+ All Categories
Home > Documents > The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

Date post: 30-Nov-2021
Category:
Upload: others
View: 4 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
35
The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on Foreign Direct Investment Nationalekonomiska Institutionen Shen Gao Uppsala Universitet Handledare: Christian Nilsson HT-2008 2009-01-06
Transcript
Page 1: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade

on Foreign Direct Investment

Nationalekonomiska Institutionen Shen Gao Uppsala Universitet Handledare: Christian Nilsson HT-2008 2009-01-06

Page 2: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

Index 1 Introduction……………………………………………………………………………3 2 Theoretical background ……………………………………………………………....5

2.1 Reasoning behind FDI………………………………………………………5

2.2 The Gravity Model ………………………………………………………….8 3 Empirical approach………………………………………………………………......10 4 Basic Model Specifications…………………………………………………………...12

4.1 The OLS model………………………………………………………..........12

4.2 OLS estimations……….……………………………………………………14 5 The Fixed-effect Model……………………………………………………………….19

5.1 Fixed-effect model specification……..……………………………………..19

5.2 Fixed-effect estimations……….……………………………………………21 6 Conclusions……………………………………………………………………………25 Appendices………………………………………………………………………………27

Page 3: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

1 Introduction

The link between foreign direct investments (FDI) and trade is firmly established in

economic literature. Casson (1990) has for example suggested that FDI is a “logical

intersection” of the theory of international capital markets, the theory of the firm and

trade theory. Singh & Jun (1995) and Tanaka (2006) mention that firms might conduct

FDI for the specific purpose of “tariff hopping” and avoiding trade costs, suggesting that

trade issues have significant sway when firms make investment decisions. Yet despite the

vast amount of literature on this subject, very few have tried to look at FDI through the

lens of trade theory, choosing rather to approach the subject on either a macroeconomic-

level or on firm-level. The purpose and scope of this paper is not to extend and build

upon the ideas from such studies, but rather to explore FDI through the lens of trade-

theory.

The gravity model has been widely used in trade-theory to predict the level of trade

between different countries based on their economic size and distance from each other,

and it has been recognized for its empirical success and consistently high statistical

explanatory power (Bergstrand 1985). However, the vast majority of FDI studies have

chosen to incorporate trade theory and certain components of the gravity model of trade

into the macroeconomic-level of study. It is the intention of this study to refrain from

doing so, but rather to use the gravity model exclusively in modeling FDI values.

Questions that will be asked are whether the gravity model of trade can serve as a reliable

model for FDI value as well? Are there certain variables in the gravity model that are

distinctively powerful determinants of FDI? The idea is of course to see how strong the

link between FDI and trade actually is; whether the gravity model can obtain as

consistently strong results for FDI as it does for trade.

For practical purposes, FDI in this paper will be defined as when an investor from one

country obtains controlling interest in a (new or existing) firm in another country, and

then operates that firm as a part of the multinational business of the investor. FDI may be

financed through parent company transfer of funds to the new affiliate, borrowing from

3

Page 4: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

home-country lenders, borrowing in the host country by the parent company, or any

combination of these strategies. A foreign investor is considered to have control over a

firm if they have 10% of shares or voting power in an enterprise (or the equivalent in an

unincorporated firm). FDI also pertains to investments in infrastructure, equipment and/or

organizations that allow the foreign investor to influence the management of the firm.

The data for FDI values come from the OECD.stat statistical database and the data used

in this paper span from the years 1990 to 2005. This time-period was chosen specifically

due to the post-Cold War market and trade liberalization initiatives that were prevalent.1

Countries included in the study are OECD countries chosen for geographic dispersion

and relevancy (Australia, Belgium, Canada, Czech Republic, France, Germany, Italy,

Japan, Korean Republic, Mexico, Netherlands, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, United

Kingdom and United States), and five major transitioning countries (Brazil, China, India,

Russia and South Africa). One issue that Ceglowski (2006) mentions in her study, which

also applies to this study, is that the OECD data were supplied by national statistical

offices. Consequently, the investment partner detail in the data varies by country. For

some country pairs, only a single source of foreign direct investment is available. In such

instances, these are the data used in the analysis. In other cases, both partners report

incoming and outgoing direct investments. These two reported values are usually not

identical, and the size of the difference varies considerably. The discrepancies reflect the

methods, scope, and quality of the data collection used by the national statistical offices

that supplied the data. In these cases, the values from the country with the most thorough

and consistent reporting was used.

Since the FDI data is only available as calculated using current US dollars, the GDP and

GDP per-capita data are also in current US dollars. The GDP data however is taken from

the World Bank World Development Index due to an easier format to use and the

availability and accuracy of the data. One concern with using current US dollars is of

course the fluctuations of the exchange rates, and whether converted current values can

1 Data for the Russian Federation start from 1991, and they start from 1993 for the Czech Republic since these countries did not gain their independence prior to these dates.

4

Page 5: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

accurately capture the effect these fluctuations had on investments in the past. The

problems associated with fluctuating exchange rates should of course be taken into

consideration when making economic inferences and drawing conclusions from the

models.

The next section serves as a theoretical background and review for FDI theory and the

Gravity Model of Trade, as well as their applications in this particular study. It is

followed by an overview of the empirical approach of this study. A specification as well

as analysis of the two models used in this study (OLS and fixed-effect) follows, and a

summary concludes.

2 Theoretical background

Traditionally studies on FDI have approached the problem either on an economic-level or

on firm-level. Firm-level approach to FDI is influenced by conventional investment

theory and microeconomics, whereas the economic-level approach is based on

international macroeconomics. This study will seek to use the firm-level approach to map

out the theoretical groundwork of the paper, and then use the economic-level approach to

empirically test the hypotheses proposed. As will become evident, this study mostly

concerns the so-called horizontal direct investment theory due to both data-constraint as

well as the nature of the study.

2.1 Theories on the reasoning behind FDI decisions

A central hypothesis of this paper will be the complementary relationship between FDI

and trade. One way to explain the FDI decision process and how it relates to trade is

through Helpman, Melitz & Yeaple’s (2004) theory of proximity-concentration trade-

offs.2 In this theory, firms engage in foreign markets because markets are imperfect, and

in weighing cost-benefits firms can decide to either; a) pull out of the foreign market, b) 2 For a detailed walkthrough of the theoretical model, refer to Appendix II.

5

Page 6: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

export to the foreign market exclusively, or c) invest in a foreign production facility to

serve that specific market (FDI). The decision of interest to my study is whether a firm

exports or invests in a foreign market. According to Helpman, Melitz & Yeaple (2004) it

is the different relative costs of the modes of access that determine whether a firm

engages in exports only or whether they decide to do FDI. Exporting involves lower fixed

costs whereas investing means lower variable costs. The choice by the firm in this case is

driven by “the proximity-concentration trade-off: relative to exports, FDI saves transport

costs, but duplicates production facilities and therefore requires higher fixed costs. In

equilibrium, no firm engages in both activities for the same foreign market.” Essentially,

Helpman, Melitz & Yeaple find that exports are more profitable than FDI for low-

productivity firms and less profitable for high-productivity firms.

The detail of importance to this paper is that all firms identify potential profits in a

foreign market; the only difference is that their mode of access varies depending on

productivity. One firm investing a production plant in a foreign market does not preclude

another firm from exporting a comparable product to that same market. In fact, a market

that is identified to be profitable by one firm is highly likely to receive the same

assessment by a competing firm. Hence it is highly possible that trade and FDI are

complementary unless there is considerable information asymmetry or barriers to entry. It

is this connection between FDI and exports/trade that is the theoretical basis for the

empirical models of this study.

Worth noting about the proximity-concentration trade-off theory is that it is only

applicable to horizontal investments3; which fits in well with my study. As Markusen,

Venables, Konan and Zhang (1996) note in their paper, horizontal direct investment is

more relevant to developed countries, whereas vertical direct investment is more relevant

to investment in developing countries. In their study they find that “horizontal

multinationals dominate when the countries are similar in both size and in relative

3 In Horizontal Direct Investment, firms usually choose to produce roughly the same product in different locations, essentially substituting international production for trade. In Vertical Direct Investment firms spread the production of a single product in several locations, taking advantage of differences in factor prices.

6

Page 7: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

endowments, and when trade costs are moderate to high”. Since a considerable majority

of the countries in my sample are developed countries, horizontal investments will be of

greater concern. However, a number of countries are transitioning economies (China,

India, Brazil etc.), in which case a blend of horizontal and vertical FDI might exist.

The issue of interest in horizontal investment is that these investments are high when

trade-costs are moderate to high. If one were to apply the proximity-concentration trade-

off theory, it would be obvious that the variable costs associated with exports are higher

in these cases and firms that would’ve otherwise engaged in exports will either pull out of

the market or simply invest (FDI). Another strand of theories worth noting is the Export-

Platform FDI that Ekholm, Forslid and Markusen (2005) have developed. In their study

they identify conditions under which large countries use small countries as an export

platform to server other high income countries. The reasoning behind this type of

horizontal investment is to avoid trade barriers as well as draw benefits from potential

free trade agreements (FTAs). The implications of their theory will be discussed further

in the empirical analysis section of this paper. The issue however is that this type of

horizontal investment seems to contradict the gravity theory of my study. According to

the export-platform theory firms inside the EU for example wouldn’t have to worry about

trade barriers or other costs, therefore their need to invest in other EU countries should be

very small. However, in this paper I would argue that investments between countries in

close proximity is still greater than distant ones due to two factors: 1) since similar

countries trade more with each other than dissimilar ones, then there should be more

investments between neighboring countries or countries that are part of the same FTA

due to less costs and risks; and 2) conventional FDI theory only deals with Multinationals,

whereas I would argue that Small and Medium-sized Enterprises (SMEs) constitute a

significant portion of FDI. One explanation for this theory would be that Multinational

firms nowadays have become Global firms and their investment costs are minimal

irrespective of region in the world. Investment costs for SMEs however, are still

considerable, and therefore these investments tend to end up in closer countries both in

geographic and cultural terms.

7

Page 8: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

Vertical investments are only of peripheral interest in this study. As Zhang and Markusen

(1997) explain in their study, vertical multinationals exploit factor-price differences in the

world economy and allocate their investments and production accordingly, essentially

relocating labor-intensive but low-skill production to low-wage countries. This type of

investment might be of interest in data from countries such as China and India who have

traditionally been recipients of such vertical investments. However, with these economies

in transition and their accumulation of capital, a “reverse” vertical investment could

potentially be of interest. This is to say that firms from these traditionally low-wage

countries could potentially invest in more developed countries in order to quickly gain

access to a high-skill labor-pool. If this is the case, then FDI in both directions would be

of interest to observe, rather than just one direction as might be suggested in conventional

vertical investment theory. This thought process might explain potential discrepancies

between expected FDI based on distance and market size, and actual observations.

To summarize, the important theoretical components of this paper are that firms from one

country identify similar foreign markets as being potentially profitable, and the means by

which they serve these foreign markets is determined by the productivity of an individual

firm. While there are several factors that affect whether a market is deemed profitable by

firms, the central theory of this paper holds that distance (both physical and cultural) and

market size are the two most prominent factors due to perceptions of risk and the

involvement of all firms (and not just MNEs as is conventional in FDI theory) in FDI

activity. Finally, growing markets are not only targets for investment, but have large

firms capable of investing abroad themselves. This changing market outlook could

potentially make international investment more reciprocal than before, and relationships

that were previously identified as being “vertical” could potentially be “horizontal” in

nature, which would make these new markets highly interesting for this study.

2.2 The Gravity Model

The core idea behind the gravity model of trade is the notion that trade is determined by

the economic size of the countries involved as well as the physical distance between them.

8

Page 9: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

In trade-theory, the gravity equation in its most basic and frequently used form is

specified as:

(1) 0 1 2 3 4ln ln ln ln lnij i j ij ij ijX Y Y D Fβ β β β β= + + + + + μ

where is the amount of trade between country i (host) and country j (home), is the

nominal GDP of each country, is the distance between the two countries, and

represents any other factors that might affect the amount of trade conducted between

country i and j. In conjunction with the economic size of a country is its market size,

meaning larger countries have greater potential markets which would attract more firms

to export to that country. To account for this possibility, some theories have suggested an

extension of the gravity model to include the population size of each country into the

equation.

ijX Y

ijD ijF

iN

4

(2) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6ln ln ln ln ln ln lnij i j i j ij ij ijX Y Y N N D Fβ β β β β β β= + + + + + + + μ

In this extended model, the economic size coupled with the actual size of the countries is

supposed to account for the market potential of a country that serves to predict trade

value.

A technical detail worth noting is that in practical application of the gravity equation, the

miscellaneous factors are frequently represented by dummy variables. This is because

more often than not, these factors tend to remain constant for each individual country.

Examples of such factors that can affect trade value are common language, common

borders, if they are members of the same RTA or FTA

ijF

5, common historical background

etc.6

4 See Cheng and Wall (2005) 5 Regional Trade Agreement and Free-Trade Agreement 6 For a common example of the use of multiple dummy variables in gravity modeling, see Stijn (2003).

9

Page 10: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

Another noteworthy detail is that in most applications of the gravity equation, the data

tends to be cross-sectional, meaning the time-component t is held constant for all

observations. As Mátyás (1997) mentions in his paper, by holding the time-component

constant one is actually creating a restriction on the effectiveness of the model since an

assumption is being made that trade value does not change with the passing of time. If

this assumption proves to be false, incorrect interpretations about the independent

variables can be made and improper economic inference would most likely occur. To

overcome this problem, Mátyás (1997) propagates the use of panel-data to incorporate

e time-component. I will also use panel-data in this study to avoid making unnecessary

fixed-effect model to

etermine whether these concerns are warranted for my study as well. A thorough fixed-

ffect model specification can be found in section 5 of this paper.

ity in

th

restrictions on the model.

In addition to the general OLS gravity model, this study will also employ the use of a

fixed-effect gravity model in predicting FDI. The Fixed-effect gravity model is primarily

used because recent literature have identified some concerns regarding the viability of an

OLS model due to faulty model specifications that could lead to inaccurate parameter

estimations. Their solution has been to essentially equate the miscellaneous factors ijF of

the OLS model with unobserved heterogeneity between each country-pair of the fixed-

effect model. In my study, I will use both an OLS model and a

d

e

3 Empirical approach

This study will use the macroeconomic approach to FDI as a framework for the empirical

study. The reason for choosing a macroeconomic approach rather than the

microeconomic firm-level approach is two-fold. Firstly, the gravity model of trade is a

model that measures macroeconomic data and to use it in modeling microeconomic data

would be problematic to say the least. Secondly, almost all empirical studies on FDI have

been done using the macroeconomic approach due to availability of data and simplic

10

Page 11: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

creating a feasible model. Essentially, the macroeconomic approach is more suited to

observe how FDI flows in certain patterns, which is also the purpose of this paper.

The idea behind the macroeconomic approach to FDI is that it emphasizes the

determinants of why net investment among pairs or groups of nations tends to flow in

certain patterns (Grosse, R. & Trevino, L.J. 1996). It attempts to explain FDI behavior

with macroeconomic variables such as inflation, national income and exchange rate etc.

(Trevino, L.J & Mixon Jr., F.G. 2004). As Grosse and Trevino (1996) demonstrate in

their study of foreign FDI in the U.S, most macroeconomic studies on FDI focus on three

separate groups of independent variables: 1) economic, such as GDP, per capita income,

exchange rate, interest rates etc.; 2) political risk; and 3) distance in both absolute terms

and cultural terms. Since this paper approaches FDI using the gravity model of trade,

only those economic factors included in the gravity model such as GDP and the distance

variable will be included explicitly. Political risk is an interesting variable since it not

only pertains to societal and governmental affairs, but also includes operations costs as

part of the overall risks involved in an investment. These operations costs can sometimes

be attributed to cultural factors, which make political risk a highly interesting variable for

this study. However, as Singh and Jun (1995) note in their paper, most empirical studies

on political risk have not been statistically significant, rendering it a rather unreliable

variable to include in the model. Thus, rather than including a separate risk variable, this

udy will use per capita income to serve as a rough proxy for political risk since in

y market size indicates the number of firms that have the capacity to invest

nd operate abroad. Thus both host country and home country GDP are expected to be

st

sweeping terms, well-off countries tend to have more stable institutions than poorer

countries.

Thus the most distinguishing variables used in this study will be home and host country

GDP and GDP per-capita, as well as the distance between each country-pair. The

reasoning behind including host country as well as home country GDP in the model is

that host country market size is an indicator of potential returns on an investment and

home countr

a

11

Page 12: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

positively correlated with FDI, meaning the larger the market size the more FDI will be

conducted.

Per-capita income being included (aside from aforementioned proxy of risk) is built upon

the concept that countries with similar markets tend to trade with each other more than

dissimilar ones. 7 As Helpman, Melitz & Yeaple (2004) mention in their proximity-

concentration trade-off theory, higher productivity firms are more likely to engage in FDI

activity and well-off countries are most likely to have higher productivity firms.

Therefore it is reasonable to expect that home country per-capita GDP should have a

positive effect on FDI. In addition Grosse and Trevino (1996) mention in their paper that

demand patterns as well as firm behavior explain the trade between similar countries.

This concept is especially interesting to this study since the data encompasses OECD

member countries as well as the five countries nearest OECD accession. Roughly

eaking, these are the “richest” countries in the world and one could expect that their

onal costs and the perception of risk that can influence FDI

ecisions. In the case of geographic distance FDI is expected to decrease with increasing

istance, and for cultural distance, FDI is expected to increase if the countries share a

Basic Model Specifications

sp

markets tend to be rather similar. Thus the per-capita income of the host country is also

expected to have a positive impact on FDI.

Distance is central to the gravity model of trade and I have included two variables in

order to test its importance to FDI. Distance in this paper pertains to geographic distance

and the language dummy serves as an indicator of cultural distance. The rationale behind

including geographic distance to explain FDI is the greater cost of obtaining relevant

information as well as the difficulties in managing affiliates in distant regions. Cultural

distance may affect operati

d

d

common official language.

4

7 This ties in with theories concerning horizontal FDI, which will be discussed further on in this section.

12

Page 13: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

4.1 The OLS Model

he basic gravity equation that will be used in this study is as follows:

(3)

T

0 1 2 3ijt it jt it 4 5 6 7ln ln ln ln ln lnjt ij ij ij ijtFDI GDP GDP PC PC DIS lang bordβ β β β β β β β= + + + + + + + + μ

j (home) to country i (host)

at time t, expressed in current US dollars.

: The GDP of country j at time t in current US dollars.

: Per-capita GDP of country i at time t in current US dollars.

: Per-capita GDP of country j at

between country i and j as measured by the distance

between each country’s capital.

my variable that takes the value 1 if country i and j share a common official

nguage, 0 otherwise.

o

ijtFDI : Total value of foreign direct investments from country

itGDP : The GDP of country i at time t in current US dollars.

jtGDP

itPC

PC jt time t in current US dollars.

DISij : The distance in kilometers

langij : A dum

la

ijbord : A dummy variable that takes the value 1 if country i and j share a comm n border,

0 otherwise.

As can be seen, per-capita GDP ( PC ) has taken the place of population size ( N ) in this

model. This is in part to account for the fact that similar countries (in terms of economic

development) have been observed to trade more with each other than dissimilar ones.8

Also, as Ceglowski (2006) mentions in her paper, some studies on trade have included

per-capita income in the gravity equation in order to capture elements of economic size

that are not fully contained in the income terms themselves. An example of this would be

8 Econometrically however, per-capita GDP (Y/N) and population (N) are essentially equivalent. As an explanatory variable, per-capita GDP only contributes through the variations in N. Variations in Y are redundant in the per-capita GDP case since these changes are already captured by the GDP variable.

13

Page 14: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

the productivity of firms, which in the proximity-concentration trade-off would in turn

determine their means of serving foreign markets and affect FDI values. In addition, as

as been mentioned earlier in this paper, per-capita GDP can be seen as a crude measure

ry, and in this case would serve as a proxy measurement for

2 OLS estimations

ble 1: OLS regressions

udy.

nally, the fourth column lists the coefficients for an OLS regression with a year dummy.

h

of the development of a count

political stability.

4. Ta

*All the above values are robust and have been corrected for heteroscedasticity.

Four different OLS regressions were done in this study. The first column lists the

coefficients of a simple OLS regression with all the countries from the dataset. The

second column includes coefficients from a regression where the five prominent

developing countries, the so-called BRICS 9 , have been excluded. The third column

represents an OLS regression of only the European OECD countries included in the st

Simple OLS Simple OLS w/o BRICS

Simple OLS only Europe

OLS with year dummy (BRICS)

lngdpi .7576971 (0.000)

.7345006 (0.000)

.5106558 (0.000)

.7359769 (0.000)

lngdpj .9246042 (0.000)

.6833374 (0.000)

.8785434 (0.000)

.6848451 (0.000)

lnpci .3575239 (0.000)

.5958057 (0.000)

1.069413 (0.000)

.5854841 (0.000)

lnpcj 1.348072 (0.000)

2.913072 (0.000)

3.446074 (0.000)

2.904034 (0.000)

lndis -.8023343 (0.000)

-.7934467 (0.000)

-.9541462 (0.000)

-.794027 (0.000)

lang 1.297567 (0.000)

1.078454 (0.000)

-.6577832 (0.000)

1.083427 (0.000)

bord -.0417723 (0.583)

.1277888 (0.113)

.3696065 (0.000)

.1269802 (0.115)

yrdummy .0731315 (0.162)

Fi

9 Brazil, Russia, India, China and South Africa

14

Page 15: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

The year dummy assumes the value 0 for all observations prior to 1999, and 1 otherwise.

The reasoning behind including this shift-dummy can be observed in Figure 1 below.

Figure 1: Absolute FDI according to year 0

1.00

0e+1

12.

000e

+11

3.00

0e+1

1FD

I

1990 1995 2000 2005Year

It is evident that FDI displays a growing trend during the time-period pertinent to this

study. However, the period after 1999 is of special interest since the IT boom took place

during this time. The variable yrdummy is thus an attempt to see whether the IT boom

had an impact on FDI, causing the sample to form a spline function. The regression that

my is based on the previous model that excludes the BRICS

includes this year dum

countries since their share of FDI has increased after the millennium shift making it hard

to determine the IT boom component of their FDI10.

Looking at the results of the simple OLS regression, we can observe that all of the

variables are significant except for the common-border variable, which is only significant

10 When doing the same year dummy regression WITH the BRICS countries, a significant value for yrdummy was attained.

15

Page 16: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

in the sample containing strictly European countries. It is difficult to ascertain why

common borders would not be a significant factor in determining FDI levels. One way of

explaining this result might be that even though FDI and trade have a proven link, the

actual determinants still vary in certain key areas. Common borders is an important factor

in determining trade values because of transport costs, yet since investments do not suffer

from these transport costs common borders would probably be less of an issue. Of note

for this study is that the common borders variable is only significant in the regression

with European countries. This could be attributed to the theory previously put forth in

is paper that SMEs do in fact play a role in FDI. SMEs are more reliant on outside

an indication there is a causal

lationship between exports and FDI, several factors point towards these two variables

th

capital for their investments and well-off countries are more likely to have excess capital,

also SMEs are probably more likely to invest in close proximity to their home-market due

to higher costs of investment.

In conjunction with the SME theory as well as the weak results found with the common

borders variable, it would be interesting to see how the relationship between exports and

FDI holds up in the data sample pertinent to this study. In appendix III I have compiled

the results from regressing FDI using exports (lnexp) as an explanatory variable in order

to determine whether there is a causal relationship. Whereas the results weren’t very

strong, two issues merit some consideration. Firstly, the correlation coefficient between

FDI and exports in this data sample is 0.5602, suggesting there is a strong positive

correlation between the two variables. Secondly, adding an export variable significantly

increases the standard errors of all the GDP-related variables, signifying strong chances

that multicollinearity is present. Most likely the GDP-related variables are also

explanatory variables for exports. Thus while there isn’t

re

being highly correlated. This high correlation could point towards the complementary

relationship between trade and FDI, and the existence of both high-productivity firms and

low-productivity firms serving a similar foreign market.

As can be seen in table 1, the GDP per-capita of the home country (lnpcj) is in all four

cases the most pronounced positive determinant of the amount of FDI between country-

16

Page 17: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

pairs. This result might tie in with Grosse & Trevino’s (1996) ideas of home market size

being a proxy for firm capacity to invest. However, instead of market size, it is per-capita

income that is of importance. One explanation for this higher capacity to invest ties in

ith Helpman, Melitz & Yeaple’s (2004) ideas of higher productivity firms being more

an issue when

e model is restricted to these countries. Yet another interpretation could be that lnpcj

l inferences.

variable (lang) makes quite drastic shifts depending on the sample being used. One

reason why the lang variable is negative for the European dataset could be that

w

likely to engage in FDI and well-off countries are prone to have more productive firms

able to invest abroad. Additionally, these countries have large pools of capital that enable

firms to make investments that they could otherwise not afford.

In conjunction with home-country per-capita GDP is the trend observed in the OLS

regressions that the more “concentrated” the sample, the more importance is attributed to

both home and host country per-capita GDP. Per-capita GDP has a higher coefficient for

strictly OECD countries than when the BRICS are included, and it becomes higher still

when the sample size is reduced to European OECD countries. This trend may follow the

observations made in several studies that countries with similar relative factor

endowments engage in more FDI activity11 (Tanaka 2006). Another way to interpret this

result would be that European economies tend to be smaller when compared with the

overall OECD dataset, and thus firm capacity to invest becomes more of

th

and lndis aren’t strictly uncorrelated, however neither a correlation matrix12 nor standard

errors suggest autocorrelation being an issue. The uncertainty surrounding the trend in

per-capita GDP makes it difficult to put forth any meaningfu

An additional observation of note is that the year dummy had no significant effect on FDI.

So there is nothing in this particular sample that would suggest that the IT boom had any

significant effect on FDI values amongst OECD countries.

One final observation from the set of OLS regressions is that the common language

11 In Appendix V I have tried to clear up the questions surrounding per-capita GDP by using dummy variables for richer countries. 12 Correlation between lngdppcj and lndis never goes above 0.08

17

Page 18: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

Switzerland has a common language with three different countries; France, Germany and

Italy. This example illustrates the difficulties when using dummy variables to model

specific effects13. One way to attempt to correct this problem is to account for what

Cheng & Wall (2005) refer to as “heterogeneous effects” by using fixed-effect models.

Aside from the ambiguity of the lang and bord variable, taking a closer look at residual

plots also reveals problems with the OLS regressions. As can be seen in Figure 2 below,

there is a slight trend of more residuals being negative than positive. In addition, if one

looks at Figure 3 one can see that the range of the residuals becomes greater the larger

lndis is. As was mentioned earlier, these trends make inference-making from the OLS

e problem is to use fixed-

effect models, which will be the topic of the following section. Figure 2: Plot of the residuals from fitted OLS values

regressions somewhat unreliable. One possible solution to th

-10

-50

510

Res

idua

ls

10 15 20 25 30Fitted values

13 In Appendix IV I have excluded certain fixed dummy variables in favor of distance squared to determine whether the results change.

18

Page 19: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

Figure 3: Regression residuals in relation to lndis

-10

-50

510

Res

idua

ls

5 6 7 8 9 10lnDIS

5 The Fixed-effect Model

5.1 Fixed-effect model specifications

The main issue with conventional OLS-methods of having a basic model and adding

dummy variables for each additional factor is that they pose several problems when

estimating results. As Cheng and Wall (2005) mention in their paper, the conventional

OLS gravity model yields biased results because they do not control for heterogeneous

effects for each country-pair. These heterogeneous effects are numerous and hard to

quantify. One example of this is if one considers the distance variable. In the OLS-

regression above I have chosen to define distance as being the distance in kilometers

between each country’s capitals. This might be an accurate measure of economic distance

if one were to compare smaller countries like Sweden and Switzerland. For larger

19

Page 20: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

countries however, the distance between capital-cities might not necessarily be a good

indicator of economic distance since a large country can have several economic centers,

each with distinctive characteristics. In addition, physical distance doesn’t always

quantify the economic distance that is of interest. An example of this would be Moscow,

London and New York. The physical distance between London and New York in

kilometers is farther than that of London and Moscow, yet the economic links between

New York and London are much greater. Even if one were to compare New York and

Washington D.C with London, one would most likely find that the economic activity

between New York and London is greater simply because of both cities being large

commercial and financial centers. These heterogeneous effects are very hard to capture

ith conventional OLS methods.

s is a blunt instrument

r modeling the variables that affect FDI between country-pairs.

w

The other dummy variables included in the OLS regressions also cause some concern.

Common language, as was mentioned in the Switzerland case earlier, is a difficult

variable to capture. It is exceedingly difficult to designate a specific point at which two

countries can be said to share a common language or not. Sweden for example does not

officially have the same language as Norway or Finland; however there is a considerable

chance that one could make oneself understood speaking Swedish in these two countries.

In a broader perspective, the Asian countries might display certain language-related

positive effects simply because their languages are more closely related, and the same

could be said for the countries in northwestern Europe. The difficulty in quantifying

language is also applicable for the border variable. Island countries for example do not

have any neighboring countries, yet they might still experience proximity effects similar

to that of common borders. Countries can also have links that provide common border

effects without actually having any real borders (the channel tunnel between Great

Britain and France, the bridge between Sweden and Denmark). With these issues in mind,

it is clear therefore that an OLS regression with dummy variable

fo

20

Page 21: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

Because of the difficulty in capturing these heterogeneous effects, some studies have

ested that a fixed-effect model approach would be most appropriate.14 sugg

(4) 0FDIijt t ij ijtijtZα α α β μ= + + + +

In the fixed-effect model above, FDIijt is trade value (or in the case of this paper, value of

FDI) from country j to country i in year t and Zijt = [zit, z ] is the vector of gravity jt …

variables (gross dom lation or per-capita GDP). The intercept

has three parts: one common to ears and country pairs,

estic product [GDP], popu

all y 0α ; one specific to year t and

common to all pairs, tα ; and one specific to the country pairs and common to all years,

ijα. In my case, since I am dealing with pane sted in the bilateral

eneous effects in FDI, the intercept of interest would b

l data and only intere

e heterog ijα. There is some debate

whether the country-pair effect ijα should be symm rding to the direction of etric acco

trade or FDI, meaning whether ij jiα α= or whether these fixed effects are indeed even

unique considering the direction of trade or FDI ij jiα α≠ . All of the fixed effect

regressions done in this study are in accordance with the two-way theory,

meaning ij jiα α≠ . It is altogether viable that a symmetric fixed-effect approach would be

equally feasible, or perhaps even better. However, due to time-constraints and concerns

generating symmetric pairs with STATA, I chose not to do regressions of symmetric

2 Fixed-effect estimations

in

fixed-effects.

5.

14 See Cheng and Wall (2005), Glick and Rose (2001), and Mátyás (1997).

21

Page 22: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

Table 2: Fixed-effect regressions

Fixed Effect

Fixed Effect w/o

BRICS

Fixed Effect Europe

Fixed Effect Year

Dummy lngdpi .5540553

(0.215) -2.571137 (0.000)

-4.042991 (0.004)

-2.524095 (0.000)

lngdpj 5.30848 (0.000)

4.141524 (0.000)

12.05305 (0.000)

4.135882 (0.000)

lnpci 1.840277 (0.000)

5.559181 (0.000)

6.346213 (0.000)

5.718852 (0.000)

lnpcj -3.203955 (0.000)

-.9550657 (0.400)

-8.601446 (0.001)

-.7691635 (0.505)

yrdummy -.0869341 (0.061)

The same four datasets are used in the fixed effect regressions as in the previous OLS

models. The difference here is that distance, common language and common borders

have been taken out of the actual equation and instead contribute to the intercept ijα. A

noticeable result at first glance is that host country GDP (lngdpi) is not significant in the

first regression. This is a striking result since lngdpi was significant and robust in the

OLS model, and the result can in essence be interpreted as host country GDP not having

a significant impact on FDI value, which is almost counterintuitive. It is hard to draw any

concrete conclusions from these results, but one could assume that certain factors that the

OLS regressions attributed to lngdpi were in fact country-pair specific, meaning these

effects can be attributed to specific relations between country-pairs. Another perplexing

result for host country GDP is that it, when significant, has a negative impact on FDI.

Meaning the bigger a country’s economy, the less FDI it receives. This goes against both

what the gravity model as well as conventional FDI theory predicts. One should be

careful when making inferences about these results, but one hypothesis would possibly be

that since the sample is restricted to OECD countries, certain countries dwarf others in its

capacity for investment. For example, the U.S receives a considerable amount of FDI,

however due to its sheer size and abundance of capital; their outward investments dwarf

those of lesser countries thereby “skewing” FDI numbers.

Another very noteworthy result from the fixed effect models is that home country per-

capita GDP has a negative effect on FDI as well. This is fairly surprising since lnpcj was

22

Page 23: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

found to be the most important positive contributor to FDI in the OLS regressions. This is

somewhat alarming since the results could also undermine the proximity-concentration

trade-off hypothesis and firm productivity effects on FDI. However, lnpcj is only

significant in the first and third model, making the results very ambiguous and it

wouldn’t be a stretch to assume that home-country per-capita GDP simply has no

significant effect on FDI. If one were to hypothesize about how home-country per-capita

GDP could negatively impact FDI, one suggestion could be that well-off countries have

sufficiently large internal markets as to make firms deem FDI to be unnecessary.

In contrast with the OLS regressions, the fixed effect models all point to home country

GDP (lngdpj) to be significant and having a highly important effect on FDI. This result

might in fact support Grosse & Trevino’s (1996) original theory that home country GDP

can be a proxy for firm ability to invest, rather than lnpcj as the OLS models seemed to

suggest. Also, the per-capita GDP of the destination country (lnpci) is found to have a

considerable effect on FDI in the fixed effect models. One explanation could be that

firms invest in well-off countries since these countries have more consumers willing to

spend, a nod to the Keynesian economy where firms cater to the market so to speak.

If one were to speculate as to what factors might explain the wildly different results of the

fixed-effect regressions, one aspect would be the existence of Free-Trade Agreements

(FTA) and Regional Trade Agreements (RTA). As Ekholm, Forslid and Markusen (2005)

mention in their Export-Platform theory, firms sometimes set up a local affiliate to serve

an entire region in order to circumvent certain trade barriers and take advantage of the

free-trade agreement. Thus, an American firm might only invest in plants in one EU

country, when its intention is actually to serve the EU in its entirety thereby affecting FDI

figures. Indeed, some of these fixed effects could also be rules and regulations that make

direct investments prohibitively costly, thereby forcing even highly productive firms to

resort to exports rather than investing. In conjunction with the trade bloc issue is the

problem with exchanges and currencies. All values in this study are designated using

current U.S dollars; inflation rate as well as foreign exchange fluctuations might affect

23

Page 24: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

FDI values. Also, since the Euro wasn’t in public circulation until 2000, its role in the

sample time period chosen for this study is still undetermined.

Another issue that relates to fixed effects to an extent is that different countries attract

certain types of FDI. Some firms engage in resource seeking FDI, other firms do market

seeking FDI. FDI can also be done for efficiency purposes or simply out of strategic

(market share) reasons. Investing in a copper mine entails entirely different commitments

and risks than setting up an assembly plant for beverage cans. Larger markets are also

more likely to attract FDI for the sole purpose of having a strategic presence in that

market. The differing characteristics enjoyed by the countries in this sample could thus

attract specific types of FDI, which in turn could affect the total FDI value in that country.

The ambiguous results from the fixed-effect models warrant the question whether it is

useful in determining FDI values. Indeed, one major flaw with the fixed-effect models

used in this study is that the vast majority of countries included have had fairly stagnant

population growth during the time-period studied. This almost “fixed” nature of the

population could have had unobserved effects on per-capita GDP, which is one of the

major explanatory variables of this study. To test whether the population is indeed

“fixed”, I redid the fixed-effect regression using population rather than per-capita GDP as

an explanatory variable (see appendix VI for results). The results were inconclusive but

overall the results from the population fixed-effect models were still weaker than in the

OLS regressions. This suggests that the population variable does in fact cause some

concerns for the fixed-effect models. Indeed, there seems to be certain underlying issues

that puts into doubt the stability and viability of the fixed-effect model. The causes for

these problems are beyond the scope of this paper; however it would be an interesting

topic for future studies.

24

Page 25: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

6 Conclusions

This study estimates FDI value using two modified versions of the gravity model of trade.

The findings when using OLS regressions are that the components of the gravity model

of trade are indeed key determinants of FDI value, and the two most significant positive

determinants were home country GDP (lngdpj) as well as home country per-capita GDP

(lnpcj). These results tie in with FDI theory where countries that are well-off are more

likely to have high-productivity firms whose profit levels allow for riskier FDI endeavors.

Larger well-off economies could also have better developed capital markets that enable

firms to make more investments. Distance (lndis), which is a key component of the

gravity model of trade, is also found to have a significant negative effect on FDI as was

expected. Several variables were found to have no significant effect on FDI value in the

fixed-effect model however, and only home country GDP (lngdpj) and host country per-

capita GDP (lnpci) were consistent positive determinants of FDI. The differing results

from the OLS models and the fixed-effect models cause inference-making to be

somewhat unreliable. There could indeed be country-pair specific factors that cannot be

modeled using simple dummy variables, yet the fixed-effect model might not be stable

enough or properly specified to accurately predict FDI.

As for the tie-in of results with the original hypothesis, the proximity-concentration trade

off seems to be accurate in the OLS model as was mentioned earlier. Distance and GDP

are also significant components, suggesting that “gravity” is indeed at work even for FDI

activity. The theory of an increasingly reciprocal international investment climate

however is hard to determine. The greater importance of the GDP variable for the dataset

including the BRICS countries, coupled with lesser importance for per-capita variables

suggest that the nature of these investments might still be “vertical”.

Finally, while the results in this study are inconclusive, there are several ways in which to

improve upon the study. One flaw is of course that OECD data is gathered from several

different sources and the accuracy of the data isn’t always completely reliable. Further

studies could also be conducted using the original population variable rather than per-

capita GDP as was used in this study. Another approach could be to test the gravity

25

Page 26: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

model regionally according to continent or economic region. Since the regressions using

only European countries exhibited different results than when using all OECD countries

in this study, it could be possible that other regional FDI values display the same

characteristics as the European regression. One final improvement would be to use

symmetric as well as two-way fixed effect models as opposed to only two-way models as

was done in this study. It is altogether possible that home and host country characteristics

do not matter when determining FDI, and that it is rather the specific combination of

home and host country that is the key.

26

Page 27: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

Appendix I

Cities Used to Calculate Distances

Country: City: Country: City:

Australia Canberra Mexico Mexico City

Belgium Brussels Netherlands Amsterdam

Brazil Brasilia Russian Federation Moscow

Canada Ottawa South Africa Johannesburg

China Beijing Spain Madrid

Czech Republic Prague Sweden Stockholm

France Paris Switzerland Bern

Germany Berlin United Kingdom London

India New Delhi United States Washington D.C

Italy Rome

Japan Tokyo

Korean Republic Seoul

27

Page 28: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

Appendix II

Below is a simplified version of Helpman, Melitz & Yeagle’s model for exports and FDI.

Df : Fixed Overhead Labor Costs in domestic market

Xf : Fixed Cost of Entering Foreign Market (Exports)

If : Fixed Cost of Entering Foreign Market (FDI)

a : Total demand for the good (market size)

π : Profit functions

Df is simply the costs of starting a firm and continuing its operations in the domestic market. We think about Xf as the costs of forming a distribution and servicing network in a foreign country (similar costs for the home market are included in Df ). The fixed costs If include these distribution and servicing network costs, as well as the costs of forming a subsidiary in a foreign country and the duplicate overhead production costs embodied in Df . Simply: I X Df f f> > . Country i and j are assumed to be fairly similar and therefore the demand patterns as well as fixed and operating costs are assumed to be comparable as well. The reasoning behind why Xπ has a different slope than the other two profit functions has to do with the variable trade costs involved in exports. We are assuming that the two

28

Page 29: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

markets are relatively similar and therefore the fixed costs involved in starting and operating a firm doesn’t differ that much. Iπ is further out due to the duplicated overhead costs of maintaining two separate plants in both country i and j.

Da is the break-even point for a firm in the domestic market. Above this point firms will continue to produce and if profits are below this point the firm will close down. is the break even point for exporting to a foreign market. If a firm has profits above this point then they will engage in exporting their good to the foreign market. is the point at which a firm switches from exporting to a foreign market to investing and creating a foreign affiliate to serve that specific market.

Xa

Ia

As can be seen, in this model the decision between exporting and engaging in FDI is decided by profits. The more profitable firms will seek to invest in foreign affiliates while less profitable firms settle with exporting. These differences in profits can be caused by several factors, but in Helpman, Melitz & Yeagle’s model they attribute the differences to firm productivity. The more productive a firm is the less cost it incurs from its operations, and therefore it is more likely to engage in costlier and riskier alternatives in supplying a market.

29

Page 30: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

Appendix III

Table A.1: OLS regressions with exports as independent variable |

Simple OLS Simple OLS w/o BRICS

Simple OLS only Europe

lngdpi .2198556 (0.000)

.1368717 (0.000)

-.1596564 (0.050)

lngdpj .0798136 (0.050)

.0987361 (0.002)

.2023012 (0.022)

lnpci .2924683 (0.000)

.4391195 (0.030)

.9210574 (0.000)

lnpcj 2.614567 (0.000)

2.615896 (0.000)

3.359847 (0.000)

lndis -.2334437 (0.000)

-.2310847 (0.000)

-.4944987 (0.000)

lang .890915 (0.000)

1.111937 (0.000)

-.4655214 (0.000)

bord -.3732731 (0.000)

-.4915177 (0.000)

-.2229595 (0.009)

lnexp .7167134 (0.000)

.7737565 (0.000)

.840576 (0.000)

Table A.2: Fixed-effect regressions with exports as independent variable Fixed

Effect Fixed

Effect w/o BRICS

Fixed Effect Europe

lngdpi -.8716026 (0.082)

-2.396176 (0.000)

-3.229703 (0.015)

lngdpj 3.684273 (0.000)

4.206138 (0.000)

11.58231 (0.000)

lnpci 2.724313 (0.000)

5.227924 (0.000)

4.708106 (0.001)

lnpcj -.4380808 (0.674)

-1.992399 (0.073)

-9.122407 (0.000)

lnexp .217473 (0.000)

.3323291 (0.000)

.5817689 (0.000)

The variable lnexp above refers to exports from country j to country i during time t.

30

Page 31: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

Appendix IV Table A.3: OLS regressions with distance squared Simple OLS Simple OLS

w/o BRICS Simple OLS only Europe

lngdpi .7614893 (0.000)

.7253432 (0.000)

.5765249 (0.000)

lngdpj .9294527 (0.000)

.6790035 (0.000)

.9242915 (0.000)

lnpci .3689059 (0.000)

.7295531 (0.000)

.9251114 (0.000)

lnpcj 1.367651 (0.000)

3.022054 (0.000)

3.339807 (0.000)

lndis -2.629262 (0.000)

-2.462159 (0.000)

-4.738608 (0.000)

lndis2 .1166761 (0.000)

.1048452 (0.000)

.286567 (0.000)

Squaring lndis and adding it as one of the independent variables in the regression doesn’t change the results very much. The only noticeable difference is that lndis has a higher coefficient in all three samples when compared with the OLS regressions done with the bord and lang variables. The larger coefficients could be due to the model attributing the common language and common border effects on FDI onto the distance variable. Appendix V The regressions below were done using a “rich country” dummy variable in order to see whether richer countries indeed trade more with each other as the horizontal direct investment theory suggests.

The basic idea behind the dummy is ( *ln ln )a richdummy pci pci+ . In essence, if the host country’s per-capita GDP (lnpci) is above $15,000 during the entire time-period of the sample (1990-2005), then that country is considered a “rich country” and the richdummy will be 1. If a country’s per-capita GDP is below $15,000 then it will have a richdummy value of 0. When doing the regressions, I found that if only the host country was classified as a “rich country” then the richdummy had very little effect on fdi (usually the coefficient was below 0.07). Also, including a richdummy in addition to the original per-capita GDP variables caused all of the per-capita variables to be less significant by a large margin.

31

Page 32: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

However, if the richdummy accounted for both the host and the home country being “rich countries” the results became more favorable. The explanatory capacity of the actual richdummy is mostly inconsequential though. The chart below is a regression done using the richdummy with the European OECD country sample as well as the non-BRICS OECD sample. Linear regression Number of obs = 1028 F( 8, 1019) = 367.14 Prob > F = 0.0000 R-squared = 0.8301 Root MSE = .97981 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ | Robust lnfdi | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------- lngdpi | .5179119 .0371958 13.92 0.000 .4449227 .5909012 lngdpj | .8552277 .0350776 24.38 0.000 .786395 .9240603 lngdppci | 1.082321 .0879805 12.30 0.000 .9096772 1.254965 lngdppcj | 3.660155 .1151881 31.78 0.000 3.434123 3.886188 lndis | -.9186476 .0563186 -16.31 0.000 -1.029161 -.8081339 lang | -.6762215 .0826395 -8.18 0.000 -.8383846 -.5140585 bord | .2954176 .0627482 4.71 0.000 .1722871 .4185481 richjlnpci | -.0005561 .000158 -3.52 0.000 -.0008662 -.000246 _cons | -55.36585 1.929752 -28.69 0.000 -59.15259 -51.57911 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------

Linear regression Number of obs = 2828 F( 8, 2819) = 860.28 Prob > F = 0.0000 R-squared = 0.7575 Root MSE = 1.3601 ------------------------------------------------------------------------------ | Robust lnfdi | Coef. Std. Err. t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] -------------+---------------------------------------------------------------- lngdpi | .7459619 .0286185 26.07 0.000 .6898465 .8020773 lngdpj | .6927902 .0247652 27.97 0.000 .6442304 .74135 lngdppci | .3228597 .0939411 3.44 0.001 .1386595 .5070599 lngdppcj | 2.696669 .0857324 31.45 0.000 2.528565 2.864774 lndis | -.7899063 .0272503 -28.99 0.000 -.8433389 -.7364737 lang | 1.014429 .0765585 13.25 0.000 .8643126 1.164545 bord | .1124194 .0806779 1.39 0.164 -.0457744 .2706132 richjlnpci | .0399937 .0089627 4.46 0.000 .0224196 .0575677 _cons | -42.13194 1.366784 -30.83 0.000 -44.81194 -39.45194

32

Page 33: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

Appendix VI

Table A.4: Fixed-effect regressions using population

Fixed Effect Fixed Effect w/o BRICS

Fixed Effect Europe

lngdpi 2.378301 (0.000)

2.613812 (0.000)

2.04444 (0.000)

lngdpj 2.233647 (0.000)

3.213383 (0.000)

4.319855 (0.000)

lnpopi -1.614999 (0.000)

-4.196301 (0.260)

-7.21433 (0.000)

lnpopj 2.428034 (0.000)

1.06274 (0.000)

5.293708 (0.018)

The population data is taken from the United Nations UNData online database. The population figures are done using 5 year intervals, meaning accurate data are only available for 1990, 1995, 2000 and 2005. The 1990 figures are used for the time period 1990 – 1994. 1995 figures are used for the time period 1995 – 1999. 2000 figures are used for the time period 2000 – 2004. 2005 figures are used for the year 2005 only.

33

Page 34: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

Data Sample References GDP and GDP Per-Capita numbers are taken from the World Bank World Development Indicators Online 2008 (WDI 2008). Export figures taken from SourceOECD ITCS International Trade by Commodities Statistics: Total Trade in Values Vol 2007 release 01.

FDI figures taken from SourceOECD International Direct Investment Statistics: International direct investment by country Vol 2008 release 01.

Population data are taken from the United Nations online statistical source (UNData).

Literary References

Bergstrand, Jeffrey H. “The Gravity Equation in International Trade: Some Microeconomic Foundations and Empirical Evidence”. The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 67, No. 3, (Aug., 1985), pp. 474-481. Bergstrand, Jeffrey H. “The Generalized Gravity Equation, Monopolistic Competition, and the Factor-Proportions Theory in International Trade”. The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 71, No. 1, (Feb., 1989), pp. 143-153. Casson, M. 1990. "The Theory of Foreign Direct Investment." In P. Buckley, ed., InternationalInvestment. Aldershot, England: Edward Elgar Publishing Ltd., pp. 244-73. Ceglowski, Janet. “Does Gravity Matter in a Service Economy?” Review of World Economics, July 2006, Volume 142, Issue 2, pp. 307-329. Cheng, I-Hui and Wall, Howard J. “Controlling for Heterogeneity in Gravity Models of Trade and Integration”. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, January/February 2005, 87(1), pp. 49-63. Dunning, John H. “The Eclectic Paradigm of International Production: A Restatement and Some Possible Extensions”. Journal of International Business Studies, March 1988, Volume 19, Number 1, pp. 1-31. Ekholm, Karolina., Forslid, Rikard., & Markusen, James R. ”Export-Platform Foreign Direct Investment”. NBER Working Paper No. 9517, March 2003. Glick, Reuven and Rosen, Andrew K. “Does a Currency Union Affect Trade? The Time Series Evidence”. NBER Working Paper No. 8396, Jul. 2001.

34

Page 35: The Predictive Capacity of the Gravity Model of Trade on ...

35

Grosse, Robert., and Trevino, Len J. “Foreign Direct Investment in the United States: An Analysis by Country of Origin”. Journal of International Business Studies, March 1996, Volume 27, Number 1, pp. 139-155. Helpman, Elhanan., Melitz, Marc J., & Yeaple, Stephen R. ” Export Versus FDI with Heterogeneous Firms”. American Economic Review, March 2004, Volume 94, Number 1, pp. 300-316. Markusen, James R., Venables, Anthony J., Eby Kohan, Denise., & Zhang, Kevin H. “A Unified Treatment of Horizontal Direct Investment, Vertical Direct Investment, and the Pattern of Trade in Goods and Services”. NBER Working Paper No. 5696, Aug. 1996. Mátyás, Lászlό. “The Gravity Model: Some Econometric Considerations”. The World Economy, May 1998, Volume 21, Number 3, pp. 397-401(5). Mátyás, Lászlό. “Proper Econometric Specification of the Gravity Model”. The World Economy, May 1997, Volume 20, Number 3, pp. 363-368. Singh, Harinder., Jun, Kwang W. ”Some New Evidence on Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment in Developing Countries”. The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 1531, Nov. 1995.

Stijns, Jean-Philippe. “An Empirical Test of the Dutch Disease Hypothesis using a Gravity Model of Trade”. EconWPA International Trade Series No. 0305001, May 2003. (For presentation at the 2003 Congress of the EEA, Stockholm, August 20 to August 24)

Tanaka, Kiyoyasu. “The Relative Importance of Horizontal Versus Vertical FDI: Evidence from Japanese and US Multinational Firms”. University of Hawaii Press, Oct. 2006. (Online Source) Zhang, Kevin H. and Markusen, James R. “Vertical Multinationals and Host-Country Characteristics”. NBER Working Paper No. 6203, Sep. 1997.


Recommended