+ All Categories
Home > Documents > The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects...

The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects...

Date post: 05-Aug-2020
Category:
Upload: others
View: 0 times
Download: 0 times
Share this document with a friend
43
The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union Arif Mamun * January 2006 Abstract A recent strand of literature in demography argues that young unmarried Americans value marriage so highly that it is perceived as a family status to be chosen after certain economic preconditions are fulfilled – after they have achieved the so-called “white picket fence dream” (a house, surplus income etc.). Motivated by these claims, in this paper we use data from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth 1979 to examine whether there is any direct relationship between the individual’s housing and financial assets and his/her transition into marriage or cohabitation. For both men and women, analysis using a proportional hazard model indicates a positive association of asset ownership with transition into marriage, but not with transition into cohabitation. Considering the potential endogeneity of asset accumulation with respect to the choice of family status, we implement instrumental variables probit estimation. These estimates either remove the statistical significance of the association between asset ownership and family union transitions, or identify effects that are in the opposite direction to those derived from the time-to-event analysis. JEL Classification: J12, D1 Keywords: asset, home-ownership, family, marriage, cohabitation * Researcher, Mathematica Policy Research, Inc. 600 Maryland Ave SW, Washington, DC 20024. E-mail: [email protected] I would like to thank Bob Plotnick, Claus Pörtner, George Masnick and the participants of the labor and development economics brownbag at the University of Washington for helpful comments. I am indebted to Shelly Lundberg for her guidance and support all through the development of this paper. Financial support from the Grover and Creta Ensley Fellowship in Economic Policy, and the Center for Studies in Demography and Ecology at the University of Washington is gratefully acknowledged.
Transcript
Page 1: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

The White Picket Fence Dream:

Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union

Arif Mamun ∗

January 2006

Abstract

A recent strand of literature in demography argues that young unmarried Americans value marriage so highly that it is perceived as a family status to be chosen after certain economic preconditions are fulfilled – after they have achieved the so-called “white picket fence dream” (a house, surplus income etc.). Motivated by these claims, in this paper we use data from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth 1979 to examine whether there is any direct relationship between the individual’s housing and financial assets and his/her transition into marriage or cohabitation. For both men and women, analysis using a proportional hazard model indicates a positive association of asset ownership with transition into marriage, but not with transition into cohabitation. Considering the potential endogeneity of asset accumulation with respect to the choice of family status, we implement instrumental variables probit estimation. These estimates either remove the statistical significance of the association between asset ownership and family union transitions, or identify effects that are in the opposite direction to those derived from the time-to-event analysis.

JEL Classification: J12, D1

Keywords: asset, home-ownership, family, marriage, cohabitation

∗ Researcher, Mathematica Policy Research, Inc. 600 Maryland Ave SW, Washington, DC 20024. E-mail: [email protected] I would like to thank Bob Plotnick, Claus Pörtner, George Masnick and the participants of the labor and development economics brownbag at the University of Washington for helpful comments. I am indebted to Shelly Lundberg for her guidance and support all through the development of this paper. Financial support from the Grover and Creta Ensley Fellowship in Economic Policy, and the Center for Studies in Demography and Ecology at the University of Washington is gratefully acknowledged.

Page 2: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

1

The White Picket Fence Dream:

Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union

I. Introduction

There have been dramatic changes in the family formation behavior of young American men

and women over the last four decades. During this period, the prevalence of cohabitation has been

increasing sharply while age at first marriage has also been rising, and the percentage of marriages

preceded by cohabitation has been growing substantially (Fields and Casper, 2001; Casper and

Cohen, 2000; Bumpass and Sweet 1989). These demographic changes have prompted serious

concerns from researchers as well as policy makers about a retreat from the traditional pattern of

family formation. However, both quantitative and qualitative research (e.g., Edin, 2000; Tucker,

2000; Thornton and Young-DeMarco, 2001; Gibson, Edin and McLanahan, 2003, Cherlin, 2004)

indicate that among the unmarried population there is not a large-scale lack of respect for marriage

and the traditional ways of family. Young Americans do place a high value on marriage and consider

it as part of their future. In fact, Gibson, Edin and McLanahan (2003) argue that at least for some

young unwed parents, high marital expectations may be precluding them from marrying. In a

qualitative analysis of 75 unmarried young couples in the Fragile Families study, they find that

marriage signals the “arrival” of the couple, both financially and emotionally. Because marriage is

valued so highly, it is perceived as a family status to be chosen after certain economic and relational

preconditions are fulfilled – after they have achieved the so-called “white picket fence dream”.

Similar observations are also reported in Edin (2000), drawing on qualitative interviews with 292

Page 3: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

2

low-income single mothers in three U.S. cities. While these are interesting observations, there has

not been any attempt to substantiate the qualitative evidence using quantitative methods in a large

scale dataset. If people postpone their marriage until they can achieve the different level of living

standard that they associate with marriage – a house, surplus income etc. – one may expect to detect

a direct relationship between the individual’s housing and financial assets, and his/her transition into

marriage. In this paper, we examine this intriguing issue using data from the National Longitudinal

Survey of Youth 1979. In addition to considering transition into marriage, we also analyze the effect

of asset ownership on transition into cohabitation.

Since we are interested in identifying whether asset ownership status explains the time until

the formation of a family union, we utilize the proportional hazard model – a natural estimation

technique for analyzing time-to-event data. The time-to-event analysis would ensure that asset

ownership status prior to a family union transition is sequentially exogenous to such a transition

decision. However, the individual’s intention to form a family next period or period after may

influence his/her asset accumulation behavior in the current period. As a result, unobserved

individual heterogeneity as well as the shocks that affect the choice of family status could be

correlated with asset ownership status, and the proportional hazard model estimates would be

potentially inconsistent. To address the potential endogeneity of assets we implement instrumental

variables estimation, where the set of excluded instruments contains the interaction of monthly

averages of the 30-year fixed-rate mortgages, the 1-year adjustable-rate mortgages, the federal funds

rate, and NASDAQ stock price index, with individual’s age, ethnicity and region of residence.

In our attempt to understand the role of assets in family union choice, we consider

cohabitation and marriage comparably. Thus, in addition to bridging the void in the literature on

Page 4: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

3

identifying the effects of assets on family union, this paper would enable us to better understand the

differences and similarities between marriage and cohabitation. Furthermore, apart from providing

insights into the mechanism underlying the individual’s decision to form families, the qualitative

evidence on assets as determinants of family union transitions are also suggestive of the potential

influence that asset building policies might have on family union behavior.1 Particularly, public

policy interventions for increasing home ownership, and enhancing savings among the low-income

group through individual development accounts, would be expected to affect the family union

choices of the participants. The results available from the current study will enable us to make more

knowledgeable estimates about whether asset-building policies could potentially influence family

union behavior.

The following section provides a conceptual discussion of the determinants of family union

decisions, and a brief review of the relevant empirical literature. Section III describes the estimation

procedures, and section IV delineates the NLSY data and summary statistics. Empirical results are

presented in Section V. Summary and conclusions follow in section VI.

II. Economic Resources and Family Union Formation: Theoretical

Perspectives and Empirical Research

II. 1. Economic resources and marriage

Economic analysis of household formation, built on the foundation of Becker’s (1973, 1974,

1991) seminal work, emphasizes the effects of economic resources on the likelihood of marriage.

1 Stern (2001), Sherraden (2001), and Seidman (2001) discuss asset-building policies in the US.

Page 5: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

4

From a microeconomic perspective, the effect of a change in the individual’s economic prospects,

such as a rise in the wage rate, on the timing of marriage can be analyzed as the effect of a change in

the wage rate on the allocation of time among family, schooling, and market work. From this point

of view, a rise in the wage rate tends to increase market work, and in turn has a negative substitution

effect on the demand for family or schooling (Becker, 1973). However, rising wages also has an

income effect, which makes marriage and family more affordable and possibly increases the rate of

return to schooling. Hence, the marriage effect of a change in young men or women’s labor market

conditions is an empirical question.

Wilson (1987, 1996) provides one of the most widely noticed discussions of a causal link

between economic resources and the postponement of marriage among the young Americans,

particularly among the low-income black population. Working his way through the complexity of

jointly determined variables, he argues that decreased employment opportunities for men is an

exogenous “prime mover”, and determines its effect on marriage rate to be negative. One way in

which the Wilson hypothesis can be put in the context of the economic theory of marriage is to

consider marriage as the matching outcome from a search process in the marriage market where

women only consider marriage with men who have demonstrated a minimum ability to perform in

the labor market (Wood, 1995).

The theoretical discussions point to three economic factors as being potentially important:

employment and earnings of men, employment and earnings of women, and welfare benefits

(Ellwood and Crane, 1990). In addition to these three factors, other measures of economic resources

that feature prominently in the empirical literature include men’s and women’s educational

attainment, work experience, and parental resources. Before we discuss the empirical studies

Page 6: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

5

analyzing the family union transitions, it would be appropriate to note that a persistent limitation of

many of these studies is that they are unable to address the issue of individual heterogeneity which

can directly influence the likelihood of a transition into marriage or cohabitation, while at the same

time being correlated with the individual’s economic potential. As a result, most of the findings

indicate an associative relationship between economic resources and family union transitions, rather

than a causal one. Only a handful of more careful studies have tried to overcome this challenge.

Empirical results indicate that men’s labor market opportunities are associated with

significantly higher rates of marriage, although their quantitative effects may be small (see, for

example, Xie et. al., 2003; Oppenheimer, Kalmijn and Lim, 1997; Willis and Michael, 1994; Schultz,

1994; Mare and Winship, 1991; Ellwood and Crane, 1990; MacDonald and Rindfuss, 1981). Among

a small number of studies that have been attentive in addressing the issue of endogeneity of men’s

labor market opportunities with respect their choice of family status are: Olsen and Farkas (1990),

Wood (1995), and Black, McKinnish and Sanders (2003). Olsen and Farkas (1990) utilize a waiting-

time regression model with individual fixed effects to evaluate the effect of a government program

that guaranteed employment opportunities to disadvantaged youth on family union and fertility, and

find that employment opportunity encourages the formation of consensual unions. Black,

McKinnish and Sanders (2003) study the shocks to the coal and steel industries to measure the effect

of long-term changes in demand for low-skilled workers on welfare expenditures and family

structures. Using county level panel data for the period 1969-93, they find that the expansion of

high-wage jobs for low-skilled men increased marriage rates, and reduced the incidence of female-

headed households, thereby reducing the number of families at risk for receiving welfare benefits.

Page 7: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

6

The findings in these more careful studies are supportive of the Wilson hypothesis that

men’s labor market opportunities are fundamental in determining the marriage rates, particularly in

the low-income group. Wood (1995), on the other hand, uses SMSA level aggregated data from US

Censuses in 1970 and 1980. The results which account for the endogeneity of marriage and

‘marriageability’, suggest that shrinking pool of high earning young black men explains little of the

decline in black marriage, and thereby, contradict the Wilson hypothesis. Thus, the empirical

evidence on the effect of changes in men’s economic status on marriage rates is mixed.

Studies focusing on women’s labor market prospects have also found mixed empirical

evidence. Some of these studies have found that better economic prospects for women are

associated with declines in marriage (e.g., Aassve, 2003; Blau, Kahn and Waldfogel, 2000;

McLanahan and Casper, 1995; Willis and Michael, 1994; Schultz, 1994; Mare and Winship, 1991),

while others find that the estimated relationship between indicators of women’s economic status and

incidence of marriage is either positive or insignificant (e.g., Xie et. al. 2003; Oppenheimer and Lew,

1995; Mare and Winship, 1991).

One aspect of family union transitions that has been ignored until recently is the transition

from cohabitation into marriage. Recent empirical endeavors in this regard find mixed evidence.

Some studies have shown positive association of men’s earnings and the transition from

cohabitation to marriage (Carlson, McLanahan and England, 2004; Brown, 2000; Sanchez, Manning

and Smock, 1998; Smock and Manning, 1997), while others have reported a significant negative

association between higher men’s earnings and cohabiters’ decision to marry (Sassler and McNally,

2003, Wu and Pollard, 2000). Previous research mostly tended to indicate that there is no significant

effect of women’s economic opportunities on transition from cohabitation to marriage (Sassler and

Page 8: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

7

McNally, 2003; Sassler and Schoen, 1999; Clarkberg, 1999), although a recent study showed that

women’s education encourage transition to marriage among young unwed mothers (Carlson,

McLanahan and England, 2004).

II.2. Economic resources and cohabitation

With a handful of recent exceptions, the existing quantitative literature on the role of

economic resources in family formation has focused exclusively on marriage, ignoring cohabitation.

The studies that consider cohabitation include Xie et. al. (2003), Clarkberg (1999), Smock and

Manning (1997), Raley (1996), and Thornton, Axinn and Teachman (1995). Two studies have

indicated that improvement in men’s economic opportunities encourage the formation of cohabiting

unions (Clarkberg, 1999; Smock and Manning, 1997), another study found that men’s school

enrollment deters entrance into cohabitation (Thornton, Axinn and Teachman, 1995), while still

others have reported no significant effect of several measures of men’s economic potential (Xie et.

al., 2003) on the rate of transition into cohabitation. With regard to women’s economic potential,

previous studies indicate that enhancing women’s economic potential discourages the formation of

cohabiting unions (Thornton, Axinn and Teachman, 1995), while others found that women’s

economic status has no significant effect on transition into cohabitation (Xie et. al., 2003). Kravdal

(1999) relates the growth in cohabitation in Norway with the issues of ‘affordability’ of marriage. He

finds that women’s cumulated income has a positive association with the likelihood of cohabitation

among women with children, but not for women without children. The author interpreted these

results as weak evidence on marriage requiring a stronger economic underpinning than cohabitation.

Page 9: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

8

However, since sufficient attention has not been paid to the issue of selection, one has to be very

cautious in interpreting such findings any more than reflections of positive correlations.

II.3. Asset ownership and family union formation

While income is certainly critical, wealth and assets are also important complementary

measures of an individual’s command over economic resources. The individual’s assets give us an

estimate of their economic readiness to marry in relation to their ideational value of marriage.

Individuals with higher exogenous endowments are more likely to marry because they have more to

share and can provide greater access to credit and insurance (Lam, 1988). On the other hand, higher

exogenous endowments can potentially reduce the marital surplus by way of requiring less

specialization in the household, and thereby dissuade the individual from marriage. Therefore, a

priori, the effect of assets on the choice of family union is ambiguous.

More realistically, assets are not exogenous and they reflect accumulated past income, and

savings behavior. The economic model of the determinants of marriage considers the concept of

potential wage rates, instead of actual or realized wage rates. Realized wages is as much the result of the

marriage decision as its cause. Since assets (net of inheritance) are accumulated savings from realized

earnings, they are likely to be directly affected by the marriage decisions. And even inheritance can

be influenced by the individual’s choice regarding family union. Also, there is substantial empirical

research showing how family composition affects household wealth and savings (e.g., Aizcorbe,

Kennickell and Moore 2003; Lupton and Smith 2003; Wolff, 2001; Mulder and Wagner, 2001;

Browning and Lusardi 1996; Lusardi, Gossa and Krupka 2001; Avery and Kennickell 1991). Most of

these empirical studies on savings are descriptive, and they generally identify that married couples

Page 10: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

9

have the highest levels of wealth and lone parents the lowest with singles in between (but with quite

low levels of wealth). Taken together, these studies suggest that addressing the endogeneity of assets

is the primary challenge in analyzing their effects on the choice of family form.

III. Empirical Methodology

The primary challenge in analyzing the effect of assets on the choice of family form is to

address the issue of endogeneity of assets with respect to family status. We undertake a two-pronged

approach to address this issue. First, we utilize a time-to-event analysis approach by using

proportional hazard model. Second, we implement instrumental variables estimation.

III.1. Time-to-event analysis

The central question we are examining is whether the individual’s asset ownership status

explains his/her family union transition. The question could be put forward alternatively as whether

asset ownership can explain the time elapsed until a family union transition occurs. A natural way to

empirically estimate such effects is to apply a time-to-event analysis approach. The benefit of using a

time-to-event analysis in our context is that it ensures ‘sequential exogeneity’ 2 of assets with regard

to family status. We are looking at the effect of asset ownership prior to the event of a family union

on the probability of a union in the next period. Hence, asset ownership is not sequentially

dependent on family transition decision.

2 For a discussion on sequential exogeneity, see Wooldridge, 2002, chapter 11.

Page 11: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

10

We consider five sets of family union transitions: a) non-partnered to first partnered union

(marriage or cohabitation); b) non-partnered to first cohabitation; c) non-partnered to first marriage;

d) cohabitation to first marriage; and e) unmarried (non-partnered or cohabiting) to first marriage.

We consider only transitions into the first marriage and first cohabitation in order to keep our

analysis simple, since subsequent family unionization is confounded by the choices on dissolving the

previous family union. Since the individual’s asset ownership status varies over time, for our

purposes we utilized a Cox proportional hazard model with time-varying covariates (see Lancaster,

1990 for details) to analyze these transitions. In this model, the instantaneous hazard rate of

transitions to family union is specified for individual i, t years until the family transition occurs, as:

0[ , ( )] ( )exp[ ( )]i x ih t x t h t x tβ=

The baseline hazard, 0 ( )h t , is a nonparametric, time-varying function; ( )ix t is a vector of regressors

that includes time-varying asset ownership indicators; and xβ is the vector of coefficients to be

estimated. We used the maximum-likelihood estimation procedure available in Stata to implement

the model (Cleves, Gould and Gutierrez, 2004).

III.2. Instrumental variables estimation

Although the time-to-event analysis ensures sequential exogeneity of asset ownership with

respect to family status, the individual’s intension to form a family in the future may influence

his/her asset accumulation behavior in the current period. Therefore, unobserved individual

heterogeneity (e.g., propensity to accumulate assets or prudence, ability to form a household etc.) as

well as the shocks that affect family status could be correlated with asset ownership status. In this

Page 12: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

11

sense, asset ownership status may not be strictly exogenous to the family transition decision, and

hence, the proportional hazard estimates are potentially inconsistent. In other words, the time-to-

event analysis may not provide us with the true effects of asset ownership on family union

transitions. Note that the true effect of asset ownership is the effect which would result were it

possible to randomly assign asset ownership to a sample of non-partnered men and women. This

true effect may be smaller than the effect we estimate by comparing the hazard rates of family union

transition for men and women with assets to the rates of transition for men and women without

assets, precisely because of the type of endogeneity that is suggested above. Since there is no

established instrumental variables framework for hazard models, we implement instrumental

variables (IV) probit estimation in a discrete-time analogue of the (continuous time) proportional

hazard model to deal with the potential endogeneity of assets.3

For the IV estimation, instead of having a standard pooled cross-sectional limited dependent

variable, we define the dependent variable as a dichotomous indicator of whether a family union

transition occurs in the next period.4 The advantage of constructing the dependent variable in this

fashion is that we are able to retain the sequential exogeneity of the asset ownership status in the

time-to-event analysis while we address the concern about strict exogeneity of asset ownership.

3 The other way to do it may be to estimate a ‘waiting-time regression model’ (Olsen and Wolpin, 1983) by linearizing the probability density function of time to failure, and estimate using linear methods. However, Olsen and Wolpin (1983) requires imposition of an exogenously chosen upper limit on the time to remain in the non-partnered status, which is deemed to be very restrictive for our analysis. 4 To use definitions from time-to-event analysis, we use the “failure indicator” in the hazard model as the dependent variable in our discrete time analysis.

Page 13: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

12

IV. NLSY79 Data and Summary Statistics

The National Longitudinal Survey of Youth 1979 (NLSY79) is a nationally representative US

sample of young men and women who were 14-22 years old when they were first interviewed

(CHRR, 2001). The respondents were interviewed annually until 1994, and biennially since then.

Data from the first through the 19 th (2000) round are used for this paper. We have used data from

the earliest round to determine the respondent’s family life history. Detailed information on wealth

and assets are, however, available only since the 7 th round (i.e., 1985).5

We stratify the data by gender, and all our analyses are conducted separately for men and

women. We observe the family life transitions of men and women in our sample during the period

1985 to 2000. The time-until-transition to a family union (in marriage, or in cohabitation) is

identified by combining information on current family status, beginning dates of cohabiting and

marital relationships, interview dates, as well as partner identifiers available in NLSY79. Table 1

presents some summary statistics on the unmarried spells considered here. As the table shows, the

median duration in non-partnered spell for both men and women in our sample is more than 11

years. This is not surprising given that the beginning of this spell is either the date of their first

interview in NLSY or their 14 birthday, whichever is later. The median duration in cohabitation is

about 2.7 years. Table 2 provides the number of events we observe in our data for each category of

transition, along with the median duration prior to any transition. During the period under analysis,

there are 1525 transitions into first-marriage among women; 659 of these transitions are from

cohabitation. For men, there are 1807 transitions into first-marriage of which 683 are from

cohabitation. We also have 1304 transitions for women from a non-partnered (i.e., never-married

5 Due to budgetary restrictions, wealth questions were not administered in 1991 and 2002 rounds of NLSY79.

Page 14: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

13

non-cohabiting) status to a family union – either in marriage or in cohabitation – of which 422 are

into cohabitation. Among men, we observe 1877 transitions from a non-partnered status to a family

union, and 722 of these transitions are into cohabitation.

In Table 3, we present snapshots on the different characteristics of the respondents in our

sample. The table is intended to provide a glimpse into the nature of the sample we have for our

analysis. The table shows that the proportions that are married increased over time for both men

and women, although the fraction of men married converged to the fraction of women married only

in the later years. Summary statistics are presented for men and women in three different family

statuses: non-partnered (never-married and non-cohabiting), cohabiting and married in 1985.

As we examine the effect of asset ownership on family union transitions in this study, we

take three types of assets into consideration6: home ownership; liquid monetary assets as indicated

by the availability of funds in savings account, certificates of deposit, money market instruments and

IRA-Keoghs; and financial investments in stocks, bonds, and mutual funds. In our empirical analysis

we include dichotomous indicators of ownership of these three types of assets. While data on home

ownership and liquid monetary assets are available since 1985, stocks-bonds-mutual funds data are

available only from 1988.

Table 3 reveals that both married men and married women are significantly more likely to be

a homeowner. On average, married men and women are also more likely to own liquid monetary

assets, as well as investments in stocks, bonds and mutual funds. This is all the more clear from

Figures 1 through 6 showing the average asset ownership status of non-partnered, cohabiting and

married men and women at different age. Although the fraction that are homeowners increases with

6 These ownership data are available from the “Asset” section of the NLSY79, and the relevant questions ask about the ownership status of the respondent and their spouse/partner with respect to the particular categories of assets.

Page 15: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

14

age for men and women in any family status, at every age those who are married are more likely to

be homeowners than those who are not married. Cohabiting men are marginally more likely to be

homeowners than non-partnered men, and the same is true for young cohabiting women. A much

larger fraction of cohabiting women in their mid-30s are homeowners compared to the non-

partnered in that age group. In terms ownership of monetary assets, married men in their early 20’s

appear to be similar to cohabiting men. However, married men who are in their late 20’s or older,

are more likely to have some monetary assets compared to men in the other two family statuses.

Married women, on the other hand, are more likely to have some monetary assets at about any age

compared to the unmarried women. The proportion owning financial investments is quite low for

both men and women in any of the three family statuses.7 However, even at that low level, married

men and women at any age are more likely to own some financial investments than their unmarried

counterparts. Interestingly, cohabiting men and women are either less (in their 20’s) or equally (in

their 30’s) likely to own monetary assets as well as financial investment compared to non-partnered

men and women.

The other characteristics that are considered in our analysis and are summarized in Table 3

include age, race and ethnicity, own education, income (wage and business income) in the past

calendar year, welfare recipiency in the past calendar year (includes receipt of cash assistance from

AFDC or TANF, supplemental security income, food stamps, housing support, or any other

benefit), religion, father’s and mother’s education, region of residence, whether or not the state of

residence recognizes common law marriage, and local unemployment rate. Men and women in our

sample are between 20 to 28 years old in 1985, the year since which we follow their family union

transitions. On average, married men and women are older than their counterparts in the other two 7 In figures 5 and 6, the outlier percentages in the highest age group reflect small sample in that age group.

Page 16: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

15

family statuses. Married men and women are also likely to be at least high school graduates than

others. Table 3 also indicates that while women in general are more likely to be welfare recipients

than men, larger fraction of unmarried women received public assistance than their married

counterparts.

V. Results

V. 1. Results from time-to-event analysis

Estimates from the Cox proportional hazard model with the asset ownership variables as

time-varying covariates are presented in Table 4. As already noted, in analyzing the relationship

between family union transitions and asset ownership, we are considering the ownership status of

housing assets, of liquid financial assets, and of stocks, bonds and mutual funds. Since data on

stocks and bonds ownership is available from a later period (from 1988, instead of 1985), in our

analysis we estimate two sets of specifications – one that excludes stocks-bonds-mutual funds

ownership indicator (Model 1), and another that includes it (Model 2). Table 4 presents the

estimated hazard ratios only for the covariates of interest, and estimates for the complete

specification are available upon request. We discuss the estimated results for men and women

separately.

Results in section (a) in Table 4 show that home ownership and money in the savings

account have no statistically significant effect on women’s transition from never-married status into

a partnered relationship (either in marriage or in cohabitation). However, as the ownership of stocks

and bonds is included in the specification (Model 2), thereby reducing the period of analysis and the

Page 17: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

16

sample size, the estimated hazard rate on women’s home ownership becomes significantly negative,

while the hazard rate on monetary assets becomes significantly positive. Table A-1 in the Appendix

reports an additional set of estimates where measures of wage and business income in the previous

calendar year, and an indicator of the individual’s public assistance recipiency (AFDC/TANF, food

stamps, unemployment insurance benefits, supplemental security income etc.) in the previous

calendar year is added to the specifications in Table 4. While we wanted to examine whether

inclusion of income and welfare recipiency in the specification have any major influence on the

estimated effects of asset ownership, their potential endogeneity with respect to family union

transitions convinced us for not including them in our initial specifications. As it appears, inclusion

of these two variables does not change the estimated effects of asset ownership on transition to a

family union in any substantive way. In addition, welfare recipiency tends to be negatively correlated

with transition into a family union, a result that resonates with a large existing literature (see Moffitt,

1998 for a recent review).

Next, we perform a competing-risks analysis that allows for two ways to exit the non-

partnered status: form a family in cohabitation, or in marriage. Estimated hazard ratios for

transitions from non-partnered to cohabitation are reported in section (b) in Table 4. For women,

both Model 1 and Model 2 show that ownership of home as well as liquid monetary assets are not

significantly associated with forming a cohabiting relationship. Results from section (c) show that

while ownership of liquid assets is positively associated with the rate of marriage for non-partnered

women, home ownership in this group has a negative association with transition into marriage. As it

appears, the pattern of association of home as well as liquid asset ownership with women’s rate of

forming any family union (in section a) is primarily driven by the association between ownership of

Page 18: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

17

these assets and transition into marriage. The positive association between liquid asset ownership

and marital transitions is also emphasized by the estimates in section (d) which indicate that women

who have access to liquid assets are more likely to marry their cohabiting partners. Results in section

(d) further show that home ownership has no significant relationship with the rate of marriage

among cohabiting women. While the results in this section for liquid assets conform to the

qualitative evidence that women would chose to marry their cohabiting partners when there is

surplus income (e.g., Gibson, Edin and McLanahan, 2003; Cherlin, 2004), the insignificant

relationship between home ownership and marital transition for cohabiting women does not

correspond to a so-called ‘white picket fence’ explanation. As we consider women’s transition into

marriage from either a never-married or a cohabiting status (section e, Table 4), we find that both

home and liquid assets ownership have positive correlation with such transitions.

Overall, results from Cox proportional hazard model estimates suggest that liquid assets are

positively associated with women’s rate of transition into marriage. For home ownership, there is

weak evidence of a negative relationship. In the case of transition into cohabitation, asset ownership

does not have a statistically significant association with women’s choice of cohabitation.

For men, the overall evidence indicates that asset ownership is positively associated with rate

of transition to marriage, but not to cohabitation. Specifically, the rate of marital transition by non-

partnered men has a significant positive relationship with both home and liquid asset ownership, but

no significant relationship exist for men’s transition from non-partnered status to cohabitation (see

sections a, b, c, and e for men in Table 4). More interestingly, cohabiting men’s rate of transition to

marriage has no significant relationship with home ownership, but there is positive significant

association with ownership of liquid assets and financial investments. These results give the

Page 19: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

18

impression that while ownership of all types of assets is positively correlated with the never-married

men’s decision to marry; only liquid assets are significantly correlated with cohabiting men’s choice

to marry.

It would be appropriate to note that the individual’s race and ethnicity indicators have been

included in all the specifications reported, along with the other control variables. Overall, for all the

transitions analyzed here, compared to non-black non-Hispanic women, black women are less likely

to be in any type family union – in marriage or in cohabitation. Black men, on the other hand, are

significantly more likely to transit to a cohabiting relationship, and less likely to transit into marriage

in comparison with their non-black non-Hispanic counterparts. Our estimates for Hispanic women

are similar to those for Black women, but somewhat weaker. For Hispanic men, we have some

evidence that unlike black men, they are less likely either to marry or to cohabit than non-black non-

Hispanic men.

The empirical estimates discussed so far provide some interesting new evidence. Taken

together they show that home ownership as well as access to liquid assets is positively associated

with rates of marital transition from a non-partnered status, particularly for men. There is weak

evidence of a negative association between home ownership and women’s marital transitions. Home

ownership is not associated with rates of marital transition among cohabiting men and women in the

sample, although access to liquid monetary assets is. In addition, both for men and women, asset

ownership is not associated with the rate of transition into cohabitation. These results only partially

agree with the previously discussed qualitative evidence that suggests a stronger relationship,

particularly between home ownership and rates of transition from cohabitation to marriage.

Moreover, the results for the transition from cohabitation to marriage might be considered as

Page 20: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

19

suggestive evidence that both men and women would accumulate monetary assets while cohabiting,

and buy a house when their commitment to a relationship is sealed by the decision to marry. This

only reinforces the apprehension about the endogeneity of asset accumulation that we have noted

earlier.

V. 2. Results from instrumental variables estimation

To address the potential endogeneity of assets we implement instrumental variables (IV)

estimation. To operationalize the procedure, we convert the structure of analysis from a continuous

time to a discrete time hazard model with the dependent variable being a dichotomous indicator of a

family union transition in the next period. As we treat the asset ownership status as endogenous to

family union transitions, the set of excluded instruments is constructed as follows. We use the

interaction of monthly averages of the 30-year fixed-rate mortgages, the 1-year adjustable-rate

mortgages,8 the federal funds rate, and NASDAQ stock price index, with individual’s age, ethnicity

and region of residence as the set of excluded instruments.9 The individual’s homeownership

decision is expected to be influenced by the mortgage rates as they play a dual role in the housing

market: on the one hand, mortgage rates show the time-value-of money; and on the other hand, they

have key roles in determining housing prices. The stock price index and the federal funds rate are

proxies for the return to savings and investment during the sample period, and are therefore

expected to influence the individual’s stock of assets at any point in time. Interacting the mortgage

8 The monthly average mortgage rates are collected from the Freddie Mac Survey of Commitment Points and Rates. 9 Housing price could not be used as an instrument since it directly affects the decision to form independent households (e.g., see, Borsch -Supan, 1986, Haurin et. al, 1993).

Page 21: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

20

rates, stock price index and the federal funds rate with the individual characteristics provides us with

the individual level variation required for identification of the estimating equation.

Test statistics on the joint-significance of the excluded instruments in the first-stage

regressions are provided in Table 5. Although the F-statistics for ownership of stocks and bonds is

quite small, the values of the F-statistic on the other two asset ownership indicators are sufficiently

high to remove the greater portion, if not all, of the potential bias in an analysis conducted without

regard to the endogeneity of assets (Bound et. al. 1995, Table A-1; Hahn and Hausman, 2002). The

validity of these instruments, particularly for the specifications that includes only home and liquid

asset ownership, is also underlined by the Hansen-Sargan J statistic for over-identification tests

reported in Table 6 along with the IV-probit estimates.

Table 6 reports both probit and IV-probit estimates for specifications described earlier as

Model 1 and Model 2. We applied Newey’s (1987) efficient two-step estimator in Stata to estimate

the IV-probit specifications. The sign and significance of the estimated coefficients on asset

indicator variables in the probit model are similar to those in the Cox proportional hazard model for

any family union transitions considered, and for both men and women.

IV-probit estimates for women show that addressing the potential endogeneity of asset

ownership removes the positive association between asset ownership and family union transitions.

On the contrary, access to monetary assets has a negative influence on the rates of transition to

marriage for non-partnered women (sections a, c and e in Table 6). Inclusion of income and welfare

recipiency in the specification (not reported in the table) does not change these results in any

important way. Section (b) in Table 6 indicates that asset ownership has no statistically significant

influence on women’s rate of transition to cohabitation as we account for the endogeneity of assets.

Page 22: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

21

IV probit estimates in section (d) of Table 6 show that home ownership reduces women’s likelihood

of marrying their cohabiting partner, although such negative effect does not remain statistically

significant when we include ownership of stocks and bonds in our specification.

For men, IV probit estimates show that the effects of asset ownership on the rates of

transition into cohabitation as well as transition into marriage, from either non-partnered or

cohabiting status, are not significantly different from zero. For men’s transitions into marriage from

any unmarried status (section e in Table 6), neither homeownership nor monetary asset-ownership

has any significant effect. However, as we add the indicator for ownership of stocks and bonds in

the specification, it has a statistically significant negative effect on the rate of marital transition for

men.

All together, the IV probit estimates either remove the statistical significance of the

association between asset ownership and family union transitions, or indicate effects that are in the

opposite direction to those derived from the time-to-event analysis. However, it has been suggested

in the literature that the influence of economic factors in family life transitions might be different for

different education groups (e.g., Moffitt, 2000). To examine whether our results also reflect a similar

pattern, we conducted the instrumental variables analysis by stratifying our sample into two groups:

those who have never attended college (i.e., at most high-school graduate), and those who have

some college or more education (i.e., more than high school education). In the stratified sample, we

implemented the IV-probit estimation for Model 1 only. Further, the F statistics for the joint

significance of the instruments in the first stage estimation indicate that as we stratify the sample, the

instruments perform satisfactorily only in the case of transitions from unmarried (never-

married/cohabiting) to married status. In Table 7 we report the IV-probit results for this particular

Page 23: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

22

transition, for men and women disaggregated by education groups. A comparison of these estimates

with those reported in section (e), Model 1 in Table 6 suggests that the estimated effects of asset

ownership on marital transitions do not vary significantly between the two education-groups, for

both men and women. While these auxiliary results are generated only for the transitions from

unmarried to married status, they provide enhanced confidence in our IV estimates for all the other

transitions identified across all education levels.

VI. Conclusion

Motivated by a recent set of findings by demographers, the paper presents two broad sets of

evidence on the relationship between asset ownership and the family union transition decisions by

men and women. The first set of findings, from Cox proportional hazard model with time varying

covariates, reveal that home ownership as well as access to liquid assets is positively associated with

rates of marital transition from a non-partnered status, particularly so for men. However, home

ownership is not associated with rates of marital transition among cohabiting men and women in the

sample, although access to liquid monetary assets is positively associated with rates of cohabiting

men and women marrying their partners. Moreover, the rates of transition into cohabitation among

men and women are not at all related to their asset ownership status.

The second set of findings stem from instrumental variables probit estimation, implemented

to remove the potential bias in the hazard model estimates. The bias is anticipated due to the

endogeneity of asset accumulation with respect to the family union decisions. The IV probit

estimates either remove the statistical significance of the association between asset ownership and

family union transitions, or indicate effects that are in the opposite direction to those derived from

Page 24: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

23

the estimated hazard model. As with any instrumental variables estimation, the strength of the set of

identifying variables in playing the role of instruments is crucial. While we would not claim that

these results are definitive, we do believe that they are suggestive. In relating asset ownership to

family union behavior, researchers need to be aware that it is likely that common preferences or

opportunities underlie both the decisions to accumulate asset and the decision to form a family by

marriage or by cohabitation.

Results from the time-to-event analysis indicate that at least as a behavioral regularity we

observe a positive relationship between asset ownership and marital transitions. The IV estimates,

however, suggest that such behavioral regularity does not indicate a causal relationship. In other

words, those who are inherently more likely to marry are the ones who would accumulate assets, and

hence asset ownership does not cause their transition into marriage. Indeed, homeownership and

monetary assets may reduce the marital surplus by reducing the level of specialization in the

household, and thereby influence people to delay marriage, as suggested by the IV results. More

importantly, these results have notable policy implications. If the IV estimates are reflective of the

true effects of asset ownership, provision of housing subsidy or incentive to accumulate assets may

not lead to any significant improvement in the rates of marriage.

Page 25: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

24

References

Aassve, Arnstein. 2003. “The Impact of Economic Resources on Premarital Childbearing and Subsequent Marriage Among Young American Women”. Demography. 40(1). pp. 105-26. Aizcorbe, Ana and Kennickell Arthur and Kevin Moore. 2003. “Recent changes in U.S. family finances: Evidence from the 1998 and 2001 Survey of Consumer Finance”. Federal Reserve Bulletin. January. 89(1). Avery, Robert and Kennickell, Arthur. 1991. “Household Savings in the US”. Review of Income and Wealth. December. 37(4). pp. 409-32. Becker, Gary S. 1973. “A Theory of Marriage: Part I”. Journal of Political Economy. 81(4). pp. 813-46. Becker, Gary S. 1974. “A Theory of Marriage: Part II”. Journal of Political Economy. 82(2-II). pp. S11-S26. Becker, Gary S. 1991. A Treatise on the Family. Enlarged Edition. Harvard University Press. Cambridge, MA. Black, Dan; McKinnish, Terra; and Sanders, Seth. 2003. “Does the Availability of High-Wage Jobs for Low-Skilled Men Affect Welfare Expenditures? Evidence from Shocks to the Steel and Coal Industries”. Journal of Public Economics. 87. pp. 1921- 42. Blau, Francine; Kahn, Lawrence; and Waldfogel, Jean. 2000. “Understanding Young Women’s Marriage Decisions: The Role of Labor and Marriage Market Conditions”. Industrial and Labor Relations Review. July. 53(4). pp. 624-47. Borsch-Supan, Axel. 1986. “Household Formation, Housing Prices, and Public Policy Impacts”. Journal of Public Economics. 30. pp. 145-64. Bound, John; Jaeger, David and Baker, Regina. 1995. “Problems with Instrumental Variables Estimation When the Correlation Between the Instruments and the Endogenous Explanatory Variable is Weak”. Journal of American Statistical Association. 90(430). pp. 443-50. Bowman, Cynthia G. 2004. “Legal Treatment of Cohabitation in the United States”. Law & Policy. January. 26(1). pp. 119-51. Brown, S., 2000. “Union Transitions among Cohabitors: The Significance of Relationship Assessments and Expectations. Journal of Marriage and the Family. 62 (3). pp. 833–47. Browning, Martin and Annamaria Lusardi. 1996. “Household Saving: Micro Theories and Micro Facts”. Journal of Economics Literature. 34(December). pp1797-1855 Bumpass, Larry L. and Hsien-Hen Lu. 2000. “Trends in Cohabitation and Implications for Children’s Family Contexts in the United States”. Population Studies 54. pp. 29-41. Bumpass, Larry L. and James A. Sweet. 1989. “National Estimates of Cohabitation”. Demography. 26. pp. 615-25.

Page 26: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

25

Carlson, Marcia; McLanahan, Sarah and England, Paula. 2004. “Union Formation in Fragile Families”. Demography. 41(2). May. pp. 237-61. Casper, Lynne M. and Cohen, Philip. N. 2000. “How does POSSLQ Measure Up? Historical Estimates of Cohabitation”. Demography. 37(2). pp. 237-45. Center for Human Resource Research (CHRR). 2001. NLSY79 User’s Guide: A Guide to the 1979-2000 National Longitudinal Survey of Youth Data. The Ohio State University. Columbus, Ohio. Cherlin, Andrew. 2004. “The Deinstitutionalization of American Marriage”. Journal of Marriage and Family. 66. November. pp. 848-61. Clarkberg, M., 1999. The Price of Partnering: The Role of Economic Well-Being in Young Adults’ First Union Experiences. Social Forces. 77 (3). pp. 945–68. Cleves, Mario, William Gould and Gutierrez, Roberto. 2004. An Introduction to Survival Analysis Using Stata (Revised Edition). Stata Corporation. College Station, TX Easterlin, Richard A. “Relative Economic Status and the American Fertility Swing”. In E.B. Sheldon (ed.) Family Economic Behaviour: Problems and Prospects. Lippincott. Toronto and Philadelphia. Edin, Kathryn. 2000. “What Do Low-Income Single Mothers Say About Marriage?”. Social Problems. 47. pp. 112-33. Ellwood, David and Crane, Jonathan. 1990. “Family Change among Black Americans: What Do We Know?”. Journal of Economic Perspective. 4(4). pp. 65-84. Fields, Jason and Casper, Lynne M.. 2001. “America’s Families and Living Arrangements: March 2000”. Current Population Reports, P20-537. U.S. Census Bureau, Washington, DC. Gibson, Christina; Kathryn Edin and Sara McLanahan. “High Hopes But Even Higher Expectations: The Retreat From Marriage Among Low-Income Couple”. Center for Research on Child Wellbeing Working Paper # 03-06-FF. June 2003 (Revised: June 2004). Hahn, Jinyong and Hausman, Jerry. 2002. “Notes on bias in estimators for simultaneous equation models”. Economics Letters. 75. pp. 237–241. Haurin, Donald; Hendershott, Patric; and Kim, Dongwook, 1993. “The Impact of Real Rents and Wages on Household Formation”. The Review of Economics and Statistics. 75(2). pp. 284-93. Lam, David. 1988. “Marriage Markets and Assortative Mating with Household Public Goods: Theoretical Results and Empirical Implicaitons”. Journal of Human Resources. 23(4). pp. 462-87. Lancaster, Tony. 1990. The Econometric Analysis of Transition Data. Cambridge University Press. Cambridge, UK. Lupton, Joseph and Smith, James. 2003. “Marriage, Assets and Saving”. Chapter 6 in Marriage and the Economy: Theory and Evidence from Advanced Industrial Societies. by Shoshana Grossbard-Shechtman (ed). Cambridge University Press.

Page 27: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

26

Lusardi, Annamaria; Cossa, Ricardo and Krupka, Erin. 2001. “Savings of Young Parents”. Journal of Human Resources. (Special Issue on Early Results from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth 1997). Autumn. 36(4). pp. 762-94. MacDonald, Maurice M. and Rindfuss, Ronald R. 1981. “Earnings, Relative Income, and Family Formation”. Demography. 18(2). pp. 123-36. Manning, W.D., Smock, P.J., 1995. “Why Marry? Race and the Transition to Marriage among Cohabitors” Demography. 32 (4). pp. 509–20. Mare, R. D. and Winship, C. 1991. “Socioeconomic Change and the Decline of Marriage for Blacks and Whites”. pp. 175-202 in The Urban Underclass. edited by C. Jencks and P.E. Peterson. The Urban Institute. Washington, DC. McLanahan, Sara and Casper, Lynne. 1995. “Growing Diversity and Inequality in the American Family”, In State of the Union: America in the 1990s. Edited by Reynolds Farley. Vol. 2. pp. 1-45. Russell Sage Foundation. New York. Moffitt, Robert A. 1998. “The Effect of Welfare on Marriage and Fertility”. In Robert Moffitt edited Welfare, the Family, and Reproductive Behavior. pp. 50-97. National Academy Press. Washington, DC. Moffitt, Robert A. 2000. “Female Wages, Male Wages, and the Economic Model of Marriage: The Basic Evidence”. In Ties That Bind: Perspectives on Marriage and Cohabitaiton. Edited by Linda Waite, Christine Bachrach, Michelle Hindin, Elizabeth Thomson, and Arland Thornton. Aldine de Gruyter. New York. Mulder, Clara and Wagner, Michael. 2001. “The Connections between Family Formation and First-time Home Ownership in the Context of West Germany and the Netherlands”. European Journal of Population. 17(2). pp. 137-64. Newey, Whitney K. 1987. “Efficient Estimation of Limited Dependent Variable Models with Endogenous Explanatory Variables”. Journal of Econometrics. 36. pp. 231-50. Olsen, Randall and Wolpin, Kenneth. 1983. “The Impact of Exogenous Child Mortality on Fertility: A Waiting Time Regression with Dynamic Regressors”. Econometrica. 51. pp. 731-49. Olsen, R., Farkas, G., 1990. The effect of economic opportunity and family background on adolescent cohabitation and childbearing among low-income blacks. Journal of Labor Economics. 8 (3), 341–362. Oppenheimer, V. and Lew, V. 1995. “American Marriage Formation in the 1980s: How Important Was Women’s Economic Independence?”. In Gender and Family Change in Industrialized Countries. Edited by K.O. Mason and A.M. Jensen. pp. 105-38. Clarendon Press. Oxford, England. Oppenheimer, V., Kalmjin, M. and Lim, N. 1997. “Men’s Career Development and Marriage Timing During a Period of Rising Inequality”. Demography. 34. pp. 311-30. Oppenheimer, Valerie K. 1997. “Women’s Employment and the Gains to Marriage: The Specialization and Trading Model of Marriage”. Annual Review of Sociology. 23. pp. 431-53.

Page 28: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

27

Raley, R.K., 1996. “A Shortage of Marriageable Men? A Note on the Role of Cohabitation in Black–White Differences in Marriage Rates”. American Sociological Review. 61. pp. 973–83. Rivers, Douglas and Vuong, Quang. 1988. “Limited Information Estimators and Exogeneity Tests for Simultaneous Probit Models”. Journal of Econometrics. Novemeber. 39(3). pp. 347-66. Sanchez, L., Manning, W., Smock, P. 1998. “Sex-specialized or Collaborative Mate Selection. Union Transitions among Cohabitors”. Social Science Research. 27. pp. 280–94. Sassler, S. and McNally, J. 2003. “Cohabiting Couples’ Economic Circumstances and Union Transitions: A Re-examination Using Multiple Imputation Techniques”. Social Science Research. 32. pp. 533-78. Sassler, S., Schoen, R., 1999. “The effect of Attitudes and Economic Activity on Marriage. Journal of Marriage and the Family. 61. pp. 147–59. Schultz, T. Paul. 1994. “Marital Status and Fertility in the United States: Welfare and Labor in the Market effects”. Journal of Human Resources. 29(2). Pp, 636-69. Seidman, Lawrence. “Assets and the Tax Code”. In Assets for the Poor: The Benefits of Spreading Asset Ownership. Edited by Thomas Shapiro and Edward Wolff. pp. 324-56. Russell Sage Foundation. New York. Sherraden, Michael. 2001. “Asset-Building Policy and Programs for the Poor”. In Assets for the Poor: The Benefits of Spreading Asset Ownership. Edited by Thomas Shapiro and Edward Wolff. pp. 302-23. Russell Sage Foundation. New York. Smock, Pamela J., and Wendy D. Manning. 1997. “Cohabiting Partners’ Economic Circumstances and Marriage.” Demography 34(3). pp. 331-41. Spitko, E. Gary. 2002. “An Accrual/Multi-Factor Approach to Intestate Inheritance Rights for Unmarried Committed Partners”. Oregon Law Review. 255. Summer. 81(2). Stern, Mark. 2001. “The Un(credit)worthy Poor: Historical Perspectives on Policies to Expand Assets and Credit”. In Assets for the Poor: The Benefits of Spreading Asset Ownership. Edited by Thomas Shapiro and Edward Wolff. pp. 269-301. Russell Sage Foundation. New York. Thornton, Arland and Linda Young-DeMarco. 2001. "Four Decades of Trends in Attitudes Toward Family Issues in the United States: The 1960s Through the 1990s." Journal of Marriage and the Family 63(4):1009-1037. Tucker, M. Belind. 2000. “Marital Values and Expectations in Context: Results from a 21-city Survey”. In Ties That Bind: Perspectives on Marriage and Cohabitaiton. Edited by Linda Waite, Christine Bachrach, Michelle Hindin, Elizabeth Thomson, and Arland Thornton. Aldine de Gruyter. New York. Willis, Robert and Michael, Robert. 1994. “Innovation in Family Formation: Evidence on Cohabitation in the United States”. In John Ermisch and Naohiro Ogawa (Eds). The Family, the Market and the State in Aging Societies. Oxford University Press. pp. 9-45. Wilson, William. J., 1987. The Truly Disadvantaged: The Inner City, the Underclass, and Public Policy. University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

Page 29: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

28

Wilson, William. J., 1996. When Work Disappears: The World of the New Urban Poor. Alfred A. Knopf, New York. Wolff, Edward N. 2001. “Recent Trends in Wealth Ownership, from 1983 to 1998”. In Assets for the Poor: The Benefits of Spreading Asset Ownership. Edited by Thomas Shapiro and Edward Wolff. pp. 34-73. Russell Sage Foundation. New York. Wood, Robert. 1995. “Marriage Rates and Marriageable Men: A Test of Wilson Hypothesis”. Journal of Human Resources. 30(1). pp. 163-93. Wooldridge, Jeffrey. 2002. Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. The MIT Press. Cambridge, MA. Wu, Z., Pollard, M., 2000. “Economic Circumstances and the Stability of Nonmarital Cohabitation”. Journal of Family Issues. 21(3). pp. 303-28. Xie, Yu; Raymo, James; Goyette, Kimberly and Thornton, Arland. 2003. “Economic Potential and Entry into Marriage and Cohabitation”. Demography. May. 20(3). pp. 351-67.

Page 30: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

29

Table 1. Summary Statistics on Spells in Different Family Status Prior to Union Transitions

NLSY79 Women and Men; 1985-2000

Spells No. of Persons

No. of Observations

Median Duration (in months)

Women Non-partnered spells 2056 11073 136.8 Cohabiting spells 1458 3668 32.4 Unmarried spells 3045 14652 116.5 Men Non-partnered spells 2875 14717 136.6 Cohabiting spells 1592 4076 34.0 Unmarried spells 3675 18665 130.3

Table 2. Number of Different Family Union Transitions

NLSY79 Women and Men; 1985-2000

Transitions No. of Transitions Conditional Median Duration (months) a

Women Non-partnered to partnered 1304 25.6 Non-partnered to cohabitation 422 24.5 Non-partnered to marriage 882 26.1 Cohabiting to marriage 659 17.7 Unmarried to marriage 1525 22.1 Men Non-partnered to partnered 1877 25.4 Non-partnered to cohabitation 722 24.4 Non-partnered to marriage 1155 25.8 Cohabiting to marriage 683 18.2 Unmarried to marriage 1807 22.9

Note: a. Duration conditional on the fact that the individual made the transition.

Page 31: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

30

Table 3: Summary of Key Variables by Family Status in 1985 Women and Men NLSY79

Women (N=4535) Men (N=4350) 1985 Status

Variables

Never Partnered

Cohabit Married Never Partnered

Cohabit Married

Proportion in 1985 0.40 0.09 0.43 0.57 0.07 0.30 Proportion in 1990 0.20 0.08 0.57 0.28 0.10 0.50

Proportion in status a

Proportion in 2000 0.12 0.05 0.61 0.14 0.07 0.60 Own house 0.02 0.07 0.38 0.03 0.10 0.33 Have money asset 0.57 0.49 0.68 0.54 0.46 0.66

Assets

Own stocks & bonds b 0.09 0.04 0.14 0.11 0.05 0.16

Age Age (years) 22.93 23.40 24.17 22.86 23.81 24.52 Hispanic 0.15 0.14 0.18 0.15 0.23 0.18 Ethnicity Black 0.38 0.22 0.15 0.31 0.30 0.15 HS grad 0.37 0.47 0.50 0.41 0.46 0.48 Some College 0.35 0.18 0.20 0.28 0.14 0.15

Education

College grad 0.16 0.07 0.10 0.12 0.05 0.12 Income Annual income ($) 6347 6326 6256 8477 11202 14604 Welfare Welfare recipiency 0.20 0.29 0.18 0.05 0.09 0.13

Protestant 0.07 0.08 0.08 0.08 0.04 0.08 Baptist 0.28 0.23 0.19 0.22 0.23 0.17 Catholic 0.25 0.25 0.26 0.24 0.28 0.26 Other Christian 0.11 0.08 0.11 0.11 0.07 0.10

Religion

Jew 0.01 0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 0.00 HS grad 0.29 0.30 0.29 0.29 0.28 0.30 Some College 0.08 0.07 0.07 0.09 0.07 0.07 College grad 0.14 0.09 0.10 0.14 0.09 0.11

Father education

Missing 0.13 0.18 0.10 0.13 0.14 0.11 HS grad 0.35 0.35 0.38 0.38 0.36 0.38 Some College 0.10 0.09 0.07 0.09 0.07 0.08 College grad 0.09 0.04 0.05 0.08 0.05 0.06

Mother's education

Missing 0.05 0.05 0.05 0.07 0.10 0.06 North Central 0.24 0.27 0.24 0.24 0.22 0.25 South 0.40 0.33 0.41 0.35 0.29 0.39

Region of Residence

West 0.15 0.22 0.20 0.19 0.28 0.22 State Common Law

Marriage 0.34 0.28 0.35 0.33 0.32 0.37 Local Unemployment rate 8.03 8.06 8.36 8.06 7.81 8.36

Note: a. The remaining sample include divorced or widowed, and those who are single after cohabiting. b. For 1988, as data on stocks, bonds and mutual funds is available only since the 1988 round of NLSY79.

Page 32: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

31

0.00

0.10

0.20

0.30

0.40

0.50

0.60

0.70

0.80

0.90

20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43

Age

%

Non-partnered Cohabit Married

Figure 1. Percent of Women with Home Ownership by Family Status

1985-2000 (NLSY79)

0.00

0.10

0.20

0.30

0.40

0.50

0.60

0.70

0.80

0.90

20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43

Age

%

Non-partnered Cohabit Married

Figure 2. Percent of Men with Home Ownership by Family Status:

1985-2000 (NLSY79)

Page 33: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

32

0.00

0.10

0.20

0.30

0.40

0.50

0.60

0.70

0.80

20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42 44

Age

%

Non-partnered Cohabit Married

Figure 3. Percent of Women with Money-assets by Family Status:

1985-2000 (NLSY79)

0.00

0.10

0.20

0.30

0.40

0.50

0.60

0.70

0.80

0.90

20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 36 38 40 42

Age

%

Non-partnered Cohabit Married

Figure 4. Percent of Men with Money-asset by Family Status:

1985-2000 (NLSY79)

Page 34: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

33

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

0.30

23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43

Age

%Non-partnered Cohabit Married

Figure 5. Percent of Women with Financial Investment by Family Status:

1988-2000 (NLSY79)

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

0.30

0.35

0.40

0.45

0.50

20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40

Age

%

Non-partnered Cohabit Married

Figure 6. Percent of Men with Financial Investment by Family Status:

1988-2000 (NLSY79)

Page 35: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

34

Table 4. Determinants of the Rate of Transitions Hazard ratios from Cox Proportional Hazard Model

Women Men Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 1 Model 2

a. Transitions from Non-partnered to Partnered Own house 0.997 0.697 1.308 1.021 (0.03) (2.29)** (3.47)*** (0.18) Have money asset 1.171 1.333 1.313 1.481 (1.86) (2.12)** (3.25)*** (3.29)*** Own stocks & bonds 1.239 1.068 (1.75) (0.45) Hispanic 0.871 1.177 0.730 0.835 (0.92) (1.04) (1.73) (1.40) Black 0.554 0.407 0.893 0.774 (6.20)*** (5.30)*** (1.25) (1.98)** N 11073 6342 14717 8280 b. Transitions from Non-partnered to Cohabiting Own house 1.019 0.710 1.143 0.960 (0.10) (1.29) (0.95) (0.19) Have money asset 0.784 0.916 1.028 1.207 (1.74) (0.40) (0.26) (1.33) Own stocks & bonds 1.041 0.859 (0.16) (0.61) Hispanic 0.710 1.093 0.508 0.483 (1.39) (0.31) (2.80)*** (3.11)*** Black 0.571 0.439 1.343 1.227 (3.43)*** (2.95)*** (2.54)** (1.25) N 11073 6342 14717 8280 c. Transitions from Non-partnered to Married Own house 0.984 0.685 1.416 1.056 (0.12) (2.05)** (3.62)*** (0.39) Have money asset 1.424 1.639 1.567 1.770 (3.51)*** (2.92)*** (4.31)*** (3.72)*** Own stocks & bonds 1.329 1.191 (1.94) (1.16) Hispanic 0.943 1.186 0.896 1.126 (0.38) (0.88) (0.63) (0.75) Black 0.550 0.403 0.654 0.530 (5.36)*** (4.73)*** (3.54)*** (3.70)*** N 11073 6342 14717 8280

Page 36: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

35

Table 4 (Cont’d).

Women Men Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 1 Model 2 d. Transitions from Cohabiting to Married Own house 1.066 1.120 0.972 0.966 (0.64) (0.96) (0.29) (0.33) Have money asset 1.437 1.388 1.831 1.695 (4.15)*** (2.99)*** (7.02)*** (5.05)*** Own stocks & bonds 1.279 1.514 (1.52) (3.23)*** Hispanic 0.718 0.791 0.503 0.463 (2.56)** (1.50) (5.06)*** (4.73)*** Black 0.578 0.562 0.421 0.457 (4.27)*** (3.69)*** (7.33)*** (5.66)*** N 3668 2496 4076 3053 e. Transitions from Unmarried (Non-partnered/Cohabiting) to Married Own house 1.279 1.152 1.416 1.257 (2.96)*** (1.50) (4.84)*** (2.56)** Have money asset 1.336 1.306 1.538 1.513 (4.49)*** (2.93)*** (7.13)*** (4.89)*** Own stocks & bonds 1.153 1.141 (1.25) (1.35) Hispanic 0.750 0.765 0.806 0.811 (3.32)*** (2.26)** (2.59)*** (1.82) Black 0.401 0.439 0.529 0.532 (11.40)*** (7.30)*** (8.68)*** (6.13)*** N 14652 8750 18665 11206

Note: a. Robust z statistics in parentheses b. ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% c. In each specification, control variables include age, age-squared, education, religion, father’s and mother’s education, region of residence, whether or not state recognizes common law marriage, local unemployment rate, and year dummy variables (10 in model 1, and 7 in model 2).

Page 37: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

36

Table 5. F-Statistic for the Joint Significance of Instrumental Variables in the First Stage

Women Men Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 1 Model 2

No. of excluded instruments 18 21 18 21 Transition from Non-partnered Own home 4.22 2.99 3.24 1.95 Have money assets 2.48 3.62 1.93 1.80 Own stocks, bonds 1.64 1.30 Transition from Cohabiting Own home 2.87 2.07 2.51 2.19 Have money assets 2.13 1.64 1.35 1.75 Own stocks, bonds 1.37 1.11 Transitions from unmarried (Non-partnered/cohabiting) Own home 5.97 4.08 5.70 3.03 Have money assets 3.00 3.90 2.16 3.02 Own stocks, bonds 1.96 1.60

Note: a. F-statistic is for a hypothesis that the instrumental variables jointly have no effect. b. Robust standard errors are calculated to account for clustering on each individual.

Page 38: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

37

Table 6. Determinants of the Rate of Transitions Probit and IV Probit Coefficients

Women: Model 1 Women: Model 2 Men: Model 1 Men: Model 2 Variables

Probit IV Probit Probit IV Probit Probit IV Probit Probit IV Probit a. Transitions from Non-partnered to Partnered Own home -0.058 -0.349 -0.024 -1.131 0.108 0.240 0.127 0.733 (0.98) (0.75) (0.36) (1.28) (2.28)** (0.36) (2.22)** (0.77) Have money assets 0.085 -1.930 0.018 0.246 0.133 -0.649 0.074 -0.309 (2.13)** (2.76)*** (0.32) (0.27) (4.13)*** (0.87) (1.63) (0.30) Own stocks, bonds 0.105 -1.118 0.098 -2.497 (1.37) (0.89) (1.57) (1.81) N 11073 11073 6342 6342 14717 14717 8280 8280 J Statistic (Overidentification test) d 8.323 24.517 20.791 18.483 P-value for the J statistic (.939) (.139) (.187) (.424) b. Transitions from Non-partnered to Cohabiting Own home -0.033 -0.134 -0.025 0.065 0.038 0.736 0.114 -0.034 (0.38) (0.22) (0.26) (0.05) (0.58) (1.03) (1.49) (0.03) Have money assets -0.099 0.301 -0.138 1.217 -0.005 -0.714 -0.019 1.511 (1.74) (0.34) (1.68) (0.90) (0.12) (0.71) (0.32) (1.74) Own stocks, bonds -0.005 -2.074 0.006 -0.374 (0.04) (1.34) (0.07) (0.17) N 11073 11073 6342 6342 14717 14717 8280 8280 J Statistic (Overidentification test) d 11.348 19.003 15.976 22.453 P-value for the J statistic (.788) (.392) (.455) (.213)

Page 39: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

38

Table 6 (Cont’d).

Women: Model 1 Women: Model 2 Men: Model 1 Men: Model 2

Variables Probit IV Probit Probit IV Probit Probit IV Probit Probit IV Probit

c. Transitions from Non-partnered to Married Own home -0.060 -0.426 -0.023 -1.636 0.125 -0.683 0.102 0.990 (0.91) (0.69) (0.31) (1.86) (2.33)** (0.90) (1.54) (0.75) Have money assets 0.175 -2.843 0.114 -0.549 0.204 -0.280 0.137 -1.720 (3.89)*** (3.60)*** (1.74) (0.61) (5.32)*** (0.22) (2.49)** (1.42) Own stocks, bonds 0.134 -0.678 0.124 -3.837 (1.61) (0.48) (1.79) (1.84)

N 11073 11073 6342 6342 14717 14717 8280 8280 J Statistic (Overidentification test) d 12.292 17.089 18.292 18.804

P-value for the J statistic (.724) (.517) (.050) (.404)

d. Transitions from Cohabiting to Married Own home 0.098 -1.846 0.067 -1.631 -0.001 -0.210 0.003 -0.820 (1.38) (2.54)** (0.80) (1.95) (0.02) (0.35) (0.05) (0.95) Have money assets 0.227 0.663 0.227 0.777 0.393 -0.698 0.328 -0.102 (3.89)*** (1.15) (3.11)*** (0.84) (7.16)*** (1.08) (4.95)*** (0.09) Own stocks, bonds 0.163 0.086 0.334 -1.105 (1.18) (0.06) (3.19)*** (0.44) N 3668 3668 2496 2496 4076 4076 3053 3053

J Statistic (Overidentification test) d 10.986 11.196 9.757 21.653

P-value for the J statistic (.810) (.886) (.714) (.117)

Page 40: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

39

Table 6 (Cont’d).

Women: Model 1 Women: Model 2 Men: Model 1 Men: Model 2 Variables

Probit IV Probit Probit IV Probit Probit IV Probit Probit IV Probit

e. Transitions from Unmarried (Non-partnered/Cohabiting) to Married Own home 0.096 -0.026 0.095 -0.920 0.164 -0.471 0.158 1.002 (2.02)** (0.05) (1.74) (1.27) (3.92)*** (0.71) (3.23)*** (1.46) Have money assets 0.177 -2.435 0.151 0.598 0.250 -0.574 0.203 -0.789 (5.02)*** (2.72)*** (3.12)*** (1.06) (7.87)*** (0.66) (4.72)*** (0.98) Own stocks, bonds 0.094 -1.359 0.126 -4.358 (1.36) (1.03) (2.21)** (2.53)** N 14652 14652 8750 8750 18665 18665 11206 11206

J Statistic (Overidentification test) d 14.024 17.145 17.215 17.096

P-value for the J statistic (.597) (.513) (.190) (.517)

Note: a. z statistics in parentheses. For probit estimates, robust standard errors are calculated to account for clustering on each individual. For the IV- probit estimates, bootstrapped standard errors are reported. b. ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%

c. In each specification, control variables include Age, age-squared, ethnicity, education, religion, father’s and mother’s education, region of residence, whether or not state recognizes common law marriage, local unemployment rate, and year dummy variables (10 in model 1, and 7 in model 2).

d. The Hansen-Sargan J Statistic is derived from a linear estimate of the binary dependent variable model.

Page 41: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

40

Table 7. Determinants of the Rate of Transition from Unmarried to Married:

Women and Men by Education Probit and IV Probit Coefficients in Model 1

HS or less educated More than HS educated Variables Probit IV Probit Probit IV Probit

a. Women Own house 0.106 0.546 0.085 -0.410 (1.50) (0.90) (1.32) (0.62) Have money asset 0.230 -1.999 0.122 -1.575 (5.09)*** (2.40)** (2.33)** (2.13)** First-stage F statistic Own house 2.95 4.57 Have money asset 1.79 2.95 N 7777 7777 6875 6875 b. Men Own house 0.159 -0.727 0.161 -1.033 (2.76)*** (0.97) (2.65)*** (1.72) Have money asset 0.277 0.644 0.237 -0.289 (7.28)*** (0.67) (4.40)*** (0.43) First-stage F statistic Own house 3.62 3.21 Have money asset 2.17 2.19 N 11505 11505 7160 7160

Note: a. The results reported in this table are estimated from specifications similar to model 1 in Table 6 (includes dummy indicators for homeownership and money assets). b. z statistics in parentheses. Robust standard errors are calculated to account for clustering on each individual. c. ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1%

Page 42: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

41

Appendix

Table A-1. Determinants of the Rate of Transitions Inclusion of Annual Income and Welfare Recipiency as Controls

Hazard ratios from Cox Proportional Hazard Model

Women Men Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 1 Model 2 a. Transitions from Non-partnered to Partnered Own house 0.985 0.689 1.287 0.999 (0.14) (2.36)** (3.25)*** (0.01) Have money asset 1.118 1.215 1.292 1.433 (1.25) (1.39) (3.07)*** (2.99)*** Own stocks & bonds 1.237 1.056 (1.71) (0.38) Annual income 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 (1.64) (0.00) (2.95)*** (2.16)** Welfare recipiency 0.802 0.650 0.820 0.640 (1.90) (1.88) (1.49) (1.72) N 11067 6337 14691 8257 b. Transitions from Non-partnered to Cohabiting Own house 1.019 0.708 1.136 0.950 (0.10) (1.29) (0.90) (0.24) Have money asset 0.782 0.892 1.019 1.181 (1.66) (0.50) (0.18) (1.16) Own stocks & bonds 1.042 0.856 (0.17) (0.63) Annual income 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 (1.26) (0.06) (0.43) (0.44) Welfare recipiency 1.002 0.886 0.849 0.631 (0.01) (0.41) (0.93) (1.70) N 11067 6337 14691 8257 c. Transitions from Non-partnered to Married Own house 0.968 0.674 1.386 1.030 (0.26) (2.15)** (3.38)*** (0.21) Have money asset 1.321 1.434 1.532 1.694 (2.69)*** (2.13)** (4.08)*** (3.42)*** Own stocks & bonds 1.324 1.179 (1.90) (1.09) Annual income 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 (1.74) (0.04) (3.24)*** (2.58)*** Welfare recipiency 0.690 0.534 0.729 0.582 (2.66)*** (2.19)** (1.50) (1.39) N 11067 6337 14691 8257

Page 43: The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the ... · The White Picket Fence Dream: Effects of Assets on the Choice of Family Union I. Introduction There have been dramatic

42

Table A-1 (Cont’d).

Women Men

Variables Model 1 Model 2 Model 1 Model 2 d. Transitions from Cohabiting to Married Own house 1.019 1.090 0.946 0.934 (0.19) (0.71) (0.58) (0.64) Have money asset 1.324 1.351 1.759 1.620 (2.96)*** (2.50)** (6.55)*** (4.59)*** Own stocks & bonds 1.215 1.477 (1.20) (3.03)*** Annual income 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 (2.29)** (1.46) (9.48)*** (7.45)*** Welfare recipiency 0.908 1.066 0.616 0.584 (0.86) (0.46) (2.72)*** (2.51)** N 3665 2494 4070 3047 e. Transitions from Unmarried (Non-partnered/Cohabiting) to Married Own house 1.265 1.147 1.389 1.231 (2.82)*** (1.46) (4.55)*** (2.31)** Have money asset 1.267 1.270 1.496 1.460 (3.62)*** (2.52)** (6.63)*** (4.43)*** Own stocks & bonds 1.154 1.131 (1.26) (1.26) Annual income 1.000 1.000 1.000 1.000 (0.66) (0.50) (4.05)*** (3.18)*** Welfare recipiency 0.782 0.884 0.703 0.705 (2.79)*** (1.09) (2.46)** (1.87) N 14643 8743 18633 11177

Note: a. Robust z statistics in parentheses b. ** significant at 5%; *** significant at 1% c. In each specification, control variables include age, age-squared, ethnicity, education, religion, father’s and mother’s education, region of residence, whether or not state recognizes common law marriage, local unemployment rate, and year dummy variables (10 in model 1 and 3; 7 in model 2 and 4).


Recommended