+ All Categories
Home > Documents > The Monetary Policy and Aggregate Demand Curves · PDF fileLEARNING OBJECTIVES After studying...

The Monetary Policy and Aggregate Demand Curves · PDF fileLEARNING OBJECTIVES After studying...

Date post: 20-Mar-2018
Category:
Upload: lamdung
View: 214 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
13
1 In response to the subprime financial crisis in the United States, the Bank of Canada lowered the target overnight interest rate from 4.5% in August 2007 to 0.25% in April 2009. Moreover, for over a year (from April 1, 2009 to June 1, 2010), the Bank of Canada also lowered the operating band for the overnight interest rate from 50 basis points to 25 basis points and instead of targeting the overnight interest rate at the midpoint of the operating band (as it does during normal times), it targeted the overnight rate at the bottom of the operating band, at 0.25%, thus setting an effect- ive lower bound for the overnight interest rate. To see how a monetary policy action like the one above affects the economy, we need to analyze how monetary policy affects aggregate demand. We start this chapter by explaining why monetary policymakers set interest rates to rise when inflation increases, leading to a positive relationship between real interest rates and inflation, which is called the monetary policy (MP) curve. Then, using the MP curve with the IS curve we developed in the previous chapter, we derive the aggregate demand curve, a key element in the aggregate demand/aggregate supply model framework used in the rest of this text to discuss short-run economic fluctuations. The Bank of Canada and Monetary Policy Central banks throughout the world use a very short-term interest rate as their pri- mary policy tool. In Canada, the Bank of Canada conducts monetary policy via its setting of the overnight interest rate. As we have seen in Chapter 17, the Bank of Canada controls the overnight rate by varying the settlement balances (reserves) it provides to the banking system. When it provides more reserves, banks have more money to lend to each other, and LEARNING OBJECTIVES After studying this chapter you should be able to 1. understand why there is a positive relationship between real interest rates and inflation, the MP curve 2. illustrate how the IS curve and the MP curve can be used to derive the aggregate demand curve featured in the aggregate demand and supply framework in the next chapter. The Monetary Policy and Aggregate Demand Curves CHAPTER 23 PREVIEW
Transcript

1

In response to the subprime financial crisis in the United States, the Bank of Canada lowered the target overnight interest rate from 4.5% in August 2007 to 0.25% in April 2009. Moreover, for over a year (from April 1, 2009 to June 1, 2010), the Bank of Canada also lowered the operating band for the overnight interest rate from 50 basis points to 25 basis points and instead of targeting the overnight interest rate at the midpoint of the operating band (as it does during normal times), it targeted the overnight rate at the bottom of the operating band, at 0.25%, thus setting an effect-ive lower bound for the overnight interest rate.

To see how a monetary policy action like the one above affects the economy, we need to analyze how monetary policy affects aggregate demand. We start this chapter by explaining why monetary policymakers set interest rates to rise when inflation increases, leading to a positive relationship between real interest rates and inflation, which is called the monetary policy (MP) curve . Then, using the MP curve with the IS curve we developed in the previous chapter, we derive the aggregate demand curve,a key element in the aggregate demand/aggregate supply model framework used in the rest of this text to discuss short-run economic fluctuations.

The Bank of Canada and Monetary Policy

Central banks throughout the world use a very short-term interest rate as their pri-mary policy tool. In Canada, the Bank of Canada conducts monetary policy via its setting of the overnight interest rate.

As we have seen in Chapter 17 , the Bank of Canada controls the overnight rate by varying the settlement balances (reserves) it provides to the banking system. When it provides more reserves, banks have more money to lend to each other, and

LEARNING OBJECTIVES

After studying this chapter you should be able to

1. understand why there is a positive relationship between real

interest rates and inflation, the MP curve

2. illustrate how the IS curve and the MP curve can be used to derive

the aggregate demand curve featured in the aggregate demand

and supply framework in the next chapter.

The Monetary Policy and

Aggregate Demand Curves

C H A P T E R 2 3

PREVIEW

M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 1M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 1 10/15/12 7:32 PM10/15/12 7:32 PM

2 P A R T V I Monetary Theory

this excess liquidity causes the overnight rate to fall. When the Bank drains reserves from the banking system, banks have less to lend and the shortage of liquidity leads to a rise in the overnight rate.

The overnight interest is a nominal interest rate, but as we learned in the previ-ous chapter it is the real interest rate that affects net exports and business spending, thereby determining the level of equilibrium output. How does the Bank of Canada’s control of the overnight rate enable it to control the real interest rate, through which monetary policy impacts the economy?

Recall from Chapter 4 that the real interest rate, r , is the nominal interest rate, i , minus expected inflation, pe

r = i - pe (1)

Changes in nominal interest rates can change the real interest rate only if actual and expected inflation remain unchanged in the short run. Because prices typically are slow to move—that is, they are sticky —changes in monetary policy will not have an immediate effect on inflation and expected inflation. As a result, when the Bank

of Canada lowers the overnight interest rate, real interest rates fall; and when the

Bank of Canada raises the overnight rate, real interest rates rise.

The Monetary Policy Curve

We have now seen how the Bank of Canada can control real interest rates in the short run. The next step in our analysis is to examine how monetary policy reacts to inflation. The monetary policy ( MP ) curve indicates the relationship between the real interest rate the central bank sets and the inflation rate. We can write this curve as follows:

r = r + lp

where r is the autonomous component of the real interest rate set by the monetary policy authorities, which is unrelated to the current level of the inflation rate, while l is the responsiveness of the real interest rate to the inflation rate.

To make our discussion of the monetary policy curve more concrete, Figure 23-1 shows an example of a monetary policy curve MP in which r = 1.0 and l = 0.5 :

r = 1.0 + 0.5p (2)

At point A, where inflation is 1%, the Bank of Canada sets the real interest rate at 1.5%, while at point B, where inflation is 2%, the Bank sets the real interest rate at 2%, and at point C, where inflation is 3%, the Bank of Canada sets the real interest rate at 2.5%. The line going through points A, B, and C is the monetary policy curve MP , and it is upward-sloping, indicating that monetary policymakers raise real interest rates when the inflation rate rises.

To see why the MP curve has an upward slope, we need to recognize that central banks seek to keep inflation stable. To stabilize inflation, monetary policymakers follow the Taylor principle , named after John Taylor of Stanford University, in which they raise nominal rates by more than any rise in expected inflation so that real interest rates rise when there is a rise in inflation, as the MP curve suggests. 1 John Taylor and many other researchers have found that monetary policymakers tend to follow the Taylor principle in practice.

The Taylor Principle: Why the Monetary Policy Curve Has an Upward Slope

1 Note that the Taylor principle differs from the Taylor rule , described in Chapter 18 , because it does not provide a rule for how monetary policy should react to conditions in the economy, while the Taylor rule does.

M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 2M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 2 10/15/12 7:32 PM10/15/12 7:32 PM

C H A P T E R 2 3 The Monetary Policy and Aggregate Demand Curves 3

To see why monetary policymakers follow the Taylor principle, in which higher inflation results in higher real interest rates, consider what would happen if monet-ary policymakers instead allowed the real interest rate to fall when inflation rose. In this case, an increase in inflation would lead to a decline in the real interest rate, which would increase aggregate output, in turn causing inflation to rise further, which would then cause the real interest rate to fall even more, increasing aggregate output. Schematically, we can write this as follows:

pc 1 r T 1 Y c 1 pc 1 r T 1 Y c 1 pc

As a result, inflation would continually keep rising and spin out of control. Indeed, this is exactly what happened in the 1970s, when the Bank of Canada did not raise nominal interest rates by as much as inflation rose, so that real interest rates fell. Inflation accelerated to over 10%. 2

In common parlance, the Bank of Canada is said to tighten monetary policy when it raises real interest rates, and to ease it when it lowers real interest rates. It is important, however, to distinguish between changes in monetary policy that shift the monetary policy curve, which we call autonomous changes, and the Taylor principle–driven changes which are reflected as movements along the monetary policy curve, which are called automatic adjustments to interest rates.

Central banks may make autonomous changes to monetary policy for various reasons. They may wish to change the inflation rate from its current value. For

FIGURE 23-1 The Monetary Policy Curve

The upward slope of the MP curve indicates that the central bank raises real interest rates when inflation rises because monetary policy follows the Taylor principle.

Inflation Rate, p (%)

Real

Interest

Rate, r(%)

1.5%

2%

2.0%1.0%

A

B

C2.5%

3.0%

MP

Shifts in the MP Curve

2 In a web appendix to Chapter 24 we formally demonstrate the instability of inflation when central banks do not follow the Taylor principle.

M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 3M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 3 10/15/12 7:32 PM10/15/12 7:32 PM

4 P A R T V I Monetary Theory

example, to lower inflation they could increase r by one percentage point, and so raise the real interest rate at any given inflation rate, what we will refer to as an autonomous tightening of monetary policy . This autonomous monetary tightening would shift the monetary policy curve upward by one percentage point from MP 1 to MP 2 in Figure 23-2 , thereby causing the economy to contract and inflation to fall. Or, the banks may have information above and beyond what is happening to infla-tion that suggests interest rates must be adjusted to achieve good economic out-comes. For example, if the economy is going into a recession, monetary policymakers would want to lower real interest rates at any given inflation rate, an autonomous easing of monetary policy , in order to stimulate the economy and also to prevent inflation from falling. This autonomous easing of monetary policy would result in a downward shift in the monetary policy curve, say, by one percentage point from MP 1 to MP 3 in Figure 23-2 .

We contrast these autonomous changes with automatic, Taylor principle–driven changes, a central bank’s normal response (also known as an endogenous response) of raising real interest rates when inflation rises. These changes to interest rates do not shift the monetary policy curve, and so cannot be considered autonomous tightening or easing of monetary policy. Instead, they are reflected in movements along the monetary policy curve.

The distinction between autonomous monetary policy changes and move-ments along the monetary policy curve is illustrated by the monetary policy actions the Bank of Canada took at the onset of the 2007–2009 financial crisis in the fall of 2007.

FIGURE 23-2 Shifts in the Monetary Policy Curve

Autonomous changes in monetary policy, such as when a central bank changes the real interest rate at any given inflation rate, shift the MP curve. An autonomous tightening of monetary policy that increases the real interest rate shifts the MP curve up to MP 2 , whereas an autonomous easing of monetary policy that lowers the real interest rate shifts the MP curve down to MP 3 .

Inflation Rate, p (%)

Real

Interest

Rate, r(%)

1.5%

1.5%

2.0%

2.5%

2.0%1.0% 2.5%

A

B

C

Autonomous monetary policy

tightening shifts the MP curve up.

Autonomous monetary

policy easing shifts the

MP curve down.

1.0%

0.5%

3.0%

3.5%

0.5% 4.0%3.0%

MP3

MP2

3.5%

MP1

M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 4M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 4 10/15/12 7:32 PM10/15/12 7:32 PM

C H A P T E R 2 3 The Monetary Policy and Aggregate Demand Curves 5

When the financial crisis started in August 2007, inflation was rising and economic growth was quite strong. Yet the Bank of Canada began an aggressive easing, lower-ing the overnight interest rate as shown in Figure 23-3 . What does this tell us about effects on the monetary policy curve?

A movement along the MP curve would have suggested that the Bank of Canada would continue to keep hiking interest rates because inflation was rising, but instead it did the opposite. The Bank thus shifted the monetary policy curve down from MP 1 to MP 3 , as in Figure 23-2 . The Bank pursued this autonomous monetary policy easing because the negative shock to the economy from the disruption to financial markets (discussed in Chapter 9 ) indicated that, despite current high inflation rates, the economy was likely to weaken in the near future and the inflation rate would fall. Indeed, this is exactly what came to pass, with the economy going into recession in December 2007 and the inflation rate falling sharply after August 2008.

APPLICATION

Autonomous Monetary Easing at the Onset

of the 2007–2009 Financial Crisis

The Aggregate Demand Curve

We are now ready to derive the relationship between the inflation rate and aggregate output when the goods market is in equilibrium, the aggregate demand curve . The MP curve we developed demonstrates how central banks respond to changes in infla-tion with changes in interest rates, in line with the Taylor principle. The IS curve we developed in Chapter 22 showed that changes in real interest rates, in turn, affect equilibrium output. With these two curves, we can now link the quantity of aggregate

FIGURE 23-3 The Inflation Rate and the Overnight Interest Rate, 2007–2011

The Bank of Canada began an aggressive autonomous easing of monetary policy in September 2007, bringing down its policy rate, the target overnight interest rate, despite the continuing high inflation.

Overnight interest rate

2007

The Inflatio

n R

ate

and

the

Overn

ight

Inte

rest

Rate

(%

annual ra

te)

–2%

–1%

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

2008

Year

2009 2010 2011

Inflation rate

M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 5M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 5 10/15/12 7:32 PM10/15/12 7:32 PM

6 P A R T V I Monetary Theory

output demanded with the inflation rate, given the public’s expectations of infla-tion and the stance of monetary policy. The aggregate demand curve is central to the aggregate demand and supply analysis we develop further in the next chapter, which allows us to explain short-run fluctuations in both aggregate output and inflation.

Using the hypothetical MP curve from Equation 2 , we know that when the inflation rate rises from 1% to 2% to 3%, real interest rates rise from 1.5% to 2% to 2.5%. We plot these points in panel (a) of Figure 23-4 to create the MP curve. In panel ( b), we graph the IS curve described in Equation 13 of Chapter 22 ( Y = 12 - r ). As the real inter-est rate rises from 1.5% to 2% to 2.5%, the equilibrium moves from point 1 to point 2 to point 3 and aggregate output falls from $10.5 trillion to $10 trillion to $9.5 trillion. In other words, as real interest rates rise, investment and net exports decline, leading to a reduction in aggregate demand. Panels (a) and (b) demonstrate that as inflation rises from 1% to 2% to 3%, the equilibrium moves from point 1 to point 2 to point 3 in panel (c), and aggregate output falls from $10.5 trillion to $10 trillion to $9.5 trillion.

The line that connects the three points in panel (c) is the aggregate demand curve, AD, and it indicates the level of aggregate output corresponding to each of the three real interest rates consistent with equilibrium in the goods market for any given infla-tion rate. The aggregate demand curve has a downward slope, because a higher inflation rate leads the central bank to raise real interest rates, thereby lowering planned spend-ing, and hence lowering the level of equilibrium aggregate output.

By using some algebra (see the FYI box, “Deriving the Aggregate Demand Curve Algebraically” ), the AD curve in Figure 23-4 can be written numerically as follows:

Y = 11 - 0.5p (3)

Movements along the aggregate demand curve describe how the equilibrium level of aggregate output changes when the inflation rate changes. When factors besides the inflation rate change, however, the aggregate demand curve can shift. We first review the factors that shift the IS curve, and then consider other factors that shift the AD curve.

Step 1. The MP curve links the

inflation rate to the real interest rate

level set by the central bank.

Inflation Rate, p (%)

Real

Interest

Rate, r(%)

3.0%

(a) MP Curve

2.0%1.0%

1.5%

2.5%

2.0%

1

2

3

MP

FIGURE 23-4 Deriving the AD Curve

The MP curve in panel (a) shows that as inflation rises from 1.5% to 2% to 3.0%, the real interest rate rises from 1.5% to 2.0% to 2.5%. The IS curve in panel ( b) then shows that higher real interest rates lead to lower planned investment spending, and hence aggregate output falls from $10.5 trillion to $10 trillion to $9.5 trillion. Finally, panel (c) plots the level of equilibrium output corresponding to each of the three inflation rates: the line that connects these points is the AD curve, and it is downward sloping.

Deriving the Aggregate Demand Curve Graphically

Factors That Shift the Aggregate Demand Curve

M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 6M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 6 10/15/12 7:32 PM10/15/12 7:32 PM

C H A P T E R 2 3 The Monetary Policy and Aggregate Demand Curves 7

(b) IS Curve

Aggregate Output, Y ($ trillions)

Real

Interest

Rate, r(%)

10.510.09.5

1.5%

2.5%

2.0%

IS

3

2

1

(c) Aggregate Demand Curve

Aggregate Output, Y ($ trillions)

Inflation

Rate, p

(%)

10.510.09.5

1.0%

3.0%

2.0%

AD

3

2

1

Step 2. The IS curve links the

real interest rate level from the

MP curve to equilibrium output.

Step 3. The AD curve

links the inflation rate

from the MP curve to

equilibrium output.

SHIFTS IN THE IS CURVE We saw in the previous chapter that six factors cause the IS curve to shift. It turns out that the same factors cause the aggregate demand curve to shift as well:

1. Autonomous consumption expenditure

2. Autonomous investment spending

3. Government purchases

4. Taxes

5. Autonomous net exports

6. Financial frictions

We examine how changes in these factors lead to a shift in the aggregate demand curve in Figure 23-5 .

Figure 23-5 shows that any factor that shifts the IS curve shifts the aggregate

demand curve in the same direction . Therefore, “animal spirits” that encourage a rise in autonomous consumption expenditure or planned investment spending, a rise in government purchases, an autonomous rise in net exports, a fall in taxes, or a decline in financial frictions—all of which shift the IS curve to the right—will also shift the aggregate demand curve to the right. Conversely, a fall in autonomous con-sumption expenditure, a fall in planned investment spending, a fall in government

M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 7M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 7 10/15/12 7:32 PM10/15/12 7:32 PM

8 P A R T V I Monetary Theory

FIGURE 23-5 Shift in the AD Curve from Shifts in the IS Curve

At a 2% inflation rate in panel (a), the monetary policy curve indicates that the real interest rate is 2%. An increase in government purchases shifts the IS curve to the right in panel ( b). At a given inflation rate and real interest rate of 2.0%, equilibrium output rises from $10 trillion to $12.5 trillion, which is shown as a movement from point A 1 to point A 2 in panel (c), shifting the aggregate demand curve to the right from AD 1 to AD 2 . Any factor that shifts the IS curve shifts the AD curve in the same direction.

Step 1. The MP curve links the

inflation rate to the real interest rate

level set by the central bank.

Inflation Rate, p (%)

Real

Interest

Rate, r(%)

(a) MP Curve

2.0%

2.0%A

MP

(b) IS Curve

Aggregate Output, Y ($ trillions)

Real

Interest

Rate, r(%)

12.510.0

IS2

IS1

A2

A1

(c) Aggregate Demand Curve

Aggregate Output, Y ($ trillions)

Inflation

Rate, p

(%)

10.0 12.5

AD2

2.0%

AD1

A2

A1

Step 2. A rise in government purchases

increases equilibrium output, shifting

the IS curve rightward . . .

Step 3. and shifting the

AD curve rightward.

2.0%

M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 8M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 8 10/15/12 7:32 PM10/15/12 7:32 PM

C H A P T E R 2 3 The Monetary Policy and Aggregate Demand Curves 9

purchases, a fall in net exports, a rise in taxes, or a rise in financial frictions will cause the aggregate demand curve to shift to the left.

SHIFTS IN THE MP CURVE We now examine what happens to the aggregate demand curve when the MP curve shifts. Suppose that the Bank of Canada decides to autonomously tighten monetary policy by raising the real interest rate by one per-centage point at any given level of the inflation rate because it is worried about the economy overheating. At an inflation rate of 2.0%, the real interest rate rises from 2.0% to 3.0% in Figure 23-6 . The MP curve shifts up from MP 1 to MP 2 in panel (a).

To derive the numerical AD curve, we start by tak-ing the numerical IS curve, Equation 13 , from the previous chapter,

Y = 12 - r

and then substitute in for r from the numerical MP curve in Equation 2 , r = 1.0 + 0.5p , to yield

Y = 12 - (1.0 + 0.5p) = (12 - 1) - 0.5p = 11 - 0.5p

as in the text. Similarly, we can derive a more general version

of the AD curve, using the algebraic version of the IS curve from Equation 12 in Chapter 22 :

Y = [C + I - d f + G + N X - mpc * T ]

*1

1 - mpc-

d + x

1 - mpc* r

and then substitute for r from the algebraic MP curve in Equation 1 , r = r + lp , to yield the more general AD curve:

Y = [C + I - d f + G + N X - mpc * T ]

*1

1 - mpc-

d + x

1 - mpc* ( r + lp) (4)

FYI

Deriving the Aggregate Demand Curve Algebraically

FIGURE 23-6 Shifts in the AD Curve from Autonomous Monetary Policy Tightening

Autonomous monetary tightening that raises real interest rates by one percentage point at any given infla-tion rate shifts the MP curve up from MP 1 to MP 2 in panel (a). With the inflation rate at 2.0%, the higher 3% interest rate results in a movement from point A 1 to A 2 on the IS curve, with output falling from $10 trillion to $9 trillion. This change in equilibrium output leads to movement from point A 1 to point A 2 in panel (c), shifting the aggregate demand curve to the left from AD 1 to AD 2 .

Step 1. Autonomous monetary policy

tightening increases the real interest rate . . .

Inflation Rate, p (%)

Real

Interest

Rate, r(%)

(a) MP

2.0%

2.0%A

1

A2

MP1

MP2

3.0%

(Continued )

M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 9M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 9 10/15/12 7:32 PM10/15/12 7:32 PM

10 P A R T V I Monetary Theory

(b) IS

Aggregate Output, Y ($ trillions)

Real

Interest

Rate, r(%)

10.09.0

IS

A2

A1

(c) Aggregate Demand

Aggregate Output, Y ($ trillions)

Inflation

Rate, p

(%)

10.09.0

2.0%

AD1

AD2

A2

A1

Step 2. causing movement

along the IS curve, decreasing

equilibrium output . . .

Step 3. and shifting

the AD curve leftward.

2.0%

3.0%

FIGURE 23-6 (Continued )

As policy rates around the world have reached the zero lower bound in recent years, central banks are in a liquidity trap , unable to lower them fur-ther. Moreover, central banks have lost their usual ability to signal policy changes via changes in the policy rate and to lower long-term interest rates by lowering short-term interest rates.

With the policy rate at the zero lower bound, a decoupling of long- and short-term interest rates, and the possibility of a deflationary trap (that is, extremely low nominal interest rates and sustained deflation), central banks have departed from the

traditional interest-rate targeting approach to monetary policy and are now considering new tools to steer their economies. As we discussed in Chapter 17 , the Bank of Canada has identified three alternative instruments that it would con-sider using in an environment with low short-term (nominal) interest rates: forward guidance, quan-titative easing, and credit easing. That is, central banks are switching from the “one tool, one tar-get” mode of operation and are searching for new tools to steer their economies in an environment with interest rates at or near zero.

FYI

The Zero Lower Bound and Nonconventional Monetary Policy

M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 10M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 10 10/15/12 7:33 PM10/15/12 7:33 PM

C H A P T E R 2 3 The Monetary Policy and Aggregate Demand Curves 11

Panel (b) shows that when the inflation rate is at 2.0%, the higher interest rate results in the equilibrium moving from point A 1 to A 2 on the IS curve, with output falling from $10 trillion to $9 trillion. The lower output of $9 trillion occurs because the higher real interest leads to a decline in investment and net exports, which lowers aggregate demand. The lower output of $9 trillion then decreases the equilibrium output level from point A 1 to point A 2 in panel (c), and so the AD curve shifts to the left from AD 1 to AD 2 .

Our conclusion from Figure 23-6 is that an autonomous tightening of monetary

policy—that is, a rise in the real interest rate at any given inflation rate—shifts the

aggregate demand curve to the left. Similarly, an autonomous easing of monetary

policy shifts the aggregate demand curve to the right . We have now derived and analyzed the aggregate demand curve—an essential

element in the aggregate demand and supply framework that we examine in the next chapter. We will use the aggregate demand curve in this framework to determine both aggregate output and inflation, as well as to examine events that cause these variables to change.

MyEconLab is an online homework and tutorial system that puts you in control of your own learning with study and practice tools directly correlated to this chapter’s content. Visit MyEconLab to explore the following resources:

• All of the Applied Problems marked in green are available in the Study Plan on MyEconLab for further practice. You will also find the answers to the questions marked with an asterisk in the Student Resources section of your MyEconLab.

MyEconLab also features Additional Readings, videos, Glossary Flashcards, Audio Chapter Summaries, Economics News Feeds, Animations, and many additional tools to help you master key concepts from the text.

MyEconLab

1. When the Bank of Canada lowers the overnight interest rate by providing more liquidity to the banking system, real interest rates fall in the short run; and when the Bank of Canada raises the overnight rate by reducing the liquidity in the banking system, real interest rates rise in the short run.

2. The monetary policy ( MP ) curve shows the relationship between inflation and the real interest rate arising from monetary authorities’ actions. Monetary policy follows the Taylor principle, in which higher inflation results in higher real interest rates, as represented by a movement up along the monetary policy curve. An autonomous tightening of monetary policy occurs when monetary policymakers raise the real interest rate at any given inflation rate, resulting in an upward shift in the monetary policy curve. An autonomous easing of monetary policy and a downward shift in the monetary policy curve occurs when monetary

policymakers lower the real interest rate at any given infla-tion rate.

3. The aggregate demand curve tells us the level of equilib-rium aggregate output (which equals the total quantity of output demanded) for any given inflation rate. It slopes downward because a higher inflation rate leads the central bank to raise real interest rates, which leads to a lower level of equilibrium output. The aggregate demand curve shifts in the same direction as a shift in the IS curve; hence it shifts to the right when government purchases increase, taxes decrease, “animal spirits” encourage consumer and business spending, autonomous net exports increase, or financial frictions decrease. An autonomous tightening of monetary policy—that is, an increase in real interest rates at any given inflation rate—leads to a decline in aggregate demand and the aggregate demand curve shifts to the left.

S U M M A R Y

K E Y T E R M S

aggregate demand curve, p. xx

autonomous easing of monetary policy, p. xx

autonomous tightening of monetary policy, p. xx

liquidity trap, p. xx

monetary policy ( MP ) curve, p. xx

Taylor principle, p. xx

M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 11M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 11 10/15/12 7:33 PM10/15/12 7:33 PM

12 P A R T V I Monetary Theory

Q U E S T I O N S

1. When the inflation rate increases, what happens to the overnight interest rate? Operationally, how does the Bank of Canada adjust the overnight interest rate?

2. What is the key assumption underlying the Bank of Canada's ability to control the real interest rate?

3. Why is it necessary for the MP curve to have an upward slope?

4. If l = 0 , what does that imply about the relationship between the nominal interest rate and the inflation rate?

5. How does an autonomous tightening or easing of mon-etary policy by the Bank of Canada affect the MP curve?

6. How is an autonomous tightening or easing of monetary policy different from a change in the real interest rate due to a change in the current inflation rate?

7. Suppose that a new Bank of Canada governor is ap-pointed, and his or her approach to monetary policy can be summarized by the following statement: “I care only about increasing employment; inflation has been at very low levels for quite some time; my priority is to ease mon-etary policy to promote employment.” How would you expect the monetary policy curve to be affected, if at all?

8. “The Bank of Canada decreased the overnight interest rate in late 2007, even though inflation was increasing. This demonstrates a violation of the Taylor principle.” Is this statement true, false, or uncertain? Explain your answer.

9. What factors affect the slope of the aggregate demand curve?

10. “Autonomous monetary policy is more effective at changing output when l is higher” Is this statement true, false, or uncertain? Explain your answer.

11. If net exports were not sensitive to changes in the real interest rate, would monetary policy be more—or less—effective in changing output?

12. How does an autonomous tightening or easing of mon-etary policy by the Bank of Canada affect the aggregate demand curve?

13. For each of the following, describe how (if at all), the IS curve, MP curve, and AD curves are affected.

a. A decrease in financial frictions. b. An increase in taxes, and an autonomous easing of

monetary policy. c. An increase in the current inflation rate. d. A decrease in autonomous consumption. e. Firms become more optimistic about the future of

the economy. f. The new Bank of Canada governor begins to care

more about fighting inflation.

14. What would be the effect of an increase in Canadian net exports on the aggregate demand curve? Would an increase in net exports affect the monetary policy curve? Explain why or why not.

15. Why does the aggregate demand curve shift when “ani-mal spirits” change?

16. If government spending increases while taxes are raised to keep the budget balanced, what happens to the aggre-gate demand curve?

17. Suppose that government spending is increased at the same time that an autonomous monetary policy tightening occurs. What will happen to the position of the aggregate demand curve?

18. “If f increases, then the Bank of Canada can keep out-put constant by reducing the real interest rate by the same amount as the increase in financial frictions.” Is this statement true, false, or uncertain? Explain your answer.

A P P L I E D P R O B L E M S

19. Assume the monetary policy curve is given by r =1.5 + 0.75p .

a. Calculate the real interest rate when the inflation rate is 2%, 3%, and 4%.

b. Draw the graph of the MP curve, labeling the points from part (a).

c. Assume now that the monetary policy curve is r = 2.5 + 0.75p . Does the new monetary policy curve represent an autonomous tightening or loos-ening of monetary policy?

d. Calculate the real interest rate when the inflation rate is 2%, 3%, and 4%, and draw the new MP curve showing the shift from part (b).

20. Use an IS curve and an MP curve to derive graphically the  AD curve.

21. Suppose the monetary policy curve is given by r =1.5 + 0.75p , and the IS curve is Y = 13 - r .

a. Calculate an expression for the aggregate demand curve.

b. Calculate the real interest rate and aggregate output when the inflation rate is 2%, 3%, and 4%.

c. Draw graphs of the IS, MP, and AD curves, label-ling the points in the appropriate graphs from part (b) above.

M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 12M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 12 10/15/12 7:33 PM10/15/12 7:33 PM

C H A P T E R 2 3 The Monetary Policy and Aggregate Demand Curves 13

22. Consider an economy described by the following:

C = 4 trillion I = 1.5 trillion G = 3.0 trillion T = 3.0 trillion NX = 1.0 trillion f = 0 mpc = 0.8 d = 0.35 x = 0.15 l = 0.5 r = 2

a. Derive expressions for the MP curve and AD curve. b. Calculate the real interest rate and aggregate output

when p = 2 and p = 4 . c. Draw a graph of the MP curve and AD curve, indi-

cating the points in part (b) above.

23. Consider an economy described by the following:

C = 3.25 trillion I = 1.3 trillion G = 3.5 trillion T = 3.0 trillion NX = -1.0 trillion f = 1 mpc = 0.75 d = 0.3 x = 0.1 l = 1 r = 1

a. Derive expressions for the MP curve and AD curve. b. Assume that p = 1 . What is the real interest rate,

equilibrium level of output, consumption, planned investment, and net exports?

c. Suppose the Bank of Canada increases r to r = 2 Calculate what happens to the real interest rate, equilibrium level of output, consumption, planned investment, and net exports.

d. Considering that output, consumption, planned in-vestment, and net exports all decreased in part (c), why might the Bank choose to increase r ?

24. Consider the economy described in Applied Problem 23 .

a. Derive expressions for the MP curve and AD curve. b. Assume that p = 2 . What is the real interest rate

and equilibrium level of output? c. Suppose government spending increases to $4 tril-

lion. What happens to equilibrium output? d. If the Bank of Canada wanted to keep output con-

stant, then what monetary policy change should occur?

25. Suppose the MP curve is given as r = 2 + p , and the IS curve is given as Y = 20 - 2r .

a. Derive an expression for the AD curve, and draw a graph labeling points at p = 0 , p = 4 , and p = 8.

b. Suppose that l increases to l = 2 . Derive an expression for the new AD curve, and draw the new AD curve using the graph from part (a).

c. What does your answer to part ( b) say about the relationship between a central bank’s distaste for inflation and the slope of the AD curve?

1. Go to http://www.bankofcanada.ca/monetary-policy-introduction/ . Review what the Bank of Canada says

its goals are for monetary policy. Explain why these are consistent with the Taylor principle.

W E B E X E R C I S E S

M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 13M23_MISH5701_05_SE_C23.indd 13 10/15/12 7:33 PM10/15/12 7:33 PM


Recommended