+ All Categories
Home > Documents > The Interaction of Domestic and International Institutions...

The Interaction of Domestic and International Institutions...

Date post: 21-Apr-2018
Category:
Upload: lyanh
View: 218 times
Download: 4 times
Share this document with a friend
35
The Interaction of Domestic and International Institutions: Democracy, Preferential Trade Agreements, and Foreign Direct Investment into Developing Countries Tim Büthe * Assistant Professor of Political Science Duke University [email protected] Helen V. Milner B. C. Forbes Professor of Politics and Int'l Affairs Princeton University [email protected] v.2 (28 April 2010) ) © Tim Büthe and Helen Milner, 2007-2008 Paper prepared for presentation at the Workshop on the Politics of Preferential Trade Agreements: Theory, Measurement, and Empirical Applications, Princeton University, Niehaus Center for Globalization and Governance Friday, 30 April - Saturday 1 May 2010 * For comments on previous drafts, we thank David Leblang, Michael Munger, Jonathan Wand and participants of presentations at the American Political Science Association Meeting 2007, the Midwest Political Science Association Meeting 2008, and at Stanford University. We thank Nancy Brune, Jose Antonio Cheibub, Freedom House, Witold Henisz, Nathan Jensen, Jon Pevehouse, the Polity Project, UNCTAD and WDI for making data available to us and Raymond Hicks and David Francis for excellent research assistance.
Transcript

The Interaction of Domestic and International Institutions: Democracy, Preferential Trade Agreements, and Foreign Direct Investment

into Developing Countries

Tim Büthe* Assistant Professor of Political Science

Duke University [email protected]

Helen V. Milner

B. C. Forbes Professor of Politics and Int'l Affairs Princeton University

[email protected]

v.2 (28 April 2010) ) © Tim Büthe and Helen Milner, 2007-2008

Paper prepared for presentation at the Workshop on the Politics of Preferential Trade Agreements:

Theory, Measurement, and Empirical Applications, Princeton University, Niehaus Center for Globalization and Governance

Friday, 30 April - Saturday 1 May 2010

* For comments on previous drafts, we thank David Leblang, Michael Munger, Jonathan Wand and participants of presentations at the American Political Science Association Meeting 2007, the Midwest Political Science Association Meeting 2008, and at Stanford University. We thank Nancy Brune, Jose Antonio Cheibub, Freedom House, Witold Henisz, Nathan Jensen, Jon Pevehouse, the Polity Project, UNCTAD and WDI for making data available to us and Raymond Hicks and David Francis for excellent research assistance.

2

ABSTRACT : Capital is scarce in most developing countries. Increasingly, direct investment (FDI) into productive assets has come to be seen as a promising avenue for boosting economic development. As a consequence, developing countries compete for FDI by making ex ante promises to foreign investors not to pass laws or regulations--or refrain from other actions--that would diminish the value of the investment ex post. But how credible are such promises? A number of studies in recent years have examined the effect of domestic institutions (veto players, democracy, etc.) on the credibility of commitments by developing country governments toward foreign private economic actors such as foreign investors. In addition, a few studies have examined the effect of international institutions on the credibility of such commitments. We examine the possible interactions of domestic and international institutions in promoting FDI. We show theoretically and empirically that democratic domestic institutions help attract more FDI into developing countries only in the context of economically liberal international institutions.

1

1. Introduction

In recent years, many developing countries have sought to increase the amount of foreign

capital invested in their countries, especially long-term capital investments (e.g., Moran 1998).

Countries tend to face a problem when trying to attract such capital, however. While they might

now promise not to take actions that lower the value of such investments, they often cannot

credibly promise to do so in the longer run. Once the investment is made, governments may be

tempted to change the terms of these investments to reap a greater share of the gains for

themselves and/or their country. Potential investors thus face political risks. They must assess

the political investment climate, as well as the economic opportunities offered by different

countries when deciding where to invest. The time inconsistency problem that creates the above

risks is well known to investors/firms, governments, and scholars (e.g., Kobrin 1982, 1984;

Moran 1978; Vernon 1971). It is a problem since it leads to underinvestment. How can

governments reassure potential investors; what can they do to reduce the political risks in order

to induce investors to make these investments?

In an earlier paper (Büthe and Milner 2008), we have found that developing country

governments can use international trade agreements (GATT/WTO and especially PTAs) to make

their commitments to economically liberal policies more credible and thus boost their countries'

attractiveness for foreign direct investors. As an unexpected corollary of that analysis we found

that measures of domestic political institutions, which we had included as controls, were mostly

insignificant. Various measures of political democracy, in particular, were insignificant after

controlling for international institutions.1 This finding seemed to challenge the recent literature

1 The measure of domestic institutional constraints ("veto points") developed by Henisz (2002) became weaker after controlling for international institutions, but remained significant at the 0.1 level in most analyses.

2

on FDI that finds democratic countries to have been more successful than non-democratic ones

in attracting inward FDI, even after controlling for market size, level of economic development,

etc. (e.g., Feng 2001; Globerman and Shapiro 2003; Jensen 2003, 2006; Tures 2003). We

cautioned, however, that one should not prematurely conclude from our findings that domestic

institutions do not matter for FDI. Quite to the contrary, we suggested that measures such as

veto points or democracy, while not significant by themselves, might interact with international

institutions or policy measures such as trade openness in affecting FDI (Büthe and Milner 2008:

754n30). The systematic analysis of the interaction between international and domestic

institutions, however, was beyond the scope of the earlier paper.

This paper seeks to address the issue by asking: Is the impact of international institutions

conditioned by domestic regime type? We first discuss the existing literature and develop the

theoretical underpinnings for our expectation that there is an interaction effect between

democracy and international institutions. Then, to get at the question empirically, we conduct

two analyses, focused like Büthe and Milner (2008) on trade agreements. First, we compare

average levels of inward FDI in four sub-samples of our data, splitting the data by PTAs (high

versus low) and democracy (yes versus no), based sequentially on one of three key measures of

democracy used in the literature (i.e., the dichotomous measure of democracy developed by Jose

Cheibub, originally with Alvarez, Limongi and Przeworski (ACLP), the 3-catetory Freedom

House aggregate score of "Freedom," and the aggregate measure of regime type, Polity). This

simple test does not allow us to control for any other factors, but provides an informative first

look at the data based on a minimum of assumptions. We find that there is a clear and in most

cases statistically significant difference in average inward FDI between high- and low-PTA

3

country years, and that this difference is more pronounced among democracies than among non-

democracies.

Second, we conduct regression analyses on the full sample, where we include the

measures of international and domestic institutions along with an interaction term, i.e., the

product of our measure of PTAs and three measures of domestic political institutions: the

dichotomous Cheibub democracy measure, the Freedom House index, and Polity (in separate

regressions due to high collinearity between the measures of democracy). We find that political

regime type (democracy) has no statistically significant effect on inward FDI, except when a

country is a party to international trade agreements. Trade agreements boost FDI to a

statistically significant extent, and democracy reinforces this effect.

Our findings lead us to conclude that the effect of international institutions on FDI is

conditioned by domestic institutions. Governments can increase the credibility of their

commitments to investors by signing international agreements, but this effect is stronger when

the commitments are made by governments with democratic political institutions at home.

Indeed, the combination of international trade agreements and democratic politics at home can

substantially increase FDI inflows. Potential investors are doubly reassured that democratic

governments which sign trade liberalization agreements with other countries are more likely to

follow market-friendly policies and to resist the temptation to intervene in ways that degrade the

value of investments. In sum, domestic institutions can reinforce the role of international

institutions as commitment mechanisms for governments who want to attract foreign investment.

Our research contributes to several current debates and has important policy implications.

First, we hope to advance the debate over foreign direct investment. We extend the work done

4

recently by scholars on the role of domestic political institutions in affecting FDI (e.g., Jensen, Li

and Resnick). Like others, we show that democracies are different and they have important

effects on economic outcomes, as well as political ones (e.g., Mansfield, Milner, and Rosendorff

2002). We show that a significant amount of the variation in FDI can be explained by political

variables neglected in previous research.

Second, our research contributes to the broader literature on institutions and how they

matter in politics. Here, our findings lend further support to the argument that institutions—

whether domestic or international—affect the credibility of the commitments that governments

make (e.g., Leeds 1999; Martin 2000; Milner 1997; North and Weingast 1989; Simmons 2000a,

2000b). There are good reasons to think that domestic democracy and liberal international

institutions increase the credibility of commitments that governments make to each other. We

find that part of this logic also holds for commitments that governments make vis-à-vis foreign

private actors in the international political economy. Furthermore, we demonstrate that the

impact of international institutions depends in part on domestic ones. Beyond the literature on 2-

level games (Evans, Jacobson, and Putnam 1993; Mayer 1991; Putnam 1988), the interaction of

domestic and international institutions has received little attention in the literature (with a few

exceptions, such as Mattli and Büthe 2003; Snidal and Thompson 2003). Our findings suggest

that it is a promising area for further research. Additionally, we show that participation in

institutions in one issue area can have effects in another—trade institutions affect foreign

investment flows.

Finally, our research has important implications for scholars and practitioners interested

in the politics of economic development and democratization. Most importantly, we find that

democracy magnifies the economic benefits a country can gain from participation in

5

international political-economic institutions, such as trade agreements. While it is unlikely that

governments are going to fully democratize (and thus risk losing power completely) to increase

foreign investments, the promise of these additional economic benefits creates incentives for

taking small steps toward greater democracy. The resulting increase in foreign investment

should promote growth, which should in turn enhance the government's political support, which

might explain the relative stability of the "hybrid" political regimes that present a puzzle for

much of the literature on democratization (Diamond 2002; Levitsky and Way 2002). Moreover,

many scholars have pointed out the tension between economic liberalization and globalization on

the one hand and democratic control of public policy on the other. Some even have argued that

economic liberalization must precede democratization for democracy and an open economy to be

compatible. We find that democratic countries can reap greater benefits from economic

liberalization and globalization, which suggests that democracy and an open economy may in

some ways be more compatible when democratization precedes economic liberalization rather

than vice versa.

2. Domestic Institutions and International Commitments

2.1. Existing Literature

The credibility problems that countries face regarding foreign direct investments have

long been known to policy makers and academics (e.g., Vernon 1971) (Moran 1985).

Investment decisions are based on the set of policies a country's government currently has in

place or the set of policies the government may have promised to adopt. Investors use this

information to calculate the potential profitability of their investment. After the investment is

made, however, governments often have incentives to renege on their promises or change

policies, thus reducing the value of the investment. All investors face the risk that the security or

6

profitability of their investments will be reduced as an intentional or unintentional consequence

of changes in government policy. All investors therefore should worry about the credibility of a

government’s commitment to any particular set of policies. But foreign investors should worry

in particular: They have often no legitimate voice in the political process that determines the

policies affecting them, which in turn makes them attractive targets of nationalistic political

opportunism. And foreign direct investors face even higher risks since their investments are by

definition less mobile.2 We investigate here how governments can mitigate the political risks

associated with these investments; we are less interested in the economic factors that induce or

repel such flows, although we try to control for these factors.

A recent and growing literature examines the domestic political institutions that countries

can use to overcome the time inconsistency problems they face. Numerous scholars have

investigated the impact of regime type on investment. They have asked whether investors care

how democratic a country is when they make investment allocation decisions. The early

literature on FDI suggested that MNCs were attracted to autocracies by their ability to suppress

labor demands and by the absence of election-induced policy uncertainty (Bornschier and Chase-

Dunn 1985; O'Donnell 1979 (1973)). Other scholars, however, found no significant effects for

regime type (e.g. Oneal 1994) or suggested more complex causal relationships (Kahler 1981).

More recent research has found that democracies attract more foreign direct investment, because

policy in democracies may be more predictable than in autocracies (e.g., Feng 2001; Jensen

2003). Jensen argues that democracies provide three advantages over autocracies when it comes

to FDI. First, democracies provide more information to potential investors because they are

2 The degree of mobility of course varies. It is very low for investments in the extraction of natural resources, which may explain why these investments have long been most at risk of expropriation; services FDI, which has increased greatly in recent years, is much more mobile, but still less mobile than financial investments, assuming equal constraints on taking funds out of a given country.

7

more transparent; second, democracies allow for more representation of the interests of investors

so investors can affect the governments of the FDI host countries; and third, democracies create a

more credible environment for market friendly policy because of the higher audience costs that

executives face if they change policies.

Li and Resnick (2003) challenge some of these arguments based on a more differentiated

notion of democracy and its potential effects on FDI. They see democracy as having both

benefits and costs for foreign investors, the main benefit being the better protection of private

property rights. They show that regime type indeed does have mixed effects; only the private

property rights component of democracy is favorable to FDI. Blanton and Blanton (2006) find

little evidence that democracy matters for FDI, but show that human rights treatment by host

countries is important. In sum, mixed evidence exists for the impact of regime type on FDI, and

the causal process by which that effect is exerted is much debated.

Another political mechanism by which political leaders may increase the credibility of

their commitments to investors is through international agreements and treaties. A number of

authors have shown that by signing bilateral investment treaties (BITs) countries can attract FDI

inflows (e.g., Neumayer and Spess 2005; Büthe and Milner 2009), though others have found

more mixed results. In recent work, Büthe and Milner (2008) show that countries that join

preferential trade agreements (PTAs) and the WTO receive more FDI.

Büthe and Milner argue that the indirect political effects of trade agreements are the most

important reasons for this effect. Trade agreements have a positive effect on investors’

assessments of how risky it is to undertake an investment in a given country, they argue, because

signing a trade agreement commits a government directly to economically liberal foreign

8

economic policies such as low trade barriers and more indirectly to economically liberal

economic polices at home (both of which foreign investors have been shown to like). Trade

agreements can serve as commitment devices that tie a government’s hands and reduce the

likelihood that it will adopt policies that hurt the value of investments. Governments can

increase the credibility of their current policies by signing trade agreements that commit them to

market friendly policies and make changing those policies more visible and more costly. Trade

agreements serve as “strategic moves” that potentially raise the costs for a country to renege on

its policies toward foreign investors later on (Dixit and Skeath 2004: chap 10). International

trade agreements may also be more credible than pure domestic policy changes since the costs of

breaking trade agreements with international partners may be higher than the costs of domestic

change. The purely economic effects of PTAs are only part of what induces foreign investors; the

political significance of trade agreements as costly and hence credible commitments also matters

to foreign investors and boosts FDI above and beyond the direct economic effects of trade

agreements.

2.2. Interaction of Domestic and International Institutions

In this paper, we explore the interaction between domestic and international institutions

in solving credibility problems for governments. Given the findings in our earlier paper, we

expect that international trade agreements like PTAs and the WTO will have a positive impact on

FDI inflows. We hypothesize that democratic domestic political institutions may multiply this

effect of trade agreements on FDI because signing a trade agreement has in the eyes of foreign

investors greater consequences for democracies than for non-democracies. The specific effect of

international institutions on FDI would thus be conditional on domestic institutions. We

stipulate two reasons for such a conditional effect.

9

First, freedom of the press and freedom of expression are a hallmark of (liberal)

democracy. Even if press freedom ratings by Freedom House and Reporters sans Frontiers show

that the extent to which citizens enjoy these freedoms in practice varies considerably among

democracies, the ratings tend to be much higher for democracies than non-democracies.3 Press

freedom ensures more, better and public information about government behavior from an

independent source; freedom of expression ensures that those who are (in danger of being)

harmed by a (planned) policy change have the opportunity to speak up and make their grievances

publicly known. While this additional information, especially the unbiased information provided

by a free press, is surely valued by foreign investors seeking to assess political risks, it may not

lead to significantly increased FDI if the government policies thus revealed are not favorable to

foreign investors. On balance, democracy by itself might therefore not have a significant effect

on FDI. However, if freedom of the press and freedom of expression coincide with trade

agreements that commit governments to economically liberal foreign economic policies (and

liberal economic policies more broadly), then the additional information would make it easier for

any interested party to identify violations of those commitments. By facilitating the detection of

any violation of a country's policy commitments, freedom of the press and expression make it

easier for a country's partners in a trade agreement to punish such violations, which in turn

should increase foreign investors' confidence in these commitments since it makes violation of

the commitments more costly in expectation than when the same commitments are undertaken

by a non-democratic government.

Second, democratic leaders face higher (domestic) audience costs than non-democratic

leaders when they break foreign policy commitments that they have made in public. Autocratic 3 See http://www.freedomhouse.org/template.cfm?page=16 (8/20/2007) and http://www.rsf.org /rubrique.php3?id_rubrique=639 (8/20/2007).

10

leaders may be able to violate international agreements with little domestic cost (though they will

still face international costs, which should ensure that trade agreements boost FDI independent of

democracy). Democratic leaders will, in addition, pay a domestic political price—what Fearon

(1994) has called "audience costs"—for reneging on their commitments, which should render

making such commitments more credible and therefore further boost the increased FDI that

democracies experience as a consequence of signing trade agreements.

The basic argument here—derived from the sizeable literature about the effect of

domestic audience costs on international relations—is that when democratic governments make

an international commitment (to a particular policy or course of action) that is visible to domestic

audiences, they increase their own political costs of not pursuing that policy or course of action,

thus making the commitment more credible.4 Our claim is that, as a country grows more

democratic, foreign investors come to consider its commitments to trade liberalization in

particular and liberal economic policies in general as more credible, because of the higher

audience costs such countries face in breaking trade agreements. This argument depends, first,

on publics not approving of their leaders violating international trade agreements once they are 4 Differences in audience costs across regimes types have been invoked to explain why democracies fight less (Fearon 1994; Schultz 2001), why they are more likely to win wars they fight (Lake 1992), why they are unlikely to back down in crises (Smith 1998), why they use international legal arbitration more (Allee and Huth 2006), and why they comply with their international commitments more than nondemocracies (McGillivray and Smith 200?). In general, the microfoundations of these arguments about audience costs have been poorly specified. Is it the public’s concern for the nation’s reputation in world affairs that matters; is it the democratic leader’s concern about how the public sees him (competent or not); or is it the political opposition that makes electoral gains from the leader’s behavior? More recent work has tried to pin down these microfoundations. Tomz, for example, finds some support for the hypothesis that citizens are concerned about the international reputation of their country (Tomz 2007). Gale (2007) has tried to show what happens when the level of audience costs can vary according to the salience of the issue at hand. His results show that treating both the level of the strategic interests and regime type as variables produces better predictions about crisis behavior than audience costs alone. Kernell (1997) and Baum (2004) show that presidents in the US can also try to generate audience costs to enhance their international bargaining positions, but that this can be a double-edged sword. Slantchev (2006), in a more direct attack on these microfoundations, shows theoretically that only an independent media can generate the information necessary for publics to be able to sanction their leaders, and thus only democracies with strong medias are capable of generating audience costs that differ from those of autocracies. In sum, the existing literature presents a number of different explanations for the public's initial preferences for keeping international agreements, but the general logic that unfolds from this assumption is widely shared.

11

signed. It also depends, second, on publics in democracies knowing whether these commitments

have been violated; third, on these publics' ability to punish their leaders for such violations; and,

fourth, on foreign investors being able to assess these differential audience costs when making

investment decisions.

While a complete analysis of the causal mechanism is beyond the scope of this paper

(and the logic of the argument suggests that actual violations of trade agreements by democracies

should be quite rare), the existing literature offers at a general level some support for each step in

the causal chain and strong support for some of the steps. First, there is a diverse literature

suggesting that publics disapprove of their governments violating international agreements (e.g.,

Fearon 1994)(McGillivray and Smith). Tomz even finds direct support for this preference on

behalf of the general public in experimental studies and in surveys about economic agreements

(Tomz 2007). Since democratic leaders depend upon broader public support than autocratic

ones, these preferences among the general public should have greater salience in democracies

than in non-democracies. As for the second issue, comparative public opinion research across

political regime types is difficult if not impossible, but existing research shows the general public

in democracies to be well informed about their countries' foreign policies. And since reneging

on international commitments almost always harms some domestic interests, freedom of

expression in democracies makes it very likely that those domestic interests will make the

government's violation of its commitments public, as discussed above. Electoral democracy in

turn guarantees that voters can punish the government if they disapprove of its policies (though

the extent to which this constrains the government will surely depend upon the salience of the

issue and the expected closeness of the next election, see, e.g., Aldrich, Sullivan, and Borgida

1989). On the fourth and final step, there is at least anecdotal evidence to support our argument.

12

While the level of explicit political consciousness among business executives tends to be low,

interviews with senior managers in multinationals in the US and Europe, conducted by one of us,

suggest that major foreign direct investment decisions almost always involve a political risk

analysis, and that a country's political and legal system is part of that analysis, along with

specific policies and international legal commitments such as BITs and trade agreements.

In sum, our claim is that, as a country grows more democratic, foreign investors

increasingly come to believe its commitments to trade liberalization in particular and more

liberal economic policies in general, because of the higher (internal) audience costs such

countries face in breaking trade agreements and because of the higher likelihood that breaking

the agreement will be detected by other signatories, who can impose costs externally. So we

expect that democracies that sign PTAs will receive more FDI than democracies that do not sign

them, and that this effect will rise with the number of PTAs they sign. The flip-side of this

argument is that among the countries that sign PTAs, those countries that are more democratic

will receive more FDI than those that are less democratic.

Overall, our argument is that democracy, even if it may not matter for FDI by itself,

combines with a country’s commitment in international trade agreements matters to make a

country more attractive for foreign investors. It is the interaction of these two institutional

factors that makes the difference. This leads us to two central hypotheses:

H1: As the extent of a country’s level of democracy rises, the positive effect of signing PTAs on

its inwards FDI increases. (In a dichotomous setting, the positive effect of signing PTAs on a

country’s FDI inflows will be greater for democracies than for autocracies.)

13

H2: As a logical corollary of H1, the positive effect of democracy on a country’s inwards FDI

will be greater for a country the more PTAs it has signed.

3. Empirical Analyses

3.1. Sample and Key Variables

To test the above hypotheses, we conduct statistical analyses of inward foreign direct

investment for a large panel of developing countries. International organizations like the UN

Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) began collecting comprehensive annual data

on foreign direct investment flows into developing countries in the 1970s. The most recent year

for which we have complete data is 2008 (though limited availability of one of the control

variables limits some analysis to 2006). We restrict our sample to non-OECD countries because

there are strong theoretical reasons to believe that FDI into developing countries (LDCs) is a

function of a different set of factors than FDI into advanced industrialized countries.5 Our

sampling frame thus consists of all independent non-OECD countries with a population of more

than 1 million. There have been 132 such countries in existence at some point in time between

1970 and 2008. We have sought to maximize our sample size and are able to analyze data for

123-125 of these 132 countries for our main analyses.

Our dependent variable, inward FDI, is the sum of direct investment undertaken by

foreigners in a given country during a given year, as a percentage of GDP (this variable tends to

be positive but can take negative values in years when foreigners withdraw more direct

investment than they undertake). The data is taken from the online version of UNCTAD's

Handbook of Statistics, the source of the most comprehensive data on FDI (see UNCTAD

5 Blonigen and Wang (2005) show empirically that pooling data from OECD countries and LDCs is problematic.

14

2003:231f for details). We use FDI as a percentage of GDP to eliminate the need to deflate our

dependent variable and to make it comparable across countries and across time.

To study the interaction of domestic and international institutions, we focus on three sets

of variables: measures of international trade agreements, measures of domestic political regime

type (democracy), and the interaction between them. Our main measure of trade agreements is

CUMULATIVE PTAs, which records the number of trade agreements (other than GATT/WTO) to

which a country is a party by the end of the given year. This variable is based on a new, more

comprehensive dataset compiled by Helen Milner and Ed Mansfield and differs from the

Pevehouse measure used by Büthe and Milner (2008) in that it covers a larger number of PTA.

For the LDCs in our sample, this variable ranges from 0 to 21.6

We employ three measures of regime type to assess the degree of political democracy at

the domestic level. We consider first a dichotomous measure of electoral democracy created by

Cheibub, which codes a regime as democratic if and only if high political offices are chosen

through fair and free contested elections where alternation of leaders occurs.7 Second, we

employ the widely-used Polity index, which combines data on five aspects of domestic political

institutions that capture the differences between democracies and autocracies: 1.) the

competitiveness of the process for selecting a country’s chief executive, 2.) the openness of this

process, 3.) the extent to which institutional constraints limit a chief executive’s decision-making

authority, 4.) the competitiveness of political participation within a country, and 5.) the degree to

6 Since we have argued that PTAs constitute a commitment to liberal economic policies and increase the informational effects and thus the costliness of breaking the commitment, we expect a positive correlation with FDI. Since we have argued elsewhere that GATT and WTO membership also constitute a costly commitment to liberal economic policies, we include in some of the analyses—as a secondary measure of trade agreements—a dichotomous measure(s) of formal membership in GATT and WTO: GATT/WTO MEMBERSHIP (coded 1 for every year in which a country is a member of GATT or WTO, see www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/gattmem_e.htm, www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/whatis_e/tif_e/org6_e.htm). The correlation with FDI should also be positive. 7 For details see Alvarez et al (1996), Cheibub (2007) Przeworski et al (2000).

15

which binding rules govern political participation within it.8 The resulting 21-point score should

be positively correlated with FDI. Third, we use Freedom House's (FH) three-point score.

Based on expert observers’ answers to questions about the electoral process, political

participation and the functioning of government, FH rates each country as free, partly free, or not

free. Note that this measure is coded such that higher numbers are less democratic; hence a

positive correlation between democracy and FDI implies in a regression setting a negative

coefficient for this variable.

None of these measures is perfect, and correlations among them, while above 0.7, are far

from unity, which suggests that they are not in fact measuring the same thing (see Elkins 2000;

Munck and Verkuilen 2002). Yet, they provide reasonable and broadly comparable indicators of

democracy, and they are the standard measures used in the literature. We therefore use all three

measures (separately, given the high correlation) to assess whether our results are robust to

changes in the conceptualization of regime type.

3.2. Empirical Analysis I: Differences in Average Inward FDI

As a very simple first cut, we split the sample between democracies and non-democracies

(the columns in Figures 1-3).9 We also split the sample into country-years with a low number of

PTAs (2 or less) and country-years with a high number of PTAs (3 or more). Since we had no

theoretical reason to expect any particular threshold for the number of PTAs, we used the median

number of PTAs to dichotomize the sample based on this measure, so that the size of the two

8 For details, see http://www.cidcm.umd.edu/inscr/polity/index.htm, Gurr et al. 1989, and Jaggers and Gurr 1995. 9 Since our unit of analysis is the country-year and many countries in the sample experienced regime changes during the time period covered by this analysis, we divide the sample based on observation-level information, i.e., we did not assume that any given country is in one column or the other for the entire period. However, for consistency with our other analyses, we used the 1-year lagged valued for democracy and PTAs. The lag allows for a time delay between these hypothesized explanatory variables (democracy and PTAs) and their stipulated effect on FDI. It also provides some safeguard against reverse causation.

16

groups (the rows in Figures 1-3) would be approximately equal. This two-way split of the

sample resulted in the 2x2 tables in Figures 1-3. We then calculated, for each cell, the mean of

FDI (net inwards FDI as a percentage of GDP), as well as the standard deviation.

Our general theoretical argument about PTAs as such suggests that—within each

column—average FDI should be higher in the top cell than in the bottom cell. If democracies

attract more FDI than non-democracies at any given level of PTAs, then—within each row—

average inward FDI should be higher in the cell on the right than in the cell on the left. Our main

focus in this paper, however, is to assess the hypothesis that the effect of PTAs on inward FDI is

conditioned by domestic political institutions and more specifically that democracy boosts the

effect of PTAs on FDI. If this hypothesis holds, we should observe a greater effect of PTAs in

the democracy column than in the non-democracy column.

Democracy (Cheibub)

NO YES

3.17 3.65 HIGH (7.39, 1054) (3.55, 708)

1.38 1.39

PTA

s

LOW (3.62, 1666) (1.99, 553)

Figure 1: Mean annual levels of inward FDI (as a percentage of GDP) by regime type and dichotomized level of PTAs (PTAs split at the median: low = 0 - 2; high = 3 and more). Standard deviation and N for each cell in parentheses.

Figure 1 shows the results when the dichotomous measure is used to differentiate

between democracies and non-democracies. We find that countries (i.e., country-years) with a

17

high number of PTAs generally attract more FDI than countries with a low number of PTAs.10

This difference is more pronounced for democracies than for non-democracies—as expected

theoretically: The estimated effect of a country increasing the number of its trade agreements

from a "low" number to a "high" number is an increase in inward FDI equal to almost 2.3% of

GDP for democracies (as measured by Cheibub's measure). By contrast, the estimated increase

for non-democracies is just below 1.8% of GDP. While the difference is highly statistically

significant (p < 0.00005) for both democracies and non-democracies, it is larger and more

significant for democracies. Democracy, on the other, has virtually no effect in a low-PTA

environment, but increases FDI inflows in a high-PTA environment to a substantively (almost

0.5% of GDP) and statistically at least weakly significant extent (p<0.0567).

Figure 2 shows the average levels of FDI for each subgroup in the 2x2 table if the

POLITY measure is used to distinguish between democracies and non-democracies. It has

become customary in much of the literature to require a polity score of 7 or more on the raw (–10

to +10) scale of the Polity index for a country to be considered a democracy.11 We accept this

threshold to create a dichotomous measure of democracy for purposes of Figure 2.

10 More precisely, we find: countries that were parties to a high number of PTAs in the previous year attract more FDI than countries that were parties to a low number of PTAs in the previous year— on average and controlling for democracy. 11 18 or more in the 1 to 21 scale that we use for the interaction terms below.

18

Democracy (Polity > 6)

NO YES

3.04 3.92 HIGH (7.02, 1180) (3.67, 568)

1.40 1.32

PTA

s

LOW (3.50, 1856) (1.94, 340)

Figure 2: Mean annual levels of inward FDI (as a percentage of GDP) by regime type and dichotomized level of PTAs (PTAs split at the median: low = 0 - 2; high = 3 and more). Standard deviation and N for each cell in parentheses.

Here again, among countries with a high number of PTAs, democratic countries attract

more FDI than non-democracies. The difference is large and strongly statistically significant

(p = 0.0025). Among countries with low PTAs, this simple analysis even suggests that

democratic countries receive less FDI, though the difference is statistically completely

insignificant (p = 0.6532) for countries with low PTAs. Also, country(year)s with high PTAs

attract more average inward FDI than country(year)s with low PTAs, both in general and

controlling for democracy. This effect is substantially larger for democracies than for non-

democracies—consistent with the hypothesis advanced above—though statistically significant in

both columns of Table 2 (p < 0.00005).

Finally, we turn in Figure 3 to the democracy measure FREEDOM from Freedom House.

We dichotomize this measure (as customary in the literature) by coding "free" countries

(FREEDOM = 1) as democracies, and by coding "semi-free" and "unfree" countries as non-

democracies. Splitting the sample based on the Freedom House measure of democracy (and

19

consequently inherently limiting the analysis to cover 1973-2008) yields the average levels of

inwards FDI recorded in Figure 3.

Democracy (Freedom House)

NO YES

3.17 4.13 HIGH (6.79, 1295) (3.77, 437)

1.41 1.49

PTA

s

LOW (3.59, 1605) (1.98, 320)

Figure 3: Mean annual levels of inward FDI (as a percentage of GDP) by regime type and dichotomized level of PTAs (PTAs split at the median: low = 0 - 2; high = 3 and more). Standard deviation and N for each cell in parentheses.

As when using the other measures, countries-years with high PTAs here, too, appear to

attract more FDI than country-years with low PTAs, and the difference again is statistically

significant for both democracies and non-democracies (p=0.0002). Democratic countries also

appear to attract generally more FDI, but in the low-PTA environment, the difference is not

statistically significance (p = 0.3481). By contrast, the difference is clearly statistically

significant in the high-PTAs environment (p = 0.0026).

These findings generally support our argument. Most importantly, the greater difference

between the top and the bottom cell in the democracy column than in the non-democracy column

suggests that democracy indeed boosts the effect PTAs on FDI. The findings also suggest that

PTAs have a greater effect than democracy, which only appears to matter in a high-PTA

environment (though the difference across the columns in the lower row is never statistically

significant).

20

While interesting, these findings suffer from several handicaps. Most importantly, this

approach does not allow us to control for other factors that previous research has found to be

significant determinants of FDI, such as market size, economic growth, political violence, or

trade or financial openness. If those factors are not perfectly orthogonal, the above results suffer

from omitted variable bias. Moreover, the findings in the Figures above may reflect spurious

correlation: The number of PTAs, measures of democracy, and FDI have all generally trended

upwards during the time period covered here. More sophisticated statistical techniques are

warranted.

3.3. Empirical Analysis II: Regression Analysis

We have noted above a number of concerns that make us hesitant to draw strong

inferences from the summary of the data in the 2x2 tables. To address these concerns and get

more directly at the interaction between international and domestic institutions, we now turn to

regression analysis. We start from a model of the following general form:

(i)

… where "TA" is a generic measure of trade agreements and "X1it-1 … Xnit-1" represent

any number of control variables. To asses whether the effect of trade agreements on FDI is

conditioned by democracy, we add "DEM," a (for now) generic measure of democracy and an

interaction terms of the general form TA*DEM:12

(ii)

12 We include democracy as the component part of the interaction term.

21

Models of the type shown in equation (i) are essentially restricted versions of models of

the type shown in equation (ii). The latter, however, is itself a restricted version of the fully

unrestricted model in equation (iii), which implies that regime type conditions the entire

structural relationship between the hypothesized explanatory variables and FDI:

(iii)

We should draw inferences from the estimated coefficients for models of type (ii) only if,

on the one hand, model (ii) offers a significant improvement in fit vis-a-vis model (i) and, on the

other hand, model (iii) does not offer a significant further improvement over model (ii). F-tests

may be used to conduct these tests for joint significance of the additional coefficients.

As discussed above, we use three measures of democracy and form interaction terms for

each of them (one at a time to avoid multicollinearity). Thus we first interact CUMULATIVE PTAs

with Cheibub's the dichotomous indicator of democracy to create PTA*CHEIBDEM. In a separate

set of models, we then interact trade agreements with POLITY, the 21-point scale measuring the

extent of democracy, PTA*POLITY.13 In a final set of estimations, we interact trade agreements

with the Freedom House measure of regime type to form PTA*FREEDOM. These interaction terms

are the key variables of interest for assessing hypotheses 1 and 2. Their estimated coefficients

should be positive, except for PTA*FREEDOM, which should have a negative coefficient.

While trade agreements and the interaction terms are the key variables of interest for us,

and while there are good reasons to keep models for panel data as simple as possible, we

recognize that FDI is also affected by other economic and political factors, not yet discussed.

13 Since a raw polity score of zero is not mathematically meaningful (as would be assumed when using it in a multiplicative way), we re-scale polity so that it exhibits no negative values. Instead of ranging from -10 to +10, POLITYpos runs from 1 through 21.

22

Specifically, in keeping with previous work, we control for host MARKET SIZE by including in our

model the log of the country's population. To control for the level of ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT,

we include the log of per capita GDP in constant (2000) dollars. To control for economic

growth, we use the percentage change in the country's real GDP from the previous year, GDP

GROWTH. Among the political factors, the most important ones identified by previous research as

predictors of FDI are the number of bilateral investment treaties (BITs) to which a country is a

signatory (from UNCTAD 2000); POLITICAL INSTABILITY, the composite measure from Arthur

Banks' dataset of political events that indicate political violence and instability (Banks 1999);

and DOMESTIC POLITICAL CONSTRAINTS, Henisz's preference-weighted measure of the number of

veto players in a national political system (2002:363).14

As the length of the time series for each country is too short to justify the usual

assumptions about asymptotics for analyses within any single country, we pool data from all

developing countries in our sample. Preliminary tests show, however, that neither simple OLS

on the pooled sample nor random effects estimation is appropriate. Since our main theoretical

interest is whether changes in international or domestic institutions affects a given country's

attractiveness to foreign direct investors, we conduct "within" estimations (OLS with country

fixed effects; for a more detailed discussion, see, e.g., ) (Hsiao 2003; Wooldridge 2002). All

explanatory variables are lagged one period; when necessary, they are also detrended to

safeguard against spurious correlation that arises from variables trending together over time (e.g.,

14 This variable indicates the extent of constitutionally mandated institutions that can exercise veto power over decisions as well as the alignment of actors’ preferences between those institutions within each state. The data measures the presence of effective branches of government outside of the executive’s control, the extent to which these branches are controlled. While this is a measure of domestic political institutions and might therefore be considered as an alternative to the measures of democracy, it is not itself a measure of democracy (neither conceptually nor empirically, as it varies greatly among democracies)

23

Davidson and MacKinnon 1993:670-673). Country fixed effects are employed in the detrending

stage; and standard errors are clustered by country.15

3.3.1. Results

Table 1 reports the estimated results when using CHEIBDEM as the measure of

democracy. The first column (model 0) replicates model 4 of Büthe and Milner (2008), albeit

with the new measure of PTAs and several years' of additional data, which increase the size of

sample by 1/3 compared to their model 4, adding more than 800 observations. Our key findings

are consistent with theirs: PTAs boost FDI inflows to a highly statistically significant extent;

GATT/WTO membership also boosts FDI, though the estimated coefficient here is only weakly

significant. The estimated positive effect BITs just misses conventional levels of statistical

significance. Political instability reduced FDI, though it is only weakly statistically significant.

Economic growth boosts FDI; market size and economic development are (after de-trending and

country fixed-effects) insignifcant. The most notable difference is that Henisz' measure of

DOMESTIC POLITICAL CONSTRAINTS is far from statistically significant (with the wrong sign). We

attribute this changes to our use the 2010 update of Henisz' measure, which differs significantly

from the 2002 version used by Büthe and Milner (2008)—the correlation is below 0.6 for the

observations in our sample. Because of the potential for multicollinearity when including

Henisz' measure simultaneously with the measures of democracy, we therefore drop this

insignificant measure from the model.

15 We use the standard errors for within estimators proposed by Arellano (1987), which are robust to both heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation and yield the most conservative inferences (see Kézdi 2004).

24

Table 1 Interactive Effect of Democracy and Trade Agreements: ACLP

Model 0 Model 1 Model 2CHEIBDEM Model 3 CHEIBDEM

cumulative PTAs 0.169*** (.0583)

0.170*** (.0581)

0.162*** (.0576)

0.172*** (.0579)

CHEIBDEM * cumulative PTAs

0.615*** (.229)

0.640 (.281)

CHEIBDEM -0.192 (.231)

-0.136 (.227)

Dom. Political Constraints

–0.345 (.538)

GATT/WTO membership

0.776* (.445)

0.762* (.449)

0.734 (.448)

0.725 (.460)

CHEIBDEM * GATT/ WTO membership

0.751*** (.775)

BITs 0.0205 (.0130)

0.0202 (.0129)

0.0201 (.0128)

0.0203 (.0130)

CHEIBDEM * BITs 0.000971 (.0317)

Political Instability -0.0150* (.0124)

-0.0142 (.0123)

-0.0134 (.0125)

-0.0144 (.0124)

CHEIBDEM * Political Instability

-0.0545* (.0312)

Market Size 0.186 (1.70)

0.202 (1.71)

0.158 (1.68)

0.193 (1.71)

CHEIBDEM * Market Size

–4.23 (3.71)

Economic Development 0.195 (.645)

0.197 (.642)

0.232 (.646)

0.234 (.657)

CHEIBDEM * Economic Development

0.232 (.899)

GDP growth 0.0997** (.0456)

0.0989** (.0451)

0.0986** (.0451)

–0.0955** (.0414)

CHEIBDEM * GDP growth

-0.169 (.105)

constant 2.38*e-10 (1.53.*e-9)

-1.63*e-9 (1.49.*e-9)

0.00711 (.00984)

0.0210 (.0134)

N 3337 3344 3344 3344

R2 +.0411 +.0413 +.0439 +.0474

p>F (F-test, this model against immediately prior model)

n/a n/a 0.0143 0.1657

Note: Robust standard errors in parentheses. * p < 0.1; ** p < 0.05; *** p < 0.01, two-tailed tests. n = 124. All estimates in Stata 10.1.

25

Model 1 then is our baseline model, following the logic of equation (i) above, Model 2

adds to this baseline model the CHEIBDEM measure of democracy and the interaction term with

PTAs. The estimated coefficient for the interaction term is positive and substantively as well as

statistically significant (at better than the .01 level), while the estimated coefficient on the PTAs

as such is virtually unchanged. Substantively, the coefficient suggests that the additional FDI

generated by every additional PTA is more than three times as much for democratic than for non-

democratic developing countries.16 The coefficient for the dichotomous measure of democracy

(CHEIBDEM), by contrast, has the wrong sign (suggesting that democracies as such get less FDI

than non-democracies) but is nowhere near conventional levels of statistical significance. The

model fit is improved, though only modestly. Jointly, the two new variables (CHEIBDEM and

CHEIBDEM*PTAs) are clearly significant (p = 0.0143), but since CHEIBDEM*PTAs was calculated

from the de-trended series, the correlation between CHEIBDEM and the interaction term is actually

very low (below 0.1), which suggests that the t-statistics on the individual coefficients can be

interpreted directly.

The last column of Table 1 shows the results for model 3, which includes interaction

terms between CHEIBDEM and every independent variable in the baseline model (model 1).

While a few of the interactions come up weakly statistically significant here (political constraints

with the wrong sign), most of the interactions are completely insignificant, and the F-test clearly

shows that estimating model 3 is not warranted. In sum, when using the CHEIBDEM measure of

democracy, we find no evidence of democracy by itself attracting FDI inflows, but quite strong

evidence of democracy interactively reinforcing the FDI-boosting effect of international trade

agreements. This effect also appears to be substantively large and statistically significant at 16 Keeping in mind that the dependent variable and most of the explanatory variables for these regressions have been de-trended.

26

conventional levels for GATT/WTO, but not for the other variables in the model. We can

therefore reject model 3 and conclude that it is, above all, the interaction between trade

agreements and domestic regime type (democracy) that matters.

Do these findings hold up when we use other, more fine-grained measures of democracy?

The first two columns of Table 2 present models 1 and 2a for POLITYpos (the 21-point regime type

measure from the Polity project, rescaled to the 1 - 21 interval before calculating the interaction

terms). The thrust of these results is very comparable to the findings for CHEIBDEM: There is no

indication of a statistically significant effect for the regime type variable alone (the insignificant

coefficient has the wrong sign),17 but the positive coefficient for the interaction term of regime

type and PTAs is both substantively and statistically significant (at p = .012). The two variables

are jointly significant at better than the 0.05 level, but this result appears to be again driven

almost entirely by the interaction term. Since the POLITY measure differentiates gradations of

democracy, this finding from country-fixed-effects regressions clearly supports the general

version of our hypothesis 1: As a country's level of democracy rises, the positive effect of

signing PTAs on its FDI inflows increases. Adding an interaction with GATT/WTO also yields

a positive coefficient, but that coefficient is only weakly statistical significant (p = 0.088); model

3 is again clearly not warranted (results not shown; available upon request).

17 Ironically, the positive effect of political constraints on FDI increases when we move from model 1 to model 2. This may be interpreted as PolCon picking up the aspect of democracy most desired by foreign investors.

27

Table 2 Interactive Effects: Alternative Measures of Democracy

Model 1polity sample Model 2Polity Model 1freedomsample Model 2Freedom

cumulative PTAs 0.144** (.0569)

0.132** (.0569)

0.170*** (.0842)

0.156*** (.0599)

(Politypos or Freedom) * cuml. PTAs

0.0442** (.0176)

-0.272** (.114)

Politypos -0.00413 (.0182)

Freedom -0.318* (.162)

GATT/WTO membership

0.813* (.445)

0.792* (.441)

0.685 (.490)

0.692 (.484)

BITs 0.0171 (.0124)

0.0170 (.0122)

0.0109 (.0135)

0.0121 (.0128)

Political Instability -0.0101 (.0120)

-0.00913 (.0123)

-0.0173 (.0148)

-0.0140 (.0147)

Market Size 0.110 (1.72)

0.178 (1.68)

0.521 (2.22)

0.839 (2.15)

Economic Development 0.142 (.654)

0.201 (.635)

0.787 (.884)

-0.823 (.852)

GDP growth 0.112** (.0458)

0.111** (.0460)

0.101** (.0485)

0.102** (.0483)

constant –2.59*e-9 (2.32*e-9)

0.0126 (.0117)

-2.07*e-10 (1.41*e-)

0.0131 (.00974)

N 3317 3317 3072 3072

n 123 123 122 122

time period covered 1970-2006 1970-2006 1973-2006 1973-2006

R2 +.0443 +.0469 +.0404 +.0433

F-test Model 2 vs. 1 p > F = .0383 p > F = .0193

Note: Robust standards errors in parentheses. * p < 0.1; ** p < 0.05; *** p < 0.01, two-tailed tests. All estimates in Stata 10.1 R2 not fully comparable across models due to changes in sample size.

The estimated coefficients for the models using the Freedom House measure of

democracy lend further support to this finding: The interaction term of PTAs and Freedom is

clearly statistically significant, but the negative coefficient here (given the encoding of this

democracy measure) again suggests substantively that PTAs boost inward FDI much more

28

strongly for democracies than for non-democracies.18 In an alternative version of model 2, in

which only the interaction term with GATT/WTO is added (not shown), that interaction term

also is significant, although the indicator variable for GATT/WTO membership alone in these

models misses the conventional threshold for statistical significance (p = 0.167), and there is

again no indication that model 3 is warranted.

In the analyses above, we examined the effect of PTAs on FDI flows in the context of

other economic and political factors that previous analyses have shown to explain FDI flows, and

we interacted our PTA measure with the three measures of regime type. Our expectation was

that the estimated coefficient for the interaction term should be positive (except for the inversely

encoded Freedom House measure, where it should be negative). The coefficients estimated for

the interaction terms bear out these expectations and substantively suggest for all measures of

democracy that the FDI-boosting effect of PTAs is stronger the more democratic a country is.

We have also found a substantively similar but more uncertain effect for the multilateral trade

agreement, GATT/WTO.

4. Conclusions

In this paper we have asked how political factors affect flows of direct foreign investment

into developing countries. We have argued that governments face time inconsistency problems,

which may reduce inward FDI because potential investors worry about the credibility of implicit

or explicit promises not to take measure that would devalue the investments, but that

governments can overcome or reduce these problems and thus increase inward FDI with the help

of domestic and international institutions that tie the hands of governments so that it is more

18 In this case, even the coefficient for the democracy measure by itself has the "correct" sign (suggesting a positive effect of democracy on FDI), but it is so far from conventional levels of statistical significance that we are ready to put much stock into that finding.

29

costly to renege on their promises later on. In an earlier paper we showed that international trade

agreements and institutions can help perform this function. Signing preferential trade

agreements or joining the WTO helped countries attract foreign investment. In this paper, we

show that this effect persists even when a more comprehensive set of PTAs is taken into account

and the time series are extended, increasing the sample size by 1/3. Furthermore, we extend the

prior research and show that domestic institutions matter as well. The impact of trade

agreements on FDI is increased when countries are more democratic. Democracy at home can

be used in combination with international institutions to enable governments to enhance the

credibility of their positions. Although we do not find an effect for domestic regime type by

itself, we do show that in combination with international trade agreements, democracy indeed

matters.

These findings have interesting implications for the current literature and future research.

First, research in both security studies and IPE has during the last two decades examined

domestic political institutions and specifically regime type as an explanatory variable for a range

of phenomena in world politics. Few, however, have systematically examined the interaction

between domestic and international institutions. Our findings that domestic institutions

condition the effect of international institutions suggests that this interaction is a fruitful avenue

for future research.

Second, recent research has suggested that governments can use international institutions

to boost the credibility of commitments that they make to each other. Our finding that

governments of developing countries can increase inward FDI by committing themselves to

economically liberal policies through PTAs suggests that governments also can use international

30

institutions to boost the credibility of their commitments vis-à-vis private actors in the

international political economy.

Third and finally, our findings have important policy implication for those who seek to

improve the investment climate and thus increase investment and economic growth in

developing countries. As North and others have emphasized, institutions can be constructed to

help leaders attract investment and thereby increase economic growth. We show not only that

international trade institutions can perform this role, but also that their effect may be increased

by having more democratic political institutions at home.

31

References Aldrich, John H., John L. Sullivan, and Eugene Borgida. 1989. "Foreign Affairs and Issue Voting: Do Presidential

Candidates 'Waltz Before a Blind Audience?'." American Political Science Review vol.83 no.1 (March 1989): 123-141.

Alvarez, R. Michael, et al. 1996. "Classifying Political Regimes." Studies in Comparative International Development vol.31 no.2 (Summer 1996): 3-36.

Arellano, M. 1987. "Computing Robust Standard Errors for Within-groups Estimators." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics vol.49 no.4 (November 1987): 431-434.

Banks, Arthur S. 1999. Cross-National Time-Series Data Archive. Binghampton, NY: Banner Software. Blonigen, Bruce A., and Miao Wang. 2005. "Inappropriate Pooling of Wealthy and Poor Countries in Empirical

FDI Studies." In Does Foreign Direct Investment Promote Development?, edited by Theodore H. Moran, Edward M. Graham and Magnus Blomström. Washington: Institute for International Economics, 2005: 221-244.

Bornschier, Volker, and Christopher Chase-Dunn. 1985. Transnational Corporations and Underdevelopment. New York: Praeger.

Büthe, Tim, and Helen V. Milner. 2008. "The Politics of Foreign Direct Investment into Developing Countries: Increasing FDI through International Trade Agreements?" American Journal of Political Science vol.52 no.4 (October 2008): 741-762.

——— and ———. 2009. "Bilateral Investment Treaties and Foreign Direct Investment: A Political Analysis." In The Effect of Treaties on Foreign Direct Investment: Bilateral Investment Treaties, Double Taxation Treaties, and Investment Flows, edited by Karl P. Sauvant and Lisa E. Sachs. New York: Oxford University Press, 2009: 171-225.

Cheibub, José Antonio. 2007. Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, and Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Davidson, Russell, and James G. MacKinnon. 1993. Estimation and Inference in Econometrics. New York: Oxford University Press.

Diamond, Larry. 2002. "Thinking about Hybrid Regimes." Journal of Democracy vol.13 no.2 (April 2002): 21-35. Elkins, Zachary. 2000. "Gradations of Democracy? Empirical Tests of Alternative Conceptualizations." American

Journal of Political Science vol.44 no.2 (April 2000): 293-300. Evans, Peter B., Harold K. Jacobson, and Robert D. Putnam, eds. 1993. Double-Edged Diplomacy: International

Bargaining and Domestic Politics. Berkeley: University of California Press. Fearon, James D. 1994. "Domestic Political Audiences and the Escalation of International Disputes." American

Political Science Review vol.88 no.3 (September 1994): 577-592. Feng, Yi. 2001. "Political Freedom, Political Instability, and Policy Uncertainty." International Studies Quarterly

vol.45 no.2 (June 2001): 271-294. Globerman, Steven, and Daniel Shapiro. 2003. "Governance Infrastructure and U.S. Foreign Direct Investment."

Journal of International Business Studies vol.34 no.1 (January 2003): 19-39. Henisz, Witold J. 2002. "The Institutional Environment for Infrastructure Investment." Industrial and Corporate

Change vol.11 no.2 (April 2002): 355-389. Hsiao, Cheng. 2003. Analysis of Panel Data. 2nd edition ed. New York: Cambridge University Press. Jensen, Nathan M. 2003. "Democratic Governance and Multinational Corporations: Political Regimes and Inflows

of Foreign Direct Investment." International Organization vol.57 no.3 (Summer 2003): 587-616. ———. 2006. Nation States and the Multinational Corporation: A Political Economy of Foreign Direct

Investment. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

32

Kahler, Miles. 1981. "Political Regime and Economic Actors: The Response of Firms to the End of Colonial Rule." World Politics vol.33 no.3 (April 1981): 383-412.

Kézdi, Gábor. 2004. "Robust Standard Error Estimation in Fixed-Effects Panel Models." Hungarian Statistical Review vol.9 (Special English Volume #9): 95-116.

Kobrin, Stephen J. 1982. Managing Political Risk Assessment: Strategic Response to Environmental Change. Berkeley: University of California Press.

———. 1984. "Expropriation as an Attempt to Control Foreign Firms in LDCs: Trends from 1960 to 1979." International Studies Quarterly vol.28 no.3 (September 1984): 329-348.

Lake, David A. 1992. "Powerful Pacifists: Democratic States and War." American Political Science Review vol.86 no.1 (March 1992): 24-37.

Leeds, Brett Ashley. 1999. "Domestic Political Institutions, Credible Commitments, and International Cooperation." American Journal of Political Science vol.43 no.4 (October 1999): 979-1002.

Levitsky, Steven, and Jucan Way. 2002. "The Rise of Competitive Authoritarianism." Journal of Democracy vol.13 no.2 (April 2002): 51-65.

Li, Quan, and Adam Resnick. 2003. "Reversal of Fortunes: Democratic Institutions and Foreign Direct Investment Inflows to Developing Countries." International Organization vol.57 no.1 (Winter 2003): 175-211.

Mansfield, Edward D., Helen V. Milner, and B. Peter Rosendorff. 2002. "Why Democracies Cooperate More: Electoral Control and International Trade Agreements." International Organization vol.56 no.3 (Summer 2002): 477-514.

Martin, Lisa. 2000. Democratic Commitments: Legislatures and International Cooperation. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Mattli, Walter, and Tim Büthe. 2003. "Setting International Standards: Technological Rationality or Primacy of Power?" World Politics vol.56 no.1 (October 2003): 1-42.

Mayer, Frederick W. 1991. "Domestic Politics and the Strategy of International Trade." Journal of Policy Analysis and Management vol.10 (Spring 1991): 222-246.

Milner, Helen V. 1997. Interests, Institutions, and Information: Domestic Politics and International Relations. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Moran, Theodore H. 1978. "Multinational Corporations and Dependency: A Dialogue for Dependistas and Non-Dependistas." International Organization vol.32 no.1 (Winter 1978).

———. 1998. Foreign Direct Investment and Development: The New Policy Agenda for Developing Countries and Countries in Transition. Washington: Institute for International Economics.

Munck, Gerardo L., and Jay Verkuilen. 2002. "Conceptualizing and Measuring Democracy." Comparative Political Studies vol.35 no.1 (February 2002): 5-34.

Neumayer, Eric, and Laura Spess. 2005. "Do Bilateral Investment Treaties Increase Foreign Direct Investment to Developing Countries?" World Development vol.33 no.10 (October 2005): 1567-1585.

North, Douglass C., and Barry R. Weingast. 1989. "Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England." Journal of Economic History vol.49 no.4 (December 1989): 803-832.

O'Donnell, Guillermo A. 1979 (1973). Modernization and Bureaucratic Authoritarianism: Studies in South American Politics. 2nd edition with a postscript by the author ed. Berkeley, CA: Institute of International Studies.

Oneal, John R. 1994. "The Affinity of Foreign Investors for Authoritarian Regimes." Political Research Quarterly vol.47 no.3 (September 1994): 565-588.

Przeworski, Adam, et al. 2000. Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Material Well-Being in the World, 1950-1990. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Putnam, Robert D. 1988. "Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two-Level Games." International Organization vol.42 no.3 (Summer 1988): 427-460.

33

Schultz, Kenneth A. 2001. "Looking for Audience Costs." Journal of Conflict Resolution vol.45 no.1 (February 2001): 32-60.

Simmons, Beth A. 2000a. "International Law and State Behavior: Commitment and Compliance in International Monetary Affairs." American Political Science Review vol.94 no.4 (December 2000): 819-835.

———. 2000b. "The Legalization of International Monetary Affairs." International Organization vol.54 no.3 (Summer 2000): 573-602.

Slantchev, Branislav L. 2006. "Politicians, the Media, and Domestic Audience Costs." International Studies Quarterly vol.50 no.2 (June 2006): 445-477.

Snidal, Duncan, and Alexander Thompson. 2003. "International Commitments and Domestic Politics: Institutions and Actors at Two Levels." In Locating the Proper Authorities: The Interaction of Domestic and International Institutions, edited by Daniel W. Drezner. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 2003: 197-230.

Tomz, Michael. 2007. "Domestic Audience Costs in International Relations: An Experimental Approach." International Organization vol.61 no.4 (Fall 2007): 821-840.

Tures, John A. 2003. "The Impact of Instability and Institutions on US Foreign Direct Investment in Developing Areas." Conflict, Security and Development vol.3 no.2 (August 2003): 163-183.

UNCTAD, United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. 2000. Bilateral Investment Treaties, 1959-1999. New York—Geneva: United Nations.

———. 2003. World Investment Report 2003: FDI Policies for Development. New York—Geneva: United Nations.

Vernon, Raymond. 1971. Sovereignty at Bay: The Multinational Spread of U.S. Enterprises. New York: Basic Books.

Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.


Recommended