft report, Washington D.C.

Repetto, R. 1990 Die Entwaldung der Tropen: ein ökonomischerFehlschlag. Spektrum der Wissenschaft 6:122-129.

Repetto, R. 1988 The forest for the trees? Government policies and themisuse of forest resources. World Resource Institute, WashingtonD.C.

Repetto, R. 1986 World enough and time. Yale University Press, NewHaven.

Repetto, R. & Gillis, M. (eds.) 1988 Public policies and the misuse offorest resources. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

Page 126: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

112

Rich, B. 1994 Mortgaging the earth: The World Bank, environmentalimpoverishment, and the crisis of development. Beacon Press,Boston.

Rijsberman, F. 1991 Potential costs of adapting to sea level rise in OECDcountries. In: OECD (ed.): Environmental policy: How to applyeconomic instruments. OECD, Paris.

Rosenthal, D. & Nelson, R. 1992 Why existence value should not be usedin cost-benefit analysis. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management11(1):116-122.

Ruitenbeek, H.J. 1991 Mangrove management: An economic analysis ofmanagement options with a focus on Bintuni Bay, Irian Jaya.Ministry of State for Population and Environment, Jakarta.

Ruitenbeek, H.J. 1990 Economic analysis of tropical forest conservationinitiatives: Examples from West Africa, WWF.

Ruitenbeek, H.J. 1990 Evaluating economic policies for promotingrainforest conservation in developing countries. Ph.D. thesis, LondonSchool of Economics and Political Science.

Ruitenbeek, H.J. 1990 The rainforest supply price: A step towardsestimating a cost curve for rainforest conservation. The DevelopmentEconomics Research Programme, London School of Economics.

Samples, K., Dixon, J., Gowen, M. 1986 Information disclosure andendangered species valuation. Land Economics 62:306-312.

Samples, K., Gowen, M., Dixon, J. 1986 The validity of the contingentvaluation method for estimating non-use components of preservationvalues for unique natural resources. Paper presented to the AmericanAgricultural Economics Association, Reno.

Schäfer, A. 1988 Kosten-Nutzen-Analyse. Ex-post-Anwendung amBeispiel der Rebflurbereinigung im Kaiserstuhl. Dissertation, Kassel.

Page 127: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

113

Scheele, M. & Isermeyer, F. 1989 Umweltschutz und Landschaftspflegeim Bereich der Landwirtschaft - Kostenwirksame Verpflichtung oderneue Einkommensquelle? Berichte über Landwirtschaft 67:86-110.

Schily, O. 1994 Flora, Fauna und Finanzen. Hoffmann und Campe,Hamburg.

Schkade, D. & Payne, J.W. 1994 How people respond to contingentvaluation questions: A verbal protocol analysis of willingness to payfor an environmental regulation. Journal of EnvironmentalEconomics and Management 26:88-109.

Schmalensee, R. 1972 Option demand and consumer's surplus: Valuingprice changes under uncertainty. American Economic Review62:813-824.

Schmitt, G. 1989 Die volkswirtschaftlichen Kosten der Agrarpolitik.WISU 6:358-362.

Schneider, R. 1992 Brazil: An analysis of environmental problems andpolicies in the Amazon. Report no. 91-04-BR, Latin America andCaribbean Region, World Bank, Washington D.C.

Schramm, G. & Warford, J. (eds.) 1989 Environmental management andeconomic development. A World Bank Publication, WashingtonD.C.

Schreiber, H. 1989 "Debt-for-nature-swap" - An instrument against debtand environmental destruction? Zeitschrift für Umweltpolitik undUmweltrecht 12:331-352.

Schüller, A. (ed.) 1983 Property rights und ökonomische Theorie. Vahlen,Munich.

Schulz, W. 1985 Der monetäre Wert besserer Luft. Lang, Frankfurt a.M.u.a.

Schulze, E.-D. & Mooney, H.A. (eds.) 1993 Biodiversity and ecosystemfunction. Springer Verlag, Berlin

Page 128: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

114

Schulze, W.D. et al. 1983 Economic benefits of preserving visibility on thenational parklands of the Southwest. Natural Resources Journal 23.

Schulze, W.D., D'Arge, R.C., Brookshire, D.S. 1981 Valuingenvironmental commodities: Some recent experiments. LandEconomics 57(2).

Schweppe-Kraft, B., Habeck, K., Schmitz, T. 1989 ÖkonomischeBewertung von Eingriffen in Natur und Landschaft. Am BeispielIndustriegebiet Schichauweg. Landschaftsentwicklung undUmweltforschung 60, Technische Universität Berlin.

Sedjo, R. 1987 The economics of natural and plantation forests inIndonesia. Resources for the Future, Washington D.C.

Setzer, A.W. & Pereira, M.C. 1991 Amazonia biomass burnings in 1987and an estimate of their tropospheric emissions. Ambio 20:19-22.

Shamsundar, P. & Kramer, R. 1993 Does contingent valuation work innon-market economies? Centre for Resource and EnvironmentalPolicy Research, Duke University, Durham, NC.

Sharma, N. 1992 Managing the world's forests. Kendall and Hunt,Dubuque, Iowa

Simberloff, D. 1987 The Spotted Owl fracas: Mixing academic, applied,and political ecology. Ecology 68:766-772.

Simberloff, D. 1986 Are we on the verge of a mass extinction in tropicalrain forests? In: Elliott, D.K. (ed.): Dynamics of extinction. JohnWiley, New York

Simonis, U.E. (ed.) 1988 Ökonomie und Ökologie. Auswege aus einemKonflikt. Alternative Konzepte 33. C.F. Müller, Karlsruhe.

Sittenfield, A. & Gámez, R. 1993 Biodiversity-prospecting in InBio. Reid,W.V. (ed.): Biodiversity prospecting: Using genetic resources forsustainable development. World Resources Institute, WashingtonD.C.

Page 129: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

115

Smith, N.J.H. & Schuktes, R.E. 1990 Deforestation and shrinking cropgene-pools in Amazonia. Environment and Conservation 17:227-234.

Smith, V.K. 1987 Non-use values in benefit-cost analysis. SouthernEconomic Journal 54:19-26.

Smith, V.K. 1983 Option value: A conceptual overview. SouthernEconomic Journal 49:654-668.

Smith, V.K. & Desvousges, W.H. 1986 Measuring water quality benefits.Kluwer-Nijhoff Publishing, Boston 54:19-26.

Smith, V.K. & Kaoru, Y. 1990 Signals or noise? Explaining the variationin recreation benefit estimates. American Journal of AgriculturalEconomics 72:419-433.

Soulé, M.E. (ed.) 1986 Conservation biology. The science of scarcity anddiversity. Sinauer, Sunderland, MA.

Southgate, D.D. & Disinger, J.F. (eds.) 1987 Sustainable resourcedevelopment in the Third World. Westview Press, Boulder - London.

Steer, A. & Lutz, E. 1993 Measuring environmentally sustainabledevelopment. Finance and Development 30(4):20-23.

Steinlin, H. 1987 Kommerzielle Nutzung und Export von Holz austropischen Feuchtwäldern. Allgemeine Forst- und Jagd-Zeitung158:50-55.

Stevens, T.H., Echeverria, J., Glass, R.J., Hager, T., More, T.A. 1991Measuring existence value of wildlife: What do CVM estimatesreally show? Land Economics 67(4):390-400.

Ströbele, W. 1987 Rohstoffökonomik. Vahlen, Munich.

Swanson, T. 1991 The economics of natural habitat utilization: a survey ofthe literature and issues. London Environmental Economics Centre.

Swanson, T.M. 1994 Biodiversity and intellectual property rights. In:Perrings, C., Mäler, K.-G., Folke, C., Holling, C.S., Jansson, B.-O.

Page 130: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

116

(eds.) Biodiversity loss: Ecological and economic issues. CambridgeUniversity Press, Cambridge.

Swanson, T. & Barbier, E. 1992 Economics for the wilds: Wildlife,wildlands, diversity and development. Earthscan, London.

Tampe, K. & Hampicke, U. 1989 Die voraussichtliche Belastung deröffentlichen Haushalte durch Ausgleichszahlungen an die Land- undForstwirtschaft aufgrund der geplanten Novellierung des §3bBNatSchG. Gutachten im Auftrag des Bundesministers für Umwelt,Naturschutz und Reaktorsicherheit. Kassel.

Thibodeau, F.R. & Ostro, B.D. 1981 An economic analysis of wetlandprotection. Journal of Environmental Management 12:19-30.

Thomas, D.H.L., Ayache, F., Hollis, T. 1990 Use values and non-usevalues in the conservation of Ichkeul National Park, Tunisia.Environmental Conservation 18(2):119-130.

Tisdell, C.A. 1992 Environmental economic guidelines - Inter-country andinter-regional requests for financial support for protected areas: Whatfactors, especially economic factors, might be important in rankingthese. University of Queensland, Brisbane.

Tisdell, C.A. 1990 Economics and the debate about preservation ofspecies, crop varieties and genetic diversity. Ecological Economics2:77-90.

Tisdell, C.A. 1989 Environmental conservation: Economics, ecology andethics. Environmental Conservation 16:107-112.

Tisdell, C.A. 1983 An economist's critique of the world conservationstrategy with examples from the Australian experience.Environmental Conservation 10:43-53.

Tisdell, C.A. 1982 Wild pigs: Environmental pest or economic resource?Pergamon Press, Sydney.

Turner, R.K. (ed.) 1991 Economics and wetland management. Ambio20:59-63.

Page 131: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

117

Turner, R.K. 1988 Wetland conservation: Economics and ethics. In:Collard, D., Pearce, D.W., Ulph, D. (eds.): Economics, growth andsustainable environments. Essays in memory of Richard Lecomber.Macmillan, Basingstoke - London, 121-159.

Turner, R.K. 1988 Sustainable environmental management. BelhavenPress & Westview Press, London - Boulder.

Turner, R.K. & Brooke, J. 1988 Management and valuation of anenvironmentally sensitive area: Norfolk broadland case study.Environmental Management 12(3).

Turner, R.K. & Jones, T. (eds.) 1991 Wetlands: Market and interventionfailures. Four case studies. Earthscan, London.

Turner, R.K. & Mendelsohn, R. 1991 Valuing ecotourism in a tropicalrainforest reserve. Ambio 20(2):91-93.

Umana, Q.A. 1989 Debt relief for energy efficiency, conservation andsustainability. Republic of Costa Rica, Washington D.C.

Umana, Q.A. 1987 Costa Rica swap debt for trees. Wall Street Journal 3.

UNEP 1992 Biodiversity country studies, synthesis report. UNEP, Nairobi.

UNEP 1992 Uganda: Country study on costs, benefits, and unmet needs ofbiological diversity conservation. UNEP, Nairobi.

UNEP 1992 Bahamas: Country study on biodiversity; census, analysis,conservation costs, benefits and unmet needs. UNEP, Nairobi.

UNEP 1992 Indonesian country study on biological diversity. UNEP,Nairobi.

UNEP 1992 Country study report for Nigerian costs, benefits and unmetneeds of biological diversity conservation. UNEP, Nairobi.

van Dieren, W. (ed.) 1995 Taking nature into account. Springer Verlag,New York.

Page 132: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

118

Vincent, J. 1990 Rent capture and the feasibility of tropical forestmanagement. Land Economics 66(2):212-223.

Vogel, H. 1988 Naturschutzprogramme mit der Landwirtschaft in derBundesrepublik Deutschland - Übersicht. In: ABN (ed.): JahrbuchNaturschutz Landschaftspflege 41:183-195.

Walsh, R.G., Johnson, D.M., McKean, J.R. 1992 Benefit transfer ofoutdoor recreation demand studies 1968-1988. Water ResourcesResearch 28(3):

Walsh, R.G., Loomis, J.B., Gillman, R.A. 1984 Valuing option, existence,and bequest demands for wilderness. Land Economics 60:14-29.

Walsh, R.G. & Rosenthal, R.D. 1990 Estimating the public benefits ofprotecting forest quality. Journal of Environmental Management30:175-189.

Ward, N.I. & Brooks, R.R. 1978 Gold in some New Zealand plants. NewZealand Journal of Botany 16:175-177.

Warren, D.M. 1991 Using indigeneous knowledge in agriculturaldevelopment. World Bank Discussion Paper no. 127.

Watson, D. 1988 The evolution of appropriate resource managementsystems. In: Berkes, F. (ed.): Common property resources: Ecologyand community based sustainable development. Belhaven, London.

Webb, A., Lopez, M., Penn, R. 1990 Estimates of producer and consumersubsidy equivalents: Government intervention in agriculture 1982-1987. US Department of Agriculture Statistical Bulletin 803,Washington D.C.

Weinberger, M., Thomassen, G., Willeke, R. 1991 Kosten des Lärms inder Bundesrepublik Deutschland. Erich Schmidt Verlag, Berlin.

Weinschenck, G. 1986 Der ökonomische oder der ökologischecWeg?Agrarwirtschaft 35:321-327.

Page 133: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

119

Weinscheck, G. & Werner, R. 1989 Einkommenswirkingen ökologischerForderungen an die Landwirtschaft. LandwirtschaftlicheRentenbank, Frankfurt am Main.

Wells, M. 1992 A summary of the benefits, costs and risks of usingenvironmental trust funds for biodiversity conservation.Environmental Policy and Research Division, World Bank.

Wells, M. 1992 Biodiversity conservation, affluence and poverty:Mismatched costs and benefits and efforts to remedy them. Ambio21(3):237-243.

Wells, M. & Brandon, K. 1992 People and parks: Linking protected areamanagement with local communities. The World Bank, World WideFund for Nature, US Agency for International Development.

Wendelaar, A., Pearce, D.W., Moran, D. 1994 Determining biodiversityconservation priorities. Centre for Social and Economic Research onthe Global Environment, University College London and Universityof East Anglia, Norwich.

Westman, W.E. 1977 How much are nature's services worth? Science197:960-964.

Whittington, D. et al. 1991 Willingness to pay for improved sanitation inKumasi, Ghana: A contingent valuation study. In: ValuingEnvironmental Benefits in Developing Economies. Michigan StateUniversity, Special Report no. 29.

Wicke, L. 1991 Umweltökonomie. Eine praxisorientierte Einführung.Vahlen, Munich.

Wicke, L. 1991 Umweltökonomie und Umweltpolitik. Beck/dtv, Munich.

Wilks, L.C. 1990 A survey of the contingent valuation method. ResourceAssessment Commission, RAC Research Paper no. 2. AustralianGovernment Publishing Service, Canberra.

Willis, K.G. & Corkindale, J.T. (eds.) 1995 Environmental valuation. CABInternational, Wallingford.

Page 134: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

The Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity

120

Willis, K.G. 1993 The national oceanic and atmospheric administrationreport on contingent valuation methods: some comments.Department of Town and Country Planning, University of Newcastleupon Tyne.

Willis, K.G. & Benson, J.F. 1988 Valuation of wildlife: A case study onthe Upper Teesdale site of special scientific interest and comparisonof methods in environmental economics. In: Turner, R.K. (ed.):Sustainable environmental management. Belhaven Press &Westview Press, London - Boulder.

Willis, K.G. & Garrod, G. 1991 Landscape values: A contingent valuationapproach and case study of the Yorkshire Dales National Park.Countryside Change Working Paper 21, University of Newcastleupon Tyne.

World Bank 1994 Making development sustainable: The World BankGroup and the environment. Washington D.C.

World Bank 1994 Financing innovation and instruments. Contribution ofthe investment portfolio of the pilot phase of the Global EnvironmentFacility. Paper presented to the Regional Conference on BiodiversityConservation. Asian Development Bank, 6-8 June 1994. WashingtonD.C.

World Bank 1994 Implementing the convention on biological diversity.Toward a strategy for World Bank assistance. EnvironmentDepartment. Washington D.C.

World Bank 1994 Incorporating social assessment and participation intobiodiversity conservation projects. Global Environment CoordinationDivision and Environment Department, Washington D.C.

World Bank 1993 The environmental data book: A guide to statistics onthe environment and development. Washington D.C.

World Bank 1992 Strategy for forest sector development in Asia. WorldBank Technical Paper 182. Washington D.C.

Page 135: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Bibliography

121

World Bank 1992 The World Bank and the environment: Fiscal 1992.Washington D.C.

World Bank 1992 World Development Report 1992. Development and theenvironment. Oxford University Press, New York.

World Bank 1991 A World Bank operations evaluation study: Forestry:The World Bank's experience. Washington D.C.

World Bank 1991 The forest sector. A World Bank policy paper.Washington D.C.

World Bank 1989 World debt tables, external debt of developing countries1982-1987. Washington D.C.

World Resources Institute 1992 World Resources 1992-1993. OxfordUniversity Press, Oxford.

World Resources Institute, The World Bank, United Nations DevelopmentProgramme 1985 Tropical forests: A call for action. Washington,D.C.

World Wide Fund for Nature 1988 Debt for nature, an opportunity.Philippines.

Young, A.M. 1986 Eco-enterprises: Eco-tourism and farming of exotics inthe tropics. Ambio 15:361-363.

Zilinskas, R.A. & Lundin, C. 1993 Marine biotechnology and developingcountries. World Bank discussion paper 210. Washington D.C.

Page 136: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Deutsche Gesellschaft fürTechnische Zusammenarbeit (GTZ) GmbH

Tropenökologisches Begleitprogramm (TÖB)Tropical Ecology Support ProgramPostfach 5180D-65726 EschbornFederal Republic of Germany

Fax: +49-(0)6196-79-6190E-Mail: [email protected] Wide Web: http://www.gtz.de/toeb

Page 137: The Economic Valuation of Biological DiversityThe Economic Valuation of Biological Diversity X reflected by market prices, it remains a theoretical concept. Because of the benefits

Im Auftrag des Bundesministeriums für wirtschaftlicheZusammenarbeit und Entwicklung (BMZ)


Recommended