+ All Categories
Home > Documents > The Future of Bretton Woods II

The Future of Bretton Woods II

Date post: 12-Feb-2016
Category:
Upload: lynch
View: 42 times
Download: 1 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
The Future of Bretton Woods II. Juha Seppälä Department of Economics University of Illinois. Starting Point. Paul Krugman summarizes the current state of the U.S. economy as follows: “Americans make a living selling each other houses, paid for with money borrowed from the Chinese.” - PowerPoint PPT Presentation
Popular Tags:
39
1 The Future of Bretton Woods II Juha Seppälä Department of Economics University of Illinois
Transcript
Page 1: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

1

The Future of Bretton Woods II

Juha SeppäläDepartment of EconomicsUniversity of Illinois

Page 2: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

2

Starting Point

Paul Krugman summarizes the current state of the U.S. economy as follows:

“Americans make a living selling each other houses, paid for with money borrowed from the Chinese.”

(New York Times, 8/12/2005)

Page 3: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

3

Outline of the Talk

1. Bretton Woods I2. Bretton Woods II3. Problems with Bretton Woods II (U.S. and

China)4. Other Players 5. New Chinese Exchange Rate Mechanism6. Conclusions

Page 4: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

4

1. Bretton Woods I

The original Bretton Woods system was the system of fixed exchange rates that existed from the end of World War II (1946), until its collapse in 1971.

• John Maynard Keynes was a principle architect of the Bretton Woods System.

• Global financial system would have fixed exchange rates in order to prevent the beggar-thy-neighbor policies of currency devaluations that characterized the 1930’s.

• The dollar could be converted to any other major currency or gold at a fixed exchange rate.

Page 5: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

5

1. Bretton Woods I

The Bretton Woods System was already criticized in 1953 by Milton Friedman:

• His argument was that in the face of external or internal shocks, for most economies, the most important channel of adjustment is the real exchange rate. This can adjust in two different ways: either nominal exchange rate depreciates (appreciates) or the price level decreases (increases). The first way is much less costly. Therefore, it would be best to let the nominal exchange rate be flexible.

Page 6: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

6

1. Bretton Woods I

In 1960, the economist Robert Triffin, testifying before the U.S. Congress, exposed a fundamental problem in the international monetary system:• Continuous U.S. balance of payments deficits during the 1950s

had provided the world with liquidity, but had also caused dollar reserves to build up in the central banks of Europe and Japan. The U.S. gold reserves were going dangerously low.

• If the United States stopped running balance of payments deficits, the resulting shortage of liquidity could pull the world economy into a contractionary spiral, leading to instability.

• Excessive U.S. deficits would erode confidence in the value of the U.S. dollar. Hence, it would no longer be accepted as the world's reserve currency. The fixed exchange rate system would break down.

Page 7: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

7

1. Bretton Woods I

By the early 1970s, as the Vietnam War accelerated inflation, the United States was running not just a balance of payments deficit but also a trade deficit. The crucial turning point was 1970, which saw U.S. gold coverage deteriorate from 55% to 22%.

In the first six months of 1971, assets for $22 billion fled the United States. In response, on August 15, 1971, President Nixon unilaterally “closed the gold window.”

Page 8: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

8

2. Bretton Woods II

“Bretton Woods II” is a term coined by three Deutsche Bank economists — Michael Dooley, Peter Garber, and David Folkers-Landau — in a series of papers in 2003–2004 to describe the current international monetary system:

In this system, the United States and the Asian economies have entered into an implicit contract where the U.S. runs current account deficits and the Asian countries keep their currencies fixed and undervalued by buying U.S. government debt.

Page 9: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

9

2. Bretton Woods II

According to Dooley, Folkert-Landau, and Garber (DFG), this system has benefits to both parties:

• The U.S. obtains a stable and low-cost source of funding for its current account and budget deficits, and can easily reduce taxes, fight two wars, and increase government spending at the same time.

• For the Asian countries, the undervalued currency creates export-led development strategy that produces economic and employment growth to keep the lid on potentially explosive pressures rising large pools of surplus labor.

Page 10: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

10

2. Bretton Woods II

At the time when DFG were writing, many countries in Asia exporting to the United States had fixed exchange rates with the United States, such as China (8.28 renminbi per dollar), or had quasi-fixed rates, such as Japan (Japan will intervene to keep the Yen above 100 per dollar).

DFG predicted that the Bretton Woods II system can last for a generation, or at least for eight years.

Remember that Bretton Woods II system lasted for 11 years after Robert Triffin presented his dilemma.

Page 11: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

11

3. Problems with Bretton Woods II: Definitions

A national trade balance (surplus/deficit) is the net value of exports of tradable goods and services minus imports.

A national current account balance is the net value of exports of goods, services, assets, and transfers – minus the imports of goods, services, assets, and transfers

Page 12: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

12

3. Problems with BW2: U.S. CAD

Volume of U.S. recent current account deficits (CAD):

• In 2003, U.S. CAD was $530 billion.

• In 2003, foreign central banks added $440 billion of dollar reserves, thus 90 percent of total U.S. CAD.

• In 2004, U.S. CAD was $660 billion.

Page 13: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

13

3. Problems with BW2: U.S. Saving Shortfall

Page 14: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

14

3. Problems with BW2: People’ Bank of China

U.S. absorbs 80 percent of world’s savings not invested at their home country.

The large CAD sends billions of dollars abroad, particularly to China.

People’s Bank of China uses the inflow of dollars to purchase assets, mostly U.S. Treasuries.

Much of the $400 billion fiscal deficit is financed by China.

If China stops purchasing U.S. assets and switches to Japan, Europe, or other markets, it will cause a fall in the dollar and long-term interest rates will increase.

Page 15: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

15

3. Problems with BW2: Nightmare Scenario

If dollar depreciates against Renminbi by 33%, this could lead to capital losses for People’s Bank of China of nearly 10 percent of China’s GDP.

In addition, higher interest rates in the U.S. would lead to the end of U.S. housing bubble, U.S. recession, fall in U.S. imports, and finally a global recession.

Page 16: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

16

3. Problems with BW2: Interest Rates

How much does the interest subsidy from the foreign central banks lower U.S. interest rates?

• Goldman Sachs: CB’s narrow yields by only 40 bps.• Federal Reserve: 50 – 100 bps.• PIMCO: 100 bps.• Morgan-Stanley, Stephen Roach: 100-150 bps.• Roubini and Setser: 200 bps.

Page 17: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

17

3. Problems with BW2: Interest Rates

Roubini and Setser get a larger number because they try to take into account also general equilibrium effects:

• If Asian central banks purchase fewer Treasuries, this would affect the dollar, U.S. growth and inflation numbers, which all impact Treasury yields.

• In addition, private investors believe that central bank purchases will inhibit currency rate movements. Hence they are more willing to invest in the U.S.

Page 18: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

18

3. Problems with BW2: U.S. Financing Needs

U.S. external debt to GDP only 30 percent, though could rise to 50 percent by 2008.

Most experts believe that deficits will continue “as far as eye can see.”

Page 19: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

19

3. Problems with BW2: Reducing CAD

Reducing the CAD would require either or all of:

• Stronger growth in world demand.• Slower growth in overall U.S. demand.• Change in the real exchange rate.

Roubini and Setser believe that a 20 percent fall in dollar is needed to impact CAD.

Page 20: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

20

3. Problems with BW2: Imports vs. Exports

Continuation of BW2 means imports rising faster than economy.

This implies resources are leaving import competing sectors toward sectors supported by low interest rates.

Imports from China are increasing 25% year on year. By 2008, Chinese imports could be double the value

of oil imports. Exports to U.S. account for 12 percent of China’s

GDP.

Page 21: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

21

3. Problems with BW2: Housing Sector

Job growth in interest sensitive sectors actually exceeds losses in competing sectors.

Interest rate subsidy from Asia discourages saving.

Promotes overinvestment in housing and under-investment in tradable goods.

Page 22: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

22

3. Problems with BW2: Some Numbers

In 2004, U.S. CAD was $660 billion.

Asia’s CA surplus was $313 billion.

Asia’s central bank reserves increased $535 billion.

From 2003 to 2005, China’s gross CB reserves will go from 32 to 48 percent of GDP.

Page 23: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

23

Problems with BW2: Case of China

Impact of reserve growth on China:

• Expanding reserves increases the money supply, fueling excess credit and bad lending.

• Klitgaard finds that only half the increases in reserves from 2000 to 2003 were sterilized.

• In 2004, reserve increases were $200 billion dollars, 13 percent of GDP. According to Roubini and Setser (2005), China sold only $70 billion in bonds, so only 35 percent sterilized.

Page 24: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

24

3. Problems with BW2: Central Banks Of the world’s $3.8 trillion in reserves, $2.5

trillion is held in dollars. Asia’s central banks have $2.4 trillion in

assets, with $1.8 trillion in dollars. If a 33 percent average appreciation of Asian

currencies is needed to reduce the U.S. CAD, the loss to Asia’s stock of $1.8 trillion in dollar reserves will be $600 billion.

If the dollar falls 33 percent against the renminbi, losses will be $150 billion for China, or 10 percent of their GDP.

Page 25: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

25

3. Problems with BW2: China’s Potential Losses

End 2004 End 2006 End 2008

33% app 9.5% 14.7% 17.7%

50% app 14.3% 22.0% 26.6%

Page 26: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

26

3. Problems with BW2: Weak Structure

There are no institutional constraints on the anchor currency (dollar): U.S. can run deficits and doesn’t need gold.

In addition to maintaining dollar levels of reserves, Asian CB’s must continue to add more dollars to their reserves to absorb the additional deficits in the United States.

Roubini and Setser in their paper “Will the Bretton Woods 2 Regime Unravel Soon? The Risk of a Hard Landing in 2005-2006” (February 2005) predict that BW2 will unravel in the next couple of years.

Page 27: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

27

4. Other Players: Short Maturity of Debt

Average maturity of U.S. debt fell from 90 months in 1999 to 33.4 months in Dec. 2004.

This is due to current interest rates being low. Because of short maturities, must roll over debt. If CB’s accumulate U.S. debt slower, U.S.

Treasuries will need a lot more other buyers. Irony: To protect dollar assets, CB’s must

purchase more of those assets. Similar to stock bubble.

Page 28: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

28

4. Other Players: Non-Japan Asia

In 2003, only 12 percent of new CB accumulations went to Euros and non-dollars. In 2004, estimates are 25 percent.

Korea, Taiwan, and Hong Kong hold $500 billion.

Singapore, Malaysia, Thailand, and India hold $350 billion in reserves.

If these banks adjust to euros, this would move the market.

Page 29: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

29

4. Other Players: Japan

In 2003, about $200 billion of $485 billion the U.S. received in CB reserve financing came from Japan.

In 2004, this dropped to $170 billion. Many experts believe Japan’s Ministry of Finance

will intervene to keep yen weak against dollar. However, Japan alone cannot provide all the

financing the U.S. needs, and Japan will provide less in 2005 and 2006.

Page 30: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

30

4. Other Players: Europe

If the European Central Bank (ECB) sold euros, that would provide one of the easiest ways to prop up the BW2 and prevent Asian CB’s from taking a large hit.

However, ECB has shown little inclination in the past to cut interest rates, let alone foreign exchange market intervention.

ECB cannot intervene as readily as China or Japan.

Page 31: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

31

4. Other Players: Foreign Investors

Private investors continue to buy U.S. assets.

If they believe their home CB’s will continue to also purchase Treasuries, foreign investors will also.

However, if investors anticipate their any CB hesitance, there will be a stampede out of U.S. assets.

Page 32: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

32

4. Other Players: U.S. Investors

If U.S. investors leave U.S. assets, that could unravel the system.

Since the end of 2002, U.S. residents have bought more foreign securities than Treasuries.

Total U.S. outflows could reach $180 billion in 2005.

Page 33: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

33

5. New Chinese Exchange Rate Mechanism

On July 21, 2005 China moved to a new exchange rate regime. Instead of pegging the dollar, China now pegs a basket of currencies with a band of 0.3%. It is still not known which currencies (or what weights) make up the basket.

For example, for the U.S. dollar the new median value is 8.11 renminbi to the U.S. dollar (previously 8.28 — 2% appreciation).

Page 34: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

34

5. New Chinese ERM: The End of BW2?

In the Wall Street Journal (8/15/2005), John Taylor (Professor of Economics at Stanford University and a former U.S. Under Secretary of Treasury for International Affairs) called this the end of Bretton Woods II and wrote:

• “The new policy shift in China from a pegged to a flexible exchange rate regime starts a new chapter in international finance, comparable to the dramatic end of the Bretton Woods system of pegged exchange rates in 1971.”

Page 35: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

35

5. New Chinese ERM: Maybe Not

According to Stephen Jen (Morgan Stanley), the estimated weight of the U.S. dollar is 85% or more of the basket.

During the first month of the new basket regime, USD/CNY has declined by cumulative 0.15% — half the daily allowable range.

For all practical purposes, Bretton Woods II is alive and well.

Page 36: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

36

5. New Chinese ERM: Japanese Example

There are strong parallels between Japanese currency policy after World War II and Chinese currency policy today:

• After two decades of pegging at 360 yen, Japan decoupled from the dollar on August 1971 and then repegged at a revalued rate of 308 yen.

• After stabilizing the exchange rate at this new level for about a year, greater flexibility was introduced.

• This phased adjustment resembles recent Chinese policy initiatives.

Page 37: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

37

5. New Chinese ERM: The Future?

If China intends to allow a series of small appreciations in the renminbi then it either has to1. Keep its interest rates below U.S. rates, so that low

interest rates offset the expected return from renminbi appreciation over time (currently bank deposit rates in China are capped at 2.5%, below the 3.5% federal funds rate).

2. Intervene a lot.3. Or do both.

Either way, this policy prevents independent Chinese monetary policy.

Page 38: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

38

6. Conclusions

In any case, the new Chinese Exchange Rate Mechanism is a step to the right direction.

The United States, in contrast, has not done anything.

President Bush has not vetoed a single spending bill. The government spending has increased faster than at any time since the 1960’s (“the Great Society” welfare programs and Vietnam War).

The massive tax cuts passed in 2001–2003 are set to expire in 2008–2010.

Page 39: The Future of  Bretton Woods II

39

6. Conclusions: What the U.S. Should Do?

Since these are temporary tax cuts and the likelihood they will be made permanent is low, basic economic theory tells us that their positive incentive effects are small.

Since the President and the Congress are unable to control spending, the simplest way for the U.S. to reduce its fiscal deficit (and, indirectly, current account deficit) would be to repeal the 2001–2003 tax cuts.


Recommended