+ All Categories
Home > Technology > The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute...

The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute...

Date post: 29-Jan-2015
Category:
Upload: andrew-williams-jr-trntv
View: 112 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
Description:
The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford
Popular Tags:
41
Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2207372 Changes in Income Inequality Among U.S. Tax Filers Between 1991 and 2006: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes Thomas L. Hungerford 1 [email protected] January 23, 2013 1 The author thanks Jane Gravelle, Stephen Jenkins, Donald Marples, and Austin Nichols for helpful comments on a previous draft. The views expressed here do not reflect the views of the Congressional Research Service or the Library of Congress.
Transcript
Page 1: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2207372

Changes in Income Inequality Among U.S. Tax Filers

Between 1991 and 2006: The Role of Wages, Capital

Income, and Taxes

Thomas L. Hungerford1

[email protected]

January 23, 2013

1The author thanks Jane Gravelle, Stephen Jenkins, Donald Marples, and Austin Nichols for

helpful comments on a previous draft. The views expressed here do not reflect the views of the

Congressional Research Service or the Library of Congress.

Page 2: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Electronic copy available at: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2207372

Abstract

This paper examines changes in after-tax income inequality among tax filers between1991 and 2006. In particular, how changes in wages, capital income, and tax policy con-tribute to changes in income inequality is investigated. To examine the role of these threepossible contributors to the increase in income inequality, the Gini coefficient is decomposedby income source using the method developed by Lerman and Yitzhaki (1985). The Ginicoefficient of after-tax income increased by 15 percent (0.071 points) between 1991 and 2006.By far, the largest contributor to this increase was changes in income from capital gains anddividends. Changes in wages had an equalizing effect over this period as did changes intaxes. Most of the equalizing effect of taxes took place after the 1993 tax hike; most of theequalizing effect, however, was reversed after the 2001 and 2003 Bush-era tax cuts. Similarresults are obtained with other inequality measures.

Page 3: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

1 Introduction

Social scientists and philosophers have been concerned with issues surrounding the distri-

bution of income or income inequality for over 200 years—for example, the economist and

philosopher Adam Smith (1937) discussed these issues as early as 1776. Academic writers

have been writing on income inequality measurement issues for at least a century.1 Policy

makers have also long been interested in income inequality issues.2 The Obama Administra-

tion has stated that one of its principles for tax reform was to observe the “Buffett rule”—“no

household making over $1 million annually should pay a smaller share of its income in taxes

than middle-class families pay” (OMB 2011).

Arguments are offered for and against rising income inequality. The classic argument

against rising income inequality is the rich get richer and the poor get poorer. This shift can

increase poverty, reduce well-being, and reduce social cohesion. Consequently, some argue

that reducing income inequality may reduce various social ills. Additionally, researchers are

concerned about the consequences of rising income inequality. Research has demonstrated

that large income and class disparities adversely affect health and economic well-being (see,

for example, Marmot 2004, Wilkinson 1996, Frank 2007, Singh and Siahpush 2006).

In contrast, others argue that rising inequality is nothing to worry about and point out

that average real income has been rising, so while the rich are getting richer, the poor are

not necessarily getting poorer. In addition, researchers and policy analysts argue that some

income inequality is necessary to encourage innovation and entrepreneurship—the possibility

of large rewards and high income are incentives to bear the risks (Deere and Welch 2002).

Furthermore, some have argued that income or social mobility (i.e., movement within the

income distribution) reduces income inequality and increases well-being (see, for example,

1For example, the Gini coefficient, which has long played a central role in the measurement of incomeinequality, was developed in 1909 by the Italian statistician and sociologist Corrado Gini.

2For example, distributional issues of wealth and income were part of Senate debate over the War RevenueAct of June 10, 1898. See Senator Richard Pettigrew, Senate debate, Congressional Record, June 10, 1898,pp. 5743–5744. More recently, there have been at least 17 hearings or testimony devoted to aspects ofincome inequality in the 110th, 111th, and 112th Congresses (based on a search of CQ.com).

1

Page 4: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Friedman 1962). Research has shown, however, that income mobility is not very great and

the degree of income mobility has either remained unchanged or decreased since the1970s

(Hungerford 2011, and Bradbury 2011).

CBO (2011) has documented that income inequality has been increasing in the United

States over the past 35 years. Several factors have been identified as possibly contributing

to increasing income inequality. This paper examines changes in after-tax income inequality

among tax filers between 1991 and 2006. In particular, how changes in wages, capital income,

and tax policy contribute to changes in income inequality is investigated. During this period,

there were changes in the sources of income that differed by income category and there were

many changes in tax policy. The years 1991, 1996, 2001, and 2006 are examined.

2 Potential Causes of Increased Income Inequality

Three potential causes of the increase in after-tax income inequality between 1991 and 2006

are examined in the analysis: changes in labor income (wages and salaries), changes in

capital income (interest income, capital gains, dividends, and business income), and changes

in taxes. These are not the only potential reasons for changes in income inequality, but

all are commonly cited as reasons by many observers (e.g., CBO 2011). It is important to

keep in mind, however, these three reasons are not mutually exclusive—a change in labor or

capital income could also affect the amount of taxes paid, which affects observed inequality

of after-tax incomes.

2.1 Changes in Labor Income

Earnings inequality has been increasing since at least the late-1960s (Kopczuk, Saez, and

Song 2010). Part of this has been attributed to increased salaries paid to CEOs, managers,

financial professionals, and athletes, which is estimated to account for 70 percent of the

increase in the share of income going to the richest Americans (Bakija, Cole, and Heim

2

Page 5: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

2010). Such changes in the earnings distribution have been described by some as a move

toward a winner-take-all reward structure—labor markets where the rewards are few but

large with more and more people competing for these rewards (Frank and Cook 1995). In

an elaboration of this argument, some have argued that “public officials have rewritten the

rules of American politics and the American economy in ways that have benefited the few

at the expense of the many” (Hacker and Pierson 2010). This explanation would primarily

affect those at the top of the income distribution. Others have argued that rising returns to

education and skill-biased technological change are the important factors explaining rising

inequality (Bound and Johnson 1992, Autor, Katz, and Kearney 2006, and Lemieux 2006).

Skill-biased technological change would likely affect earnings in the upper part of the earn-

ings distribution. Other explanations for rising earnings inequality would affect different

parts of the income distribution. A declining real minimum wage could affect lower income

tax filers (the inflation-adjusted minimum wage fell from $6.57 per hour in 1996 to $5.57 per

hour in 2006) and declining unionization could affect tax filers in the middle of the earn-

ings distribution (Lee 1999, and DiNardo, Fortin, and Lemieux 1996). Increasing earnings

inequality has been identified as the main suspect behind rising income inequality, since a

large share of total income is from earnings.

Reed and Cancian (2001) found that changes in husband’s earnings was a major source of

rising inequality of family income while changes in female earnings had an equalizing effect

on family income between 1970 and 2000. However, Gottschalk and Danziger (2005), while

also finding that male wage inequality and family income are correlated, conclude that the

correlation “seems to be coincidental.” Overall, it is well understood that wage inequality

has increased since 1979, but how this contributed to increasing income inequality is unclear.

2.2 Changes in Capital Income

The role of capital income and capital gains has recently been thrust into the debate over

increasing income inequality with the Occupy Wall Street movement and proposed legislation

3

Page 6: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

to increase the tax rate on carried interests received by private equity managers. CBO (2011)

documents the increased concentration of business income, capital income, and capital gains

between 1979 and 2007.

Capital income has generally been concentrated among higher-income tax filers. Cap-

ital income can be capital gains, dividends, and business income from partnerships and

S-corporations. The number of partnerships and S-corporations has steadily increased be-

tween 1991 and 2006. The number of partnerships increased by 1.4 million over this period

and the number of S-corporations increased by 2.2 million.3 Income from these types of busi-

ness is reported on an individual tax filer’s tax return and is not subject to the corporate

income tax. An increasing share of income for high-income tax filers is from capital income,

which could be part of the explanation for the rising income of this group of tax filers and

rising income inequality.

It has been shown that the income of the richest 0.1 percent of taxpayers is sensitive to

changes in asset prices and this may have been especially important in the increase in the

income share of those at the top of the income distribution (Bakija, Cole, and Heim 2010).

Fraβdorf, Grabker, and Schwarze (2011) also find that capital income’s share in disposable

income has increased in recent years in the U.S. and show that capital income made a large

contribution to income inequality in relation to its share in income.

2.3 Changes in Taxes

Tax policy has also been identified as a possible cause for rising income inequality (Feenberg

and Poterba 1993, and Gordon and Slemrod 2001). Research suggests that tax policy may

not have much impact on the longer-term trend or rate of change in inequality, but a change

in tax policy can have a one time affect on the level of income inequality (Slemrod and Bakija

2001, Levy and Temin 2007, Piketty and Saez 2003, and Gramlich, Kasten, and Sammartino

1993). Given that tax policy changes on an almost annual basis, the longer-term trend in

3The number of C-corporations fell by less than 150,000 or 6.8 percent. Internal Revenue Services,Statistics of Income, available at www.irs.gov.

4

Page 7: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

income inequality could have been affected by tax policy changes. While the individual

income tax system is progressive and has been since it was introduced in 1913, the trend has

been toward lower marginal tax rates and a less progressive tax system (Piketty and Saez

2007, and Alm, Lee, and Wallace 2005). As a result, the tax system may be less able to

equalize after-tax incomes.

The major tax changes between 1991 and 2006 were (1) the enactment of the Omnibus

Budget and Reconciliation Act of 1993 (OBRA93), which increased the top marginal tax

rate from 31 percent to 39.6 percent, and (2) the enactment of the 2001 and 2003 Bush tax

cuts, which reduced taxes especially for higher-income tax filers. The Bush tax cuts involved

reduced tax rates, the introduction of the 10 percent tax bracket (which reduced taxes for

all taxpayers), reduced the tax rates on long-term capital gains and qualified dividends,

and other changes. In 1991, long-term capital gains were taxed at 28 percent (15 percent for

lower-income taxpayers) and all dividends were taxed as ordinary income. The next year, the

long-term capital gains tax rate was reduced to 20 percent. By 2006, long-term capital gains

and qualified dividends were taxed at 15 percent (5 percent for lower-income taxpayers).

Tax policy changes that affect progressivity will affect after-tax income inequality (Kim and

Lambert 2009, and Hungerford 2010).

The equalizing effect of taxes can change even if there is no change in tax laws. Since the

mid-1980s, many tax parameters have been adjusted for inflation. In general, income tends

to rise faster than prices. Given the progressive nature of the U.S. individual income tax

system, modest bracket creep could lead to taxes having a larger equalizing effect in 2006

than in 1991 as more income is moved into higher tax brackets.

3 Data and Methods

The sources of data are the 1991, 1996, 2001, and 2006 Internal Revenue Service (IRS) Statis-

tics of Income (SOI) Public Use Files. The Public Use Files are nationally representative

5

Page 8: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

samples of tax returns for these tax years. To protect the identity of individual tax filers

while preserving the character of the data, the IRS made changes to the data. Consequently,

while reliable aggregate information can be obtained, individual tax filer records may or

may not contain information from just one tax return. The unit of analysis is the tax return

for a tax filer (which may be a married couple), and IRS-provided sample weights are used

throughout the analysis. The number of sample observations in each income category for

each year are reported in table 1.

The IRS SOI public use files have advantages over other data sources commonly used for

inequality analyses as well as disadvantages. The major advantages are (1) a large sample

of tax filers, with an especially large sample of very high income tax filers, (2) income from

various sources, including capital gains, and federal income taxes are reported, (3) reported

income is not censored as it is in the March Current Population Survey data files, and (4)

reported income is not subject to recall errors as in survey data. The main disadvantages are

non-tax filers are excluded from the sample (primarily low-income individuals and families),

and income from public assistance is not reported. However, since the emphasis of this

study is on after-tax income changes, especially at the top of the income distribution, the

advantages clearly outweigh the disadvantages.

The unit of observation is the tax unit rather than the family. Burkhauser, Feng, Jenkins,

and Lattimore (2012) note that “aggregating income to the household level rather than the

tax unit, and adjusting for economies of scale using an equivalence scale” may yield slightly

different inequality estimates. Hungerford (2010) notes, however, that about 75 percent

of families contain just one tax unit (another 17 percent contain two tax units with the

second tax unit usually a cohabitating adult or a working child that cannot be claimed as

a dependent on another tax return). Consequently, most of the tax units likely represent a

family.

6

Page 9: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

3.1 Income

Equivalence-adjusted gross income from all sources, except public assistance, is used for the

analysis; the equivalence scale is the square root of the total number of exemptions claimed

by the tax unit (excluding additional exemptions for the blind and the elderly). Capital

gains are also included. Piketty and Saez (2003) argue that capital gains are not an annual

flow of income and have large aggregate variations from one year to another; they exclude

capital gains from much of their analysis. Blinder (1980) argues that capital gains should not

be included in income because what is important is real accrued capital gains. Citing work

by Eisner (1980), he points out that realized capital gains represent partial maintenance of

principle in an inflationary world. Eisner examined the period between 1946 and 1977 when

annual inflation averaged almost 4 percent (using the GDP deflator). Between 1991 and

2006, however, annual inflation averaged slightly over 2 percent.

Furthermore, capitals gains have increasingly become an important source of compensa-

tion for corporate executives (through stock options4), and private equity and hedge fund

managers (carried interests). Consequently, income from capital gains is included in the

analysis.

3.2 Taxes

U.S. taxes from all sources should be included in an analysis of the effective tax burden

and this analysis considers the individual income tax, the corporate income tax, and the

payroll tax. But three issues need to be addressed regarding the burden of the corporate

income tax. The first issue is the question of who actually bears the burden of the corporate

income tax. Several recent studies estimate that most or all (in some cases more than 100

percent) of the burden of the corporate income tax falls on labor through reduced wages.

These studies, however, have been shown to suffer from various methodological deficiencies

4A stock option is reported on a tax return as wages and salaries when it is exercised, but when the stockis sold, any gain is reported as capital gains.

7

Page 10: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

(Gravelle and Hungerford 2008; Gravelle 2011). The evidence suggests that most or all of the

burden of the corporate income tax falls on owners of capital. In the analysis, it is assumed

that 100 percent of the corporate income tax falls on capital income (dividends and capital

gains), which mostly affects high-income taxpayers (almost 60 percent of all capital gains

and dividends are received by taxpayers with income over $1 million).

Second, not all of this income is taxed at the corporate level. The Internal Revenue

Service (IRS) reports that a substantial proportion of capital gains and losses (short-term

and long-term) reported by taxpayers are passthrough gains or losses (that is, the income is

not reported on any corporate tax form and passes directly to individual taxpayers to report

on their individual income tax form), gains or losses from the sale of government bonds,

and other assets never taxed at the corporate level (Wilson and Liddell 2011). For example,

hedge funds are generally organized as partnerships. Under current tax law, a partnership

does not pay income taxes; instead gains and losses flow through to the partners who include

it on their income tax returns.

The income from the partnership is often taxed as capital gains or qualified dividends at

reduced tax rates (i.e., 15 percent in 2006). Essentially, if the partnership earns long-term

capital gains or qualified dividends, the income flows through to the partners as long-term

capital gains or qualified dividends and is taxed accordinglythe income is not recharacterized

(e.g., from capital gains to ordinary income) as it passes through from the partnership to the

individual partners. Some partners receive partnership interests in exchange for contributions

of capital (that is, investments) and are referred to as limited partners; some partners receive

partnership interests in exchange for services (carried interests) and these are general partners

who actively manage the partnership. Most of this income is taxed at the reduced long-term

capital gains rate and is not taxed at the corporate level.5 It is assumed that 50 percent of

net capital gains are taxed at the U.S. corporate level as well as the individual level (such

5About 45 percent of net capital gains are from passthrough net gains or a transaction involving part-nership, S-corporation, and estate or trust interests. It is unknown how much of this was from the sale ofcorporate equities.

8

Page 11: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

as corporate stock, mutual funds, and capital gains distributions).6 It is also assumed that

all dividends are taxed at both the corporate and individual levels.7

The third issue concerns the corporate tax rate. The statutory corporate tax rate in 2010

was 39.2 percent, which includes federal and state corporate taxes. However, several studies

estimate the effective corporate tax rate is between 22.2 percent and 27.1 percent (Gravelle

2011). After subtracting out the state corporate tax rate from the highest estimate, it is

assumed that the effective corporate tax rate is 24.2 percent.

Taxes attributed to tax filers that are not directly paid by them (that is, the employer’s

contribution of the payroll tax and corporate taxes) are also imputed to the tax filer as

income. Total income includes income from all sources reported on the 1040 form including

tax-exempt interest and Social Security benefits that are excluded from adjusted gross income

as well as the imputed taxes.

3.3 Inequality Measures

To examine the role of the three explanations for the increase in income inequality, the Gini

coefficient is decomposed by income source using the method developed by Lerman and

Yitzhaki (1985). The contribution of each income source (k = 1, . . . , K) to the overall Gini

coefficient depends on (1) how important the income source is to total income (Sk), (2) how

the income source is distributed (Gk), and (3) how the income source is correlated with total

income (Rk). The overall Gini coefficient (G) can be written as:

G =

K∑

k=1

Sk × Gk × Rk.

If Sk, Gk, or Rk are close to zero, then the particular income source does not make a

significant contribution to income inequality (see Lerman and Yitzhaki 1985 for formulas).

6The results are virtually unchanged if it is assumed that 100 percent of net capital gains are taxed atboth the corporate and individual levels.

7Gale (2002) shows that about half of dividends do not face double taxation. Consequently, this assump-tion will tend to overstate the taxes paid on dividend income.

9

Page 12: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

The change in the Gini coefficient between two years can be decomposed as:

G2− G1 =

K∑

k=1

(S2

k× G2

k× R2

k− S1

k×G1

k× R1

k)

The Gini coefficient is sensitive to income changes in the middle of the income distribution

(at the mode). The generalized Gini (also known as the S-Gini), denoted as G(ν), is a

generalized version of the Gini coefficient with an additional parameter (ν) that can be

varied so as to place more weight on inequality in different parts of the income distribution

(Donaldson and Weymark 1980, 1983; and Yitzhaki 1983). If the value of ν is 2.0, then

the generalized Gini is the familiar Gini coefficient. Values of ν less than 2.0 place more

emphasis on inequality in the upper part of the distribution, while values greater than 2.0

emphasize the lower part of the distribution. In addition to the Gini coefficient (ν = 2.0),

two other values are used (1.5 and 4.0).8 Jackknife standard errors are estimated.

After-tax income is broken down into (1) wages and salaries (including the employer por-

tion of the payroll tax), (2) interest income (taxed and tax exempt), (3) capital gains and

dividends (including corporate income tax paid), (4) net business income (proprietorships,

partnerships, S-corporations, and farms), (5) social insurance (Social Security and unem-

ployment compensation), (6) retirement income (pension income and IRA distributions),

(7) all other income, and (8) federal taxes paid (individual and corporate income taxes, and

employee and employer paid payroll taxes).

3.4 Sensitivity Analysis

The Gini coefficient is not the only inequality that can be decomposed by income source.

Jenkins (1995) provides methods to decompose the coefficient of variation (CV) and half

the square of the CV (GE(2))—the latter is a member of the Generalized Entropy class of

inequality measures.9 The inequality measures (generically denoted by I) can be written as:

8The Stata command (sgini) used for the estimation was developed by Philippe Van Kerm (2009).9Stephen Jenkins has developed a Stata command (ineqfac) to perform the decomposition.

10

Page 13: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

I =K∑

k=1

Fk

where Fk is the absolute contribution of income source k to overall inequality. The change

in the inequality measure can be written as the sum of the changes of the contributions of

the income sources:

I2− I1 =

K∑

k=1

(F 2

k− F 1

k).

4 Results

The trend in after-tax income inequality as measured by the S-Gini is reported in table 2.

The first column reports the estimated Gini coefficient (i.e., ν = 2.0). The Gini coefficient

steadily climbed from 0.468 in 1991 to 0.539 in 2006—an increase of 15.2 percent. The next

two columns report the values of the S-Gini for ν = 1.5 (relative weight at the top of the

income distribution) and ν = 4.0 (relative weight at the bottom of the income distribution).

The S-Gini with ν = 1.5 increased by 23 percent between 1991 and 2006 (from 0.330 to

0.406), while the S-Gini with ν = 4.0 increased by 5.2 percent over this period. These

results are consistent with research showing that the rise in income inequality is due to

changes at the top of the income distribution rather than to changes at the bottom (e.g.,

Piketty and Saez 2003).

4.1 Income Shares by Income Source

The share of after-tax income accounted for by the various income sources (taxes are con-

sidered a negative income source) are reported in table 3.10 Wages are by far the largest

source of income, but accounted for a smaller share of income in 2006 (77 percent) than in

1991 (92 percent). In addition, the wage share appears to be counter-cyclical—the share

10The full set of basic estimation results are reported appendix tables A.1-A.3.

11

Page 14: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

is higher in the recession years of 1991 and 2001 than in the expansion years of 1996 and

2006. Interestingly, the decline in the wage share during the economic recovery after the

2001 recession (2001 to 2006) was considerably larger than the decline during the years after

the 1990–91 recession (13 percentage points versus 4 percentage points).

The next three rows of the table show the income shares of capital income. Interest

income as a share of total after-tax income fell by over half between 1991 and 2006, with

most of the decline occurring between 1991 and 1996. Capital gains and dividends as a

share of income increased from 5.4 percent in 1991 to 15.6 percent in 2006—a 287 percent

increase. The capital gains and dividends share appears to be pro-cyclical, increasing during

the expansions and falling during recessions. Business income also greatly increased as a

share of income between 1991 and 2006 by 265 percent (from less than 2 percent in 1991 to

over 5 percent in 2006). There does not appear to be a strong cyclical pattern to the trend

in the business income share. Overall, income from capital increased as a share of income

from 16.7 percent to over one-quarter over this 15-year period.

The income share of federal taxes (including individual and corporate income taxes as

well as the payroll tax) declined (in absolute value) from −28.4 percent in 1991 to −25.5

percent by 2006. The income share, however, increased (i.e., became more negative) in the

intervening years. The next three rows of table 3 separate federal taxes in three components.

The negative income share of individual income taxes increased between 1991 and 1996, most

likely due to the tax hikes contained in OBRA93. The share was essentially constant between

1996 and 2001. The income share fell (in absolute value) between 2001 and 2006 due to the

rate reductions contained in the 2001 and 2003 Bush tax cuts.11 The income share of the

corporate income tax (in absolute value) follows the same trend as for capital gains and

dividends since were no changes in the corporate tax rate during this 15-year period. The

income share (in absolute value) of the payroll tax follows the same trend as for wages.

11The Bush tax cuts were enacted by the Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001(EGTRRA) and the Jobs and Growth Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2003 (JGTRRA).

12

Page 15: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

4.2 Contributions to Income Inequality by Income Source

The contribution of each income to overall income inequality is reported in tables 4–6. Table

4 reports the results for the Gini coefficient (ν = 2.0). In each year, wages make the largest

contribution to the overall Gini coefficient, though the share of wages in inequality is less than

its share in income (compare to table 3). The contribution of wages to the Gini coefficient

fell between 1991 and 2006 (from 0.774 to 0.600). A 1 percent increase in wages, all else

equal, would reduce the 1991 Gini coefficient by 0.15 percent and the 2006 Gini coefficient

by 0.17 percent.12

In 1991, of the three capital income sources, capital gains and dividends made the largest

contribution to income inequality (with an inequality share of 0.146), followed by interest

income, and lastly by business income. A 1 percent increase in each of the sources (one at

a time) would increase the Gini coefficient by 0.025 percent (for interest income) to 0.092

percent (for capital gains and dividends). By 2006, the contribution of capital gains and

dividends to income inequality almost doubled to 0.280 while the contribution of interest

income fell by half to 0.059. The inequality share of business income increased modestly

to 0.105. Increasing each of the capital income sources by 1 percent, all else equal, would

increase the Gini coefficient by 0.016 percent for interest income, by 0.124 percent for capital

gains and dividends, and by 0.053 percent for business income.

Taxes subtract from income and, consequently, account for a negative share of income

and inequality. Total federal taxes had a −0.328 income inequality share in 1991. After the

OBRA93 tax increase the inequality share of federal taxes increased in absolute value to

−0.370 (that is, had a larger equalizing effect). The inequality share fell after the enactment

of the 2001 and 2003 Bush tax cuts to −0.305 by 2006. A 1 percent increase in taxes,

all else equal, would have reduced the Gini coefficient by about 0.04 percent in 1991 and

by 0.5 percent in 2006. In 1996, after the enactment of the OBRA93 tax increases, a 1

12The marginal effect is equal to the difference between the inequality share and the income share of anincome source.

13

Page 16: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

percent increase in federal taxes would have reduced the Gini coefficient by slightly over

0.07 percent. Individual income taxes in 2006 accounted for the smallest income inequality

share (in absolute terms) of the four years—the 15-year pattern for individual income taxes

is what would be expected with the enactment of OBRA93 (increased absolute inequality

share) and the Bush tax cuts (decreased absolute inequality share). Since the payroll tax is

regressive above the maximum taxable income limit, a 1 percent increase would lead to an

increase in the Gini coefficient of about 0.03 percent in each of the four years.

The next two tables, table 5 and table 6, show the results for the generalized Gini (S-

Gini) for ν = 1.5 (table 5) and ν = 4.0 (table 6). Wages contributed a smaller share to the

overall S-Gini when the relative weight on inequality at the top of the income distribution

is increased (ν = 1.5) compared to the bottom of the income distribution (ν = 4.0). But a

1 percent increase in wages has a larger negative effect on the S-Gini when ν = 1.5 (G(1.5))

than when ν = 4.0 (G(4.0)). Capital income is a much more important contributor to the

S-Gini when the aversion to inequality is lower (ν = 1.5).

Lastly, the negative influence of federal taxes is larger when ν = 1.5 than when ν = 4.0.

In 2001 (before the Bush tax cuts), a 1 percent increase in individual income taxes would

reduce the G(1.5) by about 0.1 percent and the G(4.0) by 0.05 percent. In 2006 after the

enactment of the Bush tax cuts, a 1 percent increase in individual income taxes would reduce

the G(1.5) by 0.08 percent and the G(4.0) by about 0.05 percent. This is consistent with

the argument that changes to the income tax system by the Bush tax cuts generally favored

taxpayers at the top of the income distribution.

The contributions of the various income sources to the change in the Gini coefficient

between 1991 and 2006 are reported in table 7. Between 1991 and 2006 the Gini coefficient

increase by 0.071 points or 15 percent (see the last row of table 7). The Gini coefficient

increased over each of the 5-year sub periods examined at what appears to be an accelerating

pace. Between 1991 and 1996, the Gini coefficient increased by 0.012 points, which is about

17 percent of the total 15-year increase. The increase in the Gini was 0.023 points between

14

Page 17: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

1996 and 2001, and was 0.036 points between 2001 and 2006. The latter 5-year sub period

accounts for half of the 15-year increase in the Gini coefficient.

The change in wages’ share of inequality was negative over the 1991 to 2006 period.

Consequently, changes in wages had an equalizing effect on income inequality (i.e., reduced

the Gini coefficient). Most of the equalizing effect occurs over the final 5-year sub-period.

Changes in capital gains and dividends are the largest contributor to the rise in income

inequality over the 15-year period, with most occurring between 2001 and 2006. Changes

in taxes had an equalizing effect on overall inequality between 1991 and 2006. Most of this

equalizing effect occurred between 1991 and 1996 due the OBRA93 tax increase; the 2001

and 2003 Bush tax cuts had a disequalizing effect between 2001 and 2006.

The effects of changes in the inequality share of various income sources on the change

in the S-Ginis are reported in table 8. The change in the inequality share of wages is

considerably larger when ν = 4.0 than when ν = 1.5 implying wages had a greater equalizing

effect when weight is on income inequality at the bottom of the income distribution. Changes

in capital gains and dividends has a greater relative disequalizing effect when ν = 4.0 than

when ν = 1.5. Changes in federal taxes has a small disequalizing effect when ν = 4.0 and an

equalizing effect when ν = 1.5. The former disequalizing effect is due to changes in payroll

taxes, which likely reflects changes in wages since the payroll tax rate remained constant.

4.3 Sensitivity Analysis

Between 1991 and 2006, both the coefficient of variation (CV) and half the square of the CV

(GE(2)) steadily increased (see table 9). This is roughly the same pattern as with the Gini

coefficient (compare to table 2). The CV increased by 105.6 percent over this period and

the GE(2) increased by 322.9 percent.

Table 10 reports the contribution of the various income sources to the increase in the CV

and GE(2) between 1991 and 2006 (compare to the last two columns of table 7 for the Gini

coefficient). The results for the CV and the GE(2) are broadly consistent with one another

15

Page 18: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

and somewhat consistent with the results for the Gini coefficient. Changes in wages makes

a relatively small contribution to the increase in the CV and the GE(2) between 1991 and

2006. Changes in wages had a modest equalizing affect on inequality as measured by the

Gini coefficient.

Changes in capital gains and dividend income account for over 100 percent of the in-

crease in both the CV and the GE(2)—the same result as with the Gini coefficient. The

contributions of interest income and business income are much smaller, and not particularly

comparable to the Gini coefficient results (reported in table 7). Changes in interest income

had a slight equalizing effect on the CV and almost no effect on the GE(2), which is in

contract to the modest to large equalizing effect on the S-Gini.

Regardless of the choice of inequality measure, overall federal taxes had a modest equal-

izing effect. The equalizing effect is due to both the individual and corporate income taxes;

payroll taxes contributed relatively little to the change in measured inequality (and often

had a disequalizing effect).

5 Simulations

To further investigate the sources of income inequality changes, a series of simulations are

performed. The basic idea of the simulations is to hold either the components of the Lerman-

Yitzhaki decomposition constant (income source shares, income source inequality, or income

source correlations), or tax law constant between two years.

5.1 Decomposition Components

The method decomposes each income source’s contribution to the Gini coefficient into three

terms, each of which change from year to year. To focus on what changes between 2006

and earlier years occurred that contributed to the increase in the Gini coefficient, a series of

simulations are performed. The simulations involve replacing the vector of Sks, Gks, or Rks

16

Page 19: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

in the calculation of the 2006 Gini coefficient with prior year values (1991, 1996, or 2001).

The results are reported in table 11.

The first entry on the table—0.4636—is the simulated Gini for 2006 using the 1991 vector

of Sks (the importance of each income source to total income). The simulated Gini is 14

percent less than the actual 2006 Gini coefficient of 0.5389. The other two entries in the first

column of numbers are the simulated Gini coefficient using the vector of Sks for 1996 and

2001. In each case, the simulated Gini is lower than the actual Gini coefficient. The lower

simulated Gini is primarily due to three sources of income: capital gains and dividends, net

business income, and taxes. Using the prior years values of Sk yields a smaller contribution

to the total Gini (that is, less disequalizing) for capital gains and dividends, and net business

income. In 1991, 1996, and 1996 capital income was a less important source of total income

than in 2006. Taxes make a greater equalizing contribution with the prior year Sks because

taxes were a more important negative source of after-tax income in the three earlier years.

The second column of numbers in table 11 report the simulated 2006 Gini coefficients

using the prior values of the Gks (the distribution of each income source). In each case, the

simulated Gini is larger than the actual 2006 Gini coefficient though the simulated Gini using

the 1996 vector of Gks is very close to the actual Gini. The simulated Gini using the 1991

vector is 25 percent larger than the actual. By far the largest contributor to the difference

between the simulated and actual Gini is capital gains and dividends, which accounted

for two-thirds of the difference. Net business income accounted for about 30 percent of

the difference. Changes in the distribution of capital income account for almost all of the

difference when the 1991 and 2001 vectors are used. Capital income appears to be more

unequally distributed in recession years than in expansion years (though capital income is a

more important source of income in expansion years).

The final column of table 11 reports the simulated Gini coefficients using prior year values

of Rk—the correlation of each income source with total income. Overall, the simulated Gini

coefficients are close to the actual Gini when the 1996 and 2001 vector is used. When the

17

Page 20: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

1991 vector of Rks is used the difference is primarily due to capital gains and dividends and

retirement income, both of which were less correlated with total income in 1991 than in 2006.

5.2 Tax Law

To investigate the role of tax policy as distinct from bracket creep an additional simulation is

performed: federal individual income taxes were calculated for 1991 and 2006 taxpayers using

NBER’s TAXSIM program using 1991 tax laws.13 The Lerman-Yitzhaki decomposition of

the Gini coefficient is estimated. Holding tax law constant at the 1991 parameters almost

doubled the equalizing effect of individual income taxes on the Gini coefficient (see table 7

for the equalizing effect). Bracket creep as well as the increasing concentration of income at

the top of the income distribution account for a fairly significant change in the equalizing

effect of individual income taxes. Tax policy changes between 1991 and 2006 appear to have

had a disequalizing effect on the Gini coefficient.

Two major tax changes occurred between 1991 and 2006 that has opposite effects on

income inequality. The simulations were repeated to focus on (1) the 1991 to 1996 period

to isolate the effect of OBRA93, and (2) the 2001 to 2006 period to isolate the effects of

the 2001 and 2003 Bush tax cuts. Holding tax law constant at the 1991 parameters reduces

the equalizing effect of the individual income tax between 1991 and 1996 by 39 percent,

suggesting that bracket creep accounted for about 60 percent of the equalizing effect of the

individual income tax.

Individual income taxes had a disequalizing effect between 2001 and 2006 (see table 7).

Holding tax law constant at the 2001 parameters actually leads to individual income taxes

having an equalizing effect (for a −136 percent change in the disequalizing effect). Bracket

creep between 2001 and 2006 would have produced a smaller Gini coefficient, which was

more than offset by the tax law changes between 2001 and 2006.

13See Feenberg and Coutts (1993) for a description of the TAXSIM program.

18

Page 21: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

6 Discussion and Concluding Remarks

The Gini coefficient of after-tax income increased by 15 percent (0.071 points) between 1991

and 2006. Other measures income inequality also increased significantly between 1991 and

2006. The coefficient of variation increased by about 106 percent while half the square of

the coefficient of variation increased by over 300 percent. Potential contributors to this

increase in after-tax income inequality among taxpayers are examined: changes in wages,

capital income, and taxes. Some of the changes between 1991 and 2006 appear to be due to

economic factors—the contribution of wages to income inequality is countercyclical (higher

in recessions, lower during the recovery) while that of capital gains and dividends appears

to be cyclical.

Changes in Labor Income. Changes in wages over this 20-year period had an equalizing

effect on the Gini coefficient. Although wages are slightly more unequally distributed than

after-tax income, the share of wages in after-tax income decreased from 92 percent in 1991

to 77 percent by 2006. Wages had no or a small disequalizing effect when other incequality

measures are used. Overall, changes in labor income does not appear to be a significant

source of increased income inequality between 1991 and 2006.

Changes in Capital Income. By far, the largest contributor to increasing income inequal-

ity (regardless of income inequality measure) was changes in income from capital gains and

dividends. Capital gains and dividends were less equally distributed in 1991 than in 2006,

though highly unequally distributed in both years. The large increase in the contribution of

capital gains and dividends to the Gini coefficient, however, is due to the large increase in

the share of after-tax income from capital gains and dividends, and to the increase in the

correlation of this income source with after-tax income.

Changes in Taxes. Federal individual and corporate income taxes had an equalizing

effect on inequality regardless of the inequality measure. Federal taxes had a slightly greater

equalizing effect in 2006 than in 1991—taxes appear to have been slightly more progressive

in 2006 than in 1991. The top marginal tax rate in 1991 was 31 percent compared to 35

19

Page 22: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

percent in 2006; the lowest tax marginal rate was 15 percent in 1991 and 10 percent in 2006.

However, the increased equalizing effect of the individual income tax is likely due to bracket

creep—more income is taxed at the highest rates—than to tax law changes. Tax policy

changes appear to have played a direct role: OBRA93 tended to have an equalizing effect

on after-tax income while the 2001 and 2003 Bush tax cuts tended to have a disequalizing

effect.

Tax policy may have also have had an indirect effect on rising income inequality, especially

between 2001 and 2006. The reduction in the tax rate on long-term capital gains and qualified

dividends may have led to the increased importance of this source in after-tax income. This

could work through two possible mechanisms. First, some researchers have found that capital

gains realizations are fairly sensitive to the capital gains tax rate (see Dowd, McClelland and

Muthitacharoen 2012 for a recent example). Others, however, conclude there is little basis

for this mechanism (see, for example, Burman 1999). Second, lower capital gains tax rates

may be part of a change in the institutional structure that increased the gains to bargaining

or rent extraction by CEOs and managers (see, for example, Hacker and Pierson 2010, and

Picketty, Saez and Stantcheva 2011).

20

Page 23: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

References

Alm, J., F. Lee, and S. Wallace (2005). How fair? changes in federal income taxation and the

distribution of income, 1978 to 1998. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management 24 (1),

5–22.

Autor, D. H., L. F. Katz, and M. S. Kearney (2006). The polarization of the U.S. labor

market. American Economic Review, papers and proceedings 96 (2), 189–194.

Bakija, J., A. Cole, and B. T. Heim (2010). Jobs and income growth of top earners and

the causes of changing income inequality: Evidence from U.S. tax return data. Working

paper, Williams College.

Blinder, A. S. (1980). The level and distribution of economic well-being. In M. Feldstein

(Ed.), The American Economy, pp. 415–479. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Bound, J. and G. Johnson (1992). Changes in the structure of wages in the 1980s: An

evaluation of alternative explanations. American Economic Review 82 (3), 371–392.

Bradbury, K. (2011). Trends in U.S. family income mobility, 1969–2006. Working paper no.

11-10, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston.

Burkhauser, R. V., S. Feng, S. P. Jenkins, and J. Larrimore (2012). Recent trends in top

income shares in the united states: Reconciling estimates from March CPS and IRS tax

return data. Review of Economics and Statistics 94 (2), 371–388.

Burman, L. E. (1999). The Labyrinth of Capital Gains Tax Policy. Washington, DC: Brook-

ings Institution Press.

Congressional Budget Office (2011). Trends in the distribution of household income between

1979 and 2007. Technical report, Washington.

Deere, D. R. and F. Welch (2002). Inequality, incentives, and opportunity. Social Philosophy

and Policy 19 (1), 84–109.

21

Page 24: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

DiNardo, J., N. M. Fortin, and T. Lemieux (1996). Labor market institutions and the

distribution of wages, 1973-1992: A semiparametric approach. Econometrica 64 (5), 1001–

1044.

Dowd, T., R. McClelland, and A. Muthitacharoen (2012). New evidence on the tax elasticity

of capital gains. Working paper no. 2012-09, Congressional Budget Office.

Eisner, R. (1980). Capital gains and income: Real changes in the value of capital in the

United States, 1946–1977. In D. Usher (Ed.), The Measurement of Capital, pp. 175–346.

Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Feenberg, D. and E. Coutts (1993). An introduction to the TAXSIM model. Journal of

Policy Analysis and Management 12 (1), 189–194.

Feenberg, D. R. and J. M. Poterba (1993). Income inequality and the incomes of very high-

income taxpayers: Evidence from tax returns. In J. M. Poterba (Ed.), Tax Policy and the

Economy, Volume 7. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Frabdorf, A., M. M. Grabker, and J. Schwarze (2011). The impact of household capital

income on income inequality—a factor decomposition analysis for the UK, Germany and

the USA. Journal of Economic Inequality 9, 35–56.

Frank, R. (2007). Falling Behind: How Rising Inequality Hurts the Middle-Class. Berkeley,

CA: University of California Press.

Frank, R. H. and P. J. Cook (1995). The Winner-Take-All Society. New York: The Free

Press.

Friedman, M. (1962). Capitalism and Freedom. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Gale, W. G. (2002). About half of dividend payments do not face double taxation. Tax

Notes 97 (6), 839.

22

Page 25: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Gordon, R. and J. Slemrod (2000). Are “real” responses to taxes simply income shifting

between corporate and personal tax bases? In J. Slemrod (Ed.), Does Atlas Shrug? The

Economic Consequences of Taxing the Rich, pp. 240–280. New York and Cambridge, MA:

Russell Sage Foundation and Harvard University Press.

Gottschalk, P. and S. Danziger (2005). Inequality of wage rates, earnings and family income

in the United States, 1975-2002. Review of Income and Wealth 51 (2), 231–254.

Gramlich, E. M., R. Kasten, and F. Sammartino (1993). Growing inequality in the 1980s:

The role of federal taxes and cash transfers. In S. Danziger and P. Gottschalk (Eds.),

Uneven Tides: Rising Inequality in America, pp. 225–249. New York: Russell Sage Foun-

dation.

Gravelle, J. C. (2011a). Corporate tax incidence: A review of empirical estimates and

analysis. CBO working paper 2011-01.

Gravelle, J. G. (2011b). International corporate tax rate comparisons and policy implications.

CRS report R41743.

Gravelle, J. G. and T. L. Hungerford (2008). Corporate tax reform: Should we really believe

the research? Tax Notes 121 (4), 419–438.

Hacker, J. S. and P. Pierson (2010). Winner-Take-All Politics. New York: Simon and

Schuster, Inc.

Haig, R. M. (1921). The concept of income—economic and legal aspects. In R. Haig (Ed.),

The Federal Income Tax, pp. 1–28. New York: Columbia University Press.

Hungerford, T. L. (2010). The redistributive effect of selected federal transfer and tax

provisions. Public Finance Review 38 (4), 450–472.

Hungerford, T. L. (2011). How income mobility affects income inequality: US evidence in

the 1980s and the 1990s. Journal of Income Distribution 20 (1), 83–103.

23

Page 26: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Jenkins, S. P. (1995). Accounting for inequality trends: Decomposition analysis for the UK,

1971-86. Economica 62 (245), 29–63.

Kim, K. and P. J. Lambert (2009). Redistributive effect of U.S. taxes and public transfers,

1994–2004. Public Finance Review 37 (1), 3–26.

Kopczuk, W., E. Saez, and J. Song (2010). Earnings inequality and mobility in the

United States: Evidence from social security data since 1937. Quarterly Journal of Eco-

nomics 125 (1), 91–128.

Lee, D. S. (1999). Wage inequality in the United States during the 1980s: Rising dispersion

or falling minimum wage? Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (3), 977–1023.

Lemieux, T. (2006). Postsecondary education and increasing wage inequality. American

Economic Review, papers and proceedings 96 (2), 195–199.

Lerman, R. I. and S. Yitzhaki (1985). Income inequality effects by income source: A new

approach and applications to the United States. Review of Economics and Statistics 67 (1),

151–156.

Levy, F. and P. Temin (2007). Inequality and institutions in 20th century America. Working

paper no. 13106, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Marmot, M. (2004). The Status Syndrome: How Social Standing Affects Our Health and

Longevity. New York: Henry Holt and Co.

Office of Management and Budget (2011). Living within our means and investing in the

future. Technical report.

Piketty, T. and E. Saez (2003). Income inequality in the United States, 1913–1998. Quarterly

Journal of Economics 118 (1), 1–39.

Piketty, T. and E. Saez (2007). How progressive is the U.S. federal tax system? a historical

and international perspective. Journal of Economic Perspectives 21 (1), 3–24.

24

Page 27: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Piketty, T., E. Saez, and S. Stantcheva (2011). Optimal taxation of top labor incomes: A

tale of three elasticities. Working paper no. 17616, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Reed, D. and M. Cancian (2001). Sources of inequality: Measuring the contributions of

income sources to rising family income inequality. Review of Income and Wealth 47 (3),

321–333.

Simons, H. C. (1938). Personal Income Taxation: The Definition of Income as a Problem

of Fiscal Policy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Singh, G. K. and M. Siahpush (2006). Widening socioeconomic inequalities in US life ex-

pectancy, 1980–2000. International Journal of Epidemiology 35, 969–979.

Slemrod, J. and J. M. Bakija (2001). Growing inequality and decreased tax progressivity.

In K. A. Hassett and R. G. Hubbard (Eds.), Inequality and Tax Policy, pp. 192–226.

Washington, DC: AEI Press.

Smith, A. (1937). The Wealth of Nations (Cannan ed.). New York: The Modern Library.

Van Kerm, P. (2010). sgini—generalized gini and concentration coefficients (with factor

decomposition) in stata. Technical report, CEPS/INSTEAD.

Wilkinson, R. (1996). Unhealthy Societies: The Afflictions of Inequality. New York: Rout-

ledge.

Wilson, J. and P. Liddell (2010, Winter). Sales of capital assets reported on individual tax

returns, 2007. Statistics of Income Bulletin, 75–104.

25

Page 28: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Table 1: Sample Observations by Income Category

1991 1996 2001 2006

Bottom Quintile 13,664 12,270 18,978 14,971Second Quintile 8,376 9,244 10,339 11,294Third Quintile 9,551 9,849 11,063 12,473Fourth Quintile 11,485 11,215 12,093 13,499p81-p90 7,991 6,863 7,341 9,391p91-p95 6,241 5,389 6,361 9,140p96-p99 14,399 13,308 16,140 21,787p99.1-p99.9 17,819 17,523 24,944 31,575Top 0.1% 18,523 19,569 24,260 11,687Total 108,049 105,230 132,519 135,817

26

Page 29: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Table 2: Trends in the S-Gini, 1991-2006

Gini (ν = 2.0) S-Gini (ν = 1.5) S-Gini (ν = 4.0)

1991 0.468 0.330 0.7051996 0.480 0.348 0.6882001 0.503 0.366 0.7302006 0.539 0.406 0.742

27

Page 30: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Table 3: Income Shares, 1991, 1996, 2001, and 2006

1991 1996 2001 2006

Wages 92.32 88.77 90.18 77.11Interest Income 9.34 5.99 5.26 4.21Capital gains/dividends 5.42 11.26 7.65 15.57Business Income 1.96 3.39 3.82 5.20Social Insurance 4.93 4.25 4.71 5.58Retirement 9.47 10.84 12.95 13.31Other Income 4.94 5.08 5.03 4.51Federal Taxes −28.38 −29.58 −29.59 −25.49Individual Income Taxes −14.70 −16.10 −16.25 −13.22Corporate Income Taxes −1.13 −1.59 −1.39 −2.08Payroll Taxes −12.55 −11.89 −11.94 −10.20Total 100.00 100.00 100.00 100.00

All estimates are statistically significant at the 1 percent level.

28

Page 31: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Table 4: Contributions to Gini Coefficient (ν = 2.0) by Income Source

1991 1996 2001 2006

Share of Marginal Share of Marginal Share of Marginal Share of MarginalIncome Effect Income Effect Income Effect Income Effect

Inequality on Gini Inequality on Gini Inequality on Gini Inequality on Gini

Wages 0.774 −0.149 0.751 −0.137 0.747 −0.154 0.600 −0.172Interest Income 0.118 0.025 0.081 0.022 0.065 0.013 0.059 0.016Capital gains/dividends 0.146 0.092 0.211 0.098 0.188 0.111 0.280 0.124Business Income 0.062 0.042 0.080 0.046 0.090 0.052 0.105 0.053Social Insurance 0.039 −0.011 0.041 −0.001 0.041 −0.006 0.037 −0.019Retirement 0.111 0.017 0.133 0.024 0.157 0.028 0.167 0.034Other Income 0.078 0.028 0.073 0.022 0.067 0.016 0.058 0.013Federal Taxes −0.328 −0.044 −0.370 −0.074 −0.355 −0.059 −0.305 −0.050Individual Income Taxes −0.212 −0.065 −0.251 −0.090 −0.244 −0.081 −0.200 −0.067Corporate Income Taxes −0.018 −0.007 −0.027 −0.011 −0.022 −0.008 −0.034 −0.014Payroll Taxes −0.098 0.028 −0.091 0.028 −0.089 0.030 −0.071 0.031

All estimates are statistically significant at the 1 percent level.

29

Page 32: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Table 5: Contributions to S-Gini (ν = 1.5) by Income Source

1991 1996 2001 2006

Share of Marginal Share of Marginal Share of Marginal Share of MarginalIncome Effect Income Effect Income Effect Income Effect

Inequality on Gini Inequality on Gini Inequality on Gini Inequality on Gini

Wages 0.726 −0.197 0.692 −0.195 0.701 −0.200 0.542 −0.229Interest Income 0.135 0.042 0.091 0.031 0.074 0.022 0.065 0.023Capital gains/dividends 0.165 0.111 0.252 0.139 0.217 0.141 0.328 0.172Business Income 0.072 0.053 0.094 0.061 0.104 0.066 0.121 0.069Social Insurance 0.034 −0.015 0.036 −0.006 0.035 −0.012 0.029 −0.027Retirement 0.117 0.022 0.136 0.028 0.163 0.033 0.166 0.033Other Income 0.084 0.035 0.078 0.027 0.071 0.021 0.060 0.015Federal Taxes −0.334 −0.050 −0.380 −0.084 −0.366 −0.070 −0.311 −0.056Individual Income Taxes −0.225 −0.078 −0.268 −0.107 −0.260 −0.098 −0.210 −0.078Corporate Income Taxes −0.022 −0.011 −0.033 −0.017 −0.027 −0.013 −0.040 −0.020Payroll Taxes −0.087 0.038 −0.079 0.040 −0.078 0.041 −0.060 0.042

All estimates are statistically significant at the 1 percent level.

30

Page 33: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Table 6: Contributions to S-Gini (ν = 4.0) by Income Source

1991 1996 2001 2006

Share of Marginal Share of Marginal Share of Marginal Share of MarginalIncome Effect Income Effect Income Effect Income Effect

Inequality on Gini Inequality on Gini Inequality on Gini Inequality on Gini

Wages 0.808 −0.115 0.820 −0.067 0.787 −0.115 0.667 −0.104Interest Income 0.090 −0.003 0.066 0.006 0.049 −0.003 0.048 0.006Capital gains/dividends 0.138 0.084 0.165 0.053 0.170 0.094 0.225 0.070Business Income 0.058 0.038 0.067 0.033 0.079 0.041 0.090 0.038Social Insurance 0.042 −0.007 0.045 0.002 0.046 −0.001 0.048 −0.007Retirement 0.098 0.003 0.120 0.012 0.137 0.007 0.156 0.023Other Income 0.071 0.022 0.067 0.016 0.059 0.009 0.054 0.009Federal Taxes −0.305 −0.021 −0.351 −0.055 −0.327 −0.031 −0.288 −0.033Individual Income Taxes −0.186 −0.039 −0.224 −0.064 −0.210 −0.048 −0.177 −0.045Corporate Income Taxes −0.013 −0.001 −0.020 −0.005 −0.016 −0.002 −0.026 −0.006Payroll Taxes −0.107 0.019 −0.106 0.013 −0.100 0.019 −0.084 0.018

All estimates are statistically significant at the 1 percent level.

31

Page 34: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Table 7: Source Contributions to Change in Gini Coefficient (ν = 2.0)

1991-1996 1996-2001 2001-2006 1991-2006

4SkGkRk % Total 4SkGkRk % Total 4SkGkRk % Total 4SkGkRk % Total

Wages −0.002 −16.8 0.016 67.5 −0.053 −148.9 −0.039 −55.3Interest Income −0.016 −136.1 −0.006 −26.5 −0.001 −3.6 −0.024 −33.4Capital gains/dividends 0.033 278.2 −0.007 −29.5 0.056 158.4 0.083 116.5Business Income 0.009 77.3 0.007 30.8 0.011 31.2 0.028 38.8Social Insurance 0.002 14.3 0.001 3.0 −0.001 −2.0 0.002 2.4Retirement 0.012 96.6 0.015 65.4 0.011 31.2 0.038 53.5Other Income −0.001 −11.8 −0.001 −6.0 −0.002 −6.7 −0.005 −7.3Federal Taxes −0.024 −202.5 −0.001 −4.7 0.014 40.4 −0.011 −15.2Individual Income Taxes −0.021 −179.8 −0.002 −8.1 0.015 42.1 −0.008 −11.7Corporate Income Taxes −0.005 −38.7 0.002 7.7 −0.007 −20.2 −0.010 −14.1Payroll Taxes 0.002 16.0 −0.001 −4.3 0.007 18.5 0.008 10.6Total 0.012 100.0 0.023 100.0 0.036 100.0 0.071 100.0

All estimates are statistically significant at the 1 percent level.

32

Page 35: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Table 8: Income Source Contributions to Change in S-Gini, 1991-2006

ν = 1.5 ν = 4.0

4SkGkRk % Total 4SkGkRk % Total

Wages −0.020 −28.9 −0.075 −202.7Interest Income −0.018 −24.5 −0.028 −75.6Capital gains/dividends 0.078 104.4 0.070 189.4Business Income 0.025 33.4 0.026 69.9Social Insurance 0.000 0.5 0.006 16.5Retirement Income 0.029 38.2 0.046 126.0Other Income −0.004 −4.6 −0.010 −27.6Federal Taxes −0.016 −20.6 0.002 4.3Individual Income Taxes −0.011 −14.4 −0.001 −1.6Corporate Income Taxes −0.009 −12.1 −0.011 −28.7Payroll Taxes 0.004 6.0 0.013 34.4Total 0.075 100.0 0.037 100.0

All estimates are statistically significant at the 1 percent level.

33

Page 36: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Table 9: Trends in the Alternative Inequality Measures, 1991-2006

CV GE(2)

1991 3.445 5.9351996 4.386 9.6182001 5.568 15.5032006 7.085 25.098

34

Page 37: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Table 10: Income Source Contributions to Change in AlternativeInequality Measures, 1991-2006

CV GE(2)

4Fk % Total 4Fk % Total

Wages 0.058 1.6 1.275 6.6Interest Income −0.367 −10.1 0.155 0.8Capital gains/dividends 4.376 120.2 19.197 100.2Business Income 0.156 4.3 1.805 9.4Social Insurance −0.004 −0.1 0.002 0.0Retirement Income 0.010 0.3 0.215 1.1Other Income 0.016 0.4 0.429 2.2Federal Taxes −0.606 −16.6 −3.915 −20.4Individual Income Taxes −0.306 −8.4 −2.449 −12.8Corporate Income Taxes −0.306 −8.4 −1.428 −7.4Payroll Taxes 0.006 0.2 −0.037 −0.2Total 3.640 100.0 19.164 100.0

35

Page 38: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Table 11: Simulated 2006 Gini Coefficient

Using First Year Values for

First Year Sk Gk Rk First Year Gini

1991 0.4636 0.6662 0.4832 0.46801996 0.4958 0.5402 0.5203 0.47992001 0.4815 0.6203 0.5135 0.5033

Actual 2006 Gini Coefficient is 0.5389.

36

Page 39: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Table A.1: Basic Estimation Results (ν = 1.5)

1991 1996

Sk Gk Rk Sk Gk Rk

Wages 0.9232 0.3575 0.7269 0.8877 0.3686 0.7367Interest Income 0.0934 0.7443 0.6425 0.0599 0.7826 0.6763Capital gains/dividends 0.0542 1.3718 0.7320 0.1126 0.9443 0.8252Business Income 0.0196 2.0106 0.6056 0.0339 1.4332 0.6779Social Insurance 0.0493 0.7067 0.3276 0.0425 0.7289 0.4077Retirement Income 0.0947 0.7665 0.5332 0.1084 0.7600 0.5764Other Income 0.0494 1.2857 0.4377 0.0508 1.1839 0.4483Federal Taxes −0.2838 −0.3240 −1.2008 −0.2958 −0.3488 −1.2819Individual Income Taxes −0.1470 −0.3880 −1.3039 −0.1610 −0.4228 −1.3711Corporate Income Taxes −0.0113 −0.4456 −1.4387 −0.0159 −0.4474 −1.5930Payroll Taxes −0.1255 −0.2834 −0.8097 −0.1189 −0.2847 −0.8158

2001 2006

Sk Gk Rk Sk Gk Rk

Wages 0.9018 0.3813 0.7467 0.7711 0.3932 0.7245Interest Income 0.0526 0.8033 0.6430 0.0421 0.8307 0.7525Capital gains/dividends 0.0765 1.3447 0.7730 0.1557 0.9702 0.8805Business Income 0.0382 1.4802 0.6763 0.0520 1.3165 0.7144Social Insurance 0.0471 0.7063 0.3821 0.0558 0.6598 0.3215Retirement Income 0.1295 0.7549 0.6097 0.1331 0.7574 0.6687Other Income 0.0503 1.1511 0.4480 0.0451 1.2180 0.4425Federal Taxes −0.2959 −0.3542 −1.2766 −0.2549 −0.3727 −1.3256Individual Income Taxes −0.1625 −0.4306 −1.3608 −0.1322 −0.4581 −1.4074Corporate Income Taxes −0.0139 −0.4517 −1.5849 −0.0208 −0.4510 −1.7519Payroll Taxes −0.1194 −0.2873 −0.8336 −0.1020 −0.2947 −0.8090

All estimates are statistically significant at the 1 percent level.

37

Page 40: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Table A.2: Basic Estimation Results (ν = 2.0)

1991 1996

Sk Gk Rk Sk Gk Rk

Wages 0.9232 0.5286 0.7423 0.8877 0.5379 0.7544Interest Income 0.0934 0.9019 0.6563 0.0599 0.9255 0.7051Capital gains/dividends 0.0542 1.6680 0.7538 0.1126 1.0558 0.8524Business Income 0.0196 2.4021 0.6159 0.0339 1.6124 0.6996Social Insurance 0.0493 0.8952 0.4108 0.0425 0.9081 0.5133Retirement Income 0.0947 0.9202 0.5985 0.1084 0.9163 0.6416Other Income 0.0494 1.6430 0.4482 0.0508 1.4987 0.4596Federal Taxes −0.2838 −0.5908 −0.9147 −0.2958 −0.6410 −0.9361Individual Income Taxes −0.1470 −0.7177 −0.9409 −0.1610 −0.7854 −0.9537Corporate Income Taxes −0.0113 −0.9641 −0.7742 −0.0159 −0.9631 −0.8542Payroll Taxes −0.1255 −0.5049 −0.7208 −0.1189 −0.5076 −0.7262

2001 2006

Sk Gk Rk Sk Gk Rk

Wages 0.9018 0.5488 0.7599 0.7711 0.5644 0.7423Interest Income 0.0526 0.9364 0.6692 0.0421 0.9488 0.7909Capital gains/dividends 0.0765 1.5879 0.7765 0.1557 1.0655 0.9092Business Income 0.0382 1.6856 0.7052 0.0520 1.4598 0.7438Social Insurance 0.0471 0.8952 0.4874 0.0558 0.8651 0.4094Retirement Income 0.1295 0.9123 0.6687 0.1331 0.9133 0.7414Other Income 0.0503 1.4490 0.4604 0.0451 1.5491 0.4468Federal Taxes −0.2959 −0.6536 −0.9233 −0.2549 −0.6938 −0.9283Individual Income Taxes −0.1625 −0.8041 −0.9375 −0.1322 −0.8633 −0.9417Corporate Income Taxes −0.0139 −0.9705 −0.8334 −0.0208 −0.9741 −0.9147Payroll Taxes −0.1194 −0.5138 −0.7297 −0.1020 −0.5298 −0.7076

All estimates are statistically significant at the 1 percent level.

38

Page 41: The Role of Wages, Capital Income, and Taxes on Income Inequality in USA Economic Policy Institute Thomas L Hungerford

Table A.3: Basic Estimation Results (ν = 4.0)

1991 1996

Sk Gk Rk Sk Gk Rk

Wages 0.9232 0.7995 0.7719 0.8877 0.8027 0.7921Interest Income 0.0934 0.9504 0.7165 0.0599 0.9366 0.8047Capital gains/dividends 0.0542 2.1526 0.8328 0.1126 0.9363 1.0796Business Income 0.0196 3.3827 0.6147 0.0339 1.8062 0.7563Social Insurance 0.0493 0.6891 0.8787 0.0425 0.6647 1.0930Retirement Income 0.0947 0.6928 1.0534 0.1084 0.7021 1.0853Other Income 0.0494 2.2855 0.4433 0.0508 2.0119 0.4516Federal Taxes −0.2838 −1.3761 −0.5510 −0.2958 −1.5397 −0.5301Individual Income Taxes −0.1470 −1.7508 −0.5088 −0.1610 −1.9644 −0.4884Corporate Income Taxes −0.0113 −2.9707 −0.2659 −0.0159 −2.9427 −0.3014Payroll Taxes −0.1255 −1.0489 −0.5720 −0.1189 −1.0610 −0.5775

2001 2006

Sk Gk Rk Sk Gk Rk

Wages 0.9018 0.8066 0.7895 0.7711 0.8213 0.7814Interest Income 0.0526 0.9226 0.7422 0.0421 0.8900 0.9527Capital gains/dividends 0.0765 2.0112 0.8071 0.1557 0.9325 1.1510Business Income 0.0382 1.9531 0.7713 0.0520 1.5074 0.8476Social Insurance 0.0471 0.6784 1.0475 0.0558 0.7020 0.9172Retirement Income 0.1295 0.7238 1.0648 0.1331 0.7242 1.1995Other Income 0.0503 1.9276 0.4450 0.0451 2.1339 0.4143Federal Taxes −0.2959 −1.5838 −0.5087 −0.2549 −1.7208 −0.4869Individual Income Taxes −0.1625 −2.0270 −0.4663 −0.1322 −2.2262 −0.4467Corporate Income Taxes −0.0139 −2.9684 −0.2826 −0.0208 −3.0095 −0.3123Payroll Taxes −0.1194 −1.0852 −0.5638 −0.1020 −1.1271 −0.5448

All estimates are statistically significant at the 1 percent level.

39


Recommended